© 2003 mcgraw-hill ryerson limited the logic of individual choice: the foundation of supply and...

56
© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited The Logic of The Logic of Individual Choice: Individual Choice: The Foundation of The Foundation of Supply and Demand Supply and Demand Chapter 8 Chapter 8

Upload: mark-jefferson

Post on 29-Dec-2015

214 views

Category:

Documents


1 download

TRANSCRIPT

© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited

The Logic of The Logic of Individual Choice:Individual Choice:The Foundation of The Foundation of

Supply and DemandSupply and Demand

Chapter 8Chapter 8

© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.

8 - 2

Utility Theory and Utility Theory and Individual ChoiceIndividual Choice Economists have an answer to the

question of why people behave as they do — self interest. Economists' analysis of individual

choice does not deny individual differences.

© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.

8 - 3

Utility Theory and Utility Theory and Individual ChoiceIndividual Choice Using the simple concept of self-

interest, two things determine what people do:

The pleasure people get from doing or consuming something.

The price of doing or consuming that something.

© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.

8 - 4

Utility Theory and Utility Theory and Individual ChoiceIndividual Choice Price is the market's tool to bring quantity

supplied equal to the quantity demanded.

Changes in price provide incentives for people to change what they are doing.

© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.

8 - 5

Measuring PleasureMeasuring Pleasure

Economists start with a proposition that individuals try to get as much pleasure as possible out of life.

The goods and services we consume provide value (satisfaction) to us.

© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.

8 - 6

Measuring PleasureMeasuring Pleasure Individuals want to maximize the

amount of satisfaction they receive through consuming goods and services.

© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.

8 - 7

Measuring PleasureMeasuring Pleasure

Economists use the concept of utility—the pleasure or satisfaction that one gets from consuming a good or service.

A util is a unit created by economists to “measure” utility.

© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.

8 - 8

UtilityUtility

Utility serves as the basis of economists' analysis of individual choice.

It is personal and individual.

Utility cannot be compared across individuals.

© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.

8 - 9

Total UtilityTotal Utility

Total utility refers to the total satisfaction one gets from consuming a product.

© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.

8 - 10

Marginal UtilityMarginal Utility

Marginal utility refers to the satisfaction one gets from the consumption of one additional unit of a product above and beyond what on has consumed up to that point.

© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.

8 - 11

Total Utility and Total Utility and Marginal UtilityMarginal Utility As additional units are consumed,

marginal utility decreases while total utility increases.

When marginal utility is zero, total utility stops increasing. Beyond this point, marginal utility is negative and total

utility decreases.

© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.

8 - 12

Number of pizza slices

123456789

Total utility

142636445054565654

Marginal utility

14121086420-2

Marginal and Total Marginal and Total Utility, Utility, Fig. 8-1a, p 180Fig. 8-1a, p 180

© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.

8 - 13

Total utility Marginal utility

Slices of pizza per hour

70

60

50

40

30

20

10

01 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9

Slices of pizza per hour

16141210

86420

-2 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9

Marginal and Total Marginal and Total Utility, Utility, Fig. 8-1b and c, p 180Fig. 8-1b and c, p 180

Total utility Marginal utility

Utils Utils

© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.

8 - 14

Diminishing Marginal Diminishing Marginal UtilityUtility The principle of diminishing marginal

utility states that, at some point, the marginal utility received from each additional unit of a good begins to decrease with each additional unit consumed.

© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.

8 - 15

Diminishing Marginal Diminishing Marginal UtilityUtility This principle does not say you do not

enjoy consuming more of a good. It only states that as you consume more of the

good, you enjoy additional units less than you enjoyed the initial units.

© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.

8 - 16

Rational Choice and Rational Choice and Marginal UtilityMarginal Utility The analysis of rational choice begins

with the premise that rational individuals want as much satisfaction as they can get from their available income.

Rational means that people prefer more to less and will make choices that give them as much satisfaction as possible.

© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.

8 - 17

Rational ChoicesRational Choices

In making choices, essentially what you are doing is buying units of utility.

Any choice (for the same amount of money) that does not give you as many units of utility as possible is an irrational choice.

© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.

8 - 18

Rational choicesRational choices

Since you want to get the most for your money, you make those choices that have the highest units of utility per dollar spent.

© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.

8 - 19

Maximizing UtilityMaximizing Utility

Total utility is maximized when marginal utility per dollar spent of two goods is equal.

y

y

x

x

P

MU

P

MU=

© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.

8 - 20

Maximizing UtilityMaximizing Utility

If:

y

y

x

x

P

MU

P

MU

Choose to consume an additional unit of good x.

© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.

8 - 21

Maximizing UtilityMaximizing Utility

If:

y

y

x

x

P

MU

P

MU

Choose to consume an additional unit of good y.

© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.

8 - 22

Maximizing UtilityMaximizing Utility

By substituting the marginal utilities and prices of goods into these formulas, you can always decide which good it makes more sense to consume.

Consume the one with the highest marginal utility per dollar.

© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.

8 - 23

Maximizing Utility and Maximizing Utility and EquilibriumEquilibrium When the ratios of the marginal utility to

price of goods are equal, you are maximizing utility.

© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.

8 - 24

Maximizing UtilityMaximizing Utility

If:

y

y

x

x

P

MU

P

MU

You’re in equilibrium. You cannot increase your utility by

adjusting your choices.

© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.

8 - 25

Maximizing Utility, Maximizing Utility, Table 8-1, Table 8-1,

p 182p 182

Q

01234567

TU

020323841413626

MU

2012

630

-5-10

MU/P

1063

1.50

-2.5-5

Q

01234567

TU

029465356575753

MU

2917

7310

-4

MU/P

2917

7310

-4

Hamburgers (P = $2) Ice Cream (P = $1)

© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.

8 - 26

Maximizing Utility, Maximizing Utility, Table 8-2, Table 8-2,

p 183p 183

Total $ spent

Purchase? MU/P MU

$1 1 ice cream cone 29 29

$2 2nd ice cream cone 17 17

$4 1 hamburger 10 20

$5 3rd ice cream cone 7 7

$7 2nd hamburger 6 12

$9 3rd hamburger 3 6

$10 4th ice cream cone 3 3

Total utility = 94 utils

© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.

8 - 27

Rational Choice and Rational Choice and Marginal UtilityMarginal Utility The same principle applies if more than

two goods are consumed: If MUx/Px > MUz/Pz, consume more of

good x. If MUy/Py > MUz/Pz, consume more of

good y.

© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.

8 - 28

Rational Choice and Rational Choice and Marginal UtilityMarginal Utility The general utility-maximizing rule is

that you are maximizing utility when the marginal utilities per dollar are equal across all goods you consume.

© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.

8 - 29

Rational Choice and Rational Choice and Marginal UtilityMarginal Utility

z

z

y

y

x

x

P

MU

P

MU

P

MU

When you are maximizing utility.

© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.

8 - 30

Rational Choice and Rational Choice and Marginal UtilityMarginal Utility When this principle is met, the

consumer is in equilibrium. The cost per additional unit of utility is

equal for all goods and the consumer is as well off as it is possible to be.

© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.

8 - 31

Rational Choice and Rational Choice and Marginal UtilityMarginal Utility The rule does not say that the rational

consumer should consume a good until its marginal utility reaches zero.

Consumers do not have enough money to reach this point, as they face an income constraint.

© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.

8 - 32

Opportunity CostOpportunity Cost

Opportunity cost is the benefit forgone of the next-best alternative. It is essentially the marginal utility per

dollar you forgo. To say MUx/Px > MUy/Py is to say that the

opportunity cost of not consuming good x is greater than the opportunity cost of not consuming good y.

So we consume x.

© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.

8 - 33

Opportunity CostOpportunity Cost

When all the marginal utilities per dollar spent are equal, the opportunity cost of all the alternatives are equal.

© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.

8 - 34

Rational Choice and the Rational Choice and the Laws of DemandLaws of Demand The principle of rational choice leads to

the law of demand. When the price of a good goes up, the

marginal utility per dollar from that good goes down and we demand less of it.

© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.

8 - 35

Rational Choice and the Rational Choice and the Law of DemandLaw of Demand Initially MUx/Px = MUy/Py When the price of good y goes up, then

MUx/Px > MUy/Py. Our condition for maximizing utility is no

longer satisfied. So when the price of a good goes up, we

would choose to consume less of that good.

© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.

8 - 36

Rational Choice and the Rational Choice and the Law of DemandLaw of Demand Our utility maximizing rule is no longer

satisfied We should now buy more of good x

© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.

8 - 37

Rational Choice and the Rational Choice and the Law of DemandLaw of Demand MUx decreases as we buy more x

(diminishing marginal utility) and MUy increases as we buy less of the

good y We are back at a point where MUx/Px =

MUy/Py and we maximize utility (but we now consume less x and more y than before the price increase).

© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.

8 - 38

Rational Choice and the Rational Choice and the Law of DemandLaw of Demand Quantity demanded rises as price falls,

other things constant.

Quantity demanded falls as price rises, other things constant.

© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.

8 - 39

Rational Choice and the Rational Choice and the Law of DemandLaw of Demand The above shows the relationship

between marginal utility and the price we are willing to pay.

© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.

8 - 40

Rational Choice and the Rational Choice and the Law of DemandLaw of Demand Since our demand for a good is an

expression of our willingness to pay for it, quantity demanded is related to marginal utility.

© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.

8 - 41

Maximizing Utility Maximizing Utility Using Indifference Using Indifference CurvesCurves Economists often use graphic

representation of the consumer’s choice.

The problem consists of two parts: The budget constraint (or the income

constraint) and Indifference curves, which represent

utility

© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.

8 - 42

Graphing the Budget Graphing the Budget LineLine The budget constraint represents all

the combinations of two goods that a person can afford to buy with given income.

The budget constraint is also called the income constraint, or budget line.

© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.

8 - 43

Jaz’s Budget LineJaz’s Budget Line

Jaz has $10 and buys chocolate and pop whose prices are $1 and $0.50 respectively.

© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.

8 - 44

Graphing the Budget Graphing the Budget Line,Line, Fig. 8-2, p 187 Fig. 8-2, p 187

0

2

4

6

8

10

2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 18 20 22

Chocolate bars

Cans of pop

Slope= - Ppop/Pchocolate

= - ½Income = $10

© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.

8 - 45

The Indifference CurveThe Indifference Curve

An indifference curve represents all the combinations of the two goods amongst which an individual is indifferent.

© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.

8 - 46

The Indifference CurveThe Indifference Curve

Jaz is equally as well off (her utility is the same) from consuming bundles A, B, C, D or E.

© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.

8 - 47

Jaz’s Indifference Jaz’s Indifference Curve,Curve, Fig. 8-3a, p 188 Fig. 8-3a, p 188

0

4

8

12

16

20

2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 18 20 22

Chocolate bars

Cans of pop

|Slope|= MUpop/MUchocolate bars

= MRS of pop for chocolate bars

U

ABC

DE

Indifference curve

© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.

8 - 48

The Indifference CurveThe Indifference Curve

The slope of the indifference curve is called the marginal rate of substitution (MRS)

The slope is bowed inward, indicating that MRS is decreasing as Jaz’s bundles contain more of the good on the horizontal axis.

© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.

8 - 49

The Indifference CurveThe Indifference Curve

The reason for decreasing MRS is that as Jaz gets more and more of one good, she is willing to give up lots of it to get more of the relatively scarce good.

|Slope| = MUpop/Muchocolate = MRS

© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.

8 - 50

A Map of Indifference A Map of Indifference CurvesCurves The bundles of goods forming

indifference curve U3 give Jaz higher utility than bundles along U2,

While the bundles of goods forming indifference curve U1 give Jaz less utility than bundles along U2.

© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.

8 - 51

A Map of Indifference A Map of Indifference Curves,Curves, Fig. 8-3b, p 188 Fig. 8-3b, p 188

0

4

8

12

16

20

2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 18 20 22

Chocolate bars

Cans of pop

U2

ABC

DE

U1

U3

© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.

8 - 52

Combining Indifference Combining Indifference Curves and Budget LineCurves and Budget Line The goal for a consumer is to get as

high on an indifference curve as possible, given her income constraint.

More is preferred to less.

© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.

8 - 53

Combining Indifference Combining Indifference Curves and Budget Curves and Budget Line,Line, Fig. 8-4, p 189 Fig. 8-4, p 189

0

4

8

12

16

20

2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 18 20 22

Chocolate bars

Cans of pop

U2

U1

U3

Slope= -MUpop/Muchocolate bars

Slope= -Ppop/Pchocolate barsD

CG

K

© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.

8 - 54

Combining Indifference Combining Indifference Curves and Budget LineCurves and Budget Line At the point D, Jaz maximizes her utility

when:

MUpop/Muchocolate bars = Ppop/Pchocolate bars

© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.

8 - 55

Combining Indifference Combining Indifference Curves and Budget LineCurves and Budget Line In other words, utility is maximized

when the slopes of the budget constraint and the indifference curve are equal.

© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited

The Logic of The Logic of Individual Choice:Individual Choice:The Foundation of The Foundation of

Supply and DemandSupply and Demand

End of Chapter 8End of Chapter 8