© 2013 pearson. how can we limit climate change?

46
© 2013 Pearson

Upload: georgia-wilkinson

Post on 27-Dec-2015

215 views

Category:

Documents


1 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: © 2013 Pearson. How can we limit climate change?

© 2013 Pearson

Page 2: © 2013 Pearson. How can we limit climate change?

© 2013 Pearson

How can we limit climate change?

Page 3: © 2013 Pearson. How can we limit climate change?

© 2013 Pearson

10When you have completed your study of this chapter, you will be able to

1 Explain why negative externalities lead to inefficient overproduction and how property rights, pollution charges, and taxes can achieve a more efficient outcome.

2Explain why positive externalities lead to inefficient underproduction and how public provision, subsidies, and vouchers can achieve a more efficient outcome.

CHAPTER CHECKLIST

Externalities

Page 4: © 2013 Pearson. How can we limit climate change?

© 2013 Pearson

An externality is a cost or a benefit that arises from:• Production that falls on someone other than the

producer• Consumption that falls on someone other than the

consumer

Negative externality

A production or consumption activity that creates an external cost.

Positive externality

A production or consumption activity that creates an external benefit.

EXTERNALITIES IN OUR DAILY LIVES

Page 5: © 2013 Pearson. How can we limit climate change?

© 2013 Pearson

Four types of externalities:

• Negative production externalities

• Positive production externalities

• Negative consumption externalities

• Positive consumption externalities

EXTERNALITIES IN OUR DAILY LIVES

Page 6: © 2013 Pearson. How can we limit climate change?

© 2013 Pearson

Negative Production Externalities

Pollution is the major example of this type of externality.

Others are noise and congestion.

Positive Production Externalities

Example: Orchards provide positive production externalities to honey producers, who in turn provide positive production externalities to orchards.

EXTERNALITIES IN OUR DAILY LIVES

Page 7: © 2013 Pearson. How can we limit climate change?

© 2013 Pearson

Negative Consumption Externalities

Smoking tobacco in a confined space

Noisy parties

Positive Consumption Externalities

Education is a major example of this type of externality.

Others are a flu vaccination and restoration of an historic building

EXTERNALITIES IN OUR DAILY LIVES

Page 8: © 2013 Pearson. How can we limit climate change?

© 2013 Pearson

10.1 NEGATIVE EXTERNALITIES: POLLUTION

Private Costs and Social Costs

Marginal private cost is the cost of producing an additional unit of a good or service that is borne by the producer of that good or service.

Marginal external cost is the cost of producing an additional unit of a good or service that falls on people other than the producer.

Page 9: © 2013 Pearson. How can we limit climate change?

© 2013 Pearson

10.1 NEGATIVE EXTERNALITIES: POLLUTION

Marginal social cost is the marginal cost incurred by the entire society—by the producer and by everyone else on whom the cost falls.

Marginal social cost (MSC) is the sum of marginal private cost (MC) and marginal external cost.

MSC = MC + Marginal external cost

Page 10: © 2013 Pearson. How can we limit climate change?

© 2013 Pearson

10.1 NEGATIVE EXTERNALITIES: POLLUTION

Figure 10.1 shows the relationship between cost and output.

When output is 4,000 tons of chemicals a month:

1. Marginal privatecost is $100 a ton.

2. Marginal externalcost is $125 a ton.

3. Marginal social cost is $225 a ton.

Page 11: © 2013 Pearson. How can we limit climate change?

© 2013 Pearson

10.1 NEGATIVE EXTERNALITIES: POLLUTION

Production and Pollution: How Much?

When an industry is unregulated, the amount of pollution it creates depends on the market equilibrium price and the quantity of the good produced.

If the industry creates an external cost, the market equilibrium is inefficient. Too much of the good is produced.

Page 12: © 2013 Pearson. How can we limit climate change?

© 2013 Pearson

10.1 NEGATIVE EXTERNALITIES: POLLUTION

3. Marginal benefit.

Figure 10.2 shows inefficiency with an external cost.

2. Marginal social cost exceeds ...

1.The market is in equilibrium at a price of $100 a ton and 4,000 tons of chemical a month is inefficient.

Page 13: © 2013 Pearson. How can we limit climate change?

© 2013 Pearson

10.1 NEGATIVE EXTERNALITIES: POLLUTION

4. The efficient quantity is 2,000 tons of chemical, where marginal social cost equals marginal benefit.

5. The gray triangle shows the deadweight loss created by the pollution externality.

Page 14: © 2013 Pearson. How can we limit climate change?

© 2013 Pearson

10.1 NEGATIVE EXTERNALITIES: POLLUTION

Property Rights

Property rights are legally established titles to the ownership, use, and disposal of factors of production and goods and services that are enforceable in the courts.

Page 15: © 2013 Pearson. How can we limit climate change?

© 2013 Pearson

10.1 NEGATIVE EXTERNALITIES: POLLUTION

Figure 10.3 shows how property rights achieve an efficient outcome.

1. With property rights, the MC curve that excludes the cost of pollution shows only part of the producers’ marginal cost.

Page 16: © 2013 Pearson. How can we limit climate change?

© 2013 Pearson

10.1 NEGATIVE EXTERNALITIES: POLLUTION

2. The marginal private cost curve includes the cost of pollution, and the supply curve is S = MC.

Page 17: © 2013 Pearson. How can we limit climate change?

© 2013 Pearson

10.1 NEGATIVE EXTERNALITIES: POLLUTION

4. Marginal social cost equals marginal benefit.

3. Market equilibrium is at a price of $150 a ton and a quantity of 2,000 tons of chemical a month and is efficient because…

Page 18: © 2013 Pearson. How can we limit climate change?

© 2013 Pearson

10.1 NEGATIVE EXTERNALITIES: POLLUTION

The Coase Theorem

Coase theorem is the proposition that if property rights exist, only a small number of parties are involved, and transactions costs are low, then private transactions are efficient and the outcome is not affected by who is assigned the property right.

Transactions costs are the opportunity costs of conducting a transaction.

Page 19: © 2013 Pearson. How can we limit climate change?

© 2013 Pearson

10.1 NEGATIVE EXTERNALITIES: POLLUTION

Application of the Coase Theorem• If factories own homes and river, the rent people willingly pay decreases as the amount of pollution increases.

• If homeowners own the river, factories must pay homeowners for any pollution, and the more they pollute, the more they pay.

• Regardless of who owns the river, so long as someone owns it, the factories bear the cost of pollution, and the quantity of production and pollution are efficient.

Page 20: © 2013 Pearson. How can we limit climate change?

© 2013 Pearson

10.1 NEGATIVE EXTERNALITIES: POLLUTION

Government Actions in the Face of External Costs

The three main methods that governments can use to achieve a more efficient allocation of resources in the presence of external costs are

• Pollution limits• Pollution charges or taxes• Marketable permits (cap-and-trade)

Page 21: © 2013 Pearson. How can we limit climate change?

© 2013 Pearson

10.1 NEGATIVE EXTERNALITIES: POLLUTION

Pollution Limits

A pollution limit seeks an efficient outcome by placing a quantity limit on a polluting activity.

The 1990 Clean Air Act administered by the Environmental Protection Agency (EPA) employs this method.

Page 22: © 2013 Pearson. How can we limit climate change?

© 2013 Pearson

10.1 NEGATIVE EXTERNALITIES: POLLUTION

Figure 10.4 shows the effects of a pollution limit.

1. A pollution limit is imposed that restricts production to the efficient quantity.

2. The efficient market equilibrium pollution limit is achieved.

Page 23: © 2013 Pearson. How can we limit climate change?

© 2013 Pearson

10.1 NEGATIVE EXTERNALITIES: POLLUTION

3. The market price is equal to marginal benefit, MB, and marginal social benefit, MSB.

4. Because the price exceeds marginal cost, producers get a producer surplus equal to the area of the blue rectangle.

Page 24: © 2013 Pearson. How can we limit climate change?

© 2013 Pearson

10.1 NEGATIVE EXTERNALITIES: POLLUTION

Pollution Charges or Taxes

Pollution charges or pollution taxes confront the producers with the external cost of pollution and provide an incentive to seek technologies that are less polluting.

To work out the pollution charge or pollution tax that achieves efficiency, the regulator needs a lot of information about the industry, which is generally not available.

Page 25: © 2013 Pearson. How can we limit climate change?

© 2013 Pearson

10.1 NEGATIVE EXTERNALITIES: POLLUTION

Marketable Pollution Permits (Cap-and-Trade)

A marketable pollution permit seeks an efficient outcome by assigning or selling pollution rights to each producer in an industry.

Producers can buy and sell permits in the market.

Producers with a low marginal cost of reducing pollution will sell permits and producers with a high marginal cost of reducing pollution will buy.

Producers will buy and sell permits until their marginal cost of pollution equals the market price of a permit.

Page 26: © 2013 Pearson. How can we limit climate change?

© 2013 Pearson

10.1 NEGATIVE EXTERNALITIES: POLLUTION

1. A pollution charge or tax is imposed that is equal to the marginal external cost of pollution.

Figure 10.5 shows the effects of a pollution charge or pollution tax.

Page 27: © 2013 Pearson. How can we limit climate change?

© 2013 Pearson

10.1 NEGATIVE EXTERNALITIES: POLLUTION

The supply curve becomes the marginal private cost curve, MC, plus the tax—the curve labeled S = MC + tax.

Because the charge or tax equals the marginal external cost, the MSC curve becomes the supply curve.

Page 28: © 2013 Pearson. How can we limit climate change?

© 2013 Pearson

10.1 NEGATIVE EXTERNALITIES: POLLUTION

2. Market equilibrium at a price of $150 a ton and 2,000 tons of chemical a month is efficient because…

3. Marginal social cost equals marginal benefit.

Page 29: © 2013 Pearson. How can we limit climate change?

© 2013 Pearson

10.1 NEGATIVE EXTERNALITIES: POLLUTION

4. The government collects revenue equal to the area of the purple rectangle.

Page 30: © 2013 Pearson. How can we limit climate change?

© 2013 Pearson

10.2 POSITIVE EXTERNALITIES: EDUCATION

Private Benefits and Social Benefits

Marginal private benefit is the benefit of an additional unit of a good or service that the consumer of that good or service receives.

Marginal external benefit is the benefit of an additional unit of a good or service that people other than the consumer of the good or service enjoy.

Page 31: © 2013 Pearson. How can we limit climate change?

© 2013 Pearson

10.2 POSITIVE EXTERNALITIES: EDUCATION

Marginal social benefit is the marginal benefit enjoyed by society—by the consumer of a good or service and by everyone else who benefits from it.

Marginal social benefit (MSB) is the sum of marginal private benefit (MB) and marginal external benefit.

MSB = MB + Marginal external benefit

Page 32: © 2013 Pearson. How can we limit climate change?

© 2013 Pearson

10.2 POSITIVE EXTERNALITIES: EDUCATION

Figure 10.6 shows an external benefit.

When 15 million studentsattend college:

2. Marginal external benefit is $15,000 per student.

1. Marginal private benefit is $10,000 per student.

3. Marginal social benefit is $25,000 per student.

Page 33: © 2013 Pearson. How can we limit climate change?

© 2013 Pearson

10.2 POSITIVE EXTERNALITIES: EDUCATION

Figure 10.7 shows inefficiency with an external benefit.

1. Market equilibrium is at a tuition of $15,000 a year and 7.5 million students and is inefficient because …

3. Marginal cost.

2. Marginal social benefit exceeds …

Page 34: © 2013 Pearson. How can we limit climate change?

© 2013 Pearson

10.2 POSITIVE EXTERNALITIES: EDUCATION

5. The gray triangle shows the deadweight loss created because too few students enroll in college.

4. The efficient number of students is 15 million.

Page 35: © 2013 Pearson. How can we limit climate change?

© 2013 Pearson

10.2 POSITIVE EXTERNALITIES: EDUCATION

Government Actions In the Face of External Benefits

Three devices that governments can use to achieve a more efficient allocation of resources in the presence of external benefits:

• Public provision• Private subsidies• Vouchers

Page 36: © 2013 Pearson. How can we limit climate change?

© 2013 Pearson

10.2 POSITIVE EXTERNALITIES: EDUCATION

Public provision is the production of a good or service by a public authority that receives the bulk of its revenue from the government.

A subsidy is a payment that the government makes to private producers to cover part of the costs of production.

A voucher is a token that the government provides to households that can be used to buy specified goods or services.

Page 37: © 2013 Pearson. How can we limit climate change?

© 2013 Pearson

10.2 POSITIVE EXTERNALITIES: EDUCATION

Figure 10.8 shows how public provision can achieve an efficient outcome.

1. Marginal social benefit equals marginal cost with 15 million students enrolled in college.

2. The efficient quantity.

3. Tuition is $10,000 per year.

4. Taxpayers cover the remaining $15,000 of marginal cost per student.

Public Provision

Page 38: © 2013 Pearson. How can we limit climate change?

© 2013 Pearson

10.2 POSITIVE EXTERNALITIES: EDUCATION

Figure 10.9 showshow a subsidy achieves an efficient outcome of 15 million students.

1. A $15,000 subsidy per student shifts the supply curve toS = MC – subsidy.

2. The dollar price is $10,000 a student.

Private Subsidies

Page 39: © 2013 Pearson. How can we limit climate change?

© 2013 Pearson

10.2 POSITIVE EXTERNALITIES: EDUCATION

4. Marginal social benefit equals marginal cost.

3. The market equilibrium is efficient with 15 million students enrolled in college.

Page 40: © 2013 Pearson. How can we limit climate change?

© 2013 Pearson

10.2 POSITIVE EXTERNALITIES: EDUCATION

Vouchers

Figure 10.10 shows how vouchers can achieve an efficient outcome.

The MSB curve becomes the demand curve because…

1. With vouchers, buyers are willing to pay MB plus the value of the voucher.

Page 41: © 2013 Pearson. How can we limit climate change?

© 2013 Pearson

10.2 POSITIVE EXTERNALITIES: EDUCATION

3. Price, marginal social benefit, and marginal cost are equal.

2. Market equilibrium is efficient with 15 million students enrolled.

4. Tuition equals the dollar price of $10,000 plus the value of the voucher.

Page 42: © 2013 Pearson. How can we limit climate change?

© 2013 Pearson

How Can We Limit Climate Change?

The average temperature of the Earth is rising and

so is the atmospheric concentration of carbon dioxide, CO2.

The figure shows these upward trends.

Page 43: © 2013 Pearson. How can we limit climate change?

© 2013 Pearson

Scientists debate the contribution of human economic activity to these trends, but most believe it to be a major source.

Economists debate the costs and benefits of alternative ways of slowing CO2 and other greenhouse gas emissions, but most favor some action.

Economists agree that lowering greenhouse gas emissions requires incentives to change.

How Can We Limit Climate Change?

Page 44: © 2013 Pearson. How can we limit climate change?

© 2013 Pearson

One idea is to cap emissions and issue tradeable emissions permits, a system called cap-and-trade.

Carbon emission permits are already priced on a global carbon trading market.

American Clean Energy and Security Act of 2009 would use a cap-and-trade scheme.

With 2005 levels as the base, emissions would be capped at 97 percent by 2012, 83 percent by 2020, 58 percent by 2030, and 17 percent by 2050.

The cost of the scheme would be about $175 per household per year.

How Can We Limit Climate Change?

Page 45: © 2013 Pearson. How can we limit climate change?

© 2013 Pearson

Another incentive might be a hike in the tax on gasoline.

Americans pay a much lower gas tax than Europeans pay.

The figure shows the stark difference between the United States and the United Kingdom.

How Can We Limit Climate Change?

Page 46: © 2013 Pearson. How can we limit climate change?

© 2013 Pearson

Why don’t we have more aggressive caps and stronger incentives to encourage a larger reduction in emissions?

There are three reasons.

First, many people don’t accept the scientific evidence that emissions produce global warming.

Second, the costs are certain and would be borne now, while the benefits would come many years in the future.

Third, if current trends persist, by 2050, three quarters of carbon pollution will come not from the United States but from the developing economies.

How Can We Limit Climate Change?