1 poverty measurement an introduction paolo verme

73
1 Poverty Measurement An Introduction Paolo Verme

Upload: roberta-beasley

Post on 27-Dec-2015

225 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: 1 Poverty Measurement An Introduction Paolo Verme

1

Poverty Measurement

An Introduction

Paolo Verme

Page 2: 1 Poverty Measurement An Introduction Paolo Verme

2

Basic Concepts

Page 3: 1 Poverty Measurement An Introduction Paolo Verme

3

Measuring Welfare

Two Approaches:

Welfarist approach. This derives from orthodox economics and the theory of revealed preferences. Individuals are the best judges of their needs and express their needs through consumption. Measuring consumption and consumption choices reveals individual preferences and utility.

Non Welfarist approaches. There are two approaches both developed by Sen as a critique to orthodox economics.

– Basic needs or functionings. Individuals need to achieve a minimum set of basic needs or functionings to be considered as non poor.

– Capabilities. Individuals need to have the capacity to reach a minimum set of functionings irrespective of whether they actually make use of these functionings or not (freedom of choice).

Page 4: 1 Poverty Measurement An Introduction Paolo Verme

4

Welfare in Orthodox Economic Theory

Happiness = Utility = Welfare

How to measure utility? Revealed preferences.

I = C (present consumption) + S (future consumption)

There is no distinction between income, consumption or expenditure

The objective is to maximise utility selecting the best consumption bundle under a budget constraint.

Page 5: 1 Poverty Measurement An Introduction Paolo Verme

5

Welfare in Orthodox Economic Theory

Quantity good A

Quantitiy good B

Budget Constraint

100

50

ΔA

ΔB

Price Ratio = ΔA/ ΔB

Indifference curve

Page 6: 1 Poverty Measurement An Introduction Paolo Verme

6

Welfare According to Sen

Poverty is the inability to reach a Minimum Standard of Living.

Page 7: 1 Poverty Measurement An Introduction Paolo Verme

7

Welfare According to Sen

What is the inability to reach…? It is the lack of capacity to obtain the minimum living standards. However, people are different and have different needs, opportunities, functionalities and capabilities.

Needs. Two persons may be have different needs. A person who weighs 150 kgs. has different nutritional needs from a person that weighs 60 kgs.

Opportunities. Two persons may have the same, needs and abilities but different opportunities because of discrimination or chance.

Functionings. Functionalities is when opportunities meet abilities. It is the capacity to exploit opportunities. One disabled person and one able person have different functionalities vis-à-vis the same opportunity of public transport.

Capabilities. Capabilities are the set of functionalities of which a person disposes of. The more the better, even if some functionalities are not used.

=> How to adjust the welfare measure to individual functionalities is one of the objective of this course (welfare adjustments).

Page 8: 1 Poverty Measurement An Introduction Paolo Verme

8

Welfare According to Sen

What is a minimum standard of living? It is a concept generally defined by countries and based on normative and positive criteria.

Value judgments about what is important for living (normative). Ex: Including or excluding a TV set from the minimum consumption basket.

Scientific notions about what is necessary for living (positive). Ex: establishing a minimum amount of daily calories necessary for survival.

=> How we define these minimum standards is one objective of this course (Poverty Lines).

Page 9: 1 Poverty Measurement An Introduction Paolo Verme

9

Welfarist or non Welfarist Approach?

In practice, when we measure poverty with HBSs, we use components of both approaches.

We are interested in the notion of minimum standards (basic needs) and will attempt to measure minimum standards with different methodologies.

We are also interested in functionings. We will adjust our measure of welfare to individual needs.

We recognize that individuals have many functionings and that welfare is multi-dimentional. However, in this course, we limit ourselves to the study of one dimension, income or consumption.

We measure welfare with consumption accepting de facto the notion of revealed preferences put forward in orthodox economics.

Page 10: 1 Poverty Measurement An Introduction Paolo Verme

10

The components of a poverty analysis

Who is poor (poverty measurement) => methodologies

What are the characteristics of the poor (poverty profile) => statistics

Where are the poor (poverty mapping) => spatial analysis

Why are the poor poor (causes of poverty) => econometrics

What can be done about the poor (pro-poor policies) => PRSP

=> This course focuses on poverty measurement

Page 11: 1 Poverty Measurement An Introduction Paolo Verme

11

Tools for Poverty Measurement

Measurement instrument: Household Budget Survey

Welfare measure: Income, consumption, expenditure

Welfare adjustments: Prices, Household composition and Economies of scale

Welfare threshold: Poverty lines

Welfare statistics: Poverty indexes and their decompositions

=> In the next sections, we explore these tools one by one.

Page 12: 1 Poverty Measurement An Introduction Paolo Verme

12

The Household Budget SurveyA Note on Strata, Clusters and Weights

Page 13: 1 Poverty Measurement An Introduction Paolo Verme

13

The Household Budget Survey

From Population to Sample:

Population

Strata

Clusters

Sample

From Sample to Population:

Population Weights

Page 14: 1 Poverty Measurement An Introduction Paolo Verme

14

From Population to Sample

Population Sample (ex. 1% population)

Strata (ex. Urban) Strata (ex. Rural)

Clusters (ex. Towns X, Y)Clusters (ex: Villages X,

Y)

PSU (ex. 50 HH) PSU (ex. 50 HH)

Page 15: 1 Poverty Measurement An Introduction Paolo Verme

15

From Sample to Population

Population Sample Selec. Prob. Weight Population

Urban (Towns) 6000 300 0.05 20 6000

Rural (Villages) 4000 800 0.2 5 4000

Total 10000 1100 10000

A Poverty analysis which ignores population weights, is an analysis of the sample, not the population. Even if we calculate only a mean, we need to use weights. Stata provides simple ways to do it with most commands (not all). In stata, population weights are described as ‘pweight’ or ‘fweight’. Remember: A statistics from the sample is only an estimate of the population statistics.

Page 16: 1 Poverty Measurement An Introduction Paolo Verme

16

Choosing a Measure of Welfare

Page 17: 1 Poverty Measurement An Introduction Paolo Verme

17

Measuring Welfare with HBSs

HBSs measure income, expenditure and sometimes savings, they do not measure consumption.

W=WelfareI=IncomeS=SavingsE=ExpenditureC=Consumption

I=C+SW=I?C=E?W=C?W=E?W=S?

Self-productionSelf-consumption

Durable goods Inter-temporal consumption

Page 18: 1 Poverty Measurement An Introduction Paolo Verme

18

How Good is Income?

It varies according to:– Seasons– Life-cycle

Likely to be poorly reported because:– Illicit activities– Informal income (tax evasion)– Fear– Gross Vs. Net income– Recall bias

Page 19: 1 Poverty Measurement An Introduction Paolo Verme

19

How Good is Expenditure?

Better than income because:

Less vulnerable to seasonality

Less vulnerable to life-cycle

Closer to the utility that people effectively extract from income

Less vulnerable to measurement errors because respondents have less reasons to lie

For the poor, by definition, most of income is consumed (little savings, access to credits, little capital goods)

Page 20: 1 Poverty Measurement An Introduction Paolo Verme

20

How Good is Expenditure?However:

The list of expenditure items is much larger than incomes

Households do not report properly certain consumption items such as alcohol, cigarettes, gambling, prostitution, drugs which may consume considerable amounts of income

Some consumption items are often neglected such as small, recurrent or irrelevant purchases.

Seasonality also affects consumption, especially the structure of consumption

Consumption includes durable goods such as a TV set or a stock of flour for the winter

Some purchases are very rare such as a flat and last long periods of time

Page 21: 1 Poverty Measurement An Introduction Paolo Verme

21

From Expenditure to Consumption

Expenditure and consumption are different:

We do not consume everything that we buy. Some purchased goods are wasted before we consume them. Very few HBS measure HH waste. Some other goods are bought and donated to other people. Donations are often but not always measured in HBS. We buy some goods that we may consume in subsequent periods.

We consume some of the things that we do not buy. We consume some goods that we produce. Self-consumption is usually measured in HBS. We consume some goods that are donated to us. Donations are often but not always measured in HBS. We consume goods that we bought in previous periods such as durable goods.

Page 22: 1 Poverty Measurement An Introduction Paolo Verme

22

From Expenditure to Consumption

In substance, we measure consumption by measuring expenditure and adjust this measure with self-production, donations, amortization, and other information that may be present in the HBS. In particular, we adjust for:

– Self-consumption (HH diary)

– Rents (Estimates)

– Durable goods (Depreciation)

– Net donations in kind (Received donations-donations made)

Page 23: 1 Poverty Measurement An Introduction Paolo Verme

23

Rent Imputation

Rent is part of expenditure and contributes to people’s welfare. Rents are registered for those who pay rent but do not appear for the owners of flats or houses. We need to calculate a fictitious rent for the owners of properities. There are many techniques to do this. One is with a simple econometric procedure as follows:

A) Estimate how rents vary according to the property characteristics of tenants:

Rent of tenants=a+b*(Properties characteristics)+u

B) Predict rent for all:

Rent of all=E(a)+E(b)*(Properties characteristics)

C) Use the predicted rent for the owners as imputed rent.

Page 24: 1 Poverty Measurement An Introduction Paolo Verme

24

Imputation of Durable Goods

Durable goods are purchsed occasionally but provide welfare for extended periods of time. We need to spread the cost of th durable good over the life of the good. This is the same process such as amortization of durable goods in companies. In principle we should consider:

– Change of value of the durable good (depreciation)– Opportunity cost of investment (foregone income of alternative investment)

Example:• I bought a TV set for 250 USD last year and this year is worth 190$.• 250 USD in a bank have a return of 10%• The total cost of the televisor for this year has been:

250-190=60+(250*0.1)=85 USD

Alternatively, we could simply attribute to the purchased good a standard duration in years and divide the cost of the good for its duration taking inflation into account.

The problem with such imputation is not about methodology but information. We need to know the purchase cost, inflation, duration of the good, present value and similar information which are not always available in the HBS we dispose of.

Page 25: 1 Poverty Measurement An Introduction Paolo Verme

25

Estimates of self-consumption

Especially in rural areas, self-consumption can represent an important share of the total HH consumption.

First, we need to have a HBS which measures self-consumption.

Second, we need to attribute a value to self-consumption via market prices. The issue is what are the relevant market prices to consider given that food prices may be very variable across seasons and locations.

Third self-consumption has a cost in terms of agricultural inputs. If we buy seeds or fodder this is accounted for as expenditure and included into consumption. Including into consumption the total market price of grains produced with the seeds bought and consumed or estimatting the value of cattles produced with the fodder bought and consumed would over-estimate total consumption. We add the value of agricultural inputs to the value of the final product.

The household that produces goods and services should be considered as an enterprise and treated economically and financially as such. This means that only the value added which is consumed should be considered. The most sophisticated HBS have entire sections dedicated to self-production and self-consumption.

Page 26: 1 Poverty Measurement An Introduction Paolo Verme

26

Adjusting Consumption for Welfare Comparisons

Page 27: 1 Poverty Measurement An Introduction Paolo Verme

27

Properties of a Welfare Measure

We have established that consumption may be the best measure of welfare we can use and we have adjusted consumption with the imputation of rents, durable goods and self-consumption.

Is household total consumption sufficient to compare individuals, households or larger communities? Not really.

A measure of welfare should have the following properties:

Horizontally equitable. All equal individuals should be treated equally. But individuals are not equal, they have different needs. Ex: Food and non-food requirements are different for adults and children. We need to ‘equalize’ the welfare measure.

Fixed over time and space. A measure of welfare should be comparable across time and

space. But prices change over time and space. Ex: Inflation over time and price differentials across regions. We need to adjust the welfare measure to comparable prices.

=> The poverty line or the poverty measure need to be adjusted accordingly.

Adjust the poverty line or the welfare measure? It’s your choice. In this course, we adjust the welfare measure.

Page 28: 1 Poverty Measurement An Introduction Paolo Verme

28

Adjusting Consumption for Welfare Comparisons

Adjust for what?

Household size

Household composition

Household purchasing power

Adjust to what?

Economies of scale (ES)

Adult Equivalent Consumption (AEC)

Purchasing Power Parity (PPP)

Adjust how?

Equivalence Scales

Deflators

Page 29: 1 Poverty Measurement An Introduction Paolo Verme

29

Adjust Consumption for HH Size and Composition

Consumption per capita. Consumption is estimated on households but households have different sizes. We need per capita estimates.

Economies of scale. Household size has an impact on economies of scales. The more people live under the same roof and share the same resources the more the fixed costs are spread, the more the unit costs are small, the greater is individual welfare.

Consumption capacity. Households are composed of different type of members such as adults, children and pensioners with different needs, costs and consumption capacity. A child eat less than an adult. If a child and an adult have the same monetary consumption, the child is better off. These differences in welfare should be taken into account.

From HH consumption to Per capita adult equivalent consumption

This is done with equivalence scales

Page 30: 1 Poverty Measurement An Introduction Paolo Verme

30

Equivalence Scales

Two simple and popular equivalence scales are the Oxford and OECD scales:

Oxford:

1 = First adult

0.7 = Other adults (adjust economies of scale)

0.5 = Children (adjust for calories needs)

OECD:

1 = First adult

0.5 = Other adults (adjust economies of scale)

0.3 = Children (adjust for calories needs)

Page 31: 1 Poverty Measurement An Introduction Paolo Verme

31

Equivalence Scales

But there are also much more sophisticated scales. A mathematical formula which may capture both adult equivalent consumption and economies of scale is the following.

ES = (A+αC)^β

A= Number of adultsC=Number of childrenα=Child adult equivalent parameterβ=Economies of scale parameter

By dividing consumption by ES, we obtain the per capita adult equivalent consumption. With α=1 and β=1, we obtain per capita consumption. However, the general assumption is that α<1 and β<1.

Page 32: 1 Poverty Measurement An Introduction Paolo Verme

32

Equivalence ScalesNote that consumption and, by consequence, poverty measures are very sensitive to the choice of equivalence scales.

Note also that equivalence scales are very arbitrary. In fact, there is no scientific ground to argue that the same equivalence scale should be applied universally as suggested by the Oxford and OECD scales for various reasons:

– A child in a poor country may cost little more than the food required. But a child in a rich country may cost more than an adult.

– Countries have different population structures. In some countries over 50% of the population is composed of children, in others less than 20%. A small change in the child parameter of the equivalence scale can lead to a substantial increase or decrease in the poverty gap observed between two countries.

– Economies of scale may be very different across countries. In Africa, people tend to live in extended and elastic families and fixed costs such as heating, water and electricity are very small. In Europe, people live in small and rather established households and fixed costs may be a substantial part of consumption.

Page 33: 1 Poverty Measurement An Introduction Paolo Verme

33

Poverty Lines

Page 34: 1 Poverty Measurement An Introduction Paolo Verme

34

Poverty Lines

The monetary value of the minimum set of basic needs necessary to reach a minimum standard of living

or, in economic terms:

The minimum consumption needed to achieve the minimum level of utility

We consider different types of poverty lines

» Absolute (APL)

» Relative (RPL)

» Subjective (SPL)

Page 35: 1 Poverty Measurement An Introduction Paolo Verme

35

Absolute Poverty LinesDifferent Approaches

Cost of basic needs (CBN)– Least cost approach– Expenditure based method

Food Energy Intake (FEI)

Direct Calories Intake Method (DCI)

All PL are composed of a food and a non food component.

However, it is the estimation of the food component which makes a difference across methods.

Page 36: 1 Poverty Measurement An Introduction Paolo Verme

36

APL-Cost of Basic Needs (CBN)

With a Cost of Basic Needs approach, the standard method is to start with evaluating in monetary terms a minimum amount of food necessary for having a healthy and active life that allows individuals to fully participate in society; we call this the Minimum Food Basket (MFB).

The MFB is based on nutritional values. First, the minimum level of energy intake is established.

Example. The FAO recommends a level of 2,100 calories/day for an adult in working age.

There are at least two different approaches:– Least cost approach– Expenditure based method

Page 37: 1 Poverty Measurement An Introduction Paolo Verme

37

APL-Cost of Basic Needs (CBN)Least Cost Approach

With a least-cost approach, we select a number of food baskets that provide the same calories intake and we then select the one that is less costly and use the value of this basket as the poverty line.

First, we find a number of products which are traditionally part of the diet of the population we are targeting.

Second, we compose an ideal basket of goods selected on the basis of their nutritional values (MFB), in terms of a correct balance between carbohydrates, proteins, vitamins and other nutritional composites to achieve the set number of calories.

Third, we evaluate in monetary terms using affordable prices. By multiplying quantities by prices we obtain the value of the MFB. This value can be used as the Food Poverty Line (FPL).

MFB=FPL= ∑ qi*pi where qi= quantity of good i and pi=price of good I

The advantage of this approach is that we do not need to know detailed data on household consumption. On the other hand, this approach will not provide a basket of goods which will be necessarily consumed by any household.

Page 38: 1 Poverty Measurement An Introduction Paolo Verme

38

APL-Cost of Basic Needs (CBN)Expenditure Based Method

The expenditure based method looks first at consumption patterns in a certain population. Usually, the sample of households that is used for this evaluation is the sample of middle income or poorer households.

The food consumed by this population group is included into the basket and the basket is weighted according to the share of different foods consumed by the target population.

The basket is then transformed into calories and adjusted so as to reach the minimum amount of calories required.

The method ensures that the food basket is relevant to the population we are assessing. However, it does not guarantee the best possible diet to reach the minimum amount of calories.

Page 39: 1 Poverty Measurement An Introduction Paolo Verme

39

APL-Food Energy Intake

The Food Energy Intake method seeks in the data the consumption level at which a person typically attains the minimum food energy intake.

First we estimate econometrically how calories intake change as consumption changes:

Ln(x)=a+bC+uWhere X=Consumption on a food basked; C=Calories obtained from the food basket; u=error term

Then the food poverty line can be estimated as:

Z=a*+b*RWhere Z=PL, a* and b* are the coefficients estimated from the first equation and R is the recommended calories intake.

Page 40: 1 Poverty Measurement An Introduction Paolo Verme

40

APL-Direct Calories Intake Method

With the DCI method we take first the quantities consumed by HH.

These quantities are transformed into HH calories.

HH calories are transformed into calories per capita.

Poor HH are those household with calories per capita below a minimum threshold.

Problem: two households with the same calories intake may enjoy very different standards of living

Page 41: 1 Poverty Measurement An Introduction Paolo Verme

41

Relative Poverty Line

A relative poverty line is not related to absolute income or consumption of the population but is established relatively to the particular distribution of income or consumption observed in a given society.

Example. This is the approach followed by the European Union that considers poor all people with per capita income or consumption below 50% of the median income.

The problem with a relative poverty line is that there is no fixed benchmark. The PL moves together with the median of the distribution. If all incomes in a distribution increase by 10%, the number of poor below the poverty line does not change. Thus, it is more similar to a measure of distribution than to a measure of poverty. It pinpoints those who are worse off but does not tell us how poor these people really are.

Page 42: 1 Poverty Measurement An Introduction Paolo Verme

42

Relative Poverty Line

Annual Consumption per Capita (Euro)

Data Sorted data10000 45009200 660013400 78004500 90007800 920015000 100009000 1050014000 1290012900 1340010500 140006600 15000

Median = 10,000Poverty Line = 10,000/2 = 5,000

Page 43: 1 Poverty Measurement An Introduction Paolo Verme

43

Subjective Poverty Line

A subjective poverty line is established by asking people about poverty. This can be done in several ways:

Ask people what they think is a minimum amount necessary for living. Answers to this question vary from person to person but one could use an average or median value to estimate a poverty line. The question could be formulated as follows: What do you think is the minimum income necessary to your family every month? And answers could be structured as open ended or multiple choice answers.

Alternatively, we can ask people how they would rank themselves on a poverty scale with several steps and estimate overall poverty by taking the mean of the answers. One example is the following: On a scale from 1 to 10 where one is “extremely poor” and 10 is “extremely rich” how would you rank the income status of your household?

Page 44: 1 Poverty Measurement An Introduction Paolo Verme

44

Poverty Lines. What is better?

Absolute, relative and poverty lines are not substitutes but complement each other and provide different types of information.

Absolute poverty lines provide information on poverty as compared to a recognized minimum threshold determined on the basis of normative and positive criteria. Such lines can be used to compare people across space and time. These lines are used to measure real welfare.

Relative poverty lines provide information on poverty based on the position of individuals relative to the position of other individuals within the same consumption distribution. Such lines cannot be used to evaluate changes in real welfare, only changes in relative welfare. They can be seen as a measure of distribution.

A subjective poverty line provides a picture of self-perceived poverty. This may be very different from absolute or relative poverty but is nevertheless a useful tool for policy. It can be seen as a measure of the feeling of individual deprivation and can used for political purposes.

Page 45: 1 Poverty Measurement An Introduction Paolo Verme

45

Poverty Indexes

Page 46: 1 Poverty Measurement An Introduction Paolo Verme

46

Poverty Indexes

In this section we look at three popular measures of poverty:

» Headcount Index» Poverty Gap» Severity of Poverty

We will see why we need three measures and we will see that these three measures belong to the same class of poverty measures.

We will also have a brief look at some other indexes:

» Watts» Atkinson» Sen» Sen-Shorrocks-Thon

Page 47: 1 Poverty Measurement An Introduction Paolo Verme

47

The Poverty Headcount Index

H P0 1n i 1

q i

yi= Individual consumption iz = Poverty linen = Population q = Number of individuals below the poverty line

or

H = q/n

Page 48: 1 Poverty Measurement An Introduction Paolo Verme

48

The Poverty Gap and the Severity of Poverty Index

PG P1 1n i 1

q z y i

z

SP P2 1n i 1

q z y i

z 2

yi= Individual consumption i

z = Poverty line

n = Population

q = Number of individuals below the poverty line

Page 49: 1 Poverty Measurement An Introduction Paolo Verme

49

The Common Structure of the Three Poverty Indexes

P y;z 1n i 1

q z y i

z

α=0 => P(0) = Headcount Index

α=1 => P(1) = Poverty Gap Index

α=2 => P(2) = Severity of Poverty Index

α is defined as the poverty aversion parameter. The larger is α the more weight we give to the poorest people. This is a normative choice which may reflect, for example, the weight that governments wish to attribute to poverty in public policy.

Page 50: 1 Poverty Measurement An Introduction Paolo Verme

50

A Graphical Illustration of the Three Indexes

0 Consumption z

P1

P0

P2

1

Poverty Index

If all people have zero consumption, all the three indexes are equal to 1. All people reach maximum poverty.

If all people consume the same amount as the poverty line z (or above), the poverty indexes are all equal to zero. There is no poverty.

In between the two extremes:

P0 (headcount index) is constant. Each additional poor add an equal amount of poverty.

P1 (poverty gap) is linear and increasing in poverty. Each additional poor increases poverty proportionally to the level of poverty. The poorest contribute to the index more than the less poor.

P2 (severity of poverty) is exponential and increasing in poverty. Each additional poor increases poverty more than proportionally to the level of poverty. The poorest contribute to the index much more than the less poor.

Page 51: 1 Poverty Measurement An Introduction Paolo Verme

51

Headcount Index

Person Poverty line Consump.Number of

obs.Poor=1 Non-

poor=0Number of

poor

Poverty Headcount Index

P0z y n Poor q H=q/n

A 1 3 1 4 1 3 0.752 3 1 4 1 3 0.753 3 1 4 1 3 0.754 3 4 4 0 3 0.75

B 1 3 1 4 1 3 0.752 3 2 4 1 3 0.753 3 3 4 1 3 0.754 3 4 4 0 3 0.75

C 1 3 2 4 1 3 0.752 3 2 4 1 3 0.753 3 2 4 1 3 0.754 3 4 4 0 3 0.75

Page 52: 1 Poverty Measurement An Introduction Paolo Verme

52

Poverty Gap Index

Poverty line Consump.

Distance from the

poverty line

Relative distance from the

poverty line

Sum of the relative

distances from the

poverty linePoverty Gap Index

P1z y z-y (z-y)/z sum(z-y)/z sum((z-y)/z)n

A 1 3 1 2 0.67 2.00 0.52 3 1 2 0.67 2.00 0.53 3 1 2 0.67 2.00 0.54 3 4 0 0.00 0.00 0

B 1 3 1 2 0.67 1.00 0.252 3 2 1 0.33 1.00 0.253 3 3 0 0.00 1.00 0.254 3 4 0 0.00 0.00 0

C 1 3 2 1 0.33 1.00 0.252 3 2 1 0.33 1.00 0.253 3 2 1 0.33 1.00 0.254 3 4 0 0.00 0.00 0

Page 53: 1 Poverty Measurement An Introduction Paolo Verme

53

Severity of Poverty Index

Poverty line Consump.

Relative distance from the

poverty line

Square of the relative

distance from the

poverty line

Sum of the squares of the relative

distance from the

poverty lineSeverity of

Poverty Index P2z y (z-y)/z ((z-y)/z)^2 sum((z-y)/z)^2 sum(((z-y)/z)^2)/n

A 1 3 1 0.67 0.44 1.33 0.332 3 1 0.67 0.44 1.33 0.333 3 1 0.67 0.44 1.33 0.334 3 4 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00

B 1 3 1 0.67 0.44 0.56 0.142 3 2 0.33 0.11 0.56 0.143 3 3 0.00 0.00 0.56 0.144 3 4 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00

C 1 3 2 0.33 0.11 0.33 0.082 3 2 0.33 0.11 0.33 0.083 3 2 0.33 0.11 0.33 0.084 3 4 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00

Page 54: 1 Poverty Measurement An Introduction Paolo Verme

54

The Three Indexes Compared (Kazakhstan)

P(0)

(1)

P(1)

(2)

P(2)

(3)

Mean income of

the poor P(0) (4)

Aver. income gap of the poor P(0)

(5) 2001

Akmola 0.11 0.02 0.01 30000 7890 Aktubinsk 0.18 0.05 0.02 27200 10700 Almaty 0.20 0.04 0.01 30500 7380 Atirau 0.24 0.07 0.03 27300 10600 West-Kazakhstan 0.16 0.03 0.01 31900 5940 Jambul 0.29 0.07 0.02 28900 8990 Karaganda 0.12 0.02 0.01 30000 7900 Kostanay 0.21 0.05 0.02 28100 9740 Kizilorda 0.28 0.05 0.01 31000 6890 Magnistau 0.39 0.10 0.03 28200 9680 South-Kazakhstan 0.29 0.06 0.02 29500 8360 Pavlodar 0.06 0.02 0.01 27600 10300 North-Kazakhstan 0.05 0.01 0.00 30300 7620 East-Kazakhstan 0.13 0.03 0.01 29300 8560 Astana city 0.02 0.00 0.00 31300 6620 Almaty city 0.03 0.01 0.00 31500 6420 Kazakhstan 0.17 0.04 0.01 29538 8349

Page 55: 1 Poverty Measurement An Introduction Paolo Verme

55

Interpretation of the three IndexesThe headcount index (P0) is easily interpreted. It is the percentage of poor people in the population.

The poverty gap (P1) index can be interpreted as the cost necessary to eliminate poverty. That is because P1 is the sum of the consumption gap between each poor and the poverty line.

More difficult is to interpret the severity of poverty index (P2) and, more in general, all indexes where α>1.

Note first, that the greater is α the smaller is the size of the index. Comparing the three indexes between each other, only provides information on the size of poverty aversion parameter, i.e. on the normative judgment made about the weight that we wish to give to poverty.

The three indexes cannot be compared between each other, they are only relative to themselves and they are only useful when we observe changes over time or space. They mean little in absolute values.

Therefore, the severity of poverty index can only be interpreted as a measure of intensity of poverty. If the index is larger, the intensity of poverty is larger. If it the index is smaller the intensity of poverty is smaller.

Page 56: 1 Poverty Measurement An Introduction Paolo Verme

56

Example

P0 Rank P1 Rank P2 RankSmall farmers 82 1 41 1 25 1Large farmers 77 2 35 2 19 2Unskilled workers 63 3 26 4 14 5Herders/Fishermen 51 4 28 3 16 3Retirees/disabled 50 5 24 5 14 4

Page 57: 1 Poverty Measurement An Introduction Paolo Verme

57

Watts and Atkinson Poverty Indexes

Watts (1968) Atkinson (1987)

q

ii nyzW

1

/)/log(

yi= Consumption of individual iz = Poverty linen = Population q = Number of poorε= Poverty aversion parameter

1

11

1

11

n

i

ig

y

y

nA

Page 58: 1 Poverty Measurement An Introduction Paolo Verme

58

Sen and Sen-Shorrocks-Thon Indexes

Sen (1976) Sen-Shorrocks-Thon (SST)

)1(10qq

S GPGPP

P0=Poverty Headcount

P1=Poverty gap

G^q=Gini index among the poor

Gz-q^q= Gini index calculated on the poverty gaps

)1(10q

qzq

SST GPPP

Page 59: 1 Poverty Measurement An Introduction Paolo Verme

59

Poverty Decompositions

Page 60: 1 Poverty Measurement An Introduction Paolo Verme

60

Poverty Decomposition into Sub-groups

K

kkk PvP

1

K = Number of sub-groupsk = Sub-groupsP = Poverty indexPk = Poverty index for group kp = Populationpk = Population of sub-group k

p

pv k

k

Page 61: 1 Poverty Measurement An Introduction Paolo Verme

61

Poverty Shares by Sub-groups

P

PvS kk

k 11

K

kkS

K = Number of sub-groups

k = Sub-groups

P = Poverty index

Pk = Poverty index for group k

p = Population

pk = Population of sub-group k

p

pv k

k

Page 62: 1 Poverty Measurement An Introduction Paolo Verme

62

Poverty Risk

k

kkk v

S

P

PR

P

PvS kk

k p

pv k

k

K = Number of sub-groups

k = Sub-groups

P = Poverty index

Pk = Poverty index for group k

p = Population

pk = Population of sub-group k

Page 63: 1 Poverty Measurement An Introduction Paolo Verme

63

Poverty Indexes, Shares and Risk: Example (Kosovo)

Poverty Headcount(complete pov. line)

Poverty Headcount(food pov. line)

Index Share Risk Index Share Risk

Gender

Male 36.6 50.3 98.8 14.6 48.9 96.1

Female 37.5 49.7 101.2 15.9 51.1 104

Age

Age<=25 38.4 56.2 103.6 16.5 58.8 108.3

Age 26-65 34.5 37.5 93.1 13.4 35.4 87.9

Age > 65 42.2 6.2 113.9 16.2 5.8 106.1

Page 64: 1 Poverty Measurement An Introduction Paolo Verme

64

Inequality

Page 65: 1 Poverty Measurement An Introduction Paolo Verme

65

From Units to Population

Thus, in order of size we have:– Population units (Individuals)– Population units (Households)– Sample units (Individuals)– Sample units (Households)– Quantiles (Equal groups of sample units)– Sample– Population

Page 66: 1 Poverty Measurement An Introduction Paolo Verme

66

Units and Quantiles

For the measurement of inequality it is essential to understand the distinction between units of measurement and quantiles.

Units of measurement can be individuals, households or larger communities.

Quantiles are groups of observations of equal size, i.e. containing the same number of units. If we order the surveyed sample in ascending order of one variable such as income and then we split the sample in groups of equal size we obtain ‘quantiles’. If we order individuals in ascending order of income and then we split the sample into ten groups we talk of deciles. We talk of quartiles if the groups are four and quintiles if the groups are five and so on. Evidently the maximum number of quantiles we can obtain from the sample is equal to the number of units in that sample.

Dividing the sample into quantiles is useful because we can then calculate statistics for each quantile and compare these statistics across quantiles. For example, we can calculate the percentage of people with access to basic health services and compare this percentage across income quintiles to see if the poorest groups (quintiles one and two) have more or less access than the richest groups (quintiles four and five) to these basic services.

Page 67: 1 Poverty Measurement An Introduction Paolo Verme

67

Measures of Inequality

There is a very wide range of measures of inequality. We focus here on a few basic measures to get acquainted with the practice of inequality measurement.

We also focus on discrete measures (with income measured in finite quantities - we use formulas) as opposed to continuous measures (with income measured in infinite quantities comprised in an interval - where integrals are used).

We consider the following inequality measures:

» The variance

» The coefficient of variation

» The quintile ratio

» The Lorenz curve

» The Gini coefficient

Page 68: 1 Poverty Measurement An Introduction Paolo Verme

68

The Variance

The variance is the relative square of the distances of income from the mean of income and is measured as follows:

n

ii yy

nV

1

2)(1

where: yi=income of individual or family i

y = mean income n=number of individual or family i

The variance varies from 0 (where all incomes are the same) to )1(2

ny This measure is not very useful because if, for example, we double all incomes, the

variance would quadruple while the shape of the distribution would stay the same. In other words, the variance is affected by size while it is the distribution of income we are more concerned with.

Page 69: 1 Poverty Measurement An Introduction Paolo Verme

69

Coefficient of Variation

The coefficient of variation is the square root of the variance divided by mean income as follows:

y

Vc

The coefficient of variation varies between 0 (where all incomes are the same) to

1n . This measure standardizes the variance making it relative to the mean income which makes it a better measure of inequality because we can compare numbers of different

magnitude and with different means. However, the fact that it varies between 0 and 1n makes it a difficult measure when we want to compare samples of different sizes.

Page 70: 1 Poverty Measurement An Introduction Paolo Verme

70

Top/Bottom Quantile Ratio

One simple way to calculate an inequality index is to divide the population income in quantiles and take the ratio of the total income of the top quantile(s) to the total income of the bottom quantile(s). Suppose we have the following quintiles in a particular income distribution.

1st 2nd 3rd 4th 5th Total Income 10 30 50 70 140 300 % of income 3.3 10 16.7 23.3 46.7 100 Cum % income 3.3 13.3 30 53.3 100 Population 220 220 220 220 220 1100 % Population 20 20 20 20 20 100 Cum % Population 20 40 60 80 100

The top/bottom quintile ratio would be 140/10=14. In other words, the top 20% of

earners in our income distribution earns 14 times the bottom 20% which is a rough but indicative measure of inequality.

Page 71: 1 Poverty Measurement An Introduction Paolo Verme

71

The Lorenz Curve

The Lorenz curve uses the concept of quantiles to construct a curve determined by the cumulative income of a population and by its cumulative population, both measured normalised to 1 or to 100. To see how a Lorenz curve is constructed we will use the same data used for the quintile ratio above.

Cumulative Income

1

0.8

0.6

0.4 A

0.2 B

0

0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1

Cumulative Population

Page 72: 1 Poverty Measurement An Introduction Paolo Verme

72

The Gini Coefficient

The Gini coefficient is the average difference between all possible pairs of incomes in the population expressed as a proportion of total income. It can be constructed starting from the Lorenz curve and it represents the ratio between area A and area A+B:

G=A/(A+B)

It is evident that the larger is A (which is the area that represents the distance from the

diagonal) the smaller is B and the larger is the Gini coefficient. For simplicity, the area A+B is normalised (put equal to) to 1 so that the Gini coefficient varies between 0 and 1. A Gini coefficient of zero points to perfect equality. A Gini coefficient of 1 points to perfect inequality.

There many different ways of calculating the Gini coefficient. One possibility is to do it

geometrically as follows:

n

iiii yyxxG11

11 ))((1

where x is the cumulated percentage population and y is the cumulated percentage income (normalised to 1 in our example).

Page 73: 1 Poverty Measurement An Introduction Paolo Verme

73

Properties of an Inequality Measure

Mean independence. This means that if all incomes were doubled, the measure would not change.

Population size independence. If the population were to change, the measure of inequality should not change, ceteris paribus. This is the problem we had with the variance which changes in size if incomes change in size.

Symmetry. If you and I swap incomes, there should be no change in the measure of inequality. This principle says that you can swap income and ranks between different people and that this would leave the inequality measure unchanged. Inequality measures are concerned with incomes, not people.

Pigou-Dalton Transfer sensitivity. Under this criterion, the transfer of income from richer to poorer reduces measured inequality. If I take X income from the rich and I give it to the poor the inequality measure should decrease.

Decomposability. This means that inequality may be broken down by population sub-groups and that the inequality index may be reconstructed by summing-up the sub-group indexes (additivity principle).

Statistical testability. One should be able to test for the significance of changes in the index over time.