2 wu 2009 voluntary and involuntary job mobility

Upload: hkustcaser

Post on 30-May-2018

215 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

  • 8/14/2019 2 WU 2009 Voluntary and Involuntary Job Mobility

    1/14

    Voluntary and involuntary job mobility and earnings inequality in urban

    China, 19932000q

    Xiaogang Wu *

    Division of Social Science, Hong Kong University of Science and Technology, Clear Water Bay, Kowloon, Hong Kong

    a r t i c l e i n f o

    Article history:

    Available online xxxx

    Keywords:

    China

    Earnings inequality

    Labor markets

    Layoffs

    Market transition

    Propensity-score matching methods

    a b s t r a c t

    This paper proposes a model of selective mobility of workers from the state sector to the

    market sector to illustrate how the market transition has led to earnings inequality in for-

    mer state socialist countries. Analysis of the survey data collected in 2000 from 10 Chinese

    cities reveals that recent entrants into the market are driven by two different institutional

    processessome are self-selected for higher economic returns (voluntary entrants) and

    some are pushed into the market through layoffs (involuntary entrants), resulting in a

    more heterogeneous body of workers in the market sector than before. Linear regression

    results show that the commonly observed higher earnings in the market sector are limited

    only to a subgroup of later entrants who enter the sector voluntarily. Propensity-score

    matching analyses further demonstrate that the effect of a late market entry on earnings

    is negatively associated with the propensity of making such a transition. Those who would

    otherwise do well in the state sector and therefore have a lower propensity for entering the

    market benefit more from the entry.

    2009 Elsevier Inc. All rights reserved.

    1. Introduction

    Empirical analysis of stratification deals primarily with the stratification outcomes, namely, the inequalities in education,

    occupation and income among different social groups. Studies of the underlying process through which such inequalities are

    produced, however, are yet to be emphasized in the literature (Blalock, 1991). Therefore, when sociologists attempt to make

    inferences about the causal mechanisms of inequality, they tend to rely on many overly simplistic and untested assumptions,

    often leading to substantial bias and untenable conclusions.

    The existing literature on social inequality and stratification in former state socialist countries serves as a good example

    to illustrate this problem. The institutional transition to market economies in China and East European countries has re-stim-

    ulated scholars theoretical interest in how macro-level social transformation has reshaped the structure of inequality ( Nee,

    1989; Szelnyi, 1978). Early empirical research in this field mainly relied on the investigation of income inequality, partic-

    ularly on returns to human capital and political power, to infer the changes in the mechanism of social stratification (e.g.,

    Bian and Logan, 1996; Gerber and Hout, 1998; Nee, 1989, 1996; Parish and Michelson, 1996; Rna-Tas, 1994; Xie and Han-

    0049-089X/$ - see front matter 2009 Elsevier Inc. All rights reserved.doi:10.1016/j.ssresearch.2009.11.003

    q An earlier version of this paper was presented in the American Sociological Association Annual Meeting, Philadelphia, PA, August 1215th, 2005, a

    conference of the ISA Research Committee on Social Stratification and Mobility (RC28), University of California, Los Angeles, August 1921st, 2005, the

    Populations Association of America Annual Meeting, Los Angeles, March 30 to April 1st, 2006. The author thanks Zheng Hangsheng of Renmin University of

    China for making the data available, Yu Xie of University of Michigan, Ann Arbor, several anonymous reviewers of the Social Science Research for comments,

    suggestions. This research was supported by two research grants: Educational Inequalities in Reform-era China, 19902000 (HKUST6424/05H), Social

    Mobility, Stratification Dynamics in China Since mid-1990s (GRF 644208), both from the Hong Kong Research Grants Council.

    * Fax: +852 23350014.

    E-mail address: [email protected]

    Social Science Research xxx (2009) xxxxxx

    Contents lists available at ScienceDirect

    Social Science Research

    j o u r n a l h o m e p a g e : w w w . e l s e v i e r . c o m / l o c a t e / s s r e s e a r c h

    ARTICLE IN PRESS

    Please cite this article in press as: Wu, X. Voluntary and involuntary job mobility and earnings inequality in urban China, 19932000. So-

    cial Sci. Res. (2009), doi:10.1016/j.ssresearch.2009.11.003

    http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.ssresearch.2009.11.003mailto:[email protected]://www.sciencedirect.com/science/journal/0049089Xhttp://www.elsevier.com/locate/ssresearchhttp://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.ssresearch.2009.11.003http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.ssresearch.2009.11.003http://www.elsevier.com/locate/ssresearchhttp://www.sciencedirect.com/science/journal/0049089Xmailto:[email protected]://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.ssresearch.2009.11.003
  • 8/14/2019 2 WU 2009 Voluntary and Involuntary Job Mobility

    2/14

    num, 1996). Such an intellectual leap from the observed income inequality to the underlying causal mechanisms has ini-

    tiated an unresolved debate among sociologists on the social consequences of the market transition in the 1990s ( Cao and

    Nee, 2000; Zhou, 2000a,b).

    Recent studies have shifted the theoretical paradigm by specifyingconcrete institutional settings or intermediate processes

    through which income inequality is generated (Gerber, 2002; Walder, 2002, 2003; Wu, 2002, 2006; Wu and Xie, 2003; Zhou,

    2000a,b). In analyzing income determination, scholars have emphasized structural changes in the emerging labor markets and

    workers mobility in the process of producing new inequalities. For instance, rapid economic expansions in rural China during

    the 1980s created many opportunities for wage employment other than farming and entrepreneurship. As a result, ordinary

    peasants income from these sources substantially altered the income distribution among different social groups (Walder,

    2002). In post-Soviet Russia, shock therapy led to sweeping structuralchanges in labormarket opportunities, facilitating indi-

    viduals labor market transitions (Gerber, 2002) and thereby affecting inequalities (Gerber and Hout, 1998).

    Emphasis on the effect of structural changes in labor markets on social stratification has moved one step further towards

    understanding the process of how diverse stratification outcomes are produced in the context of macro social changes in

    post-socialist countries. This approach links the studies of social stratification in transition economies to a broad literature

    on labor market processes in developed capitalist economies (e.g., DiPrete, 1993; DiPrete and Lynn Nonnemaker, 1997).

    However, this is only one-sided story. Unless we are willing to make the fundamental assumption that either individual

    behaviors are nearly completely determined by structural factors or, if not, individual differences are simply cancelled

    out in some sort of aggregation process, it is difficult to account for structural changes without examining the more micro-

    or individual-level process that undergirds them (Blalock, 1991; Blau, 1977; Hannan, 1991).

    From this perspective, Wu and Xie (2003) argue that workers are dynamic social actors, who are not simply affected by

    the market transition, but rather respond to it by actively situating themselves in the labor markets. Based on the history

    of individual mobility in urban China, Wu and Xie (2003) characterized four types of workers: (1) those who are in the

    state sector and continue to stay there (stayers); (2) those who enter the market sector early and stay there (early

    birds); (3) those who begin in the state sector but later transfer to the market sector (later entrants); and (4) those

    who are initially in the market sector, but later retreat to the state sector (market losers). They examined differential

    earnings returns to education among early birds and later entrants in the market sector in comparison with stayers in

    the state sector.1

    Wu and Xies (2003) contribution was primarily conceptual and their empirical analyses hinged on a temporal argument:

    the returns to the market sector employment and the returns to education within the market sector depended on when Chi-

    nese workers entered the sector. Those who entered early on (early birds) experienced neither higher earnings nor higher

    returns to education than those who remained in the state sector, but later entrants did experience an earnings premium

    and higher returns to education. They interpreted this temporal variation as evidence that selection mechanisms differed

    between early birds and later entrants. However, they had no direct evidence to support this claim. Moreover, the advanta-

    ges that later entrants enjoyed over stayers were not convincingly explained (Jann, 2005; Xie and Wu, 2005). As Wu and Xie

    (2003) speculated (pp. 438439),

    Two different institutional processes in urban China may have contributed to this phenomenon. On one hand, a growing

    number of qualified workers voluntarily gave up their career opportunities in the state sector and entered the market, or

    jumped into the sea (xiahai). On the other hand, an increasing number of workers were laid off by ailing state enterprises

    and thus pushed into the market (xiagang). Due to the different selection mechanisms, the two subgroups could be very

    different from each other in observed and unobserved characteristics. . . .. . .. Pooling them would yield higher returns to

    education for later market entrants as a single group.

    Because the data analyzed by Wu and Xie (2003) did not contain a direct measurement of respondents motivations/rea-

    sons for making labor market transitions (i.e., whether they jumped or were pushed into the market), they were unable

    to test the distinction between voluntary and involuntary transitions and their associated consequences.

    In this paper I advance the inquiry above in two respects. First, based on the survey data collected in 10 cities in 2000, I

    investigate the patterns of entry into the market sector in urban China and directly test the claim on the differential mobilitypatterns between early birds and later entrants, with a special attention to the distinction between involuntary and volun-

    tary later entrants. Second, using both multiple linear regression and the propensity-score matching methods, I examine

    how differential patterns of entry into the market sector affect earnings inequality among later entrants compared to those

    who stayed in the state sector.

    2. Individual labor market transitions, group heterogeneity and earnings inequality

    For the past few decades or so, economic reforms in former state socialist countries have led to the emergence of a market

    sector in the redistributive economy. The market sector has offered a new window of opportunity for social mobility, thus

    yielding important implications for changes in social stratification (Nee, 1989). In the dual opportunity structure, one could

    climb the rank order of the bureaucratic hierarchy, or one could try the market (Szelnyi, 1988: 65). To a great extent, the

    1 Only a few cases of market losers were documented. They were therefore excluded from Wu and Xies (2003) analysis.

    2 X. Wu / Social Science Research xxx (2009) xxxxxx

    ARTICLE IN PRESS

    Please cite this article in press as: Wu, X. Voluntary and involuntary job mobility and earnings inequality in urban China, 19932000. So-

    cial Sci. Res. (2009), doi:10.1016/j.ssresearch.2009.11.003

    http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.ssresearch.2009.11.003http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.ssresearch.2009.11.003
  • 8/14/2019 2 WU 2009 Voluntary and Involuntary Job Mobility

    3/14

    question under debatewho wins and who loses in the course of market transitionis contingent upon who stays in the

    hierarchy and who switches to the market sector (Szelnyi and Kostello, 1996).

    Workers labor market transition is an integral part of the transition from state socialism to market capitalism. For exam-

    ple, the rate of job mobility in China, particularly from the redistributive state sector to the market sector, has dramatically

    increased since the economic reform. In 1978, only 150,000 Chinese workers in the entire country were employed in the

    market sector; the employed workers in the market sector climbed to 62,410,000 in 1999, with an increase of 416 times

    within two decades (National Bureau of Statistics, 2000).

    Such dramatic changes in labor mobility were by no means a random process, but rather reflected individual selective

    mobility in response to the changing opportunity structures during the market reform ( Wu, 2006). There have been some

    anecdotal and contradictory accounts of how different social groups associate themselves with new market opportunities.

    In his early study of Hungarian rural entrepreneurship, Szelnyi (1988) found that cadres are less likely to participate in mar-

    ket-oriented businesses, and that the new economic elite are more likely to emerge from less privileged groups. Various sur-

    veys conducted in urban China in the mid-1980s show that most private entrepreneurs and individual business owners

    (getihu) were migrant peasants, unemployed youth, dismissed workers, former criminals released from prisons and retirees,

    who were unable to secure employment in the state sector (Davis, 1999; Gold, 1990; Li, 1993). Zhou et al., 1997, based on the

    data from a representative survey of urban China, reported minimal mobility from the state sector to the market sector in

    urban China as of 1993, especially among those with high human and political capital (also see Gold, 1990; Li, 1993).

    However, in post-1989 Hungary after the collapse of the communist regime, the communist elites became more likely

    than ordinary workers to convert themselves into corporate entrepreneurs and to maintain their economic advantages

    (Rna-Tas, 1994). In China, with the Communist Party still firmly holding onto political power, the market economy gained

    full legitimacy since 1992, when the paramount leader Deng Xiaoping made his famous trip to southern China and called for

    further economic reforms. Cadres and professionals increasingly started giving up their career opportunities within the state

    sector in search for new advantages in the market sector. A new Chinese phrase, xia hai (jumping into the sea), was coined

    to refer to the new phenomenon of workers moving into the market sector (Wu and Xie, 2003; Wu, 2006).

    Szelnyi and Kostello (1996) brought together different and somewhat contradictory observations of entry into the mar-

    ket sector by relating them to the process of marketization. According to them, in the early stages of economic reforms when

    participation in the market was highly risky and required little skill, entrants into the market sector tended to be those in the

    low tiers of the social hierarchy, who were not at risk of losing privileges like those enjoyed by workers in the state sector.

    However, as marketization proceeded and the risks in the market were further reduced, workers with more marketable skills

    started to seek the new opportunities available in the market. Communist cadres also learned to embrace the market to cash

    in on their political and social capital (Wu, 2006). In the face of competition from these groups, with more to lose but also

    more to gain, the early market pioneers were marginalized under certain circumstances (Szelnyi and Kostello, 1996:1089).

    Hence, workers are fluid in the labor markets and their mobility into the market sector is unlikely to be exogenous to the

    process of marketization. It is this underlying social process that is directly responsible for the different stratification out-

    comes that have been observed by many scholars involved in the debate.

    Not all workers are rational actors who can control their own fate and maximize their benefits in the course of market-

    ization. Market transitions have brought not only new opportunities for people to take advantage of, but also job losses and

    downward mobility for those who suffer from, particularly in the late reform period. Gerber and Hout (1998) presented a

    transition scenario that was clearly at odds with the claims in Nees market transition theory (Nee, 1989). After the sudden

    collapse of the Soviet Union, the sweeping transition to capitalism did not increase returns to human capital and to profes-

    sionals in post-socialist Russia. Since the mid-1990s, the growth of the private economy in China has gained a new momen-

    tum, which, on one hand, attracted talented workers from the state sector, but on the other hand, pushed some state-owned

    enterprises into bankruptcy because of market competition. Many workers were pushed into the market for a living ( Cai,

    2002; Lee, 2000; Solinger, 2002).

    Hence, the fact that workers recently entered the market sector through two qualitatively different mechanismsthrough

    layoffs that pushed them into the market involuntarily or through self-selection that allowed them to voluntarily jump

    into the market sector for new opportunitiesfurther enhances the heterogeneity of workers in the market sector and com-

    plicates our investigation of the impact of the labor market transition on stratification outcomes. Compared with those who

    stayed in the state sector, the early market entrants came mostly from disadvantaged backgrounds and had little chance to

    do well in the state sector. Among the recent market entrants, those who were forced to leave the state sector might possess

    less human and political capital or other unobserved characteristics negatively associated with potential earnings, whereas

    those who were self-selected into the market sector might possess certain observable or unobservable characteristics that

    are positively associated with potential earnings. That the workers, who entered the market through these two mechanisms,

    fared differently has been well documented by some ethnographic researchers (e.g., Solinger, 2002; Wank, 1999).

    These differential sorting processes of workers into the market sector are endogenous to the pace of marketization and

    therefore should be incorporated into the analysis of the change in earnings inequality in the context of market transitions.

    Previous research in this field has largely ignored such varying processes and has relied on comparisons among highly het-

    erogeneous groups to make causal inferences on the effects of the political or market institutions (mechanisms) on income

    inequality. Without knowing how individuals are sorted/placed into different social groups/sectors, the estimates of group

    differences in earnings based on aggregate data are likely to be biased, and the interpretation of the group differences as

    caused by group membership is unwarranted (Gerber, 2000; Wu and Xie, 2003).

    X. Wu / Social Science Research xxx (2009) xxxxxx 3

    ARTICLE IN PRESS

    Please cite this article in press as: Wu, X. Voluntary and involuntary job mobility and earnings inequality in urban China, 19932000. So-

    cial Sci. Res. (2009), doi:10.1016/j.ssresearch.2009.11.003

    http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.ssresearch.2009.11.003http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.ssresearch.2009.11.003
  • 8/14/2019 2 WU 2009 Voluntary and Involuntary Job Mobility

    4/14

    3. Research design and methodology: bringing the process back in

    The discussion above suggests that the group heterogeneity among later entrants is crucial to understanding causal

    mechanisms of the stratification outcomes (earnings inequality) in Chinese labor markets. To advance this inquiry, I first dis-

    aggregate later entrants into involuntary and voluntary entrants based on whether they had layoff (xiagang) experience in

    the state sector and examine how these two subgroups fare differently in earnings return after entering the market sector. I

    then re-conceptualize the substantive problem with an explicit counterfactual framework ( Holland, 1986; Manski, 1995;

    Winship and Morgan, 1999) and employ a propensity-score matching method to assess the causal effect of an individualslabor market transition on earnings in 2000, the year when the analyzed survey data were collected.

    On the first step, later entrants aredivided into twosubgroups based on theirpreviouslayoff (xiagang) experience in thestate

    sector. Here, xiagangin Chinese literally means step-down-from-the-post. For a long time since the Maoist era, the Chinese

    party-state had committed to providing urban citizens life-time employment and most social services via the unique work unit

    (danwei) system, to which overstaffing was almost an inherent problem (Wu, 2002). With the competition from the emerging

    market sector since the 1990s, Chinese state-owned enterprises(SOEs), especially in traditional manufacturing industries, have

    increasingly failed to make profits (Xie and Wu, 2008). To make the state-owned enterprises more efficient and sustainable, the

    government had to allow them to streamline superfluous laborers,though in a moderateway. Thetermxiaganginitially applied

    only to workers from bankrupted, merged, closed-down enterprises but gradually included those whose salary was cut or sus-

    pended (Lee, 2000). Theseoff-duty workers continued to maintain theiremployment relationship with theiroriginalwork units

    to receive living stipends and claim social security benefits (Lee, 2000).2 In this sense, xiagangarrangement does not apply to

    employees in the private sector but instead serves as a transient step for the state work unit to streamline redundant work forces.

    While some xiagangworkers may still be able to find a new job within the state sector, more tend to enter the market forsurvival, because the living stipends paid to xiagang workers would gradually fade away and the job opportunities in the

    state sector had been shrinking since the 1990s. Earlier studies have consistently reported that xiagangworkers in the state

    sector tend to be less educated, in middle age, women, concentrated in certain industries and regions ( Solinger, 2001; Xie,

    2006). The state mass layoff thus had forced these workers to depart for the market sector in the end. Thus, those who had

    experienced a layoff in the state sector and ended up in the market sector can be defined as involuntary entrants.

    The substantive interest of this paper is to examine the causal impact of the transition to the market sector on subsequent

    earnings. This question can be re-conceptualized in a counterfactual framework, in which a late entry into the market sector

    is considered as a treatment whereas the control group consists of stayers. The causal effect of a late market entry for an

    individual can be defined as the difference between his (her) observed earnings in the market sector and counterfactual

    earnings had the person stayed in the state sector.3

    The propensity score stratum also provides a continuous measure of voluntary and involuntary movers from the state sec-

    tor to the market sector. Those who have the lower propensity for market entry, but indeed have made the transition, are as-

    sumed to have more control over the change (more voluntary) than those who have higher propensity for entry. To answerwhether the process of how individuals move from the state sector to the market sector affects their current earnings, I show

    the heterogeneous treatment effect on earnings across different propensity score strata (see also Xie and Wu, 2005).

    4. Data and variables

    4.1. Data

    The empirical analyses are based on the data collected from Social Changes in Urban China since the Reform, a survey

    conducted in 2000 in 10 cities of five provinces (Jilin, Shaanxi, Henan, Hunan and Guangdong) and a province-level munic-

    ipality (Tianjin). These provinces represent three different geographic regions and also different levels of economic develop-

    ment in China. The capital city of each province and Tianjin, one of the four municipalities directly under the central

    governments jurisdiction, were chosen as representative of large cities. In addition, a medium-size city was randomly se-lected in four of the five provinces (except Shaanxi). The procedure resulted in the selection of 10 cities: Changchun, Chang-

    sha, Guangzhou, Jilin, Kaifeng, Tianjin, Xian, Xiangtan, Zhengzhou and Zhongshan (see Fig. 1). In each city, the multi-stage

    stratified probability sampling method was used to select individuals aged from 18 to 65 years old. As a result, 4307 indi-

    viduals were selected, of which 2631 held a job in 2000.4 The survey contains the historical information on the respondents

    job mobility concerning work unit, occupation, industry, and income in 1993 and 2000.

    2 According to Chinese government statistics, there were 12.7 million laid-off (xiagang) workers at the end of 1997, 8.77 million at the end of 1998, 9.37

    million at the end of 1999, and 9.11 million at the end of 2000. These figures include only those who were still looking for jobs at the end of the respective year;

    indeed, more workers have suffered from the experience of xiagang (Xie, 2006, p. 23).3 To render the matching estimates unbiased for the true average treatment, the observable characteristics are assumed to be exhaustive, that is, no other

    important covariates affect both the propensity of receiving the treatment and the earnings. This is known as the ignorability assumption (Rosenbaum and

    Rubin, 1984).4 According to the authors own calculation based on a sample of the 2000 Population Census of China, the non-agricultural employment rate for men and

    women aged between 18 and 65 was 61.8 percent in all urban areas and 57.3 percent in the 10 selected cities (ranging from 50 percent in Jilin to 71.7 percent inZhongshan).

    4 X. Wu / Social Science Research xxx (2009) xxxxxx

    ARTICLE IN PRESS

    Please cite this article in press as: Wu, X. Voluntary and involuntary job mobility and earnings inequality in urban China, 19932000. So-

    cial Sci. Res. (2009), doi:10.1016/j.ssresearch.2009.11.003

    http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.ssresearch.2009.11.003http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.ssresearch.2009.11.003
  • 8/14/2019 2 WU 2009 Voluntary and Involuntary Job Mobility

    5/14

    This study investigates the process of labor market transitions in the period between 1993 and 2000. It chooses 1993 as

    the benchmark year for both substantive and methodological reasons. First, 1992 marked a milestone in the history of Chi-

    nas economic reforms, when Deng Xiaoping made his famous political tour to southern China to push for further market

    reforms after the Tiananmen Incident in 1989. A one-year lag is used to gauge the impact of the new policy shift on workers

    transitions in labor markets. Second, the retrospective information from 1993 is subject to fewer recall errors than would be

    information recalled from earlier years. Finally, focusing on a relatively short period may avoid a high sample attrition rate

    and provides more sample cases in the labor force in both 1993 and 2000.5

    Young people yet to enter the labor force in 1993 are excluded in the analysis for two reasons. First, the papers main

    concern is the process of labor market transition from 1993 to 2000, applicable only to those who already held a job as

    of 1993; second, as the state job allocation was ended around 1993, more and more workers started their first job directly

    in the market sector.

    Hence, workers status in 1993 and 2000 are used to characterize four types of workers in Chinas urban labor markets: (1)

    those in the state sector in both 1993 and 2000 are defined as stayers; (2) those in the market sector in both 1993 and 2000

    are defined as early birds; (3) and those in the state sector in 1993, but in the market sector in 2000, are defined as late

    entrants. After eliminating those not active in the labor force and those who held a job but without income information in

    either 1993 or 2000, I obtain 1669 cases for analysis.

    4.2. Variables

    Distinguishing the market sector from the state sector is crucial to the typology of workers. Two criteria are employed to

    make this distinction: respondents affiliated work organizations and respondents occupation. Concerning the first criterion,

    workers in the newly emerging types of work organizations, such as domestic private enterprises, joint ventures/foreign-

    invested firms (sanzi qiye), individual-owned businesses (geti hu), and other self-employed businesses, are coded as

    being in the market sector, and workers in government agencies, state institutions, state-enterprises, and collective

    enterprises are coded as being in the state (public) sector. Concerning the second criterion, workers whose occupations

    are individual business-owners (geti hu), private enterprise owners (siying qiye zhu), and other self-employed occupa-

    tions are coded as being in the market (private) sector.

    Fig. 1. Selected cities in the 2000 Urban Social Change Survey.

    5 Indeed, sample attributions from 1993 to 2000 are partly due to retirement. In the survey data, 880 respondents who had a job in 1993 but no long worked

    in 2000, and 208 of them have passed the retirement age in 2000 (60 years old for men and 55 years old for women in China). The rest withdrew from the labor

    market before retirement: majority indeed had worked in the state sector in 1993, and they tended to be less educated and older, more likely to be women and

    non-party members, and to report to have xiagangexperience since 1993. In other words, they are similar to involuntary later entrants, and income advantagesassociated with voluntary later entrants over stayers presumably would not be affected by the omission of this group in the analysis.

    X. Wu / Social Science Research xxx (2009) xxxxxx 5

    ARTICLE IN PRESS

    Please cite this article in press as: Wu, X. Voluntary and involuntary job mobility and earnings inequality in urban China, 19932000. So-

    cial Sci. Res. (2009), doi:10.1016/j.ssresearch.2009.11.003

    http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.ssresearch.2009.11.003http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.ssresearch.2009.11.003
  • 8/14/2019 2 WU 2009 Voluntary and Involuntary Job Mobility

    6/14

    The two criteria are then combined to define the number of workers in the market sector and in the state sector. Workers

    are coded as being in the market sector if they meet any of the two criteria.6 This corresponds to the broad measure employed

    by Wu and Xie (2003). As the bottom line of Table 1 shows, among 1,669 respondents included in the analysis, 194 worked in

    the market sector before 1993 and stayed in 2000 (early birds). During the same period, 158 who were in the state sector in

    1993 had moved into the market sector by 2000 (later entrants), with the rest continuing to stay in the state sector (stayers).

    The later entrants and early birds, together with those who entered the market after 1993, constituted workers in the market

    sector, accounting for 26 percent of all urban workers in 2000. 7

    The survey asked the respondents whether they had experienced a layoff (xiagang), and if so, when the most recent layoff

    occurred. Based on the information, a dichotomous distinction is made between voluntary and involuntary later entrantsbased on whether or not they had experienced layoff since 1993.

    Earnings are the major indicator of social stratification outcomes. 8 The survey collected information on the total monthly

    income earned in both 1993 and 2000, measured in RMB yuan (where 1 RMB yuan %0.12 USD in 2000). Individual character-

    istics commonly used in the studies of earnings determination include education, party membership, age and gender. Education,

    which denotes human capital, is a continuous variable measured in years of schooling. Whether the respondent is a party mem-

    ber or not as of 1993 measures his/her political capital, which is coded as a dummy variable (yes = 1). Age is measured as a

    continuous variable, and gender is coded as a dummy variable, with male as 1 and female as 0.

    Industry and occupation plays important roles in linking individuals labor market transitions and institutional changes

    (Zhou et al., 1997). Traditional manufacturing industries in the state sector (e.g., machinery, mining, chemicals, textile,

    clothes and foods), have lost their competitiveness in the market transition, and employment downsizing and layoffs took

    place mainly in these industries (Solinger, 2001; Xie, 2006). Industry in 1993 is coded as a dummy variable, with traditional

    manufacturing industry as 1 and otherwise as 0. A respondent occupation in 1993, measured by the 3-digit code of the Chi-

    nese Standard Classification of Occupation (CSCO), is also coded as a dummy variable (professionals/leading cadres = 1).Finally, the large regional variations in economic structures and the pace of the reforms have created varying opportuni-

    ties for entering the market sector and consequently for income inequality (Hauser and Xie, 2005; Xie and Hannum, 1996).

    For example, Guangdong accounts for 28.9 percent of the early birds and also 29.1 percent of voluntary later entrants,

    6 The two criteria are indeed overlapped: both can be used to identify the self-employed and private entrepreneurs. However, the first criterion additionally

    captures wage employees in the market sector.

    Table 1

    Un-weighted summary statistics of variables for different types of workers in 10 selected Chinese cities, 2000.

    Variables Overalla Stayers Early birds Later entrants

    Combined Voluntary Involuntary

    Monthly earnings 2000 (RMB) 1066.1 (1475.5)b 943.8 (1028.9) 1592.8 (2555.0) 1425.3 (2380.4) 1808.9 (2960.4) 1041.6 (1530.8)

    Monthly earnings 1993 (RMB) 613.9 (2000.6) 526.0 (709.9) 1294.5 (5500.8) 447.5 (558.5) 516.7 (483.6) 378.3 (619.9)

    Monthly earnings 2000 (logged) 6.643 (0.733) 6.595 (0.666) 6.888 (0.918) 6.721 (0.933) 6.992 (0.988) 6.521 (0.833)

    Monthly earnings 1993 (logged) 5.966 (0.837) 5.915 (0.785) 6.476 (0.892) 5.722 (0.858) 5.882 (0.937) 5.563 (0.743)

    Years of schooling 11.48 (3.395) 11.77 (3.368) 9.995 (3.361) 10.76 (3.146) 10.92 (3.572) 10.91 (2.690)

    Party member (1993) 0.191 0.220 0.057 0.108 0.139 0.076

    Male 0.558 0.556 0.593 0.519 0.620 0.418

    Age 41.51 (9.232) 42.30 (9.341) 38.5 (8.928) 38.92 (8.523) 39.23 (10.25) 38.61 (6.402)

    Layoff since 1993 0.100 0.037 0.500

    Manufacturing (1993) 0.367 0.362 0.258 0.544 0.494 0.595

    Professionals/cadres (1993) 0.330 0.375 0.129 0.209 0.215 0.203

    Province

    Guangdong 0.182 0.165 0.289 0.177 0.291 0.063

    Hunan 0.178 0.194 0.088 0.152 0.051 0.253

    Henan 0.143 0.140 0.134 0.177 0.165 0.190

    Tianjin 0.147 0.155 0.113 0.127 0.152 0.101

    Jilin 0.177 0.178 0.180 0.184 0.203 0.165

    Shaanxi 0.173 0.167 0.196 0.184 0.139 0.228

    Number of cases 1669 1303 194 158 79 79

    a Including 14 workers who were in the market sector in 1993 but moved to the state sector in 2000 (market losers).b Figures in parentheses are standard deviations for continuous variables.

    7 Given the structural change in employment opportunities, those who entered the labor force after 1993 had a higher propensity of entering the market

    sector directly than their older counterparts. Among 451 of these workers, 42 percent were in the market sector in 2000. These young later entrants were 27.7

    years old and, on average, received 11.6 years of schooling and earned 1121 RMB yuan per month. Together with the later entrants who had been in the labor

    force before, they contributed to the rapid employment growth in the market in the 1990s and characterizing the market sector as of 2000. Because this paper is

    mainly concerned with individuals job shifts from the state sector to the market sector, those who entered the labor force after 1993 are excluded from the

    analysis.8

    It should be noted that using earnings only to characterize the distinction between the state and market sectors would substantially underestimate theeconomic returns for those in the state sector, which also cover fringe benefits such as health care, housing, and pension, etc.

    6 X. Wu / Social Science Research xxx (2009) xxxxxx

    ARTICLE IN PRESS

    Please cite this article in press as: Wu, X. Voluntary and involuntary job mobility and earnings inequality in urban China, 19932000. So-

    cial Sci. Res. (2009), doi:10.1016/j.ssresearch.2009.11.003

    http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.ssresearch.2009.11.003http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.ssresearch.2009.11.003
  • 8/14/2019 2 WU 2009 Voluntary and Involuntary Job Mobility

    7/14

    whereas involuntary later entrants are mainly concentrated in Hunan (25.3 percent) and Shaanxi (22.8 percent). Five dummy

    variables are included in the model to represent the provinces from which the samples were drawn.

    Table 1 presents descriptive statistics for the entire sample and the comparisons among three/four types of workers. For

    instance, in 2000, early birds on average earned 1593 RMB yuan per month and later entrants earned 1425 RMB yuan per

    month, compared to stayers who earned 944 RMB yuan per month but might receive more benefits. In 1993, their respective

    monthly earnings were 1295 RMB yuan, 448 RMB yuan and 526 RMB yuan. Therefore, it seems that, by entering the market

    sector, later entrants gained in terms of a higher income from 1993 to 2000.

    Pertaining to the two variableseducation and the Chinese Communist Party membership (1993)which are of partic-

    ular interest to some scholars, stayers have the highest years of schooling, whereas early birds have the least. Of the stayers,

    22 percent were party members in 1993, but only 5.7 percent of early birds and 10.8 percent of later entrants were party

    members in 1993. Such observations are consistent with the findings reported elsewhere: as the reforms proceeded, while

    the redistributive state in China continued to be the dominant provider of career opportunities for both the professional and

    political elite (Walder et al., 2000), the market started offering opportunities that increasingly attracted them ( Wu, 2006). As

    Table 1 shows, only 12.9 percent of early birds and 20.9 percent of later entrants were professionals/leading cadres in 1993,

    in contrast to 37.5 percent of those who stayed in the state sector. 9

    Of all the surveyed workers in 2000, 10 percent had experienced a layoff (xiagang) between 1993 and 2000. Most of the

    laid off workers were highly concentrated among later entrants in the market sector, as this had become new phenomenon

    only since the mid-1990s. In fact, 50 percent of later entrants were former xiagangworkers in the state sector, whereas few

    laid off workers could have found another job within the state sector; they constituted only 3.7 percent of all current

    stayers.10

    The above observation can be further buttressed by the structural transformation of workers across industries since 1993.

    Indeed, 54.4 percent of later entrants were from the traditional manufacturing industry in 1993, and the share among invol-

    untary later entrants (presumably due to layoff) was even higher. As of 2000, over 80 percent of later entrants and early birds

    are in the service sector.

    The following empirical analyses consist of two parts: First, I examine the determinants of transition to the market sector

    via multinomial logistic regressions; I then link the patterns to earnings inequality among different types of workers via lin-

    ear regression methods, paying particular attention to voluntary and involuntary later entrants. Second, I employ the pro-

    pensity-score matching methods to directly estimate the causal effect of a late market entry on earnings gains in 2000.

    Because the sample was clustered within 52 street communities (jiedao) in each city, an adjustment of standard errors is

    needed in regression analyses. In all model estimations, data are weighted to represent the general population of the selected

    cities and robust standard errors are reported.

    5. Patterns of entry into the market sector and earnings determination

    Table 2 presents estimates for multinomial logit models that predict the likelihood of workers moving from the state to

    the market sector under different scenarios. Respondents years of schooling, party membership as of 1993, age, age2, gender,

    industry in 1993, and province are included as the covariates. 11 First, the models among stayers, early birds and later entrants

    are estimated, and then with later entrants divided into voluntary and involuntary later entrants, models are re-estimated and

    stayers are used as the reference group. The following discussion is focused on the interpretation of the effects of schooling,

    party membership, and industry, omitting those of other control variables.

    As the models indicate, years of schooling are negatively associated with the likelihood of early entry into the market sec-

    tor, and party members are also less likely than are non-party members to be in the market sector. This is because people

    with more human and political capital would have more career opportunities in the state sector and also enjoy more fringe

    benefits (e.g., housing, health care, and pension) other than cash income. However, as the marketization proceeds, such

    deterring effects tend to fade away (Wu, 2006), as suggested by the difference in coefficients between the equations for early

    birds and later entrants. More specifically, an additional year of schooling decreases the net odds of entering the market sec-tor by 18.1 percent (e0.200 1) (p < .001) in an early period (in or before 1993), but only by 9.1 percent ( e0.096 1) in a late

    period (after 1993) (p < .01). Similarly, controlling for other variables, a party members odds of entry into the market are

    only 34.2 percent (e1.072) (p < .05) of those for a non-party member in an early period, but the odds increase to 79.1 percent

    (e0.235) and become statistically insignificant in a late period. A Wald test shows that the change in coefficients are statis-

    9 Early birds major occupations include individual business-owners (geti hu), private enterprise owners (siying qiye zhu), and salesmen/saleswomen,

    which could not attract those with human capital and political capital in early years; and private enterprise owners earned much higher than others and

    thereby lifted the average earnings for early birds as a group.10 Because xiagang arrangement does not apply to employees in the private sector and there is no information on the year when the respondent entered the

    market sector, it should be noted that xiagang would not immediately lead to move into in the market sector, and that involuntary later entrants current job

    may not necessarily be the result of the state layoff. Even for those who were first laid off from the state sector and landed a job in the market sector but

    changed jobs within the market sector, they are still classified as involuntary later entrants, because the main concerns of this paper is to the impact of job

    mobility across sectors on earnings inequality.11

    The inclusion of occupation as an independent variable in the model is complicated by the fact that it is also employed to define the type of workers movingacross sectors in the labor market.

    X. Wu / Social Science Research xxx (2009) xxxxxx 7

    ARTICLE IN PRESS

    Please cite this article in press as: Wu, X. Voluntary and involuntary job mobility and earnings inequality in urban China, 19932000. So-

    cial Sci. Res. (2009), doi:10.1016/j.ssresearch.2009.11.003

    http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.ssresearch.2009.11.003http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.ssresearch.2009.11.003
  • 8/14/2019 2 WU 2009 Voluntary and Involuntary Job Mobility

    8/14

    tically significant (v2[2] = 6.8, p < .05), suggesting that early birds and later entrants indeed are different in terms of their

    possession of human capital and political capital, although they both differ from stayers at the same time.

    As previously pointed out, later entrants may be more heterogeneous because they consist of two subgroups of people

    who entered the market sector via different institutional channels. Hence, later entrants are further divided into voluntary

    and involuntary entrants based on whether they had layoff (xiagang) experience or not since 1993, and the multinomial logit

    models are re-estimated among stayers, early birds, voluntary later entrants, and involuntary later entrants. Results in the

    right two columns ofTable 2 show that, while schooling seems to play a similar role in deterring one from entering the mar-

    ket, both voluntarily and involuntarily (v2[1] = 0.17, p = 0.68), party membership plays an opposite role: party members are

    less likely than non-party members to become involuntary later entrants (p < .05), but they are more likely to become vol-

    untary later entrants, as opposed to staying in the state sector. As expected, those from traditional manufacturing industry in

    1993 were much less likely to become early birds, but they are more likely to become later entrants (specifically, involuntary

    later entrants).

    The analyses from multinomial logistic regression above have revealed that early birds, later entrants (both voluntary and

    involuntary), and stayers differ in certain characteristics. In other words, the patterns of entry into the market sector are con-

    tingent upon when and how people moved from the state sector into the market sector. Such variant patterns have impor-

    tant implications for the stratification outcomes (earnings), which are examined next.

    The logarithm of monthly earnings is used as the dependent variable in the multiple linear regression analysis. Worker

    types, the logarithm of monthly earnings in 1993, schooling, party membership in 1993, age, age2, gender, industry in 1993,

    and province are included as independent variables. The analysis is focused on mean difference in earnings among three/four

    groups of workers, adjusting for the effects of other covariates. Table 3 presents the estimated results.

    In Model 1, all workers are divided into three groups: stayers, early birds, and later entrants, and included in the model as

    two dummies, with stayers as the reference group. Because the model controls the earnings prior to 1993, the net effect of an

    independent variable on the logged earnings in 2000 can be interpreted as that on earnings change. Similar to the results

    reported by Bian and Logan (1996), education and party membership both are significant predictors of earnings growth from

    1993 to 2000. Men enjoy significantly higher earnings gains than did women in the same period (p < .01), and those who

    worked in the traditional manufacturing industry in 1993 continued to be disadvantaged in 2000 (p < .05). The effect of

    age, nonetheless, is insignificant.

    Controlling for other factors, Model 1 suggests that only those who have shifted from the state sector to the market sector

    after 1993 enjoyed significantly higher earnings growth than did those who remained in the state sector, by 26.4 percent

    (e0.234 1) (p < .05). This result provides some support to Wu and Xies (2003) argument that people with more human cap-

    ital and political capital were self-selected into the market in the late reform stage, who tended to do better economically

    (also see Szelnyi and Kostello, 1996; Xie and Wu, 2005).

    Not all later entrants were self-selected. In Model 2 ofTable 3, later entrants are further divided into voluntary and invol-

    untary later entrants, and enter the models as two dummy variables. The patterns become even more evident: neither invol-

    untary entrants nor early birds differ from stayers in earnings; higher earnings are only limited to those who voluntarily

    entered the market after 1993. Other things being equal, voluntary later entrants enjoy 47.1 percent ( e0.386 1) higher earn-

    ings change than stayers, and the difference is statistically significant (p < .01).

    Table 2

    Estimated coefficients from multinomial logit models of entry into the market sector in Chinese cities, 2000.

    Variables Early birds vs

    stayers

    Later entrants vs.

    stayers

    Voluntary later entrants vs.

    stayers

    Involuntary later entrants vs.

    stayers

    Years of schooling 0.200*** (0.038) 0.096** (0.035) 0.105*(0.048) 0.080 (0.044)

    Party membership (1993) 1.072* (0.484) 0.235 (0.298) 0.275 (0.369) 0.935* (0.452)

    Age 0.197** (0.067) 0.085 (0.085) 0.373*** (0.091) 0.548** (0.171)

    Age2*10 0.015 (0.008) 0.003 (0.010) 0.036*** (0.010) 0.076** (0.024)

    Male 0.330 (0.179)

    0.156 (0.188) 0.211 (0.328)

    0.500*

    (0.199)Manufacturing (1993) 0.724** (0.241) 0.653*** (0.202) 0.391 (0.345) 0.974*** (0.270)

    Province [Guangdong omitted]

    Hunan 0.601* (0.297) 0.085 (0.401) 0.763 (0.670) 0.556 (0.419)

    Henan 0.018 (0.330) 0.738 (0.387) 0.584 (0.513) 0.883* (0.441)

    Tianjin 0.195 (0.320) 0.009 (0.426) 0.294 (0.580) 0.384 (0.552)

    Jilin 0.086 (0.276) 0.392 (0.452) 0.536 (0.579) 0.219 (0.580)

    Shaanxi 0.234 (0.251) 0.493 (0.440) 0.207 (0.582) 0.680 (0.492)

    Constant 5.847*** (1.304) 1.404 (1.797) 6.506** (2.206) 11.74*** (3.095)

    Pseudo R2 0.092 0.104

    Wald v2 227.5 592.4

    Degree of freedom 22 33

    Notes: Data are weighted, numbers in parentheses are robust standard errors adjusted for clustering on community (jiedao). p < .10.*

    p < .05.** p < .01.*** p < .001.

    8 X. Wu / Social Science Research xxx (2009) xxxxxx

    ARTICLE IN PRESS

    Please cite this article in press as: Wu, X. Voluntary and involuntary job mobility and earnings inequality in urban China, 19932000. So-

    cial Sci. Res. (2009), doi:10.1016/j.ssresearch.2009.11.003

    http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.ssresearch.2009.11.003http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.ssresearch.2009.11.003
  • 8/14/2019 2 WU 2009 Voluntary and Involuntary Job Mobility

    9/14

    It should be noted that voluntary here refers to those who did not experience a layoff (xiagang) since 1993. Such a sim-

    ple dichotomous distinction between involuntary and voluntary later entrants cannot fully capture the group heterogeneity

    this paper intends to highlight, because people may be forced to depart due to reasons other than xiagang. In fact, the results

    from multinomial logistic regression show that people with higher education are still less likely to become voluntary later

    entrants, but once they do, they enjoy higher income growth on average than those stayers. A possible explanation is that the

    income advantages of later entrants may be due to the self-selection effects, which cannot be demonstrated with the sep-

    arate analyses of multinomial logistic regression and linear regression. To establish such a causal link between labor market

    transitions on earnings growth, I employ a propensity-score matching method.

    6. Estimating the causal effect of market entry with the propensity-score matching method

    In the causal inference framework, the matching method allows researchers to summarize all the differences between the

    treatment and control groups with propensity scores, which are estimated from binary logit models. The propensity scores

    are then stratified to balance both propensity scores and observed covariates, and the average treatment effect on earnings

    within each stratum can be computed. A large body of literature has shown that the propensity score stratification method

    can remove great amounts of biases in causal inference with observational data (e.g., Becker and Ichino, 2002; Dehejia and

    Wahba, 1999; Winship and Morgan, 1999), affording us an easy way to examine differences in observed covariates and com-

    pare the groups flexibly and non-parametrically (for recent applications in sociological research, see Brand and Halaby, 2005;

    Harding, 2003; Morgan, 2001; Smith, 1997; Xie and Wu, 2005).

    For the research question in this paper, the focus is explicitly on the between-group differences in earnings, whereas

    group differences in observed covariates that affect earnings are encompassed by the propensity scores. An individuals pro-pensity for entering the market vs. staying in the state sector since 1993 can be estimated on a number of selected variables:

    the logged income in 1993, years of schooling, party membership in 1993, age, age 2, gender, xiagang experience, job satis-

    faction in 1993, and province.12 Based on estimated propensity scores, respondents are divided into different strata to balance

    both propensity score and covariates between the treatment and comparison groups (p < .001) (Becker and Ichino, 2002). As a

    result, eight strata are obtained. Fig. 2 presents the number of cases in each stratum, separated by treatment and control

    groups.13

    Table 3

    Estimated coefficients from the multiple linear regression of earnings in selected Chinese cities, 19932000.

    Variables Model 1 Model 2

    Worker type (stayers omitted)

    Early bird 0.075 (0.057) 0.079 (0.056)

    Later entrants 0.234* (0.110)

    Voluntary 0.386** (0.134)

    Involuntary (via layoff) 0.093 (0.111)

    Logged earnings (1993) 0.444***

    (0.031) 0.444***

    (0.031)Years of schooling 0.039*** (0.005) 0.040*** (0.005)

    Party member (1993) 0.102** (0.037) 0.097* (0.037)

    Age 0.009 (0.018) 0.005 (0.017)

    Age2*10 0.001 (0.002) 0.001 (0.002)

    Male 0.133*** (0.032) 0.130*** (0.033)

    Manufacturing (1993) 0.089* (0.042) 0.086* (0.042)

    Province [Guangdong omitted]

    Hunan 0.149* (0.071) 0.144* (0.071)

    Henan 0.310*** (0.082) 0.310*** (0.083)

    Tianjin 0.282*** (0.062) 0.288*** (0.063)

    Jilin 0.236*** (0.069) 0.240*** (0.068)

    Shaanxi 0.317*** (0.050) 0.317*** (0.050)

    Constant 3.900*** (0.435) 3.837*** (0.433)

    R2 0.419 0.423

    Notes: Data are weighted, numbers in parentheses are robust standard errors adjusted for clustering on community (jiedao).* p < .05.** p

  • 8/14/2019 2 WU 2009 Voluntary and Involuntary Job Mobility

    10/14

  • 8/14/2019 2 WU 2009 Voluntary and Involuntary Job Mobility

    11/14

    p < .001). That is, the benefit of a late transition into the market sector is the greatest among those who were least likely to

    make such a transition and diminishes with the propensity for making the transition. 16

    7. Summary and discussion

    To summarize, the analyses of this paper revealed that the pattern of entry into the market sector in urban China haschanged since 1993. While early entrants to the market tend to come from the lower tiers of the social hierarchy, with less

    human capital and political capital, the disadvantages of later entrants have been reduced. Compared to early birds, for later

    entrants, while education continues to play a significant role in deterring one from entry into the market, such deterring ef-

    fect is weakened; the effect of party membership becomes positive and statistically insignificant.

    Later entrants are recruited through two distinct processes. On the one hand, as the market reform proceeded, state lay-

    offs took place and workers lacking educational credentials and political connections were thrown into the market for sur-

    vival. On the other hand, the growth of the market economy also increasingly attracted from the state sector more capable

    workers who had been able to cash their human capital and political capital for even greater economic advantages. Regres-

    sion analysis reveals that those later entrants who entered the market involuntarily following a state layoff have no earnings

    advantages compared to both stayers and earlier birds, and that the higher average earnings growth in the market sector is

    limited to a subgroup of workers who entered the market sector voluntarily.

    Based on an alternative operationalization of the distinction between involuntary and voluntary later entrants, it is con-

    firmed that a late transition to the market sector is associated with higher earnings. Furthermore, among those later entrants,the benefit of working in the market sector sharply decreases with their propensity for having made the transition. Hence,

    the market premium is only limited to those later entrants who otherwise have a low propensity for making such a transition

    to the market sector. These workers could have been doing quite well in the state sector but indeed ended up in the market

    sector, and who are labeled as the voluntary later entrants in contrast to involuntary ones.

    The propensity-score matching method is by no means perfect, because it takes into account of the effects of only obser-

    vable characteristics and is unable to address the selection of unobservable characteristics (also see footnote 3). This limi-

    tation is alleviated to a large extent given the fact that respondents pre-treatment earnings (earnings in 1993) are

    included in estimating propensity scores, hence the effects of individuals unobserved characteristics on earnings are fixed

    in this setup. The results using the matching method confirm the patterns observed in regression analysis based on the

    dichotomous distinction between voluntary and involuntary entrants and therefore are robust.

    0.43

    0.85

    0.77

    1.38

    1.5

    2.26

    3.17

    4.60

    0

    200

    400

    600

    800

    1000

    1200

    1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8

    Propensity Score Stratum

    MarketEffectonEarnings

    (RMB

    Yuan)

    observed linear fit

    Y=1067.1-97.1*STRATUM_RANK

    Fig. 3. Market treatment effect on earnings by propensity strata: later entrants vs. stayers. Notes: (a) Numbers in the scatter plot are t values for earnings

    comparison between later entrants (treatment group) and stayers (control group). A tvalue less than 1.96 indicates that there is no significant difference in

    earnings between the treatment and control groups within a propensity score stratum. (b) The linear plot is based on the hierarchical-linear model (HLM)

    estimates (level-2 model with slopes from level-1 model as outcomes regressed on propensity stratum rank. For model specification, see (2c) in footnote

    15). The effect of the propensity stratum rank is statistically significant (std = 28.2, t=3.45, and p = 0.017).

    16 While one might worry about whether or not the small number of level-2 units (8 strata) can afford estimation of a hierarchicallinear model, the number

    of strata created is not fixed, dependent upon the data available. The key point here, however, is to parametrically show a varying treatment effect acrosspropensity score strata.

    X. Wu / Social Science Research xxx (2009) xxxxxx 11

    ARTICLE IN PRESS

    Please cite this article in press as: Wu, X. Voluntary and involuntary job mobility and earnings inequality in urban China, 19932000. So-

    cial Sci. Res. (2009), doi:10.1016/j.ssresearch.2009.11.003

    http://-/?-http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.ssresearch.2009.11.003http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.ssresearch.2009.11.003http://-/?-
  • 8/14/2019 2 WU 2009 Voluntary and Involuntary Job Mobility

    12/14

    Indeed, the two approaches to operationalizing the distinction between voluntary vs. involuntary later entrants are quite

    consistent. As Fig. 4 shows, in the three strata with the lowest propensity scores, most workers had not experienced layoff,

    whereas in the three strata with the highest propensity scores, all workers experienced layoff. Workers who do well in the

    state sector and thus are unlikely to lose their jobs have a low propensity for entering the market. For them, the attraction of

    the market sector needs to be large enough to overcompensate for the advantages they already enjoyed in the state sector,

    including fringe benefits that are less available in the market sector. Higher earnings of this subgroup of later entrants lifted

    the average earnings of the workers in the market sector as a single group.

    Hence, selectivity plays a key role in determining higher returns to the market sector employment compared to the state

    sector employment. Without attending to the process through which individuals are selectively allocated or sorted into a

    group, relying on the comparison of group means to address the causal effect of being in that group may lead to wrong

    conclusions.Why do some later entrants perform so well? The propensity-score matching analysis has illustrated a classical case of

    the endogeneity problem: individuals select their treatment based on the anticipated outcome, which is nothomogeneous

    across workers. This suggests a strong self-selection mechanism at work: when workers with a low (latent) propensity of

    making a transition indeed did make such a late transition to the market sector, they benefited the most from the transition.

    In other words, it is a story about what drives workers to move into the market sector, and our research should be devoted to

    understanding this micro-process and its economic consequences.

    To be certain, the self-selection and sorting process cannot be fully understood without appreciating the changing

    employment opportunities in the labor markets. Since the 1990s, more corporate jobs became available in the private sector

    and foreign companies, given the development of labor markets and capital markets in China. The market started attracting

    more and more talents, resulting in a more heterogeneous body of workers in the sector, and high earnings returns to the

    employment in the market sector.17

    How to interpret the apparent returns to market employment among those who choose it? We believe that individuals

    unobserved heterogeneity plays an important role in explaining the advantages, that is, those who have low observed pro-pensity to make the transition and actually do would have higher earnings in either sector; what appears to be a return to

    market employment for them actually reflects their higher expected earnings and non-monetary benefits in the state sector,

    which raises the reservation wage at which they would take employment in the market sector.

    8. Conclusions

    This paper posited an existing intellectual gap in the literature on modern social stratification in general and on post-so-

    cialist stratification in particular. Scholars often jump from the observed structure of inequality to the causal mechanisms on

    the theory of social stratification, without solid knowledge of the underlying social processes that generate the stratification

    0

    10

    20

    30

    40

    50

    60

    70

    80

    90

    100

    1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8

    Propensity Score Stratum

    Percentag

    e

    Voluntary Entrants Layoffs

    Fig. 4. The composition of two types of later entrants by propensity score stratum.

    17 Such a pattern is by no means unique in Chinas transition economy. Studies of Poland, another former socialist country, revealed a similar story: wage

    premium in the private sector is particularly pronounced for highly educated workers; and the positive selection effects into the private sector can be identifiedfor both men and women (Adamchik and Bedi, 2000).

    12 X. Wu / Social Science Research xxx (2009) xxxxxx

    ARTICLE IN PRESS

    Please cite this article in press as: Wu, X. Voluntary and involuntary job mobility and earnings inequality in urban China, 19932000. So-

    cial Sci. Res. (2009), doi:10.1016/j.ssresearch.2009.11.003

    http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.ssresearch.2009.11.003http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.ssresearch.2009.11.003
  • 8/14/2019 2 WU 2009 Voluntary and Involuntary Job Mobility

    13/14

    outcomes. Commenting on this gap, the late Hubert M. Blalock (1991) advises that researchers should delimit their theories

    to what he refers to as allocation processes, through which individuals are assigned or sorted into positions by a series of

    micro-level decisions. Without benefit of more micro analyses, such macro theories are likely to require so many untested

    assumptions, and to ignore such huge data gaps, our intellectual and ideological biases are likely to predominate, resulting in

    unanswerable theoretical disputes that merely hamper the process of arriving at a cumulative body of knowledge (Blalock,

    1991: 27).

    This paper proposed a micro perspective to shed new lights on the relationship between the institutional transition to a

    market economy and the changes in earnings inequality in China. It emphasized the differential sorting processes of workers

    in the emerging labor markets in understanding how earnings inequalities are produced in the course of Chinas economic

    transition. Using both the linear regression models and the propensity-score matching method, the paper found that work-

    ers performance in the market sector is contingent upon how they entered the market, and only those voluntary entrants in

    the late reform period enjoyed earnings advantages over those who stayed in the state sector; moreover, among those later

    entrants, the causal effect of a market entry on earnings is negatively associated with the propensity for making such a tran-

    sition. Those who would otherwise do well in the state sector and therefore have lower propensity of entering the market

    have benefited more from the entry.

    While the paper put the emphasis on the impact of workers self-selection processes on earnings inequality, such self-

    selection processes were contingent upon the institutional transitions at the macro-level and interacting with the change

    in opportunity structures in the labor markets (Wu, 2006). Future data collection and research should link the two processes

    and specifically examine the career trajectory among those self-selected later entrants.

    The findings from this paper suggest that researchers should be cautioned about the danger in reliance on group compar-

    isons to make theoretical causal inferences without fully acknowledging the process of how individuals are sorted into a

    group and the resulting heterogeneity. This methodological advice is equally applicable to the study of inequality between

    party members and non-party members (e.g. Gerber, 2000), between cadres and non-cadres (Nee, 1996; Walder, 2002), and

    among different types of work organizations (Zhou, 2000a,b). Hence, a simplistic causal explanations of post-socialism earn-

    ings inequality in terms of the state or the market mechanisms is rejected, and further research is to be devoted to uncover

    the underlying micro-process of individual mobility between social positions (constrained and influenced by macro-level

    institutional transitions), and the aggregate outcomes of these processes (Blau, 1977; Hannan, 1991). Identifying these pro-

    cesses is an intellectually challenging task but a necessary step towards constructing a solid theory on the changing strat-

    ification mechanism in post-socialist transitional societies.

    References

    Adamchik, Vera A., Bedi, Arjun S., 2000. Wage differentials between the public and the private sectors: evidence from an economy in transition. LaborEconomics 7, 203224.

    Becker, Sascha O., Ichino, Andrea, 2002. Estimation of average treatment effects based on propensity scores. The Stata Journal 2 (4), 358377.Bian, Yanjie, Logan, John, 1996. Market transition and persistence of power: the changing stratification system in urban China. American Sociological

    Review 61, 739758.Blalock, Hubert.M., 1991. Understanding Social Inequality. Sage, Newbury Park, CA.Blau, Peter M., 1977. Inequality and Heterogeneity. Free Press, New York, NY.Brand, Jennie E., Halaby, Charles, 2005. Regression and matching estimates of the effects of elite college attendance on educational and career achievement.

    Social Science Research 35, 749770.Cai, Yongshun, 2002. The resistance of chinese laid-off workers in the reform period. The China Quarterly 170, 327344.Cao, Yang, Nee, Victor, 2000. Comment: Controversies and Evidence in the Market Transition Debate. American Journal of Sociology 105, 11751189.Davis, Deborah, 1999. Self-employment in Shanghai: a research note. China Quarterly 157, 2243.Dehejia, H. Rajeev, Wahba, Sadek, 1999. Causal effects in non-experimental studies: reevaluating the evaluation of training programs. Journal of American

    Statistical Association 94, 10531062.DiPrete, Thomas A., 1993. Industrial restructuring and the mobility response of American workers in the 1980s. American Sociological Review 58, 7496.DiPrete, Thomas A., Lynn Nonnemaker, K., 1997. Structural change, labor market turbulence, and labor market outcomes. American Sociological Review 62,

    386404.Gerber, Theodore, 2000. Membership benefits or selection effects? Why former communist party members do better in post-soviet Russia. Social Science

    Research 29, 2550.

    Gerber, Theodore P., Hout, Michael, 1998. More shock than therapy: market transition, employment, and income in Russia, 19911995. American Journal ofSociology 104, 150.

    Gerber, Theodore, 2002. Structural change and post-socialist stratification: labor market transitions in contemporary Russia. American Sociological Review67, 629659.

    Gold, Thomas, 1990. Urban private business and social change, In: Davis, D., Vogel, E.F., (Eds.), Chinese Society on the Eve of Tiananmen: the Impact ofReform. Council on East Asian Studies, Harvard University, Cambridge, MA, pp. 157180.

    Harding, David, 2003. Counterfactual model of neighborhood effects: the effect of neighborhood poverty on high school dropout and teenage pregnancy.American Journal of Sociology 109 (3), 676719.

    Hannan, Michael, 1991. Aggregation and Disaggregation in the Social Sciences. Lexington Books, Lexington, MA.Hauser, Seth, Xie, Yu, 2005. Temporal and regional variation in earnings inequality: urban China in transition between 1988 and 1995. Social Science

    Research 34, 4479.Holland, Paul W., 1986. Statistics and causal inference (with discussion). Journal of American Statistical Association 81, 945970.

    Jann, Ben, 2005. Earnings returns to education in urban China: a note on testing difference among groups. American Sociological Review 70, 860865.Lee, Hong Yung, 2000. Xiagang, the Chinese style of laying off workers. Asian Survey 40 (6), 917937.Li, Qiang, 1993. Dangdai Zhongguo de Shehui Fenceng Yu Liudong (Social Stratification and Mobility in Contemporary China). China Economy Press, Beijing

    (in Chinese).Manski, Charles, 1995. Identification problems in the social sciences. Harvard University Press, Boston, MA.

    Morgan, Stephen L., 2001. Counterfactuals, causal effect heterogeneity, and the catholic school effect on learning. Sociology of Education 74, 341374.National Bureau of Statistics, PRC, 2000. China Statistical Yearbook. China Statistics Press, Beijing, China.

    X. Wu / Social Science Research xxx (2009) xxxxxx 13

    ARTICLE IN PRESS

    Please cite this article in press as: Wu, X. Voluntary and involuntary job mobility and earnings inequality in urban China, 19932000. So-

    cial Sci. Res. (2009), doi:10.1016/j.ssresearch.2009.11.003

    http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.ssresearch.2009.11.003http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.ssresearch.2009.11.003
  • 8/14/2019 2 WU 2009 Voluntary and Involuntary Job Mobility

    14/14

    Nee, Victor, 1989. A theory of market transition: from redistribution to markets in state socialism. American Sociological Review 54, 663681.Nee, Victor., 1996. The emergence of a market society: changing mechanisms of stratification in China. American Journal of Sociology 101, 908949.Parish, William.L., Michelson, Ethan., 1996. Politics and markets: dual transformations. American Journal of Sociology 101, 10421059.Raudenbush, Steve W., Bryk, Anthony S., 2002. Hierarchical Linear Models, second ed. Sage Publication, Thousand Oaks.Rna-Tas, Akos, 1994. The first shall be last? Entrepreneurship and communist cadre in the transition from socialism. American Journal of Sociology 100,

    4069.Rosenbaum, Paul R., Rubin, Donald B., 1984. Reducing bias in observational studies using sub-classification on the propensity score. Journal of American

    Statistical Association 79, 516524.Smith, Herbert.L., 1997. Matching with multiple controls to estimate treatment effect in observational studies. Sociological Methodology 27, 325343.Solinger, Dorothy, 2001. Why we cannot count the unemployed. The China Quarterly 167, 67188.

    Solinger, Dorothy., 2002. Labor market reform and plight of the laid-off proletariat. The China Quarterly 170, 304326.Szelenyi, Ivan, 1978. Social inequalities in state socialist redistributive economies. International Journal of Comparative Sociology 19, 6387.Szelnyi, Ivan, 1988. Socialist Entrepreneurs. University of Wisconsin Press, Madison, WI.Szelnyi, Ivan., Kostello, Eric., 1996. The market transition debate: toward a synthesis. American Journal of Sociology 101, 10821096.Walder, Andrew.G., 2002. Markets and income inequality in rural China: political advantage in an expanding economy. American Sociological Review 67,

    231253.Walder, Andrew.G., 2003. Elite opportunity in transitional economies. American Sociological Review 68, 899916.Walder, Andrew, Li, Bobai, Treiman, Donald, 2000. Politics and life chances in state socialist regime: dual career paths into the urban Chinese elite, 1949

    1996. American Sociological Review 65, 191209.Wank, David., 1999. Commodifying Communism: Business, Trust, and Politics in a Chinese City. Cambridge University Press.Winship, Christopher., Morgan, Stephen.L., 1999. The estimation of causal effects from observational data. Annual Review of Sociology 25, 659707.Wu, Xiaogang., 2002. Work units and income inequality: the effect of market transition in urban China. Social Forces 80 (3), 10691099.Wu, Xiaogang, 2006. Communist cadres and market opportunities: entry into self-employment in urban and rural China. Social Forces 85, 389411.Wu, Xiaogang., Xie, Yu., 2003. Does the market pay off? Earnings returns to education in urban China. American Sociological Review 68, 425442.Xie, Guihua, 2006. Shichang Zhuanxin yu Xiagang Gongren (Market transition and laid-off workers. Shehuixue Yanjiu 121 (1), 2258 (in Chinese).Xie, Yu., Hannum, Emily., 1996. Regional variation in earnings inequality in reform-era urban China. American Journal of Sociology 102, 950992.Xie, Yu, Wu, Xiaogang, 2005. Market premium, social process, and statisticism. American Sociological Review 70, 865870.

    Xie, Yu, Wu, Xiaogang, 2008. Danwei profitability and earnings inequality in urban China. The China Quarterly 195 (September), 558581.Zhou, Xueguang., 2000a. Economic transformation and income inequality in urban China. American Journal of Sociology 105, 11351174.Zhou, Xueguang., 2000b. Reply: beyond the debate and toward substantive institutional analysis. American Journal of Sociology 105, 11901195.Zhou, Xueguang., Tuma, Nancy.Brandon., Moen, Phyllis., 1997. Institutional change and job-shift patterns in urban China, 19491994. American Sociological

    Review 62, 339365.

    14 X. Wu / Social Science Research xxx (2009) xxxxxx

    ARTICLE IN PRESS

    Please cite this article in press as: Wu, X. Voluntary and involuntary job mobility and earnings inequality in urban China, 19932000. So-