a nonparametric test of market timing1

52
1 A Nonparametric Test of Market Timing 1 Wei Jiang 2 August 2001 1 I Thank Jason Abrevaya, Gene Amromin, Brad Barber, Terry Odean, Douglas Diamond, Lars Hansen, Milton Harris, two anonymous referees, and workshop participants at the University of Chicago and the University of California, Davis for their helpful comments and suggestions. All errors are mine. 2 Finance and Economics Division, Columbia Business School, New York, NY 10027. E-mail: [email protected] .

Upload: others

Post on 05-Oct-2021

2 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: A Nonparametric Test of Market Timing1

1

A Nonparametric Test of Market Timing1

Wei Jiang2

August 2001

1 I Thank Jason Abrevaya, Gene Amromin, Brad Barber, Terry Odean, Douglas Diamond, Lars Hansen, Milton Harris, two anonymous referees, and workshop participants at the University of Chicago and the University of California, Davis for their helpful comments and suggestions. All errors are mine. 2 Finance and Economics Division, Columbia Business School, New York, NY 10027. E-mail:

[email protected].

Page 2: A Nonparametric Test of Market Timing1

2

______________________________________________________________________________

Abstract

In this paper we propose a nonparametric test for money managers’ market timing ability and

apply the analysis to a large sample of mutual funds that have different benchmark indices. The

test (i) only requires the ex post returns of the funds and the benchmark portfolios; (ii) isolates

timing from selectivity; (iii) separates the quality of timing information a money manager

possesses from the aggressiveness with which she reacts to such information; and (iv) is robust

to different information and incentive structures as well as underlying distributions. Theta—the

parameter for timing ability—is on average below the neutral level (indexation) among actively

managed domestic equity funds, and is very difficult to predict from observable fund

characteristics. Overall, actively managed funds aiming at “timing the market” in general fall

short of just “riding with the market.”

JEL classification: G1; C1

Keywords: Market timing; Nonparametric test; U-statistics

______________________________________________________________________________

1. Introduction

“My money was in mutual funds. Several of them. They worked like this:

When the market went down, my funds went down a lot; when the market went

up, my funds went up a little…I thought I could do better.”

—Confessions of a day trader, to the Time magazine.

The confessions of the do-it-yourself investor speak out the doubts concerning active portfolio

management: Do and can professional money managers time the market? Investors who put

their money in actively managed mutual funds when index funds are available at a much lower

Page 3: A Nonparametric Test of Market Timing1

3

cost hope to “beat the market” instead of merely to “ride with the market.” These investors, not

all of whom are aware of the theory of market efficiency in its strong and weak forms, expect

professional money managers to be better informed than common people about individual

securities or about the general market movements. If this is true, the superior information

possessed by a money manager will show up as one or both of the abilities: securities selectivity

and market timing. The first ability concerns identifying, and investing disproportionately in,

securities that have the potential to outperform the market in risk-adjusted terms. And the

second ability is about predicting the overall market movement and adjusting the portfolio’s

exposure to systematic risk accordingly. This is why mutual funds sometimes distinguishably

market themselves as either “stock pickers” or “market timers.” The aim of this paper is to

develop a test examining whether actively managed mutual funds—with an average annual

turnover rate around 100%3—deserve the second title.

Based on the theory of market efficiency with costly information, there has been ample

research work on measuring the performance of professional money managers with emphasis on

one of the two basic abilities. The selectivity test answers the question whether the portfolio

composed by a fund manager outperforms the benchmark portfolio in risk-adjusted terms

(Jensen, 1972; Gruber, 1996; Ferson and Schadt, 1996; Kothari and Warner, 2001). The timing

test deals with whether a fund manager can outguess the market by moving in and out of the

“time portfolios”—portfolio proxies for factors (Treynor and Mazuy, 1966; Henriksson and

Merton, 1981; Admati, et al., 1986). Measures of market timing have fallen into two categories.

The first one directly tests whether money managers successfully allocate funds among different

classes of assets (e.g., equity versus cash) to catch the market ascendancy and/or to avoid the

downturns. Theoretical work includes those by Merton (1981) and Cumby and Modest (1987).

Graham and Harvey (1996) run an empirical test on investment newsletters’ asset allocation

recommendations. Methods in this category require the knowledge of managers’ asset positions

at a reasonably high frequency, and have thus been constrained in practice. The second category,

on the other hand, requires only data on the ex post returns of the funds and the relevant markets.

3 Averaged over all actively managed domestic equity funds that were listed in the Morningstar mutual fund database for the 1980-1999 period.

Page 4: A Nonparametric Test of Market Timing1

4

The two most popular methods so far are those proposed by Treynor and Mazuy (1966)

(henceforth “TM”) and Henriksson and Merton (1981) (henceforth “HM”).

Most of the work on mutual fund performance measurement extends the alpha-beta analysis

of securities and portfolios to mutual funds. There has been controversy over using such a

metric to evaluate mutual fund performance. The static alpha-beta analysis misses the

diversified and dynamic aspects of managed portfolios (Admati, et al., 1985; Ferson and Schadt,

1996; Becker, et al., 1999; Ferson and Khang, 2000). In efforts to beat the market, fund

managers vary their portfolios’ exposure to market or other risk factors from time to time based

on the information they receive. Further, fund managers can alter their funds’ correlation to the

benchmark index in order to make best out of the incentives they face (Chevalier and Ellison,

1997). Consequently, the systematic part of the fund risk can be misestimated when the market

timing effect is present, and existing measures may fail to attribute superior returns to informed

investors if risk aversion varies (Grinblatt and Titman, 1990). To address these issues, there has

been a lot of work on the extension of the TM and HM measures in order to capture the effect of

conditioning information in timing performance (Ferson and Schadt, 1996; Becker, et al., 1999;

Ferson and Khang, 2000), to control for spurious timing arising from not holding the benchmark

(Jagannathan and Korazjczyk 1986; Breen and Jagannathan, 1986), to decompose abnormal

performance into selectivity and timing (Admati, et al., 1986; Grinblatt and Titman, 1990), and

to minimize the loss of test power due to sampling frequencies (Goetzmann, et al., 2000; Bollen

and Busse, 2001).

In this paper we develop an independent test to measure the market timing ability of portfolio

managers without resorting to the estimation of alpha or beta. The test is based on the simple

idea, as stated in the confession of the day trader at the start of the paper, that a successful timer

should have the fund go up a lot when the market rises and dip down a little when the market

heads south. The non-regression based nonparametric test has the following desirable properties.

First, it only requires the ex post returns of the funds and the benchmark portfolios, and is thus

easy to implement. Second, under the condition that a fund manager’s timing information is

independent from her selectivity information, the test can isolate timing from selectivity. Third,

the test separates the quality of timing information a fund manager possesses from the

Page 5: A Nonparametric Test of Market Timing1

5

aggressiveness with which she reacts to such information. The test statistic is not affected by the

manager’s risk aversion. Finally, the test is robust to different information and incentive

structures as well as timing frequency and underlying distributions. The method that we develop

in this paper is also readily applicable to analyzing the market timing ability of financial advisors

or newsletters (Graham and Harvey, 1996), or the timing behavior of individual investors

(Odean, 1998; Barber and Odean, 2000).

The rest of the paper is organized as follows: Section 2 starts with a review of market timing

measures, and then presents the model of the nonparametric test of market timing that allows

flexibility in information and incentive structures as well as in the underlying distributions. We

demonstrate the effectiveness of the test and compare it with the TM and HM methods in a

simulation. Section 3 applies the method to a data set of mutual funds with different benchmark

indices. We show that the average actively managed fund underperforms the respective index

fund in terms of market timing. Section 4 concludes.

2. Model

2.1. Preliminaries

If we could observe the portfolio composition of mutual funds at the same frequency as we

observe the returns, we can infer funds’ market timing by testing whether the portfolio’s

exposure to the relevant market is pro-trend on average (Merton, 1981; Cumby and Modest,

1987; Ferson and Khang, 2000). But in more practical situations we tie our hands to the returns

of funds and benchmark portfolios only. The method we propose needs only ex post returns of

funds and their benchmark returns, and can be applied to funds that do not have derivatives in

their portfolios.4

4 Buying call options, for example, can induce spurious timing ability, as analyzed in Jagannanthan and Korajczk (1986). Koski and Pontiff (1999) find that 21 percent of the 679 domestic equity funds in their sample use derivative securities, but detailed information about their derivative usage is not available. To minimize spurious timing due to derivatives, we do not include funds that invest in convertible bonds in our empirical test.

Page 6: A Nonparametric Test of Market Timing1

6

We interpret selectivity as the manager’s ability to pick up securities that have positive risk-

adjusted excess returns, and timing as the manager’s ability to move the fund’s exposure to the

relevant market according to her forecast about future market returns. We assume that

manager’s timing information is independent of her selectivity information, a fairly standard

assumption in the performance literature (e.g., see Admati, et al. (1986) and Grinblatt and

Titman (1990)).5 Combining the selectivity and timing, we have the following equation for fund

i (all returns are expressed in excess of the riskfree rate):

,1,1,,1, +++ ++= titmtiiti rr εβα (1)

where ti ,β is a random variable adapted to the information available to the manager at time t. rm

represents the return of the relevant market (which is usually a subset of the total market) that the

mutual fund invests in. Alternatively, we can take rm to be the benchmark portfolio return

against which the fund is evaluated.

Note that equation (1) is not an equation for asset pricing, but is designed for measuring

market timing of mutual funds. We omit in the equation other factors that might affect the

expected returns of the portfolios, such as size or book-to-market factors. We justify such

abstraction as follows. First, for large diversified portfolios of securities, unlike individual

securities, the (relevant) market return is the dominant factor in the return equation. Second, the

market return in the equation is not the total market return, but the return of a narrower market

defined by the mutual fund’s investment policy, for example, small-cap growth stocks. In the

absence of security selectivity, we can think of market timing as moving in and out of the

relevant market portfolio. In the simplest case, a market timer decides on βt at date t and during

the next period t+1 she invests βt percent in the relevant market portfolio and the rest in bond.

Then equation (1) represents the return profile from such a timing strategy.

Finally, if there are other factors affecting the expected return of funds, αi may contain return

to omitted risk factors, but the method remains valid if we are only interested in testing whether

fund managers successfully time the market they are in. Our method does not require or rely on

5 Correlated timing and selectivity information would in general cause technical difficulties in separating abnormal performance from timing and that from selectivity. See detailed discussion in Grinblatt and Titman (1990).

Page 7: A Nonparametric Test of Market Timing1

7

the correct estimation of αi or βi,t. We will show later that we use the same measure to check

that the omitted factors (size and book-to-market) do not display “timing” property against the

benchmark indices we use in the analysis. Therefore, abnormal timing performance is due to

managers’ market timing instead of to their holding a particular class of assets that exhibit

“timing” characteristics.

Treynor and Mazuy (1966) suggest the following quadratic regression:

[ ] ,1,2

1,1,,1, ++++ +++= titmitmtiiti rrr εγβα (2)

for the ith fund. Assume the manager observes a private signal yt which equals the future market

return plus an independent noise term:

.1, ttmt ry η+= + (3)

Superior timing ability corresponds to that the variance of the noise term is finite, or ∞<<2ησ .

The manager with constant absolute risk aversion (CARA) preference will respond to the signal

by making the portfolio beta a linear function of the signal (Admati, el al., 1986), which in turn

makes the portfolio return a quadratic function of the market return as in equation (2). Thus a

significantly positive coefficient iγ represents superior market timing performance.

Henriksson and Merton (1981) define the manager’s timing ability as

( ) ( ) 10|0ˆPr0|0ˆPr 1,1,1,1, −<<+>>=∆ ++++ tmtmtmtm rrrr (4)

where 1,ˆ +tmr is the manager’s forecast about 1, +tmr . Superior ability corresponds to ∆ being

greater than zero. The HM model assumes that the manager sets a higher target beta in an up

market (when the excess return on the market portfolio is greater than one) forecast than that in a

down market one. Given the aggressiveness of the manager’s reaction (expressed as the

difference between the two betas), the contribution of ∆ to the fund return can be inferred by the

following regression:

[ ] ,1,1,1,,1, ++

+++ +++= titmitmtiiti rrr εγβα (5)

Page 8: A Nonparametric Test of Market Timing1

8

where [ ] ),0max( 1,1, ++

+ = tmtm rr . The coefficient on [ ]++1,tmr becomes the value added by effective

timing that is equivalent to a call option on the market portfolio where the exercise price equals

the riskfree rate. As we can see, the γ coefficients in both the TM and HM models cannot

disentangle pure market timing (expressed as 2ησ in the TM model and ∆ in the HM model)

from the manager’s aggressiveness (expressed as the linear reaction coefficient in TM and the

difference between the high and low betas in HM).

2.2. A Nonparametric Test Statistic

In this section we propose a nonparametric measure to identify the market timing aspect of fund

performance. As specified in (1), a manager who times the market would move ti ,β

endogenously. Let ( )1,, ˆ += tmti rφβ , where )|(ˆ 1,1, ttmtm ZrEr ++ = is the manager’s prediction

about the next period market return based on tZ , the set of information available to her at time t,

both public and private. It is reasonable to assume that the manager does not make systematic

mistake, therefore the predictions should be unbiased. We do not put any parametric restrictions,

such as linearity, on the response function ( )⋅φ except requiring it to be a non-decreasing

function of 1,ˆ +tmr . If the manager does not possess valuable information or does not react to her

information, (1) collapses to the standard CAPM equation. Let ( )tii E ,ββ = be the unconditional

expectation of the fund’s beta, which should be commensurate with the fund’s stated investment

policy.

The manager’s timing ability relies on the relevance and accuracy of the signal tZ .

Suppose tZ is not informative at all. Then the conditional distribution of the forecast equals the

unconditional one, that is, ( ) ( )1,1,1, ˆ|ˆ +++ = tmtmtm rfrrf , where ( )⋅f stands for the probability density

function. In that case the probability of a right prediction in excess of that of a wrong one should

be zero, that is, the following parameter:

Page 9: A Nonparametric Test of Market Timing1

9

( ) ( )( ) ,1|ˆˆPr2

|ˆˆPr|ˆˆPr

1,1,1,1,

1,1,1,1,1,1,1,1,

2121

21212121

−>>=

><−>>=

++++

++++++++

tmtmtmtm

tmtmtmtmtmtmtmtm

rrrrrrrrrrrrν

(6)

takes the value of zero for two periods 21 tt ≠ in the absence of timing ability. In the other

extreme, if the forecast is always perfect, that is, 1,1,ˆ ++ ≡ tmtm rr , then ν attains its upper bound of

one. Symmetrically, ν equal to –1 represents perfect perverse market timing. Therefore, the

value of ]1,1[−∈ν can be a measure of the fund manager’s market timing ability. The more

accurate the information tZ is, the higher the value of ν .

Now we can put the information structure and the reaction function together. Grinblatt

and Titman (1990) prove that an investor who has independent timing and selectivity

information and nondecreasing absolute risk aversion6 always increases her beta as her

information about the market becomes more favorable, or, 0ˆ 1,

>∂∂

+tm

t

. We will discuss in more

detail about this specification in the next section. Combining this result with (6), the following

probability

( ) ( )( ) 1|Pr2

|Pr|Pr

1,1,

1,1,1,1,

2121

21212121

−>>=

><−>>

++

++++

tmtmtt

tmtmtttmtmtt

rrrrrr

ββββββ

(7)

is greater than zero if and only if the manager possesses superior information. At any range of

market return, the fund return should on average rise more when the market return is higher

and/or lose less when the market is lower if the manager times the market successfully. If so, the

probability that the fund returns bear a convex relation with the relevant market returns should be

higher than that of a concave relation, but the convexity or concavity needs not be global nor be

restricted to the parametric forms as specified in the TM and HM models. Based on (7), we

construct the following nonparametric test statistic.

6 Nonincreasing absolute risk aversion requires that the investor’s risk aversion measured by

)(')(''

wuwu− be

nonincreasing in the wealth level w. Commonly used utility functions, such as exponential, power, and log utilities, all meet this criterion.

Page 10: A Nonparametric Test of Market Timing1

10

For a triplet { }31,, ,=jtmti jj

rr sampled from any three periods such that 321 ,,, tmtmtm rrr << , a

manager with superior information should, on average, maintains a higher average beta in the

[ ]32 ,, , tmtm rr range than in the [ ]

21 ,, , tmtm rr range. Since beta at any point is the slope of the fund

return against the market return, the parameter

−−

<−−

−−

>−−

=12

12

23

23

12

12

23

23

,,

,,

,,

,,

,,

,,

,,

,, PrPrtmtm

titi

tmtm

titi

tmtm

titi

tmtm

titi

rrrr

rrrr

rrrr

rrrr

θ (8)

is an indicator for the manager’s market timing ability. We will drop the fund subscript i where

there is no confusion. Under the null hypothesis of no timing ability, the beta has no correlation

with the market return in which case the statistic θ assumes the neutral value of zero. Without

superior information, a manager would move the portfolio exposure to the market in the right

direction as often as she would in the wrong direction if she tries to time the market.

The sample analogue to θ becomes a natural candidate as a statistic. It is a U-statistic with

kernel of order three:

=<<

−<

−−

−>

−−

kmrjmrimrn

imrjmrirjr

jmrkmrjrkr

imrjmrirjr

jmrkmrjrkrnU

,,, ,,,,1

,,,,1

1

3, (9)

where n is the sample size and ( )⋅1 is the indicator function. By the property of U statistics, nU

is a n -consistent and asymptotically normal estimator for θ (Serfling, 1980; Abrevaya and

Jiang, 2000), that is,

( ) ),0( 2nU

dn NUn σθ →− .

Further it is the least variance estimator among the unbiased estimators for the same parameter

θ , the probability in favor for the manager to form a correct prediction about the next-period

market return.

Page 11: A Nonparametric Test of Market Timing1

11

Abrevaya and Jiang (2000) provide detailed discussions about the asymptotic distribution of

the nU statistic and the simulation results of its limited sample properties. Let ( )jjj tmtt rrz ,,≡

and denote the kernel function of nU by

( )

.|1

|1,,

,,,,,,,

,,,,,,,

<<

−−

<−−

<<

−−

>−−

=

kmjmimimjm

ij

jmkm

jk

kmjmimimjm

ij

jmkm

jkkji

rrrrrrr

rrrr

rrrrrrr

rrrr

zzzh

The sample analogue to the asymptotic standard error of nU is derived in Abrevaya and Jiang

(2000) using the jackknife method:

( )∑ ∑=

=

n

i kjnkjiU Uzzzh

nnn

1

2

,

12 ,,

29σ̂ . (10)

For small samples (below 50) the nonparametric bootstrap by resampling the triplets offers a

better approximation. Simulation results in Abrevaya and Jiang (2000) show that the size of the

test is very accurate7 if we use bootstrap method in standard error estimation for sample sizes

below 50 and use the asymptotic formula for larger sample sizes.

2.3. Properties

Now we have a new measure of market timing. We will call it theta (θ). It has a ready

interpretation of the probability (with a neutral value of zero) that a fund manager loads on more

systematic risk in a higher return period than in a low return one in excess of the probability that

she does the perverse. Since the seminal work by Treynor and Mazuy (1966) and Henriksson

and Merton (1981), there has been a lot of work on the extension of these measures in order to

relax the restrictive behavioral and distribution assumption, while retaining their intuitive appeal,

7 For 1,000 simulations, rejection rates at 5% significance level are between 4.5% and 5.5% for all error specifications.

Page 12: A Nonparametric Test of Market Timing1

12

ease of implementation, and minimal data requirements.8 In this section we discuss how theta as

a measure of market timing represents a significant contribution on these grounds, and point out

its limitations.

2.3.1. Information Structure and Behavioral Assumptions

The measure ν in (6) puts weaker restrictions on the information structure than the TM and HM

measures. The TM measure assumes noise additive signals with normal distributions as

expressed in (3). The manager is considered possessing valuable information if and only if

∞<<2ησ . This criterion is built on the grounds of Blackwell informativeness (Blackwell, 1951).

Comparing a manager with superior information ( ∞<<2ησ ) with one without ( ∞→2

'ησ ), it is

known that the first manager’s signal y is Blackwell more informative than the latter one’s y’ if

and only if 'η has the same distribution as ζη + for some ζ that is independently distributed

from η . This criterion can only order information structures where all random variables are

from the same distribution family, such as the normal distribution.

In our model, a manager is considered possessing valuable information if and only if the

probability ν specified in (6) is greater than zero. A sufficient condition for this result is that the

conditional distribution ( )11 ,, |ˆ tmtm rrF first-order stochastically dominates ( )

22 ,, |ˆ tmtm rrF

whenever 21 ,, tmtm rr > . That is, for any possible value of *

mr , the two distributions satisfy

( ) ( )2211 ,

*,,

*, |ˆPr|ˆPr tmmtmtmmtm rrrrrr <<< ,

whenever 21 ,, tmtm rr > . Dewatripont, et al. (1999) show that the first-order stochastic dominance

(FOSD) criterion about informativeness is compatible, but weaker than, the Blackwell

informativeness. To see this, take the TM specification of private signals as in (3), where 1tη

8 Goetamann, et al. (2000) had an excellent review on the research work that addresses the limitation of the TM and HM timing measures.

Page 13: A Nonparametric Test of Market Timing1

13

and 2tη are i.i.d. for 21 tt ≠ , and the manager’s ability determines 2

ησ . In their setting, we can

calculate our ν as follows:

[ ],1

22

1|Pr2

1,1,

1,1,1,1,

21

212112

−Φ=

−>−<−=

++

++++

ησ

ηην

tmtm

tmtmtmtmtt

rr

rrrr

where ( )⋅Φ stands for the cumulative probability function of the standard normal distribution. It

is easy to see that ν in monotonically increasing in ησ

1 , the precision of the private signal.

∞=ησ leads to 0=ν (no timing) and 0=ησ implies 1=ν (perfect timing).

The HM method characterizes a valuable forecast as the sum of two conditional probabilities

of a correct forecast about the sign of the market excess return exceeding one, as specified in (4).

Suppose a pure HM market timer gives only two possible predictions about 1, +tmr , positive or

negative. Then the ν measure of our model picks up the manager’s timing ability among a

subset of pairs of data where 01,1, 21<++ tmtm rr . On the other hand, our measure uses more

information in the return data by looking at all pairs of { }1,1, 21, ++ tmtm rr for 21 tt ≠ .

The theta measure also allows flexible specification of fund managers’ response functions to

the information. We only require that ( )1,ˆ += tmt rφβ is a nondecreasing function of 1,ˆ +tmr , that is,

the manager sets a higher beta for the fund when her forecast of the next period market return is

more favorable. Grinblatt and Titman (1990) prove that this is true when the manager has

independent timing and selectivity information and has nonincreasing absolute risk aversion.

The first assumption is required by all performance measures in order to separate timing from

selectivity, and the second assumption is satisfied by commonly adopted utility functions in

research. The flexibility on the response part is particularly appealing because a fund manager’s

reaction to the acquired information depends on her risk aversion as well as the incentive she

faces. The functional form of her response is difficult to specify without being somewhat

arbitrary. For example, a linear response by the fund manager:

Page 14: A Nonparametric Test of Market Timing1

14

( )[ ]mtmt rEr −+= +1,ˆλββ (11)

(Treynor and Mazuy, 1966; Admati, et al., 1986) is consistent with the manager’s acting as if she

were maximizing the expected utility of a CARA preference. However such an assumption is

questionable if the fund manager maximizes the utility related to her own payoff under the

incentive instead of the total return. The deviation from maximizing a CARA preference is large

when there is non-linearity in the incentive, explicitly or implicitly, in the forms of benchmark

evaluation, option compensation, or non-linear flow-to-performance responses by fund investors.

After all, there is no reason to expect a uniform reaction to information among all fund

managers. Comparatively, the theta measure imposes less stringent restrictions on the manager’s

reaction function.

2.3.2. Ability versus Response and Conditional Information

Theoretically there is a distinction between performance and ability. A fund manager’s market

timing performance relies on both the quality of her private information (ability) and the

aggressiveness with which the manager reacts to her information (response). This constitutes a

dichotomy that is difficult to decompose. Ability possessed by the manager is more important to

the investors because investors can essentially “undo” the aggressiveness of the manager by

investing more or less of their wealth in the fund or by trading in other accounts.

Regressions like (2) and (5) basically cater for the response aspect of market timing. We see

that the estimated TMγ̂ in the TM regression will pick up the coefficient in the linear reaction

function, that is, the λ term in (10). Hence more aggressive funds can show up as better market

timers with higher TMγ̂ . The HMγ̂ coefficient in the HM model is an unbiased estimate for

)( LH ββ −∆ where ∆ is the probability defined in equation (4) and Hβ ( Lβ ) is the manger’s

target beta when the predicted market excess return is positive (negative). Both ability (the ∆

term) and aggressiveness (the LH ββ − term) are reflected in the estimated timing. The

nonparametric statistic theta, on the other hand, measures how often a manager correctly ranks a

Page 15: A Nonparametric Test of Market Timing1

15

market movement and appropriately acts on it, instead of measuring how aggressively she acts

on it. We see that in the linear response case,

1|ˆˆˆˆ

Pr2321

12

1122

23

2233,,,

,,

,,,,

,,

,,,, −

<<

−−

>−−

= tmtmtmtmtm

tmtmtmtm

tmtm

tmtmtmtm rrrrr

rrrrrr

rrrrλλθ ,

where λ cancels out. The probability of a correct signal is closely related to the signal quality,

while the magnitude has more to do with the fund manager’s risk aversion. Thus our measure

largely reflects quality, and offers a way to estimate timing ability without a simultaneous

estimation of risk aversion which has been a difficult task in empirical studies.9 For the same

reason, there is great complementarity between the nonparametric method and the two other

methods. Used together in empirical work they can offer a more complete picture of market

timing performance of fund managers.

The theta statistic can also be extended to the context of conditional market timing. The

literature on conditional performance evaluation stresses the importance of distinguishing

abnormal performance that merely reflects publicly available information (as captured by a set of

lagged instrumental variables) from performance attributed to better information. In the context

of market timing, work by Ferson and Schadt (1996), Harvey and Graham (1996), Becker, et al.

(1999), and Ferson and Khang (2000) are all in this line. The conditional market timing

approach assumes that investors can time the market on their own using readily available public

information, or they can undo any perverse timing that is predicted from the public information

by trading on other accounts. Under such circumstances, the real contribution of a fund manager

would be her successful timing on the residual part of market returns that is not predictable from

public information.

Let tmr ,~ be the residuals of market returns that cannot be explained by lagged instrumental

variables. Then a conditional version of our measure is to test whether a fund manager, on

average, maintains a relatively high tβ when the unexplained part of the return 1,~

+tmr is

relatively high. Accordingly, we can use a variation of the statistic defined in (9) to capture 9 Becker, et al. (1999) estimate signal precision and funds’ risk aversion simultaneously, but the estimated risk aversion coefficients are largely out of reasonable range (and being negative in some cases).

Page 16: A Nonparametric Test of Market Timing1

16

funds’ conditional performance on market timing. Specifically, the test statistics is computed on

all triplets such that kmjmim rrr ,,,~~~ << :

=

−<

−−

−>

−−

<< imrjmrirjr

jmrkmrjrkr

imrjmrirjr

jmrkmrjrkrn

kmrjmrimrnU

,,,,1

,,,,1

1

3 ,~

,~

,~

~ . (12)

The standard error of nU~ can be estimated using (10) with ( )kji zzzh ,, replaced by

<<−

−<

−−

<<−

−>

kmrjmrimrimrjmr

irjr

jmrkmrjrkr

kmrjmrimrimrjmr

irjr

jmrkmrjrkr

,~

,~

,~|

,,,,1,

~,

~,

~|,,,,

1 .

2.3.4. Model Specification and Potential Bias

Theoretically superior performance of managed portfolios can be decomposed into selectivity

and timing components (Admati, et al., 1986; Griblatt and Titman, 1990), but such

decomposition has been proved difficult empirically (Coggin, et al., 1993; Kothari and Warner,

2001). Like other timing measures, our measure relies on two assumptions to avoid detecting

spurious timing because of selectivity issues. The first assumption is that a portfolio manager’s

information on the selectivity side (individual securities) is independent of her information on

the timing side (market movement). Practically this requires that each individual security

constitutes only a small portion of a diversified portfolio and has a negligible impact on the

whole market,10 or the fund manager acts on selectivity at a much lower frequency than on

market timing (so that the manager keeps roughly constant the composition of her risky portfolio

for most of the times when she tries to time the market frequently). The second assumption is

that the portfolio does not consist of derivatives, such as options, whose returns bear a convex

(concave) relationship with the market in the absence of market timing.

For most timing measures, bias in estimation would arise when econometricians observe

return data at a frequency different from the frequency at which the manager times the market.

Goetzmann, et al. (2000) show that monthly evaluation of daily timers using the HM measure is

10 This may not be a reasonable assumption for large companies and industry bellwethers.

Page 17: A Nonparametric Test of Market Timing1

17

biased downward. At the same time, a big component of timing skill would show up as

selectivity. Bollen and Busse (2001) show that the results of standard timing tests are sensitive

to the frequency of data used. The major source of the bias is the mis-specification of the

regressor [ ]+mr in the HM equation which should take different values depending on the actual

timing frequency, while the regressions use returns at uniform frequencies (such as monthly).

Goetzmann, et al. (2000) suggest replacing the monthly option value [ ]+mr with accumulated

daily option value when daily data are not readily available. Our simulation (more details at the

end of this section) show that the theta measure is more robust to the difference between timing

frequency and sampling frequency because it does not rely on a regression involving a

potentially unknown regressor, that is, [ ]+mr measured on the “right” frequency.

Another problem is the negative correlation between estimated selectivity and timing in the

context of TM or HM type regression models (Jagannathan and Korajczyk, 1986; Coggin, 1993).

The negative correlation may well arise as an artifact because of the negatively correlated

sampling errors from the two estimates. Our simulation shows that a significant negative

correlation between the two estimated abilities would occur in the TM or HM models (or

between the selectivity measure from one model and the timing measure from the other) even

when the correlation is non-existent. Goetzmann, et al. (2000) and Coggin, et al. (1993) have

similar results. On the other hand, the correlation between theta and the selectivity measures

from standard regression models is close to the truth (which is zero by the construction of the

simulation). Therefore, if one is interested in testing whether the information about individual

securities and overall market movement are largely independent, or whether good stock pickers

tend to be bad timer, it would be a good idea to compose the two measures from two statistical

procedures that have little correlated sampling errors. This can be done, for example, by

calculating the correlation between the theta measure and the alpha measure from other

regression-based models. However, such a method to isolate timing from selectivity still

depends on a reliable estimation of selectivity,11 an issue that falls out of the scope of this paper.

11 Several papers, e.g., Goetzmann, et al. (2000) and Kothari and Warner (2001), point out the difficulty of measuring accurately selectivity using multifactor regression models.

Page 18: A Nonparametric Test of Market Timing1

18

2.3.5. Statistical Robustness

Breen, et al. (1986) point out that heteroscedasticity can significantly affect the conclusion of the

HM tests. Jagannathan and Korajczyk (1986) and Goetzmann, et al. (2000) demonstrate the bias

of the HM measure due to skewness. The theta measure, on the other hand, is asymptotically

distribution free. Abrevaya and Jiang (2000) prove that the asymptotic distribution of the U-

statistic is unaffected by heteroscedasticity or skewness. Finally, statistically nU in (9) is the

least variance estimator among all unbiased estimators of θ in (8). The simulation results shown

in Abrevaya and Jiang (2000) demonstrate that the nonparametric test has accurate size even for

small samples and is robust (both the value of the statistic and its standard error) to outliers, non-

normality, and heteroscedasticity which are common in financial data.12

2.4. Simulations

In this section we compare the effectiveness of all three methods using simulations. We simulate

on two sample sizes, 60 and 120 monthly returns. The market returns tmr , are the last five or ten

years of the S&P500 monthly returns as of December 1999. The first two unconditional

moments are calculated from the data to calibrate ( )mrE and ( )mrσ . Assume that both ( )mrE

and ( )mrσ are public knowledge. The fund return data are generated according to (1). Assume

that the manager receives a private signal in the noise-additive form of (3). Her response to the

signal is making the portfolio beta a linear function of the signal as specified in (10).

The quality of the manager’s private information is characterized by ησ , the standard

deviation of tη . We classify the quality of information into three groups: precise ( ( )mrσση 2= ),

medium ( ( )mrσση 4= ), and coarse ( ( )mrσση 8= ). They correspond to the correlation between

12 For example, Bollen and Busse (2001) test the hypothesis that fund returns are normally distributed, and reject normality at the one percent level. They also conjecture that the relative skewness of market and fund returns is driven by the crash of 1987 and other smaller crashes in the sample.

Page 19: A Nonparametric Test of Market Timing1

19

the signal and the actual market return ( )1,, +tmt ryρ being 0.44, 0.24, and 0.12 respectively.13

Similarly, we divide the response intensity into three groups: aggressive ( 20.0=λ ), medium

( 10.0=λ ), and conservative ( 05.0=λ ). For each information/response combination we apply

the three methods: the TM method, the HM method and the nonparametric method. We run

1,000 simulations for each design. At medium information quality and ten-year horizon, the

correlation between the nonparametric measure and the TM measure ranges from 0.42 to 0.44;

the same for the nonparametric measure and the HM measure ranges from 0.57 to 0.60. Both

correlations are lower when the manager reacts more aggressively to the signals. The correlation

between the TM and HM measures is high and stable at around 0.98. Quantitative results are

posted in Table 1 from which we can infer the following qualitative features.

First, Panel A of Table 1 reports the nonparametric measure θ̂ and the two γ̂ coefficients

from the TM and HM models. The θ̂ estimates are roughly invariant across different degrees of

responsiveness (aggressiveness) but vary significantly across different levels of information

quality (ability). Further, the standard errors of θ̂ are very robust to different specifications, too.

The two other methods are just the opposite. Both parametric γ̂ coefficients are basically

adjusted to the manager’s aggressiveness, and display little variation with the quality of

information. The intuition behind this separation is as follows:14 the TM and HM coefficients

essentially measure the expected convexity in the funds’ relation to the market return. That

reflects both the probability (related to signal quality) and the magnitude (related to risk

aversion). The nonparametric measure is just the probability, not the magnitude; thus it largely

reflects quality, not risk aversion.

[Table 1 Panel A here]

In Panel B of Table 1, we examine the spurious correlation between the estimated selectivity

ability and timing ability when the true correlation is non-existent ( 0=α by the construction of

the simulation). Since we design the simulation according to the TM model, the correctly

13 Farnsworth, et al. (2001) find that the best performing mutual funds (those in the upper 5%) have performance similar to artificial mutual funds that have the correlation values ranging from 0.24 to 0.32. 14 I am grateful to an anonymous referee for suggesting this interpretation.

Page 20: A Nonparametric Test of Market Timing1

20

specified TM regression produces unbiased estimation for selectivity, TMα̂ . We show the

correlation between TMα̂ and the timing measures from the three models. There is a significant

negative relationship between the selectivity and the timing measures from both the TM and HM

models. Coggin, et al. (1993) point out that such a negative correlation is largely an artifact of

negatively correlated sampling errors for the two estimates. The spurious part of the correlation

is difficult to be detached if one uses both selectivity and timing measures from one statistical

procedure or similar procedures (such as TM and HM). If we use θ̂ and TMα̂ as proxies for

timing and selectivity, the spurious correlation largely vanishes, especially at large samples.

[Table 1 Panel B here]

Next we examine the issue of using uniform measuring frequency (such as monthly) when

the timing frequency is unknown (can be daily or weekly). Simulations in Goetamann, et al.

(2000) show that the HM monthly measure severely underestimates the performance of daily

timers. Bollen and Busse (2001) show that standard tests of timing are very sensitive to data

frequency. We obtain the S&P 500 daily data from January 1990 to December 1999 from the

Center for Research in Securities Prices (CRSP). We simulate the daily returns of a daily timer

according to (11) using nine possible combinations of information quality and manager

responsiveness as before. Then we compound the daily return data into monthly returns and

proceed on the estimation with the monthly data only. Results are displayed in Table 1 Panel C.

Comparing them to those in Panel A, we see that the nonparametric test slightly underestimates

the daily timer’s ability when the information quality is high. At medium and low information

quality, the nonparametric test delivers quite accurate results. On the other hand, the magnitude

of timing is reduced by about two-thirds for the TM and the HM methods. The latter result is

consistent with what obtained by Goetamann, et al. (2000) using data simulated from the HM

model. At medium information quality and medium responsiveness, the average θ̂ for monthly

and daily timer are 0.124 and 0.123 respectively, the average TMγ̂ changes from 0.101 to 0.031,

and the average HMγ̂ from 2.093 to 0.572. As we discussed before, the TM and HM measures

largely pick up the magnitude of convexity of fund returns against the market. Linear

regressions produce downward (in magnitude) biased estimates when the regressor is measured

Page 21: A Nonparametric Test of Market Timing1

21

with error. On the other hand, the nonparametric measure is about the probability of convexity,

which is less affected by the measurement frequency.

[Table 1 Panel C here]

3. Testing Market Timing of Mutual Funds

3.1. Data

Data in this paper are retrieved from Morningstar Principai Pro Plus for Mutual Funds (1980-

1999) published by Morningstar Incorporated in January 2000 and the CRSP Bias-Free Mutual

Funds Data. Morningstar offers quality data on surviving funds of all categories on the monthly

frequency. To overcome the survivorship bias, we supplemented the data set with the perished

funds from the CRSP data.

For the purpose of this research, we focused on diversified equity funds and domestic sector

funds that specialize in technology. The latter was included because those funds invest heavily

in a sector that had been high-flying and much more volatile than the overall stock market. It

would be interesting to see how well these funds perform in a sector where market timing can be

highly rewarding. Morningstar records separately multiple classes of shares issued by the same

fund out of basically the same portfolio. We use one series of return data (the one that has the

longest record) for each unique portfolio, but add together assets under management for that

fund. We exclude index funds and enhanced index funds whose managers are not expected to

time the market. We also exclude funds that have R2 greater than 0.95 from a regression on a

best-fitted index because these funds are highly suspicious of being “closet indexers.” Finally,

for estimation of meaningful accuracy, we only use funds (survived or perished) that have at

least two full years’ monthly return data within the 1980-1999 window. Altogether there are

1,827 surviving funds and 110 dead funds in the sample. The sample of dead funds are under-

represented because CRSP does not have data at monthly frequency for about half the dead funds

that perished during the 1980s. However, this does not affect the conclusion of our results. If

managers of perished funds do not have better market timing ability than those of live funds,

Page 22: A Nonparametric Test of Market Timing1

22

then evidence of no significant market timing ability is likely to hold up in a sample with full

information about perished funds.

All returns are expressed in percentage terms. Morningstar reports monthly returns that are

computed each month by taking the change in monthly net asset value (NAV), reinvesting all

income and capital gains during the month, and dividing by the starting NAV. Unless otherwise

noted, we do not adjust total returns for sales charges (such as front-end or deferred loads and

redemption fees), preferring to give a clearer picture of fund manager’s ability and strategy.

However, the returns do account for management, administrative, 12b-1 fees, and other costs that

are automatically taken out of fund assets. We use the monthly return of three-month T-bills as

the proxy for the riskfree rate fr . To find the proper benchmark for each funds, we regress its

returns on four representative indices: S&P 500 (benchmark for large-cap funds); S&P 400 (for

mid-cap funds); Russell 2000 (for small-cap funds); and NASDAQ Composite (for technology

funds). The index that gives the largest R2 of regression is selected as the benchmark for

measuring the fund’s market timing ability. The average R2 on a best-fitted index is 82.2%, and

the average R2 on the next best-fitted index is 72.4%.

The summary statistics of the mutual funds are reported in Table 2. We classify funds into

different groups according to their stated prospectus objective and best fitted indices. The seven

objective groups are: Small Company, Growth, Equity Income, Growth and Income, Asset

Allocation, Balanced, Specialty—Technology, and Aggressive Growth. We report the number

of funds in each group, the median assets under management, the mean monthly return and the

standard deviation, the mean alpha values from one-factor regressions and the standard

deviation, and the mean alpha values from Fama-French (1993) three-factor regressions and the

standard deviation. All together 26.1% of the live funds and 18.2% of the dead funds beat their

respective indices before taking out their sales charges.

[Table 2 here]

Page 23: A Nonparametric Test of Market Timing1

23

3.2. Do Funds Outguess the Market?

Using the nonparametric theta method introduced in the previous section, we are ready to test the

market timing ability of mutual funds. We assume that a fund manager sets a target average beta

according to the fund’s investment objective and policy. This is the unconditional expected beta

of the fund. In an attempt to time the market, the manager will vary the fund’s beta according to

her prediction about future market movement. The theta method lets us see how often the

manager sets a higher beta in a high market return period than in a low market return period. In

Table 3, we report the average market timing θ̂ estimation for all groups of funds, together with

the number of funds that have positive and negative θ̂ , and the number of funds whose θ̂ values

are significantly positive or negative (at 5% and 2.5% significance levels). In computing the

average θ̂ , we use both equal weighting and standard error weighting, that is, assigning a weight

to each fund’s θ̂ that is inversely proportional to its standard error.

[Table 3 Panel A here]

Overall there is no evidence that mutual fund managers possess superior market timing

abilities. The average θ̂ value of all live funds is –1.33, that of the dead funds is –2.62. As

expected, dead funds underperform live funds in market timing performance. According to the

interpretation of theta as defined in (8), the probability that the manager of an average live fund

moves the fund’s exposure to the market in the correct direction is 1.34 percentage points lower

than the probability of a move in the wrong direction. The total numbers of funds with positive

and negative θ̂ values are 719 to 1,108. Out of eight fund groups by stated prospectus

objectives, only the smallest fund group (special-technology) shows up an average θ̂ parameter

above the neutral level zero. All other seven groups have negative average timing coefficients,

and have more funds with θ̂ values significantly (at both 5% and 2.5% significance levels)

different from zero on the negative side than on the positive side. All fund groups by best-fitted

indices have average θ̂ values below zero. Further, the group of funds that is most expected to

time the market—Asset Allocation funds—has an average theta value of –1.8, which is not

indicative of their possessing superior market timing ability. These results are consistent with

Page 24: A Nonparametric Test of Market Timing1

24

those in Ferson and Schadt (1996), Becker, et al. (1999), Edelen (1999), and Goetzmann, et al.

(2000) on the tendency for perverse market timing estimates among mutual funds.

The top five percent market timers have θ̂ values above 8.47. Recall from (6) that in

probability terms, θ is equal to ( ) ( )1,1,1,1,1,1,1,1, 21212121|ˆˆPr|ˆˆPr ++++++++ ><−>> tmtmtmtmtmtmtmtm rrrrrrrr ,

the probability that a fund manager makes a right prediction about future market returns in

excess of the probability of a wrong one. Suppose the manager’s private signal takes the noise

additive form of (3). We find by simulation using the empirical distribution of the S&P 500

monthly returns during the sampling period (similar to the one we have done in Section 2.4) that

θ̂ equal to 8.47 corresponds the correlation between the manager’s signal and the future market

return being around 0.20. By the nature of the theta method, this estimation is not affected by

the manger’s risk aversion or the intensity of her reaction to her private signals. It is interesting

that Farnsworth, et al. (2001), through a completely different statistical procedure, find that the

best performing mutual funds (those in the upper 5%) have performance similar to artificial

mutual funds that have correlation values ranging from 0.24 to 0.32.

Since θ̂ is a random variable, with the large sample of mutual funds, we are bound to find

funds with significantly positive or negative θ̂ values even when the truth is 0=θ . Hence we

would like to see whether superior ability exists among fund managers beyond the statistical tail

probability. We plotted in Figure 1 and Figure 2 the cumulative empirical distribution of θ̂ of

all live and dead funds against normal distributions with the same standard deviation but

centered on the neutral value of zero (no ability). The empirical distributions lie mostly above

the reference normal distributions, suggesting that the empirical distributions are first-order

stochastically dominated by their respective reference normal distributions based on the

hypothesis of no ability. We applied the Kleacan-McFadden-McFadden (1991) robust test for

stochastic dominance15 on both empirical distributions of θ̂ and their respective normal

15 The test is based on the following idea: if F does not first-order stochastically dominate G, then

[ ] 0)()(maxmax >−= xGxFd , for all values of x within the support. The test statistic is built on the empirical

analogue d̂ by constructing )(ˆmax xd of F against G at fine grids. The resulting statistic follows a non-standard distribution and its standard error is obtained through an algorithm provided in Kleacan, et al. (1991).

Page 25: A Nonparametric Test of Market Timing1

25

distributions with equal variances. The test rejects the hypothesis that the normal distribution

does not first-order stochastically dominate the empirical distribution of live funds at 1%

significance level, and that of dead funds at 5% significance level (the significance level is

higher due to a smaller sample size). This result implies that the distribution of timing ability of

actively managed funds is first-order stochastically dominated by a normal distribution that

would prevail if no superior ability exists on average and manager’s abilities are similarly

dispersed. If an investor does not have superior knowledge about individual managers’ ability,

she would be better off timing wise by choosing an index fund (no timing) than randomly

choosing a fund from the pool of actively managed funds.

[Figure 1 here]

[Figure 2 here]

As a comparison, we list in Table 3 Panel B the TM and HM estimation of market timing for

the same sample. The correlations between the TM and the HM estimates are above 0.90 for all

groups. The correlations between the nonparametric and the TM estimates vary from 0.29 to

0.62, those between the nonparametric and the HM measures range from 0.44 to 0.73. The latter

correlation is higher because, as we discuss in Section 2, the HM measure caters more on the

information quality side of the market timing while the TM measure basically reflects the

intensity of manager’s reaction. The group of Special-Technology funds has positive average

market timing using all three methods. All other fund groups except the Asset Allocation group

have negative average timing parameters using all three methods. The average TMγ̂ value of

Asset Allocation funds is positive but is very close to zero (in a magnitude of 0.13 of its standard

error). The aggregate picture of mutual funds’ market timing performance is similar across

different methods. For the purpose of individual fund evaluation, however, the three methods

contain different information.

[Table 3 Panel B]

It is hard to see why equity fund managers as a whole end up mistiming the market when no

timing can be done easily by passive management. One hypothesis is that the real contribution

of market timing concerns private information, not publicly available information. The

Page 26: A Nonparametric Test of Market Timing1

26

conditional performance evaluation literature says that investors will not pay managers to use

readily available public information, nor would they penalize managers for mistiming that is

predictable from the public information. According to the view taken in this literature, any effect

of timing or mistiming stemming from the public information component is spurious timing.

Work by Ferson and Schadt (1996), Ferson and Warther (1996), and Becker, et al. (1999) show

that fund managers do vary beta according to publicly available information, such as past returns,

dividend yields, and term structure. More importantly, their results indicate that conditioning

beta on such public information removes part of the negative value of the TMγ̂ coefficient in a

TM type regression.

We use (12) to analyze mutual funds’ market timing on information that is more

sophisticated than those readily implied by publicly available indicators and lagged variables.

To represent public information, we use a collection of variables that are adopted by previous

studies on conditional market timing (Becker, et al., 1999; Ferson and Khang, 2000). The

variables are: (1) the lagged level of the one-month Treasury bill yield, less its 12-month lagged

moving average; (2) the lagged dividend-to-price ratio for the CRSP value-weighted NYSE and

Amex stock index; (3) the lagged slope of the U.S. Treasury yield curve measured as the

difference between four-year and one-year fixed-maturity bond yields from the CRSP Fama-

Bliss files, and (4) a dummy variable for the month of January. We use four months’ lagged

values for the first three variables. The results are reported in Table 3 Panel C. Comparing it

with Panel A we see that funds’ timing on the unpredicted part of the market returns is almost

identical to their timing on the aggregate market returns, and the overall performance is on the

negative side. Therefore after controlling for the public information, we find no evidence that

mutual funds have market timing ability based on superior information. This result is not

surprising since the lagged variables only explain less than four percent of the variations in

market returns, and the overall picture of timing on gross returns should not be much different

from timing on residual returns. The empirical work by Edelen (1999) attributes the poor timing

performance to the cost of liquidity motivated trading caused by the random in and out flows of

funds, an issue we will also address in the next section. Another explanation is human

Page 27: A Nonparametric Test of Market Timing1

27

psychology, if traders are more prone to taking profits than taking losses (Odean, 1998), the mis-

timing phenomenon can result.

[Table 3 Panel C here]

Finally, we want to check that the deviation of the theta values from the neutral level zero is

mainly due to timing instead of to holding particular classes of assets that exhibit timing

characteristics. Jagannathan and Korajczyk (1986) predict that funds investing in small stocks

can show up spurious timing against a market benchmark that consists mainly of big stocks. For

example, they find that an equally weighted stock index shows “timing” relative to a value-

weighted index. This is because small stocks have payoffs resembling that of a call option

related to its underlying assets. This is why we classify mutual funds into groups by best-fitted

indices (from the large-cap S&P 500 to the small-cap Russell 2000) and test market timing of

funds relative their own benchmarks, instead of relative to a uniform market portfolio. To check

whether common factors (such as book-to-market ratio) may interfere with our timing test

results, we apply the same nonparametric test on the Fama-French (1993) factor portfolios

against the market indices that we use for the same sampling period. Altogether there are six

factor-mimicking portfolios sorted by size (small and big) and book-to-market equity (low,

medium, and high). We find none of the six portfolios exhibits timing characteristics relative to

the indices we use at less than 10% significance level. Therefore, our results on market timing

should not be driven by the characteristics of the portfolios that mutual funds hold. However, the

TM and HM regressions show that the small size portfolios sorted by book-to-market show some

spurious timing effect relative to the small-cap index Russell 2000. Both regressions produce

positive and significant (at 5% level) timing coefficients for the Small/Low portfolio, and

negative and significant (at 5% level) timing coefficients for the Small/Medium and Small/High

portfolios. This points out that performance measurement can be sensitive to benchmark

specification.

The overall mis-timing phenomenon is related to the puzzle that the Jensen’s alpha is

predominantly negative among actively managed funds (Jensen, 1972; Gruber, 1996). Work by

Grinblatt and Titman (1989), and Goetzmann, et al. (2000) address the bias that time-varying

Page 28: A Nonparametric Test of Market Timing1

28

betas introduce into performance evaluation measures. In the HM model, for example, the

manger sets a higher target beta in an up market than in a down market. Suppose the manager

does not possess any selectivity information, i.e., alpha is zero, but she can perfectly predict the

general market movement. Then the portfolio return as a function of the market return will be a

piece-wise linear function convexly kinked at the origin. Regressions without control for timing

would pick up a positive alpha under such circumstances. That is, timing ability shows up as

selectivity. Symmetrically, negative alpha can be partially attributed to market mis-timing.

3.3. Some Related Questions

In this section we analyze some related questions about market timing by focusing on the live

funds. The issues of interest are: (1) Do experienced managers do better in timing the market?

(2) Is it easier for small funds to time the market? (3) Can the high turnover ratio of actively

managed funds be justified as successful attempts to time the market? And (4) does funds’

market timing impaired by the in- and out-flows of investment money? We report the results in

Table 4. Overall the relationship between the average timing performance and fund

characteristics is weak. It is difficult to predict market timing ability of fund managers from

observable characteristics.

[Table 4 here]

3.3.1. Does Experience Matter?

If established funds are more likely to be matched to experienced managers, we can test upon

fund age to see whether experience contributes to better timing ability. Results are posted in

Table 4 Panel A. Estimated averaged market timing ability increases monotonically with the age

of funds. Young funds (less than five years old) have a weighted average θ̂ of –1.533. The

same estimates for the medium aged funds (between five and ten years old) and old funds (more

than ten years old) are –1.315 and –1.250 respectively. Therefore, older funds are doing better

Page 29: A Nonparametric Test of Market Timing1

29

on average than younger funds. However, the survivorship bias, if any, would work in favor of

the older funds.

We can also use manager tenure directly as a proxy for experience. In the data set we only

have the tenure information of the current managers. Accordingly we crop out the turn data that

they are responsible for. We divide all managers into three groups depending on whether their

tenure is less than three years, between three and five years, or five years and more. The results

are shown in Panel B. The least experienced manager group (manager tenure less than three

years) has an average θ̂ of -1.550, those of more experiences groups (manager tenure between

three and five years, and five years or more) are –1.284 and –1.326. And there are

proportionately more out of experienced managers who turn out extraordinary records.

However, the length of manager tenure is endogenous to the mutual fund performance. The

manager who remains in the position for a long time is likely to have produced a reasonably

good record. Further, from the data such differences from experience are not statistically

significant. In general these results show that it is very difficult to outguess the market in the

long run.

3.3.2. Do Small Funds Fare Better?

One common sense has that small funds are in a better position to time the market since it is easy

for them to reshuffle their portfolios in a timely manner without affecting the market. This is

also consistent with the efficient market hypothesis that activities out of (costly) superior

information must be “small” relative to the market.

The size of the funds varies from less than 1 million to 99,184 million dollars in the sample.

The median is 104.75 million dollars. We divide the funds into four groups: Micro (under 20

million dollars), Small (up to 100 million), Big (up to 500 million), and Huge (500 million or

more). Results are shown in Table 4 Panel C. Estimated market timing ability deteriorates

monotonically with fund size. From the smallest to the biggest fund groups, estimated average

θ̂ are –0.629, -1.420, -1.432, and -1.635 respectively. The Micro fund group beats the Huge

fund group at 5% significance. It seems that on average small funds are doing better than their

Page 30: A Nonparametric Test of Market Timing1

30

larger counterparts. Especially the percentages of those with theta significantly smaller than zero

suggest a larger proportion of mis-timers among big and huge funds, who drive down their group

average results.

Chevalier and Ellison (1999) document that small mutual funds are managed often by more

experienced managers. Too see whether part of the small fund timing premium is attributed to

manager experience, we make a comparison by a two-way sort on fund size and manager tenure.

It turns out that the difference of timing performance due to fund size is similar across manager

tenure. For manager with less than three years in tenure, the timing performance of Micro/Small

funds and Big/Huge funds are -1.335 versus –1.840. For mangers with five years or more in

tenure, the corresponding estimates are –1.044 and –1.478 respectively.

3.3.3. Is High Turnover Rate Justified as Timing?

The turnover rate of a fund is a proxy for how frequently a manager trades her portfolio. The

inverse of a fund’s turnover rate is the average holding period for a security in that fund. If one

maintains a S&P 500 benchmark portfolio, the average annual turnover rate is about 4-6% for the

past ten years.16 As a comparison, the average turnover rate of actively managed funds investing

in the same market is 92.8%. Assuming turnover rate is positively correlated with the frequency

of timing-oriented trading, we would like to see to what extent does high turnover represent

successful market timing.

1,708 funds out of 1,827 report their annual turnover rates in the Morningstar database. We

divide all reporting funds into three categories according to their average annual turnover rates

during the sampling period: Low (less than 50%), Median (between 50% and 100%), and High

(100% or higher) turnover. Results are shown in Table 4 Panel D. It turns out that the highest

turnover fund group has the worst market timing record with an average theta value of –1.580.

Moderate turnover funds (-1.130) slightly outperform low turnover funds (-1.419). This result is

consistent with Morningstar’s report that mutual funds with annual turnover higher than 100%

16 Source: Vanguard 500 index fund.

Page 31: A Nonparametric Test of Market Timing1

31

significantly underperform their lower turnover counterparts. 17 In particular, the group of Asset

Allocation funds usually explicitly market themselves as market timers. Managers of those

funds often use a flexible combination of stocks, bonds, and cash; and shift assets frequently

based on their analyses of market trends. The average annual turnover rate of Asset Allocators is

114.4%, which is higher than the average of all funds. The relationship between average timing

and turnover rate for Asset Allocators is very similar to that of other funds. Results are shown in

Table 4 Panel B. Asset allocators with moderate turnovers have the best timing performance (-

0.878), outperforming that of low turnover asset allocators (-2.016) and high turnover ones (-

2.565).

It seems that moderate turnover represents some market timing while very high turnover

rates cannot be justified as effective timing. Dow and Gorton (1997) consider a model where

portfolio managers trade even though they have no reason to because their clients cannot

distinguish “actively doing nothing” from “simply doing nothing.” Lakonishok, et al. (1991) tell

a story that fund managers dress up their portfolios, and selling off the losers in particular, before

disclosing to the public in order to make the composition look “smart.” Haugen and Lakonishok

(1988) suggest window dressing by professional money managers as a possible explanation of

the “January Effect.” Funds engaging in such window dressing activities are selling to avoid

apologizing for and defending a losing stock’s presence to clients even though the investment

judgment may be to hold (Lakonishok, et al., 1991). As such, the high turnover rate can go with

mis-timing.

3.3.4. Do Investor Flows Affect Market Timing?

One plausible explanation about mutual funds’ unsatisfactory timing performance has been its

open nature (as opposed to closed-end funds). While fund managers try to time the market, there

are investors who attempt at timing the mutual finds. When the market fares well, new money

flows in, and the funds have a higher portion of their portfolios in cash, which results in lower

betas. When the market dips, more investors try to redeem their shares, then the cash reserve

17 Source: Morningstar report September 12, 1997.

Page 32: A Nonparametric Test of Market Timing1

32

runs low, which leads to higher betas. Further, without a stream of new money, big redemption

orders can force funds to liquidate shares often at inopportune times, such as selling into a falling

market. From this point of view, market mis-timing of mutual funds constitutes a price that

investors have to pay for the liquidity that they enjoy with open-end funds. Edelen (1999)

documents a negative relation between a fund’s risk-adjusted return and investor flows, and

attributed the negative return performance at open-end mutual funds to the cost of liquidity-

motivated trading.

Such logic implicitly assumes that fund investors can time the market ahead of the fund

managers. Only if investor money flows in prior to market ascendancy or flows out prior to

market descent will hit offset fund managers’ market timing endeavor. Works by Gruber (1996)

and Zheng (1999) show some evidence that funds receiving more money subsequently beat the

market—the “smart money” effect, but in the aggregate such effect is weak. Warther (1995)

documents a positive relation between flows and subsequent returns in the weekly data. Short-

term switchers in and out of funds are more likely to attack on no-load funds where they take the

advantage of the cost-free entry and exit. Hence we can look at the possible difference in timing

between load and no-load funds and infer whether fund managers’ timing ability is impaired by

investor flows. Out of the 1,827 funds, 1,012 are no-load funds. Results in Table 4 Panel E

show that load funds (with an average theta value of -1.215) slightly outperform no-load funds (-

1.467), but overall the timing performance profiles of the two groups of funds are very similar.

Further, from investors’ point of view, index funds also provide the liquidity service the cost of

which has been negligible.18

There has been evidence in the literature that retail investors and institutional investors make

their investment decisions quite differently, both with respect to the timing and to the

information content of their investment. Sias and Starks (1997) find that institutional investors

are more likely to be informed traders by comparing the return autocorrelation of securities and

portfolios dominated by institutional investors with those dominated by individual investors. In

18 Since its inception, for example, the Vanguard Total Stock Market Index Fund has lagged the index return for only 0.3%, the Vanguard 500 Index Fund about 0.2% annually, although they stand ready for investors’ purchase or redemption as open-end funds.

Page 33: A Nonparametric Test of Market Timing1

33

addition, if informative signals about market returns contain a marketwise component (i.e., they

are cross-sectionally correlated), then funds mainly open to institutional investors are likely to

have more difficulty timing the market because the informed in- and out-flows of investor money

can offset the funds’ attempt to time the market. To see whether this effect is reflected in data,

we divide funds into retail and institutional funds using $25,000 minimum initial investment as

the cutoff between the two. In Table 4 Panel F we compare the timing skills of the two groups of

funds. There are 1,557 retail funds and 210 institutional funds in the sample. Retail funds have

an average theta –1.330 while that of the institutional funds is –1.822. The result is consistent

with the hypothesis that funds’ market timing is impaired by informed investor money flows, but

the difference is not significant.

4. Conclusion

In this paper we propose a nonparametric test for money managers’ market timing ability and

apply the analysis to a large sample of domestic equity funds that have different benchmark

indices. Theta, the parameter for timing ability, is on average negative among actively managed

equity funds. The distribution of the estimated theta of all equity funds, both live and dead, are

first-order stochastically dominated by the equal variance normal distributions based on the null

hypothesis of no timing ability. Further, the number of funds that display extraordinary timing

ability is smaller than that implied by the right-tail probability of the reference normal

distribution.

Common wisdoms have that manager experience, small fund size and stable investment

money contribute to better timing performance. We find that average timing performance bears

a positive relationship with fund age or management tenure (proxy for manager experience), and

fund load (proxy for the stability of fund flow), and bears a negative relation with fund size.

Further, funds with moderate turnover rates outperform both low and high turnover funds.

However, overall the relation between market timing ability and fund characteristics are very

weak. The differences of the average market timing ability between different fund groups are

small to make any economic significance. Overall market timing ability is fund specific and is

Page 34: A Nonparametric Test of Market Timing1

34

very difficult to predict by observable characteristics. This implies that it is difficult for

investors to pick up good timers from the universe of mutual funds

With the overall negative theta values, the beta from a CAPM type regression tends to

underestimate the true systematic risk of a fund and the alpha tends to exaggerate on negative

selectivity. The negative pictures on both timing and selectivity documented by this paper and

previous studies inevitably translate into mutual funds’ total returns. Among actively managed

funds that primarily invest in domestic equities up to December 1999, only about 19.2% of the

funds beat the Vanguard S&P 500 index fund over the past 15 years , 21.8% over the past ten

years, 14.2% over the past five years, and 20.8% over the most recent three years, all before

accounting for sales charges and tax exposure. When an average actively managed fund does not

time the market successfully, investors without superior information about mutual funds would

be a better market timer by holding the relevant index portfolio. It would be imposing to expect

from an average investor the ability to select and to time mutual funds when lack of time or

ability to do so is the reason for an investor to hire a professional money manager in the first

place.

References

Abrevaya, J., Jiang, W, 2000. Simple statistics for testing curvature. Working paper, University

of Chicago Graduate School of Business.

Admati, A. Bhattacharya, S., Pfleiderer, P., Ross, S., 1986. On timing and selectivity. Journal of

Finance 41, 715-730.

Barber, B., Odean, T., 2000. Trading is hazardous to your wealth: the common stock

investment performance of individual investors. Journal of Finance 55, 773-806.

Becker, C., Ferson, W., Myers, D., Schill, M., 1999. Conditional market timing with benchmark

investors. Journal of Financial Economics 52, 119-148.

Blackwell, D., Comparison of experiments. Proceedings of Second Berkeley Symposium on

Mathematical Statistics and Probability, 93-102, University of California Press.

Page 35: A Nonparametric Test of Market Timing1

35

Bollen, N., and Busse, J., 2001. On the timing ability of mutual fund managers. Journal of

Finance 56, 1075-1094.

Breen, W., Jagannathan, R., Ofer, A., 1986. Correcting for heteroscedasticity in tests for market

timing ability. Journal of Business 59, 585-598.

Chevalier, J., Ellison, G., 1997. Risk taking by mutual funds as a response to incentives. Journal

of Political Economy 105, 1167-1200.

Chevalier, J., Ellison, G., 1999. Are some mutual funds managers better than others? Cross-

sectional patterns in behavior and performance. Journal of Finance 54, 875-899.

Coggin, D., Fabozzi, F., Rahman, S., 1993. The investment performance of U.S. equity pension

fund managers: An empirical investigation. Journal of Finance 48, 1039-1055.

Cumby, R., and Modest, D., 1987. Testing for market timing ability. Journal of Financial

Economics, 19, 169-189.

Dewatripont, M., Jewitt, I., Tirole, J., 1999. The economics of career concerns, part I:

comparing information structures. The Review of Economic Studies 66, 183-198.

Dow, J., Gorton, G., 1997. Noise trading, delegated portfolio management, and economic

welfare. Journal of Political Economy 105, 1024-1050.

Edelen, R., 1999. Investor flows and the assessed performance of open-end mutual funds.

Journal of Financial Economics 53, 439-466.

Edwin, E., Gruber, M., Das, S., Hlavka, M., 1993. Efficiency with costly information: a

reinterpretation of evidence from managed portfolios. The Review of Financial Studies 6, 1-

22.

Fama, E., French, K., 1993. Common risk factors in the returns on stocks and bonds. Journal of

Financial Economics 33, 3-56.

Farnsworth, H., Ferson, W., Jackson, D., Todd, S., 2001. Performance evaluation with stochastic

discount factors. Journal of Business forthcoming.

Ferson, W., and Khang, K., 2000. Conditional performance measurement using portfolio

weights: Evidence for pension funds. University of Washington working paper.

Page 36: A Nonparametric Test of Market Timing1

36

Ferson, W., Schadt, R., 1996. Measuring fund strategy and performance in changing economic

conditions. The Journal of Finance 51, 425-461.

Ferson, W., Warther, V., 1996. Evaluating fund performance in a dynamic market. Financial

Analysts Journal 52, 20-28.

Goetzmann, W., Ingersoll, J., Jr., Ivkovich, Z., 2000. Monthly Measurement of Daily Timers.

Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 35, 257-290.

Graham, J., Harvey, C., 1996. Market timing ability and volatility implied in investment

newsletters' asset allocation recommendations. Journal of Financial Economics 42, 397-421.

Grinblatt, M., Titman, S., 1990. Portfolio performance evaluation: Old issues and new insights.

Review of Financial Studies 2, 393-421.

Gruber, M., 1996. Another puzzle: the growth in actively managed mutual funds, The Journal

of Finance 51, 783-809.

Haugen, R., Lakonishok, J., 1988. The Incredible January Effect, Homewood: Dow Jones

Irwin.

Henriksson, R., Merton, R., 1981. On market timing and investment performance. II. Statistical

procedures for evaluating forecasting skills, Journal of Business 54, 513-533.

Jagannathan, R., Korajczyk, R., 1986. Assessing the market timing performance of managed

portfolios. Journal of Business 59, 217-235.

Jensen, M., 1968. The performance of mutual funds in the period 1945-1964. Journal of

Finance 23, 389-416.

Jensen, M., 1972. Optimal utilization of market forecasts and the evaluation of investment

portfolio performance, in: Szego, G., Shell, K., Mathematical Methods in Investment and

Finance. North Holland, Amsterdam.

Klecan, L., McFadden, R., McFadden, D., 1991. A robust test for stochastic dominance.

Unpublished paper, MIT.

Kosik, J., Pontiff, J., 1999. How are derivative used? Evidence from the mutual fund industry.

Journal of Finance 54, 791-816.

Page 37: A Nonparametric Test of Market Timing1

37

Kothari, S., Warner, J., 2001. Evaluating mutual fund performance. Journal of Finance,

forthcoming.

Lakonishok, J., Shleifer, A., Thaler, R., Vishny, R., 1991. Window dressing by pension fund

managers. American Economic Review Papers and Proceedings 81, 227-231.

Merton, R., 1981. On market timing and investment performance. I. An equilibrium theory of

value for market forecasts. Journal of Business 54, 363-406.

Odean, T., 1998. Are investors reluctant to realize their losses? Journal of Finance 53, 1775-

1798.

Serfling, R., 1980. Approximation Theorems of Mathematical Statistics. Wiley, New York.

Sias, R., Starks, L., 1997. Return autocorrelation and institutional investors. Journal of

Financial Economics 46, 103-131.

Treynor, J., and Mazuy, K., 1966. Can mutual funds outguess the market? Harvard Business

Review 44, 131-136.

Warther, V., 1995. Aggregate mutual fund flows and security returns. Journal of Financial

Economics 39, 209-235.

White, H., 1980. A heteroscedasticity-consistent covariance matrix estimator and a direct test

for heteroscedasticity. Econometrica 48, 817-838.

Zheng, L., 1999. Is money smart? A study of mutual fund investors' fund selection ability. The

Journal of Finance 54, 901-933.

Page 38: A Nonparametric Test of Market Timing1

38

Table 1. Comparison of Three Measures of Market Timing Panel A. Three Market Timing Parameters: What Do They Measure

Returns are simulated according to equation (1) with sample sizes equal to 60 and 120 (months). The quality of information is classified into three groups: precise, medium, and coarse based on the magnitude of ησ . Similarly, the response intensity is sorted by λ into three groups: aggressive, medium, and conservative. The average estimated market timing parameters using the three methods are displayed and their standard deviations are shown in the parentheses.

Nonparametric Treynor-Mazuy Henriksson-Merton

Precise

mrσση 2=

Medium

mrσση 4=

Coarse

mrσση 8=

Precise

mrσση 2=

Medium

mrσση 4=

Coarse

mrσση 8=

Precise

mrσση 2=

Medium

mrσση 4=

Coarse

mrσση 8=

Sample size = 60

Aggressive

20.0=λ

0.204

(0.070)

0.122

(0.072)

0.060

(0.072)

0.204

(0.078)

0.209

(0.157)

0.208

(0.318)

4.422

(1.609)

4.529

(3.152)

4.495

(6.241)

Medium

10.0=λ

0.200

(0.068)

0.120

(0.072)

0.062

(0.072)

0.099

(0.041)

0.105

(0.084)

0.109

(0.165)

2.169

(0.779)

2.277

(1.604)

2.335

(3.138)

Conservative

05.0=λ

0.166

(0.064)

0.106

(0.070)

0.060

(0.072)

0.049

(0.022)

0.047

(0.042)

0.049

(0.078)

1.063

(0.498)

1.073

(0.804)

1.065

(1.467)

Sample size = 120

Aggressive

20.0=λ

0.234

(0.048)

0.128

(0.050)

0.066

(0.052)

0.200

(0.059)

0.198

(0.118)

0.203

(0.242)

4.151

(1.042)

4.123

(2.083)

4.189

(4.249)

Medium

10.0=λ

0.210

(0.048)

0.124

(0.050)

0.062

(0.052)

0.100

(0.029)

0.101

(0.059)

0.093

(1.119)

2.065

(0.516)

2.093

(1.043)

1.966

(2.088)

Conservative

05.0=λ

0.192

(0.044)

0.110

(0.048)

0.066

(0.050)

0.049

(0.015)

0.049

(0.030)

0.050

(0.059)

1.025

(0.268)

1.019

(0.523)

1.035

(1.038)

Page 39: A Nonparametric Test of Market Timing1

39

Table 1. Comparison of Three Measures of Market Timing (Continued) Panel B: Correlation between Estimated Selectivity and Timing

Use the same model specifications as in Panel A, we examine the correlation between estimated timing from different models and estimated selectivity ( TMα̂ ) from the TM model (which is unbiased). The first column (Nonparametric-HM) displays the correlation between θ̂ and TMα̂ ; the second column (TM-TM) and the third column (TM-HM) show the correlation between

TMγ̂ and TMα̂ , and that between HMγ̂ and TMα̂ .

Nonparametric-TM TM-TM HM-TM

Precise

mrσση 2=

Medium

mrσση 4=

Coarse

mrσση 8=

Precise

mrσση 2=

Medium

mrσση 4=

Coarse

mrσση 8=

Precise

mrσση 2=

Medium

mrσση 4=

Coarse

mrσση 8=

Sample size = 60

Aggressive

20.0=λ 0.033 -0.031 -0.008 -0.720 -0.688 -0.724 -0.630 -0.650 -0.649

Medium

10.0=λ -0.039 -0.019 0.028 -0.696 -0.726 -0.705 -0.596 -0.650 -0.653

Conservative

05.0=λ -0.093 -0.081 -0.017 -0.626 -0.694 -0.696 -0.595 -0.568 -0.618

Sample size = 120

Aggressive

20.0=λ 0.065 0.035 0.012 -0.721 -0.759 -0.726 -0.611 -0.653 -0.637

Medium

10.0=λ 0.013 0.002 0.024 -0.688 -0.734 -0.721 -0.630 -0.613 -0.622

Conservative

05.0=λ -0.047 -0.041 0.026 -0.639 -0.721 -0.711 -0.533 -0.625 -0.614

Page 40: A Nonparametric Test of Market Timing1

40

Table 1. Comparison of Three Measures of Market Timing (Continued) Panel C: Data Frequency: How Robust Is Monthly Measurement of Daily Timers?

We CRSP S&P500 daily return data for the January 1990 to December 1999 as the market return, and simulate the return data of a daily timer using the TM model as in Panel A. All return data are then compounded into monthly returns on which we perform the timing test using all three methods. For each case 1,000 simulations are tried, and the average estimated parameters are displayed in the table with their standard errors shown in the parentheses.

Nonparametric Treynor-Mazuy Henriksson-Merton

Precise

mrσση 2=

Medium

mrσση 4=

Coarse

mrσση 8=

Precise

mrσση 2=

Medium

mrσση 4=

Coarse

mrσση 8=

Precise

mrσση 2=

Medium

mrσση 4=

Coarse

mrσση 8=

Aggressive

20.0=λ

0.170

(0.039)

0.125

(0.039)

0.078

(0.039)

0.065

(0.018)

0.064

(0.021)

0.065

(0.032)

1.204

(0.320)

1.202

(0.381)

1.201

(0.578)

Medium

10.0=λ

0.169

(0.038)

0.123

(0.038)

0.073

(0.039)

0.031

(0.009)

0.031

(0.010)

0.031

(0.016)

0.577

(0.151)

0.572

(0.187)

0.569

(0.282)

Conservative

05.0=λ

0.167

(0.039)

0.124

(0.039)

0.075

(0.039)

0.015

(0.004)

0.015

(0.005)

0.015

(0.008)

0.283

(0.075)

0.283

(0.091)

0.274

(0.138)

Page 41: A Nonparametric Test of Market Timing1

41

Table 2. Summary Statistics of Mutual Funds

There are altogether 1,827 live funds and 110 dead ones in the sample. They are actively managed domestic equity funds that have at least two years’ monthly return data during the sampling period from January 1980 to December 1999. N is the number of funds in the group. Median Assets are expressed in term of million dollars. Mean and Std are the sample mean and standard deviation of monthly returns. 1Fα is the mean alpha value from one-factor regressions on the best-fitted indices, and Std( 1Fα ) is its sample standard deviation. 3Fα is the mean alpha value from the Fama-French (1993) three-factor regressions, and Std( 3Fα ) is its sample standard deviation.

Fund Group N Median Assets

($MM) Mean Std

1Fα Std( 1Fα ) 3Fα Std( 3Fα )

By Funds Prospectus Objective

Small company 333 139.55 1.545 6.042 0.095 0.692 0.079 0.654

Growth 722 187.60 1.744 5.291 -0.040 0.524 0.007 0.539

Equity income 94 165.40 1.200 3.625 -0.195 0.290 -0.198 0.268

Growth and income 256 212.30 1.374 4.154 -0.189 0.301 -0.184 0.281

Balanced 188 118.40 1.069 2.760 -0.118 0.327 -0.119 0.297

Asset allocation 120 108.80 1.019 2.871 -0.111 0.234 -0.108 0.202

Specialty-technology 39 724.40 3.890 9.191 0.711 1.025 1.453 1.214

Aggressive growth 75 119.15 2.063 6.758 -0.037 0.564 0.189 0.524

By Best-Fitted Indices

S&P 500 803 201.85 1.376 3.861 -0.177 0.283 -0.137 0.238

Page 42: A Nonparametric Test of Market Timing1

42

Fund Group N Median Assets

($MM) Mean Std

1Fα Std( 1Fα ) 3Fα Std( 3Fα )

S&P 400 240 106.90 1.178 4.431 -0.156 0.433 -0.254 0.378

Russell 2000 422 101.70 1.390 5.567 0.257 0.711 -0.014 0.619

NASDAQ Composite 362 278.90 2.469 6.776 -0.010 0.619 0.491 0.780

Dead funds 110 - 1.033 4.874 -0.392 0.532 -0.420 0.516

Page 43: A Nonparametric Test of Market Timing1

43

Table 3. Market Timing of Mutual Funds Panel A: The Nonparametric Method

This table reports the nonparametric estimation of mutual funds’ market timing abilities. The second column lists the equally weighted average θ̂ of all funds within the group, its standard error is reported in the parenthesis. The weighted average θ̂ (and its standard error in the parenthesis) reported in the third column uses weights that are inversely proportional to each estimation standard error. The fourth column shows the number of funds that have θ̂ above (below) zero. The fifth and sixth columns report the percentage of funds in each group that have θ̂ above (below) zero at 5% and 2.5% significance level.

Fund Group Mean θ̂ Weighted

Average θ̂

No. of θ̂ >0

(θ̂ <0)

% of θ̂ >0

(θ̂ <0) at 5%

% of θ̂ >0

(θ̂ <0) at 2.5%

By Funds Prospectus Objective

Small company -1.766

(0.356)

-1.389

(0.289)

133

(200)

2.40

(9.31)

0.60

(4.81)

Growth -0.725

(0.245)

-0.654

(0.184)

320

(402)

4.57

(5.96)

1.80

(3.46)

Equity income -2.658

(0.592)

-3.226

(0.448)

21

(73)

2.13

(18.1)

1.06

(13.8)

Growth and income -1.549 (0.357)

-1.764 (0.266)

90 (166)

3.52 (10.94)

1.95 (5.47)

Balanced -1.924

(0.442)

-2.245

(0.331)

61

(127)

1.06

(12.23)

1.06

(8.51)

Asset allocation -1.896

(0.634)

-1.775

(0.501)

45

(75)

0.83

(5.00)

0.00

(3.33)

Specialty-technology 2.633

(1.110)

2.494

(0.856)

28

(11)

7.69

(2.56)

5.13

(0.00)

Aggressive growth -2.393

(0.695)

-2.368

(0.541)

21

(54)

1.33

(10.67)

0.00

(5.33)

By Best-Fitted Indices

S&P 500 -0.163

(0.219)

-0.733

(0.159)

360

(443)

4.86

(8.22)

2.12

(5.11)

Page 44: A Nonparametric Test of Market Timing1

44

Fund Group Mean θ̂ Weighted

Average θ̂

No. of θ̂ >0

(θ̂ <0)

% of θ̂ >0

(θ̂ <0) at 5%

% of θ̂ >0

(θ̂ <0) at 2.5%

S&P 400 -4.368

(0.417)

-3.725

(0.313)

50

(190)

0.83

(16.3)

0.83

(10.83)

Russell 2000 -0.699

(0.319)

-0.294

(0.259)

203

(219)

2.61

(3.79)

0.47

(1.90)

NASDAQ Composite -2.624

(0.341)

-2.444

(0.270)

106

(256)

1.93

(9.94)

1.10

(4.70)

Dead funds -2.621

(0.672)

-2.932

(0.583)

41

(69)

3.63

(19.03)

1.82

(12.73)

Page 45: A Nonparametric Test of Market Timing1

45

Table 3. Market Timing of Mutual Funds (Continued) Panel B: The TM and HM methods

This table lists the market timing parameters from the TM and HM methods. Weighted average TMγ̂ and HMγ̂ use the inverse standard error weighting method. Their standard errors are White (1980) heteroscedasticity consistent. Corr.( θγ ˆˆ ,TM ) and Corr.( θγ ˆˆ ,HM ) are the coefficients of correlation between the TM/HM parameters and the nonparametric θ̂ values.

TM HM

Fund Group Weighted

Average TMγ̂

(10-3)

Std. Error

(10-3) Corr.( θγ ˆˆ ,TM )

Weighted

Average HMγ̂

(10-2)

Std. Error

(10-2) Corr.( θγ ˆˆ ,HM )

By Funds Prospectus Objective

Small company -3.362 0.233 0.617 -7.473 0.940 0.746

Growth -3.496 0.138 0.465 -7.134 0.510 0.601

Equity income -3.874 0.350 0.522 -9.416 1.108 0.744

Growth and income -3.266 0.206 0.509 -7.166 0.655 0.635

Balanced -0.514 0.199 0.412 -2.371 0.622 0.557

Asset allocation 0.031 0.239 0.288 -0.550 0.776 0.438

Specialty-technology 3.374 0.664 0.545 15.568 2.892 0.679

Aggressive growth -3.182 0.429 0.429 -10.944 1.776 0.570

By Best-Fitted Indices

S&P 500 -1.515 0.118 0.334 -2.870 0.358 0.491

S&P 400 -6.322 0.237 0.459 -18.105 0.835 0.660

Russell 2000 -2.804 0.199 0.567 -4.457 0.812 0.659

Page 46: A Nonparametric Test of Market Timing1

46

TM HM

Fund Group Weighted

Average TMγ̂

(10-3)

Std. Error

(10-3) Corr.( θγ ˆˆ ,TM )

Weighted

Average HMγ̂

(10-2)

Std. Error

(10-2) Corr.( θγ ˆˆ ,HM )

NASDAQ Composite -2.689 0.168 0.606 -7.172 0.746 0.699

Dead funds -4.104 0.487 0.549 -9.788 1.827 0.645

Page 47: A Nonparametric Test of Market Timing1

47

Table 3. Market Timing of Mutual Funds (Continued) Panel C: Conditional Market Timing

In this table θ̂ is calculated using equation (12), conditional on the residual market returns instead of on market returns. The residual market returns are the residuals of each index returns from a regression on lagged instrumental variables, which include the detrended TB yield, the dividend-to-price ratio for the CRSP value-weighted NYSE and Amex stock index, the slope of the U.S. Treasury yield curve measured as the difference between four-year and one-year fixed-maturity bond yields, and a dummy variable for the month of January.

Fund Group Mean θ̂ Weighted

Average θ̂

No. of θ̂ >0

(θ̂ <0)

% of θ̂ >0

(θ̂ <0) at 5%

% of θ̂ >0

(θ̂ <0) at 2.5%

By Funds Prospectus Objective

Small company -1.740

(0.355)

-1.369

(0.289)

135

(198)

1.80

(9.61)

0.60

(4.20)

Growth -0.718

(0.246)

-0.689

(0.184)

319

(403)

4.02

(6.51)

1.94

(3.46)

Equity income -2.797

(0.599)

-3.359

(0.449)

20

(74)

1.06

(20.21)

1.06

(14.89)

Growth and income -1.653

(0.356)

-1.936

(0.265)

90

(166)

3.52

(13.28)

1.56

(5.86)

Balanced -2.070

(0.445)

-2.426

(0.332)

58

(130)

1.06

(13.83)

0.53

(10.11)

Asset allocation -1.846

(0.636)

-1.748

(0.500)

46

(74)

0.83

(5.83)

0.00

(3.33)

Specialty-technology 2.544

(1.105)

2.415

(0.850)

28

(11)

12.82

(2.56)

7.69

(2.56)

Aggressive growth -2.284

(0.689)

-2.284

(0.534)

21

(54)

1.33

(10.67)

0.00

(8.00)

By Best-Fitted Indices

S&P 500 -0.272

(0.220)

-0.887

(0.159)

353

(450)

4.11

(9.84)

1.87

(5.60)

Page 48: A Nonparametric Test of Market Timing1

48

Fund Group Mean θ̂ Weighted

Average θ̂

No. of θ̂ >0

(θ̂ <0)

% of θ̂ >0

(θ̂ <0) at 5%

% of θ̂ >0

(θ̂ <0) at 2.5%

S&P 400 -4.345

(0.416)

-3.708

(0.313)

53

(187)

1.25

(16.35)

0.83

(11.25)

Russell 2000 -0.653

(0.319)

-0.258

(0.259)

204

(218)

1.89

(4.50)

0.71

(1.66)

NASDAQ Composite -2.567

(0.339)

-2.441

(0.268)

107

(255)

2.76

(10.22)

1.38

(5.25)

Dead funds -2.401

(0.664)

-2.626

(0.581)

44

(66)

4.55

(19.04)

1.82

(11.82)

Page 49: A Nonparametric Test of Market Timing1

49

Table 4. Market Timing: Related Issues In this table we compare the timing performance of mutual funds sorted by fund characteristics. In each row we report the number of funds, the inverse standard error weighted average θ̂ and its standard error, and the percentage of funds that outperform or underperform the market at 5% and 2.5% significance level. Fund Age and Manager Tenure are proxies for manager experience. The median age and manger tenure are 5 and 4 years respectively. The median fund size is 104.75 million dollars. The turnover ratio is the average annual rate during the sampling period. The median turnover ratio is 69.0%. Load charges and minimum initial purchase are proxies for fund flow stability. Load Charges are the sum of front and deferred loads. 55.3% of the funds in the sample are no-load funds. 54.1% of the funds have minimum initial purchase of 1,000 dollars or less. 11.5% of the funds have minimum initial purchase of 25,000 dollars or more.

Fund Characteristics

No. of Funds

Weighted Average θ̂

Std. Error

% of θ̂ > 0

at 5%

% of θ̂ < 0

at 5%

% of θ̂ > 0

at 2.5%

% of θ̂ < 0

at 2.5%

Panel A: Fund Age (years since inception)

< 5 768 -1.533 0.282 2.53 11.09 0.97 7.19

≥ 5 and < 10 545 -1.315 0.206 4.77 11.38 2.20 6.97

≥ 10 514 -1.250 0.137 2.60 4.94 1.04 2.21

Panel B: Manager Tenure (years)

< 3 386 -1.550 0.251 3.89 9.84 1.81 6.73

≥ 3 and < 5 741 -1.284 0.221 2.43 6.07 0.67 2.97

≥ 5 690 -1.326 0.150 3.77 10.72 1.88 6.38

Panel C: Fund Size ($mm)

< 20 362 -0.629 0.331 4.70 5.24 2.49 3.31

≥ 20 and < 100 528 -1.420 0.239 2.27 7.95 0.95 4.92

≥ 100 and < 500 515 -1.432 0.207 3.50 9.51 1.55 5.63

≥ 500 420 -1.635 0.179 2.86 11.19 0.71 5.95

Panel D: Turnover Ratio (annual %)

All funds

< 50 522 -1.419 0.197 3.43 8.32 2.29 5.06

≥ 50 and < 100 613 -1.130 0.184 4.02 8.55 1.47 4.73

> 100 573 -1.580 0.210 2.44 10.15 0.52 6.13

Page 50: A Nonparametric Test of Market Timing1

50

Fund Characteristics

No. of Funds

Weighted Average θ̂

Std. Error

% of θ̂ > 0

at 5%

% of θ̂ < 0

at 5%

% of θ̂ > 0

at 2.5%

% of θ̂ < 0

at 2.5%

Asset Allocation funds only

< 50 42 -2.016 0.805 2.38 4.76 0.00 4.76

≥ 50 and < 100 26 -0.878 0.974 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00

> 100 44 -2.565 0.868 0.00 9.09 0.00 4.55

Panel E: Load Charges

No-Load Funds 1012 -1.467 0.154 3.06 8.50 0.99 5.43

Load Funds 815 -1.215 0.166 3.44 8.71 1.84 4.54

Panel F: Minimum Initial Purchase ($ 1,000)

< 25 1557 -1.330 0.121 3.21 8.41 1.54 4.95

≥ 25 210 -1.822 0.392 2.86 10.95 0.48 7.14

Page 51: A Nonparametric Test of Market Timing1

51

Figure 1. Distribution of Market Timing of Live Funds

To check whether superior ability exists among fund managers beyond the statistical tail probability, we plot in this graph the empirical cumulative distribution of live funds’ θ̂ values against a reference normal distribution that has the same standard deviation but centers on zero (no ability). The empirical distribution lies all the way above the normal distribution, suggesting that the distribution of live mutual funds’ market timing ability is first-order stochastically dominated (FOSD) by a comparable distribution. The FOSD hypothesis passed the Kleacan-McFadden-McFadden (1991) test at 1% significance level.

-30 -20 -10 0 10 20 300

0.1

0.2

0.3

0.4

0.5

0.6

0.7

0.8

0.9

1

θ

cum

ulat

ive p

roba

bilit

y

normal distributionlive funds

Page 52: A Nonparametric Test of Market Timing1

52

Figure 2. Distribution of Market Timing of Dead Funds

In this graph we plot the empirical cumulative distribution of dead funds’ θ̂ values against a reference normal distribution that has the same standard deviation but centers on zero (no ability). The empirical distribution lies mostly above the normal distribution, suggesting that the distribution of dead mutual funds’ market timing ability is first-order stochastically dominated by a comparable distribution. The FOSD hypothesis passed the Kleacan-McFadden-McFadden (1991) test at 5% significance level.

-30 -20 -10 0 10 20 300

0.1

0.2

0.3

0.4

0.5

0.6

0.7

0.8

0.9

1

θ

cum

ulat

ive p

roba

bilit

y

normal dis tributiondead funds