a welfare evaluation of east asian monetary policy regimes under foreign output shock

Upload: asian-development-bank

Post on 14-Apr-2018

221 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

  • 7/27/2019 A Welfare Evaluation of East Asian Monetary Policy Regimes under Foreign Output Shock

    1/31

    A Welare Evaluation o East Asian MonetaryPolicy Regimes under Foreign Output Shock

    Joseph D. Alba, Wai-Mun Chia, and Donghyun Park

    No. 299 | February 2012

    ADB EconomicsWorking Paper Series

  • 7/27/2019 A Welfare Evaluation of East Asian Monetary Policy Regimes under Foreign Output Shock

    2/31

    ADB Economics Working Paper Series No. 299

    A Welare Evaluation o East Asian Monetary

    Policy Regimes under Foreign Output Shock

    Joseph D. Alba, Wai-Mun Chia, and Donghyun Park

    February 2012

    oseph . Alba is Associate rofessor, ivision of conomics, chool of umanities and ocial ciences,

    anyang echnological niversity, ingapore. ai-Mun Chia is Assistant rofessor, ivision of conomics,

    chool of umanities and ocial ciences, anyang echnological niversity. onghyun ark is rincipal

    conomist, Macroeconomics and inance esearch ivision, conomics and esearch epartment,Asian evelopment Bank.

  • 7/27/2019 A Welfare Evaluation of East Asian Monetary Policy Regimes under Foreign Output Shock

    3/31

    Asian evelopment Bank

    AB Avenue, Mandaluyong City

    1550 Metro Manila, hilippines

    www.adb.org/economics

    2012 by Asian evelopment Bankebruary 2012

    155-5252

    ublication tock o. 1245

    he views expressed in this paper

    are those of the authors) and do not

    QHFHVVDULO\UHHFWWKHYLHZVRUSROLFLHV

    of the Asian evelopment Bank.

    he AB conomics orking aper eries is a forum for stimulating discussion and

    eliciting feedback on ongoing and recently completed research and policy studies

    undertaken by the Asian evelopment Bank AB) staff, consultants, or resource

    persons. he series deals with key economic and development problems, particularly

    WKRVHIDFLQJWKH$VLDDQG3DFLFUHJLRQDVZHOODVFRQFHSWXDODQDO\WLFDORU

    methodological issues relating to project/program economic analysis, and statistical data

    and measurement. he series aims to enhance the knowledge on Asias development

    DQGSROLF\FKDOOHQJHVVWUHQJWKHQDQDO\WLFDOULJRUDQGTXDOLW\RI$'%VFRXQWU\SDUWQHUVKLS

    VWUDWHJLHVDQGLWVVXEUHJLRQDODQGFRXQWU\RSHUDWLRQVDQGLPSURYHWKHTXDOLW\DQG

    availability of statistical data and development indicators for monitoring development

    effectiveness.

    7KH$'%(FRQRPLFV:RUNLQJ3DSHU6HULHVLVDTXLFNGLVVHPLQDWLQJLQIRUPDOSXEOLFDWLRQ

    ZKRVHWLWOHVFRXOGVXEVHTXHQWO\EHUHYLVHGIRUSXEOLFDWLRQDVDUWLFOHVLQSURIHVVLRQDO

    journals or chapters in books. he series is maintained by the conomics and esearch

    epartment.

    Printed on recycled paper

  • 7/27/2019 A Welfare Evaluation of East Asian Monetary Policy Regimes under Foreign Output Shock

    4/31

    Contents

    Abstract v

    . ntroduction 1

    . ole of Monetary and xchange ate olicies

    in Cushioning xternal hocks 4

    . he Model 5

    A. ouseholds 5

    B. omestic irms

    C. rice evel, erms of rade, and eal xchange ate 8

    . Monetary olicy and xchange ate egimes 9

    . elfare 9

    . Model arameterization 10

    . imulation esults and elfare 11

    A. mpulse esponses under arious Monetary olicy egimes 11

    B. elfare osses under arious Monetary olicies 1

    C. ummary of imulation esults and elfare 19

    . Conclusions 20

    eferences 22

  • 7/27/2019 A Welfare Evaluation of East Asian Monetary Policy Regimes under Foreign Output Shock

    5/31

  • 7/27/2019 A Welfare Evaluation of East Asian Monetary Policy Regimes under Foreign Output Shock

    6/31

    Abstract

    Adverse foreign output shocks have a sizable impact on the welfare of small

    open economies. herefore, one of the key roles of monetary policy in those

    economies is to minimize the welfare losses arising from such shocks. o

    assess the welfare impact of external shocks under different monetary policy

    regimes, we numerically solve and calculate the welfare loss function of a

    G\QDPLFVWRFKDVWLFJHQHUDOHTXLOLEULXPPRGHOZLWKFRPSOHWHH[FKDQJHUDWHSDVV

    WKURXJK:HQGWKDWFRQVXPHUSULFHLQGH[&3LQDWLRQWDUJHWLQJPLQLPL]HV

    welfare losses for import-to-gross domestic product ) ratios from 0. to 0.9.

    +RZHYHUZHOIDUHXQGHUWKHSHJJHGH[FKDQJHUDWHUHJLPHLVDOPRVWHTXLYDOHQWWR&3LQDWLRQWDUJHWLQJZKHQWKHLPSRUWWR*'3UDWLRLVZKLOHWKHGRPHVWLF

    LQDWLRQWDUJHWLQJPLQLPL]HVZHOIDUHZKHQWKHLPSRUWWR*'3UDWLRLV:H

    calibrate the model and derive welfare implications for eight ast Asian small

    open economies.

  • 7/27/2019 A Welfare Evaluation of East Asian Monetary Policy Regimes under Foreign Output Shock

    7/31

  • 7/27/2019 A Welfare Evaluation of East Asian Monetary Policy Regimes under Foreign Output Shock

    8/31

    I. Introduction

    Adverse foreign output shocks have a sizable impact on the macroeconomic performance

    of small open economies. or example, the sharp recession of the advanced economies

    GXHWRWKHJOREDOQDQFLDODQGHFRQRPLFFULVLVRIKDGDSURQRXQFHGHIIHFWRQ

    the export and growth of ast Asias highly open, export-dependent economies. able 1

    shows the cumulative contraction in real gross domestic product ) growth, relative

    WRWUHQGRIWRIRU6LQJDSRUH7DLSHL&KLQDDQG+RQJRQJ&KLQDRU

    WKHHSXEOLFRIRUHDDOD\VLDWKH3KLOLSSLQHVDQG7KDLODQGLWZDVWR

    7DEOHFRQUPVWKDWWKHSULPDU\FKDQQHOIRUWKHWUDQVPLVVLRQRIWKHJOREDOFULVLVWR(DVW

    Asia was the trade channel. he cumulative contraction of real export growth ranged

    from 5.9 for ndonesia to 8.8 for hailand. t is not surprising that exports have

    a large impact on the real of ast Asian economies in light of their heavy export

    GHSHQGHQFH7KHUDWLRRIH[SRUWVWR*'3HYHQH[FHHGVLQ+RQJRQJ&KLQD

    DOD\VLDDQG6LQJDSRUH

    n light of their large effect on the macroeconomic outcomes of small open economies,

    we can expect adverse foreign output shocks to have a large effect on their welfare.

    herefore, one of the key roles of monetary policy in those economies is to minimize

    the welfare losses arising from such shocks. able 1 shows the various monetary and

    H[FKDQJHUDWHSROLF\UHJLPHVDGRSWHGE\(DVW$VLDQHFRQRPLHV+RQJRQJ&KLQDDQG

    6LQJDSRUHKDYH[HGDQGSHJJHGH[FKDQJHUDWHUHJLPHVUHVSHFWLYHO\ZKLOHWKHHSXEOLF

    RIRUHDQGRQHVLDWKH3KLOLSSLQHVDQG7KDLODQGKDYHDGRSWHGLQDWLRQWDUJHWLQJ

    policies. Malaysia and aipei,China aim to do both, i.e., stabilize prices and intervene in

    WKHIRUHLJQH[FKDQJHUDWHPDUNHWV(FRQRPLHVWKDWWDUJHWH[FKDQJHUDWHV+RQJRQJ

    &KLQD6LQJDSRUHDQG7DLSHL&KLQDVKRZHGORZHUDYHUDJHFKDQJHVLQH[FKDQJHUDWHV

    WKDQFRXQWULHVWKDWWDUJHWLQDWLRQQGRQHVLDWKHHSXEOLFRIRUHDWKH3KLOLSSLQHV

    and hailand.1 he exception is Malaysia, which target both variables but experienced

    DQDYHUDJHFKDQJHLQH[FKDQJHUDWHFORVHUWRLQDWLRQWDUJHWLQJFRXQWULHVQDGGLWLRQ

    economies that target the exchange rate suffered a visibly larger cumulative decline in

    UHDO*'3FRPSDUHGWRHFRQRPLHVWKDWWDUJHWLQDWLRQQDWLRQKDVEHHQJHQHUDOO\ORZIRU

    all economies regardless of policy regimes.

    2

    1 Hong Kong, China; Singapore; and Taipei,China experienced the smallest average percentage change in exchangerates o 0.42%, 3.01%, and 3.98%, respectively. In contrast, Indonesia, the Republic o Korea, the Philippines, andThailand experienced an average percentage change in exchange rates in the range o 6.92% to 27.16%. Malaysia,which targets both exchange rate and ination but experienced an average change in exchange rate o 6.90%,which is closer to ination-targeting countries, is an exception.

    2 In act, Indonesia and Thailand experienced deation.

  • 7/27/2019 A Welfare Evaluation of East Asian Monetary Policy Regimes under Foreign Output Shock

    9/31

  • 7/27/2019 A Welfare Evaluation of East Asian Monetary Policy Regimes under Foreign Output Shock

    10/31

    he central objective of this paper is to evaluate and compare the welfare impact of

    H[WHUQDOVKRFNVXQGHUGLIIHUHQWPRQHWDU\DQGSROLF\UHJLPHVRUHVSHFLFDOO\ZHORRNDW

    the welfare effects of foreign output shocks under seven different types of monetary and

    H[FKDQJHUDWHSROLF\UHJLPHVD[HGRUSHJJHGH[FKDQJHUDWHUXOHDFRQVXPHUSULFH

    LQGH[&3LQDWLRQWDUJHWLQJUXOHLQDWLRQDQGH[FKDQJHUDWHWDUJHWLQJUXOHGRPHVWLFLQDWLRQWDUJHWLQJ7D\ORUW\SHUXOHQRPLQDORXWSXWWDUJHWLQJDQGUHDORXWSXWWDUJHWLQJ

    :HGRVRIRUHLJKWVPDOORSHQHFRQRPLHVLQ(DVW$VLD+RQJRQJ&KLQDQGRQHVLD

    WKHHSXEOLFRIRUHDDOD\VLDWKH3KLOLSSLQHV6LQJDSRUH7DLSHL&KLQDDQG7KDLODQG

    to assess and compare the extent to which each monetary and exchange rate policy

    regime protects each of the eight economies from external shocks. ur welfare evaluation

    is based on numerically solving and calculating the welfare loss function of a dynamic

    VWRFKDVWLFJHQHUDOHTXLOLEULXP'6*(PRGHO:HFDOLEUDWHWKHPRGHOWRGHULYHZHOIDUH

    implications for the eight countries.

    ur paper is broadly similar with Alba, u, and Chia 2011) in its methodology. More

    precisely, the two papers both use a model that is broadly based on Monacellis 2004) model of a small open economy. owever, Alba, u, and Chia 2011) examine the

    impact of a negative foreign output shock on the volatility of macroeconomic variables

    under alternative monetary and exchange rate policy regimes while we examine the

    more fundamental, policy-relevant issue of the impact of such a shock on welfare. hile

    macroeconomic volatility is important, it is a much less complete yardstick for evaluating

    policy regimes than welfare. urthermore, the analysis of Alba, u, and Chia 2011) is

    OLPLWHGWRWKUHHSROLF\UHJLPHVDQGIRXUFRXQWULHV7KHLUPDLQQGLQJLVWKDWVPDOORSHQ

    HFRQRPLHVWKDWIROORZHLWKHU[HGH[FKDQJHUDWHRULQDWLRQWDUJHWLQJWHQGWRVWDELOL]H

    UHDOH[FKDQJHUDWHDQGLQDWLRQEXWDWWKHH[SHQVHRIVXEVWDQWLDOYRODWLOLW\LQWKHUHDO

    economy.

    ur paper evaluates and compares the welfare losses of foreign output shocks under

    alternative monetary and exchange rate policy regimes, and is thus able to inform us

    about the relative desirability of different policy regimes. uch a welfare comparison is

    useful for determining the optimal monetary and exchange rate policy regime in ast

    Asias small open economies that are highly dependent on trade and hence vulnerable

    WRIRUHLJQRXWSXWVKRFNV7KHSURQRXQFHGLPSDFWRIWKHUHFHVVLRQLQWKH

    DGYDQFHGHFRQRPLHVLVDYLYLGUHPLQGHURIWKLVYXOQHUDELOLW\7KHFHQWUDOTXHVWLRQZH

    seek to answer is the following which monetary and exchange rate policy regime leaves

    ast Asian small open economies best off under external shocks? he rest of this paper

    is organized as follows. ection explores the relationship between monetary and

    H[FKDQJHUDWHSROLF\UHJLPHVDQGPDFURHFRQRPLFSHUIRUPDQFH6HFWLRQVSHFLHVRXUmodel. ection reports and discusses the main results, and ection concludes the

    paper.

    A Welfare Evaluation of East Asian Monetary Policy Regimes under Foreign Output Shock | 3

  • 7/27/2019 A Welfare Evaluation of East Asian Monetary Policy Regimes under Foreign Output Shock

    11/31

    II. Role o Monetary and Exchange Rate Policies

    in Cushioning External Shocks

    he current crisis calls for a re-examination of macroeconomic policies in general andPRQHWDU\DQGH[FKDQJHUDWHSROLFLHVLQSDUWLFXODU6WLJOLW]DUJXHVWKDWLQDWLRQ

    targeting is inappropriate, especially for emerging economies where energy and

    commodities make up a larger share of the household budget compared to industrialized

    countries. ther economists have suggested alternative monetary policy targets such as

    nominal . n addition, Blanchard, ellAriccia, and Mauro 2010) argue that there

    PD\EHDFDVHIRUWKHHPHUJLQJPDUNHWFHQWUDOEDQNHUVSUDFWLFHRIWDUJHWLQJLQDWLRQ

    ZKLOHDOVRLQWHUYHQLQJLQWKHIRUHLJQH[FKDQJHPDUNHWV'HVSLWHWKHFULWLFLVPRILQDWLRQ

    WDUJHWLQJGH&DOYDOKRLOKRQGVWKDWLQDWLRQWDUJHWLQJFRXQWULHVRXWSHUIRUPHG

    QRQLQDWLRQWDUJHWLQJFRXQWULHVLQWKHSRVWSHULRG+HDUJXHVWKDWGXULQJWKHFULVLV

    LQDWLRQWDUJHWLQJFRXQWULHVORZHUHGQRPLQDOLQWHUHVWUDWHVE\PRUHUHVXOWLQJLQHYHQ

    larger real interest rate differentials and thus an even stronger monetary stimulus.

    he theoretical and empirical literature also suggest a number of rationales for why

    different monetary and exchange rate policy regimes may differ in their capacity to protect

    FRXQWULHVIURPH[WHUQDOVKRFNVRUH[DPSOHLWLVRIWHQDUJXHGWKDWFRXQWULHVZLWKH[LEOH

    exchange rate regimes can better insulate their economies from negative real shocks.4

    n a study that is highly relevant to the transmission of foreign output shocks to ast Asia

    GXULQJWKHFULVLV+RIIPDQQXVHVGDWDIURPDVDPSOHRIGHYHORSLQJ

    FRXQWULHVWRWHVWWKHK\SRWKHVLVWKDWH[LEOHH[FKDQJHUDWHVVHUYHDVDVKRFNDEVRUEHU

    in small open economies, and mitigate the impact of external shocks more effectively

    WKDQ[HGH[FKDQJHUDWHUHJLPHV+RIIPDQQGVWKDWFRXQWULHVZLWKPRUHH[LEOH

    nominal exchange rates suffer smaller decline of real . his is due to real exchangerate depreciation, which improves external competitiveness and thus partly offsets the

    negative impact of foreign output shocks.

    n this paper, we evaluate and compare the welfare loss due to foreign output shocks in

    ast Asias small open economies under alternative monetary and exchange rate policy

    regimes. o do so, we develop a simple model that contains a goods market

    characterized by imperfect competition and nominal rigidities.5 e numerically solve and

    calculate the welfare loss function of the model under seven types of monetary

    DQGH[FKDQJHUDWHSROLF\UHJLPHVD[HGRUSHJJHGH[FKDQJHUDWHUXOHD&3LQDWLRQ

    WDUJHWLQJUXOHLQDWLRQDQGH[FKDQJHUDWHWDUJHWLQJUXOHGRPHVWLFLQDWLRQWDUJHWLQJ

    3 A debate on nominal GDP targeting among economists could be accessed online at http://economistsview.typepad.com/economistsview/2010/12/bernanke-and-mishkin-on-nominal-gdp-growth-targeting.html

    4 Please reer to Friedman (1953), Mundell (1961), Poole (1970), Dornbusch (1980), Luer (1994), Obsteld andRogof (2000), Devereux (2004), Devereux, Lane, and Xu (2006), Broda (2004), Edwards and Levy Yeyati (2005), andHofman (2007).

    5 There is a large and growing literature on open economy DSGE models that incorporate imperect competitionand nominal rigidities. Obsteld and Rogof (1995 and 1996) initiated open-economy macroeconomics researchbased on a synthesis o dynamic intertemporal approaches and sticky-price models o macroeconomicuctuations. This synthesis is known as the new open economy macroeconomics. Many economists have relied onthis new class o models to address many classical problems with new tools, and to generate new research ideasand questions.

    4 | ADB Economics Working Paper Series No. 299

  • 7/27/2019 A Welfare Evaluation of East Asian Monetary Policy Regimes under Foreign Output Shock

    12/31

    aylor-type rule, nominal output targeting, and real output targeting. he open economy

    framework makes it possible to examine the exchange rate channel in the transmission of

    foreign output shocks to the domestic economy. e assume foreign output shocks to be

    exogenous.

    DQ\'6*(PRGHOVFRQVLGHURQO\WZRIDFWRULQSXWVQFRQWUDVWZHIROORZLPDQG

    oungani 1992) and assume oil to be an input in a constant elasticity of substitution

    C) production function where oil and capital are substitutes. ence, our model

    captures an important stylized fact of global energy use, i.e., more developed economies

    use less energy per unit of capital than less developed economies. n addition, it is

    possible that exchange rate depreciation affects the price of imported oil which, in turn,

    affects domestic output. e follow Monacelli 2004) and assume that capital is subject

    to adjustment costs. ach monetary and exchange rate policy regime implicitly assigns

    GLIIHUHQWZHLJKWVRQRYHUDOOLQDWLRQGRPHVWLFLQDWLRQWKHRXWSXWJDSDQGH[FKDQJHUDWH

    in the interest rate rule. By explicitly evaluating and comparing the welfare loss due to

    foreign output shocks under different types of monetary policy regimes, we address theextent to which different policy regimes mitigate the loss of welfare.

    III. The Model

    n this section, we lay out our model, which is broadly based on Monacellis 2004)

    PRGHORIDVPDOORSHQHFRQRP\GHQWLFDODQGLQQLWHO\OLYHGKRXVHKROGVHDUQLQFRPH

    IURPZRUNLQJIRUDQGUHQWLQJSK\VLFDOFDSLWDOWRGRPHVWLFUPV7KH\FRQVXPHEDVNHWVRI

    differentiated domestic and foreign tradable goods.

    A. Households

    he domestic economy is populated by a continuum RILQQLWHO\OLYHGLGHQWLFDO

    households. hey consume baskets of differentiated domestic and foreign goods that

    are both tradable and indexed byj. he baskets of domestic and foreign varieties

    of goods are associated with utility-based price indices P P j dj H t H t , , ( )( )

    1

    0

    1 11--

    and

    P P j dj F t F t , , ( )( )

    1

    0

    1 11--

    , respectively, where the His the index for home and Ffor

    foreign. he price indices are expressed in units of domestic currency.P jH t, ( ) and

    P jF t, ( ) are prices of the individual domestic and foreign good j, respectively, where - ! 1is the elasticity of substitution between varieties within each category. he utility-based

    consumer price index is given by P P Pt H t F t = + ( )( )

    , ,

    /1 1

    1 1

    1 .

    A Welfare Evaluation of East Asian Monetary Policy Regimes under Foreign Output Shock | 5

  • 7/27/2019 A Welfare Evaluation of East Asian Monetary Policy Regimes under Foreign Output Shock

    13/31

    n each period, the households optimally allocate their expenditure on differentiated goods

    within each category. he demand functions are

    C jP j

    PC C j

    P j

    PH t

    H t

    H t

    H t F t

    F t

    F t

    ,

    ,

    ,

    , ,

    ,

    ,

    ) )

    ; ) )

    =

    =

    -

    -

    CF t, 1)

    for alljgoods within the interval of 0 and 1, where the goods are produced

    E\DFRQWLQXXPRIUPVDQGWKHUPVDUHRZQHGE\GRPHVWLFKRXVHKROGV

    C C j dj H t H t , , ( )( )

    - -

    - -1

    0

    1 1

    and C C j dj F t F t , , ( )( )

    - -

    - -1

    0

    11

    are composite indices of

    domestic and foreign goods, respectively. he households consume a C composite of

    both home products CH) and foreign products CF)

    C C Ct H t F t = + ( )( )

    1 1 1 1

    1

    1, , 2)

    where J0,1 is the share of home-produced goodsLQWRWDOFRQVXPSWLRQVRJrepresents the share of foreign-produced goods. U>1 is the elasticity of substitution

    between domestic and foreign goods. nvestment composite index In In Int H t F t , ,,( ) hasan identical expression as consumption for simplicity. he optimal allocation of any

    given expenditure between domestic and foreign goods yields the consumption demand

    CP

    PC C

    P

    PCH t

    H t

    t

    t F t

    F t

    t

    t,

    ,

    ,

    ,; )=

    =

    1

    .

    he representative domestic household maximizes the utility function over time

    EC N

    t t t t

    t

    1 1

    0 1 1

    +

    =

    +

    )where V > 0 and M > 0, E is the discount factor and E ( )0 1, . 1/V is the intertemporalelasticity of substitution and M is the elasticity of labor substitution. Et is the expectation

    operator. Ct is the consumption and Nt is the labor supply of the representative household

    at time t.

    he representative household holds securities denominated in domestic currency, rents

    RXWLWVFDSLWDOWRWKHKRPHEDVHGPRQRSROLVWLFFRPSHWLWLYHUPDQGGHULYHVLQFRPHIURP

    working for each time t. ence, the households budget constraint is written as

    P C In B W N Z K Bt t t t t h

    t t t t t t t

    t

    +( ) + ( ) = + + ++ ++ , 1 11 4)

    where Bt1 is the portfolio of state contingent securities household holds at the end of

    t, Qt t, 1 LVGHQHGE\RQDFHOOLDVWKHSULFLQJNHUQHORIVWDWHFRQWLQJHQWSRUWIROLR

    HTXDOWRQ = + )h ht t1 where Monacelli lets h h ht t ,...., )0 be the history of events up toperiod tand the date 0 probability of observing htLVGHQHGDVdtwhere at the initial

    6 | ADB Economics Working Paper Series No. 299

  • 7/27/2019 A Welfare Evaluation of East Asian Monetary Policy Regimes under Foreign Output Shock

    14/31

    state d h )0 1 RQDFHOOLGHQHVWKHH[SHFWDWLRQRSHUDWRU E d h ht ht t

    t

    . ){} +

    +1

    1

    . Wtis

    the nominal wage, Zt is the nominal rental cost, and Wt represents the lump-sum transfer

    payment.

    ollowing Monacelli, capital accumulation is described as

    K KIn

    KKt t

    t

    t

    t+ = ( ) +

    1 1 G 5)

    where G is the physical depreciation rate of capital. ) is an increasing and concave

    function that assumes the adjustment cost in capital accumulation. ence, Intunits of

    investment translate into In K K t t t( ) units of additional capital.

    ith the arbitrage condition holding, it implies that

    11

    1Rt

    t tht

    = ++

    Q ,and

    11

    1

    1Rt

    t th

    t

    tt

    ,= +

    +

    +

    given that Rt and Rt

    are expected returns in terms of domestic and foreign currency on

    the bond portfolio.RQDFHOOLHTXDOL]HVWKHVHUHWXUQVWRJHW

    t t t t t

    thR R

    t

    , + + =+ 1

    1

    1

    0

    he rest of the world is assumed to have foreign households with similar preferences

    as the home country so that foreign demand for home produced goodjis

    C jP j

    PC

    P j

    PH t

    H t

    H t

    H t

    H t

    H t

    ,

    ,

    ,

    ,

    ,

    ,

    ( ) =( )

    =

    ( )

    - --

    CH t,

    where CP

    PCH t

    H t

    t

    t,

    ,

    = ( )

    1

    .

    B. Domestic Firms

    abor, capital, and oil are inputs to production described by the constant elasticity of

    substitution C production function. il is included in the C function following Alba,

    u, and Chia 2011).7KHUHLVDFRQWLQXXPRIPRQRSROLVWLFDOO\FRPSHWLWLYHUPVZKLFK

    are indexed by j[ ]0 1, . he C production function with constant return to scale hasWKHIROORZLQJVSHFLFDWLRQ

    Y j A K j O j N j t t t t t ( ) = ( ) + ( ) ( ) ( ) ( )

    1 1

    1 1

    1 )/

    )

    where 0 1 D , L ! 0 and X ! 0 . he elasticity of substitution between capital andRLOLVHTXDOWR 1/Q while labor share in production is given by D.

    6 Rt = 1 + it where it is the nominal interest rate.7 For details, please reer to Alba, Su, and Chia (2011). Similarly, Backus and Crucini (2000) and Kim and Loungani

    (1992) nest capital and oil as a CES unction within a Cobb-Douglas production unction while Rotemberg andWoodord (1996) and Blanchard and Gali (2007) consider oil and labor as inputs to production. Alternatively, Finn(2000) assumes oil and capital as complimentary. The complemetarity or substitutability o oil and capital areunresolved in empirical literature. For a survey o the literature, please reer to Apostolakis (1990). In addition,Bodenstein, Erceg, and Guerrieri (2008) consider oil as part o household consumption while Aoki (2001) examinesthe relationship between sector-specic supply shocks such as oil price shocks and ination uctuations.

    A Welfare Evaluation of East Asian Monetary Policy Regimes under Foreign Output Shock | 7

  • 7/27/2019 A Welfare Evaluation of East Asian Monetary Policy Regimes under Foreign Output Shock

    15/31

    Monacelli 2004) follows Calvos 198) pricing. A fraction 1Ip RIDOOUPVDGXVWVWKHLUSULFHVUDQGRPO\ZKLOHWKHUHVWRIWKHUPVIp, do not adjust their prices. he parameter

    Ip represents the degree of nominal rigidity whereby a largerIp LPSOLHVIHZHUUPV

    adjusting their prices, causing a longer expected time between price adjustments. irms

    IXWXUHSURWVDW t+kare affected by the choice of price at time tRQO\LIWKHUPGRHVQRWget another opportunity to adjust its price between tand t+k. Ip

    k

    LVWKHSUREDELOLW\RIDUP

    not adjusting its price from tto t+k7KHGRPHVWLFUPjwill set price PH tNew

    , to maximize the

    SURWIXQFWLRQ

    E P j MC j Y j tk

    p

    k

    t t k H t

    new

    t kk

    t k , ,+ +

    =

    +( ) ( ) ( )

    0

    )

    subject to the domestic and foreign demand given byY jP j

    PC Ct k

    H t

    new

    H t k

    H t k H t k ++

    + +( )

    ( )

    +

    ,

    ,

    , ,

    -

    where t t k, + LVWKHWLPHYDU\LQJSRUWLRQRIWKHUPVGLVFRXQWIDFWRU+HQFHWKHRSWLPDOpricing condition is

    P j

    E MC j Y j

    H t

    new

    t

    k

    p

    k

    t t k t k t k k

    ,

    ,

    ( ) =

    ( ) ( )

    + + +

    =

    1

    0

    ( )

    + +=

    E Y jt k pk t t k t k k

    ,0

    8)

    7KHDERYHHTXDWLRQGHVFULEHVWKHG\QDPLFPDUNXSIRUSULFHVHWWLQJ:KHQWKHSULFH

    signal Ip

    HTXDOV]HURHTXDWLRQEHFRPHV P j MC H t

    new

    t, ( ) = ( )- - 1 . ith symmetric

    HTXLOLEULXPWKHGRPHVWLFDJJUHJDWHSULFHLQGH[LV

    P P PH t p H t p H t new

    , , ,= + ( ) ( )

    ( )

    1

    11

    1 1

    1 9)

    C. Price Level, Terms o Trade, and Real Exchange Rate

    he nominal exchange rate Ht is the price of one unit of foreign currency in terms of

    domestic currency. Assuming the law of one price holds, P PH t t H t , ,H and P PF t t F t , ,

    H . he

    terms of trade, StLVGHQHGDVWKHSULFHRIWKHLPSRUWHGJRRGUHODWLYHWRWKHSULFHRIWKH

    domestic good S PP

    PP

    t

    F t

    H t

    t F t

    H t

    =

    ,

    ,

    ,

    ,

    H ). he real exchDQJHUDWHLVWKHQGHQHGDV H Ht

    r t t

    t

    PP

    .

    or a small open economy, domestic price changes do not affect the foreign price level.

    o without loss of generality, we assume that P PF t t, = , where the foreign price level

    is determined by the prices of non-oil goods and oil. ence, it can be expressed as

    8 | ADB Economics Working Paper Series No. 299

  • 7/27/2019 A Welfare Evaluation of East Asian Monetary Policy Regimes under Foreign Output Shock

    16/31

    P P Pt NO t O t no no = ( ) ( ), ,

    J J1

    . or simplicity, we normalize PNO t, to one so the foreign non-oil

    LQDWLRQSNO t,

    LV]HUR7KHWRWDO&3LQDWLRQLVGHQHGDVS t t tP P ( )log 1 and theGRPHVWLFLQDWLRQLVGHQHGDV S H t H t H t P P, , ,log ( )1 .

    D. Monetary Policy and Exchange Rate Regimes

    ROORZLQJRQDFHOOLGHYLDWLRQVRILQDWLRQRXWSXWDQGQRPLQDOH[FKDQJHUDWH

    from their long-run target have feedback effects on short-run movements of the nominal

    interest rate target given by

    11

    1

    +( ) =

    iP

    PYt

    t

    t

    t ty

    10)

    where it LVWKHLQDWLRQWDUJHWDQG , y and

    are weights assigned to the movements

    RI&3LQDWLRQRXWSXWDQGQRPLQDOH[FKDQJHUDWHUHVSHFWLYHO\DWKHUWKDQ&3

    LQDWLRQHTXDWLRQFRXOGEHPRGLHGWRFRQVLGHUGRPHVWLFLQDWLRQZKHUHLQDWLRQ

    could be written as P PH t H t H

    , , ( )1

    , where HLVWKHZHLJKWRQGRPHVWLFLQDWLRQ7KH

    actual short-run interest rate is determined based on the monetary authoritys desire to

    smooth changes in the nominal interest rate

    1 1 11

    1+( ) = +( ) +( )

    i i it t tF F

    11)

    he exogenous stochastic processes for the foreign output, foreign interest rate,

    domestic technology, and nominal oil price can be summarized as

    Y Yt t tyy exp= ( )1

    , 1 1 1+( ) = +( ) ( )i it t tii

    exp

    , A At t taa= ( )1 exp and

    P PO t O t t po

    po

    ,

    , exp= ( ) ( )1 , respectively.8

    E. Welare

    e analyze the impact of various monetary policy regimes based on social welfare loss

    function minimized by the central banks. he function is based on the second-order

    aylor expansion of the households utility around the steady state as in otemberg and

    oodford 1998 and 1999) and oodford 200), and extended to small open economies

    by Chung, ung, and ang 200) and ivino 2009). he social welfare loss function is

    derived as in alsh 2010) and could be expressed as

    ^ `E S Of

    : 2 2

    00

    ( )flexiblet t t tt

    W E y y 12)

    8 The rst order conditions, the steady state and market equilibrium, and the log-linearized equations are availablerom the authors upon request.

    A Welfare Evaluation of East Asian Monetary Policy Regimes under Foreign Output Shock | 9

  • 7/27/2019 A Welfare Evaluation of East Asian Monetary Policy Regimes under Foreign Output Shock

    17/31

    where =

    ( ) ( )

    +( )1

    2 1 1

    1 2U CCp

    p p

    ,

    =

    ( ) ( )

    +( )+( )

    1 1

    1

    p p

    p, and

    flexible

    ty is obtained by setting the probability of nonadjustment in price, Mp, close to zero.e set the inverse of elasticity of intertemporal substitution, V, and the elasticity of

    substitution between home and foreign produced goods, HTXDOWRIROORZLQJ*DOLDQG

    RQDFHOOL7KH\VKRZWKDWXVLQJWKLVVSHFLFDWLRQWRJHWKHUZLWKWKHDVVXPSWLRQV

    of purchasing power parity and uncovered interest parity, the combined effects of

    PDUNHWSRZHUDQGWHUPVRIWUDGHGLVWRUWLRQVFRXOGEHRIIVHWVRWKDWXQGHUH[LEOHSULFH

    HTXLOLEULXPGRPHVWLFLQDWLRQWDUJHWLQJLVWKHRSWLPDOPRQHWDU\SROLF\(TXDWLRQ

    measures welfare loss as a second order approximation to the utility loss of the domestic

    consumer resulting from deviations from optimal monetary policy. ollowing ucas 198),

    DOWHUQDWLYHPRQHWDU\SROLFLHVDUHVSHFLHGLQWKHFRQWH[WRIDVLPSOH'6*(PRGHODQG

    the welfare losses are compared to draw policy implications.

    F. Model Parameterization

    he model is solved numerically and parameterized following Monacelli 2004).9 he

    marginal disutility of work effort M is set to . As common in the Calvo 198) pricing

    models, the probability of price nonadjustment, I, is set at 0.5. he steady-state

    markup, --HTXDOVWR7KHODERUVKDUHRIRXWSXWHTXDOV7KHHODVWLFLW\RI

    investment rate to the price of capital KHTXDOV

    he monetary policy regime parameters are set as follows he interest rate smoothing

    parameter, F, is 0.5. ZHIRU[HGRUSHJJHGH[FKDQJHUDWHZKLOHZH = 0.1 for

    H[LEOHH[FKDQJHUDWHQGHUWKHH[LEOHH[FKDQJHUDWHUHJLPHWKHFHQWUDOEDQNFRXOGFKRRVHWRWDUJHWRQO\&3LQDWLRQVRZS= 1.5 and ZyRURQO\GRPHVWLFLQDWLRQVXFK

    that ZS+ = 1.5 and ZyRUFKRRVHWRIROORZWKH7D\ORUUXOHVRZS = 1.5 and Zy

    or target nominal output and set ZS = 1.5 and Zy = 1.5 or real output and set ZS = 0 and

    Zy7KHFHQWUDOEDQNFRXOGDOVRWDUJHW&3LQDWLRQDQGH[FKDQJHUDWHDQGVHW

    ZS= 1.5, Zy = 0 and ZH = 0.8.

    As in Alba, u, and Chia 2011), the parameters of the serial correlation of the oil price

    shocks Uy), foreign interest rate Ui), foreign output Uy), and technology Ua ) are set

    to 0.90. he degrees of the impact of oil price on the foreign price level JNOHTXDOV

    IRUDSRVLWLYHRLOSULFHVKRFNDQGIRUDQHJDWLYHRLOSULFHVKRFN7KHVHUHHFW

    the asymmetric effect of oil price shocks.10 hese asymmetric effects also imply thatDSRVLWLYHRLOSULFHVKRFNKDVVLJQLFDQWHIIHFWRQPDUJLQDOFRVWZKLOHDQHJDWLYHRLO

    price shock has negligible effect on marginal cost. he share of capital relative to oil in

    production L) is 0.90. he standard deviations from the steady state of oil price

    Po

    ) of

    9 The numerical solution o the model is described in Uhlig (1997).10 For example, Chen, Finney, and Lai (2005) nd empirical evidence that gasoline prices in the US respond quickly to

    a crude oil price increase but not to a decrease.

    10 | ADB Economics Working Paper Series No. 299

  • 7/27/2019 A Welfare Evaluation of East Asian Monetary Policy Regimes under Foreign Output Shock

    18/31

    foreign nominal interest rate i

    ) and of technology a) are set at 1. he standard

    GHYLDWLRQRIIRUHLJQRXWSXWIURPWKHVWHDG\VWDWHLVVHWWRRYHURQHSHULRG

    he inverse of the elasticity of substitution between oil and capital, X, is calculated

    from the expression of the steady state of the oil to capital ratio as a function of

    the parameters X,G,E, and L.11:HIROORZLPDQGRXQJDQLLQVHWWLQJWKH

    depreciation rate, GHTXDOVWRDQGWKHGLVFRXQWUDWHEHTXDOVWR7KH

    share of oil relative to capital stock, 1L), is 0.10. iven these parameter values, X is

    FDOFXODWHGEDVHGRQDYHUDJHHQHUJ\WRFDSLWDOUDWLRRIIRUQGRQHVLDIRUWKH

    3KLOLSSLQHVIRUDOD\VLDIRU7KDLODQGIRUWKHHSXEOLFRIRUHD

    IRU6LQJDSRUHIRU+RQJRQJ&KLQDIRU7DLSHL&KLQDDQGIRUWKHQLWHG

    tates ), which is our benchmark country. hese values are used to calculate X of 9.

    IRUQGRQHVLDIRUWKH3KLOLSSLQHVIRUDOD\VLDIRU7KDLODQGIRUWKHHSXEOLF

    RIRUHDIRU6LQJDSRUHIRU+RQJRQJ&KLQDIRU7DLSHL&KLQDDQG

    for the .127KHHVWLPDWHVIRUWKH6DUHFRPSDUDEOHWRLPDQGRXQJDQLVVHWWLQJ

    ofXHTXDOVWRDQGDQHODVWLFLW\RIVXEVWLWXWLRQRIIRUWKH6$VDSUR[\IRUWKH

    SDUDPHWHURQWKHSURSRUWLRQRIIRUHLJQJRRGVLQWRWDOFRQVXPSWLRQ J), we use imports

    over of ast Asian countries as shown in able 1.

    IV. Simulation Results and Welare

    n this section, we report and discuss our simulation results, including estimates ofwelfare losses under alternative monetary policy regimes.

    A. Impulse Responses under Various Monetary Policy Regimes

    7KHVLPXODWHGLPSXOVHUHVSRQVHVLQLJXUHVUHSUHVHQWWKHG\QDPLFUHVSRQVHVRI

    UHDORXWSXWLQDWLRQWHUPVRIWUDGHQRPLQDOUDWHVDQGUHDOH[FKDQJHUDWHVXQGHUVHYHQ

    PRQHWDU\SROLF\UHJLPHV[HGRUSHJJHGH[FKDQJHUDWHUHJLPHVWULFW&3LQDWLRQ

    WDUJHWLQJH[FKDQJHUDWHDQG&3LQDWLRQWDUJHWLQJWKH7D\ORUUXOHVWULFWGRPHVWLF

    LQDWLRQWDUJHWLQJQRPLQDO*'3WDUJHWLQJDQGUHDO*'3WDUJHWLQJ

    11 The steady-state capitaloil ratio is given by

    K

    O

    Z

    ( )

    =

    1, where

    Z= +

    11

    , which is the steady-

    state rental cost o capital. The details o the derivation are available rom the authors upon request.12 Data on energy use in kiloton o oil equivalent (KOE) and gross capital ormation are rom the World Economic

    Indicators or Hong Kong, China; Indonesia; the Republic o Korea; Malaysia; Philippines; Singapore; and the US.Data or Taipei,China are rom the CEIC Database. We calculate energy use by multiplying energy use in KOE by theaverage price o a kiloton o crude oil in 2000 US dollars. We use the CPI to convert energy use in 2000 US dollarsto 1985 international dollars in relation to the US. Data on CPI and the price o crude oil are rom the InternationalFinancial Statistics online.

    A Welfare Evaluation of East Asian Monetary Policy Regimes under Foreign Output Shock | 11

  • 7/27/2019 A Welfare Evaluation of East Asian Monetary Policy Regimes under Foreign Output Shock

    19/31

    Figure 1: Impulse Responses to a Negative Shock in Foreign Output

    Figure 5: Under Fixed/Pegged Exchange Rate

    33

    0.5

    0.4

    0.3

    0.2

    0.1

    0

    0.1

    0.2

    0.3

    1 3 5 7 9 11 13 15 17 19 21 23 25 27 29 31 33

    Terms o trade Domestic ination

    CPI ination Nominal exchange rate

    Real exchange rate Output

    Source: Authors' estimates.

    Figure 2: Impulse Responses to a Negative Shock in Foreign Output

    Figure 5: Under CPI Infation Targeting

    0.5

    0.4

    0.3

    0.2

    0.1

    0

    0.1

    0.2

    0.3

    1 3 5 7 9 11 13 15 17 19 21 23 25 27 29 31 33

    Terms o trade Domestic ination

    CPI ination Nominal exchange rate

    Real exchange rate Output

    CPI = consumer price index.

    Source: Authors' estimates.

    12 | ADB Economics Working Paper Series No. 299

  • 7/27/2019 A Welfare Evaluation of East Asian Monetary Policy Regimes under Foreign Output Shock

    20/31

    Figure 3: Impulse Responses to a Negative Shock in Foreign Output

    Figure 5: Under Exchange Rate and CPI Infation Targeting

    0.5

    0.4

    0.3

    0.2

    0.1

    0

    0.1

    0.2

    0.3

    1 3 5 7 9 11 13 15 17 19 21 23 25 27 29 31 33

    Terms o trade Domestic ination

    CPI ination Nominal exchange rate

    Real exchange rate Output

    CPI = consumer price index.Source: Authors' estimates.

    Figure 4: Impulse Responses to a Negative Shock in Foreign Output

    Figure 5: Under Taylor Rule

    0.4

    0.3

    0.2

    0.1

    0

    0.1

    0.2

    0.3

    0.4

    0.5

    1 3 5 7 9 11 13 15 17 19 21 23 25 27 29 31 33

    Terms o trade Domestic ination

    CPI ination Nominal exchange rate

    Real exchange rate Output

    CPI = consumer price index.Source: Authors' estimates.

    A Welfare Evaluation of East Asian Monetary Policy Regimes under Foreign Output Shock | 13

  • 7/27/2019 A Welfare Evaluation of East Asian Monetary Policy Regimes under Foreign Output Shock

    21/31

    Figure 5: Impulse Responses to a Negative Shock in Foreign Output

    Figure 5: with Domestic Infation Targeting

    0.4

    0.3

    0.2

    0.1

    0

    0.1

    0.2

    0.3

    1 3 5 7 9 11 13 15 17 19 21 23 25 27 29 31 33

    Terms o trade Domestic ination

    CPI ination Nominal exchange rate

    Real exchange rate Output

    CPI = consumer price index.Source: Authors' estimates.

    Figure 6: Impulse Responses to a Negative Shock in Foreign Output

    Figure 5: with Nominal GDP Targeting

    0.4

    0.2

    0

    0.2

    0.4

    0.6

    0.8

    1

    1 3 5 7 9 11 13 15 17 19 21 23 25 27 29 31 33

    Terms o trade Domestic ination

    CPI ination Nominal exchange rate

    Real exchange rate Output

    CPI = consumer price index, GDP = gross domestic product.Source: Authors' estimates.

    14 | ADB Economics Working Paper Series No. 299

  • 7/27/2019 A Welfare Evaluation of East Asian Monetary Policy Regimes under Foreign Output Shock

    22/31

    Figure 7: Impulse Responses to a Negative Shock in Foreign Output

    Figure 5: with Real GDP Targeting

    0.2

    0

    0.2

    0.4

    0.6

    0.8

    1

    1.2

    1 3 5 7 9 11 13 15 17 19 21 23 25 27 29 31 33

    Terms o trade Domestic ination

    CPI ination Nominal exchange rate

    Real exchange rate Output

    CPI = consumer price index, GDP = gross domestic product.Source: Authors' estimates.

    $QHJDWLYHIRUHLJQRXWSXWVKRFNKDVWKHELJJHVWLPSDFWRQGRPHVWLFRXWSXWXQGHU[HGRU

    SHJJHGH[FKDQJHUDWHUHJLPHIROORZHGE\&3LQDWLRQDQGH[FKDQJHUDWHWDUJHWLQJ&3

    LQDWLRQWDUJHWLQJGRPHVWLFLQDWLRQWDUJHWLQJ7D\ORUW\SHUXOHQRPLQDO*'3WDUJHWLQJ

    and the least under real targeting. or a 1 decline in foreign output, real output

    GHFOLQHVIURPLWVVWHDG\VWDWHE\XQGHU[HGH[FKDQJHUDWHUHJLPHXQGHU

    &3LQDWLRQFXPH[FKDQJHUDWHWDUJHWLQJXQGHU&3LQDWLRQWDUJHWLQJ

    XQGHUGRPHVWLFLQDWLRQWDUJHWLQJXQGHU7D\ORUUXOHDQGXQGHUQRPLQDO

    RXWSXWQGHUUHDORXWSXWWDUJHWLQJLWULVHVE\LQWKHUVWSHULRGEHIRUHGHFOLQLQJE\

    0.08.

    he mitigated effect on real output under real and nominal output targeting and to a

    lesser extent, aylor-type rule, could be explained by the large and sharp depreciation

    in the nominal exchange rate following a negative foreign output shock. n the period

    following the 1 negative foreign output shock, nominal exchange rate depreciates

    from the steady state value by 0.4 for real output targeting, 0.5 for nominal output

    targeting, and 0.24 for aylor-type rule. n turn, the large exchange rate depreciation

    LQFUHDVHVWKHSULFHVRIRLODQGRWKHULPSRUWVFDXVLQJKLJKHUWRWDO&3LQDWLRQLNHZLVH

    H[SHFWDWLRQVRIKLJKHULQDWLRQDQGIXUWKHUGHSUHFLDWLRQUDLVHWKHQRPLQDOLQWHUHVWUDWH

    he impact on the nominal interest rate is shown in igure 8 where a 1 negative

    foreign output shock increases nominal interest rate by 0.41, 0.11, and 0.08 from

    the steady state for nominal output targeting, real output targeting, and aylor-type rule,

    respectively. n contrast, nominal exchange rate depreciates only by 0.08, 0.02,

    A Welfare Evaluation of East Asian Monetary Policy Regimes under Foreign Output Shock | 15

  • 7/27/2019 A Welfare Evaluation of East Asian Monetary Policy Regimes under Foreign Output Shock

    23/31

    DQGIRU&3LQDWLRQGRPHVWLFLQDWLRQDQG&3LQDWLRQFXPH[FKDQJHUDWH

    WDUJHWLQJUHVSHFWLYHO\7KLVOHDGVWRDUHGXFWLRQRI&3LQDWLRQIURPLWVVWHDG\VWDWH

    E\IRU&3LQDWLRQWDUJHWLQJIRUSHJJHGH[FKDQJHUDWHUHJLPHDQG&3

    LQDWLRQDQGH[FKDQJHUDWHWDUJHWLQJDQGIRUGRPHVWLFLQDWLRQWDUJHWLQJWZR

    periods after the shock. ence, nominal interest rate in igure 8 shows a decline fromVWHDG\VWDWHYDOXHVRIDQGIRU&3LQDWLRQGRPHVWLFLQDWLRQ

    DQG&3LQDWLRQFXPH[FKDQJHUDWHWDUJHWLQJUHVSHFWLYHO\7KHQRPLQDOLQWHUHVWUDWH

    hardly changes under pegged exchange rate regime. he impulse responses clearly show

    DWUDGHRIIEHWZHHQORZHURXWSXWYRODWLOLW\DQGKLJKHULQDWLRQDQGQRPLQDOLQWHUHVWUDWH

    volatility.

    Figure 8: Impulse Responses o Interest Rate to a Negative Foreign

    Figure 5: Output Shock Under Various Monetary Policies

    0.1

    0.08

    0.06

    0.04

    0.02

    0

    0.02

    0.04

    0.06

    0.08

    0.1

    1 3 5 7 9 11 13 15 17 19 21 23 25 27 29 31 33

    Pegged exchange rate Taylor-type rule

    CPI ination targeting Domestic ination targeting

    CPI inationexchange rate targeting Nominal output targeting

    CPI = consumer price index.Source: Authors' estimates.

    B. Welare Losses under Various Monetary Policies

    e examine the impact of various monetary policies after a negative foreign output

    shock using a welfare loss function described in ection , and shown in able 2

    with the model parameters of oil-to-capital ratio of 0.25 and import-to- ratio of 0.5

    taken as average values for ast Asian countries. he results show from least to most

    ZHOIDUHORVVHVDVFRPSDUHGZLWKWKHRSWLPDOPRQHWDU\SROLF\DUHDVIROORZV&3LQDWLRQ

    WDUJHWLQJ&3LQDWLRQFXPH[FKDQJHUDWHWDUJHWLQJSHJJHGH[FKDQJHUDWHUHJLPH

    GRPHVWLFLQDWLRQWDUJHWLQJ7D\ORUW\SHUXOHQRPLQDORXWSXWWDUJHWLQJDQGUHDORXWSXW

    16 | ADB Economics Working Paper Series No. 299

  • 7/27/2019 A Welfare Evaluation of East Asian Monetary Policy Regimes under Foreign Output Shock

    24/31

    WDUJHWLQJ:LWKFRPSOHWHSDVVWKURXJK&3LQDWLRQWDUJHWLQJGHOLYHUVWKHOHDVWZHOIDUH

    loss under negative foreign output shock.

    Table 2: Welare Loss ater a Negative Foreign Output Shock

    Table 2: under Dierent Monetary Policies

    Monetary Policy

    Weights in the Interest Rate Rule Welare

    Loss H y

    Fixed /pegged exchange rate regime 0 0 0 0.99 2.35

    CPI ination targeting 1.5 0 0 0.1 0.71

    Exchange rate and ination targeting 1.5 0 0 0.8 1.91

    Taylor-type rule 1.5 0 0.5 0.1 10.13

    Domestic ination targeting 0 1.5 0 0.1 3.69

    Nominal output targeting 1.5 0 1.5 0.1 49.25

    Real output targeting 0 0 1.5 0.1 122.14

    CPI = consumer price index, GDP = gross domestic product.Note: Welare loss is calculated based on the average percentage o imports over real GDP o 50% or the six East Asian countries

    excluding Hong Kong, China and Singapore, which have percentage imports over GDP o 172% and 191%, respectively. Theaverage oil-to-capital ratio is 0.25 and the average elasticity o substitution o oil-to-capital is 3.14, excluding the Philippinesand Indonesia, which have an average oil-to-capital (elasticity o substitution o oil or capital) o 0.58 (7.8) and 0.90 (9.3),respectively. In the model, the import to GDP is (1) equals 0.5 while the elasticity o substitution o oil and capital is . ,H, y, and are the weights on overall ination, domestic ination, output gap, and exchange rate in the interest rate

    rule equation. 1 in which optimal monetary policy under exible price equilibrium is domestic ination targetingas in Gali and Monacelli (2005).

    Source: Authors' estimates.

    ince there are large variations in import-to- ratio among ast Asian countries, we

    FRQGXFWVHQVLWLYLW\DQDO\VLVEDVHGRQWKLVUDWLRUHSUHVHQWHGE\WKHSDUDPHWHU

    his is the proportion of import in household consumption in the model. able shows

    the estimates of welfare losses due to a 1 negative output shock for various ratiosof import-to- given an oil-to-capital ratio of 0.25 under different monetary policy

    UHJLPHV7KHUHVXOWVVKRZWKDWIRUDQHFRQRP\ZLWKLPSRUWWR*'3UDWLRRI&3LQDWLRQ

    WDUJHWLQJSHJJHGH[FKDQJHUDWHUHJLPHDQGDFRPELQDWLRQRI&3LQDWLRQDQGH[FKDQJH

    rate targeting minimize the welfare losses.

    RUDQHFRQRP\ZLWKLPSRUWWR*'3UDWLRRIGRPHVWLFLQDWLRQWDUJHWLQJGHOLYHUV

    WKHOHDVWZHOIDUHORVVIROORZHGE\&3LQDWLRQWDUJHWLQJDQGWKHQ7D\ORUW\SHUXOHRU

    FRXQWULHVZLWKLPSRUWWR*'3UDWLRVRI&3LQDWLRQWDUJHWLQJGHOLYHUVWKHOHDVW

    ZHOIDUHORVVRULPSRUWWR*'3RI&3LQDWLRQWDUJHWLQJH[FKDQJHUDWHSHJDQG

    &3LQDWLRQFXPH[FKDQJHUDWHSHJKDYHHTXLYDOHQWZHOIDUHORVVHV+HQFHFRXQWULHV

    ZLWKDODUJHLPSRUWFRPSRQHQWFRXOGFRQWUROLQDWLRQXVWDVZHOOE\WDUJHWLQJH[FKDQJHUDWHVVLQFHLPSRUWHGLQDWLRQPDNHVXSDODUJHSURSRUWLRQRIRYHUDOORU&3LQDWLRQ

    hese results are consistent with the literature under complete exchange rate pass

    WKURXJKQDUHODWLYHO\FORVHGHFRQRP\GRPHVWLFLQDWLRQWDUJHWLQJVWDELOL]HVGRPHVWLF

    prices and output. As the level of opennessproxied by the import-to- ratiorises,

    increasing the ratio of foreign goods in the consumption basket so that C targeting

    stabilizes overall prices and output.1

    13 Chung, Jung, and Yang (2007) note that the lower levels o openness could be less relevant with incompleteexchange rate pass through.

    A Welfare Evaluation of East Asian Monetary Policy Regimes under Foreign Output Shock | 17

  • 7/27/2019 A Welfare Evaluation of East Asian Monetary Policy Regimes under Foreign Output Shock

    25/31

    Table 3: Welare Loss ater a Negative Foreign Output Shock Under Dierent Monetary

    Table 3: Policies and Various Values o Import over GDP

    Imports

    over GDP

    Monetary Policy

    Fixed/

    PeggedExchange

    Rate Regime

    CPIInfation

    Targeting

    Exchange

    Rate andInfation

    Targeting

    Taylor-type

    Rule

    DomesticInfation

    Targeting

    NominalIncome

    Targeting

    RealIncome

    Targeting

    1.0 0.44 0.44 0.44 55.65 10.04 246.11 693.19

    0.9 0.57 0.37 0.51 42.18 8.56 187.02 515.26

    0.7 1.53 0.51 1.22 22.37 5.91 101.58 265.77

    0.5 2.35 0.71 1.91 10.13 3.69 49.25 122.14

    0.3 2.33 0.78 1.97 3.47 1.06 19.92 47.48

    0.1 1.42 0.61 1.28 0.64 0.53 5.60 13.56

    CPI = consumer price index, GDP = gross domestic product.Note: We use import over GDP as a proxy or (1) in the model. The elasticity o oil-to-capital is set at 3.14 as in Table 2.

    1 in which optimal monetary policy under exible price equilibrium is domestic ination targeting as in Gali andMonacelli (2005).

    Source: Authors' estimates.

    e also calibrate the model for a pair of economies based on their ratios of oil to capital

    and of import to and calculate the welfare losses under various monetary policy

    UHJLPHV7KHSDLUVRIHFRQRPLHVDUH+RQJRQJ&KLQDDQG6LQJDSRUHWKHHSXEOLFRI

    RUHDDQG7DLSHL&KLQDDOD\VLDDQG7KDLODQGDQGQGRQHVLDDQGWKH3KLOLSSLQHV7KH

    estimates of welfare losses under various monetary policy regimes are shown in able 4.

    7KH\VKRZWKDWHLWKHU[HGSHJJHGH[FKDQJHUDWHUHJLPHVRU&3LQDWLRQWDUJHWLQJ

    GHOLYHUWKHOHDVWZHOIDUHORVVIRU+RQJRQJ&KLQDDQG6LQJDSRUHQWKHRWKHUKDQG

    &3LQDWLRQWDUJHWLQJGHOLYHUVWKHOHDVWZHOIDUHORVVIRUQGRQHVLDWKHHSXEOLFRIRUHD

    DOD\VLDWKH3KLOLSSLQHV7DLSHL&KLQDDQG7KDLODQG

    Table 4: Welare Loss ater a Negative Foreign Output Shock under Dierent Monetary

    Table 3: Policies Calibrated or Various East Asian Countries

    Country

    Monetary Policy

    Fixed/

    Peg

    Exchange

    Rate Regime

    CPI

    Infation

    Targeting

    Exchange

    Rate and

    Infation

    Targeting

    Taylor-

    type

    Rule

    Domestic

    Infation

    Targeting

    Nominal

    Income

    Targeting

    Real

    Income

    Targeting

    Hong Kong, China and Singapore 0.47 0.47 0.47 56.90 10.97 258.76 720.08

    Korea, Rep. o and Taipei,China 2.44 0.77 2.02 5.98 1.87 29.93 79.34

    Malaysia and Thailand 0.93 0.39 0.77 31.01 17.66 134.55 357.72

    Indonesia and the Philippines 2.27 0.73 1.87 6.47 1.87 31.53 70.50

    CPI = consumer price index, GDP = gross domestic product.Note: Hong Kong, China and Singapore have an average import over GDP o 1, and elasticity o substitution o 2.1. The Republic

    o Korea and Taipei,China have an average import over GDP o 0.4 and an elasticity o substitution o oil and capital o 2.3.Malaysia and Thailand have an average import over GDP o 0.8 and an elasticity o substitution o oil and capital o 5.1.Indonesia and the Philippines have an average import over GDP o 0.4 and an elasticity o substitution o oil and capital o

    8.5. 1 in which optimal monetary policy under exible price equilibrium is domestic ination targeting as in Galiand Monacelli (2005).

    Source: Authors' estimates.

    18 | ADB Economics Working Paper Series No. 299

  • 7/27/2019 A Welfare Evaluation of East Asian Monetary Policy Regimes under Foreign Output Shock

    26/31

    C. Summary o Simulation Results and Welare

    Consistent with the empirical evidence documented by offman 200), the comparison

    EHWZHHQUHVSRQVHVRIDOWHUQDWLYHPRQHWDU\SROLF\UHJLPHVVXJJHVWVWKDWLERWK[HG

    H[FKDQJHUDWHUHJLPHDQGLQDWLRQWDUJHWLQJWHQGWRVWDELOL]HUHDOH[FKDQJHUDWHDQGLQDWLRQDWWKHH[SHQVHRIVXEVWDQWLDOLQVWDELOLW\LQWKHUHDOHFRQRP\LLWKHPLWLJDWHG

    decline in real output under the aylor-type rule is explained by the large depreciation

    RIQRPLQDODQGUHDOH[FKDQJHUDWHVDQGLLLLQDWLRQUDWHLVORZHVWXQGHU&3LQDWLRQ

    targeting. n addition, the decline in output is smallest under nominal and real

    targeting due to the higher rate of nominal and real exchange rate depreciation. owever,

    ERWKRXWSXWWDUJHWLQJDOVROHGWRWKHZRUVWLQDWLRQRXWFRPH&RQVLVWHQWZLWKULHGPDQV

    SUHGLFWLRQVORQJUXQGLIIHUHQFHVDFURVVUHJLPHVDUHQRWVLJQLFDQW

    e also compare the welfare effects of the various monetary policy regimes as compared

    ZLWKWKHRSWLPDOPRQHWDU\SROLF\XQGHUH[LEOHSULFHVXVLQJDTXDGUDWLFVRFLDOZHOIDUH

    loss function. e show that with an average oil-to-capital ratio of 0.2 and import-to-UDWLRRI&3LQDWLRQWDUJHWLQJOHDGVWRWKHOHDVWZHOIDUHORVVIROORZHGE\LQDWLRQ

    DQGH[FKDQJHUDWHWDUJHWLQJSHJJHGRU[HGH[FKDQJHUDWHUHJLPHGRPHVWLFLQDWLRQ

    targeting, aylor-type rule, and nominal and real output targeting. he simulation results

    VKRZWKDWDQHJDWLYHRXWSXWVKRFNFDXVHVWKHLQDWLRQUDWHDQGVXEVHTXHQWO\WKHQRPLQDO

    LQWHUHVWUDWHWRGHFOLQHXQGHU&3LQDWLRQWDUJHWLQJQFRQWUDVWLQDWLRQULVHVXQGHU

    aylor-type rule or nominal and real output targeting due to the large depreciation in the

    QRPLQDODQGUHDOH[FKDQJHUDWHV7KHVHQGLQJVDUHFRQVLVWHQWZLWKGH&DUYDOKRLOKR

    2010).

    IWKHLPSRUWWR*'3UDWLRLVWKHZHOIDUHORVVRIFRXQWULHVZLWK&3LQDWLRQFXP

    exchange rate targeting is comparable to countries with either pegged exchange rate or&3LQDWLRQWDUJHWLQJ+RZHYHULIWKHUDWLRLVEHWZHHQDQG&3LQDWLRQFXP

    H[FKDQJHUDWHWDUJHWLQJLVRQO\VHFRQGEHVWWR&3LQDWLRQWDUJHWLQJIWKHUDWLRLVOHVV

    WKDQLWLVZRUVHWKDQHLWKHU7D\ORUW\SHUXOHRU&3LQDWLRQRUGRPHVWLFLQDWLRQ

    targeting.

    ince ast Asian economies vary a lot with respect to the ratio of import-to-, ranging

    IURPIRUQGRQHVLDWRPRUHWKDQIRU6LQJDSRUHDQG+RQJRQJ&KLQDZH

    calculate the welfare loss of various monetary policy regimes for ratios between 10

    DQG:HQGWKDWZLWKLPSRUWWR*'3UDWLRRIZHOIDUHORVVXQGHUWKH[HGRU

    SHJJHGUHJLPHLVDOPRVWHTXLYDOHQWWRWKHZHOIDUHORVVXQGHU&3LQDWLRQWDUJHWLQJ7KLV

    LVFRQVLVWHQWZLWKWKH&KRZDQGFHOLVQGLQJWKDW6LQJDSRUHVZHOIDUHORVVZLOO

    QRWEHVLJQLFDQWO\OHVVLILWVZLWFKHVWRDPRUHH[LEOHH[FKDQJHUDWHV\VWHPDQGLQDWLRQ

    WDUJHWLQJ(FRQRPLHVWKDWGHSHQGKHDYLO\RQLPSRUWVVXFKDV6LQJDSRUHDQG+RQJRQJ

    &KLQDFDQPRGHUDWHLPSRUWHGLQDWLRQE\SHJJLQJWKHH[FKDQJHUDWHQFRQWUDVWIRU

    LPSRUWVWR*'3UDWLRRIWKHGRPHVWLFLQDWLRQWDUJHWLQJGHOLYHUVWKHOHDVWZHOIDUH

    loss as it also stabilizes output. hen import-to- ratio is between 0. and 0.9, C

    LQDWLRQWDUJHWLQJGHOLYHUVWKHRXWFRPHZLWKWKHOHDVWZHOIDUHORVV

    A Welfare Evaluation of East Asian Monetary Policy Regimes under Foreign Output Shock | 19

  • 7/27/2019 A Welfare Evaluation of East Asian Monetary Policy Regimes under Foreign Output Shock

    27/31

    V. Conclusions

    7KHJOREDOQDQFLDODQGHFRQRPLFFULVLVRIXQGHUOLQHGWKHYXOQHUDELOLW\RI

    VPDOORSHQHFRQRPLHVWRDGYHUVHH[WHUQDORXWSXWVKRFNV$OWKRXJK(DVW$VLDVQDQFLDO

    V\VWHPVZHUHODUJHO\LPPXQHIURPWKHJOREDOQDQFLDOLQVWDELOLW\WKHLUUHDOHFRQRPLHV

    were severely affected by the deep recession of the advanced economies. his reignites

    the debate about the appropriate monetary policy regime for a small open economy

    subject to external shocks. he primary objective of our paper is to evaluate and compare

    the welfare impact of external output shocks acting through the trade channel in eight

    ast Asian countries with different monetary policy regimes. o do so, we use a simple

    G\QDPLFVWRFKDVWLFJHQHUDOHTXLOLEULXPPRGHOZLWKVWLFN\SULFHVDQGLPSHUIHFWFRPSHWLWLRQ

    LQWKHJRRGVPDUNHW7KHDOWHUQDWLYHPRQHWDU\SROLF\UHJLPHVFRQVLGHUHGDUH[HGRU

    SHJJHGH[FKDQJHUDWHUHJLPH&3DQGGRPHVWLFLQDWLRQWDUJHWLQJ&3LQDWLRQFXP

    exchange rate targeting, the aylor-type rule, and nominal and real output targeting.

    $OWKRXJKRXU'6*(PRGHO LVKLJKO\VLPSOLHGZHFDQXVH LWVVLPXODWLRQ UHVXOWVWR

    VFUXWLQL]H+RIIPDQVHPSLULFDOHYLGHQFHDQGLGHQWLI\VLJQLFDQWGLIIHUHQFHVLQUHVSRQVHV

    to foreign output shocks across monetary policy regimes. Compared to a aylor-type

    UXOHDQGQRPLQDODQGUHDORXWSXWWDUJHWLQJ[HGRUSHJJHGH[FKDQJHUDWHUHJLPHVDQG

    LQDWLRQWDUJHWLQJSUHYHQWQRPLQDOH[FKDQJHUDWHDQGLQDWLRQIURPDGXVWLQJDQGWKXV

    prevents the real exchange rate from depreciating. he negative impact of a fall in foreign

    output is thus largely passed to the domestic economy. he mitigated decline in real

    output under a aylor-type rule and nominal and real targeting is explained by a larger

    GHSUHFLDWLRQRIWKHQRPLQDODQGUHDOH[FKDQJHUDWHV:HDOVRYHULI\WKDWLQDWLRQUDWHLV

    ORZHVWXQGHU&3LQDWLRQWDUJHWLQJDQGQRPLQDOH[FKDQJHUDWHLVVWDEOHXQGHUSHJVXU

    VLPXODWLRQUHVXOWVDUHFRQVLVWHQWZLWKWKHGH&DUYDOKRLOKRQGLQJVWKDWLQDWLRQ

    WDUJHWLQJFRXQWULHVKDYHORZHULQWHUHVWUDWHVWKDQQRQLQDWLRQWDUJHWLQJFRXQWULHV

    ur simulation results are also broadly consistent with the stylized facts of the ast

    $VLDQH[SHULHQFHGXULQJWKHHFRQRPLFFULVLV$V7DEOHVKRZV+RQJRQJ

    &KLQD6LQJDSRUHDQG7DLSHL&KLQDZKLFKWDUJHWWKHH[FKDQJHUDWHH[SHULHQFHGWKH

    smallest volatility in exchange rate but suffered the largest cumulative reduction in real

    *'3JURZWKQWKHRWKHUKDQGWKHRWKHU(DVW$VLDQFRXQWULHVZKLFKSUDFWLFHLQDWLRQ

    targeting, experienced larger currency depreciation but suffered a smaller cumulative

    UHGXFWLRQLQUHDO*'3JURZWKQDGGLWLRQWZRRIWKHLQDWLRQWDUJHWLQJFRXQWULHV

    QGRQHVLDDQG7KDLODQGH[SHULHQFHG&3GHDWLRQDVSUHGLFWHGE\WKHPRGHO

    XUZHOIDUHDQDO\VLVVKRZVWKDW+RQJRQJ&KLQDDQG6LQJDSRUHVSHJJHGH[FKDQJH

    rate regimes give the least welfare losses in light of their high ratios of imports to .

    7KLVLVFRQVLVWHQWZLWKWKH&KRZDQGFHOLVQGLQJIRU6LQJDSRUH:HDOVRQG

    LQDWLRQWDUJHWLQJWREHDSSURSULDWHIRUQGRQHVLDWKHHSXEOLFRIRUHDDOD\VLDWKH

    hilippines, and hailand since it offers the least welfare loss. his is consistent with the

    VWXG\RI&KXQJXQJDQG

  • 7/27/2019 A Welfare Evaluation of East Asian Monetary Policy Regimes under Foreign Output Shock

    28/31

    DOD\VLDDQG7DLSHL&KLQDFRXOGUHGXFHWKHLUZHOIDUHORVVHVE\PRYLQJIURP&3LQDWLRQ

    FXPH[FKDQJHUDWHWDUJHWLQJWRZDUGWDUJHWLQJRQO\LQDWLRQ

    At a broader level, our analysis can provide some guidance about monetary policy

    regimes for small open economies. or such economies, which depend heavily onexports and trade for growth, the capacity of monetary policy to cushion the impact of

    adverse external output shocks is one of the most important criteria for the appropriate

    policy regime. he pronounced impact of the recession in the advanced economies on

    WKHVPDOORSHQHFRQRPLHVGXULQJWKHJOREDOFULVLVRIXQGHUOLQHVWKLVSRLQW

    XUKLJKO\VLPSOLHG'6*(PRGHOVLPXODWLRQUHVXOWVVXJJHVWWKDW&3LQDWLRQWDUJHWLQJ

    delivers the least welfare loss for most ast Asian small open economies except for those

    ZLWKDQH[FHSWLRQDOO\KLJKGHJUHHRILPSRUW7KHUHIRUHDQLPSRUWDQWDGGLWLRQDOEHQHWRI

    &3LQDWLRQWDUJHWLQJIRUVPDOORSHQHFRQRPLHVPD\EHWKDWLWSURWHFWVWKHPEHWWHUIURP

    external output shocks.

    A Welfare Evaluation of East Asian Monetary Policy Regimes under Foreign Output Shock | 21

  • 7/27/2019 A Welfare Evaluation of East Asian Monetary Policy Regimes under Foreign Output Shock

    29/31

    Reerences

    Alba, . ., . u, and -M. Chia. 2011. oreign utput hocks, Monetary olicy ules and

    Macroeconomic olatilities in mall pen conomies. International Review of Economics andFinance

    $RNLSWLPDORQHWDU\3ROLF\HVSRQVHVWRHODWLYHSULFH&KDQJHVJournal of Monetary

    Economics

    $SRVWRODNLV%((QHUJ\&DSLWDO6XEVWLWXWDELOLW\&RPSOHPHQWDULW\7KH'LFKRWRP\Energy

    Economics

    %DFNXV'DQG&UXFLQLLO3ULFHDQGWKH7HUPVRI7UDGHJournal of International

    Economics

    Blanchard, ., and . ali. 200. he Macroeconomic ffects of il rice hocks hy are

    the 2000s so ifferent from the 190s? NBER Working Paper18, ational Bureau of

    conomic esearch, Massachusetts.

    Blanchard, ., . ellAriccia, and . Mauro. 2010. ethinking Macroeconomic olicy. IMF Staff

    Position Note /10/0), nternational Monetary und, ashington, C.

    Bodenstein, M., C. rceg, and . uerrieri. 2008. ptimal Monetary olicy with istinct Core and+HDGOLQHQDWLRQDWHV Journal of Monetary Economics6

    Broda, C. 2004. erms of rade and xchange ate egimes in eveloping Countries. Journal of

    International Economics

    &DOYR*$6WDJJHUHG3ULFHVLQDWLOLW\D[LPL]LQJUDPHZRUNJournal of Monetary

    Economics

    &KHQLQQH\DQGDL$7KUHVKROG&RLQWHJUDWLRQ$QDO\VLVRI$V\PPHWULF3ULFH

    ransmission from Crude il to asoline rices. Economic Letters

    &KRZ:DQG3'FHOLVHHG6LQJDSRUHHDUORDWLQJ$%D\HVLDQ'6*($

    Approach. Manuscript, ordham niversity, ew ork.

    Chung, ., . ung, and . . ang. 200. ptimal Monetary olicy in a mall pen conomy he

    &DVHRIWKHHSXEOLFRI@RUHDJournal of Asian Economics

    &ODULGD*DOLDQG*HUWOHU7KH6FLHQFHRIRQHWDU\3ROLF\$HZH\QHVLDQ

    erspective. Journal of Economic Literature

    GH&DUYDOKRLOKRQDWLRQ7DUJHWLQJDQGWKH&ULVLV$Q(PSLULFDO$VVHVVPHQW IMF

    Working Paper/10/05, nternational Monetary und, ashington, C.

    evereux, M. 2004. hould the xchange ate be a hock Absorber? Journal of International

    Economics

    evereux, M., . ane, and . u. 200. xchange ates and Monetary olicy in merging Market

    conomies. The Economic Journal

    ivino, . A. 2009. ptimal Monetary olicy in a mall pen conomy. Economic Modelling

    ornbusch, . 1980. Open Economy Macroeconomics. ew ork Basic Book nc.

    dwards, ., and . evy eyati. 2005. lexible xchange ates as hock Absorbers. European

    Economic Review

    inn, M. . 2000. erfect Competition and the ffects of nergy rice ncreases on conomicActivity. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking

    riedman, M. 195. he Case for lexible xchange ates. n Essays in Positive Economics.

    Chicago niversity of Chicago ress.

    ali, ., and . Monacelli. 2005. Monetary olicy and xchange ate olatility in a mall pen

    conomy. Review of Economic Studies

    offman, M. 200. ixed ersus lexible xchange ates vidence from eveloping Countries.

    Economica

    22 | ADB Economics Working Paper Series No. 299

  • 7/27/2019 A Welfare Evaluation of East Asian Monetary Policy Regimes under Foreign Output Shock

    30/31

    LPDQG3RXQJDQL7KHROHRI(QHUJ\LQHDO%XVLQHVV&\FOHRGHOVJournal of

    Monetary Economics

    ufer, . 1994. he nternational ransmission of conomic hocks in a hree-Country orld

    under Mixed xchange ates. Journal of International Money and Finance

    ucas, . 198. Models of Business Cycles. xford Blackwell ublisher.

    Monacelli, . 2004. nto the Mussa uzzle Monetary olicy egimes and the eal xchange atein a mall pen conomy. Journal of International Economics

    Mundell, . A. 191. A heory of ptimum Currency Areas. American Economic Review

    5.

    XUUD\&$LNROVNR]KHYVN\\DQG'3DSHOOQDWLRQ3HUVLVWHQFHDQGWKH7D\RU

    rinciple. Available http//mpra.ub.uni_muenchen.de/115/

    EVWIHOGDQGRJRII([FKDQJHDWH'\QDPLFVHGX[Journal of Political Economy

    . 199. Foundations of International Macroeconomics. Cambridge M ress.

    . 2000. ew irections for tochastic pen conomy Models. Journal of International

    Economics

    oole, . 190. ptimal Choice of Monetary olicy nstruments in a imple tochastic Macro

    Model. Quarterly Journal of Economics

    otemberg, . ., and M. oodford. 199. mperfect Competition and the ffects of nergy rice

    ncreases on conomic Activity. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking

    $QSWLPL]DWLRQ%DVHG(FRQRPHWULFUDPHZRUNIRU WKH(YDOXDWLRQRIRQHWDU\

    olicy xpanded ersion. NBER Working Papero. 2. Massachusetts ational Bureau of

    conomics.

    . 1999. nterest ate ules in an stimated ticky rice Model. n . aylor, ed., Monetary

    Policy Rules Chicago he niversity of Chicago ress.

    6WLJOLW](7KHDLOXUHRIQDWLRQ7DUJHWLQJ$YDLODEOHZZZSURHFWV\QGLFDWHRUJ

    commentary/stiglitz99/nglish

    aylor, . B. 199. iscretion ersus olicy ules in ractice. CarnegieRochester Conference

    Series on Public Policy

    7UXPDQ(QDWLRQ7DUJHWLQJLQWKH:RUOG(FRQRP\:DVKLQJWRQ'&QVWLWXWHIRU

    nternational conomics.hlig, . 199. A oolkit for Analyzing onlinear ynamic tochastic Models asily. n . Marimon

    and A. cott, eds., Computational Methods for the Study of Dynamic Economies. xford

    xford niversity ress.

    :DOVK&(HZH\QHVLDQRQHWDU\(FRQRPLFVQMonetary Theory and Policy.

    Cambridge M ress.

    oodford, M. 200. Interest and Prices: Foundations of a Theory of Monetary Policy. rinceton

    rinceton niversity ress.

    A Welfare Evaluation of East Asian Monetary Policy Regimes under Foreign Output Shock | 23

  • 7/27/2019 A Welfare Evaluation of East Asian Monetary Policy Regimes under Foreign Output Shock

    31/31

    A Welare Evaluation o East Asian Monetary Policy Regimes under Foreign Output Shock

    Joseph D. Alba, Wai-Mun Chia, and Donghyun Park assess the welare impact o external shocksunder diferent monetary policy regimes in East and Southeast Asia. To do so, they numericallysolve and calculate the welare loss unction o a dynamic stochastic general equilibrium (DSGE)model with complete exchange rate pass through. Their DSGE model simulation results suggestthat consumer price index ination targeting delivers the least welare losses or most small open

    economies in East and Southeast Asia.

    About the Asian Development Bank

    ADBs vision is an Asia and Pacic region ree o poverty. Its mission is to help its developingmember countries reduce poverty and improve the quality o lie o their people. Despite theregions many successes, it remains home to two-thirds o the worlds poor: 1.8 billion peoplewho live on less than $2 a day, with 903 million struggling on less than $1.25 a day. ADB iscommitted to reducing poverty through inclusive economic growth, environmentallysustainable growth, and regional integration.

    Based in Manila, ADB is owned by 67 members, including 48 rom the region. Its main

    instruments or helping its developing member countries are policy dialogue, loans, equityinvestments, guarantees, grants, and technical assistance.

    Asian Development Bank6 ADB Avenue, Mandaluyong City1550 Metro Manila, Philippineswww.adb.org/economics