alternative value elicitation formats in contingent ...cvossler/files/alternative cv mechanisms...

49
Alternative Value Elicitation Formats in Contingent Valuation: Mechanism Design and Convergent Validity Christian A. Vossler and J. Scott Holladay Department of Economics and Howard H. Baker Jr. Center for Public Policy, University of Tennessee, Knoxville, TN The published version of this study is in the Journal of Public Economics. The final publication is available at https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jpubeco.2018.07.004. © 2018. This manuscript version is made available under the CC-BY-NC-ND 4.0 license http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by-nc-nd/4.0/. * Correspondence should be directed to Christian Vossler, Department of Economics, 523 Stokely Management Center, The University of Tennessee, Knoxville, TN 37996-0550. E-mail: [email protected]. Telephone: 865-974-1699. Fax: 865-974-4601. The authors thank Scott Gilpatric, Chris Knittel, seminar participants at the University of Kentucky, the 2016 AERE conference and the 2016 EAERE conference, and two anonymous reviewers for very helpful comments and suggestions. Thanks also go to the Institute for Policy Integrity at NYU, Michael Livermore and Howard Kunreuther for help designing and fielding the survey. This research was funded in part through a grant from the Alfred P. Sloan Foundation.

Upload: others

Post on 15-Mar-2020

8 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Alternative Value Elicitation Formats in Contingent ...cvossler/files/Alternative CV mechanisms (accepted).pdfformat, we hope to identify ways to improve survey design as well as enhance

Alternative Value Elicitation Formats in Contingent Valuation: Mechanism

Design and Convergent Validity

Christian A. Vossler and J. Scott Holladay

Department of Economics and Howard H. Baker Jr. Center for Public Policy,

University of Tennessee, Knoxville, TN

The published version of this study is in the Journal of Public Economics. The final publication

is available at https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jpubeco.2018.07.004.

© 2018. This manuscript version is made available under the CC-BY-NC-ND 4.0 license

http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by-nc-nd/4.0/.

*Correspondence should be directed to Christian Vossler, Department of Economics, 523 Stokely

Management Center, The University of Tennessee, Knoxville, TN 37996-0550. E-mail:

[email protected]. Telephone: 865-974-1699. Fax: 865-974-4601. The authors thank Scott

Gilpatric, Chris Knittel, seminar participants at the University of Kentucky, the 2016 AERE

conference and the 2016 EAERE conference, and two anonymous reviewers for very helpful

comments and suggestions. Thanks also go to the Institute for Policy Integrity at NYU, Michael

Livermore and Howard Kunreuther for help designing and fielding the survey. This research was

funded in part through a grant from the Alfred P. Sloan Foundation.

Page 2: Alternative Value Elicitation Formats in Contingent ...cvossler/files/Alternative CV mechanisms (accepted).pdfformat, we hope to identify ways to improve survey design as well as enhance

Alternative Value Elicitation Formats in Contingent Valuation: Mechanism Design and

Convergent Validity

Abstract: To date, much of the theoretical work on the incentive properties of contingent

valuation surveys has focused on the oft-recommended single binary choice (SBC), referendum

format. This work has identified conditions under which an SBC elicitation is incentive

compatible, and empirical evidence lends support to the predictive power of the theory.

Nevertheless, researchers and practitioners commonly use alternative elicitation formats, and

defend their design choices based on efficiency or other criteria. In this study, we demonstrate

that it is possible to identify conditions under which alternative elicitation formats are incentive

compatible, using as examples open ended (OE) and payment card (PC) question formats. We

then implement theory-informed value elicitations in the context of a flood control policy for

New York City. We fail to reject convergent validity in mean willingness-to-pay when

comparing the theory-driven OE format with SBC, but reject convergent validity between the

theory-driven PC and SBC formats. As an informative counterfactual, we find that a “standard”

OE elicitation congruent with prior work leads to significantly lower values and a lower

proportion of respondents who view the elicitation as consequential.

Keywords: contingent valuation, mechanism design, field experiment, flood protection

JEL classification: H41, Q51, C93

Page 3: Alternative Value Elicitation Formats in Contingent ...cvossler/files/Alternative CV mechanisms (accepted).pdfformat, we hope to identify ways to improve survey design as well as enhance

1

1. Introduction

Though stated preference surveys remain a standard approach for estimating values for

public goods in the context of government cost-benefit analysis and in litigation over damages to

natural resources, no consensus has been reached over a large number of important design

issues.1 Perhaps the most central issue is the choice over methods for eliciting Hicksian welfare

measures. Dating back to at least the report of the US National Oceanic and Atmospheric

Administration Blue Ribbon Panel (Arrow et al., 1993), a single binary choice (SBC) question

framed as an advisory referendum has been viewed as the industry standard. This guidance was

reaffirmed recently by Johnston et al. (2017), who provide best practice recommendations for

stated preference studies used to inform public decision making. Nevertheless, many alternatives,

such as open-ended (OE) questions, are used in practice.2 Researchers routinely adopt alternative

formats, as they can reduce complications associated with experimental design (e.g. bid design)

and increase the power of the experimental design (e.g. by asking about multiple goods in the

same survey and/or by eliciting more precise information on preferences). However, alternative

value questions are argued to be more complex and unfamiliar to respondents, and are

hypothesized to give rise to strategic, untruthful responses.

A handful of recent papers have used mechanism design theory to establish conditions

under which an SBC elicitation is incentive compatible (Carson and Groves, 2007; Carson,

Groves and List, 2014; Vossler, Doyon and Rondeau, 2012; Vossler and Evans, 2009). This

theory work has motivated refinements in survey design, such as emphasizing that surveys are

inputs to public decision-making in order to incentivize responses. Moreover, since incentive

compatibility pivots on unobserved beliefs, surveys now routinely include questions to measure

1 See Kling, Phaneuf and Zhao (2012) for a thoughtful discussion of accumulated evidence on contingent valuation. 2 We refer to any format other than a SBC elicitation as an “alternative” format.

Page 4: Alternative Value Elicitation Formats in Contingent ...cvossler/files/Alternative CV mechanisms (accepted).pdfformat, we hope to identify ways to improve survey design as well as enhance

2

these beliefs. That theory is important to contingent valuation is further emphasized by empirical

evidence. For instance, enhancing beliefs over policy consequences has been shown to increase

construct validity (Herriges et al., 2010), predictions from theory are supported by controlled

experiments (Carson et al., 2014), and evidence from field tests suggests that external validity

can pivot on whether theoretical assumptions appear to hold (Vossler and Watson, 2013).

Johnston et al. (2017) strongly recommend the use of incentive-compatible response formats, and

indicate that the “most straightforward means” to accomplish this is with a SBC question.

In this study, we demonstrate that it is possible to identify conditions under which

alternative elicitation formats are incentive compatible, using as examples OE and payment card

(PC) question formats. In doing so, following in the footsteps of prior research on the SBC

format, we hope to identify ways to improve survey design as well as enhance the validity of

alternative formats. In the context of a flood control policy for New York City (NYC), we

develop survey elicitation mechanisms informed by the theory, and test for convergent validity

through comparisons with parallel SBC elicitations. As an important counterfactual, we include

in the experimental design a “standard” OE elicitation that better resembles current practice.

Alternative formats face at least two incentive challenges related to SBC. First, as in

market settings, e.g. when purchasing a car, a participant may believe that her response can

influence the price paid for the good thus incentivizing her to under-reveal demand. This is not

only true for an OE elicitation, but other formats that present respondents with more than one

possible cost. The second challenge stems from the lack of an implementation rule. Although an

explicit rule is largely absent in SBC applications, it is natural for respondents in this familiar

setting to believe that (if anything) a response in favor will increase the chance of

implementation. In contrast, implementation rules that would seem natural for alternative

Page 5: Alternative Value Elicitation Formats in Contingent ...cvossler/files/Alternative CV mechanisms (accepted).pdfformat, we hope to identify ways to improve survey design as well as enhance

3

elicitation formats can give rise to untruthful responses. For example, as discussed by Carson and

Groves (2007), respondents to an OE question may believe that the chance a policy is

implemented increases with the sum (or average) of stated valuations. Thus, if the respondent

believes that the cost to her is fixed, but her true valuation is less than the expected cost, the

optimal response to an OE question is to state zero. To overcome these issues in theory, we

assume that the respondent believes her stated valuation will be interpreted as a yes or no vote to

the proposed policy at the actual cost, which is unknown to the respondent when taking the

survey and determined exogenously. The basic logic of using an uncertain and exogenous price

stems from the Becker-DeGroot-Marschak (BDM) mechanism (Becker, DeGroot and Marschak,

1964) and the random price voting mechanism (RPVM) of Messer et al. (2010), which elicit

continuous responses (bids) for private and public goods, respectively.

The theory, in turn, provides new insight for survey design. Indeed, standard OE and PC

implementations are very unlikely to adhere to theory stipulations for incentive compatibility, as

highlighted above. In the context of a valuing a proposed flood control policy for NYC, we

develop theory-driven OE and PC formats, which emphasize cost uncertainty and suggest the

possible interpretation of responses as yes or no votes. Our designs further include a coercive

payment vehicle and frame the elicitation as an advisory referendum. Some prior studies utilizing

PC or OE elicitations have incorporated one or both features, but they are not systematically

included by practitioners or in the academic literature.

As primary evidence on the theory-driven mechanisms, we implement two

complementary field survey experiments. In the first, we use a split-sample approach to test for

convergent validity between our theory-informed PC and a parallel SBC mechanism. We find

that, consistent with prior comparisons involving PCs, SBC values are statistically higher (see

Page 6: Alternative Value Elicitation Formats in Contingent ...cvossler/files/Alternative CV mechanisms (accepted).pdfformat, we hope to identify ways to improve survey design as well as enhance

4

Champ and Bishop, 2006). In a second experiment, we compare a theory-driven OE mechanism

with SBC. As a third treatment in this experiment, designed to provide an indication of whether

the modifications we propose matter empirically, we include a more standard OE elicitation.

Interestingly, we find that mean WTP from the SBC treatment is statistically higher than with the

standard OE question, but statistical equivalence between SBC and our theory-informed OE

mechanism. The frequency of zeroes is much lower in the theory-driven elicitation, which

provides suggestive evidence that the zero-response strategies discussed by Carson and Groves

(2007) may have been dampened by survey refinement. The above results are robust to the

inclusion/exclusion of control variables, including whether respondents indicated beliefs

consistent with both payment and policy consequentiality, which coincide with incentive

compatibility assumptions.

Taking an appropriately designed SBC elicitation as a yardstick from which to measure

alternative elicitation approaches, our results for the OE elicitation support the notion that

truthful demand revelation using OE questions pivots on whether theory-based enhancements are

implemented. The results for the PC suggest that convergent validity is rejected. Although

additional work is needed to decipher the drivers of the result, it is possible that individuals form

values based on the list of possible payment amounts included on the PC. Further, the PC

elicitation produces an interval-censored signal of willingness-to-pay (WTP), which gives rise to

speculation over how responses will be interpreted should the (exogenous) cost fall within this

interval; as a result, the assumptions for incentive compatibility are stronger relative to OE, and

may have been violated in practice.

The valuation of flood protection measures is important in its own right. Climate change

is predicted to alter the frequency and severity of flood events. While equity issues surrounding

Page 7: Alternative Value Elicitation Formats in Contingent ...cvossler/files/Alternative CV mechanisms (accepted).pdfformat, we hope to identify ways to improve survey design as well as enhance

5

paying for climate change adaptation have been the subject of some attention in the literature

(Bichard and Kazmierczak, 2012), the WTP for adaptation remains unclear. We take advantage

of detailed flood maps and parcel-level data to identify households within and just beyond the

100-year flood plain to evaluate how WTP varies with exposure to flood risk.

Our results suggest that the WTP for flood control systems varies markedly with risk.

Households just outside the 100-year flood plain are willing to pay significantly less (half as

much) to install a flood control system in the city. We further find that factors correlated with

actual or perceived attitudes towards risk (e.g., whether the household has flood insurance)

influence WTP in expected ways. These results complement those found in a related literature

that focuses on estimating the WTP for flood insurance (see Botzen and van den Bergh, 2012a,

2012b).

2. Theoretical framework

In this section, we discuss the incentives facing respondents to OE and PC questions, and

identify a set of conditions that as a group are sufficient to establish the incentive compatibility

of the elicitations. Similar to prior mechanism design work in this area, embedded in these

conditions are beliefs assumed to be held by respondents in terms of how responses will be

interpreted, aggregated and used in the context of public decision making. While we can

speculate on the reasonableness of these beliefs, there are of course challenges to identifying

whether they hold in practice or whether they are important empirical drivers of stated

preferences.

In our analysis we build upon the conditions proposed by Carson and Groves (2007) for

an SBC elicitation, and later formalized and expanded upon by Vossler and Evans (2009),

Page 8: Alternative Value Elicitation Formats in Contingent ...cvossler/files/Alternative CV mechanisms (accepted).pdfformat, we hope to identify ways to improve survey design as well as enhance

6

Vossler, Doyon and Rondeau (2012) and Carson, Groves and List (2014). Proceeding in this

fashion allows us to highlight differences across formats. These conditions are as follows:3, 4

(i) the participants care about the outcome;

(ii) the authority can enforce payments by voters;

(iii) the elicitation involves a yes or no vote on a single project, which relates to the

implementation of a single possible policy that is identical to the project; and

(iv) the probability that the proposed project is implemented is weakly monotonically

increasing with the proportion of yes votes.

Briefly, condition (i) rules out indifference, which presumably would be an issue for

predicting responses to any elicitation mechanism. Condition (ii) suggests that respondents

consider both the potential benefits and costs of the policy when formulating votes. This

assumption is clearly violated for voluntary contributions mechanisms. We refer to an elicitation

that meets this condition as maintaining “payment consequentiality”. Condition (iii) restricts the

survey elicitation to a SBC vote, and requires that the proposal described in the survey must only

influence whether an identically defined policy is implemented. As a possible violation of this, as

supported by some empirical evidence and analyzed theoretically by Flores and Strong (2007),

respondents may perceive that the actual cost to them would be higher or lower than the stated

cost. Condition (iv) requires the respondent to have a positive subjective probability that her vote

will be pivotal to the outcome. In other words, the voter needs to envision that at least one

possible scenario exists where her vote will matter, considering the possible distributions of

3 These conditions are identical to those in Vossler, Doyon and Rondeau (2012), with the exception of (iii) which is

expanded upon for clarity. 4 For our purpose, the use of the term “voter” here refers to a respondent who participants in the advisory survey

referendum.

Page 9: Alternative Value Elicitation Formats in Contingent ...cvossler/files/Alternative CV mechanisms (accepted).pdfformat, we hope to identify ways to improve survey design as well as enhance

7

votes from others and possible ways in which votes translate into a policy decision. We will refer

to an elicitation that meets this condition as maintaining “policy consequentiality”.

A. Incentive compatibility of open ended questions

The BDM mechanism and RPVM are continuous, revealed preference response formats

that are incentive compatible under expected utility. For either mechanism, the actual cost of the

good is based on an exogenous process, implemented after respondents submit their bid for the

good. For the BDM, if one submits a bid that is less than or equal to the randomly drawn cost,

she purchases the good at this cost; otherwise, no purchase is made. For the RPVM, bids from a

group of voters are converted into yes and no votes (based on whether the bid is higher or lower

than the cost), and a majority-vote rule determines provision. In what follows, we apply similar

logic to OE, stated preference questions.

Let 𝑐 denote the cost of providing the public good, as perceived by voter, and let her true

valuation be denoted by 𝑣. The utility from the policy is then 𝑈(𝑣 − 𝑐). As the voter is not given

precise information on cost, to her 𝑐 is a random variable described by a density function 𝑓(𝑐)

with positive density over the interval [𝑐𝑚𝑖𝑛, 𝑐𝑚𝑎𝑥].5 If the elicitation is policy consequential,

then voter 𝑖’s stated preference, 𝑠𝑖, can influence the probability that a policy is implemented.

Let 𝑃(𝑠𝑖, 𝒔−𝑖; 𝐺) denote the probability that a policy is implemented, with 𝑃 increasing in 𝑠𝑖. The

vector 𝒔−𝑖 denotes the stated preferences of other voters and 𝐺 represents nuances of the policy

process, including policymaker preferences and decision rules. With the expected utility

framework, the voter wishes to maximize:

5 It is uncommon for studies that use an OE or PC format to provide information on cost. Even with an explicit cost,

as in a standard SBC elicitation with a coercive payment mechanism, respondents may nevertheless have uncertainty

over the actual cost they may pay.

Page 10: Alternative Value Elicitation Formats in Contingent ...cvossler/files/Alternative CV mechanisms (accepted).pdfformat, we hope to identify ways to improve survey design as well as enhance

8

(1) 𝐸𝑈(𝑠𝑖) = ∫ [𝑃(𝑠𝑖, 𝒔−𝑖; 𝐺) 𝑈(𝑣 − 𝑐) + (1 − 𝑃(𝑠𝑖, 𝒔−𝑖; 𝐺) )𝑈(0)]𝑓(𝑐)𝑑𝑐𝑐𝑚𝑎𝑥

𝑐𝑚𝑖𝑛 .

If a voter perceives her response will influence the particular cost paid upon

implementation, in which case 𝑐 ≡ 𝑐(𝑠𝑖), a tension arises. In particular, as long as 𝑠𝑖 < 𝑣,

increasing 𝑠𝑖 can increase the chance a desirable policy is implemented (i.e. one where 𝑣 > 𝑐)

while also increasing the cost paid conditional on the policy being implemented. This tension can

easily result in a loss of incentive compatibility, including cases where 𝑠𝑖 = 0 is an optimal

response when 𝑣 > 0.

With cost uncertainty, voters may perceive there to be a set of policies under possible

consideration, which correspond to the proposal described in the advisory referendum but that

vary in terms of their cost. Following the logic of the BDM and RPVM, incentive compatibility

is possible if the voter believes that the cost is exogenous to her stated valuation. Formally, we

provide an alternative to condition (iii):

(iii´) the open-ended response 𝑠 is interpreted as a vote on a single policy, consisting of

non-cost attributes as described in the survey and a cost 𝑐 determined

exogenously from 𝑠. That 𝑠 ≥ 𝑐 (𝑠 < 𝑐) signals a yes (no) vote.

Condition (iii´) eliminates 𝑠 as a determinant of 𝑐, and from an ex ante perspective maps the OE

response into a continuum of binary choices on possible policies uniquely defined by their cost.

Ex post, the OE response is a single yes or no vote for one policy defined by the exogenously

determined cost. Condition (iii´) is unlikely to hold in standard OE applications where little or no

information is given on the cost of the policy nor how responses would be interpreted. However,

beliefs consonant with (iii´) may arise with information provision, in particular that cost is not

known with certainty, and that cost would be the actual cost of implementing the project and not

Page 11: Alternative Value Elicitation Formats in Contingent ...cvossler/files/Alternative CV mechanisms (accepted).pdfformat, we hope to identify ways to improve survey design as well as enhance

9

based on stated valuations. Relaying uncertainty over cost further provides a rationale for

eliciting a continuous response as a means of having available relevant preference information in

the event uncertainty is later resolved and the policy is considered seriously by authorities. In

turn, such information provision has the potential to prevent the onset of undesirable beliefs on

the part of OE respondents. We now provide a proof of the incentive compatibility of OE

questions.

PROPOSITION: An OE question is incentive compatible if conditions (i), (ii), (iii´) and (iv)

hold.

PROOF:

With OE responses interpreted as yes and no votes for any given cost, we can define the

implementation probability as a function of the number of yes votes. Let 𝑃(1{𝑐≤𝑠𝑖} +

∑ 1{𝑐≤𝑠𝑗}𝑗≠𝑖 ; 𝐺) denote the probability that the policy is implemented, where 1{𝑐≤𝑠𝑖} is an

indicator function that equals 1 when 𝑐 ≤ 𝑠𝑖. Then, we can write 𝑃1(1 + ∑ 1{𝑐<𝑠𝑗}𝑗=𝑖 ; 𝐺) for 𝑐 ≤

𝑠𝑖 and 𝑃0(∑ 1{𝑐≤𝑠𝑗}𝑗≠𝑖 ; 𝐺) for 𝑐 > 𝑠𝑖. It follows from condition (iv) that 𝑃1 ≥ 𝑃0. We can then

write the expected utility of the voter as:

(2) 𝐸𝑈(𝑠𝑖) = 1{𝑐≤𝑠𝑖} ∫ [𝑃1(𝑈(𝑣 − 𝑐) + 𝑈(0)) + 𝑈(0)]𝑓(𝑐)𝑑𝑐𝑐𝑚𝑎𝑥

𝑐𝑚𝑖𝑛

+ (1 − 1{𝑐≤𝑠𝑖}) ∫ [𝑃0(𝑈(𝑣 − 𝑐) + 𝑈(0)) + 𝑈(0)]𝑓(𝑐)𝑑𝑐𝑐𝑚𝑎𝑥

𝑐𝑚𝑖𝑛 .

With expected utility written in this form, it is straightforward to see that the stated preference 𝑠𝑖

determines the range of costs for which the voter increases or decreases the implementation

probability.

Page 12: Alternative Value Elicitation Formats in Contingent ...cvossler/files/Alternative CV mechanisms (accepted).pdfformat, we hope to identify ways to improve survey design as well as enhance

10

The proof proceeds by considering deviations from the truthful strategy 𝑠𝑖 = 𝑣. Consider

first a strategy 𝑠𝑖 < 𝑣. From (2), expected utility is increasing in 𝑠𝑖 over the interval [𝑐𝑚𝑖𝑛, 𝑣].

This is because an increase in 𝑠𝑖 increases the probability that a desirable policy, one with

𝑈(𝑣 − 𝑐) ≥ 0, is implemented. Therefore, the deviation decreases expected utility. Consider

instead a strategy 𝑠𝑖 > 𝑣. Expected utility is decreasing in 𝑠𝑖 over the interval (𝑣, 𝑐𝑚𝑎𝑥]. An

increase in 𝑠𝑖 beyond 𝑣 increases the probability that an undesirable policy, where 𝑈(𝑣 − 𝑐) < 0,

is implemented. Therefore, this deviation decreases expected utility. As long as 𝑐𝑚𝑖𝑛 < 𝑣 <

𝑐𝑚𝑎𝑥, it follows that deviating from the strategy 𝑠𝑖 = 𝑣 decreases expected utility. Therefore

𝑠𝑖 = 𝑣 is a weakly dominant strategy.

An interior solution requires that the voter perceives there to be a chance the actual cost

of the policy is equal to her valuation. This may not hold for certain projects if the voter has a

very low or very high valuation and/or well-defined beliefs over the cost distribution. If 𝑣 >

𝑐𝑚𝑎𝑥 , in which case 𝑓(𝑣) = 0, the voter is indifferent between stating any value in the range

[𝑐𝑚𝑎𝑥 , 𝑣] as they all yield the same expected utility. Otherwise, if 𝑣 < 𝑐𝑚𝑖𝑛 , the voter is

indifferent between stating any value in the range [𝑣, 𝑐𝑚𝑖𝑛].

B. Incentive compatibility of payment card questions

A PC lists a set of possible cost amounts and, depending on the form of the PC, the

respondent is asked to indicate (yes or no) whether she is willing to pay each cost or instead

asked to circle the highest amount she would be willing to pay. Regardless of the form of the PC,

one can interpret the response(s) as a set of yes or no votes on possible policies characterized by

the non-cost attributes described in the survey and uniquely defined by cost. Let 𝑐1, 𝑐2, … , 𝑐𝑁

denote listed PC cost amounts, rank-ordered from lowest to highest. Further, let the stated

Page 13: Alternative Value Elicitation Formats in Contingent ...cvossler/files/Alternative CV mechanisms (accepted).pdfformat, we hope to identify ways to improve survey design as well as enhance

11

preference 𝑠 = 𝑐𝑛 denote that the voter indicates a no vote to 𝑐𝑛+1, 𝑐𝑛+2, … , 𝑐𝑁 and a yes vote to

𝑐1, 𝑐2, … , 𝑐𝑛. Given the voter’s true valuation, 𝑣, denote as 𝑐𝑣 the cost which bounds from below

the true valuation such that 𝑐𝑣 ≤ 𝑣 < 𝑐𝑣+1. For a PC mechanism to be incentive compatible, it

must incentivize the voter to indicate 𝑠 = 𝑐𝑣.

For the stated preference 𝑠 = 𝑐𝑛, it is reasonable to believe that any cost for which 𝑐 ≥

𝑐𝑛+1, including those not listed on the PC, will be interpreted as a no vote, and for any cost 𝑐 ≤

𝑐𝑛 this will become a yes vote. This is consistent with the voter’s stated preferences. For costs in

the interval 𝑐𝑛 < 𝑐 < 𝑐𝑛+1, a complexity arises that is not present in the OE elicitation.

Depending on the density 𝑓(𝑐) and how the PC response may be translated into a vote, it is

possible for 𝑠 = 𝑐𝑣, 𝑠 = 𝑐𝑣−1 or 𝑠 = 𝑐𝑣+1 to be an optimal response. In other words, the voter

may under or over-reveal demand.

To see this, suppose that the voter who responds truthfully with 𝑠 = 𝑐𝑣 believes that for

any cost in the interval (𝑐𝑣, 𝑐𝑣+1), her response will be interpreted as a no vote. The voter should

instead indicate 𝑠 = 𝑐𝑣+1 if the expected losses over the interval (𝑣, 𝑐𝑣+1] are less than the

expected gains over the interval (𝑐𝑣, 𝑣). This would occur if 𝑣 is sufficiently close to 𝑐𝑣+1.

Otherwise, she should indicate 𝑠 = 𝑐𝑣. At the other extreme, the voter may perceive that for any

cost in the interval (𝑐𝑣, 𝑐𝑣+1), her response 𝑠 = 𝑐𝑣 will be interpreted as a yes vote. In the case

that 𝑣 is sufficiently close to 𝑐𝑣, she is better-off voting 𝑠 = 𝑐𝑣−1. By doing so, she only votes

yes when 𝑐 < 𝑐𝑣 and avoids voting yes for any cost in the interval (𝑣, 𝑐𝑣+1) which would yield

expected losses. Otherwise, if 𝑣 is sufficiently close to 𝑐𝑣, she is better-off voting truthfully.

As another possibility, a voter who states 𝑠 = 𝑐𝑣 may speculate that her stated preference

will simply be ignored over the interval (𝑐𝑣, 𝑐𝑣+1). This too can result in a loss of incentive

compatibility. If, for instance, 𝑣 is sufficiently close to 𝑐𝑣+1 the voter may want to instead vote

Page 14: Alternative Value Elicitation Formats in Contingent ...cvossler/files/Alternative CV mechanisms (accepted).pdfformat, we hope to identify ways to improve survey design as well as enhance

12

𝑠 = 𝑐𝑣+1 so that she can help increase the probability a policy defined by a cost in this range is

implemented. In doing so, her vote would then be ignored if 𝑐𝑣+1 < 𝑐 < 𝑐𝑣+2. Nevertheless,

holding fixed her perceived influence over outcomes across these cost intervals, if the voter

perceives that the actual cost of the policy is much more likely to fall in the interval (𝑐𝑣, 𝑐𝑣+1)

than in the interval (𝑐𝑣+1, 𝑐𝑣+2) she would be willing to make this tradeoff.

Given the complications above, we need to place restrictions on 𝑓(𝑐) for a PC elicitation

to be incentive compatible. One possibility is to assume 𝑓(𝑐) = 0 for 𝑐𝑣 < 𝑐 < 𝑐𝑣+1. This

assumption renders moot the undesirable effects of the speculations described above. For costs

outside of this interval, the PC response is then interpreted identically to that of an OE response,

and the Proposition applies. This assumption may be reasonable if, given the complexity of the

decision task, voters do not even speculate over “what if” scenarios in the event that 𝑐𝑣 < 𝑐 <

𝑐𝑣+1. As another possibility, voters may believe that if the actual cost falls between 𝑐𝑣 and 𝑐𝑣+1,

or any two amounts listed on the PC for that matter, authorities will simply adjust the cost up or

down to equal one of the listed amounts prior to interpreting responses. In practice, policymakers

may be naturally inclined to avoid fractional costs, and amounts listed on PCs tend to represent

focal points such as $10 and $25. If the process by which authorities adjust costs is exogenous to

valuations, this in and of itself does not lead to a loss in incentive compatibility.

3. Survey description and experimental design

A. Background

On October 29, 2012, Hurricane Sandy hit the northeastern U.S. coastline. Based on

storm surge predictions, mandatory evacuations were ordered on October 28, including for

NYC’s Evacuation Zone A, the coastal zone at risk for flooding from any hurricane. By October

Page 15: Alternative Value Elicitation Formats in Contingent ...cvossler/files/Alternative CV mechanisms (accepted).pdfformat, we hope to identify ways to improve survey design as well as enhance

13

31, the region had 6 to12 inches of precipitation, 7 to 8 million customers without power and

approximately 20,000 persons in shelters. According to mortality tracking by the American Red

Cross, there were 117 Sandy-related deaths, with nearly 75% of deaths occurring in New York

and New Jersey.

In December 2012, Mayor Bloomberg launched the Special Initiative for Rebuilding and

Resiliency and charged it with recommending steps the city should take to protect against the

impacts of climate change. This culminated into the June 11, 2013 report “A Stronger, More

Resilient New York” (NYC Special Initiative for Rebuilding and Resiliency, 2013), which

provides recommendations for protecting neighborhoods and infrastructure from future climate

events. Chapter 3 of the report is a Coastal Protection Plan for NYC, which forms the basis of the

flood protection proposal described in our survey.

B. Description of survey

The development of the survey was informed by extensive pretesting with focus groups

convened at New York University, and under consultation with flood insurance experts and

academics. Based on this information, we implemented as a pilot the theory-driven PC, using

cost amounts of $1, $2, $3, $5, $7, $10, $15, $20, $25, $35, $50, $70 and $100. The pilot utilized

just over 5% of our sample frame in the high-risk flood zone. Nearly one-quarter of pilot

respondents indicated a WTP of less than $1, and fewer than 3% indicated they were willing to

pay more than $50 per month. Based on these results, in the subsequent PC and SBC bid designs

we included a lower cost amount (50 cents), and omitted an intermediate amount ($25) and the

two highest amounts.

Page 16: Alternative Value Elicitation Formats in Contingent ...cvossler/files/Alternative CV mechanisms (accepted).pdfformat, we hope to identify ways to improve survey design as well as enhance

14

The introduction to the survey emphasized the potential policy consequences of the

survey, by relaying that the results will be used to inform policymakers about the opinions of

NYC residents, and that results will be distributed to NYC’s Department of Environmental

Protection, FEMA and other agencies interested in coastal flooding in NYC and elsewhere.

After agreeing to participate, respondents were asked a series of questions about their home,

insurance coverage and then presented with a flood protection proposal.

The flood protection proposal, consistent with the city’s proposed plan, described the

construction of flood control measures including raised berms and deployable seawalls. To

provide context for these systems we included in the survey the images displayed in Figure 1.

We emphasized that while the images show particular places in the city, the flood control

measures would be deployed “in the areas of the city most at risk of flooding”. The payment

vehicle chosen was the household water bill, and the proposal involved an additional monthly fee

on the water bill to recover construction and maintenance costs.

Following the proposal, an advisory referendum was described. This description

necessarily varies across experimental treatments, and we provide the details in the next

subsection. Respondents are reminded of their budget constraint, and the included language

emphasizes the “advisory” nature of the survey and that results may or may not be taken into

consideration by authorities.6 The value elicitation question is framed as a vote for all treatments,

with minimal adjustments in language made to accommodate the different question formats.

Follow-up questions to the value elicitation were included to probe respondents about the

reasons underlying their decision(s), and, measured using Likert-scales, beliefs regarding both

6 To promote beliefs over policy consequentiality, an ideal experiment setting is one where authorities pre-commit to

using stated preferences in the decision process in a transparent way. However, this does not reflect the political

reality surrounding the vast majority of stated preference studies.

Page 17: Alternative Value Elicitation Formats in Contingent ...cvossler/files/Alternative CV mechanisms (accepted).pdfformat, we hope to identify ways to improve survey design as well as enhance

15

policy and payment consequentiality. After the valuation exercise, respondents participated in an

experiment where they were induced to search for flood insurance through a randomly presented

subsidy. This aspect of the survey required using the online software to dynamically respond to

home ownership and flood insurance status.7 For this reason, all respondents were required to use

the online survey, and no mail version of the survey was available. Finally, respondents

participated in a risk preference elicitation and answered some demographic questions.

C. Experiment treatments

The main objective of the field experiments is to provide primary empirical evidence on

theory-driven implementations of the PC and OE value elicitation questions. In an ideal world,

we would be able to compare the different formats with a parallel measure that reflects actual

demand. This is not possible for our application as the policy we analyze was merely in the

proposal stage. Further, the large scale of the proposed flood control system prevents the use of

experimental methods to devise an appropriate revealed preference benchmark. As a commonly

used alternative, we include a SBC elicitation in our experimental design. Field validity tests that

compare SBC surveys and parallel public referenda involving local environmental policies

suggest a close correspondence (e.g., Johnston, 2006; Vossler and Watson, 2013).

Taking as given the inclusion of a SBC elicitation as a treatment, the design is further

motivated by the question of whether the theory-driven enhancements matter empirically. There

are many differences between theory-driven mechanisms we develop and common

implementations. Importantly, the theory-driven mechanisms (a) introduce cost uncertainty, (b)

suggest that cost is exogenous to stated valuations, (c) suggest one way in which responses may

7 Results of that experiment will be presented in a separate study.

Page 18: Alternative Value Elicitation Formats in Contingent ...cvossler/files/Alternative CV mechanisms (accepted).pdfformat, we hope to identify ways to improve survey design as well as enhance

16

be interpreted, and (d) include in the proposal that the cost is the same across households, and

that money collected would only go towards the proposed project. Our theory-driven versions

also use a coercive payment vehicle and frame the elicitation as an advisory referendum.

Although most recent CV surveys utilizing continuous response formats do not include either of

the latter two features, their use is consistent with NOAA Panel recommendations, and there are

now examples in the literature of studies with one or both of these attributes.

To address fully the research questions as presented above requires myriad treatments. As

we were limited by sample size and budget, we instead converged on a smaller design that we

view as a starting point to addressing the questions posed. There are five treatments,

implemented across two experiments. In Experiment 1, we compare what we label as a theory-

driven PC format with a SBC format. To yield an informative comparison, the SBC format is

also informed by mechanism design theory. Thus, the experiment allows for a test of convergent

validity between SBC and PC formats.

In Experiment 2, which utilizes a different sample, we compare a theory-driven OE

format with SBC to test for convergent validity. The SBC elicitation is identical to that in

Experiment 1. As a third treatment, we include what we label as a standard OE format.

Comparing the two OE formats thus provides insight into whether the alterations we propose are

meaningful in practice. We now highlight the specific ways we used the theory to inform our

survey design.

Theory-driven OE format

The theory assumptions presented in Section 2 highlight that respondents must hold

specific beliefs regarding how cost would be determined and how responses might be

Page 19: Alternative Value Elicitation Formats in Contingent ...cvossler/files/Alternative CV mechanisms (accepted).pdfformat, we hope to identify ways to improve survey design as well as enhance

17

interpreted. To convey this in the survey, in describing the advisory referendum we state

(Passage 1):

“Given the scope and cost of this project, it is important for us to learn the opinions of

New York City residents. Some people might be willing to pay for these measures while

others might not. At this point, the cost of the proposed flood control system is uncertain.

Until detailed designs are completed and evaluated by engineers and architects, the

monthly fee needed to fund the project is not known for sure. For this reason we are

going to present you with an advisory referendum and ask you to indicate the highest

amount you would be willing to pay for the project. This way, if cost information

becomes available, we will be able to compare the necessary monthly fee with the

amount you (and others) indicate you are willing to pay. We will then be able to know the

percentage in favor and against the proposal at the resulting monthly fee.

Voting results from this study are not binding, but instead are advisory in nature. Results

will be shared with local authorities, and these authorities may or may not take this

information into consideration.

Please consider the advisory referendum below. Keep in mind that the purpose of asking

you to indicate the highest amount you would pay is that, at this time, the fee needed to

fund the project is uncertain. Consider that New York City has over 500 miles of

shoreline. When considering your decision, please bear in mind that there may be other

things that you would rather spend your money on. Think about how much, if anything,

you are willing to pay before entering your decision. In the space below, write in the

highest dollar amount at which you would still vote in favor of the program.”

Thus, the passage suggests that cost is (rightfully) uncertain at this time, uses cost uncertainty to

motivate the value question format, and suggests that responses can be used to determine the

percentage in favor at the realized cost amount. We do not explicitly mention that the local

authorities would use information in this exact manner, as this of course cannot be guaranteed.

We speculate however that by mentioning this possible interpretation that respondents would be

less likely to devise alternative interpretations, importantly including interpretations that would

threaten the incentive compatibility of the elicitation.

Important for the theory is that cost is exogenous to responses. Passage 1 is not definitive

about this, but we emphasized this point through the discussion of the payment mechanism

(Passage 2):

Page 20: Alternative Value Elicitation Formats in Contingent ...cvossler/files/Alternative CV mechanisms (accepted).pdfformat, we hope to identify ways to improve survey design as well as enhance

18

“The seawall would be funded by adding a mandatory fixed fee to every New York City

households’ monthly water bill for the foreseeable future. This fee would be the same for

every household. The Department of Environmental Protection would use the money

only to pay for the construction and maintenance of seawalls.”

Finally, the exact wording of the referendum is as follows:

“What is the highest mandatory fixed fee that City authorities could include on every

New York City households’ monthly water bill, for the foreseeable future, for which you

would still vote in favor of funding the proposed flood control system for New York

City?”

Directly following the referendum, we included the following passage to further emphasize cost

uncertainty and a possible interpretation of the OE responses (Passage 3):

“Remember, the cost of this project is very uncertain at this time, and this is why we are

asking you to indicate the highest amount at which you would still vote in favor. This

way, when the construction and maintenance costs are known, and the necessary monthly

fee is calculated, we will be able to know the percentage in favor and against at this

amount.”

Standard OE format

Relative to the theory-driven OE format, paragraphs 2 and 3 of Passage 1 are included

verbatim, and all but the first, second and sixth sentence of the first paragraph is excluded.

Passage 3 is excluded, and Passage 2 is replaced with a vague description of the payment

vehicle:

“The seawall would be funded with money collected through fees added to New York

City household monthly water bills.”

As such, any differences between the two OE formats may be driven by the presence/absence of

the set of attributes (a) – (d) described above.

Theory-driven PC format

Page 21: Alternative Value Elicitation Formats in Contingent ...cvossler/files/Alternative CV mechanisms (accepted).pdfformat, we hope to identify ways to improve survey design as well as enhance

19

The description of the advisory referendum deviates only slightly from that used for the

theory-driven OE format. Passage 2 from the OE elicitation is included verbatim, with only

slight adjustments to Passage 1 and Passage 3 to account for the different value elicitation

question. Importantly, we present the PC as a series of yes or no votes, as in Bateman et al.

(2005) and Vossler and McKee (2006). This contrasts with the more commonly used PC format,

where respondents are asked to circle the highest amount they would pay. Although this is

merely speculative, framing the PC in this manner may better convey that, upon resolving cost

uncertainty, the votes corresponding to actual cost will be viewed in isolation. This

implementation of the PC also allows for possible “mistakes” in the form of switching from “no”

to “yes” as cost increases, and thus gives rise to anecdotal evidence of whether the elicitation

format is understood. The PC referendum reads:

“Should City authorities introduce a mandatory fixed fee of $_____ to every New York

City households’ monthly water bill, for the foreseeable future, to fund the proposed

flood control system for New York City?”

As discussed previously, a theoretical complication arises because the PC elicits an interval-

censored response. Although we could have, for instance, indicated that only those listed costs

are probable, such a statement presumably would not be viewed as credible.

SBC format

We include a SBC elicitation that follows conditions (i) – (iv) presented in Section 2.

Passage 2 is included verbatim, and there is no discussion of cost uncertainty. The advisory

referendum is worded as for the PC, with the exception that a randomly selected cost amount is

presented (rather than a blank). In particular, one of the 11 cost amounts included in the PC is

selected, with equal probability.

D. Survey Samples

Page 22: Alternative Value Elicitation Formats in Contingent ...cvossler/files/Alternative CV mechanisms (accepted).pdfformat, we hope to identify ways to improve survey design as well as enhance

20

We constructed a sample of households living in and near the 100-year flood plain using

data from FEMA Flood Insurance Rate Maps (FIRMs) and New York City’s Primary Land Use

Tax Lot Output (PLUTO) database. FIRMs are created using detailed hydrological and

topographical studies. FEMA uses FIRMs to delineate officially the flood risk zones nationwide.

FEMA provides digital versions of these maps suitable for mapping in Geographic Information

Systems through the National Flood Hazard Layer.

To identify households, we employed New York City’s PLUTO database. PLUTO

contains New York City Assessor’s data for each parcel in the city as well detailed latitude and

longitude data. Using a Geographic Information System, we mapped each NYC parcel to a

FEMA flood zone. The parcel data also include a rich set of information about the parcel and

structures including structure type, assessed value, square footage, number of floors and whether

the structure has a basement. We employ this data to confirm our randomization of treatments

was effective and to identify heterogeneity in elicited values.

We restrict our sample frame to single family residences in New York City for two

reasons.8 First, in the survey the payment vehicle is a fee in the household water bill. Households

in single family residences (owner or renter occupied) typically pay their own water bill while

many residents in multifamily buildings have their water, oil and electric bills folded into their

rent or paid through some type of collective assessment. Additionally, the assessor’s data

includes the parcel address, but very limited information on the number of units in multifamily

dwellings, and no apartment numbers, making it difficult to reach these households by mail.

8 We identify single family households by restricting our sample to parcels with ownership type “P” or null in the

PLUTO data. The majority of records in PLUTO are blank and the documentation states that null indicates

“Unknown (Usually Private Ownership)”. To assure that we have restricted the sample to single family homes we

also include only parcels with Building Class Codes beginning with “A”, which signifies “One Family Dwellings”.

Page 23: Alternative Value Elicitation Formats in Contingent ...cvossler/files/Alternative CV mechanisms (accepted).pdfformat, we hope to identify ways to improve survey design as well as enhance

21

Table 1 summarizes the number of single family households in our data by flood zone

and NYC borough. Just over one-third of the parcels in the city are single family dwellings and

only four percent of parcels are in the 100-year flood plain. Relative to the number of tax parcels

in the city our flood plain sample has more parcels in Staten Island and the Bronx is

underrepresented.

Each of the 13,342 single family households in the high-risk zone were selected into the

sample for Experiment 1. We also used GIS to identify parcels that lived within 500 meters

beyond the 100-year flood zone boundary, which generated an additional set of just over 23,500

households. Of these, 12,000 were randomly selected to be included in the sample for

Experiment 2. These households, as well as much of the rest of the city are inside the 500-meter

buffer zone. Figure 2 maps the high-risk flood plain across the city.

In the summer and fall of 2015, selected households were sent a letter inviting them to

direct their web browser to a specific URL and complete the survey. Each letter included a

unique four-character code that allows us to map survey responses to assessor’s data and flood

zones. The PLUTO extract includes the name of the parcel owner according to tax documents,

but we cannot be certain which households are owner occupied and which are rentals. There are

also some concerns that the owner name field might not be updated in our extract of the

assessor’s data. For this reason, each mailing is addressed to “Flood Zone Resident”. Upon

accessing the survey website respondents are provided information on the study and prompted to

enter their unique access code. The survey itself was created and hosted in Qualtrics, an online

survey software suite. The survey was presented in eight sequential pages and took an average of

just over ten minutes to complete. After completing a page, respondents clicked on a button and

were unable to return. Respondents were asked in which flood zone their home was located, but

Page 24: Alternative Value Elicitation Formats in Contingent ...cvossler/files/Alternative CV mechanisms (accepted).pdfformat, we hope to identify ways to improve survey design as well as enhance

22

they were not told their flood zone (as mapped using the FEMA flood maps and PLUTO data)

until after completing the value elicitation exercise.

Ten days after sending the initial letter a follow-up post card was sent to all households

who had not yet responded. A final reminder was sent one week later, and households were

informed that we would not contact them further.9 The letter and each of the follow up post cards

reminded households that ten respondents would be randomly selected to receive a $100 gift

card. To minimize mailing processing fees, the two samples were surveyed approximately one

month apart.

Across the two experiments we mailed 24,640 letters and received 1,719 complete

responses for a response rate of 7%. For the households in the 100-year flood plain we mailed

12,640 letters of which 88 were returned as undeliverable. The mailings led to 1,128 surveys

being started and 900 completed, for a dropout rate of just over 20%. In the second experiment

we randomly selected 12,000 households living within 500 meters of the 100-year flood plain to

recruit by mail. Only 15 of those letters were returned as undeliverable. 1,019 respondents began

the survey and 819 completed it, for a dropout rate of 20%.

To gain insight on possible differences due to sample self-selection, we make use of the

PLUTO database. Table 2 compares means of key variables from the assessors’ data on housing

characteristics across respondents and non-respondents. Across house size, age, renovation

status, renovation year and the assessed value of the lot and total structure, the two groups are

nearly identical. Unfortunately, no available data source describes other socio-economic

characteristics such as income and education specific to our targeted population.10 While we

9 Anonymized versions of the initial letter and the reminder post cards appear in the appendix. 10 Census data on income, household size and education are not available for only single-family residences and

Census tracts do not line up well with the high-risk zone.

Page 25: Alternative Value Elicitation Formats in Contingent ...cvossler/files/Alternative CV mechanisms (accepted).pdfformat, we hope to identify ways to improve survey design as well as enhance

23

cannot rule out that characteristics of respondents differ based on observable or unobservable

factors, the survey respondent homes look remarkably like the homes of those who chose not to

respond.

4. Results

In this section we describe the results of our two experiments. We begin by describing the

data. We follow this with a formal econometric analysis of WTP, with a focus on testing not only

convergent validity but on assessing the extent to which theory is important for stated

preferences.

Table 3 describes information on our respondents, using both assessor’s data and survey

data, for Experiment 1. Table 4 provides parallel data for Experiment 2. As evident from

summary statistics, the respondents were properly randomized into treatments within each

experiment. The main difference across the two experiment samples is that a higher proportion

of the Experiment 1 sample has flood insurance, experienced property damage from Hurricane

Sandy and were forced to evacuate. Of course, this is to be expected given these respondents are

in the 100-year flood plain.

Mortgage lenders typically require flood insurance on properties in the 100-year flood

plain. This protects the value of their collateral in the event of a major flood. In the high-risk

flood plain the average premium is over $3,000 a year and prices vary from house to house based

on risk (Dixon et al., 2017). Many policies require a surveyor to provide detailed elevation data.

Outside the 100-year flood plain, coverage is typically optional even for mortgage holders,

relatively low cost and can be priced simply by entering an address and coverage level into an

online form.

Page 26: Alternative Value Elicitation Formats in Contingent ...cvossler/files/Alternative CV mechanisms (accepted).pdfformat, we hope to identify ways to improve survey design as well as enhance

24

Table 5 presents the raw proportion of Experiment 1 respondents indicating a yes vote

across the possible cost amounts included in the survey.11 At a cost of fifty cents 68% of PC

respondents vote yes. A handful of those respondents then stopped filling out the payment card.

Beyond 50 cents, the survival function for the PC is monotonically decreasing, with 69% of

respondents voting yes at $1 per month and 6% for $50. Percentages for the SBC treatment vary

from a high of 86% at a cost of $2 per month to a low of 28% at $50 per month. Although the

percentage of yes votes, as expected, is generally decreasing with cost, this relationship is not

monotonic. Each probability is based on a different random sample, however, and so violating

monotonicity is somewhat expected. This is especially true given our bid design, which included

many small dollar amounts with little separation between them.12

The PC and SBC distributions are similar across treatments at lower cost levels, but as

the presented cost rises the proportion of yes votes falls more quickly for the PC. Indeed, for a

range of higher costs there are stark differences of over 20% and 30%.

Table 6 reports the proportion of yes votes in Experiment 2. To compare the OE

distributions with the SBC data we construct empirical survival functions with the raw data and

report the acceptance rates as they correspond with SBC cost levels. The percentage of yes votes

at the lowest cost level varies somewhat by treatment, with the theory-driven OE producing 81%

yes votes, the SBC 75% yes votes, and the standard OE 68% yes votes. The two OE formats

diverge by roughly 10% for low cost amounts, but are similar at costs of $5 and higher. In

examining the raw data, the percentage of reported zero valuations is different: 32% for standard

11 For this table and all subsequent ones, we present the raw data including respondents who provided incomplete

answers to other questions. The only exceptions are regression specifications that include a number of controls for

which there may be missing data for some. 12 We further note that the empirical survival functions for the SBC data in both experiments are better behaved if

the sample is restricted to those indicating consequentiality.

Page 27: Alternative Value Elicitation Formats in Contingent ...cvossler/files/Alternative CV mechanisms (accepted).pdfformat, we hope to identify ways to improve survey design as well as enhance

25

OE, and 19% for theory-driven OE. Using a Fisher exact test, the proportion of zero responses is

statistically different.13 Carson and Groves (2007) argue that, in a handful of cases where

incentive-compatibility is lost, theory predicts OE that respondents will strategically report zero.

As such, this finding provides some suggestive evidence that the theory-driven elicitation may

serve to circumvent strategic zeros. Compared to the OE treatments, the SBC begins with

roughly the same proportion of yes votes, but at the highest costs, the proportions of yes votes

are somewhat higher.

Finally, in Tables 7 − 10 we report the distribution of responses to two follow-up survey

questions, one that targets beliefs tied to policy consequentiality and the other, to payment

consequentiality. Payment consequentiality was elicited using a four-point Likert scale ranging

from “definitely no” to “definitely yes” as to whether participants would have to pay if a flood

control system were built. For the policy consequentiality question, responses were on a five-

point Likert scale ranging from their responses having “no effect” on the probability the flood

control system is built to being “absolutely crucial”.

In Experiment 1, for both consequentiality questions there are similar response

distributions across the SBC and PC treatments. A majority of respondents answered “Maybe

Yes” to the payment consequentiality question. Around 80 percent of respondents in the PC

treatment indicated the elicitation to be at least weakly consequential in both dimensions,

whereas this figure is 75 percent with SBC.

In Experiment 2 the differences in stated consequentiality across treatments are more

pronounced. A majority of respondents still choose “Maybe Yes” as their answer to the payment

consequentiality question in each treatment, but around five percent more respondents answer

13 Unless otherwise noted, in drawing conclusions we use a 5% significance level throughout the analysis.

Page 28: Alternative Value Elicitation Formats in Contingent ...cvossler/files/Alternative CV mechanisms (accepted).pdfformat, we hope to identify ways to improve survey design as well as enhance

26

“Definitely No” for the standard OE elicitation relative to the theory-driven OE. Interestingly, an

important difference arises when we focus on the percentage of respondents indicating at least

weak agreement with both consequentiality questions. These figures are 72% and 69% for SBC

and theory-driven OE formats, respectively, but just 59% for the standard OE. In both pairwise

comparisons, the standard OE treatment yields a statistically different percentage based on Fisher

exact tests. This provides suggestive evidence that the theory enhancements help in fostering

beliefs that are theoretically relevant for truthful demand revelation.

A. Econometric analysis

The data generated from the three types of value questions give rise to continuous, left-

censored, right-censored or interval-censored signals of WTP. As a first-cut at data analysis, we

estimate survival functions based on the nonparametric maximum likelihood estimator of

Turnbull (1976) using the R package “icenReg” (Anderson-Bergman, 2017). The survival

function for OE data is identical to the empirical survival function (i.e. the raw data). For the

SBC data, the estimator imposes monotonicity smoothing out of the function relative to what is

presented in Tables 5 and 6. Using a likelihood ratio test, we soundly reject equality of the PC

and SBC distributions in Experiment 1 (p < 0.01). For Experiment 2, we fail to reject equality of

either OE distribution when compared with SBC, although we reject equality of the two OE

distributions (p < 0.01).

Nonparametric methods have the clear advantage of avoiding distributional assumptions.

However, a rejection does not necessary signal that welfare estimates such as mean and median

WTP differ. Nor does a fail to reject, especially since each distribution is censored, and the

degree of censoring differs across elicitation formats. To facilitate welfare estimation, we turn to

Page 29: Alternative Value Elicitation Formats in Contingent ...cvossler/files/Alternative CV mechanisms (accepted).pdfformat, we hope to identify ways to improve survey design as well as enhance

27

parametric methods. The maximum likelihood estimator we specify, which nests the estimators

of Cameron and James (1987) and Cameron and Huppert (1989), accommodates the different

types of information elicited across question formats in a unified way, and allows for

straightforward tests of treatment effects. The estimation allows for the possibility that some

individuals have negative WTP. This is plausible as, for instance, respondents may experience

disutility due to obstruction of views and modifications to the coastal landscape. As suggestive

evidence that some valuations may be negative, we note again that there are many zeros for the

OE elicitations, and a fair fraction of PC and SBC respondents who vote no to the lowest cost

amount (50 cents).

Let 𝑊𝑇𝑃𝑖 denote respondent 𝑖’s willingness to pay for the proposal. 𝑊𝑇𝑃𝑖 is not directly

observed, except for a subset of OE respondents, but instead can be treated as a censored

dependent variable. For a PC elicitation, we obtain the signal 𝑐𝑖,𝑙 ≤ 𝑊𝑇𝑃𝑖 < 𝑐𝑖,𝑢 where 𝑐𝑖,𝑙 is the

highest cost for which the participant votes yes and 𝑐𝑖,𝑢 is the next highest amount. For the case

where the respondent votes no to the lowest amount, 𝑐𝑖,𝑙 = −∞; similarly, 𝑐𝑖,𝑢 = ∞ if she votes

yes to the highest amount. For a SBC elicitation, we obtain the signal 𝑊𝑇𝑃𝑖 < 𝑐𝑖 if the agent

votes no to the stated cost 𝑐𝑖 and 𝑊𝑇𝑃𝑖 ≥ 𝑐𝑖 for a yes vote. As such, the SBC data represent a

special case of PC data, where 𝑐𝑖 defines only an upper or lower bound on the WTP interval

(e.g., 𝑐𝑖,𝑙 = 𝑐𝑖 and 𝑐𝑖,𝑢 = ∞ for a yes vote). For OE responses, 𝑊𝑇𝑃𝑖 is directly observed, with

the exception of zero valuations, which we interpret to be left-censored to allow for possibly

negative WTP, which is consistent with our treatment of SBC and PC data. These left-censored

observations are accommodated into the PC framework by defining the WTP interval with 𝑐𝑖,𝑙 =

−∞ and 𝑐𝑖,𝑢 = 0.

Page 30: Alternative Value Elicitation Formats in Contingent ...cvossler/files/Alternative CV mechanisms (accepted).pdfformat, we hope to identify ways to improve survey design as well as enhance

28

Assume 𝑊𝑇𝑃𝑖 is a linear function of a row vector of covariates, 𝐱𝑖, such that 𝑊𝑇𝑃𝑖 =

𝐱𝑖𝜷 + 𝜀𝑖, where 𝜷 is a column vector of unknown parameters and 𝜀𝑖 is a normally distributed

mean-zero error term with standard deviation 𝜎𝑖. With the linear conditional mean function,

assuming the error term has a normal distribution is analogous to assuming a normal distribution

for 𝑊𝑇𝑃𝑖. Moreover, interpretation of estimated parameters is the same as for a standard linear

regression model that treats 𝑊𝑇𝑃𝑖 as a directly observed (i.e. uncensored) dependent variable.

Let 𝐷𝑖 = 1 if the response is censored (PC, SBC; OE zero responses), and 𝐷𝑖 = 0 otherwise

(uncensored OE responses). Then, the log-likelihood function is

(4) ln ℒ = ∑ {𝐷𝑖 ∙ ln Φ ((𝑐𝑖,𝑢−𝐱𝑖𝜷

𝜎𝑖) − (

𝑐𝑖,𝑙−𝐱𝑖𝜷

𝜎𝑖)) + (1 − 𝐷𝑖) ∙ ln (

1

𝜎𝑖𝜙 (

𝑊𝑇𝑃𝑖−𝐱𝑖𝜷

𝜎𝑖))}𝑁

𝑖=1 ,

where Φ and 𝜙 denote the CDF and PDF of the standard normal distribution, respectively. The

first term corresponds with the log-likelihood for an interval regression whereas the second

corresponds to that of a normal regression model. The estimator for OE data is thus a Tobit with

left-censoring at zero.

Studies such as Haab, Huang and Whitehead (1999) highlight the importance of allowing

for different error variances when pooling preference data from different experimental

treatments. To allow for possibly different error variances across response formats, for instance

PC and SBC, we can define 𝜎𝑖 = 𝜎0 + 𝑃𝐶𝑖𝜎1, where 𝑃𝐶𝑖 = 1 for PC observations. In this

formulation, 𝜎0 is the standard deviation of the errors for the SBC data and 𝜎0 + 𝜎1 is the

standard deviation for the PC data. This is easily extended for Experiment 2 data, where there are

three treatments.

Table 11 reports the results of the WTP regressions for Experiment 1. Model 1 allows for

a simple unconditional test of the treatment effect. The coefficient on the indicator for the PC

Page 31: Alternative Value Elicitation Formats in Contingent ...cvossler/files/Alternative CV mechanisms (accepted).pdfformat, we hope to identify ways to improve survey design as well as enhance

29

treatment is negative and statistically significant, indicating a difference in mean WTP between

the two treatments. In fact, SBC respondents indicate they are willing to pay twice as much.

Mean WTP for the SBC elicitation is $20.25 (SE = 2.93), and is $8.67 (1.01) for the PC. The

standard deviation of the error term is notably smaller for the PC treatment, indicating that the

WTP distribution for this format has less dispersion along with a lower mean.

The survey asks a number of questions about experience with Hurricane Sandy as well as

sociodemographic characteristics. We merged in data on house characteristics from the county

assessor’s data file. We employ answers to some of these questions as controls, but several of the

survey questions suffer from item non-response. Model 2 is estimated using exactly the same

specification as Model 1, but on a sample restricted to respondents with complete data. This

represents about 90% of the sample. There are no notable differences between the estimates

across Models 1 and 2.

Model 3 includes the socio-demographic and housing variables. These covariates may

explain some of the variation in WTP across individuals, while also controlling for unintended

differences due to sampling. We further include interactions between treatment-specific

indicators and the dummy variable Inconsequential, which equals 1 if the respondent indicated

“definitely no” to the payment consequentiality or “no effect” to the policy consequentiality

question. The model thus allows for differences for those stated beliefs inconsistent with two of

the incentive compatibility assumptions.14 We demean the socio-demographic and housing

14 Given there is mixed evidence on whether measures of consequentiality can be treated as exogenous in WTP

regressions, we also estimated instrumental variables models that parallel those reported as models 3 and 6, using

the control function approach described in Wooldridge (2010, p. 784). Using as IVs various measures found to be

strongly correlated with consequentiality but insignificant determinants of WTP, such as response certainty, SBC

cost amounts and short-term flood risk perceptions, we fail to reject exogeneity of the consequentiality-related

variables for both experiments. Additional details of these models are available from the authors upon request.

Page 32: Alternative Value Elicitation Formats in Contingent ...cvossler/files/Alternative CV mechanisms (accepted).pdfformat, we hope to identify ways to improve survey design as well as enhance

30

variables, which allows the estimated intercept, which is $30.59, to be directly interpretable as

mean WTP for SBC treatment respondents who perceive consequentiality.

From this model, there is a large and statistically significant effect of consequentiality on

both PC and SBC values. This effect is more pronounced for the SBC elicitation, where the

model estimates that WTP is $35.52 lower for those who do not perceive consequentiality to

hold. The direction of this finding mirrors results from other recent studies utilizing a SBC

format (e.g., Herriges et al., 2010; Vossler and Watson, 2013). Conditioning on consequentiality

does not alter the previous result of a significant difference between elicitation formats. In fact,

the difference in WTP nearly doubles from roughly $11 to over $20.

Turning to the effects of other control variables, we find that the income effect is positive

and statistically significant, which can be construed as evidence of construct validity. Females

are willing to pay $4.03 less than males, and participating in extreme sports (a proxy for risk-

taking behavior) decreases WTP. Respondents indicating property damage from Hurricane

Sandy and those living in houses with a basement have a statistically higher WTP. The direction

of these effects are intuitive. As most households living in the 100-year flood plain have flood

insurance, it is not overly surprising that this indicator variable has no statistically significant

effect.

Table 12 reports parallel WTP regressions for Experiment 2 data. The baseline is again

the SBC treatment. Recall that the samples are different across the two experiments, with

Experiment 1 respondents drawn from the 100-year flood plain and Experiment 2 respondents

from just outside this flood plain. From Model 4, mean WTP for the SBC treatment is $10.72,

which is roughly one-half the corresponding Experiment 1 estimate. As respondent

characteristics (aside from insurance and effects from Hurricane Sandy) are similar across the

Page 33: Alternative Value Elicitation Formats in Contingent ...cvossler/files/Alternative CV mechanisms (accepted).pdfformat, we hope to identify ways to improve survey design as well as enhance

31

two samples, this result can be interpreted as evidence of scope sensitivity to exogenous

differences in flood risk. Mean WTP for standard OE is $15.18 (6.90) lower than the SBC and

the difference is statistically significant. In contrast, there is no statistical difference between the

SBC and theory-driven OE formats, and there is less than a 10% difference in point estimates.

Further, as indicated by the estimated standard deviation parameters, there is no statistical

difference in the variances either for these two formats. In contrast, the standard OE variance is

substantially higher.

Turning to Model 5, the same basic conclusions arise when restricting the sample to the

respondents with complete sociodemographic characteristics. The mean WTP estimate from

SBC does increase modestly, and the difference between SBC and standard OE becomes only

weakly significant (p = 0.06). Model 6 again allows for the effect of inconsequentially to differ

across treatments, and includes other controls. Similar to what we observed in Experiment 1,

inconsequentiality has a large and negative effect on WTP for all treatments. Conditional on

consequentiality holding, mean WTP for the three treatments are: SBC, $21.31 (3.04); theory-

driven OE $22.02 (4.20); standard OE $21.13 (6.21). Interestingly, there are no pairwise

differences in these estimates and further the point estimates are very similar. Recalling that the

fraction of inconsequential respondents is higher for the standard OE, this serves as one

explanation for the unconditional difference in WTP.

In Model 6, the sociodemographic and housing characteristics added to regression

produce results that are generally consistent with expectations. As with Experiment 1, these

variables have been demeaned to allow us to interpret the treatment indicators as WTP measures

at the mean of these covariates. Income is again positive and statistically significant. Households

with active flood insurance policies, and those who had property damage from Hurricane Sandy,

Page 34: Alternative Value Elicitation Formats in Contingent ...cvossler/files/Alternative CV mechanisms (accepted).pdfformat, we hope to identify ways to improve survey design as well as enhance

32

have a higher WTP. Similar to the Experiment 1 findings, being female and participating in

extreme sports decreases WTP. Persons indicating membership in an environmental organization

interestingly have much lower WTP (about $14 less).

5. Discussion

Contemporary best-practice guidelines for stated preference studies advocate the use of

incentive compatible formats (Johnston et al., 2017). To date, much of the theory focus has been

on the single binary choice (SBC) format, and alternative mechanisms are often argued to give

rise to untruthful responses. In this study, we identified sets of incentive compatibility conditions

for two alternative and (near) continuous response formats: purely open-ended (OE) questions

and payment cards (PCs). We therefore highlight that incentive compatibility may not be an

elusive goal when considering alternative elicitation formats. Our theory work, when considered

along with the work of Vossler, Doyon and Rondeau (2012) on discrete choice experiments,

suggests that incentive compatibility is not necessarily lost in surveys that either elicit a

continuous response or include two or more value elicitation questions. The work to date thus

encompasses many of the stated preference question formats in use.

The theory assumptions we identify are unlikely to have been met in prior studies,

however, and with the hope of informing practice, we illustrate one possible execution of the

theory. One particular issue with the OE and PC formats, in their standard implementations, is

that they leave much to the respondents’ imaginations. An OE format for instance may remind us

of a situation where we are haggling over price. In speculating about how survey results might be

aggregated, one would naturally think that valuations would be summed up or averaged, which

can lead to extreme stated valuations to influence the outcome in a discernable way. The survey

Page 35: Alternative Value Elicitation Formats in Contingent ...cvossler/files/Alternative CV mechanisms (accepted).pdfformat, we hope to identify ways to improve survey design as well as enhance

33

refinements we implement, in particular information relaying how responses can be interpreted

as votes in an advisory referendum, are likely to restrict these undesirable speculations by

providing what has traditionally been missing information.

On a related note, such speculations over the interpretation and use of values elicited

through continuous response formats may vary wildly across case studies and populations. Even

a person confronted with the same valuation scenario at different points in time may provide

different responses depending on what particular ideas and beliefs have entered her mind during

the valuation exercise. To the extent that survey refinements are widely adopted, this is likely to

enhance reliability by eliminating nuisance variables.

Important for practitioners, the survey refinements we highlight can be applied broadly

and amount to adding a few paragraphs to the value elicitation scenario and framing the value

elicitation as an advisory referendum. Although we limited our attention to PC and OE formats

in this paper, we speculate that similar theoretical assumptions and associated empirical

implementations can be identified for other question formats that ask the same respondent about

different cost amounts, such as the double-bounded dichotomous choice or multiple-bounded

discrete choice formats.

Central to the theory is that the cost to the respondent upon project implementation is not

known with certainty but would be exogenously determined based on actual project costs if plans

moved forward. That cost is uncertain should be plausible to respondents, and in early planning

stages of a project there typically is considerable cost uncertainty. Those skeptical about the

policy process could still suspect the survey information may be used to extract additional

revenue. There is certainly merit in gauging beliefs related to the plausibility of this cost

Page 36: Alternative Value Elicitation Formats in Contingent ...cvossler/files/Alternative CV mechanisms (accepted).pdfformat, we hope to identify ways to improve survey design as well as enhance

34

determination process in focus groups, along with other aspects of the valuation scenario. In our

case study at least, no issues were identified.

The results from the field study highlight that theory is a potentially important tool for

understanding empirical results. We fail to reject convergent validity in mean WTP when

comparing our single binary choice (SBC) and theory-driven OE elicitations, all the while

finding significantly lower values for a counterfactual “standard” OE format included in the

design. That the standard elicitation yields lower values is consistent with the stylized fact from

the literature, whereas equivalence is rare. Moreover, conditional on respondents holding beliefs

that the elicitation is consequential, we find that the difference between the “standard” OE

format and other treatments goes away. Related to this, we find that the proportion of

respondents who view the elicitation as consequential is similar between the theory-driven OE

and SBC formats, but statistically lower for the standard OE elicitation. One implication of the

latter result is that, if the research goal is to maximize the number of respondents who view the

elicitation as consequential, our theory-driven refinements may be useful.

Researchers using OE formats often defend their design choice based on lower sample

size requirements. To our surprise, although there is work comparing SBC and double-bounded

binary choice (e.g. Kanninen, 1993), we did not find any analytical or Monte Carlo analyses

comparing the efficiency of OE and SBC formats. To explore this, we ran a simple Monte Carlo

experiment, using the estimated WTP distribution for the SBC treatment in Experiment 2 as the

population WTP distribution. We assumed the same SBC bid design, and analyzed the simulated

data using an interval regression model. Based on 1000 replications, for SBC sample sizes of

200, 350 and 500, we find that the same level of precision for mean WTP is achieved with OE

sample sizes of approximately 125, 250 and 355, respectively. We note that this is just

Page 37: Alternative Value Elicitation Formats in Contingent ...cvossler/files/Alternative CV mechanisms (accepted).pdfformat, we hope to identify ways to improve survey design as well as enhance

35

suggestive evidence of the possible efficiency gains, as the efficiency of the SBC format can

depend critically on factors such as bid design.

The results related to convergent validity are not all encouraging, however, as we find

that the SBC elicits higher values than our theory-driven PC. Unfortunately, the size of our

sample frame did not allow for a “standard” PC to be included in the design, and so it is not

known whether our theory enhancements to the PC had an empirical impact. The theory

assumptions are stronger for the PC relative to the OE format, as the discreteness of the response

format leaves open the question of how responses are interpreted if the actual cost lies within a

respondent’s implied WTP interval. In our opinion, however, this explanation is unlikely.

Indeed, if we take an extreme view that all respondents under-revealed demand, in particular that

they voted truthfully with the exception of incorrectly voting no to the highest cost they would

pay, this does little to bridge the observed WTP gap. A second possible explanation is that there

is a behavioral effect of providing respondents with a set of possible payment amounts. Such

possible value cues are largely absent from both the SBC and OE formats.

The results have important policy implications. Respondents whose homes were damaged

in Hurricane Sandy consistently reported higher WTP. If climate change increases the frequency

of natural disasters, support for these types of controls is likely to grow. Interestingly, flood

insurance coverage had no impact on WTP for residents in the 100-year flood plain, but had a

positive impact on the WTP of residents outside the flood plain, comparable in magnitude to the

effect of experiencing damage during Sandy. Households inside the 100-year flood plain

frequently have flood insurance and might believe that their insurance will offset some of the

damages during floods. Flood insurance is optional for households outside the 100-year flood

Page 38: Alternative Value Elicitation Formats in Contingent ...cvossler/files/Alternative CV mechanisms (accepted).pdfformat, we hope to identify ways to improve survey design as well as enhance

36

plain, so households that have purchased coverage there might be those that find the risk of flood

particularly salient despite their relatively safe location.

On a final, policy note, the results from our experiment bode ill for efforts to fund

extensive flood protection systems in the New York City area. The mean WTP of households in

the 100-year flood plain, conditioned on respondent beliefs that the elicitation is consequential, is

estimated to be around $30. Even taking the upper-end of the 95% confidence interval associated

with this estimate, perceived benefits do not appear sufficient to support the construction of new

flood control systems. Only 36 thousand households live in the 100-year flood plain in New

York City. A fee of $40 a month from these households would generate less than $15 million a

year in revenue. Expanding to include the 23 thousand families in the 500-meter buffer zone

only increases the flow of revenue to $25 million a year. While, as noted earlier, detailed costs

estimates are not available, the city has projected that a full flood control and climate resiliency

plan could cost around $20 billion. While the benefits of such a program can be argued to exceed

the costs, the results presented here suggest that NYC residents in and around the 100-year flood

plain may not be willing to pay for the system.

Page 39: Alternative Value Elicitation Formats in Contingent ...cvossler/files/Alternative CV mechanisms (accepted).pdfformat, we hope to identify ways to improve survey design as well as enhance

37

References

Anderson-Bergman, Clifford. 2017. Bayesian regression models for interval-censored data in R.

The R Journal 9(2), 487-498.

Arrow, Kenneth, Robert Solow, Paul R. Portney, Edward E. Leamer, Roy Radner and Howard

Shuman, 1993. Report of the NOAA Panel on Contingent Valuation. Federal Register 58, 4601-

4614.

Bateman, Ian J., Philip Cooper, Stavros Georgiou, Stale Navrud, Gregory L. Poe, Richard C.

Ready, Pere Reira, Mandy Ryan and Christian A. Vossler. 2005. Economic Valuation of Policies

for Reducing Acidity in Remote Mountain Lakes. Aquatic Sciences 67(3), 274-291.

Becker, Gordon M., Morris H. DeGroot and Jacob Marschak, 1964. Measuring Utility by a

Single-Response Sequential Method. Behavioral Science 9(3), 226-232.

Bichard, E. and A. Kazmierczak. 2012. Are homeowners willing to adapt to and mitigate the

effects of climate change? Climatic Change 112, 633-654.

Botzen, W.J. Wouter and Jeroen C.J.M. van den Bergh. 2012a. Monetary Valuation Of Insurance

Against Flood Risk Under Climate Change. International Economic Review 53(3), 1005-1026.

Botzen, W.J. Wouter and Jeroen C.J.M. van den Bergh. 2012b. Risk attitudes to low-probability

climate change risks: WTP for flood insurance. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization

82, 151-166.

Cameron, Trudy A. and Daniel D. Huppert. 1989. OLS versus ML estimation of non-market

resource values with payment card interval data. Journal of Environmental Economics and

Management 17, 230-246.

Cameron, Trudy A. and Michael D. James. 1987. Efficient estimation methods for use with

“closed-ended” contingent valuation survey data. The Review of Economics and Statistics 69,

269-276.

Carson, Richard T. and Theodore Groves. 2007. Incentive and informational properties of

preference questions. Environmental and Resource Economics 37, 181-210.

Carson, Richard T., Theodore Groves and John A. List. 2014. Consequentiality: A theoretical

and experimental exploration of a single binary choice. Journal of the Association of

Environmental and Resource Economists 1(1-2), 171-207.

Champ, Patricia A. and Richard C. Bishop. 2006. Is willingness to pay for a public good

sensitive to the elicitation format? Land Economics 82(2), 162-173.

Dillman, Don A., Jolene D. Smyth and Leah Melani Christian, 2014. Internet, Phone, Mail, and

Mixed-Mode Surveys: The Tailored Design Method, 4th Edition. Hoboken, New Jersey: John

Wiley & Sons.

Page 40: Alternative Value Elicitation Formats in Contingent ...cvossler/files/Alternative CV mechanisms (accepted).pdfformat, we hope to identify ways to improve survey design as well as enhance

38

Dixon, Lloyd, Noreen Clancy, Benjamin M. Miller, Sue Hoegberg, Michael M. Lewis, Bruce

Bender, Samara Ebinger, Mel Hodges, Gayle M. Syck, Caroline Nagy, and Scott R. Choquette.

“The Cost and Affordability of Flood Insurance in New York City: Economic Impacts of Rising

Premiums and Policy Options for One- to Four-Family Homes.” Santa Monica, CA: RAND

Corporation, 2017.

Flores, Nicholas E. and Aaron Strong. 2007. Cost credibility and the stated preference analysis of

public goods. Resource and Energy Economics 29(3), 195-205.

Haab, Timothy C., Ju-Chin Huang and John C. Whitehead. 1999. Are hypothetical referenda

incentive compatible? A comment. Journal of Political Economy 107(1), 186-196.

Herriges, Joseph, Catherine L. Kling, Chih-Chen Liu and Justin Tobias. 2010. What are the

consequences of consequentiality? Journal of Environmental Economics and Management

59(1), 67-81.

Johnston, Robert J. 2006. Is hypothetical bias universal? Validating contingent valuation

responses using a binding public referendum. Journal of Environmental Economics and

Management 52, 469-481.

Kanninen, Barbara J. 1993. Optimal experimental design for double-bounded dichotomous

choice contingent valuation. Land Economics 69(2), 138-146.

Kling, Catherine L., Daniel J. Phaneuf and Jinhua Zhao. 2012. From Exxon to BP: Has Some

Number Become Better Than No Number? Journal of Economic Perspectives 26(4), 3-26.

Messer, Kent D., Gregory L. Poe, Daniel Rondeau, William D. Schulze and Christian A.

Vossler, 2010. Social Preferences and Voting: An Exploration Using a Novel Preference

Revealing Mechanism. Journal of Public Economics 94, 308-317.

NYC Special Initiative for Rebuilding and Resiliency. 2013. A stronger, more resilient New

York. Last accessed January 26th, 2016: http://www.nyc.gov/html/sirr/html/report/report.shtml.

Turnbull, Bruce W. 1976. The Empirical Distribution Function with Arbitrarily Grouped,

Censored and Truncated Data. Journal of the Royal Statistical Society Series B (Methodological)

38(3), 290-295.

Vossler, Christian A., Maurice Doyon and Daniel Rondeau. 2012. Truth in consequences:

Theory and field evidence on discrete choice experiments. American Economic Journal:

Microeconomics 4(4), 145-171.

Vossler, Christian A. and Mary F. Evans. 2009. Bridging the gap between the field and the lab:

Environmental goods, policy maker input, and consequentiality. Journal of Environmental

Economics and Management 58(3), 338-345.

Page 41: Alternative Value Elicitation Formats in Contingent ...cvossler/files/Alternative CV mechanisms (accepted).pdfformat, we hope to identify ways to improve survey design as well as enhance

39

Vossler, Christian A. and Michael McKee, 2006. Induced-Value Tests of Contingent Valuation

Elicitation Mechanisms. Environmental & Resource Economics 35, 137-168.

Vossler, Christian A. and Sharon B. Watson. 2013. Understanding the Consequences of

Consequentiality: Testing the Validity of Stated Preferences in the Field. Journal of Economic

Behavior & Organization 86, 137-147.

Wooldridge, Jeffrey M. 2010. Econometric Analysis of Cross Section and Panel Data, Second

Edition. Cambridge, MA: The MIT Press.

Page 42: Alternative Value Elicitation Formats in Contingent ...cvossler/files/Alternative CV mechanisms (accepted).pdfformat, we hope to identify ways to improve survey design as well as enhance

40

Table 1. Number of households by New York City borough

Total Single family 100-year

flood plain

Single family &

100-year flood

plain

Single family &

500-meter

buffer zone

Brooklyn 283,913 62,313 7,644 2,478 2,702

Bronx 94,784 23,316 3,505 1,241 3,822

Manhattan 44,948 2,016 1,968 21 86

Queens 335,450 158,713 12,881 4,417 7,804

Staten Island 131,488 80,224 10,085 5,275 9,087

Total 890,583 326,582 36,083 13,432 23,501

Notes: 12,000 of the 23,501 households in the single family-500-meter buffer zone sample frame were randomly

selected to participate in the survey. All 13,432 households in the 100-year flood plain were recruited as part of

either the pilot or the main wave of the survey.

Table 2. Housing characteristics for survey respondents and non-respondents

Residential

Area

Num.

Floors

Year

Built

Ever

Altered

Year

Altered

Land

Assessment

Total

Assessment

Non-

respondents 1648.9 sf. 1.9 1954.9 0.064 2002.2 $13,624.5 $28,156.0

Respondents 1632.7 sf. 1.9 1954.8 0.063 2003.2 $13,718.1 $28,157.3 Notes: Table entries correspond to sample means. Ever Altered is an indicator equal to 1 if the residence was

renovated since built, and Year Altered is the average year of alterations conditional on it having been renovated.

Page 43: Alternative Value Elicitation Formats in Contingent ...cvossler/files/Alternative CV mechanisms (accepted).pdfformat, we hope to identify ways to improve survey design as well as enhance

41

Table 3. Summary Statistics by Treatment, Experiment 1

Single binary choice Theory-driven payment card

Income (thousands $) 100.1 99.1

(79) (83)

Female 0.54 0.52

(.50) (0.50)

Environmental Org. Member 0.10 0.09

(0.30) (0.29)

Flood Insurance 0.77 0.82

(0.42) (0.39)

Damaged in Hurricane Sandy 0.81 0.84

(0.39) (0.37)

Evacuate in Hurricane Sandy 0.41 0.48

(0.49) (0.50)

Basement 0.76 0.75

(0.43) (0.43)

Extreme Sport Participant 0.18 0.18

(0.38) (0.39)

Inconsequential 0.29 0.25

(0.46) (0.43)

N 478 244 Note: Summary statistics by treatment type are for Experiment 1 households that live inside the 100-year flood zone.

Flood insurance is an indicator for households indicating they have an active flood insurance policy. Damaged and

evacuated in Hurricane Sandy are indicators for respondents who answered yes to those questions. Inconsequential

is an indicator for respondents stating either that they did not believe their vote would not affect the probability that

the flood control system was built or that if it was built they would not have to pay. See the main text for details.

Page 44: Alternative Value Elicitation Formats in Contingent ...cvossler/files/Alternative CV mechanisms (accepted).pdfformat, we hope to identify ways to improve survey design as well as enhance

42

Table 4. Summary Statistics by Treatment, Experiment 2

Single binary

choice

Theory-driven

Open-ended

Standard

Open-ended

Income (thousands $) 116 113 110

(91) (116) (82)

Female 0.50 0.46 0.49

(0.50) (0.5) (0.50)

Environmental Org. Member 0.09 0.10 0.08

(0.3) (0.3) (0.30)

Flood Insurance 0.43 0.41 0.45

(0.50) (0.49) (0.50)

Damaged in Hurricane Sandy 0.47 0.50 0.45

(0.50) (0.50) (0.50)

Evacuated in Hurricane Sandy 0.23 0.19 0.20

(0.42) (0.39) (0.40)

Basement 0.71 0.73 0.76

(0.45) (0.44) (0.43)

Extreme Sport Participant 0.16 0.13 0.15

(0.37) (0.34) (0.36)

Inconsequential 0.24 0.32 0.38

(0.43) (0.47) (0.49)

N 300 193 193 Note: Summary statistics by treatment type for Experiment 2 households that live just outside the 100-year flood

zone. Flood insurance is an indicator for households indicating they have an active flood insurance policy. Damaged

and evacuated in Hurricane Sandy are indicators for respondents who answered yes to those questions.

Inconsequential is an indicator for respondents stating either that they did not believe their vote would not affect the

probability that the flood control system was built or that if it was built they would not have to pay. See the main

text for details.

Page 45: Alternative Value Elicitation Formats in Contingent ...cvossler/files/Alternative CV mechanisms (accepted).pdfformat, we hope to identify ways to improve survey design as well as enhance

43

Table 5

Proportion of Yes Votes by Cost Level, Experiment 1

Cost Theory-driven payment card (PC) Single binary choice (SBC)

0.5 0.68 0.68

1 0.69 0.76

2 0.58 0.86

3 0.52 0.49

5 0.49 0.56

7 0.35 0.60

10 0.28 0.49

15 0.16 0.43

20 0.13 0.53

35 0.06 0.43

50 0.05 0.28

Notes: PC treatment is based on N=261, and SBC treatment utilizes N=535 with between 45 and 51 responses at

each cost level.

Table 6

Proportion of Yes Votes by Cost Level, Experiment 2

Cost Single binary choice (SBC) Theory-driven open ended Standard open ended

0.5 0.75 0.81 0.68

1 0.63 0.80 0.68

2 0.63 0.75 0.64

3 0.63 0.69 0.63

5 0.57 0.66 0.63

7 0.53 0.52 0.53

10 0.46 0.52 0.52

15 0.18 0.30 0.31

20 0.29 0.27 0.29

35 0.35 0.13 0.14

50 0.21 0.13 0.13 Notes: Open ended responses were tabulated at levels consistent with costs included in the SBC design. Sample

sizes: N=382 (SBC); N=249 (standard OE); N=244 (theory-driven OE).

Page 46: Alternative Value Elicitation Formats in Contingent ...cvossler/files/Alternative CV mechanisms (accepted).pdfformat, we hope to identify ways to improve survey design as well as enhance

44

Table 7

Experiment 1 Payment Consequentiality

Treatment

Definitely

No Maybe No Maybe Yes

Definitely

Yes N

Single binary choice 0.10 0.08 0.56 0.27 531

Payment card 0.11 0.08 0.57 0.24 263 Notes: Cell entries indicate the fraction of respondents who selected the indicated response option to the question

“If the City goes forward with a plan to construct the seawall, do you think New York City households will have to

pay for it?”.

Table 8

Experiment 1 Policy Consequentiality

Treatment

No

Effect

Small

Effect

Moderate

Effect

Large

Effect

Absolutely

Crucial N

Single binary choice 0.21 0.29 0.26 0.14 0.10 534

Payment card 0.17 0.29 0.29 0.14 0.11 263

Notes: Cell entries indicate the fraction of respondents who selected the indicated response option to the question

“To what degree do you believe that the advisory referendum decision from you and other survey participants

will affect whether a flood control system is built?”.

Table 9

Experiment 2 Payment Consequentiality

Treatment

Definitely

No Maybe No

Maybe

Yes

Definitely

Yes N

Single binary choice 0.17 0.09 0.57 0.18 381

Standard open-ended (OE) 0.20 0.10 0.50 0.21 246

Theory-driven OE 0.14 0.15 0.58 0.14 237 Notes: Cell entries indicate the fraction of respondents who selected the indicated response option to the question

“If the City goes forward with a plan to construct the seawall, do you think New York City households will have to

pay for it?”.

Table 10

Experiment 2 Policy Consequentiality

Treatment

No

Effect

Small

Effect

Moderate

Effect

Large

Effect

Absolutely

Crucial N

Single binary choice 0.14 0.31 0.32 0.12 0.10 381

Standard open-ended (OE) 0.25 0.30 0.22 0.16 0.07 247

Theory-driven OE 0.22 0.27 0.31 0.15 0.05 237 Notes: Cell entries indicate the fraction of respondents who selected the indicated response option to the question

“To what degree do you believe that the advisory referendum decision from you and other survey participants

will affect whether a flood control system is built?”.

Page 47: Alternative Value Elicitation Formats in Contingent ...cvossler/files/Alternative CV mechanisms (accepted).pdfformat, we hope to identify ways to improve survey design as well as enhance

45

Table 11

Willingness-to-pay regressions for Experiment 1. (1) (2) (3)

Theory-driven payment card (PC) -11.58*** -11.42*** -20.18*** (3.10) (3.51) (4.97)

Inconsequential × Single binary choice (SBC) -35.52*** (9.30)

Inconsequential × Theory-driven PC -7.16*** (2.54)

Income (thousands US$) 0.03**

(0.01)

Female -4.03**

(1.94)

Environmental Org. Member 0.45 (2.55)

Flood insurance 0.65 (2.87)

Damaged in Hurricane Sandy 6.90**

(3.03)

Evacuated in Hurricane Sandy 2.25

(2.16)

Basement 6.77***

(2.27)

Extreme Sport Participant -4.31* (2.26)

Constant 20.25*** 20.46*** 30.59***

(2.93) (3.34) (4.84)

Standard deviation function (σ)

Theory-driven PC -31.38*** -34.41*** -30.34*** (8.63) (10.46) (9.39)

Constant 47.37*** 50.56*** 45.74*** (8.49) (10.34) (9.21)

Log-L -1006.61 -937.20 -902.32

N 796 720 720

Notes: “Inconsequential” is an indicator equal to 1 for respondents with stated beliefs inconsistent with payment

and/or policy consequentiality as described in the main text. All sociodemographic and house characteristics have

been demeaned to ease interpretation. Robust standard errors reported in parentheses. *** significant at the 1% level, ** significant at the 5% level and * significant at the 10% level.

Page 48: Alternative Value Elicitation Formats in Contingent ...cvossler/files/Alternative CV mechanisms (accepted).pdfformat, we hope to identify ways to improve survey design as well as enhance

46

Table 12

Willingness-to-pay regressions for Experiment 2. (4) (5) (6)

Theory-driven open-ended (OE) 1.52 -1.56 0.71 (3.41) (3.74) (4.83)

Standard OE -15.18** -13.75* -0.18 (6.90) (7.22) (6.83)

Inconsequential × Single binary choice (SBC) -29.31*** (7.42)

Inconsequential × Theory-driven OE -30.26***

(9.13)

Inconsequential × Standard OE -58.52** (27.20)

Income (thousands US$) 0.09** (0.04)

Female -9.59**

(4.01)

Environmental Org. Member -14.01**

(6.72)

Flood insurance 7.38* (4.40)

Damaged in Hurricane Sandy 7.78*

(4.46)

Evacuated in Hurricane Sandy -3.47

(4.55)

Basement -5.32 (4.53)

Extreme Sport Participant -8.31*

(4.98)

Constant 10.72*** 14.54*** 21.31***

(2.53) (2.67) (3.04)

Standard deviation function (σ)

Theory-driven OE 12.91 18.32 21.10**

(14.71) (16.40) (10.70)

Standard OE 80.14** 63.08 67.95*

(36.44) (39.07) (37.15)

Constant 38.32*** 34.94*** 28.45***

(7.27) (6.74) (5.24)

Log-L -2450.50 -1930.92 -1880.07

N 875 686 686

Notes: Inconsequential is an indicator equal to 1 for respondents with stated beliefs inconsistent with payment and/or

policy consequentiality as described in the main text. All sociodemographic and house characteristics have been

demeaned to ease interpretation. Specification allows for heterogeneous variances across treatments. Robust

standard errors reported in parentheses. *** significant at the 1% level, ** significant at the 5% level and * significant

at the 10% level.

Page 49: Alternative Value Elicitation Formats in Contingent ...cvossler/files/Alternative CV mechanisms (accepted).pdfformat, we hope to identify ways to improve survey design as well as enhance

47

Figure 1. Flood wall and berm images Notes: Images of a deployable seawall (left) and bridging berm (right) submitted as part of a contest to design a

flood control system for New York City hosted by Rebuild by Design. Source: http://www.rebuildbydesign.org [last

accessed August 10, 2016]

Figure 2. New York City’s 100 year flood plain (source: FEMA flood maps distributed by

WNYC)