“energy-economy-environment interaction using olg ......3 the mitigation of enhanced ghg effects...

27
1 Very preliminary and incomplete. Please do not cite. “Energy-Economy-Environment Interaction Using OLG Framework: Evaluation of Alternative Policies under Demographic Transition“ Ebru Voyvoda Department of Economics Middle East Technical University, Ankara/Turkey [email protected] Abstract This paper presents a multi-sectoral, large-scale OLG model calibrated to a developed (German) and a developing (Turkish) economy, including details on demographic structure, age-dependent consumption patterns, government taxes and expenditures and energy production. The model, based on the seminal work of Auerbach and Kotlikoff (1987) closely follows Rutherford, Böhringer and Pahlke (1999) and Rasmussen (2003) by its representation of energy-related activities and environmental variables. The model is then used (i) to study the effects of demographic transition on the energy demand and GHG emissions (ii) to study the effect of alternative policies under age- dependent consumption structures, within a dynamic general equilibrium framework. The results emphasize that life-cycle of consumers and the demographic structure of a society play an important role in OLG analysis of energy-economy-environment relations.

Upload: others

Post on 25-Jul-2020

2 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: “Energy-Economy-Environment Interaction Using OLG ......3 the mitigation of enhanced GHG effects over long time horizons etc., but falls short of answering questions around the effects

1

Very preliminary and incomplete. Please do not cite.

“Energy-Economy-Environment Interaction Using OLG Framework: Evaluation of

Alternative Policies under Demographic Transition“

Ebru Voyvoda

Department of Economics

Middle East Technical University, Ankara/Turkey

[email protected]

Abstract

This paper presents a multi-sectoral, large-scale OLG model calibrated to a developed (German) and

a developing (Turkish) economy, including details on demographic structure, age-dependent

consumption patterns, government taxes and expenditures and energy production. The model,

based on the seminal work of Auerbach and Kotlikoff (1987) closely follows Rutherford, Böhringer

and Pahlke (1999) and Rasmussen (2003) by its representation of energy-related activities and

environmental variables. The model is then used (i) to study the effects of demographic transition on

the energy demand and GHG emissions (ii) to study the effect of alternative policies under age-

dependent consumption structures, within a dynamic general equilibrium framework. The results

emphasize that life-cycle of consumers and the demographic structure of a society play an important

role in OLG analysis of energy-economy-environment relations.

Page 2: “Energy-Economy-Environment Interaction Using OLG ......3 the mitigation of enhanced GHG effects over long time horizons etc., but falls short of answering questions around the effects

2

I. Introduction

This paper aims to analyze the effects of alternative energy/environment policies under demographic

transition. To this end, it builds up and utilizes a multi-sectoral, large-scale overlapping generations

model that represents the economy-energy-environment interactions to serve the purpose of

carrying out impact assessment of alternative energy-environment policies. The model is calibrated

to the German economy to match the data on the demographic structure and the age-dependent

consumption patterns of the households as well as the production structure of the economy.

The energy–economy–environment (E3) Computable General Equilibrium (CGE) modeling has been

one of the widely employed frameworks for the analysis of alternative environmental policies and

their potential impacts on economy, environment and social welfare. The E3-CGE models, which

often explicitly model the linkages between economic activities, energy transformation and

associated environmental impacts have been identified to provide a decent coverage of

environmental and economic indicators.1

Inherent in the policies focusing on environment, for instance policies aiming at mitigating climate

change, lies a long time frame, which naturally raises the question of intergenerational welfare and

intergenerational equity. A broad range of policy issues – natural resource scarcity, biodiversity

conservation, ozone depletion, and climate change involve both long term horizons and an

asymmetric distribution of costs and benefits between present and future society. This question has

received increasing attention and culminating in the discussions and recent contributions to the

literature. Böhringer and Löschel (2006) for instance, identify that whereas most existing E3-CGE

models have a good coverage of central economic and environmental indicators, they lack through

representation of the social indicators including ageing society, demographic change, the welfare of

older vis á vis younger generations...etc.

The infinitely-living agent (ILA) modeling framework, which has been the central structure in the

assessment of climate change policies, is based on the assumption that future generations can be

represented by a single consumer/household living over infinite periods of time. This representative

agent acts on behalf of all future generations, by possessing the rights to decide on the amount of

saving and investment of the entire present and future generations. . The dynamic ILA framework

makes it an appropriate environment to study questions such as the effects of abatement policies,

1 Böhringer and Löschel (2006) provide a detailed analysis of the uses of E-3 CGE models for Sustainability

Impact Analysis (SIA).

Page 3: “Energy-Economy-Environment Interaction Using OLG ......3 the mitigation of enhanced GHG effects over long time horizons etc., but falls short of answering questions around the effects

3

the mitigation of enhanced GHG effects over long time horizons etc., but falls short of answering

questions around the effects of demographic transition or the inter/intra-distribution of welfare

among/within different generations. Schelling (1995) points out the standard ILA framework in the

context of climate change modeling involves a fallacy of composition in that the generations that are

making the sacrifices are not the ones that would be reaping the benefits. He proposes that the

evaluation of abatement policies should be seen in the context of decisions involving

intergenerational re-distribution rather than intertemporal saving. The ILA framework, where the

(infinite) life-span of individuals and the life-span of the economy are the same, analyzes the problem

in the context of intertemporal-saving rather than analyzing it in the context of decisions involving

intra and intergenerational re-distribution. Accordingly, Rasmussen (2003) emphasizes the

opportunity of investigating the distributional effects of alternative green-house gas abatement

policies between current and future generations within the finite-lifetimes framework.

The OLG structure (the finite-lifetime framework) provides a dynamic environment within a general

equilibrium framework. First, it provides an adequate treatment of the individual’s finite-life span in

a (relatively) open-ended world. The framework particularly avoids the assumption that an immortal

agent acts as a trustee on behalf of both the present and future generations. Moreover, it provides a

realistic modeling of the demographic structure of a society. The OLG structure, which, not only

distinguishes the agents by their age groups but allows one to represent different (age-dependent)

consumption patterns, different wealth endowments etc. , provides an environment to analyze in

detail any energy-environment policy action taken by the government. Such policies of course,

would have both short-run and long-run influences on the production structure, energy demand,

consumption/saving patterns, government budget, current account balance, environmental variables

(e.g. GHG emissions) and therefore, on the distribution of wealth and welfare. These features make

the OLG approach applicable to a wide range of intertemporal phenomena such as the trade-off

between intergenerational equity and economic efficiency of climate policy.

Applied studies of global environmental change, however, remain strongly focused on the

representative agent model in ILA framework. However, taking into account both the public good

nature and the intergenerational equity concerns of the problem has recently led to a few but

growing literature of quantitative, welfare-based evaluation of government policies designed to

mitigate the effects of climate change in the “finite-lifetimes framework. The very restricted set of

"calibrated" CGE models in this field include John and Pecchenino (1994, 1997), Howarth (1998),

Rutherford, Böhringer and Pahlke (1999), Rasmussen (2003), Dalton et al (2008), Kavuncu (2007) and

Leach (2009).

Page 4: “Energy-Economy-Environment Interaction Using OLG ......3 the mitigation of enhanced GHG effects over long time horizons etc., but falls short of answering questions around the effects

4

Based on this literature, this paper presents a multi-sectoral, large-scale OLG model (calibrated to

German and Turkish economies), including details on demographic structure, age-dependent

consumption patterns, government taxes and expenditures and energy production. Thus the model,

based on the seminal work of Auerbach and Kotlikoff (1987) follows Rutherford, Böhringer and

Pahlke (1999) and Rasmussen (2003) closely by its representation of energy-related activities and

environmental variables. The model is then used (i) to study the effects of demographic transition on

the energy demand and GHG emissions (ii) to study the effect of alternative policies under age-

dependent consumption structures, within a dynamic general equilibrium framework.

II. Applied - OLG Models for Climate Change Policy Analysis

The earliest OLG modes were basically used for the purpose of re-examining the climate change

policy implications derived from planner-based ILA models within the finite-lifetimes framework.

Manne (1999) presents concise CGE models of climate change which allows for comparison of the

two approaches and conclude OLG and ILA models particularly lead to similar results w.r.t carbon

prices, share of fossil fuels in energy consumption, economic damages, etc. On the other hand,

Howarth (1998), Rutherford et al. (1999), Gerlagh and van der Zwaan (2001), Schneider et al (2010)

present models with substantial differences between the results of OLG and ILA models.

The discussion of Inter-generational equity/trade-offs both within ILA and OLG frameworks and

comparison of the results of these two different approaches has basically set up the basis for

employing finite-lifetimes framework for energy- economy-environmental modeling. Howarth

(1998), for instance examines structural ties between the well-known DICE mode (Nordhaus, 1994)

and the homologous OLG model and establishes that the ILA prescribes optimal (equivalent) paths

for aggregate variables provided that: (i) The weight the decision maker attaches to the life-cycle

utility of successive generations declines geometrically over time (ILA sensitive to changes in inter-

generational weights used in the social welfare function); and (ii) Transfers of capital from present to

future generations are affected by private/public institutions to achieve an optimal distribution of

welfare between generations.

The ILA framework is based on the assumption that future generations can be represented by a

single consumer/household living over infinite periods of time. This representative consumer also

acts as the representative on behalf of all future generations by possessing the rights to decide on

the amount of saving and investment of the entire present and future generations. The infinite-

Page 5: “Energy-Economy-Environment Interaction Using OLG ......3 the mitigation of enhanced GHG effects over long time horizons etc., but falls short of answering questions around the effects

5

horizon nature of the model characterizes it as an environment that is appropriate to study questions

on abatement of emissions, the mitigation of enhanced GHG effects over long time horizons. The

model, to an extent, also allows for concerns on inter-generational equity by achieving equity

between generations by assuming each generation’s utility depends only on own consumptions,

adding the resulting utility levels by means of a certain weight procedure using a properly chosen

discount factor.

The argument of the properly chosen discount factor has led to a wave of discussion on the positive

vs. normative approaches surrounding the problem of global warming. Rutherford et al. (1999)

points to the case that if per-capita incomes continue to increase at even modest rates over a long-

horizon, it is likely that carbon abatement today would benefit the rich (future generations) at the

expense of the poor (those alive today). Similarly, Parfit (1983) emphasizes the moral discussion on

importance of future events declining “n” percent a year in a standard positive approach utilizing the

interest rate to calibrate for the discount factor. Schneider et al. (2010) also show that the

preference parameters of the households in an OLG economy differs from those of ILA economy. In a

general discussion, Solow (1986) argues that adjusting utility discount rates within infinitely lived

agent models is an unattractive way to frame inter-generational choices.

The set of "calibrated" CGE models for climate change policy analysis within finite-lifetimes

framework can generally be divided into three sets: (1) Standard models taking into account only the

interaction between the economic activity and energy and the directed impact of the economic

activity on the environmental indicators (i.e. greenhouse gas emissions), (2) the integrated

assessment models (IAMs) that also take the feedback of the environmental outcome on the

economic activity, (3) the models that take into account the directed technical change, i.e. the

models of endogenous growth or induced innovation models. Rutherford, Böhringer and Pahlke

(1999), Rasmussen (2003), Dalton et al (2008) are among the first set of modeling practices; Howarth

(1998) and Leach (2009) set examples of the second set; and finally, John and Pecchenino (1994,

1997), Kavuncu (2007) and Laurent-Lucchetti and Leach (forthcoming) are the few studies that

represent the induced innovation mechanism in an OLG-general equilibrium framework.

Rutherford, Böhringer and Pahlke (1999) is one of the basic examples of such CGE Models. The

authors’ focus in the study is the emissions target of Germany as adopted as part of the Kyoto

Meeting in 1997 and show that the OLG modeling framework is the appropriate framework for the

analysis of policies to achieve the carbon abatement target. To this end, the authors construct a

multi-sectoral OLG model (10 – sectors aggregated on the basis of carbon intensity) to investigate

Page 6: “Energy-Economy-Environment Interaction Using OLG ......3 the mitigation of enhanced GHG effects over long time horizons etc., but falls short of answering questions around the effects

6

how alternative schemes for limiting carbon emissions can affect welfare of different generations.

The model is calibrated to 1993 macroeconomic general equilibrium of the German economy. The

policy analyses of the paper basically focus on revenue-neutral tax reforms: carbon taxes (sufficient

to reduce emissions by 15% from a growing baseline trajectory) to raise revenue which can be used

to reduce other distortionary taxes (capital, labor, consumption) in the economy. The results of the

OLG setting is then compared to the results of the associated dynamic ILA model.

Rasmussen (2003) adopts a very similar model to that of Rutherford, Böhringer and Pahlke (1999)

and presents another basic example for the methodology employed in this research. Rasmussen

builds up a multi-sectoral OLG model (8 sectors depending on energy intensities, 55 period lifetime)

to investigate the inter-generational impact of CO2 abatement for the US economy. Here, the CO2

emissions are defined as fixed proportions to the use of fossil fuels in the production processes. The

author, utilizing such an environment, investigates the impact of 15.4% reduction in CO2 emissions

over a 10 year period via emission tax. Following a similar approach with Rutherford, Böhringer and

Pahlke (1999), the tax revenues are recycled through consumption, labor, capital taxation.

Accordingly, an emission tax that is accompanied by a reduction of either the capital or the

consumption taxes benefit the current elderly who have large consumption shares and substantial

capital income. On the other hand, when it is the labor tax that is reduced to accompany the

introduction of the emission tax, all current generations are made worse off.

The model constructed in this paper is designed to be a close follower of the first set of CGE models

for climate change policy analysis within finite lifetimes framework: it takes into account the

interaction between the economic activity, energy usage and directed impact of economic activity on

environmental indicators (CO2 emissions).

III. Model Structure

The OLG model constructed is based on the idea each generation born (entering into economy to

carry out economic decisions) in each period make independent decisions on consumption/saving

throughout the finite-lifetime. Under this basic set up, there is no bequest-leaving behavior to the

off-spring. The model assumes perfect competition and no uncertainty with consistent expectations.

The economy is assumed small in world commodity and financial markets. Domestic and foreign

products are distinguished in accordance with Armington assumption. The calibration procedure

carried out ensures that solving the model with constant policy gives the solution where the first

Page 7: “Energy-Economy-Environment Interaction Using OLG ......3 the mitigation of enhanced GHG effects over long time horizons etc., but falls short of answering questions around the effects

7

period aggregate values match the benchmark data and where all real variables grow at a constant

rate. The economy is disaggregated into n sectors on the basis of their relevance to the topic.

Each period, the households of different generations, that are at different stages of their finite-

lifetimes make their consumption/saving decisions which accrues to aggregate consumption/saving

of the macro-economy and thorough financial and international markets to the government and

international trade balances. The sources of household income are the factor incomes that are

coming from the supply-side and the transfers. The government gets revenues from taxes (capital

income, labor income, output) and spends these revenues on total government expenditures

(government consumption) and gives transfers to households. The model allows for any potential

government deficit to be financed by either domestic private of foreign savings.

Figure 1 adopted from by Rutherford, Böhringer and Pahlke (1999), displays the general structure of

the model which also sets the general framework for the proposed research. The economy is

disaggregated into n sectors on the basis of their carbon intensity.

Figure 1. Economic structure within a single period

Source: Adopted from Rutherford, Böhringer and Pahlke (1999)

Production OLG Demand System

Input-Output Matrix

(12x12)

capital taxes value added taxes

labor taxes transfer income

output taxes

labor income labor-income profiles

capital income

go

ve

rnm

en

t

de

ma

nd

fore

ign

de

ma

nd

inv

estm

en

t

de

ma

nd

consumption demand by

different cohorts: g=0, g=G

government

Page 8: “Energy-Economy-Environment Interaction Using OLG ......3 the mitigation of enhanced GHG effects over long time horizons etc., but falls short of answering questions around the effects

8

PRODUCTION

Firms face competitive output and input markets to maximize profits. To keep the basic model as

tractable as possible, the production structure is assumed to be Cobb-Douglas with physical capital,

labor, non-energy intermediate inputs and energy composite. There is a simple nested structure for

the production technology where the energy composite input is produced along a constant elasticity

of substitution (CES) production technology using fossil fuel and electricity:

[ ] iii

xx

iELiEL

x

iFOiFOii IDIDAEENGρρρ κκ

/1

,,,,´

−−− += (1)

Under the above production technology, differentiation of the minimum cost per unit of primary

energy inputs gives the sectoral demand for coal, petroleum and gas and electricity:

)1/(1

2

,,

)1(

i

i

x

C

ij

px

i

ENG

iij

i

ij

PtNCOAE

P

ENG

IDρ

κ+

+= j= FO, EL (2)

The energy composite, iENG along with physical capital, labor, non-energy intermediate inputs

enters into the production technology for gross output of sector i:

= ∏ iEijIDiLiK

i

j

iiii ENGIDLKAXXS ,,,,, λλλλ (3)

with i typically representing the sectors of the economy. AXi is the technology level parameter, iK ,λ ,

iL,λ , iE ,λ denote the shares of capital input, the labor input and the energy input in the value of

gross output in sector i.

Capital and labor are assumed to be perfectly mobile between sectors. In period t, gross investment,

It, add to the next period’s capital stock, Kt+1, according to the standard accumulation equation Kt+1 =

(1-δ) Kt + It. Factor demands are obtained from profit maximization decision of the firms by paying

each factor its marginal product.

An exogenous technological improvement which is “labor-augmenting” is specified. Every generation

entering the workforce has a higher stock of technological knowledge than the previous one, and

thus becomes more productive by a constant factor, ϕ :

Page 9: “Energy-Economy-Environment Interaction Using OLG ......3 the mitigation of enhanced GHG effects over long time horizons etc., but falls short of answering questions around the effects

9

1,1,1 )1( −Ω+=Ω tt ϕ (4)

Moreover, in order to be able to account for the effect of demographic changes and related policy

alternatives in future stages of this study, the model also incorporates an age-related productivity

profile:

)exp(3

3

2

210, gcgcgcctg +++=π (5)

With c0, c1, c2 and c3 are labor productivity parameters to be estimated based on the micro-data.

Therefore, not only each generation is more productive than the previous one, but also once in the

workforce accumulates labor productivity with age. Based on these specifications, aggregate labor

stock of the economy at time t is:

∑=

=G

g

tgtgtgt neL1

,,, π (6)

where g is the index for each generation and ng,t is the population of age-group g at time t.

HOUSEHOLDS

The household part of the model is disaggregated in overlapping generations (cohorts) which

typically face an identical life-cycle but different time profiles of labor supply decision and

consumption profiles over their lifetime. Each age cohort is carries out its economic decisions on a

finite life-span. Taking prices as given, the household’s life-time maximization problem is of the

form:

ερ

ε

111

1)(

11

,

0

,max, −

+=

+

=+ ∑

+

gtg

gG

g

gtgt

z

zzu

gtg

(7)

s.t.

[ ] )1/(/11

,

/11

,, )1(−−

+−

++ −+=σσσσ χχ gtggtggtg lecz

∑∑=

++++++

=

+ +−Ω=G

g

gtg

F

tgtggtggtg

l

gtgtg

G

g

c

gt trfplepcp0

,,,,,

0

))(π

gtggtgle ++ Ω≤ ,,

, 0, ,, ≥++ tgtgtg lec

Here, zg,t and the formulation of it as a composite of (composite) consumption and leisure represents

the constant elasticity of substitution (CES) demand structure and implies interior solutions for

Page 10: “Energy-Economy-Environment Interaction Using OLG ......3 the mitigation of enhanced GHG effects over long time horizons etc., but falls short of answering questions around the effects

10

(composite) consumption cg,t and labor/leisure, leg,t. 1/(1-σ) is the elasticity of substitution between

(composite) consumption and leisure, ptc is the price of consumption and

l

tp is the wage rate at

time.

The discount rate ρ, and the intertemporal elasticity of substitution, ε are the two parameters

governing the utility function of each generation. trfg,t+g represents the total transfers that an agent,

born at time t gets at the age of g at time t+g. Following Rasmussen and Rutherford (2004), lump-

sum transfers are assumed to be dominated in foreign exchange for simplicity.

The household’s decision is based on the life-time budget constraint where each period each

member of generation t (an agent entering the economy at time t) earns the ongoing market wage

per efficiency unit of labor she supplies. While age-related productivity profile is the same for all

generations ( tg ,π ), each new generation’s efficiency labor is larger than the previous one due to

labor augmenting technological progress as stated in Equation (4).

GOVERNMENT

The government distributes transfers and does public consumption. Government expenditures are

financed by tax revenues. At this current state of the model, I define labor/capital income taxes and

production tax for each sector.

Since, in a dynamic setting, it is possible to define intertemporal solvency constraint, the model at

each period allows for running government surpluses/deficits to be financed by either domestic

private savings (through private saving –investment balance) or through foreign saving (through

trade balance). The period-wise budget constraint of the government then, is:

∑∑ −+=++g

tttg

F

tti

Y

ti

i

Y

it

R

tRt

l

tl DGtrfpXSpRpLp ,,,τττ (8)

where Lt is the aggregate labor supply in efficiency units, Rt is the aggregate capital services, XSi,t is

the (gross) output of sector i and Dt is the government budget deficit at time t.

ENVIRONMENTAL EFFECTS, TAXATION

Following an earlier modeling framework employed by Telli, Voyvoda and Yeldan (2008), three basic

sources of CO2 emissions are distinguished in the model: (i) due to (primary) energy usage, (ii) due to

industrial processes (for instance, cement production), and (iii) due to energy consumption of

households. Total CO2 emissions in the economy is the sum over from all these sources. Emissions

Page 11: “Energy-Economy-Environment Interaction Using OLG ......3 the mitigation of enhanced GHG effects over long time horizons etc., but falls short of answering questions around the effects

11

from industrial processes is regarded to depend on the level of industrial activity, and is regarded

proportional to gross output:

IND

iEMCO2 = iXSiδ (9)

On the other hand, total emissions due to energy usage originate from sectoral emissions due to

combustion of fossil fuels (coal and petroleum and gas). The mechanism of emission is dependent on

the level of pollutant-emitting inputs in each sector:

ENG

iFOEMCO ,2 = ij,ϖ IDFO,i (10)

Finally, total emission of CO2 in the use of energy by households is given by:

∑=i

iiCDHHTOTCO ψ2 (11)

Here, iψ is the coefficient of emissions of CO2 in private consumption (CDi) of the basic fossil fuels

by households.

Carbon taxes can be introduced via at rates CO2tP, CO2tNi and CO2tCi per tons of carbon dioxide

emitted, on production, on intermediate input usage, and on consumption respectively.

FOREIGN TRADE, CAPITAL FLOWS, AGGREGATION

The economy is treated small relative to the world market. Domestic and foreign products are

distinguished by origin according to the Armingtonian specification. The Armingtonian goods are

aggregated with identical import shares for a given import good across all components of final and

intermediate demand. Similarly, on the export side, products of Armingtonian specification are either

supplied to the domestic market or to international markets under the assumption that they are

imperfect substitutes. I assume here a constant elasticity of transformation function (CET):

ααα χχ /1))1(( iiii EXDATXS −+= (12)

with export-domestic good ratio:

Page 12: “Energy-Economy-Environment Interaction Using OLG ......3 the mitigation of enhanced GHG effects over long time horizons etc., but falls short of answering questions around the effects

12

γγ

χ

χε

⋅=

1i

W

i

i

i

PD

P

D

EX (13)

with, α = (γ-1)/ γ.

The aggregate demand in the macro-economy is characterized by national account balances relating

capital income, Rt, labor income, Lt, government transfers to households Tt, private sector aggregate

consumption, Ct, private sector net saving, St, and investment It, primary government deficit Dt, and

trade deficit Bt. So, together with the government budget constraint, the following equilibrium

conditions are to be satisfied:

Rt + Lt + Tt = Ct + St (14)

with

St - Dt + Bt = It (15)

Together with the aggregate demand-supply conditions, the equilibrium in each commodity and

factor markets has to be satisfied through the adjustment of the associated price vector in each

period.

CALIBRATION, CONSTRUCTION OF BENCHMARK2

In comparison to models of ILA framework, the OLG set-up introduces extra dimensions in the

calibration process, namely the decisions of the overlapping generations households should be

consistent with the aggregate observed values of the macro-economy at any point in time. Therefore

the calibration of an OLG model, first should solve for the optimal profile of decision variables of a

reference generation subject to given aggregate levels using the steady state assumption. Next,

comes the stage where the aggregate variables for the rest of the economy should be put in

consistency with the aggregate variables that come out of the household model of the first stage.

Rasmussen and Rutherford (2004) present both a consistent set of procedures and steps to set-up a

baseline reference path of the model. I do generally follow the procedure described to set up the

basic modeling environment I will be utilizing for the rest of the paper here. Transformation of the

standard OLG modeling environment to account for energy-economy-environment interactions

demands further extensions to this basic modeling framework.

2 This Section is to be completed.

Page 13: “Energy-Economy-Environment Interaction Using OLG ......3 the mitigation of enhanced GHG effects over long time horizons etc., but falls short of answering questions around the effects

13

As is customary in applied general equilibrium analysis, the model is based on economic transactions

in a benchmark year3. Benchmark data helps to determine the parameters of the functional forms of

the model framework as described above. Here, I provide a brief summary of the basic steps

followed in the calibration process and the set of the parameter values associated.

Time-generation structure of the OLG modeling framework demands that, on the one axis, one has

to trace and keep account of the time t, and on the other axis lies the generations, g=0,…G alive at

each time period. By the life-span of the representative generation that enters the economy at time

t=0, there is an indirect relationship between the household’s maximization problem given in

Equation (7) and the macroeconomic general equilibrium at time t=0. For the optimal life-span

problem to be consistent with the macro-aggregates of the economy, one has to establish

consistency in terms of the parameters of the household’s maximization problem.

It is customary for the calibration procedure to assume that initially the economy is at its steady-

state equilibrium. Therefore the parameter ϕ represents the steady –state growth rate of the

economy (in case there is no population growth). Similarly, given the (real) interest rate, one can

impose the dynamic path for the level of general price index pt = (1+r)t with the value equated to p=1

for t=0. Such restrictions can also be imposed for the steady state path of the overall trade deficit of

the economy: Bt+1 = (1+ϕ ) Bt.

The following equations help understanding the general calibration procedure followed. In terms of

aggregate consumption observed in t=0, and aggregate labor income generated at t=0, one has to

match the household optimization problem in Equation (7) and the macro- balance of the economy,

represented in Equations (14)-(15):

∑+

=+

gg

gtg

t

cC

)1(

,

ϕ (16)

∑+

−Ω=

+++

gg

gtggtggtg

t

leL

)1(

)( ,,,

ϕ

π (17)

3 In this version of the paper, the benchmark year for German data is 2008, for Turkish data, it is chosen to be

2010.

Page 14: “Energy-Economy-Environment Interaction Using OLG ......3 the mitigation of enhanced GHG effects over long time horizons etc., but falls short of answering questions around the effects

14

Similarly, consistency between micro-and-macro behaviors implies that total value of household

assets equals total domestic plus foreign assets. Therefore, it is the value of the trade deficit that

determines the volume of foreign asses in the economy. Then, the value of households’ total assets

has to be equal to the value of aggregate capital stock of the economy less future obligations to

government. Therefore, allowing for permanent deficits, the steady state assumption implies:

∑−

+−++==

g

ttttgtr

rDBKrmA

ϕ

1)()1(´, (18)

where mg,t is the value of assets held at period zero by the members of the generation of age g.

Imposing such a condition helps the calibration procedure to represent the steady-state relationship

between capital income, Rt and the capital stock of the economy Kt, such that Rt = (r+ϕ )Kt.

The model described is calibrated to both developing (Turkish) and developed (German) economies

to investigate the effect of demographic transition under different economic structures. The data for

the Turkish calibration comes from the multi-sectoral Social Accounting Matrix (SAM) of the Turkish

economy, constructed on latest TURKSTAT 20002 Input-Output Table that is re-arranged accordingly

to give a structural portray of intermediate flows at the intersection of commodities row and

activities column in the 12-sector 2010 macro-SAM.

The calibration for the German economy is based on the World Input Output Database (WIOD) that

is re-arranged accordingly to give a structural portray of intermediate flows at the intersection of

commodities row and activities column in the 35-sector 2008 macro-SAM.4

As the model described contains a number of economic and environmental parameters, the

estimation of them becomes important in evaluating the quantitative results of the alternative policy

scenarios. In this case, it is important to represent the critical sectors w.r.t. energy demand and also

w.r.t environmental variables.

Following the model structure and the calibration procedure described above, two pieces of

quantitative analysis has been carried out: (i) Calibration of parameters ρ, the utility discount rate

and Ω, time endowment-scaling factor along with tax rates, emission parameters etc. ; (ii) the base-

path of the economy under the assumption of steady-state has been generated. This base path

4 See Pothen and Koesler (2012) for more on WIOD data and the transformation of the raw data into a form to be

utilized in environmental CGE models.

Page 15: “Energy-Economy-Environment Interaction Using OLG ......3 the mitigation of enhanced GHG effects over long time horizons etc., but falls short of answering questions around the effects

15

generated typically serves as the benchmark case to which alternative policy simulation results will

be compared in later stages of the research.

To provide an idea on the consistent set of calibrated values, Table A1 in Appendix displays the set of

selected (exogenous) variables and parameters (for calibration to Turkish data), and the calibration

results under two different settings: (i) under the assumption that leisure is given a positive

importance in the period-wise utility of each representative household, (ii) under the assumption of

exogenous (full) labor supply.

IV. SCENARIOS AND RESULTS

THE EFFECTS OF DEMOGRAPHIC TRANSITION

Demographic structure may have serious impacts on the economy. The issue of demographic change

has been addressed around the questions on sustainability of social security systems, or fiscal policy

etc., but not within the question of sustainable environment. Yet, change in demographic structure

may affect the greenhouse gas emissions (not only via its effects on household consumption or

consumption patterns but also via its indirect demand effect on the production structure of the

economy).

For instance, by increasing the share of old people in total population, demographic change may

affect the use of different energy sources, which in turn affects the emissions.

Dalton et al. (2008) study that the demographic change in US reduces the CO2 emissions in US by

40% between 2000 and 2100. Kronenberg (2008) has also shown that demographic change in

Germany has a significant impact on the structure of private households’ consumption expenditures.

Especially, the energy use of households is also significantly affected. Generally, the findings of the

paper show that demographic change tends to increase the consumption of energy for heating

purposes and to reduce the consumption of motor vehicle fuels. Thus, demographic change has an

interesting effect on the ‘energy mix’ consumed by private households. The change in the structure

of consumption expenditures also triggers effects on the sectoral production of output. Most

notably, the output of the sector refined petroleum products and other fuels is reduced, while the

output of the sector electricity and district heat is increased.

Page 16: “Energy-Economy-Environment Interaction Using OLG ......3 the mitigation of enhanced GHG effects over long time horizons etc., but falls short of answering questions around the effects

16

Following the claim that demographic change (relative to stable population dynamics) may have

serious impact on the greenhouse gas emissions of an economy, the model constructed is first

utilized to simulate the forecasted German/Turkish demographic structures. Given the population

projections by United Nations (UN), one can observe the projected demographic structures. Figure 2

provides the forecasts for the population growth rate of Germany/Turkey vis á vis Western Europe.

Figure 2. Population growth rates, Germany, Turkey & Western Europe, % (1950-2100)

Source: UN

A transformation of such population forecasts into the modeling framework here is the change in

the cohort-structure. Using the UN Population Projections w.r.t age, a simulation designed is to give

the demographic shock and evaluate the changes in the model economy (Figure 3 and 4).

-1

-0.5

0

0.5

1

1.5

2

2.5

3

3.5

Germany

Western Europe

Page 17: “Energy-Economy-Environment Interaction Using OLG ......3 the mitigation of enhanced GHG effects over long time horizons etc., but falls short of answering questions around the effects

17

Figure 3: Future Projections (t = t0, t0+50, t0+100) on population of different age-groups relative

to a stable population growth (Germany)

(with 0.2% population growth rate)

Age-group

Source: Based on UN Projections

One can observe from Figure 3 that the current middle-income dominated demographic structure

(w.r.t. a stable population growth) of the German economy is forecasted to move towards a more

older structure in t+50 and a more balanced structure in t+100.

As Figure 4 indicates, Turkish demographic structure as of 2005-2010 period, on the other hand,

shows a youth-dominated picture compared to the case of constant population growth. Yet, with

the forecasted reduction in the population growth rate and increase in life-spans, Turkish

demographics is expected to move towards a middle-aged profile in the medium run and towards

an older profile in the longer run. Yet, a lower value relative to a constant 0.2% population growth

rate, causes the ratios to stay lower than 1.0 in the Figure.

0

0.2

0.4

0.6

0.8

1

1.2

1.4

20-25 25-30 30-35 35-40 40-45 45-50 50-55 55-60 60-65 65-70 70-75

0

50

100

Page 18: “Energy-Economy-Environment Interaction Using OLG ......3 the mitigation of enhanced GHG effects over long time horizons etc., but falls short of answering questions around the effects

18

Figure 4: Future Projections (t = t0, t0+50, t0+100) on population of different age-groups relative

to a stable population growth (Turkey)

(with 0.2% population growth rate)

Age-group

Source: Based on UN Projections

Demographic Shock: Germany

I compare the baseline path under a stable population growth to the path generated under the

demographic shock, as pictured in Figure 3 for Germany. Figure 5 and Figure 6 display the effects of

such a transition on the major macroeconomic variables; Figure 7 portrays the path of aggregate

CO2 emissions by the production sectors of the economy and the households.

Both Figures 5 and 6 indicate that the currently relatively older population structure of the German

economy keeps both the aggregate labor supply (in efficiency labor units) and aggregate capital

supply of the economy higher than it would have been under a stable population growth. Yet, in the

longer run, as the population growth rate turns into negative the aggregate labor supply follows a

path that decreases at a higher rate than aggregate capital supply. Such a result is expected for it is

the middle-aged and older generations that have accumulated assets over their lifecycles. The

comparison of Gross Domestic Product (GDP) and Private Consumption variables (Figure 6) also

provide similar results w.r.t. to effects of projected demographic transition on the macroeconomic

0

0.2

0.4

0.6

0.8

1

1.2

20-24 25-29 30-34 35-39 40-44 45-49 50-54 55-59 60-64 65-69 70-74

0

50

100

Page 19: “Energy-Economy-Environment Interaction Using OLG ......3 the mitigation of enhanced GHG effects over long time horizons etc., but falls short of answering questions around the effects

19

variables. As the economy get deprived of capital and labor supplies, (in comparison to the stable

population growth benchmark case), total GDP, total income and private consumption decreases. In

line with decreased consumption demand, CO2 emissions by households decrease faster than the

CO2 emissions by the production sectors of the economy.

Figure 5: Effects of Demographic Shock, Germany:

Macroeconomic variables, % Change w.r.t. Benchmark

Figure 6: Effects of Demographic Shock, Germany:

Macroeconomic variables, % Change w.r.t. Benchmark

Page 20: “Energy-Economy-Environment Interaction Using OLG ......3 the mitigation of enhanced GHG effects over long time horizons etc., but falls short of answering questions around the effects

20

Figure 7: Effects of Demographic Shock, Germany:

Emission variables, % Change w.r.t. Benchmark

Yet, we observe from Figure 8 that the source of aggregate emissions by households changes its

structure over time. In the short run, as the economy shows a more middle-age dominant structure,

the majority of the emissions is caused by the households that fall into this age group. Over time

(t0+20 - t0+25) the economy becomes older and it is now the old-age group that becomes

responsible for a major portion of total CO2 emissions. The contribution of younger age groups (w.r.t.

an age structure under stable population growth) reduces and becomes negative over time. Such a

picture strongly emphasizes that effects of different environmental policies will be differentiated for

different age groups living together in the economy.

Page 21: “Energy-Economy-Environment Interaction Using OLG ......3 the mitigation of enhanced GHG effects over long time horizons etc., but falls short of answering questions around the effects

21

Figure 8: Effects of Demographic Shock, Germany:

Household Emissions by Age Structure over Time, % Change w.r.t. Benchmark

Demographic Shock: Turkey

In order to provide insight for the effects of demographic transition on the macroeconomic, energy

and environmental variables in the context of a developing economy, Figures 9-12 illustrate the

paths of a selected set of variables for the Turkish economy under demographic transition. Here, a

demographic shock that keeps the population of each age group below the corresponding level

under a stable population growth indicates a lower profile for the aggregate capital stock and

aggregate labor stock variables, w.r.t. benchmark (Figures 9, 10). As the population becomes more

middle-aged, both the profile of aggregate capital and aggregate (efficiency) labor stock increases;

in the longer run, as the population gets older, both macro-variables show a declining trend.

Similarly, gross domestic product shows a trend below the benchmark, along with private

consumption. Yet, both the upturn and downturn of GDP is smoother than that of consumption

since the older tend to consume relatively higher and it is mostly the younger and the middle-aged

that hold labor and capital stocks of the economy.

Page 22: “Energy-Economy-Environment Interaction Using OLG ......3 the mitigation of enhanced GHG effects over long time horizons etc., but falls short of answering questions around the effects

22

Figure 9: Effects of Demographic Shock, Turkey:

Macroeconomic variables, % Change w.r.t. Benchmark

Figure 10: Effects of Demographic Shock, Turkey:

Macroeconomic variables, % Change w.r.t. Benchmark

The paths of emission variables under the effect of the Turkish demographic change mostly follow

the patterns of consumption and the real GDP (Figure 11). The lower consumption path generates a

lower emissions path for the households’ contribution. Yet, the lower demand also causes shifts

within the production structire of the economy and in line with the path of GDP, produces a

Page 23: “Energy-Economy-Environment Interaction Using OLG ......3 the mitigation of enhanced GHG effects over long time horizons etc., but falls short of answering questions around the effects

23

relatively favorable path for contribution to total emissions by the production sectors of the

economy.

Figure 11: Effects of Demographic Shock, Turkey:

Emission variables, % Change w.r.t. Benchmark

The contribution of different age groups to aggregate household emissions through time is illustrated

in Figure 12. Following the Figure, one can trace that as the population gets older, the contribution

of young decreases and the contributions of middle-aged and old increases. Although aggregate

household emissions are lower than the benchmark in the short run (Figure 11), one can understand

that such lower figure is actually governed by the lower consumption profile of old households. The

contribution of young and middle aged are still high, even in the short run; thanks to relatively higher

consumption possibilities for these age groups. As the economy moves towards medium-long run,

the population structure stabilizes and the contribution of different age groups to total household

emissions also stabilizes at lower paths w.r.t. benchmark.

Page 24: “Energy-Economy-Environment Interaction Using OLG ......3 the mitigation of enhanced GHG effects over long time horizons etc., but falls short of answering questions around the effects

24

Figure 12: Effects of Demographic Shock, Turkey:

Household Emissions by Age Structure over Time, % Change w.r.t. Benchmark

THE EFFECTS OF DEMOGRAPHIC TRANSITION UNDER AGE-DEPENDENT CONSUMPTION PATTERNS

To be completed.

V. DISCUSSION

The energy–economy–environment CGE modeling has been one of the widely employed frameworks

for the analysis of alternative environmental policies and their potential impacts on economy,

environment and social welfare.

The OLG structure built in this paper provides a dynamic environment within a general

equilibrium framework. First, the framework provides an adequate treatment of the

individual’s finite-life span in a (relatively) open-ended world. Moreover, it provides a more

realistic modeling of the demographic structure of a society. As the OLG structure

characterizes the agents/generations not only by their age but by their wealth/endowment,

revenue-raising, expenditure decreasing devices will naturally have distortionary side-effects

on the allocation of resources. These features make the OLG approach applicable to a wide

range of intertemporal phenomena such as the trade-off between intergenerational equity

and economic efficiency of climate policies.

Page 25: “Energy-Economy-Environment Interaction Using OLG ......3 the mitigation of enhanced GHG effects over long time horizons etc., but falls short of answering questions around the effects

25

Following the discussion, the model designed in this paper is utilized to show what OLG structure

can provide for the energy-economy- environment analysis. To such an end, this report illustrates

the results of a simulation experiment to reflect demographic shocks for a developing (Turkey) and a

developed (German) economy. The change in demographic structure of an economy is important

for the analysis since it may affect the greenhouse gas emissions (not only via its effects on

household consumption or consumption patterns but also via its indirect demand effect on the

production structure of the economy). As the greenhouse gas, especially CO2 emissions are closely

related with the use of fossil fuels, an energy tax is one of the effective policy instruments in

mitigation effects. The OLG framework constructed is used to show the impact of demographic

shocks to the macroeconomic, sectoral and generational variables of the economy.

The large-scale OLG model that represents the economy-energy-environment interactions is an

effective tool to serve the purpose of carrying out impact assessment of alternative energy-

environment policies. Further calibration of the model to World scale should help to set up an

environment where numerical evaluations of alternative policies w.r.t. economy, environment and

intra-and inter-generational welfare can be carried out.

REFERENCES

Auerbach, A. J. ve Kotlikoff, L. J. (1987) Dynamic Fiscal Policy, Cambridbe, UK: Cambridge University

Press.

Böhringer, C. and A. Löschel (2006), Computable General Equilibrium Models for Sustainability

Impact Assessment: Status Quo and Prospects, Ecological Economics, 60, 49-64.

Dalton. M., O’Neill, B., Prskawetz, A., Jiang, L. and J. Pitkin (2008), Population Aging and Future

Carbon Emissions in the United States, Energy Economics, 30, 642–675

Gerlagh, R. and B. van der Zwaan (2001), The Effects of Ageing and an Environmental Trust

Fund in an Overlapping Generations Model on Carbon Emission Reductions, Ecological Economics,

36, 311–326.

Howarth, R. B. (1998), An Overlapping Generations Model of Climate-Economy Interactions,

Scandinavian Journal of Economics, 100, 575–591.

Page 26: “Energy-Economy-Environment Interaction Using OLG ......3 the mitigation of enhanced GHG effects over long time horizons etc., but falls short of answering questions around the effects

26

John A. A. and R. A. Pecchenino (1997), International and Intergenerational Environmental

Externalities, Scandinavian Journal of Economics, 99, 371-387.

John A. A. and R. A. Pecchenino (1994), An Overlapping Generations Model of Growth and the

Environment, The Economic Journal, 104, 1393-1410.

Kavuncu, O. (2007), Intergenerational Cost–benefit Aanalysis of Climate Change: an Endogenous

AbatementAapproach, Environment and Development Economics, 12, 183-211.

Kronenberg, T. (2009), The impact of demographic change on energy use and greenhouse gas

emissions in Germany, Ecological Economics, 68(10), 2637-2645.

Leach, A. J. (2009), The Welfare Implications of Climate Change Policy, Journal of Environmental

Economics and Management, 57, 151 – 165.

Laurent-Lucchetti, J. and A. J. Leach (forthcoming), Generational welfare and induced innovation

under climate change policy, Scandinavian Journal of Economics.

Manne, A.S., (1999), Discounting and Intergenerational Equity, in, Weyant, J.P., P.R. Portney, (eds.),

Discounting and Intergenerational Equity, Resources for the Future, Washington, DC, 111–129.

Nordhaus W.D. (1994), Managing the Global Commons, MIT Press, Cambridge, Massachusetts.

Parfit, D. (1983), Energy Policy and the Further Future: The Social Discount Rate, in MacLean, D. and

Brown, P. G. (eds.), Energy and the Future, Totowa, NJ, Rowman and Litlefield.

Pothen F. and S. Koesler (2012), Basic WIOD CGE Model: An Implementation of the WIOD Data to the

CGE Framework, ZEW.

Rasmussen, T. (2003), Modeling the Economics of Greenhouse Gas Abatement: An Overlapping

Generations Approach, Review of Economic Dynamics, 6, 99-119.

Rutherford, T., Bohringer, C. And A. Pahlke (1999), Carbon Abatement, Revenue Recycling and

Intergenerational Burden Sharing, in: P.J.J. Herings, G. van der Laan and A.J.J. Talman, The Theory of

Markets, Amsterdam, 305-326.

Schelling, T.C. (1995), Intergenerational Discounting, Energy Policy, 23, 395-401.

Schneider, M. T., Traeger, C. and R. Winkler (2010), Trading Off Generations: Infinitely-Lived Agent

Versus OLG, Center for Economic Research at ETH Zurich, Working Paper No: 10/128.

Solow, Robert M, (1986), On the Intergenerational Allocation of Natural Resources, Scandinavian

Journal of Economics, 88, 141-49.

Telli, Ç., Voyvoda E. and Yeldan E. (2008), Economics of Environmental Policy in Turkey: A General

Equilibrium Investigation of the Economic Evaluation of Sectoral Emission Reduction Policies for

Climate Change, Journal of Policy Modeling, 30(1), 321-340.

Page 27: “Energy-Economy-Environment Interaction Using OLG ......3 the mitigation of enhanced GHG effects over long time horizons etc., but falls short of answering questions around the effects

27

Appendix

Table A1. Selected Variable and Parameter Values, Calibration Results (Turkish Case)

Variable and Parameter Values

Consumpti

on share in

composite,

χ = 0.8

Consumption

share in

composite, χ =

1.00

Annual real interest rate r 0.05

Steady-state growth rate n 0.005

Annual depreciation rate for physical capital δ 0.07

Elasticity of substitution (c vs le) 1-1/ σ 0.80

Elasticity of transformation D vs EX η 4.00

Armington elasticity on imports σ_AL 4.00

Intertemporal elasticity ε

Age-Productivity parameters

Constant c 0 1.078462

Coeffcient on age (starting at age 21) c 1 0.097136

Coefficient on age squared c 2 -0.001517

Coeffcient on age cubed c 3 0.000007

Calibrated Parameters

Ratio of capital stock to assets θA 0.712

Ratio of government deficit to assets θD 0.094

Ratio of trade deficit to assets θB 0.194

Household behavioral parameters

Period utility discount rate ρ -0.126 -0.202

Scaling factor on time endowment Ω 2.038 0.786

Tax rates

Labor Income τl 0.200

Capital Income τR 0.239

Output τiY

AG 0.038

MW 0.010

CO 0.034

ET 0.007

PG 0.005

AU 0.005

PE 0.028

EL 0.003

CE 0.016

CN 0.025

IS 0.011

OE 0.018

Emissions coef.

Coal 13.409

Petroleum-Gas 4.978

Industrial Proc. 1.509

ij,ϖ