appendix to chapter 1 mathematics used in microeconomics © 2004 thomson learning/south-western

56
Appendix to Chapter 1 Mathematics Used in Microeconomic s © 2004 Thomson Learning/South- Western

Post on 18-Dec-2015

217 views

Category:

Documents


1 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Appendix to Chapter 1 Mathematics Used in Microeconomics © 2004 Thomson Learning/South-Western

Appendix to Chapter 1

Mathematics Used in Microeconomics

© 2004 Thomson Learning/South-Western

Page 2: Appendix to Chapter 1 Mathematics Used in Microeconomics © 2004 Thomson Learning/South-Western

2

Functions of One Variable

Variables: The basic elements of algebra, usually called X, Y, and so on, that may be given any numerical value in an equation

Functional notation: A way of denoting the fact that the value taken on by one variable (Y) depends on the value taken on by some other variable (X) or set of variables

)(XfY

Page 3: Appendix to Chapter 1 Mathematics Used in Microeconomics © 2004 Thomson Learning/South-Western

3

Independent and Dependent Variables

Independent Variable: In an algebraic equation, a variable that is unaffected by the action of another variable and may be assigned any value

Dependent Variable: In algebra, a variable whose value is determined by another variable or set of variables

Page 4: Appendix to Chapter 1 Mathematics Used in Microeconomics © 2004 Thomson Learning/South-Western

4

Two Possible Forms of Functional Relationships

Y is a linear function of X

– Table 1.A.1 shows some value of the linear function Y = 3 + 2X

Y is a nonlinear function of X– This includes X raised to powers other than 1– Table 1.A.1 shows some values of a quadratic

function Y = -X2 + 15X

bXaY

Page 5: Appendix to Chapter 1 Mathematics Used in Microeconomics © 2004 Thomson Learning/South-Western

5

Table 1A.1: Values of X and Y for Linear and Quadratic Functions

Linear Function Quadratic FunctionY = f(X) Y = f(X)

x = 3 + 2X x = -X2 + 15X-3 -3 -3 -54-2 -1 -2 -34-1 1 -1 -16 0 3 0 0 1 5 1 14 2 7 2 26 3 9 3 36 4 11 4 44 5 13 5 50 6 15 6 54

Page 6: Appendix to Chapter 1 Mathematics Used in Microeconomics © 2004 Thomson Learning/South-Western

6

Graphing Functions of One Variable

Graphs are used to show the relationship between two variables

Usually the dependent variable (Y) is shown on the vertical axis and the independent variable (X) is shown on the horizontal axis– However, on supply and demand curves, this

approach is reversed

Page 7: Appendix to Chapter 1 Mathematics Used in Microeconomics © 2004 Thomson Learning/South-Western

7

Linear Function

A linear function is an equation that is represented by a straight-line graph

Figure 1A.1 represents the linear function Y=3+2X

As shown in Figure 1A.1, linear functions may take on both positive and negative values

Page 8: Appendix to Chapter 1 Mathematics Used in Microeconomics © 2004 Thomson Learning/South-Western

8

10

5

3

-5-10

-10

-5

0 1 5 10

Y-axis

Y-intercept

X-intercept

X-axis

Figure 1A.1: Graph of the Linear Function Y = 3 + 2X

Page 9: Appendix to Chapter 1 Mathematics Used in Microeconomics © 2004 Thomson Learning/South-Western

9

Intercept

The general form of a linear equation is Y = a + bX

The Y-intercept is the value of Y when when X equals 0– Using the general form, when X = 0, Y = a, so this is

the intercept of the equation

Page 10: Appendix to Chapter 1 Mathematics Used in Microeconomics © 2004 Thomson Learning/South-Western

10

Slopes

The slope of any straight line is the ratio of the change in Y (the dependent variable) to the change in X (the independent variable)

The slope can be defined mathematically as

where means “change in” It is the direction of a line on a graph.

X

Y

X in Change

Yin Change Slope

Page 11: Appendix to Chapter 1 Mathematics Used in Microeconomics © 2004 Thomson Learning/South-Western

11

Slopes

For the equation Y = 3 + 2X the slope equals 2 as can be seen in Figure 1A.1 by the dashed lines representing the changes in X and Y

As X increases from 0 to 1, Y increases from 3 to 5

201

35 Slope

X

Y

Page 12: Appendix to Chapter 1 Mathematics Used in Microeconomics © 2004 Thomson Learning/South-Western

12

10

5

3

-5-10

-10

-5

0 1 5 10

Y-axis

Y-intercept

X-intercept

Slope

X-axis

Figure 1A.1: Graph of the Linear Function Y = 3 + 2X

201

35

X

Y

YX

Page 13: Appendix to Chapter 1 Mathematics Used in Microeconomics © 2004 Thomson Learning/South-Western

13

Slopes

The slope is the same along a straight line. For the general form of the linear equation the

slope equals b The slope can be positive (as in Figure 1A.1),

negative (as in Figure 1A.2) or zero If the slope is zero, the straight line is

horizontal with Y = intercept

Page 14: Appendix to Chapter 1 Mathematics Used in Microeconomics © 2004 Thomson Learning/South-Western

14

Slope and Units of Measurement

The slope of a function depends on the units in which X and Y are measured

If the independent variable in the equation Y = 3 + 2X is income and is measured in hundreds of dollars, a $100 increase would result in 2 more units of Y

Page 15: Appendix to Chapter 1 Mathematics Used in Microeconomics © 2004 Thomson Learning/South-Western

15

Slope and Units of Measurement

If the same relationship was modeled but with X measured in single dollars, the equation would be Y = 3 + .02 X and the slope would equal .02

Page 16: Appendix to Chapter 1 Mathematics Used in Microeconomics © 2004 Thomson Learning/South-Western

16

Changes in Slope

In economics we are often interested in changes in the parameters (a and b of the general linear equation)

In Figure 1A.2 the (negative) slope is doubled while the intercept is held constant

In general, a change in the slope of a function will cause rotation of the function without changing the intercept

Page 17: Appendix to Chapter 1 Mathematics Used in Microeconomics © 2004 Thomson Learning/South-Western

17

Y

X

10

5

0 5 10

FIGURE 1A.2: Changes in the Slope of a Linear Function

Page 18: Appendix to Chapter 1 Mathematics Used in Microeconomics © 2004 Thomson Learning/South-Western

18

Y

X

10

5

0 5 10

FIGURE 1A.2: Changes in the Slope of a Linear Function

Page 19: Appendix to Chapter 1 Mathematics Used in Microeconomics © 2004 Thomson Learning/South-Western

19

Changes in Intercept

When the slope is held constant but the intercept is changed in a linear function, this results in parallel shifts in the function

In Figure 1A.3, the slope of all three functions is -1, but the intercept equals 5 for the line closest to the origin, increases to 10 for the second line and 12 for the third– These represent “Shifts” in a linear function.

Page 20: Appendix to Chapter 1 Mathematics Used in Microeconomics © 2004 Thomson Learning/South-Western

20

Y

X

5

0 5 1012

FIGURE 1A.3: Changes in the Y-Intercept of a Linear Function

10

12

5 XY

Page 21: Appendix to Chapter 1 Mathematics Used in Microeconomics © 2004 Thomson Learning/South-Western

21

Y

X

5

0 5 1012

FIGURE 1A.3: Changes in the Y-Intercept of a Linear Function

10

12

10 XY5 XY

Page 22: Appendix to Chapter 1 Mathematics Used in Microeconomics © 2004 Thomson Learning/South-Western

22

Y

X

5

0 5 1012

FIGURE 1A.3: Changes in the Y-Intercept of a Linear Function

10

12 12 XY10 XY

5 XY

Page 23: Appendix to Chapter 1 Mathematics Used in Microeconomics © 2004 Thomson Learning/South-Western

23

Nonlinear Functions

Figure 1A.4 shows the graph of the nonlinear function Y = -X2 + 15X

As the graph shows, the slope of the line is not constant but, in this case, diminishes as X increases

This results in a concave graph which could reflect the principle of diminishing returns

Page 24: Appendix to Chapter 1 Mathematics Used in Microeconomics © 2004 Thomson Learning/South-Western

24

Y

60

50

40

A

30

20

10

0 1 2 3 4 5 6 X

FIGURE 1.A.4: Graph of the Quadratic Function Y = X2 + 15X

Page 25: Appendix to Chapter 1 Mathematics Used in Microeconomics © 2004 Thomson Learning/South-Western

25

Y

60

50

40

A

B

30

20

10

0 1 2 3 4 5 6 X

FIGURE 1.A.4: Graph of the Quadratic Function Y = X2 + 15X

Page 26: Appendix to Chapter 1 Mathematics Used in Microeconomics © 2004 Thomson Learning/South-Western

26

The Slope of a Nonlinear Function

The graph of a nonlinear function is not a straight line

Therefore it does not have the same slope at every point

The slope of a nonlinear function at a particular point is defined as the slope of the straight line that is tangent to the function at that point.

Page 27: Appendix to Chapter 1 Mathematics Used in Microeconomics © 2004 Thomson Learning/South-Western

27

Marginal Effects

The marginal effect is the change in Y brought about by one unit change in X at a particular value of X (Also the slope of the function)

For a linear function this will be constant, but for a nonlinear function it will vary from point to point

Page 28: Appendix to Chapter 1 Mathematics Used in Microeconomics © 2004 Thomson Learning/South-Western

28

Average Effects

The average effect is the ratio of Y to X at a particular value of X (the slope of a ray to a point)

In Figure 1A.4, the ray that goes through A lies about the ray that goes through B indicating a higher average value at A than at B

Page 29: Appendix to Chapter 1 Mathematics Used in Microeconomics © 2004 Thomson Learning/South-Western

29

APPLICATION 1A.1: Property Tax Assessment

The bottom line in Figure 1 represents the linear function Y = $10,000 + $50X, where Y is the sales price of a house and X is its square footage

If, other things equal, the same house but with a view is worth $30,000 more, the top line Y = $40,000 + $50X represents this relationship

Page 30: Appendix to Chapter 1 Mathematics Used in Microeconomics © 2004 Thomson Learning/South-Western

30

House value(dollars)

40,000

110,000

160,000 House withoutview

10,000

Floor area(square feet)

0 2,0003,000

FIGURE 1: Relationship between the Floor Area of a House and Its Market Value

Page 31: Appendix to Chapter 1 Mathematics Used in Microeconomics © 2004 Thomson Learning/South-Western

31

House value(dollars)

40,000

110,000

160,000House with view

House withoutview

10,000

Floor area(square feet)

0 2,0003,000

FIGURE 1: Relationship between the Floor Area of a House and Its Market Value

Page 32: Appendix to Chapter 1 Mathematics Used in Microeconomics © 2004 Thomson Learning/South-Western

32

Calculus and Marginalism

In graphical terms, the derivative of a function and its slope are the same concept

Both provide a measure of the marginal inpact of X on Y

Derivatives provide a convenient way of studying marginal effects.

Page 33: Appendix to Chapter 1 Mathematics Used in Microeconomics © 2004 Thomson Learning/South-Western

33

APPLICATION 1A.2: Progressive and Flat Taxes

Advocates of tax fairness argue that income taxes should progressive so that richer people should pay a higher fraction of their incomes in taxes– This is illustrated in Figure 1 by the nonlinear line

OT that becomes steeper as taxable income increases

– This represents an increasing marginal tax rate

Page 34: Appendix to Chapter 1 Mathematics Used in Microeconomics © 2004 Thomson Learning/South-Western

34

TaxLiability$1,000

OT

10

50

40

30

20

Taxableincome

($1,000)

0 25 50 75 100 125 150 175

FIGURE 1: Progressive Rates Compared to a Flat Tax Schedule

Page 35: Appendix to Chapter 1 Mathematics Used in Microeconomics © 2004 Thomson Learning/South-Western

35

APPLICATION 1A.2: Progressive and Flat Taxes

Opponents of progressive taxes have argued for a flat tax

The straight line OT’ represents a proposal where the first $18,000 of taxable income would not be taxed with a flat tax of 17 percent on additional taxable income– This would also be progressive but not as much as

in the current system

Page 36: Appendix to Chapter 1 Mathematics Used in Microeconomics © 2004 Thomson Learning/South-Western

36

TaxLiability$1,000

OT

OT’

10

50

40

30

20

Taxableincome

($1,000)

0 25 50 75 100 125 150 175

FIGURE 1: Progressive Rates Compared to a Flat Tax Schedule

Page 37: Appendix to Chapter 1 Mathematics Used in Microeconomics © 2004 Thomson Learning/South-Western

37

Functions of Two or More Variables

The dependent variable can be a function of more than one independent variable

The general equation for the case where the dependent variable Y is a function of two independent variables X and Z is

),( ZXfY

Page 38: Appendix to Chapter 1 Mathematics Used in Microeconomics © 2004 Thomson Learning/South-Western

38

A Simple Example

Suppose the relationship between the dependent variable (Y) and the two independent variables (X and Z) is given by

Some values for this function are shown in Table 1A.2

ZXY

Page 39: Appendix to Chapter 1 Mathematics Used in Microeconomics © 2004 Thomson Learning/South-Western

39

TABLE 1A.2: Values of X, Z, and Y that satisfy the Relationship Y = X·Z

X Z Y1 1 11 2 21 3 31 4 42 1 22 2 42 3 62 4 83 1 33 2 63 3 93 4 124 1 44 2 84 3 124 4 16

Page 40: Appendix to Chapter 1 Mathematics Used in Microeconomics © 2004 Thomson Learning/South-Western

40

Graphing Functions of Two Variables

Contour lines are frequently used to graph functions with two independent variables

Contour lines are lines in two dimensions that show the sets of values of the independent variables that yield the same value for the dependent variable

Contour lines for the equation Y = X·Z are shown in Figure 1A.5

Page 41: Appendix to Chapter 1 Mathematics Used in Microeconomics © 2004 Thomson Learning/South-Western

41

Z

9

4

3

2

1

0 1 2 3 4 9 X

FIGURE 1A.5: Contour Lines for Y = X·Z

4Y9Y

1Y

Page 42: Appendix to Chapter 1 Mathematics Used in Microeconomics © 2004 Thomson Learning/South-Western

42

Simultaneous Equations

These are a set of equations with more than one variable that must be solved together for a particular solution

When two variables, say X and Y, are related by two different equations, it is sometime possible to solve these equations to get a set of values for X and Y that satisfy both equations

Page 43: Appendix to Chapter 1 Mathematics Used in Microeconomics © 2004 Thomson Learning/South-Western

43

Simultaneous Equations

1

3

YX

YXThe equations [1A.17]

can be solved for the unique solution

1

2

Y

X

Page 44: Appendix to Chapter 1 Mathematics Used in Microeconomics © 2004 Thomson Learning/South-Western

44

Changing Solutions for Simultaneous Equations

1

5

YX

YXThe equations [1A.19]

can be solved for the unique solution

2

3

Y

X

Page 45: Appendix to Chapter 1 Mathematics Used in Microeconomics © 2004 Thomson Learning/South-Western

45

Graphing Simultaneous Equations

The two simultaneous equations systems, 1A.17 and 1A.19 are graphed in Figure 1A.6

The intersection of the graphs of the equations show the solutions to the equations systems

These graphs are very similar to supply and demand graphs

Page 46: Appendix to Chapter 1 Mathematics Used in Microeconomics © 2004 Thomson Learning/South-Western

46

Y

5

3

2

1

0 1 2 3 5X

Figure 1A.6: Solving Simultaneous Equations

XY 3

1XY

Page 47: Appendix to Chapter 1 Mathematics Used in Microeconomics © 2004 Thomson Learning/South-Western

47

Y

5

3

2

1

0 1 2 3 5X

Figure 1A.6: Solving Simultaneous Equations

XY 5

XY 3

1XY

Page 48: Appendix to Chapter 1 Mathematics Used in Microeconomics © 2004 Thomson Learning/South-Western

48

APPLICATION 1A.3: Can Iraq Affect Oil Prices?

Assume the demand for crude oil is given by

PQD 4.080 where QD is crude oil demanded (in millions of barrels per day) and P price in dollars per barrel.

Assume the supply of crude oil is given byPQS 6.055

The solution to these equations, market equilibrium, is P = 25 and QS = QD = 70 and can be found by

70Q 25,Por 6.0554.080 P

Page 49: Appendix to Chapter 1 Mathematics Used in Microeconomics © 2004 Thomson Learning/South-Western

49

APPLICATION 1A.3:Can Iraq Affect Oil Prices?

Iraq produces about 2.5 million barrels of oil per day. The impact of the decision to sell no oil can be evaluated by assuming that the supply curve in Figure 1 shifts to S’ whose equation is given by

PPQS 6.05.526.0)5.255(

Repeating the algebra yields a new equilibrium, as shown in Figure 1, of P=27.50 and Q = 69. The reduction in oil supply raised the price and decreased consumption. The higher price caused non-OPEC producers to supply about 0.5 million additional barrels.

Page 50: Appendix to Chapter 1 Mathematics Used in Microeconomics © 2004 Thomson Learning/South-Western

50

Price($/barrel) S

D20

22

24

26

28

30

32

Q((millionsbarrels)

62 64 666870 68 70 72 74

FIGURE 1: Effect of OPEC Output Restrictions on World Oil Market

Page 51: Appendix to Chapter 1 Mathematics Used in Microeconomics © 2004 Thomson Learning/South-Western

51

Price($/barrel) S

D20

22

24

26

28

30

32

Q((millionsbarrels)

66 68 70 68 70 72 74

FIGURE 1: Effect of OPEC Output Restrictions on World Oil Market

S’

Page 52: Appendix to Chapter 1 Mathematics Used in Microeconomics © 2004 Thomson Learning/South-Western

52

Empirical Microeconomics and Econometrics

Economists test the validity of their models by looking at data from the real world

Econometrics is used for this purpose Two important aspects of econometrics are

– random influences– the ceteris paribus assumption

Page 53: Appendix to Chapter 1 Mathematics Used in Microeconomics © 2004 Thomson Learning/South-Western

53

Random Influences

No economic model exhibits perfect accuracy so actual price and quantity values will be scattered around the “true” demand curve

Figure 1A.7 shows the unknown true demand curve and the actual points observed in the data from the real world

The problem is to infer the true demand curve

Page 54: Appendix to Chapter 1 Mathematics Used in Microeconomics © 2004 Thomson Learning/South-Western

54

Price(P)

D

Quantity (Q)

FIGURE 1A.7: Inferring the Demand Curve from Real-World Data

Page 55: Appendix to Chapter 1 Mathematics Used in Microeconomics © 2004 Thomson Learning/South-Western

55

Random Influences

Technically, the problem is statistical inference: the use of actual data and statistical techniques to determine quantitative economic relationships

Since no single straight line will fit all of the data points, the researcher must give careful consideration to the random influences to get the best line possible

Page 56: Appendix to Chapter 1 Mathematics Used in Microeconomics © 2004 Thomson Learning/South-Western

56

The Ceteris Paribus Assumption

To control for the “other things equal” assumption two things must be done– Data should be collected on all of the other factors

that affect demand, and– appropriate procedures must be used to control for

these measurable factors in the analysis

Generally the researcher has to make some compromises which leads to many controversies in testing economic models