author's personal copy - its - boston college · immulogic pharmaceutical corporation (b-2)....

32
This article appeared in a journal published by Elsevier. The attached copy is furnished to the author for internal non-commercial research and education use, including for instruction at the authors institution and sharing with colleagues. Other uses, including reproduction and distribution, or selling or licensing copies, or posting to personal, institutional or third party websites are prohibited. In most cases authors are permitted to post their version of the article (e.g. in Word or Tex form) to their personal website or institutional repository. Authors requiring further information regarding Elsevier’s archiving and manuscript policies are encouraged to visit: http://www.elsevier.com/copyright

Upload: dangkiet

Post on 12-Jun-2018

214 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Author's personal copy - ITS - Boston College · ImmuLogic Pharmaceutical Corporation (B-2). To quote: The one certainty about the current open window for biotechnology initial public

This article appeared in a journal published by Elsevier. The attachedcopy is furnished to the author for internal non-commercial researchand education use, including for instruction at the authors institution

and sharing with colleagues.

Other uses, including reproduction and distribution, or selling orlicensing copies, or posting to personal, institutional or third party

websites are prohibited.

In most cases authors are permitted to post their version of thearticle (e.g. in Word or Tex form) to their personal website orinstitutional repository. Authors requiring further information

regarding Elsevier’s archiving and manuscript policies areencouraged to visit:

http://www.elsevier.com/copyright

Page 2: Author's personal copy - ITS - Boston College · ImmuLogic Pharmaceutical Corporation (B-2). To quote: The one certainty about the current open window for biotechnology initial public

Author's personal copy

IPO waves, product market competition, and the going publicdecision: Theory and evidence$

Thomas J. Chemmanur a,�, Jie He b

a Carroll School of Management, Boston College, MA 02467, USAb Terry College of Business, University of Georgia, GA 30602, USA

a r t i c l e i n f o

Article history:

Received 30 December 2009

Received in revised form

19 July 2010

Accepted 25 October 2010Available online 16 March 2011

JEL classification:

G32

Keywords:

IPO waves

Product market competition

Going public

a b s t r a c t

We develop a new rationale for initial public offering (IPO) waves based on product

market considerations. Two firms, with differing productivity levels, compete in an

industry with a significant probability of a positive productivity shock. Going public,

though costly, not only allows a firm to raise external capital cheaply, but also enables it

to grab market share from its private competitors. We solve for the decision of each firm

to go public versus remain private, and the optimal timing of going public. In

equilibrium, even firms with sufficient internal capital to fund their new investment

may go public, driven by the possibility of their product market competitors going

public. IPO waves may arise in equilibrium even in industries which do not experience a

productivity shock. Our model predicts that firms going public during an IPO wave

will have lower productivity and post-IPO profitability but larger cash holdings

than those going public off the wave; it makes similar predictions for firms going

public later versus earlier in an IPO wave. We empirically test and find support for these

predictions.

& 2011 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved.

1. Introduction

The existence of IPO waves, otherwise known as ‘‘hot’’IPO markets, has been widely documented: see, e.g.,Ritter (1984). The reasons for the existence of such IPOwaves, however, are less widely understood. Two recent

theoretical models of IPO waves are Pastor and Veronesi(2005) and Alti (2005). Pastor and Veronesi (2005) arguethat IPO waves are generated due to the ‘‘real option’’effect of going public: entrepreneurs possess a real optionto take their firms public, invest part of the IPO proceeds,and begin producing, and, in a setting of time-varying

Contents lists available at ScienceDirect

journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/jfec

Journal of Financial Economics

0304-405X/$ - see front matter & 2011 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved.

doi:10.1016/j.jfineco.2011.03.009

$ For helpful comments and discussions, we thank Kenneth Ahern, Pierluigi Balduzzi, Walid Busaba, David Chapman, Craig Dunbar, Joseph Fan, Shan

He, Clifford Holderness, Gang Hu, Jiekun Huang, Tim Jenkinson, Yawen Jiao, Karthik Krishnan, Praveen Kumar, Alan Marcus, Ronald Masulis, Debarshi

Nandy, Tom Noe, Neil Stoughton, Paul Povel, Jun Qian, Jonathan Reuter, Ronnie Sadka, Philip Strahan, Robert Taggart, Hassan Tehranian, and Xuan Tian.

We also thank seminar participants at Boston College, The Chinese University of Hong Kong, Concordia University, George Washington University,

Hebrew University of Jerusalem, Nanyang Technological University, National University of Singapore, Oxford University, Singapore Management

University, Tel-Aviv University, University of Georgia, University of Houston, University of Illinois at Chicago, University of New South Wales, University

of Western Ontario, and conference participants at the RICAFE 2008 conference at Amsterdam, the FIRS 2009 Meetings at Prague, the 2009 Southwestern

Finance Association Meetings, the 2009 Financial Management Association Meetings, the 2009 Midwestern Finance Association Meetings, the 2009

Eastern Finance Association Meetings, the 2009 Northern Finance Association Meetings, and the 2009 Southern Finance Association Meetings for helpful

comments. Special thanks to Bill Schwert and an anonymous referee for several helpful comments. The research presented in this paper was conducted

while the authors were special sworn status researchers at the Boston Research Data Center of the U.S. Census Bureau. Any opinions and conclusions

expressed herein are those of the authors and do not necessarily represent the views of the U.S. Census Bureau. All results have been reviewed to ensure

that no confidential information is disclosed. Any remaining errors or omissions are the responsibility of the authors.� Corresponding author.

E-mail address: [email protected] (T.J. Chemmanur).

Journal of Financial Economics 101 (2011) 382–412

Page 3: Author's personal copy - ITS - Boston College · ImmuLogic Pharmaceutical Corporation (B-2). To quote: The one certainty about the current open window for biotechnology initial public

Author's personal copy

market conditions, choose the best time to exercise thisoption. When stock market conditions are sufficientlyfavorable (expected market return is low, expected aggre-gate profitability is high, and prior uncertainty is high),many entrepreneurs exercise their options to go public,thus generating an IPO wave. Alti (2005) focuses insteadon information spillovers across IPOs to generate IPOwaves. He considers a setting in which IPOs are sold toinstitutional investors, who are asymmetrically informedabout a valuation factor common across private firms.Since IPO offer prices are set based on investors’ indica-tions of interest, the outcome of an IPO (a high versus lowIPO offer price) reflects information that was previouslyprivate, reducing information asymmetry across investorsand reducing valuation uncertainty for future issuers,thereby triggering an IPO wave.

While the above two theoretical analyses have drivingforces quite different from each other, they also have onefeature in common: they are both driven by considera-tions of stock market valuation and stock returns: theaggregate stock market in the case of Pastor and Veronesi(2005), and stock valuation in the IPO market in the caseof Alti (2005). While stock market valuation is indeed animportant driving force behind the creation of IPO waves,another driving force that has not been analyzed so far inthe literature is product market competition. The objec-tive of this paper is to develop a theory of the timing of afirm’s going public decision and IPO waves based onproduct market considerations that allow us to answerseveral interesting questions: First, which industries aremost likely to have an IPO wave? Second, what are thedifferences between firms that go public ‘‘on the wave’’(i.e., as part of an IPO wave) versus ‘‘off the wave’’ (i.e.,either individually, or as part of a cold IPO market) both interms of pre-IPO productivity and post-IPO product mar-ket performance? Third, within the set of firms goingpublic as part of an IPO wave, does timing matter: i.e., isthere a difference in productivity and post-IPO perfor-mance (as well as other firm characteristics) betweenfirms that go public earlier in an IPO wave versus later inthe wave?1 Our theoretical model answers these andrelated questions, and we empirically test the implica-tions of our theory.

Our theory departs from existing analyses with theassumption that going public not only allows a firm toraise capital at a lower cost than if it were a private firm,but also allows it to grab market share from competitorswho remain private. It is particularly interesting toexamine, both theoretically and empirically, the implica-tions of the notion that going public enables a firm to grab

market share from competitors in the product market,since there is some anecdotal evidence from practitionersthat this is indeed the case in practice.2 We do not makeany assumptions regarding the precise mechanismsthrough which firms going public early are able to grabmarket share from their competitors: possible mechan-isms include gaining additional credibility with customersand suppliers; being able to hire higher-quality employ-ees as a public firm and rewarding them more efficientlyusing stock and stock options; and being able to acquirerelated firms in the same industry (holding patentsvaluable for introducing various product innovations)through takeovers paid for using their own (publiclytraded) stock.3

We consider an industry with two firms: firm 1 andfirm 2, both of which are private to begin with. Each firmhas a scalable project with decreasing returns to scale,which it proposes to implement. Firm 1 has higherproductivity of capital compared to firm 2, so that itsequilibrium scale of investment is higher than that of firm2. Each firm has a certain amount of internal capitalavailable to it as a private firm. However, if the amountof capital required for investment exceeds the aboveinternal capital, the firm needs to either scale back itsinvestment (i.e., operate at a scale smaller than its optimallevel) or raise external financing by going public.4 Thus,going public has two benefits in our setting: it allows thefirm to raise external financing if necessary, and alsoallows it to grab market share from other firms in theindustry that are private. On the other hand, going publicis costly: we assume that each firm has to incur asignificant cost if it chooses to go public.

Each firm knows its own productivity, and also thattheir industry may soon experience a positive productiv-ity shock with a certain probability. We assume that, inthe absence of a productivity shock, the available internal

1 While we are not aware of any prior empirical analyses of this

question, there is some anecdotal evidence that higher-quality firms go

public earlier in an IPO wave: see, e.g., the Harvard Business School Case

ImmuLogic Pharmaceutical Corporation (B-2). To quote: ‘‘The one

certainty about the current open window for biotechnology initial public

offerings (IPOs) was that sooner or later it would shut again. Further-

more, he (Henry McCance) has observed that in past periods of intense

IPO activity, the best firms tended to go public early in the cycle, while

lower-quality firms went public later.’’ See also Ritter and Welch (2002)

for a discussion of practitioner arguments on the timing of firms going

public within an IPO wave.

2 To quote Killian, Smith, and Smith (2001): ‘‘An IPO can establish its

brand and gain loyal customers ahead of competitors. Palm established

itself as the leader with a suite of spiffy handheld devices and great

marketing, grabbing 80% of market share. Then Handspring, founded by

Palm alums, created a device with a twist: add-on modules that allow

Handspring users to download and play music or to access the Internet.

Handspring priced its PDAs aggressively and captured most of the

remaining (market) share. With these two aggressive players dominat-

ing PDA sales, it was very difficult for a new entrant to compete. Even

Microsoft, with its billions of dollars of marketing clout, retreated from

the field.’’ Killian, Smith, and Smith (2001) also give a number of

examples from other industries where firms that went public earlier

were able to grab significant market share in their industry. Examples

include Affymetrix, the maker of microchips that identify and analyze

gene sequences; Petsmart, the pet superstore, which went public ahead

of its competitor, pets.com, and grabbed significant market share; and

Capstone Turbine, the maker of microturbines, which was the first to

introduce such turbines for commercial use.3 Another possibility is that a public firm may compete more

aggressively in the product market than a private firm, since a risk-

averse entrepreneur may find it easier to diversify his personal portfolio

and therefore care less about operating risk after going public: see Chod

and Lyandres (2011), who develop a model formalizing this argument.4 Thus, for simplicity, we assume that it is prohibitively costly for

the firm to raise external financing as a private firm. However, note that

all our results go through as long as the cost of external financing is

significantly cheaper for a public firm compared to that for a private

firm.

T.J. Chemmanur, J. He / Journal of Financial Economics 101 (2011) 382–412 383

Page 4: Author's personal copy - ITS - Boston College · ImmuLogic Pharmaceutical Corporation (B-2). To quote: The one certainty about the current open window for biotechnology initial public

Author's personal copy

capital will be enough to fund the projects of both firm 1and firm 2 at their optimal scale. If, however, a produc-tivity shock is realized, firm 1 (which has higher produc-tivity to begin with) needs to go public to raise externalfinancing in order to operate at its new optimal scale,while firm 2 will continue to have enough internal capitalto operate at its new optimal scale (since, given its lowerlevel of initial productivity, its new optimal scale will besmaller than its available internal capital even after theproductivity shock is realized). We allow a firm to gopublic either early (before the productivity shock isrealized) or late (after the shock is realized). We assumethat there will be two rounds of competition for marketshare between the two firms in the product market: onebefore the productivity shock is realized, and another oneafterward.

We solve for the equilibrium time at which each firmgoes public (if at all), which in turn determines whetheror not there is an IPO wave (we define an IPO wave as asituation where both firms in the industry go public).There are five possible equilibria in our model, dependingon the following four parameter values: the magnitude ofa potential productivity shock; the probability of a pro-ductivity shock; the cost of going public; and the levels ofinitial productivity of each firm in the industry. Considerfirst the benchmark equilibrium, where going publicmerely allows a firm to raise external financing (and doesnot give it any advantage in terms of competing formarket share). In this case, the lower-productivity firm2 remains private throughout, regardless of whether ornot there is a productivity shock, since going public iscostly and it has adequate capital to fund its project at itsoptimal scale even in the event of a productivity shock.Firm 1 will go public only if a productivity shock isrealized, since going public does not give it any advantagein terms of competition for market share, and the onlyreason for going public is to raise external financing(which becomes necessary if and only if a productivityshock is realized).

Consider now the full-fledged model, where goingpublic enables a firm to grab market share from compe-titors. There are three categories of equilibria in this case,depending on the model parameters discussed earlier. Thefirst category of equilibria involves an IPO wave occurringeven without the realization of a productivity shock: i.e.,both firms go public early without waiting to see whethera productivity shock is realized or not. The secondcategory of equilibria involves both firms going public,but at least one of the two firms goes public only if aproductivity shock is realized: in other words, an IPOwave occurs only in the event of a productivity shock. Thethird category of equilibria involves firms going public offthe wave: i.e., only one of the two firms goes public, andthe other remains private throughout.

To understand the intuition behind the above equili-bria, it is useful to consider the costs and benefits of goingpublic versus remaining private, as well as those of goingpublic early versus late. Consider first firm 1. This firm hastwo benefits from going public. First, in the event of aproductivity shock, its internal capital is not sufficient tofund its investment to its optimal level, so that it needs to

raise additional capital by going public. Second, by goingpublic, it can grab market share from firm 2, in the eventthat the latter remains private. Its cost of going public isthe deadweight cost discussed earlier. Now consider firm2. Since its productivity is lower, its only benefit fromgoing public is to prevent firm 1 from grabbing marketshare from it (and to grab market share from firm 1 in theevent that it does not go public); recall that we haveassumed that firm 2’s initial productivity is low enoughthat, even after the shock, it can still fund its investmentat its optimal level using internal capital. Note, however,that a productivity shock nevertheless increases its ben-efit of going public, since its profits from additionalmarket share will be greater if its productivity is greater.For either firm, the trade-off between going public earlyversus late is as follows. The advantage of going publicearly is that the firm is able to grab market share from theother firm (and to prevent the other firm from grabbingmarket share from it) in two rounds of product marketcompetition. The disadvantage of going public early isthat it incurs the cost of going public before it knows forsure whether a productivity shock is realized (so that thefirm may end up being public in a situation where noshock is realized, and it would have been better offremaining private). Note that the benefit of going publicearly versus late is always greater for firm 1 than for firm2 (since it has multiple reasons for going public, whilefirm 2 has only the benefit of grabbing market share); onthe other hand, the cost of going public is the same forboth firms. We show that the above trade-offs result inthe higher-productivity firm going public alone in equili-brium in the absence of an IPO wave. Further, if theequilibrium involves an IPO wave, the higher-productivityfirm always goes public either earlier than or at the sametime as the lower-productivity firm.

Our theoretical analysis yields several testable predic-tions. The first prediction is that, on average, firms goingpublic outside an IPO wave (i.e., in a cold market) willhave higher productivity and post-IPO profitability thanthose going public within an IPO wave. Second, onaverage, firms going public earlier in an IPO wave willhave higher productivity and post-IPO profitability thanthose going public later in the wave. Third, since ourmodel predicts that firms going public outside an IPOwave have higher average pre-IPO productivity, and giventhat higher-productivity firms have a larger optimal scale,firms going public in an IPO wave will, on average, holdmore cash on hand than firms going public off the wave(for a given amount raised in the IPO). Similarly, ourmodel predicts that firms going public later in an IPOwave will, on average, hold more cash on hand than firmsgoing public earlier in the wave (for a given amountraised in the IPO).

Before testing the implications of our theory, we firstprovide some evidence regarding our model assumptionthat going public allows a firm to grab market share fromcompetitors who remain private. For this empirical ana-lysis, we make use of the Longitudinal Research Database(LRD) of the U.S. Census Bureau, which covers the entireuniverse of private and public U.S. manufacturing firms.We find that IPO firms experience an increase in their

T.J. Chemmanur, J. He / Journal of Financial Economics 101 (2011) 382–412384

Page 5: Author's personal copy - ITS - Boston College · ImmuLogic Pharmaceutical Corporation (B-2). To quote: The one certainty about the current open window for biotechnology initial public

Author's personal copy

market share soon after they go public at the expense oftheir private competitors (Table 3). Further, IPOs in a givenindustry are associated with a reduction in the marketshare of same-industry competitors, and this negativecorrelation is larger for competitors that are private(Table 4).5 There are two possible scenarios that canexplain the above findings. First, going public causes anincrease in the IPO firm’s market share and a reduction inits competitors’ market share (which is our modelassumption). Second, the anticipation of increased marketshare induces a firm to go public. Without a valid instru-ment for the going public decision of a firm, it is difficult todistinguish between the above two scenarios. Thus, whilethe above results are broadly consistent with the mainassumption of our model, we do not wish to claim thatgoing public causes an increase in market share.6 In otherwords, the objective of the above analysis is not to presentconvincing empirical support for the above assumption ofour model. We believe that, like all other models, ourmodel should be evaluated based on the evidence wepresent here regarding its predictions.

We test the predictions of our model using threedifferent data sets. We obtain our overall IPO sample fromthe Thomson Financial Securities Data Corporation (SDC)new issues database. We obtain the data required tocalculate the total factor productivity (TFP) and the marketshare of firms remaining private as well as those goingpublic (or are already public) from the LRD of the U.S.Census Bureau. Finally, we obtain data on the accountingperformance of IPO firms subsequent to going public (likereturn on assets (ROA) and cash holdings) from theCompustat database. To compare on-the-wave IPO firmsversus off-the-wave ones in the same industry, we definethe ‘‘hotness’’ of an IPO market as the total number of IPOsin the same Fama-French industry within a 90-day win-dow symmetrically surrounding the issuance date for anygiven IPO and use this number as a raw measure of thehotness of the IPO market in that industry for theparticular issuance date under consideration. Consistentwith our first prediction, we find that a firm that goespublic within a hot period of eight other same-industryIPOs will, on average, have total factor productivity (TFP)0.028 less than a firm that goes public within a cold periodof only one other same-industry IPO. Given that the meanof TFP in our sample is 0.046, this represents a 61%difference in TFP, which is economically significant. Wealso find that a firm that goes public within a hot period ofeight other same-industry IPOs will, on average, have apost-issuance ROA 1.1% less than a firm that goes public

within a cold period of only one other same-industry IPO.Given that the mean of post-IPO ROA in our sample is 5%,this represents a 20% difference in post-issuance operatingperformance. We also use two refinements of the abovemeasure for hotness and find similar results.

To compare leaders and followers in an IPO wave for aparticular industry, we first identify and define IPO waveswithin that industry and then rank the IPOs in our samplewithin each wave by the order of their issuance dates.Consistent with our second prediction, we find that a firmthat goes public earlier in an IPO wave (among the first25% of firms going public in this wave) will, on average,have TFP 0.081 more than a firm that goes public later inthe wave (among the last 25% of firms going public in thiswave). Given that the mean of TFP in our sample is 0.046,this represents a 176% difference in TFP. Further, we findthat a firm that goes public earlier in an IPO wave (amongthe first 25% of firms going public in the wave) will, onaverage, have an ROA 2.3% more than a firm that goespublic later in the wave (among the last 25% of firmsgoing public in the wave). Given that the mean ROA in oursample is 5%, this represents a 46% difference in post-issuance ROA. Similar results hold if we use alternativemeasures of how early an IPO takes place within a wave.

The above empirical results regarding the TFP as wellas post-IPO profitability of firms going public on the waveversus off the wave, and that of firms going public early ina wave versus later in the wave are also consistent withthe predictions of a variation on the model of Pastor andVeronesi (2005) which relies on stock market conditions(details in Sections 7.2.1 and 7.3.1). We therefore conductseveral robustness tests to distinguish our predictionsfrom those of that model and find that, even afterincorporating proxies for short-term and long-term mar-ket conditions as controls, there is residual empiricalsupport for our model predictions.

We also find evidence supporting our other predic-tions. Our results show that, on average, firms that gopublic in an IPO wave will hold more cash on hand afterthe IPO and experience a larger increase in cash and cashequivalents around the IPO date than firms that go publicoff the wave. Similarly, we find that firms going publiclater in an IPO wave on average hold a larger cash balanceon hand after the IPO and experience a larger increase incash and cash equivalents around the IPO date than firmsthat go public earlier in the wave. Finally, since our modelargues that product market competition is an importantfactor driving firms’ going public decisions, we analyzewhether and how industry concentration relates to therelationship between post-issuance operating perfor-mance and IPO timing (‘‘on the wave’’ versus ‘‘off thewave,’’ and ‘‘early in a wave’’ versus ‘‘later in the wave’’).We find that a higher level of industry concentrationtends to weaken the difference in post-IPO performancebetween firms that go public on the wave versus off thewave, and between firms going public earlier in a waveversus later in the wave. We discuss the implications ofthis finding for our theory in Section 7.5.

Apart from the two theoretical analyses of IPO wavesdiscussed earlier, the theoretical literature most directlyrelated to this paper is the literature on the going public

5 See also Hsu, Reed, and Rocholl (2010), who find that firms

experience negative stock price reactions to completed IPOs in their

industry and positive stock price reactions to IPO withdrawals. Further,

they show that following a successful IPO in their industry, competing

firms show significant deterioration in their operating performance.

Slovin, Sushka, and Ferraro (1995) present similar evidence in the

context of equity carve-outs.6 It is difficult to find a convincing firm-level instrumental variable

for a firm’s going public decision that satisfies the exclusion restriction

requiring that the variable, while correlated with the going public

decision, should not directly affect the subsequent product market share

of the firm going public.

T.J. Chemmanur, J. He / Journal of Financial Economics 101 (2011) 382–412 385

Page 6: Author's personal copy - ITS - Boston College · ImmuLogic Pharmaceutical Corporation (B-2). To quote: The one certainty about the current open window for biotechnology initial public

Author's personal copy

decision: see, e.g., Chemmanur and Fulghieri (1999) orMaksimovic and Pichler (2001). In a recent paper, Spiegeland Tookes (2007) develop a model of the relationshipbetween product market innovation, product marketcompetition, and the public versus private financingdecision in an infinite horizon model. In their model, theadvantage of going public is the ability to obtain cheaperfinancing while the disadvantage is the disclosurerequirements associated with going public that allowcompetitors in the firm’s industry to copy the innovation.Another related model is Pastor, Taylor, and Veronesi(2009), in which an entrepreneur trades off the diversifi-cation benefits of going public against the cost of doing so(the loss of his benefits of control), in the presence ofBayesian learning about the average productivity of hisfirm. IPO waves are not the main focus of the abovemodels.7,8 In terms of empirical literature, this paper ismost directly related to the papers studying hot and coldIPO markets (see, e.g., Helwege and Liang, 2004) and theliterature studying fluctuations in IPO volume (see, e.g.,Lowry, 2003; Lowry and Schwert, 2002; or Benveniste,Ljungqvist, Wilhelm, and Yu, 2003). Unlike our paper,Helwege and Liang (2004) mostly study IPO waves in theentire equity market rather than with respect to eachindustry, and conclude that there is no difference in thequality of firms going public in hot and cold IPO markets.In contrast to their findings, our empirical analysis indi-cates that there is indeed a significant difference in bothpre-IPO productivity and post-IPO operating performance(both in the short and the long run) between firms goingpublic during an IPO wave versus those going public offthe wave. The empirical literature on the going publicdecision (see, e.g., Pagano, Panetta, and Zingales, 1998; orChemmanur, He, and Nandy, 2010) is also indirectlyrelated to this paper.9

The rest of the paper is organized as follows. In Section2, we describe our model setup, and in Section 3 wecharacterize its equilibria. We describe our testable pre-dictions in Section 4 and our data and sample selection

procedures in Section 5. We discuss variable constructionand summary statistics in Section 6. In Section 7, wedescribe our empirical results and conclude in Section 8.

2. The model

We consider the going public decision of two compet-ing private firms in an industry. For simplicity, we assumethat the two firms are duopolies who split the totalproduct market between them. The model has four dates(time 0, 1, 2, and 3). At time 0, the two private firms areendowed with the same amount of initial capital and thesame form of cash-flow-generating technology. Firm 1 hasa market share of m and firm 2 has the rest (1�m).10

Without loss of generality, we assume firm 1 to have ahigher productivity A1 than firm 2, with productivity A2

(A14A2). As we shall see in Section 2.1, both firms’ long-term (time 3) valuation increases with their market shareand production efficiency (which depends on their pro-ductivity as well as their available capital).

At time 1, each firm knows that a productivity shockmay take place at time 2, in which case its productivitymay increase by amount DA ð40Þ with probability p. Wedenote the enhanced productivity of firm i asAiH � AiþDA. Given this distribution of potential shocks,the firms will calculate their expected optimal capitallevel and may go public in case of an expected fundingshortage. Going public, at a fixed cost of B, has twobenefits. First, it can provide cheaper capital for a firm’sproduction than debt or private placements (i.e., weassume that alternative financing methods are too costlyto be feasible). Second, it can improve a firm’s efficiency ingrabbing market share from its competitors, for example,by enhancing its credibility with customers and suppliers;allowing it to hire higher-quality employees as a publicfirm and rewarding them more efficiently using stock andstock options; or allowing it to acquire related firms in thesame industry through takeovers paid for using theirpublicly traded stock. After the firms make their goingpublic decisions, they will start the first round of productmarket competition, the details of which will be discussedin Section 2.2.

At time 2, productivity shocks, if any, are realized, anda firm can go public at this stage if it has not already doneso at time 1. The capital raised at this stage and theenhancement in its market-share-grabbing ability willalso help the firm increase long-term (time 3) cash flowsand thus raise its market valuation. The second round ofproduct market competition now takes place and the totalmarket share is redivided between the two rivals.

At time 3, the firms’ long-run cash flows are realizedand distributed to shareholders, and they liquidate. Weassume that all agents (firm managers, shareholders, andinvestors) are risk-neutral and the risk-free rate is zero.Everything in the model is publicly observable and

7 Yung, C- olak, and Wang (2008) develop a model in which time-

varying investment opportunities lead to time-varying adverse selection

in the IPO market. They test this model taking as given the premise that

asymmetric information is revealed over time, and find that hot-market

IPOs are associated with greater cross-sectional return variance and

higher delisting rates. Khanna, Noe, and Sonti (2008) develop a model of

going public in which screening IPOs requires specialized labor, which is

in fixed supply. A sudden increase in demand for IPO financing increases

the compensation of this screening labor, which results in reduced

screening, resulting in submarginal firms entering the IPO market. Their

model predicts increased underpricing in hot markets. Boot, Gopalan,

and Thakor (2006) study an entrepreneur’s choice between private and

public ownership when insiders and outsiders disagree about the best

way to maximize firm value.8 Our paper is also broadly related to the literature on product and

financial market interactions: see, e.g., Chemmanur and Yan (2009), who

analyze the relationship between product market advertising and new

equity issues (IPOs and SEOs), and Stoughton, Wong, and Zechner

(2001), who argue that the decision of a firm to go public may serve

to signal high quality to the product market.9 Our paper is also broadly related to the large theoretical and

empirical literature on IPOs: see, e.g., Chemmanur (1993), Allen and

Faulhaber (1989), Welch (1989), and Grinblatt and Hwang (1989), for

theoretical IPO models, and Ritter and Welch (2002) for a review.

10 Since firms already gone public play no role in our model, we

simply assume that they own zero market share. As a result, the sum of

market share for the two private firms is assumed to be one. Alterna-

tively, we can specify the sum of market share to be d ð0odo1Þ, which

allows our subsequent analysis to go through unaffected.

T.J. Chemmanur, J. He / Journal of Financial Economics 101 (2011) 382–412386

Page 7: Author's personal copy - ITS - Boston College · ImmuLogic Pharmaceutical Corporation (B-2). To quote: The one certainty about the current open window for biotechnology initial public

Author's personal copy

information is symmetric. The sequence of events isdepicted in Fig. 1.

2.1. The firm’s problem

Each firm’s objective is to maximize its long-term cashflows at time 3, which depends on the amount of capital ituses to generate cash flows as well as its market share inthe product market. Specifically, firm i’s cash flow at time3, Vi, is given as follows:

Vi ¼ fAIIi ðm

IIi Þ

1�gðK�i Þ

g�cK�i gþKi, 0rK�i rKi, i¼ 1,2, ð1Þ

where Ki is the amount of capital firm i possesses at theend of time 2. If the firm remains private for the twoperiods, then Ki is simply K0, its original capital endow-ment (which is assumed to be the same for both firms). If,on the other hand, firm i goes public in any period (time 1or 2), Ki will become K0þEi, where Ei denotes the amountof capital raised in the offering. mi

IIis firm i’s market share

at the end of time 2 (i.e., after two rounds of productmarket competition), whose level depends on both firms’going public decisions. The details of product marketcompetition are provided in Section 2.2. Ai

IIis firm i’s

productivity at time 2. If it experiences the productivityshock at time 2, then Ai

IIis AiH. Otherwise Ai

IIremains at Ai.

Kin, the capital firm i uses to generate cash flows, cannot

exceed Ki, the total amount of capital it owns at time 2. c

is the constant marginal cost of deploying each unit ofcapital (i.e., it is the production cost per unit of capital),0ocr1. Lastly, we adopt a Cobb-Douglas productionfunction and assume that 0ogo1 so that the cash-flow-generating technology exhibits decreasing returnsto scale in its capital usage.11 All parameters arepublicly known.

Given the above setup, it is straightforward to showthat the efficient level of capital chosen by firm i, Ki

e, is

linearly increasing in its long-term market share and also

increasing in the firm’s productivity: Kei �mII

i ðAIIi Þ

1=ð1�gÞ

ðc=gÞ1=ðg�1Þ and K�i ¼Min½Kei ,Ki�.

2.2. Product market competition

Product market competition in this model involves thefirms’ campaigns to gain market share by attracting eachother’s customers.12 There are two successive rounds ofcompetition in our model, during which each firm relieson its own market power to launch marketing campaignsand to attract customers away from its rival. Specifically,the evolution of market share for firm i is given by

mtþ1i ¼mt

iþð1�mti Þs

tþ1i �mt

i stþ1j , iaj and t¼ 0,1, ð2Þ

where mit

is firm i’s market share at the end of time t andsi

tþ1is its ability to grab rivals’ market share during the

round of competition at time tþ1 (t¼ 0,1). Here, m01 ¼m

and m02 ¼ 1�m. si

tþ1denotes the effectiveness of market-

ing efforts made by firm i at time tþ1. While firm i can

grab its competitor’s time-t market share ðmtj � 1�mt

i Þ

with intensity sitþ1

, the other firm (firm j) can also attractcustomers away from firm i at the same time. Thus, itsfinal market share depends on both players’ relativemarketing abilities.

To make the model realistic yet tractable, we assumethat a public firm’s ability to grab market share after itsIPO is linear in its existing market share. Moreover, aprivate firm’s ability to grab market share from competi-tors is normalized to be zero. Specifically, we assume:

stþ1i ¼

smti if firm i is public,

0 if firm i is private,

(0oso1: ð3Þ

Here, s denotes the per-unit-market-share advantage thata public firm enjoys relative to a private firm in terms ofproduct market competition. If firm i goes public early(i.e., before the first round of competition at time 1), it cangrab market share from firm j for two rounds (at time 1and 2). In other words, a late IPO may be costly due to theloss in market share at time 1.13

Time 1 Time 3

Firms get to know thedistribution of productivityshocksFirms choose to go public orremain privateFirst round of product marketcompetition takes place

Time 2

Productivity shocks arerealizedFirms that are private decideagain whether to go publicor remain privateSecond round of productmarket competition takesplace

All cash flowsare realizedEnd of game

Time 0

Both firmsare private

Fig. 1. Sequence of events.

11 We assume a Cobb-Douglas type of production function to

capture the idea that capital and market share are substitutes: the firm

can increase profits either by selling more (if it has greater market share)

or by producing more cheaply (which involves greater investment in

capital). We adopt the above production function for analytical simpli-

city: adopting more complex production functions complicates our

analysis considerably without changing our results qualitatively.

12 The market share competition is a variant of the Lanchester

(1916) battle model, which has been widely adopted in the marketing

literature. Some recent finance papers such as Spiegel and Tookes (2007)

also make use of this model to characterize product market competition.13 The market-share-grabbing technology that we postulate here

does not allow a firm that goes public later (at time 2) to grab back some

of the market share it lost to its public competitor in the previous period

(when it was private). However, even if we allow the firm that goes

public later to grab back some of the market share it lost to its

competitor who went public early, our results will remain qualitatively

T.J. Chemmanur, J. He / Journal of Financial Economics 101 (2011) 382–412 387

Page 8: Author's personal copy - ITS - Boston College · ImmuLogic Pharmaceutical Corporation (B-2). To quote: The one certainty about the current open window for biotechnology initial public

Author's personal copy

If a firm wants to go public, it is better off doing so attime 1 rather than delaying it to time 2: in other words,there is a first-mover advantage from going public early.Let us use firm 1 as an illustration. If the final industryoutcome is that both firms go public, then for firm 1, anIPO at time 1 weakly dominates an IPO at time 2. This isdue to the fact that going public at time 1 will give it animmediate competitive edge while deferring the IPO willresult in a loss of this opportunity and may even subjectthe firm to more aggressive competition from the rivalfirm. Likewise, if the final industry outcome is that onlyfirm 1 goes public, an IPO at time 1 is still weaklydominant. This means that the IPO decision at time 1 isa real option driven by both capital concerns and compe-titive forces. While deferring the IPO decision may savethe firm the cost of going public if its productivity turnsout not to increase and it is unnecessary for it to raiseexternal financing, doing so may sacrifice the opportunityto enlarge its market share at an earlier date. As we willdiscuss in the next section, this trade-off prompts manyfirms to go public purely out of product market competi-tion concerns and drives industry-wide IPO waves.

3. Equilibrium

The equilibrium concept we use is perfect Bayesianequilibrium (PBE). At time 1, both firms choose to eithergo public or remain private. If they go public at time 1,they have no choice to make at time 2.14 Otherwise theycan choose to go public at time 2 after observing therealization of the potential productivity shock. Therefore,a PBE is a complete characterization of all contingentstrategies of the two firms in the two periods. First, wewill analyze the benchmark case where an IPO does notaffect product market competition. We will then proceedto solve the full model where an IPO enhances a firm’scompetitiveness in the product market. Due to spaceconsiderations, in this section we confine ourselves tointuitive discussions of various equilibria and the situa-tions where they arise. Formal propositions with proofscan be obtained from the Internet Appendix B available on

the authors’ Web sites or from the working paper versionof this article.

3.1. Benchmark case: IPO does not affect product market

competition

Given the level of newly raised capital, Ei, and therational expectation of the firm’s long-run market value,Et(Vi), the sharing rule between existing owners (insiders)and new shareholders during an IPO is determined asfollows: the investors will acquire Ei=EtðViÞ fraction of thefirm and the remaining shares belong to the existingowners. Thus, firm insiders will try to maximize the entirefirm’s market value (since their stake in the firm isEtðViÞ�Ei) and will choose its optimal investment policy.We thus do not model any agency problems betweeninsiders and outsiders. Insiders can choose to use only afraction of the capital raised for investment in the firm.Further, unlike physical production which exhausts rawmaterials and other inputs, the capital used here is non-perishable.15 The firm will not use capital beyond theefficient level (Ki

e), which in turn depends on its market

share as well as its productivity at time 2. Depending onwhether firm i experiences the productivity shock at time2, Ki

ecan be either mII

i ðAIIi Þ

1=ð1�gÞðc=gÞ1=ðg�1Þ

�mIIi ke

iL (with-out a productivity shock) or mII

i ðAIIiHÞ

1=ð1�gÞðc=gÞ1=ðg�1Þ

mIIi ke

iH (with a productivity shock), where kiLe

and kiHe

denote firm i’s efficient level of capital per unit of marketshare without and with the productivity shock, respec-tively. For simplicity, we assume that E1 ¼ E2 � E4Maxðke

iH�K0,0Þ, 8 i¼ 1,2. In other words, we assume thatif either firm decides to go public, the amount raised is thesame, and is large enough to meet the investmentrequirement of the higher-productivity firm after a pro-ductivity shock.16 Since the investor’s participation

(footnote continued)

unchanged as long as the firm going public earlier retains some of the

‘‘first-mover advantage’’ it gained by going public earlier even after its

competitor goes public. As we illustrated through various anecdotes in the

introduction (and show later in our empirical analysis), this seems to be

consistent with practice, at least in many industries. Further, a large

theoretical literature in industrial organization has demonstrated that first

movers can obtain significant permanent advantages in the product market

through a variety of mechanisms, three of which are leadership in product

and process technology (e.g., Spence, 1981), preemption of scarce assets

(e.g., Schmalensee, 1978), and development of buyer switching costs (e.g.,

Wernerfelt, 1985): see Lieberman and Montgomery (1988) for a review of

this theoretical literature. Finally, a large empirical literature in industrial

organization has shown that market pioneers can indeed develop first-

mover advantages that span decades: see Robinson, Kalyanaram, and

Urban (1994) for a review of this empirical literature.14 We do not allow firms to go private once they have gone public.

However, there will be no change in the equilibrium of our model even if

we relax this assumption, since, once a firm has already incurred the

cost B of going public, it does not have any advantage from reverting

back to become a private firm.

15 This assumption is innocuous. As long as the capital depreciation

rate is the same for both firms, all our results are unaffected.16 The assumption that both high- and low-productivity firms raise

the same amount of money in their IPOs can be endogenized in an

asymmetric information setting where the precise productivity of firms

(high versus low) is unobservable to outsiders, there are significant costs

associated with making additional equity issues after the IPO, and the

objective of firm insiders is to maximize the long-run value of their

equity holdings in the firm. In such a setting, the market valuation of the

equity of the two firms will be done in a pooling equilibrium, where the

low-productivity firm mimics the high-productivity firm (otherwise the

low-productivity firm will reveal its type to outsiders and get a lower

valuation). The high-productivity firm will raise the amount of money

needed for it to meet its investment requirements in the event of a

productivity shock in full (it will not raise an amount smaller than that,

since it will have to incur additional costs to make subsequent equity

issues); neither will it raise a larger amount, since it wants to minimize

the dilution in insider’s equity holdings at the time of the IPO (recall that

it will be undervalued in the pooling equilibrium). In such a scenario,

both types of firms would raise the same amount of money in the IPO.

See, e.g., Chemmanur (1993) for an IPO model with asymmetric

information where higher- and lower-productivity (intrinsic value)

firms raise the same amount of money in equilibrium. Since we adopt

a reduced-form modeling approach here, we have chosen not to

endogeneize the IPO amount raised by introducing asymmetric informa-

tion into our setting, since this will add considerable complexity to our

analysis. There is also some empirical support for the assumption that

the amount raised in a firm’s IPO is not directly related to its productiv-

ity. In an unreported empirical analysis, we find that the amount of

T.J. Chemmanur, J. He / Journal of Financial Economics 101 (2011) 382–412388

Page 9: Author's personal copy - ITS - Boston College · ImmuLogic Pharmaceutical Corporation (B-2). To quote: The one certainty about the current open window for biotechnology initial public

Author's personal copy

constraint has to be satisfied, the fraction of equity soldto new investors is E/Et(Vi). Once the firm goes public,the long-run (time 3) value of firm i, Vi, is given byfAII

i ðmIIi Þ

1�gðKe

i Þg�cKe

i gþK0þE�B.Without product market concerns, a firm will go public

if and only if its initial capital level (K0) is lower than itsefficient level (Ki

e) and the efficiency gain from raising

new capital exceeds the cost of going public B. Byexamining the expression for efficient capital level, wehave K0oKe

i 3AIIi 4 ðcK1�g

0 Þ=ðgðmIIi Þ

1�gÞ � Ai . Recall that

firm 1 is assumed to have higher productivity. Withoutloss of generality, we further assume that the productivityshock raises firm 1’s productivity above the thresholdlevel (A1 ) but not that of firm 2 (A2 ). We make thefollowing parametric assumption regarding the produc-tivity levels of firms 1 and 2 with and without a produc-tivity shock17:

A2oA1ocK1�g

0

g oAi ,

A2H ocK1�g

0

goA2 ,

A1H 4cK1�g

0

g½mc�smcð1�mcÞ�1�gZA1 :

8>>>>>>>>><>>>>>>>>>:

ð4Þ

Given the above assumption, both firms are able tooperate at their optimal scale if they do not experience aproductivity shock, whether or not they go public. Like-wise, firm 2 will always be able to use its efficient level ofcapital whether or not its productivity increases. How-ever, firm 1 will need new capital after experiencing aproductivity shock if it is to operate at its efficient scale,though it may also choose to remain private (and operateat an inefficient scale) if the cost of going public is toolarge. Lastly, to make the model interesting, we alsoassume that the cost of going public B is not too largeso that firm 1, upon the realization of the productivityshock, will choose to go public even if doing so results inno additional market share.18

In the above setting, where going public does notenhance a firm’s market-share-grabbing ability (i.e., s¼0

for both public and private firms), neither firm goes publicin equilibrium without a productivity shock. Further, evenwith a productivity shock, the lower-productivity firm 2will never go public. Finally, the higher-productivity firm1 will go public if (and only if) there is a productivityshock, driven only by the need to raise additional externalfinancing. The benchmark case thus predicts no IPO waves(or hot-issuing periods) in the absence of product marketcompetition (we define an IPO wave in our model to bethe situation where both firms go public either at time 1or time 2, so that by the end of the game both are public).

3.2. Full model: IPO enhances product market

competitiveness

In this section, we assume that going public not onlyprovides necessary funding to firms, but also enhancestheir competitiveness in the product market. Without aproductivity shock, a firm’s benefit from going publicpurely comes from an IPO’s enhancement in its competi-tiveness in the product market. We assume that the fixedcost of going public, B, exceeds these additional benefitsfrom going public in the absence of a productivity shock.Thus, both firms will optimally choose to remain privatewithout a productivity shock.19

At time 1, the two firms, under the common belief thata productivity shock may take place in the future withprobability p40, consider their going public decision. Weassume that the productivity shocks are industry-wide(perfectly correlated), which means that with probabilityp, both firm 1 and firm 2 will experience an increase inproductivity at time 2 and with probability 1�p they willnot.20

Unlike in the benchmark setting, in this full-fledgedmodel, firm 1 has two incentives to go public: in additionto the benefit of raising capital that it needs to operate atits optimal scale in the event of a productivity shock,going public now has the additional benefit of increasingfirm 1’s ability to grab market share from its competitor.Knowing that firm 1 may go public, firm 2 may also wishto go public (even though it does not need to raise anyadditional capital if a productivity shock is realized), sincestaying private will put it in a much worse productmarket position. This strategic concern of firm 2 givesfirm 1 an additional incentive to go public even at time 1when the actual productivity shock is not realized. Ofcourse, to obtain the above benefits from going public,either firm has to incur the deadweight cost of goingpublic. For either firm, the trade-off between going publicearly (at time 1) versus late (at time 2) is as follows. Theadvantage of going public early is that the firm is able tograb market share from the competing firm (and toprevent the other firm from grabbing market share fromit) in two rounds of product market competition. The

(footnote continued)

money raised in the IPO by higher-productivity firms (measured by total

factor productivity or three-year average sales growth) does not sig-

nificantly differ from that raised by lower-productivity firms, after

controlling for firm size and stock market conditions. Moreover, we also

find empirically that the amount of money raised in the IPO is not

significantly different for firms going public within a wave versus

outside a wave, and for firms going public early in a wave versus later

in the wave.17 Note that this assumption is not as restrictive as it appears. The

crucial assumption here is that firm 1 has higher productivity ex ante

than firm 2. The assumption that firm 1 needs new capital after the

productivity shock whereas firm 2 does not (even after the productivity

shock) can be relaxed without affecting the central intuition of the

paper, although such relaxation may lead to uninteresting equilibria

where both firms always want to go public at time 1 or to remain private

during both periods.18 This assumption is not unduly restrictive, since it simply requires

that, if external financing is required, then the cash-flow benefits to firm

1 of raising such external financing by going public dominates the cost

of doing so, even in absence of any product market benefits from going

public.

19 This assumption is not crucial for the intuition behind our results

to go through, but is made only for analytical tractability.20 We have also analyzed the scenario where either firm’s produc-

tivity shock is purely idiosyncratic. Most of our results remain qualita-

tively unchanged even in this case. These results are available from the

authors upon request.

T.J. Chemmanur, J. He / Journal of Financial Economics 101 (2011) 382–412 389

Page 10: Author's personal copy - ITS - Boston College · ImmuLogic Pharmaceutical Corporation (B-2). To quote: The one certainty about the current open window for biotechnology initial public

Author's personal copy

disadvantage of going public early is that it incurs the costof going public before it knows for sure whether aproductivity shock is realized (so that the firm may endup being public in a situation where no shock is realized,and it would have been better off remaining private). Thebenefit of going public early versus late is always greaterfor firm 1 than for firm 2 (since it has multiple reasons forgoing public, while firm 2 has only the benefit of grabbingmarket share); on the other hand, the cost of going publicis the same for both firms. Therefore, with product marketcompetition, both firms may go public around the possi-ble arrival of a productivity shock, potentially creating anIPO wave that would not happen in the benchmark case.Depending on whether or not an IPO wave is generated(i.e., both firms go public) and the timing of their goingpublic, there are five possible equilibria, which we discussin detail in the next section.

3.2.1. Description of equilibria and intuition

There are a total of five possible perfect Bayesianequilibria (PBEs) in this game, which are summarized inFig. 221:

Eq. (1) refers to the PBE where IPO waves occur evenwithout a productivity shock. When the magnitude of theshock is at least moderate (A1�A2oDArDAL), the prob-ability of the shock is large, the cost of going public issmall, and the existing productivity levels of firm 1 andfirm 2 are high, both firms will go public before therealization of a productivity shock (at time 1). The intui-tion here is straightforward: when both firms’ existingproductivity levels are high (close to the threshold levelAi ), a highly probable industry-wide shock with a mod-erate or even larger magnitude is very likely to render thefirms’ current production scales inefficient, making firm 1eager to obtain fresh capital through an IPO. Since theproductivity shock is likely and both firms are close to

their efficient operating scales, firm 2 knows for sure thatfirm 1 will go public by the end of the game (byconducting its IPO at time 1 or 2), which means that if itdoes not go public, it will lose market share at least in thesecond round of product market competition. The benefitof additional market share depends on the magnitude ofeach firm’s productivity level. Hence, the high existingproductivity level of firm 2 makes it care much about thepotential loss of market share due to firm 1’s strengthen-ing competitive position after the IPO. When thispotential loss exceeds the cost of going public, firm 2 willgo public. Inferring this, firm 1’s incentive to go public isalso enhanced. The cost to firm 1 from going public attime 1 is that it wants to avoid paying an ‘‘unnecessary’’cost of going public should the shock not be realized attime 2. Therefore, when the cost of going public isconsiderably smaller than the expected gain in profits(due to its high existing productivity) and given itsconjecture about firm 2’s aggressive going-public strat-egy, firm 1 will be prompted to go public at time 1 itself,even without the realization of a productivity shock.Knowing this, firm 2 will also go public at time 1 tocombat firm 1 in the product market as early as possible.Consequently, both firms end up going public at time 1,creating an IPO wave even before the realization of theproductivity shock.

Eqs. (2) and (3) refer to PBEs where IPO waves occuronly after a productivity shock. When the magnitude of apotential shock is large (DA4DAL), in addition to Eq. (1),we have two more equilibria. When the existing marketshare of firm 1 is moderately large (mZ ð2þs�ffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffi

s2þ4p

Þ=ð2sÞ), and the existing productivity levels of firm1 and firm 2 are low, both firms will remain private beforethe realization of a productivity shock (at time 1) and gopublic only upon the realization of a shock (at time 2). Thisis Eq. (2). When the existing market share of firm 1 is small(mo ð2þs�

ffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffis2þ4p

Þ=ð2sÞ), the existing productivity of firm1 is high, and the existing productivity of firm 2 is low, firm1 will go public before the realization of a productivityshock (at time 1) and firm 2 will go public only upon therealization of a shock (at time 2). This is Eq. (3).

Market share distribution (firm 1’s market share)

Magnitude of shock

Small Moderate Large Very large

Large(ΔAL ≤ΔA <ΔAH)

Very Large( ΔA ≥ ΔAH)

Moderate(A1−A2 < ΔA ≤ ΔAL)

Small( ΔA ≤ A1 − A2 )

Eq1: both firms go public at time 1. Eq2: both firms remain private at time 1 and go public only upon the realization of a shock at time 2. Eq3: firm 1 goes public at time 1 and firm 2 goes public only upon the realization of a shock at time 2. Eq4: firm 1 goes public only upon the realization of a shock at time 2 and firm 2 remains private throughout. Eq5: firm 1 goes public at time 1 and firm 2 remains private throughout.

Eq4, Eq5 Eq4, Eq5 Eq4, Eq5 Eq4, Eq5

Eq1, Eq4, Eq5 Eq1, Eq4, Eq5 Eq1, Eq4, Eq5

Eq1, Eq2, Eq5 Eq1, Eq2, Eq5Eq1, Eq2, Eq5Eq1, Eq3, Eq4

Eq1, Eq2, Eq3 Eq1, Eq2, Eq3 Eq1, Eq2, Eq3 Eq1, Eq2, Eq3

Eq1, Eq4, Eq5

Fig. 2. Distribution of possible equilibria over different parameter ranges.

21 Note: the definitions of DAL and DAH are given in the Internet

Appendix B available on the authors’ Websites or from the working

paper version of this article.

T.J. Chemmanur, J. He / Journal of Financial Economics 101 (2011) 382–412390

Page 11: Author's personal copy - ITS - Boston College · ImmuLogic Pharmaceutical Corporation (B-2). To quote: The one certainty about the current open window for biotechnology initial public

Author's personal copy

If the existing market share of firm 1 is small enough(moð2þs�

ffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffis2þ4p

Þ=ð2sÞ), Eq. (3), rather than Eq. (2), willoccur when the other parametric conditions specifiedabove are met. The intuition is as follows. The additionalmarket share each firm can gain by product marketcompetition depends on two things: the available marketshare to grab from rivals (i.e., rivals’ existing marketshare), and its own market-share-grabbing ability, whichin turn depends on its own existing market share. Whenfirm 1’s existing market share is much smaller than thatof firm 2, the latter’s gain in market share by going publicat time 2 would be larger if firm 1 goes public at time 1compared to the case where firm 1 goes public only uponthe realization of the productivity shock (at time 2). Thereason is that when firm 1 is currently a small player inthe product market, firm 2, despite its strong market-share-grabbing ability, has little to grab by going public,so that its gain from an IPO is small. On the other hand,when firm 1 goes public at time 1, its market share willincrease in the first round of product market competition,which in turn increases firm 2’s incentive to compete formarket share in the second round of competition. Thus,firm 2’s incentive to go public at time 2 will be stronger iffirm 1 goes public at time 1 than if firm 1 delays its IPOdecision. When firm 1’s existing market share is largerthan ð2þs�

ffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffis2þ4p

Þ=ð2sÞ and the magnitude of a potentialshock DA is between DAL and DAH , the benefit of firm 2’sgoing public upon a productivity shock dominates its costof going public if firm 1 remains private at time 1, but isless than its cost of going public if firm 1 chooses to gopublic one period earlier. Thus, Eq. (3) cannot occurwhereas Eq. (2) can. When the magnitude of the produc-tivity shock is very large (DA4DAH), both Eqs. (2) and (3)will exist since the initial market share distributionbetween the two firms does not matter in determiningthe equilibrium.

Apart from the existing market share distribution, thedifference in the two firms’ existing productivity levelsalso determines which PBE will occur when the magni-tude of the shock is at least DAL. Note that in both Eqs. (2)and (3), the existing productivity of firm 2 is so low that ithas no desire to go public before a productivity shock isrealized. When the existing productivity of firm 1 is high,it has a strong incentive to go public earlier (i.e., at time 1)because each unit of additional market share gainedthrough more effective product market competition willbring it larger time-3 cash flows. This leads to Eq. (3), themost interesting ‘‘sequential IPO wave equilibrium.’’ Onthe other hand, if the existing productivity level of firm 1is also low (as that of firm 2), it will also choose to waituntil the realization of a productivity shock because themarginal benefit of additional market share gained bygoing public earlier does not outweigh the cost of goingpublic. In this scenario, we will observe Eq. (2), whereboth firms adopt exactly the same strategy: remainprivate at time 1 and go public if and only if theproductivity shock occurs at time 2.

Eqs. (4) and (5) refer to the PBEs where IPOs only occuroff the wave. When the magnitude of a potential produc-tivity shock is not too large (DAoDAH), we have thesetwo equilibria in addition to the above three PBEs. When

the probability of a potential shock is low, the existingmarket share of firm 1 is small (moð2þs�

ffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffis2þ4p

Þ=ð2sÞ),the existing productivity of firm 1 is low, and the cost ofgoing public is large, firm 1 will go public only upon therealization of a shock (at time 2) and firm 2 will remainprivate throughout. This is Eq. (4). When the probabilityof a potential productivity shock is high, the existingmarket share of firm 1 is moderately large (mZ ð2þs�ffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffi

s2þ4p

Þ=ð2sÞ), the existing productivity of firm 1 is high,and the cost of going public is small, firm 1 will go publicbefore the realization of a productivity shock (at time 1)and firm 2 will remain private throughout. This is Eq. (5).

In both Eqs. (4) and (5), firm 2 will remain privatethroughout the two periods because its marginal cash-flowbenefit from additional market share gained by going publicis too small compared to the cost of going public. Eventhough a productivity shock may improve its productivity attime 2, firm 2’s incentive to go public is still small as theshock is not large enough to make it go public after takinginto account the cost involved. Hence, the only differencebetween Eqs. (4) and (5) is the timing of firm 1’s goingpublic. Eq. (4) will exist if the cost of going public is verylarge, and when the existing productivity level of firm 1 islow. Eq. (5) will exist when the cost of going public is not toolarge and the existing productivity level of firm 1 is high. Inthis case, firm 1 has a stronger incentive to go public earlierand grab market share from firm 2. Similar to the case of Eqs.(2) and (3), the existing market share distribution affects theoccurrence of Eq. (4) versus Eq. (5) when DALoDAoDAH .

It is useful to understand why the probability of apotential productivity shock, p, influences the occurrenceof various equilibria. Its effect on Eq. (1) is clear: if p islarger, both firms will be more likely to go public at time1. This is because given the rival firm going public at time1, there is no uncertainty with respect to the rival’sstrategy at time 2, so each firm’s benefit of going publicearlier (at time 1) purely depends on the probability ofgetting a productivity shock. Even firm 2’s incentive to gopublic increases with p, since the shock is large enough tomake the additional market share gained from goingpublic early profit-enhancing. The effect of p on theoccurrence of Eqs. (4) and (5) is also clear: when p islarger, firm 1 will be more likely to benefit from theadditional market share grabbed from firm 2 if it goespublic at time 1. Firm 2 will remain private throughout inboth these equilibria (because its benefit of going public istoo small compared to the cost of going public), so thatfirm 1 does not have to be concerned about the possibleloss of market share due to firm 2’s going public at time 2.Thus, its incentive to go public at time 1 monotonicallyincreases with p. When p is large, we are more likely toobserve Eq. (4), whereas a small p leads to Eq. (5).22

22 The effect of p on the occurrence of Eqs. (2) and (3), however, is

ambiguous. For these two equilibria to be possible, the magnitude of the

shock must be large enough so that firm 2, in addition to firm 1, will also

find it desirable to go public at time 2 if the shock is realized. The

difference between the two equilibria is firm 1’s choice of IPO timing. On

the one hand, a higher p gives firm 1 stronger incentives to go public at

time 1 because it knows there is a bigger chance that it will need

additional capital after the shock occurs. This concern tends to make Eq.

T.J. Chemmanur, J. He / Journal of Financial Economics 101 (2011) 382–412 391

Page 12: Author's personal copy - ITS - Boston College · ImmuLogic Pharmaceutical Corporation (B-2). To quote: The one certainty about the current open window for biotechnology initial public

Author's personal copy

4. Implications and testable hypotheses

By inspecting the five possible PBEs above, we can seethat an IPO wave (defined as both firms going public,either at time 1 or time 2) can result from Eqs. (1)–(3),and that stand-alone IPOs can happen in Eqs. (3)–(5).23

Under all circumstances, the lower-productivity firm(firm 2 here) never goes public alone, but rather conductsits IPO either following or at the same time as its higher-productivity rival (firm 1). This leads to the implicationthat in general, stand-alone IPOs are conducted only byhigher-productivity firms, but IPOs in an IPO wave involveboth high- and low-productivity firms. The intuition hereis simple: besides product market concerns, higher-pro-ductivity firms need more capital to approach theirefficient operating scales. They therefore have muchstronger incentives to go public than lower-productivityfirms who merely go public under pressure from productmarket competition. Hence, higher-productivity firms willgo public even when doing so does not bring any addi-tional market share. The same intuition also leads to theimplication that everything else equal, firms going publicin an IPO wave will, on average, have lower post-IPOoperating performance than firms going public off thewave. This is because if two firms in an industry having anidentical initial capital level (K0) raise the same amount ofequity (E) and have the same post-IPO market share (mi

II),

then the higher-productivity firm will also have betterpost-IPO operating performance. In summary, our modelpredicts that, on average, firms going public outside anIPO wave (i.e., in a cold market) will have higher produc-tivity (H3) and better post-IPO profitability (H5) thanthose going public within an IPO wave.

We do not have an equilibrium in which firm 2 goespublic at time 1 and firm 1 follows suit at time 2 (thuscreating a ‘‘sequential IPO wave’’). In fact, as we havediscussed in the last section, firm 2 will never go publicalone at time 1. Eq. (3) is the only equilibrium that maygenerate an IPO wave that spans both time 1 and 2, giventhat an industry-wide productivity shock actually takesplace. The intuition why firms with superior pre-IPOproductivity are more eager to go public early on in a givenwave is as follows. Both types of firms need to evaluate thebenefits and costs of waiting to go public. On the one hand,the cost of waiting, which is the loss of the opportunity togain market share, is larger for the higher-productivity firm1, due to its superior cash-flow-generating ability per unitof market share. On the other hand, the benefit of waitinguntil time 2, which arises from being able to avoid incurringthe cost of going public unnecessarily if the productivityshock does not take place, is larger for firm 2 (the lower-

productivity firm), since its only benefit of going publiccomes from considerations of product market competition(recall that firm 2 does not need additional capital tooperate at its optimal scale). Whether or not the produc-tivity shock occurs, firm 2 does not need extra capital forproduction, so that if it goes public at time 1, it pays thecost of going public only for product market reasons. Insummary, the expected cost of going public ‘‘unnecessa-rily,’’ arising from the scenario where the firm goes publicearly (at time 1) but a productivity shock is not realized attime 2, is bigger for firm 2, which implies that the benefit ofwaiting is also larger for lower-productivity firms. Compar-ing both the costs and benefits of waiting for the two typesof firms will give rise to the prediction that firms withhigher pre-IPO productivity will go public earlier within anIPO wave. This fact also means that these (higher-produc-tivity) firms that go public earlier in an IPO wave willperform better after the IPO than those that go public laterin the wave, if they have the same level of post-IPO capitalstock and market share. Thus, our model predicts thateverything else equal, a firm that goes public earlier in anIPO wave will have higher post-IPO operating performance,on average, than a firm that goes public later in the wave. Insummary, our model predicts that, on average, firms goingpublic earlier in an IPO wave will have higher productivity(H4) and better post-IPO profitability (H6) than those goingpublic later in the wave.

Since higher-productivity firms in general need morecapital for expansion, our next hypothesis (H7) is thatcontrolling for the total amount of proceeds raised, firmsgoing public in an IPO wave will, on average, hold morecash on hand (or use less of the amount raised throughtheir IPO) than firms going public off the wave. Similarly,we have the hypothesis (H8) that controlling for the totalamount of proceeds raised, firms going public earlier in anIPO wave will, on average, hold less cash on hand (or usemore of the cash raised through their offerings forinvestment) than firms going public later in the wave.The above two predictions arise from our assumption thatboth high- and low-productivity firms raise the sameamount of money in the IPO. Since higher-productivityfirms have a larger optimal scale (investment require-ment) than lower-productivity firms, they are left withless cash after investing in their projects than lower-productivity firms. As we discuss in Section 3 (footnote16), this assumption can be endogenized in a setting ofasymmetric information where only firm insiders canobserve the true productivity of a firm and there aresignificant transaction costs to making additional equityissues after the IPO.24

(footnote continued)

(3) more likely than Eq. (2). On the other hand, a higher p means that

firm 2 is also more likely to go public at time 2 when the shock is

realized, reducing the additional market share that firm 1 expects to

grab by going public before the shock is actually realized (at time 1).

Given this, firm 1 may wish to delay its IPO decision until time 2, leading

to Eq. (2).23 Eq. (3) may involve an IPO wave (if a productivity shock is

realized) or only one firm (firm 1) going public (if the shock is not

realized).

24 Note also that the above two predictions can be generated even in

the absence of the assumption that the IPO amount raised by the two

kinds of firms are the same, as long as the IPO amount raised by both

firms is greater than their optimal investment requirement, and this

difference between the IPO amount raised and the optimal investment

requirement is proportionately greater for low-productivity firms than

for high-productivity firms. The latter condition is likely to hold as long

as there are significant economies of scale in raising external financing

in an IPO, which seems to be the case in practice: see, e.g., Ritter (1987),

who shows that the cost of going public is significantly larger (as a

T.J. Chemmanur, J. He / Journal of Financial Economics 101 (2011) 382–412392

Page 13: Author's personal copy - ITS - Boston College · ImmuLogic Pharmaceutical Corporation (B-2). To quote: The one certainty about the current open window for biotechnology initial public

Author's personal copy

The predictions of our model regarding the effect ofindustry concentration on the pre-IPO productivity andpost-IPO profitability of firms going public on the waveversus off the wave and earlier in the wave versus later inthe wave are ambiguous. On the one hand, for an industrycharacterized by a few large players (high concentration),any competitor’s IPO will exert a large product marketpressure on the rest of the firms in the industry, whichmay then go public, thereby creating an IPO wave. This leadsto the prediction that greater industry concentration willamplify the difference in post-IPO operating performance forfirms going public on the wave versus those going public offthe wave, and between those going public earlier in a waveversus those going public later in the wave. On the otherhand, it may be the case that larger firms that already havesignificant market share in an industry as private firms donot have too much to gain by going public. This is becausesuch firms already have considerable credibility with poten-tial employees, customers, and suppliers even as privatefirms. In this case, firms in more concentrated industries willbe less likely to go public out of product market concerns,attenuating the above difference. In sum, the effect ofindustry concentration on the difference in post-IPO operat-ing performance for firms going public on the wave versusoff the wave and earlier in a wave versus later in the wave isan empirical question, and will be the ninth hypothesis (H9)we test in our empirical analysis.

Before we test the above predictions of our model, wewill first present some evidence regarding the importantassumption we make in our model that IPO firms can grabadditional market share from their competitors (espe-cially private competitors). Our objective here is not toshow causality, but to analyze the relation between a firmgoing public and its subsequent market share. Thus, ourfirst hypothesis (H1) is that going public will be associatedwith a significant increase in an IPO firm’s market share.Our second hypothesis (H2) is that IPOs in an industry willbe associated with a reduction in the market share ofsame-industry competitors, and this negative correlationwill be larger for competitors that are private.

5. Data and sample selection

The data used in this study mainly come from threesources. We obtain our overall IPO sample consisting of6,647 IPO firms from the Thomson Financial Securities DataCorporation (SDC) new issues database. We obtain the datarequired to calculate the total factor productivity (TFP) andthe market share of firms remaining private as well as thosegoing public (or are already public) from the LRD of the U.S.Census Bureau. Finally, we obtain data on the accountingperformance of IPO firms subsequent to going public, likeROA and cash holdings, from the Compustat database. Wetest our first four hypotheses (H1 to H4) regarding marketshare and TFP by using the Longitudinal Research Database(LRD) of the U.S. Census Bureau, which provides plant-level

information for all public and private firms in the manu-facturing sector. We test our next five hypotheses (H5 to H9)regarding post-IPO profitability by using the overall IPOsample from SDC (which includes all industries) mergedwith Compustat and a number of other data sources (to beexplained in depth below).

We obtain our initial IPO sample from the ThomsonFinancial Securities Data Corporation (SDC) new issuesdatabase. We exclude from our initial IPO sample spin-offs, ADRs, unit offerings, reverse LBOs, foreign issues,REITS, closed-end funds, offerings in which the offer priceis less than $5, finance and utilities (with Fama French (FF)49 industry codes 31, 45, 46, and 48), and those offeringswhose industries are unidentified (with Fama French 49industry code 49 or missing).25 To minimize the effect ofwrong data entries on our study, we corrected for severalmistakes and typos in SDC’s database following Jay Ritter’s‘‘Corrections to Security Data Company’s IPO database’’(http://bear.cba.ufl.edu/ritter/ipodata.htm).26 Thus, ourfinal sample contains 6,647 IPOs between 1970 and2006. We then extract financial statement informationfor the IPO firms in our sample from Standard and Poor’sCompustat files, stock price and shares outstanding datafrom CRSP, institutional investors’ positions in new stocksfrom the Thomson Financial 13f Institutional Holdingsdatabase, and IPO firms’ founding years as well as theirunderwriter reputation from Jay Ritter’s database. Due tomissing observations for various variables, we may lose upto 55% of the sample when we conduct our empiricalanalysis (depending on the specification).

To examine the first four hypotheses regarding marketshare and TFP, we make use of the Longitudinal ResearchDatabase (LRD), maintained by the Center for EconomicStudies at the U.S. Bureau of Census. The LRD is a largemicro database which provides plant-level information forfirms in the manufacturing sector (SIC codes 2000 to 3999).In the census years (1972, 1977, 1982, 1987, 1992, 1997),the LRD covers the entire universe of manufacturing plantsin the Census of Manufacturers (CM). In non-census years,the LRD tracks approximately 50,000 manufacturing plantsevery year in the Annual Survey of Manufacturers (ASM),which covers all plants with more than 250 employees. Inaddition, it includes smaller plants that are randomlyselected every fifth year to complete a rotating five-yearpanel. Therefore, all U.S. manufacturing plants with morethan 250 employees are included in the LRD database on ayearly basis from 1972 to 2000, and smaller plants withfewer than 250 employees are included in the LRD databaseevery census year and are also randomly included in thenon-census years, continuously for five years, as a rotatingfive-year panel.27 Most of the data items reported in the LRD

(footnote continued)

proportion of the IPO amount raised) when the IPO issue amount is

smaller.

25 The definition of Fama French 49 industries (based on four-digit

historical SIC codes) is obtained from Ken French’s Web site (http://mba.

tuck.dartmouth.edu/pages/faculty/ken.french/data_library.html).26 Moreover, due to duplicated entries, we checked Factiva and

modified the observation for Wynn Resorts Ltd (CUSIP ‘‘983134,’’ issue

date ‘‘October 25, 2002’’) whose proceeds and shares offered should be

the sum of two entries in the database: ‘‘449.8’’ and ‘‘34.6 million,’’

respectively.27 Given that a random sample of smaller plants is continuously

present in our sample, our data are not substantially skewed towards

T.J. Chemmanur, J. He / Journal of Financial Economics 101 (2011) 382–412 393

Page 14: Author's personal copy - ITS - Boston College · ImmuLogic Pharmaceutical Corporation (B-2). To quote: The one certainty about the current open window for biotechnology initial public

Author's personal copy

(e.g., the number of employees, employee compensation,and total value of shipments) represent items that are alsoreported to the Internal Revenue Service (IRS), thus increas-ing the accuracy of the data.

We use the LRD data to examine private and publicfirms’ market share based on their sales (total value ofshipments) and to construct productivity measures suchas the total factor productivity (TFP), which will bedescribed in detail later. To match our sample of IPOfirms and the LRD data, we require that the IPOs takeplace between 1972 and 2000 and that the primaryindustry of the firm going public is within the manufac-turing sector (SIC codes 2000 to 3999). We also requirethat the IPO firm is present on Compustat for the fiscalyear of the IPO. Then we match this sample of IPO firms tothe LRD using the LRD-Compustat bridge file for a span offive years around the IPO date. In addition, we alsoidentified all public firms (as defined by CRSP), i.e., firmsthat had an IPO prior to the start of our sample period(1972), in the LRD by using the same approach. For anindustry distribution of LRD firms going public, seeChemmanur, He, and Nandy (2010).

6. Construction of variables and summary statistics

6.1. Definitions of IPO clusteredness and IPO waves

To compare the productivity and post-IPO operatingperformance of on-the-wave IPO firms versus off-the-wave ones in the same industry, we define the clustered-ness (hotness) of a certain industry’s IPO market for theperiod within which a firm goes public. For each IPO inthe sample, we count the total number of IPOs in thesame FF-49 industry within a 90-day window symmetri-cally surrounding the issuance date for the given IPO anduse this number (IPONUM) as a raw measure of theclusteredness of the IPO market in that industry for theparticular issuance date under consideration. We also usetwo refinements for this raw measure (IPONUM). First, tocontrol for the relative frequency of IPOs across differentindustries, we deflate IPONUM by the total number of IPOsover the entire sample period in the same industry as theparticular IPO under consideration (IPONUM/Same Indus-

try Vol.). Second, to control for overall hotness of the IPOmarket such as in a stock market boom, we deflateIPONUM by the total number of IPOs done in all industrieswithin the same 90-day window surrounding that parti-cular issue date (IPONUM/Same Window Vol.).28

To compare the productivity and post-IPO operatingperformance of firms going public early versus late in anIPO wave for a particular industry, we first identify and

define IPO waves and then rank the IPOs in our samplewithin each wave by the order of their issuance dates.Using a procedure similar to that of Helwege and Liang(2004) as well as Pastor and Veronesi (2005), we firstcompute the three-month moving averages of IPO volumein a particular industry for each month.29 Then we define‘‘hot periods’’ as those in which the moving average fallsinto the top quartile of that industry’s IPO months. Lastly,we define IPO waves as all sequences of consecutive ‘‘hotperiods’’ that begin and end with a non-zero number ofissuances. To minimize the possibility of misclassifyingconcurrent stand-alone IPOs as a tiny wave (such as thosewaves consisting of only two offerings), we reclassify IPOwaves by dropping those with a total number of fourofferings or lower.30 Once the waves are defined, we thenidentify how early a firm goes public in a particular waveaccording to its issuance date. If more than one IPOs takeplace on the same date, we rank these IPOs according totheir filing dates (if possible) or we randomize if the filingdates are missing (there are 32 such cases). A naivemeasure of how early an IPO takes place in a wave is justthe order of that IPO’s appearance within its wave(ORDER). However, this measure has two limitations. First,waves with a larger size will carry an undue weight in ouranalysis. For example, the last IPO in a wave with fiveofferings will get ‘‘5’’ as its score for ORDER whereas thelast IPO in a wave with 50 offerings will get ‘‘50,’’ eventhough they are both the last one in a given wave. Second,the relationship between post-IPO operating performance(or other accounting measures) and ORDER may not belinear, especially considering the fact that ORDER can onlytake positive integer values that can be as huge as 300:those extremely large integers will be unduly influentialin our regression analysis. In light of the above twolimitations, we use three refinements to ORDER in ouranalysis. First, to make this measure robust to the size of awave and to control for the possible nonlinear relation-ship between post-IPO operating performance and ORDER,we chop ORDER for a given wave into four quartiles andassign ‘‘0,’’ ‘‘1,’’ ‘‘2,’’ and ‘‘3’’ to each of them with largernumbers meaning later appearance in a wave. We call thismeasure EARLINESS. Second, to make the measure com-parable across all waves, we divide ORDER by the medianof it for a given wave (ORDER/Median ORDER) so that theorder measure for all waves will be centered around 1.0and have an approximate range between zero and 2.0.Third, to control for the possible concave relationshipbetween post-IPO variables and ORDER, we take thenatural logarithm of ORDER and use it (Log (ORDER)) as

(footnote continued)

larger firms; smaller firms are well represented in the data. The rotating

sample of smaller plants is sampled by the Census Bureau each year in

the non-census years in order to minimize such a bias in the data.28 Alternatively, one can do the two deflations by using the number

of new business formations gathered from Dun and Bradstreet (Helwege

and Liang, 2004) or the number of outstanding public firms in that

industry one day before the issuance date (Lowry, 2003; Pastor and

Veronesi, 2005).

29 It is worth emphasizing that our definition of IPO waves is based

on a specific industry, unlike Pastor and Veronesi (2005), who use an IPO

market-wide definition. However, given that we are testing a theory

which is based explicitly on competition between firms in an industry, it

seems to be quite appropriate in our case to use an industry-specific

definition of waves.30 We have repeated our analysis by either keeping all of the

originally defined IPO waves (with number of offerings within a wave

greater than or equal to two) or using a stricter filtering rule by dropping

all waves with number of IPOs fewer than ten. All our results are

qualitatively similar.

T.J. Chemmanur, J. He / Journal of Financial Economics 101 (2011) 382–412394

Page 15: Author's personal copy - ITS - Boston College · ImmuLogic Pharmaceutical Corporation (B-2). To quote: The one certainty about the current open window for biotechnology initial public

Author's personal copy

a crude measure of how early a firm goes public within ahot-issue market.

6.2. Definitions of variables for tests of hypotheses H1 to H4

We test our first four hypotheses (H1 to H4) by using theLRD, thus focusing on the IPOs of manufacturing firms. Totest the first two hypotheses, we construct measures formarket share growth, fraction of IPO firms within anindustry, and an IPO dummy. More specifically, the one-year market share growth is the difference between the logmarket share in the next year and the current log marketshare (based on firm sales in the FF-49 industry). Thethree-year market share growth is the difference betweenthe log market share three years later and the currentlog market share. IPO Fraction is the total number of IPOsin the current year divided by the total number of firms(both public and private) in the same FF-49 industry in thesame year. The reason we scale the total number of IPOsby the total number of firms is that we want to rule out thepossibility that the reduction in market share isactually due to more firms in the industry (hence, a higherlevel of competition) rather than due to more firms goingpublic (more IPOs). IPO is a dummy that equals one if thefirm went public in the current year, and equals zerootherwise.

We also measure other control variables by usinginformation within the LRD database. Log (capital stock)is the natural logarithm of firm capital stock in thousands ofdollars in the current year, where capital stock is con-structed via the perpetual inventory method and is the sumof building assets plus machinery assets. Log (age) is thenumber of years since the birth of the first plant of thefirm as recorded in the Census data. Sales growth is theaverage growth in sales in the past three years. Marketshare is a firm’s current-year market share within the FF-49industries based on all LRD firms’ sales. Capex Ratio iscapital expenditure over capital stock. Venture Capital is adummy that equals one if the firm is backed by venturecapitalists.

To test the third and fourth hypotheses, we construct ourmeasure for firm productivity, total factor productivity (TFP).We first calculate TFP for each individual plant at the annualfour-digit (SIC) industry level using the entire universe ofplants in the LRD as in previous literature (see, e.g.,Chemmanur, He, and Nandy, 2010). The total factor produc-tivity of the firm is then calculated as a weighted sum ofplant Total Factor Productivities (TFP) at the annual level. Inparticular, we obtain measures of TFP at the plant level byestimating a log-linear Cobb-Douglas production function foreach industry and year. Industry is defined at the level offour-digit SIC codes. Individual plants are indexed i; indus-tries j; for each year t, in the sample. Plant-level TFP iscomputed as the residuals of regression (5), estimatedseparately for each year and each four-digit SIC industry.31

lnðYijtÞ ¼ ajtþbjtlnðKijtÞþgjtlnðLijtÞþdjtlnðMijtÞþeijt : ð5Þ

Since the above regressions include a constant term,TFP only contains the idiosyncratic part of plant produc-tivity. Output (Y) is constructed as plant sales (total valueof shipments in the LRD) plus changes in the value ofinventories for finished goods and work-in-progress.Since we appropriately deflate plant sales by the annualindustry-specific price deflator, our measure is propor-tional to the actual quantity of output. Thus, the disper-sion of TFP for firms in our sample almost entirely reflectsdispersions in efficiency.

Labor input (L) is defined as production worker equiva-lent man-hours. This is the product of production workerman-hours, and the ratio of total wages and salaries toproduction worker wages. We also re-estimate the TFP

regression by specifying labor input to include non-production workers, which yields qualitatively similarresults. Values for the capital stock (K) are generated bythe recursive perpetual inventory formula. We use theearliest available book value of capital as the initial valueof net stock of plant capital (this is either the value in1972, or the first year a plant appears in the LRD sample).These values are written forward annually with nominalcapital expenditure (appropriately deflated at the indus-try level) and depreciated by the economic depreciationrate at the industry level obtained from the Bureau ofEconomic Analysis. Since values of all these variables areavailable separately for buildings and machinery, weperform this procedure separately for each categoryof assets. The resulting series are then added togetherto yield our capital stock measure. Finally, material input(M) is defined as expenses for the cost of materialsand parts purchased, resales, contract work, and fueland energy purchased, adjusted for the change in thevalue of material inventories. All the variables are deflatedusing annual price deflators for output, materials,and investment at the four-digit SIC level from theBartelsman and Gray NBER Productivity Database. Defla-tors for capital stock are available from the Bureau ofEconomic Analysis. Plant-level TFP measures are thenaggregated to the firm level by a value-weightedapproach, where the weights on each plant is the ratioof its output (total value of shipments) to the total outputof the firm. The firm-level TFP is winsorized at the 1st and99th percentiles.

31 This measure of TFP is more flexible than the cash-flow measure

of performance, as it does not impose the restriction of constant returns

(footnote continued)

to scale and constant elasticity of scale. Also, since coefficients on

capital, labor, and material inputs can vary by industry and year, this

specification allows for different factor intensities in different industries.

These production function estimates are pooled across the entire

universe of manufacturing plants in the LRD, including plants belonging

to both public and private firms, thus giving us an accurate measure of

the relative performance of a plant within a particular four-digit SIC

industry in any given year. The TFP measure for each individual plant is

the estimated residual of these regressions. Thus, it is the difference

between the actual output produced by the plant compared to its

‘‘predicted output.’’ This ‘‘predicted output’’ is what the plant should

have produced, given the amount of inputs it used and the industry

production technology in place. Hence, a plant that produces more than

the predicted amount of output in any given year has a greater than

average productivity for that year. Thus, TFP can be understood as the

relative productivity rank of a plant within its industry in any given year.

T.J. Chemmanur, J. He / Journal of Financial Economics 101 (2011) 382–412 395

Page 16: Author's personal copy - ITS - Boston College · ImmuLogic Pharmaceutical Corporation (B-2). To quote: The one certainty about the current open window for biotechnology initial public

Author's personal copy

6.3. Definitions of variables for tests of hypotheses H5 to H9

We test hypotheses H5 to H9 by using our overall IPOsample (not restricted to the manufacturing firms in theLRD). Our basic measure for a firm’s post-IPO operatingperformance is its return on assets (ROA) for the firstfiscal year after the IPO date (Compustat item DATA13/DATA6).32 To test the seventh and eighth hypotheses(H7 and H8), we also construct two variables to measurefirms’ usage of cash raised in the IPO: (1) the increase incash and cash equivalents in the IPO year scaled by totalnet assets at the first fiscal year-end after the IPO(DATA274/DATA6); and (2) cash and short-term invest-ments at the first fiscal year-end after the IPO scaled bytotal net assets (DATA1/DATA6). To test the ninth hypoth-esis (H9), we need a measure of industry concentration.Following previous literature, we calculate the Herfindahl-Hirschman Index (HHI) based on public firms’ marketshare in total book assets within the FF-49 industries.33

We construct other control variables for hypotheses H5

to H9 following standard procedures in the literature.These include: (1) Firms’ financial statement variables(from Compustat): logarithm of firm’s market capital(DATA199nDATA25) at the first fiscal year-end after theIPO; capital expenditure scaled by firm’s net property,plant, and equipment (PPE) (DATA128/DATA8); researchand development (R&D) expenses scaled by total netassets (DATA46/DATA6); and firms’ market share withinthe FF-49 industries based on all Compustat firms’ netsales (DATA12). (2) IPO characteristics (from SDC and JayRitter’s database): IPO’s offer price; a dummy variableshowing whether the issuer is backed by venture capital-ists (equals one if yes); the initial return of the IPO firm’sstock price (difference between the first closing price andthe offer price, divided by the offer price); logarithm oftotal IPO proceeds; percentage of secondary shares sold inthe IPO; logarithm of firm’s age at IPO date (the number ofyears between the firm’s founding year (from Jay Ritter’sdatabase) and the IPO year); and the reputation of under-writers.34 (3) Institutional investors’ holdings for a com-pany’s stock (from the Thomson Financial 13f Institu-tional Holdings database): percentage of shares owned byall types of institutional investors right after the IPO but

before the first fiscal year-end for the firm as a fraction ofthe total number of shares outstanding in the firmreported in CRSP. In case there is more than one dis-closure for the holdings, we use the first one. To reducethe effect of outliers, all financial ratios in our study arewinsorized at their 1% and 99% values.

6.4. Summary statistics

Table 1 reports descriptive statistics of IPO waves andIPO characteristics in our overall sample (not restricted tomanufacturing firms in the LRD). Panel A gives thedistribution of IPOs and IPO waves across different dec-ades, both for the whole SDC sample and for the samplewith available Compustat information. The 1990s havethe most number of IPOs (3,378) and the highest propor-tion of ‘‘on-the-wave’’ IPOs among all decades (more than75% of the IPOs done between 1990 and 1999 occurredduring a hot market). Based on our classification of IPOwaves or ‘‘hot periods’’ (with the number of IPOs greaterthan or equal to five), 4,180 IPOs took place duringindustry-based waves while the remaining 2,467 offeringsoccurred during a ‘‘cold’’ period. Except for the 1990s, thenumber of ‘‘off-the-wave’’ IPOs seems to exceed thenumber of ‘‘on-the-wave’’ IPOs for all decades, suggestingthat the ‘‘hot-issue’’ market for IPOs mainly took place inthe 1990s when productivity shocks hit many industries.

Panel B of Table 1 presents the distribution of IPOwaves across the FF-49 industries. As we see, both the‘‘Electronic Equipment’’ and ‘‘Wholesale’’ industries have16 IPO waves over the sample period, but the waves forthe former have a larger magnitude: on average, an IPOwave in the ‘‘Electronic Equipment’’ industry has approxi-mately 25 offerings while a wave in the ‘‘Wholesale’’industry has approximately 15. The industries ranked thethird to the fifth are: ‘‘Computer Hardware,’’ ‘‘Retail,’’ and‘‘Medical Equipment,’’ with 15, 14, and 13 IPO waves,respectively.

Panel C describes the duration of IPO waves in oursample. The mean length of a wave is 268 days while themedian length is 211 days.

Panel D of Table 1 lists the five largest IPO waves in oursample. The ‘‘Computer Software’’ industry has the twobiggest waves with 334 and 278 IPOs, respectively, withineach hot-issuing period; the ‘‘Business Services’’ industryhas the two next largest waves with 185 and 104 offer-ings, respectively; and the ‘‘Electronic Equipment’’ indus-try has the fifth largest wave with 81 IPOs. Three out offive of these giant waves took place during the techbubble period (from 1998 to 2000). The wave fromNovember 1998 to November 2000 in the ‘‘ComputerSoftware’’ industry is the most ‘‘condensed’’ hot-issuingperiod because, on average, 15 firms in this industry wentpublic per month during this wave and the maximumnumber of offerings within one month was as high as 27.

Panel E of Table 1 gives summary statistics of ourmeasures for the industry IPO clusteredness (IPONUM,IPONUM/Same Industry Vol., and IPONUM/Same Window

Vol.) as well as the order of going public in a wave(EARLINESS, ORDER/Median ORDER, and Log (ORDER) mul-tiplied by 100). A maximum of 100% for IPONUM/Same

32 We have also tried different measures including post-IPO operat-

ing cash flows over assets (DATA13-DATA128 divided by DATA6), return

on equity (ROE: DATA172/DATA60), and the profit margin (DATA172/

DATA12), which all yield similar results to the ones reported here. To

gauge the impact of IPO timing on firms’ long-term operating perfor-

mance, we also repeated our study by using the two-year and three-year

averages of post-IPO ROA, operating cash flow over assets, ROE, and

profit margin, and obtain broadly similar results.33 The market share is calculated by using data for all public firms’

net assets (DATA6) available in Compustat, and thus, may not have

incorporated the impact of private firms. However, given the unavail-

ability of private firms’ data outside the LRD, this is the best available.

This limitation also applies to our measure of market share based on

total net sales (DATA12) used as a control variable. For robustness, we

also calculated HHI based on firms’ market share in total net sales and

book equity and obtain similar results.34 This variable, obtained from Jay Ritter’s database, has a range

from zero to 9.1, with the higher values indicating better reputation. For

simplicity, we only use the reputation for bookrunners of the offerings.

T.J. Chemmanur, J. He / Journal of Financial Economics 101 (2011) 382–412396

Page 17: Author's personal copy - ITS - Boston College · ImmuLogic Pharmaceutical Corporation (B-2). To quote: The one certainty about the current open window for biotechnology initial public

Author's personal copy

Table 1Descriptive statistics on IPOs and IPO waves, 1970–2006.

This table presents descriptive statistics on IPOs and IPO waves between 1970 and 2006, as listed on SDC. IPOs in which the offer price is less than $5,

ADRs, units, REITS, spin-offs, reverse LBOs, foreign issues, close-end funds, finance and utilities (with FF-49 industry codes 31, 45, 46, and 48), and those

offerings whose industries are unidentified (with FF-49 industry code 49 or missing) are excluded. The three industry IPO clusteredness measures are

defined as follows: ‘‘IPONUM’’ is the total number of IPOs in the same Fama-French 49 industry within the 90-day window symmetrically surrounding

each IPO issuance date; ‘‘IPONUM/Same Industry Vol.’’ is IPONUM scaled by the total number of IPOs in the same FF-49 industry during the whole sample

period; and ‘‘IPONUM/Same Window Vol.’’ is IPONUM scaled by the total number of IPOs in all FF-49 industries during the same 90-day window used to

calculate IPONUM. The three measures for the order of going public within an IPO wave are defined as follows. For any FF-49 industry, we define all IPO

waves within it (according to the procedure outlined in Section 6.1 of the paper) and rank the offerings in a particular wave in terms of their sequence of

issuances. Waves whose number of IPOs is less than five are deleted. We denote the rank by an integer variable ORDER, whose larger values indicate late

occurrence in a wave. We then divide the ranked offerings in a given wave into four groups of equal size and use a dummy variable (EARLINESS) to denote

whether an IPO takes place ‘‘early’’ or ‘‘late’’ in the wave it belongs to. EARLINESS equals ‘‘3’’ if the IPO belongs to the latest batch of offerings, equals ‘‘0’’ if

it falls into the earliest category, and ‘‘1’’ and ‘‘2’’ if in the middle. ‘‘ORDER/Median ORDER’’ is ORDER scaled by its median in the given wave; and ‘‘Log

(ORDER)’’ is the logarithm of ORDER. The IPO characteristics include: IPO’s offer price; a dummy variable showing whether the issuer is backed by venture

capitalists (equals one if yes); the initial return of the IPO firm’s stock (difference between the first closing price and the offer price, divided by the offer

price); logarithm of total IPO proceeds; percentage of secondary shares sold in the IPO; logarithm of firm’s age at IPO date (number of years between the

firm’s founding year and the IPO year); and the reputation for underwriters.

Whole sample Sample with available Compustat information

Year All On-the-wave Off-the-wave All On-the-wave Off-the-wave

Panel A: Number of IPOs in the sample

1970–1979 720 333 387 189 71 118

1980–1989 1661 820 841 1534 756 778

1990–1999 3378 2611 767 3304 2551 753

2000–2006 888 416 472 861 405 456

Total 6647 4180 2467 5888 3783 2105

Industry name Number Percentage Mean number of Median number of Std. of IPO Minimum Maximum

of waves IPOs in the wave of IPOs in the volume in the number of IPOs number of IPOs

wave wave in the wave in the wave

Panel B: Distribution of IPO waves across the Fama-French 49 industries

1st Electronic equipment 16 7.51 24.7 9.5 26.3 6 81

2nd Wholesale 16 7.51 14.7 15.0 9.7 5 46

3rd Computers (hardware) 15 7.04 13.6 10.0 12.8 5 49

4th Retail 14 6.57 27.5 23.5 18.3 8 71

5th Medical equipment 13 6.10 14.9 8.0 16.3 5 63

Rest 139 65.26 20.7 10.0 40.3 5 334

Total 213 100 20.1 10.0 34.2 5 334

Panel C: Duration of IPO waves

Mean duration (days) Median duration (days) Std. of duration (days) Min duration (days) Max duration (days)

268 211 194 60 1430

Industry name Number Beginning Ending Mean no. of Median no. Std. of IPO Minimum no. Maximum

of IPOs month of month of IPOs per of IPOs per volume of IPOs per no. of IPOs

wave wave month month across month month per month

Panel D: The five largest IPO waves in the sample

1st Computer software 334 Oct. 1994 Aug. 1998 9.0 9 3.9 0n 18

2nd Computer software 278 Nov. 1998 Nov. 2000 15.2 15 6.2 1 27

3rd Business services 185 Jun. 1995 Aug. 1998 6.0 6 2.3 0nn 10

4th Business services 104 Feb. 1999 Aug. 2000 7.2 6 3.2 1 13

5th Electronic equipment 81 Apr. 1999 Nov. 2000 5.5 6 2.9 1 11

� The only month that has zero IPOs in the wave is Nov. 1994.� The only month that has zero IPOs in the wave is Jan. 1998.

Measure No. of obs. Mean Median Std. Min Max

Panel E: Summary statistics for measures of industry IPO clusteredness and the order of going public in a wave

Industry clusteredness IPONUM 6647 8.0 5.0 10.1 1.0 72.0

IPONUM/Same Industry Vol. (%) 6647 2.3 1.8 2.0 0.1 40.0

IPONUM/Same Window Vol. (%) 6647 8.2 5.5 8.2 0.5 100.0

Order in a wave ORDER/Median ORDER (%) 4180 99.9 100.0 55.1 1.2 199.4

Log (ORDER) (multiplied by 100) 4180 286.1 270.8 128.5 69.3 581.4

T.J. Chemmanur, J. He / Journal of Financial Economics 101 (2011) 382–412 397

Page 18: Author's personal copy - ITS - Boston College · ImmuLogic Pharmaceutical Corporation (B-2). To quote: The one certainty about the current open window for biotechnology initial public

Author's personal copy

Window Vol. denotes that the IPOs occurring in the 90-daywindow centering an offering are all in the same industryas the given offering. Panel F presents summary statisticsof IPO characteristics in our sample, which are by andlarge consistent with that in the existing literature.

Table 2 presents the summary statistics of firm char-acteristics for LRD manufacturing firms that go public(have an IPO) between 1972 and 2000 and for firmsremaining private throughout the same sample period.All reported statistics are firm-year observations and forthe sample of IPO firms, only the years prior to the firm’sIPO are included. These basic comparisons show thatfirms going public between 1972 and 2000 are, onaverage, more productive, larger, and older than firmsthat remain private. The average sales growth for firmsthat have an IPO is 14.5%, which is significantly greaterthan the sales growth of firms remaining private, which isaround 4%. Moreover, the TFP of firms going public is, onaverage, 0.046, while that of private firms is �0.012, bothof which suggest that firms going public are, on average,more productive and efficient and perform better thantheir industry peers.

7. Empirical tests and results

In this section, we discuss the empirical methodologyused to test our hypotheses and report the results fromour empirical analyses.

7.1. Relation between going public, the market share of IPO

firms themselves, and the market share of their competitors

In this subsection, we carry out a multivariate analysisof the relationship between going public and the marketshare of IPO firms themselves (H1) as well as the

relationship between going public and the market shareof its competitors (H2).35

Table 3 presents OLS regressions of one-year andthree-year market share growth on an IPO dummy andother firm-level characteristics. The sample consists of allU.S. manufacturing firms that either went public (IPO) orremained private in the LRD between 1972 and 2000. TheIPO sample is restricted to the IPO year and the yearswhen a firm was private (prior to going public). The firsttwo models report results with respect to one-yearmarket share growth, and the latter two models reportresults with respect to three-year market share growth.IPO is a dummy that equals one if the firm went public inthe current year, and equals zero otherwise. As we cansee, the coefficient before IPO is positive and significant atthe 1% level, showing that IPO firms enjoy a significantincrease in market share growth relative to those firmsremaining private.36

Table 4 presents OLS regressions of one-year andthree-year market share growth on the fraction of IPOfirms in the same FF-49 industry (IPO Fraction), laggedmarket share growth, firm size (as proxied by log ofcapital stock), and firm age. All specifications include yearand firm fixed effects. For each panel, Models (1) and (4)analyze the market share growth of private firms;

Table 1 (continued )

Measure No. of obs. Mean Median Std. Min Max

Panel E: Summary statistics for measures of industry IPO clusteredness and the order of going public in a wave

EARLINESS Category Number Percentage

0 972 23.25

1 1174 28.09

2 1055 25.24

3 979 23.42

Total 4180 100

Measure No. of obs. Mean Median Std. Min Max

Panel F: Summary statistics for IPO characteristics

Offer price ($) 6647 12.1 12.0 5.7 5.0 189.6

Initial return (%) 4182 25.6 11.4 50.0 �96.0 697.5

IPO proceeds ($ million) 6646 54.5 24.0 173.2 0.3 7322.4

Secondary shares (%) 6646 14.5 0.0 22.8 0.0 100.0

Firm age at IPO date (years) 5455 13.6 7.0 18.5 0.0 165.0

Underwriter reputation (0–9.1) 5442 7.2 8.1 2.2 0.0 9.1

Dummy for VC backing (yes¼1)

Category Number Percentage

0 4008 60.3

1 2639 39.7

Total 6647 100

35 Univariate analyses of these two hypotheses, though unreported,

yield similar results.36 As a robustness check, we also matched IPO firms with private

and already public firms of the same size (amount of capital stock) and

in the same FF-49 industry in the IPO year. We then compared the one-

year and three-year market share growth for these matched firms. We

found that IPO firms enjoy a significantly positive increase in market

share after they go public while the market share of matched private

firms or those that are already public drop during the same period, with

the dropped for private firms the largest. These results are available

from the authors upon request.

T.J. Chemmanur, J. He / Journal of Financial Economics 101 (2011) 382–412398

Page 19: Author's personal copy - ITS - Boston College · ImmuLogic Pharmaceutical Corporation (B-2). To quote: The one certainty about the current open window for biotechnology initial public

Author's personal copy

whereas Models (2) and (5) analyze the market sharegrowth of public firms. Our results show that IPO Fraction

has a significantly negative relationship with both theone-year and three-year market share growth of privateas well as public competitors in the same industry.Moreover, this correlation is considerably larger for pri-vate competitors than for public competitors. The magni-tude of the drop is even larger for market share growthmeasured over a three-year horizon. These results areboth statistically and economically significant. Models (3)and (6) analyze the market share growth of both privateand public firms together. Private is a dummy that equalsone if the firm is private in the year that IPO Fraction ismeasured, and equals zero otherwise. As we can see, theinteraction of Private and IPO Fraction is significantlynegative, suggesting that private firms will experience alarger reduction in their market share growth than publicfirms when more competitors in the same industry gopublic. Overall, the evidence provided in Table 4 isconsistent with our second hypothesis (H2) that IPOs ina given industry will be associated with a reduction in themarket share of same-industry competitors, and thisnegative correlation is larger for competitors that areprivate.

There are two possible scenarios that can explain theabove findings. First, going public causes an increase inthe IPO firm’s market share and a reduction in itscompetitors’ market share (which is our model assump-tion). Second, the anticipation of increased market shareinduces a firm to go public. Without a valid instrument forthe going public decision of a firm, it is difficult to

distinguish between the above two scenarios. Thus, whilethe above descriptive results are broadly consistent withthe main assumption of our model, we do not wish toclaim that going public causes an increase in the marketshare of the IPO firm or a reduction in the market share ofits competitors.

7.2. Total factor productivity (TFP), industry IPO

clusteredness, and the order of going public in a wave

In this subsection, we carry out a multivariate analysisof the different total factor productivity (TFP) betweenfirms that go public in an IPO wave and those that gopublic outside it (H3), and between firms that go publicearlier in an IPO wave and those that go public later in thewave (H4), after controlling for lagged TFP, size, age, andindustry and year fixed effects.37

Table 5 presents the results of multiple regressions oftotal factor productivity (TFP) on our three measures ofindustry IPO clusteredness (Panel A) and our three mea-sures of the order of going public within an IPO wave(Panel B). Models (1)–(3) study the TFP of IPO firms onlyin the years before going public, while the rest of themodels study the TFP of IPO firms in all years before andafter going public. Panel A shows that average TFP forfirms that go public in a hot period (with larger clustered-ness measures) is in general smaller than those that go

Table 2Summary statistics of the LRD sample.

This table presents summary statistics for firms that went public and firms that remained private in the LRD between 1972 and 2000. The going public firms

are those firms in the manufacturing sector (SIC 2000-3999) that went public between 1972 and 2000 as recorded in SDC. The firms remaining private are all

the firms in the LRD which did not have an IPO between 1972 and 2000, and which were not public prior to 1972. All statistics are firm-year observations, with

the IPO sample being restricted to the years when the firms were private, prior to going public. Capital Stock is constructed via the perpetual inventory method

and is the sum of building assets plus machinery assets. Sales is the total value of shipments in thousands of dollars. Age is the number of years since the birth of

the first plant of the firm as recorded in the Census data. Capital Intensity is the capital stock over total employment. TFP is the weighted average of plant-level

Total factor productivity at the four-digit SIC level. To calculate TFP, one regresses the value of output (total value of shipments adjusted for changes in

inventories) on labor (production worker equivalent man-hours), capital stock, and material inputs (intermediate inputs, fuels, and energy consumed). Sales

Growth is the average growth in sales in the past three years. Total Wage is sum of total salaries and wages of the firm (in thousands of dollars). Average Wage is

total wage over total employment. Material Cost is the expenses for the cost of materials and parts purchased, resales, contract work, and fuel and energy

purchased in thousands of dollars. Rental and Administrative Expenses is the rental payments or equivalent charges made during the year for the use of

buildings, structures, and various office equipments in thousands of dollars. All the dollar values are in real terms. The last two columns report the t-stat. and

the Z-stat. for the test of difference in means and the distribution between the sample of firms going public and the sample of firms remaining private,

respectively. nnn, nn, and n indicate significance at the 1%, 5%, and 10% levels, respectively.

Firms going public Firms remaining private Test of differences

Mean Wilcoxon

Mean Std. dev. Obs. Mean Std. dev. Obs. difference rank-sum

t-test test

Capital Stock 63,451.570 110,107.700 6401 5443.286 25,768.150 918,445 170.00nnn 96.06nnn

Total Employment 1295.147 1795.960 6401 150.792 448.210 918,445 190.00nnn 100.72nnn

Sales 168,558.700 274,834.900 6401 17,021.850 65,688.850 918,445 170.00nnn 100.20nnn

Capital Intensity 43.664 48.830 6401 24.229 36.369 882,929 42.44nnn 52.13nnn

Age 7.048 6.047 6401 5.178 5.652 918,445 26.38nnn 31.49nnn

TFP 0.046 0.246 6361 �0.012 0.250 869,203 18.63nnn 22.43nnn

Sales Growth 0.145 0.338 5260 0.038 0.356 637,287 21.76nnn 27.09nnn

Total Wage 38,131.420 55,686.820 6401 3948.162 13,190.770 918,445 200.00nnn 103.23nnn

Average Wage 29.447 10.246 6401 24.368 10.437 882,929 38.77nnn 39.75nnn

Materials Cost 95,429.530 160,667.400 6401 10,559.200 42,532.190 918,445 150.00nnn 95.48nnn

Rental & Admin. Exp. 7857.582 11,935.600 6401 775.621 2821.635 918,445 190.00nnn 101.72nnn

37 An unreported univariate analysis of TFP, industry IPO clustered-

ness, and the order of going public in a wave yields similar conclusions.

T.J. Chemmanur, J. He / Journal of Financial Economics 101 (2011) 382–412 399

Page 20: Author's personal copy - ITS - Boston College · ImmuLogic Pharmaceutical Corporation (B-2). To quote: The one certainty about the current open window for biotechnology initial public

Author's personal copy

public in a cold period, and this relationship is statisticallysignificant at the 5% level for both IPONUM/Same Industry

Vol. and IPONUM/Same Window Vol. The significantly nega-tive coefficients of our IPO clusteredness measures areconsistent with our third hypothesis (H3) that firms goingpublic outside a wave have higher pre-IPO productivitythan firms going public within a wave. The coefficientof �0.004 for IPONUM in Model (6) tells us that a firm goingpublic within a hot period of eight other same-industry IPOs(75% quantile of IPONUM) will, on average, have TFP 0.028less than a firm going public within a cold period of onlyone other same-industry IPO (25% quantile of IPONUM).Given the mean of TFP in our sample is 0.046, thisrepresents a 61% difference in TFP, which is economicallysignificant.

The results in Panel B with respect to the order ofgoing public in an IPO wave are much stronger: ‘‘on-the-wave’’ firms that go public later in a hot period (withlarger measures for the order of going public) in generalhave smaller TFP than those that go public earlier in thewave, and this relationship is significant at the 5% level(and in some cases at the 1%) for all three measures of theorder of going public. This lends strong support to ourfourth hypothesis (H4) that firms going public earlierwithin a wave have higher pre-IPO productivity thanfirms going public later in the wave. The coefficient of

�0.027 for EARLINESS in Model (6) tells us that a firmgoing public earlier in a hot period (among the first 25% offirms going public in this IPO wave) will, on average, havea TFP 0.081 more than a firm going public later in thewave (among the last 25% of firms going public in this hotperiod). Given the mean of TFP in our sample is 0.046, thisrepresents a 176% difference in overall TFP, which iseconomically significant.

In sum, the empirical results presented in this subsec-tion support the hypotheses that firms going public out-side an IPO wave (i.e., in a cold market) will have higherproductivity than those going public within an IPO wave,and that firms going public earlier in an IPO wave willhave higher productivity than those going public later inthe wave.

7.2.1. Alternative explanations and robustness tests of TFP

analysis

In this subsection, we discuss an alternative explana-tion of our TFP results and conduct several robustnesstests regarding the above TFP analysis.

Our findings that firms going public outside a wavehave higher productivity and better post-IPO operatingperformance than those going public within a wave andthat firms going public earlier in a wave have higherproductivity and better post-IPO operating performance

Table 3Relationship between going public and the IPO firm’s own market share growth.

This table presents OLS regressions of 1-year and 3-year market share growth on IPO dummy and other firm-level characteristics. The sample consists

of all U.S. manufacturing firms that either went public (IPO) or remain private in the LRD between 1972 and 2000. The IPO sample is restricted to the IPO

year and the years when a firm was private (prior to going public). The 1-year market share growth is the difference between the log market share in the

next year and the current log market share (based on firm sales in the FF-49 industry). The 3-year market share growth is the difference between the log

market share three years later and the current log market share. IPO is a dummy that equals one if the firm went public in the current year, and equals

zero otherwise. Log (capital stock) is the natural logarithm of firm capital stock in thousands of dollars, where capital stock is constructed via the

perpetual inventory method and is the sum of building assets plus machinery assets. TFP, measured one year prior to IPO, is the value-weighted average

of plant level total factor productivity at the four-digit SIC level, where one regresses the value of output (total value of shipments adjusted for changes in

inventories) on labor (production worker equivalent man-hours), capital stock, and material inputs (intermediate inputs, fuels, and energy consumed).

Sales Growth is the average growth in sales in the past three years. Market Share is firms’ market share within the FF-49 industries based on all LRD firms’

sales. Capex Ratio is capital expenditure over capital stock. Venture Capital is a dummy that equals one if the firm is backed by venture capitalists. All

models control for industry and year fixed effects. White standard errors, clustered at the firm level, adjusted for possible correlation within the cluster

(Rogers standard errors) are reported. Heteroskedasticity-robust t-statistics are reported in parentheses. nnn, nn, and n indicate significance at the 1%, 5%,

and 10% levels, respectively.

Dependent variable 1-Year market share growth 3-Year market share growth

(1) (2) (3) (4)

IPO 0.113nnn 0.092nnn 0.219nnn 0.175nnn

(5.64) (4.71) (5.18) (4.21)

Lagged dependent variable �0.087nnn�0.095nnn

�0.155nnn�0.182nnn

(37.06) (28.90) (32.46) (25.66)

Log (capital stock) 0.001nnn 0.009nnn�0.016nnn

�0.008nnn

(3.92) (16.46) (12.53) (2.69)

TFP �0.049nnn�0.047nnn

(29.05) (7.56)

Market Share �7.022nnn�3.968nnn

(16.53) (3.14)

Sales Growth 0.029nnn 0.169nnn

(7.55) (7.72)

Capex Ratio 0.063nnn 0.266nnn

(10.72) (12.17)

Venture Capital 0.028nnn 0.075nnn

(3.64) (2.92)

Constant �0.118nnn�0.111nnn

�0.097nn�0.153nnn

(10.23) (8.79) (2.01) (2.88)

Observations 437,578 363,228 119,734 112,786

R-squared 0.01 0.02 0.04 0.04

T.J. Chemmanur, J. He / Journal of Financial Economics 101 (2011) 382–412400

Page 21: Author's personal copy - ITS - Boston College · ImmuLogic Pharmaceutical Corporation (B-2). To quote: The one certainty about the current open window for biotechnology initial public

Author's personal copy

Table 4Relationship between other firms’ IPOs and the market share growth of private and public competitors.

This table presents OLS regressions of 1-year and 3-year market share growth on the fraction of IPO firms in the same FF-49 industry (IPO Fraction) and other

firm-level characteristics. The sample consists of all U.S. manufacturing firms (both public and private) in the LRD between 1972 and 2000. The 1-year market

share growth is the difference between the log market share in the next year and the current log market share (based on firm sales in the FF-49 industry). The

3-year market share growth is the difference between the log market share three years later and the current log market share. IPO Fraction is the total number

of IPOs in the current year divided by the total number of firms (both public and private) in the same FF-49 industry in the same year. Log (capital stock) is the

natural logarithm of firm capital stock in thousands of dollars in the current year, where capital stock is constructed via the perpetual inventory method and is

the sum of building assets plus machinery assets. Log (age) is the number of years since the birth of the first plant of the firm as recorded in the Census data.

TFP, measured one year prior to IPO, is the value-weighted average of plant-level total factor productivity at the four-digit SIC level, where one regresses the

value of output (total value of shipments adjusted for changes in inventories) on labor (production worker equivalent man-hours), capital stock, and material

inputs (intermediate inputs, fuels, and energy consumed). Sales Growth is the average growth in sales in the past three years. Market Share is firms’ market

share within the FF-49 industries based on all LRD firms’ sales. Capex Ratio is capital expenditure over capital stock. Venture Capital is a dummy that equals one

if the firm is backed by venture capitalists. Models (1) and (4) analyze the market share growth of private firms; Models (2) and (5) analyze the market share

growth of public firms; and Models (3) and (6) analyze the market share growth of both private and public firms. Private is a dummy that equals one if the firm

is private in the current year, and equals zero otherwise. Panel A reports results with respect to 1-year market share growth, and Panel B reports results with

respect to 3-year market share growth. All models control for firm and year fixed effects. Heteroskedasticity-robust t-statistics are reported in parentheses. nnn,nn, and n indicate significance at the 1%, 5%, and 10% levels, respectively.

Dependent variable 1-Year market share growth 1-Year market share growth

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)

Private Public Both Private Public Both

Panel A: 1-Year market share growth

IPO Fraction �8.148nnn�4.316nnn

�4.702nnn�7.790nnn

�3.306nnn�3.768nnn

(11.70) (3.96) (5.20) (11.28) (3.04) (4.19)

PrivatenIPO Fraction �3.054nnn�3.586nnn

(2.79) (3.29)

Private 0.000 �0.010

(0.48) (0.83)

Lagged dependent

variable

�0.261nnn�0.169nnn

�0.245nnn�0.251nnn

�0.155nnn�0.235nnn

(152.97) (34.59) (152.25) (120.61) (28.76) (121.68)

Log (capital stock) �0.031nnn�0.043nnn

�0.032nnn�0.031nnn

�0.043nnn�0.032nnn

(39.21) (20.52) (44.17) (38.72) (20.24) (43.97)

Log (age) �0.168nnn�0.196nnn

�0.174nnn�0.161nnn

�0.197nnn�0.169nnn

(28.42) (10.11) (31.98) (27.39) (10.02) (31.00)

TFP �0.108nnn�0.079nnn

�0.106nnn

(42.02) (9.75) (43.37)

Market Share �6.574nnn�1.908nnn

�2.342nnn

(19.88) (10.88) (17.19)

Sales Growth �0.108nnn�0.105nnn

�0.107nnn

(22.95) (7.99) (24.53)

Capex Ratio 0.013n 0.117nnn 0.025nnn

(1.76) (4.34) (3.45)

Venture Capital 0.078nnn 0.059nn 0.065nnn

(3.34) (2.57) (4.42)

Constant 0.501nnn 0.640nnn 0.338nnn 0.332nnn 0.657nnn 0.357nnn

(26.30) (20.92) (31.86) (38.28) (21.33) (33.67)

Observations 439,224 48,463 487,687 437,140 48,297 485,437

R-squared 0.08 0.05 0.07 0.09 0.05 0.08

Dependent variable 3-Year market share growth 3-Year market share growth

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)

Private Public Both Private Public Both

Panel B: 3-Year market share growth

IPO Fraction �10.789nnn�5.091nnn

�5.060nnn�10.115nnn

�4.349nnn�4.659nnn

(7.08) (3.08) (3.39) (6.77) (2.71) (3.18)

PrivatenIPO Fraction �5.561nnn�5.243nnn

(2.76) (2.66)

Private 0.000 �0.010

(0.11) (1.04)

Lagged dependent

variable

�0.331nnn�0.301nnn

�0.317nnn�0.283nnn

�0.236nnn�0.273nnn

(104.91) (50.42) (113.95) (70.98) (31.93) (77.92)

Log (capital stock) �0.110nnn�0.123nnn

�0.113nnn�0.096nnn

�0.096nnn�0.096nnn

(55.57) (31.50) (64.43) (47.44) (24.41) (54.09)

Log (age) �0.388nnn�0.447nnn

�0.402nnn�0.332nnn

�0.258nnn�0.321nnn

(15.91) (8.39) (18.56) (13.83) (4.96) (15.07)

TFP �0.114nnn�0.092nnn

�0.115nnn

(19.26) (7.50) (21.45)

Market Share �107.161nnn�69.420nnn

�77.339nnn

(50.95) (38.50) (59.95)

T.J. Chemmanur, J. He / Journal of Financial Economics 101 (2011) 382–412 401

Page 22: Author's personal copy - ITS - Boston College · ImmuLogic Pharmaceutical Corporation (B-2). To quote: The one certainty about the current open window for biotechnology initial public

Author's personal copy

than those going public later in the wave may also begenerated by a model along the lines of Pastor andVeronesi (2005), as we discuss below (see Section 7.3below for our findings on post-IPO operating perfor-mance). Consider a setting where firms with differentproductivities (and expected profitabilities) are born gra-dually over time and go public as soon as market condi-tions allow them to do so. If a firm is strong, then itsthreshold market condition for going public is low. Suchfirms will go public soon after they are born, even ifthe market conditions are not very good and no IPOwave is generated. When market conditions improve,weaker firms will start to go public, creating an IPO wave.Hence, firms going public outside a wave tend to havehigher TFP and better post-IPO operating performancebecause these are the firms that can overcome unfavor-able market conditions to go public, while those firmsgoing public within a wave tend to have lower TFP andworse post-IPO operating performance. Similarly, early ina wave, when market conditions are good but not great,the stronger firms will go public. Later in the wave, ifmarket conditions improve and become excellent, manylower-quality firms will go public. Therefore, firms goingpublic earlier in a wave will have higher TFP and betterpost-IPO profitability than firms going public later inthe wave.

The above alternative explanation implies that if themarket conditions are constant, then we would notobserve better quality (in terms of either TFP or post-IPOoperating performance) of off-the-wave and early-in-the-wave firms. In contrast, our model is purely based onproduct market competition and does not require marketconditions to differ when firms go public on the waveversus off the wave, and when firms go public early in awave versus later in the wave. Hence, to distinguish ourmodel predictions from the variant of the Pastor andVeronesi (2005) market condition theory outlined above,we control for short-term and long-term stock marketconditions when empirically comparing the TFP andoperating performance of on-the-wave versus off-the-wave firms, and early-in-the-wave versus later-in-the-wave firms. If, even after controlling for differences insuch stock market conditions, we find that firms goingpublic off the wave have higher TFP and better profit-ability than those going public within an IPO wave, and

those going public early in a wave have higher TFP andbetter profitability than those going public later in thewave, these residual effects can be attributed to theproduct market effects suggested by our theory.

We therefore re-run our regressions on the effect of IPOclusteredness and the order of going public on TFP aftercontrolling for various market condition variables. We useIPONUM/Same Industry Vol. as our measure of IPO clustered-ness and EARLINESS as our measure of the order of goingpublic.38 We construct various proxies for market conditionsmainly following Pastor and Veronesi (2005): see Tables 6and 7 of their paper for their market condition variables. Themarket condition variables are for the month during whicha given firm went public (and also first differences, lags, andleads of such variables). IPO Month Market Return is the totalmonthly return on the value-weighted portfolio of all NYSE,AMEX, and NASDAQ stocks. IPO Month Market Volatility isthe standard deviation of daily value-weighted marketreturns. IPO Month Risk-free Rate is the yield on a 1-monthT-bill in excess of expected inflation, where the latter is thefitted value from an AR(12) process applied to the monthlyseries of log changes in CPI from the Bureau of LaborStatistics. IPO Month MB Ratio is the sum of market valuesof equity across all ordinary common shares divided by thesum of the most recent book values of equity. IPO Month Ind

Stock Return is the monthly return on a value-weightedportfolio of NYSE, AMEX, and NASDAQ stocks in the sameFF-49 industry of the IPO firm. IPO Month Aggregate ROE isaggregate return on equity. IPO Month New Firm MB is thelog difference between the median MB ratio of new firmsand the median MB Ratio across all firms. IPO Month New

Firm Vol is the difference between the median returnvolatility of new firms and market volatility. See Pastorand Veronesi (2005, Section III.B.1), for more details on the

Table 4. (continued )

Dependent variable 3-Year market share growth 3-Year market share growth

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)

Private Public Both Private Public Both

Sales Growth 0.035nn 0.136nnn 0.069nnn

(2.41) (5.27) (5.45)

Capex Ratio 0.096nnn 0.050 0.088nnn

(4.74) (1.21) (4.76)

Venture Capital 0.226nnn 0.060n 0.126nnn

(5.50) (1.81) (5.16)

Constant 1.899nnn 2.057nnn 2.042nnn 1.778nnn 1.898nnn 1.851nnn

(24.39) (23.84) (29.05) (23.24) (22.50) (26.78)

Observations 120,990 32,790 153,780 120,512 32,717 153,229

R-squared 0.14 0.13 0.14 0.16 0.17 0.16

38 Due to space constraints, we present these robustness tests on

the effect of IPO clusteredness and the order of going public on TFP after

controlling for various market condition variables using only one

measure of IPO clusteredness and one measure of the order of going

public in a wave in Table A1 (as part of the Internet Appendix A available

from the authors’ Web sites). The results of additional specifications

using these two measures as well as our analysis based on specifications

using all three measures of clusteredness and the order of going public

are also available upon request. While the significance level varies across

specifications, these additional results are broadly similar to those

presented in Table A1.

T.J. Chemmanur, J. He / Journal of Financial Economics 101 (2011) 382–412402

Page 23: Author's personal copy - ITS - Boston College · ImmuLogic Pharmaceutical Corporation (B-2). To quote: The one certainty about the current open window for biotechnology initial public

Author's personal copy

Ta

ble

5T

ota

lfa

cto

rp

rod

uct

ivit

y(T

FP),

ind

ust

ryIP

Ocl

ust

ere

dn

ess

,a

nd

the

ord

er

of

go

ing

pu

bli

cin

aw

av

e.

Th

ista

ble

pre

sen

tsO

LSre

gre

ssio

ns

of

tota

lfa

cto

rp

rod

uct

ivit

y(T

FP)

on

the

thre

em

ea

sure

so

fin

du

stry

IPO

clu

ste

red

ne

ssa

nd

the

thre

em

ea

sure

so

fth

eo

rde

ro

fg

oin

gp

ub

lic

wit

hin

an

IPO

wa

ve

.T

he

sam

ple

con

sist

so

fU

.S.m

an

ufa

ctu

rin

gfi

rms

inth

eLR

Dth

at

we

nt

pu

bli

cb

etw

ee

n1

97

2a

nd

20

00

.TFP

isth

ev

alu

e-w

eig

hte

da

ve

rag

eo

fp

lan

t-le

ve

lto

tal

fact

or

pro

du

ctiv

ity

at

the

fou

r-d

igit

SIC

lev

el,

wh

ere

on

ere

gre

sse

s

the

va

lue

of

ou

tpu

t(t

ota

lv

alu

eo

fsh

ipm

en

tsa

dju

ste

dfo

rch

an

ge

sin

inv

en

tori

es)

on

lab

or

(pro

du

ctio

nw

ork

er

eq

uiv

ale

nt

ma

n-h

ou

rs),

cap

ita

lst

ock

,an

dm

ate

ria

lin

pu

ts(i

nte

rme

dia

tein

pu

ts,f

ue

ls,a

nd

en

erg

y

con

sum

ed

).T

he

thre

ein

du

stry

IPO

clu

ste

red

ne

ssm

ea

sure

sa

red

efi

ne

da

sfo

llo

ws:

‘‘IP

ON

UM

’’is

the

tota

ln

um

be

ro

fIP

Os

inth

esa

me

Fam

a-F

ren

ch4

9in

du

stry

wit

hin

the

90

-da

yw

ind

ow

sym

me

tric

all

y

surr

ou

nd

ing

ea

chIP

Ois

sua

nce

da

te;

‘‘IP

ON

UM

/Sa

me

Ind

ust

ryV

ol.’

’is

IPO

NU

Msc

ale

db

yth

eto

tal

nu

mb

er

of

IPO

sin

the

sam

eFF

-49

ind

ust

ryd

uri

ng

the

wh

ole

sam

ple

pe

rio

d;

an

d‘‘I

PO

NU

M/S

am

eW

ind

ow

Vo

l.’’i

s

IPO

NU

Msc

ale

db

yth

eto

tal

nu

mb

er

of

IPO

sin

all

FF-4

9in

du

stri

es

du

rin

gth

esa

me

90

-da

yw

ind

ow

use

dto

calc

ula

teIP

ON

UM

.Th

eth

ree

me

asu

res

for

the

ord

er

of

go

ing

pu

bli

cw

ith

ina

nIP

Ow

av

ea

red

efi

ne

da

s

foll

ow

s.Fo

ra

ny

FF-4

9in

du

stry

,w

ed

efi

ne

all

IPO

wa

ve

sw

ith

init

(acc

ord

ing

toth

ep

roce

du

reo

utl

ine

din

Se

ctio

n6

.1o

fth

ep

ap

er)

an

dra

nk

the

off

eri

ng

sin

ap

art

icu

lar

wa

ve

inte

rms

of

the

irse

qu

en

ceo

f

issu

an

ces.

Wa

ve

sw

ho

sen

um

be

ro

fIP

Os

isle

ssth

an

fiv

ea

red

ele

ted

.W

ed

en

ote

the

ran

kb

ya

nin

teg

er

va

ria

ble

OR

DE

R,

wh

ose

larg

er

va

lue

sin

dic

ate

late

occ

urr

en

cein

aw

av

e.

We

the

nd

ivid

eth

era

nk

ed

off

eri

ng

sin

ag

ive

nw

av

ein

tofo

ur

gro

up

so

fe

qu

al

size

an

du

sea

du

mm

yv

ari

ab

le(E

AR

LIN

ESS

)to

de

no

tew

he

the

ra

nIP

Ota

ke

sp

lace

‘‘ea

rly

’’o

r‘‘l

ate

’’in

the

wa

ve

itb

elo

ng

sto

.E

AR

LIN

ESS

eq

ua

ls‘‘3

’’if

the

IPO

be

lon

gs

toth

ela

test

ba

tch

of

off

eri

ng

s,e

qu

als

‘‘0’’

ifit

fall

sin

toth

ee

arl

iest

cate

go

ry,

an

d‘‘1

’’a

nd

‘‘2’’

ifin

the

mid

dle

.‘‘O

RD

ER

/Me

dia

nO

RD

ER

’’is

OR

DE

Rsc

ale

db

yit

sm

ed

ian

inth

eg

ive

nw

av

e;

an

d‘‘L

og

(OR

DE

R)’

’is

the

log

ari

thm

of

OR

DE

R.L

og

(ca

pit

al

sto

ck)

isth

en

atu

ral

log

ari

thm

of

firm

cap

ita

lst

ock

inth

ou

san

ds

of

do

lla

rs,w

he

reca

pit

al

sto

ckis

con

stru

cte

dv

iath

ep

erp

etu

al

inv

en

tory

me

tho

da

nd

isth

esu

m

of

bu

ild

ing

ass

ets

plu

sm

ach

ine

rya

sse

ts.

Log

(ag

e)is

the

nu

mb

er

of

ye

ars

sin

ceth

eb

irth

of

the

firs

tp

lan

to

fth

efi

rma

sre

cord

ed

inth

eC

en

sus

da

ta.

Yea

rsfr

om

IPO

yea

ra

rea

seri

es

of

du

mm

ies

toin

dic

ate

the

ga

pb

etw

ee

nth

ecu

rre

nt

ye

ar

an

dth

eIP

Oy

ea

ro

fth

efi

rm.

Mo

de

ls(1

)to

(3)

stu

dy

the

TFP

of

IPO

firm

so

nly

inth

ey

ea

rsb

efo

reg

oin

gp

ub

lic,

wh

ile

the

rest

of

the

mo

de

lsst

ud

yth

eT

FPo

fIP

Ofi

rms

ina

lly

ea

rs

be

fore

an

da

fte

rg

oin

gp

ub

lic.

Pa

ne

lA

pre

sen

tsth

ere

sult

sfo

rth

eth

ree

me

asu

res

of

ind

ust

ryIP

Ocl

ust

ere

dn

ess

an

dP

an

el

Bp

rese

nts

the

resu

lts

for

the

thre

em

ea

sure

so

fth

eo

rde

ro

fg

oin

gp

ub

lic

wit

hin

an

IPO

wa

ve

.Pa

ne

lA

an

aly

zes

all

firm

sth

at

we

nt

pu

bli

cd

uri

ng

the

sam

ple

pe

rio

d,w

hil

eP

an

el

Ba

na

lyze

so

nly

firm

sth

at

we

nt

pu

bli

cw

ith

inIP

Ow

av

es

tha

tin

clu

de

at

lea

stfi

ve

sam

e-i

nd

ust

ryIP

Os.

All

mo

de

lsco

ntr

ol

for

ind

ust

ry(F

F-4

9le

ve

l)a

nd

IPO

-ye

ar

fix

ed

eff

ect

s.W

hit

est

an

da

rde

rro

rs,

clu

ste

red

at

the

firm

lev

el,

ad

just

ed

for

po

ssib

leco

rre

lati

on

wit

hin

the

clu

ste

r(R

og

ers

sta

nd

ard

err

ors

)a

rere

po

rte

d.

He

tero

ske

da

stic

ity

-ro

bu

stt-

sta

tist

ics

are

rep

ort

ed

inp

are

nth

ese

s.nnn,nn,

an

dn

ind

ica

tesi

gn

ifica

nce

at

the

1%

,5

%,

an

d1

0%

lev

els

,re

spe

ctiv

ely

.

De

pe

nd

en

tv

ari

ab

le:

To

tal

fact

or

pro

du

ctiv

ity

(TFP

)

Yea

rsb

efo

reg

oin

gp

ub

lic

Yea

rsb

efo

rea

nd

aft

erg

oin

gp

ub

lic

(1)

(2)

(3)

(4)

(5)

(6)

(7)

(8)

(9)

(10

)(1

1)

(12

)

Pa

ne

lA

:T

FPa

nd

IPO

clu

ste

red

ne

ss

IPO

NU

M�

0.0

10

�0

.00

8nnn

�0

.00

4nn

�0

.00

4nn

(1.6

0)

(2.7

8)

(2.2

2)

(2.5

5)

IPO

NU

M/S

am

eIn

du

stry

Vo

l.�

3.4

98nn

�3

.54

4nn

�1

.60

2nn

�1

.88

3nn

(2.0

2)

(2.4

5)

(2.1

5)

(2.4

9)

IPO

NU

M/S

am

eW

ind

ow

Vo

l.�

2.5

20nn

�2

.36

7nn

�1

.01

9nn

�0

.85

5n

(2.0

1)

(2.4

4)

(2.1

3)

(1.7

1)

Lag

ge

dd

ep

en

de

nt

va

ria

ble

0.5

63nnn

0.5

62nnn

0.5

63nnn

0.5

61nnn

0.5

63nnn

0.5

62nnn

(31

.42

)(3

1.3

5)

(31

.30

)(3

1.2

1)

(31

.48

)(3

1.3

7)

Log

(ca

pit

al

sto

ck)

0.0

11nn

0.0

11nn

0.0

11nn

0.0

07nnn

0.0

03nn

0.0

03nn

0.0

07nnn

0.0

03nn

0.0

04nn

0.0

07nnn

0.0

03nn

0.0

04nn

(2.2

9)

(2.3

9)

(2.3

0)

(2.7

8)

(2.3

2)

(2.3

7)

(2.9

0)

(2.3

8)

(2.4

2)

(2.8

7)

(2.3

8)

(2.5

0)

Log

(ag

e)0

.02

00

.02

00

.02

00

.01

00

.00

00

.01

00

.01

00

.00

00

.01

00

.01

00

.01

00

.01

0

(0.9

0)

(0.8

5)

(0.8

1)

(0.6

4)

(0.3

8)

(1.3

2)

(0.6

1)

(0.3

4)

(1.3

3)

(0.9

2)

(0.5

9)

(1.3

5)

Co

nst

an

t�

0.0

20

0.0

20

0.0

30

0.0

50

0.0

00

0.2

09nnn

0.0

86n

0.0

20

0.1

88nnn

0.0

88n

0.0

20

0.1

49nnn

(0.3

4)

(0.3

0)

(0.5

1)

(1.3

1)

(0.0

9)

(3.9

1)

(1.7

8)

(0.5

2)

(3.8

5)

(1.8

9)

(0.4

6)

(3.3

9)

Yea

rsfr

om

IPO

Yea

rN

oN

oN

oN

oN

oY

es

No

No

Ye

sN

oN

oY

es

Ob

serv

ati

on

s3

27

43

27

43

27

47

01

76

32

46

32

47

01

76

32

46

32

47

01

76

32

46

32

4

R-s

qu

are

d0

.06

0.0

70

.06

0.0

50

.35

0.3

60

.05

0.3

50

.36

0.0

50

.35

0.3

6

Pa

ne

lB

:T

FPa

nd

the

ord

er

of

go

ing

pu

bli

cin

an

IPO

wa

ve

De

pe

nd

en

tv

ari

ab

le:

To

tal

fact

or

pro

du

ctiv

ity

(TFP

)

Yea

rsb

efo

reg

oin

gp

ub

lic

Yea

rsb

efo

rea

nd

aft

erg

oin

gp

ub

lic

(1)

(2)

(3)

(4)

(5)

(6)

(7)

(8)

(9)

(10

)(1

1)

(12

)

T.J. Chemmanur, J. He / Journal of Financial Economics 101 (2011) 382–412 403

Page 24: Author's personal copy - ITS - Boston College · ImmuLogic Pharmaceutical Corporation (B-2). To quote: The one certainty about the current open window for biotechnology initial public

Author's personal copy

construction of these variables and the motivation for usingthem as proxies for market conditions.

Our results incorporating the above controls are pre-sented in Table A1 (as part of Internet Appendix Aavailablefrom the authors’ Web sites). We find that some of themarket condition variables are significant in some regres-sion specifications: for example, IPO Month Market Volatility

is negative and significant in our regression for IPO cluste-redness (Model (1)), indicating that firms going publicduring these periods of greater market uncertainty havelower TFP, on average. However, the significantly negativecoefficients of IPONUM/Same Industry Vol. and EARLINESS

across all specifications show that, even after controlling forshort- and long-term stock market conditions, firms goingpublic outside a wave tend to have higher pre-IPO TFP thanthose going public within a wave, and firms going publicearlier in a wave tend to have higher pre-IPO TFP than thosegoing public later in the wave. In summary, even aftercontrolling for various market conditions, we still findresidual empirical support for the predictions of our productmarket theory of IPO waves.

7.3. Post-IPO operating performance, industry IPO

clusteredness, and the order of going public in a wave

In this subsection, we carry out a multivariate analysisof the difference in post-issuance operating performancebetween firms that go public in an IPO wave and thosethat go public outside it (H5), and between firms that gopublic earlier in an IPO wave and those that go publiclater in the wave (H6).39

Table 6 summarizes the results of the multivariateanalysis of post-issuance ROA on our measures of indus-try IPO clusteredness as well as on our measures of theorder of an IPO within a wave. To control for unobservablemacroeconomic shocks that affect all firms in a givenyear, we put a dummy for IPO year in all our modelspecifications. Similarly, we use an industry dummythroughout our regressions to control for unobservableindustry-invariant characteristics that may affect theoperating performance of all firms in a certain industry.40

Model (1) provides results with respect to the measureIPONUM. The significantly negative coefficient of IPONUM

is consistent with our fifth hypothesis (H5) that firmsgoing public outside a wave have better post-IPO profit-ability than firms going public within a wave. The coeffi-cient of �0.0016 for IPONUM tells us that even aftercontrolling for industry and time effects as well as variousfirm and IPO characteristics, a firm that goes public withina hot period of eight other same-industry IPOs (75%quantile of IPONUM) will, on average, have an ROA 1.1%less than a firm that goes public within a cold period of

Ta

ble

5.

(co

nti

nu

ed)

EA

RLI

NE

SS�

0.0

63nnn

�0

.04

9nnn

�0

.02

7nn

�0

.02

7nn

(2.8

1)

(2.6

7)

(2.4

4)

(2.3

4)

OR

DE

R/M

ed

ian

OR

DE

R�

0.1

20nn

�0

.09

3nn

�0

.05

2nn

�0

.05

1nn

(2.5

8)

(2.5

1)

(2.2

3)

(2.1

2)

Log

(OR

DE

R)

�0

.08

8nn

�0

.07

2nnn

�0

.03

8nn

�0

.03

8nn

(2.5

2)

(2.7

2)

(2.3

1)

(2.2

3)

Lag

ge

dd

ep

en

de

nt

va

ria

ble

0.5

00nnn

0.5

00nnn

0.5

00nnn

0.5

00nnn

0.5

00nnn

0.5

00nnn

(17

.45

)(1

7.2

0)

(17

.39

)(1

7.1

4)

(17

.43

)(1

7.1

5)

Log

(ca

pit

al

sto

ck)

0.0

00

0.0

00

0.0

00

0.0

10

0.0

00

0.0

00

0.0

10

0.0

00

0.0

00

0.0

10

0.0

00

0.0

00

(0.3

0)

(0.2

7)

(0.1

1)

(1.2

3)

(1.1

5)

(1.1

5)

(1.1

9)

(1.1

2)

(1.1

1)

(1.0

6)

(1.0

2)

(1.0

0)

Log

(ag

e)0

.05

9nn

0.0

58nn

0.0

58nn

0.0

41n

0.0

10

0.0

20

0.0

41n

0.0

10

0.0

20

0.0

39n

0.0

10

0.0

20

(2.2

6)

(2.2

3)

(2.2

0)

(1.8

9)

(0.7

4)

(1.0

9)

(1.8

8)

(0.7

3)

(1.0

9)

(1.7

8)

(0.6

7)

(1.0

3)

Co

nst

an

t0

.22

00

.26

00

.33

00

.34

9nnn

0.0

90

�0

.03

00

.38

0nnn

0.1

03n

0.2

11nn

0.4

88nnn

0.1

61nn

0.0

90

(1.1

2)

(1.3

0)

(1.6

2)

(3.7

2)

(1.5

1)

(0.0

8)

(4.0

5)

(1.7

8)

(2.4

3)

(4.5

7)

(2.3

3)

(0.3

0)

Yea

rsfr

om

IPO

Yea

rN

oN

oN

oN

oN

oY

es

No

No

Ye

sN

oN

oY

es

Ob

serv

ati

on

s1

60

71

60

71

60

73

27

42

92

02

92

03

27

42

92

02

92

03

27

42

92

02

92

0

R-s

qu

are

d0

.22

0.2

20

.22

0.1

60

.38

0.3

90

.16

0.3

80

.39

0.1

60

.38

0.3

9

39 An unreported univariate analysis of post-issuance operating

performance, industry IPO clusteredness, and the order of going public

in a wave yields results similar to those from our multivariate analysis.40 In unreported results, we tried three other specifications for each

of the three measures of clusteredness as well as of the three measures

of the order of going public within a wave. Our results are robust to

these alternative specifications.

T.J. Chemmanur, J. He / Journal of Financial Economics 101 (2011) 382–412404

Page 25: Author's personal copy - ITS - Boston College · ImmuLogic Pharmaceutical Corporation (B-2). To quote: The one certainty about the current open window for biotechnology initial public

Author's personal copy

Table 6Post-IPO operating performance, industry clusteredness of IPOs, and the order of going public in an IPO wave.

This table presents OLS regressions of post-IPO operating performance on three measures of industry IPO clusteredness (‘‘hotness’’ of the IPO market)

and the three measures for the order of going public within an IPO wave. The post-IPO operating performance measure is defined as the return on assets

(ROA) for the first fiscal year after the IPO date (Compustat DATA13/DATA6). The sample includes IPOs between 1970 and 2006, as listed on SDC. IPOs in

which the offer price is less than $5, ADRs, units, REITS, spin-offs, reverse LBOs, foreign issues, close-end funds, finance and utilities (with FF-49 industry

codes 31, 45, 46, and 48), and those offerings whose industries are unidentified (with FF-49 industry code 49 or missing) are excluded. The three industry

IPO clusteredness measures are defined as follows: ‘‘IPONUM’’ is the total number of IPOs in the same Fama-French 49 industry within the 90-day

window symmetrically surrounding each IPO issuance date; ‘‘IPONUM/Same Industry Vol.’’ is IPONUM scaled by the total number of IPOs in the same FF-49

industry during the whole sample period; and ‘‘IPONUM/Same Window Vol.’’ is IPONUM scaled by the total number of IPOs in all FF-49 industries during

the same 90-day window used to calculate IPONUM. The three measures for the order of going public within an IPO wave are defined as follows. For any

FF-49 industry, we define all IPO waves within it (according to the procedure outlined in Section 6.1 of the paper) and rank the offerings in a particular

wave in terms of their sequence of issuances. Waves whose number of IPOs is less than five are deleted. We denote the rank by an integer variable ORDER,

whose larger values indicate late occurrence in a wave. We then divide the ranked offerings in a given wave into four groups of equal size and use a

dummy variable (EARLINESS) to denote whether an IPO takes place ‘‘early’’ or ‘‘late’’ in the wave it belongs to. EARLINESS equals ‘‘3’’ if the IPO belongs to

the latest batch of offerings, equals ‘‘0’’ if it falls into the earliest category, and ‘‘1’’ and ‘‘2’’ if in the middle. ‘‘ORDER/Median ORDER’’ is ORDER scaled by its

median in the given wave; and ‘‘Log (ORDER)’’ is the logarithm of ORDER. The other independent variables include: logarithm of firm’s market capital

(DATA199nDATA25) at the first fiscal year-end after the IPO; IPO’s offer price; a dummy variable showing whether the issuer is backed by venture

capitalists (equals one if yes); the initial return of the IPO firm’s stock (difference between the first closing price and the offer price, divided by the offer

price); logarithm of total IPO proceeds; percentage of secondary shares sold in the IPO; firms’ market share within the FF-49 industries based on all

Compustat firms’ net sales (DATA12); percentage of shares owned by institutional investors right after the IPO; logarithm of firm’s age at IPO date

(number of years between the firm’s founding year and the IPO year); capital expenditure scaled by firm’s net property, plant, and equipment (DATA128/

DATA8); research and development expenses scaled by total net assets (DATA46/DATA6); and the reputation for underwriters. The first three columns

analyze all firms that went public during the sample period, while the latter three columns analyze only firms that went public within IPO waves that

include at least five same-industry IPOs. All models control for industry (FF-49 level) and IPO-year fixed effects. White standard errors, clustered at the

industry level, adjusted for possible correlation within the cluster (Rogers standard errors) are reported. Heteroskedasticity-robust t-statistics are

reported in parentheses. nnn, nn, and n indicate significance at the 1%, 5%, and 10% levels, respectively.

Dependent variable: ROA

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)

IPONUM �0.0016nnn

(�4.16)

IPONUM/Same Industry Vol. �0.6741nnn

(�3.09)

IPONUM/Same Window Vol. �0.2340nnn

(�4.72)

EARLINESS �0.0076nn

(�2.40)

ORDER/Median ORDER �0.0160nn

(�2.71)

Log (ORDER) �0.0086nnn

(�3.00)

Log (market cap) 0.0579nnn 0.0573nnn 0.0579nnn 0.0543nnn 0.0544nnn 0.0542nnn

(8.61) (8.58) (8.64) (8.20) (8.21) (8.07)

Offer Price 0.0033nn 0.0033nn 0.0034nn 0.0035nn 0.0035nn 0.0036nn

(2.59) (2.56) (2.56) (2.13) (2.12) (2.25)

Dummy for VC backing �0.0254nn�0.0270nn

�0.0256nn�0.0373nnn

�0.0374nnn�0.0370nnn

(�2.41) (�2.56) (�2.48) (�3.51) (�3.52) (�3.46)

Initial Return (percent) �0.0004nnn�0.0004nnn

�0.0004nnn�0.0003nnn

�0.0003nnn�0.0003nnn

(�4.89) (�5.05) (�4.80) (�3.42) (�3.45) (�3.32)

Log (IPO proceeds) �0.0747nnn�0.0732nnn

�0.0749nnn�0.0815nnn

�0.0817nnn�0.0818nnn

(�7.72) (�7.68) (�7.71) (�6.90) (�6.93) (�6.90)

Percent of Secondary Shares 0.2032nnn 0.2031nnn 0.2025nnn 0.2367nnn 0.2365nnn 0.2382nnn

(7.14) (7.00) (7.04) (7.19) (7.22) (7.32)

Market Share �0.2182 �0.2513 �0.2185 0.2956 0.2926 0.2398

(�1.00) (�1.08) (�1.00) (0.51) (0.50) (0.41)

Percent of Institutional Holding 0.1165nnn 0.1196nnn 0.1176nnn 0.1392nnn 0.1391nnn 0.1396nnn

(5.83) (5.91) (6.00) (4.37) (4.36) (4.42)

Log (firm age at IPO date) 0.0317nnn 0.0312nnn 0.0315nnn 0.0316nnn 0.0315nnn 0.0318nnn

(5.58) (5.64) (5.62) (5.33) (5.30) (5.34)

CapEx/PPE �0.0618nnn�0.0638nnn

�0.0614nnn�0.0827nnn

�0.0829nnn�0.0812nnn

(�4.76) (�4.96) (�4.71) (�5.76) (�5.78) (�5.52)

R&D/Assets �1.0463nnn�1.0528nnn

�1.0394nnn�1.0647nnn

�1.0644nnn�1.0539nnn

(�8.84) (�8.98) (�8.88) (�8.82) (�8.76) (�8.71)

Underwriter Reputation 0.0095nnn 0.0092nnn 0.0094nnn 0.0111nnn 0.0111nnn 0.0111nnn

(4.93) (4.81) (5.01) (4.85) (4.84) (4.90)

Constant �0.0795nn�0.0595n

�0.0768nn�0.1616nn

�0.1550nn�0.1592nn

(�2.15) (�1.72) (�2.11) (�2.69) (�2.61) (�2.61)

Observations 3259 3259 3259 2321 2321 2321

R-squared 0.556 0.555 0.557 0.581 0.581 0.581

T.J. Chemmanur, J. He / Journal of Financial Economics 101 (2011) 382–412 405

Page 26: Author's personal copy - ITS - Boston College · ImmuLogic Pharmaceutical Corporation (B-2). To quote: The one certainty about the current open window for biotechnology initial public

Author's personal copy

only one other same-industry IPO (25% quantile of IPO-

NUM). Given that the mean of ROA in our sample is 5%,this represents a 20% difference in post-issuance ROA,

which is economically significant. Models (2) and (3)provide results with respect to the measure IPONUM/Same

Industry Vol. and IPONUM/Same Window Vol., respectively.

Table 7Post-IPO cash balance, industry clusteredness of IPOs, and the order of going public in an IPO wave.

This table presents OLS regressions of post-IPO cash balance on the three measures of industry IPO clusteredness and the three measures of the order of

going public within an IPO wave. The post-IPO cash balance is measured in two ways: Panel A uses the increase in cash and cash equivalents scaled by

total net assets (DATA274/DATA6) as the dependent variable; and Panel B uses cash and short-term investments scaled by total net assets (DATA1/

DATA6). The sample includes IPOs between 1970 and 2006, as listed on SDC. IPOs in which the offer price is less than $5, ADRs, units, REITS, spin-offs,

reverse LBOs, foreign issues, close-end funds, finance and utilities (with FF-49 industry codes 31, 45, 46, and 48), and those offerings whose industries are

unidentified (with FF-49 industry code 49 or missing) are excluded. The three industry IPO clusteredness measures are defined as follows: ‘‘IPONUM’’ is

the total number of IPOs in the same Fama-French 49 industry within the 90-day window symmetrically surrounding each IPO issuance date; ‘‘IPONUM/

Same Industry Vol.’’ is IPONUM scaled by the total number of IPOs in the same FF-49 industry during the whole sample period; and ‘‘IPONUM/Same

Window Vol.’’ is IPONUM scaled by the total number of IPOs in all FF-49 industries during the same 90-day window used to calculate IPONUM. The three

measures for the order of going public within an IPO wave are defined as follows. For any FF-49 industry, we define all IPO waves within it (according to

the procedure outlined in Section 6.1 of the paper) and rank the offerings in a particular wave in terms of their sequence of issuances. Waves whose

number of IPOs is less than five are deleted. We denote the rank by an integer variable ORDER, whose larger values indicate late occurrence in a wave. We

then divide the ranked offerings in a given wave into four groups of equal size and use a dummy variable (EARLINESS) to denote whether an IPO takes

place ‘‘early’’ or ‘‘late’’ in the wave it belongs to. EARLINESS equals ‘‘3’’ if the IPO belongs to the latest batch of offerings, equals ‘‘0’’ if it falls into the

earliest category, and ‘‘1’’ and ‘‘2’’ if in the middle. ‘‘ORDER/Median ORDER’’ is ORDER scaled by its median in the given wave; and ‘‘Log (ORDER)’’ is the

logarithm of ORDER. The other independent variables include: logarithm of firm’s market capital (DATA199nDATA25) at the first fiscal year-end after the

IPO; IPO’s offer price; a dummy variable showing whether the issuer is backed by venture capitalists (equals one if yes); the initial return of the IPO firm’s

stock (difference between the first closing price and the offer price, divided by the offer price); logarithm of total IPO proceeds; percentage of secondary

shares sold in the IPO; firms’ market share within the FF-49 industries based on all Compustat firms’ net sales (DATA12); percentage of shares owned by

institutional investors right after the IPO; logarithm of firm’s age at IPO date (number of years between the firm’s founding year and the IPO year); and

the reputation for underwriters. The first three columns in each panel analyze all firms that went public during the sample period, while the latter three

columns analyze only firms that went public within IPO waves that include at least five same-industry IPOs. All models control for industry (FF-49 level)

and IPO-year fixed effects. White standard errors, clustered at the industry level, adjusted for possible correlation within the cluster (Rogers standard

errors) are reported. Heteroskedasticity-robust t-statistics are reported in parentheses. nnn, nn, and n indicate significance at the 1%, 5%, and 10% levels,

respectively.

Dependent variable: Increase in cash and cash equivalents after the IPO scaled by assets

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)

Panel A: The increase in cash and cash equivalents after the IPO scaled by total net assets

IPONUM 0.0013n

(1.83)

IPONUM/Same Industry Vol. 0.4190nn

(2.12)

IPONUM/Same Window Vol. 0.0319

(0.40)

EARLINESS 0.0201nnn

(3.42)

ORDER/Median ORDER 0.0387nnn

(3.53)

Log (ORDER) 0.0182nnn

(4.09)

Log (market cap) 0.0212nnn 0.0216nnn 0.0214nnn 0.0214nnn 0.0211nnn 0.0214nnn

(5.56) (5.52) (5.41) (4.88) (4.82) (5.02)

Offer Price 0.0020nn 0.0020nn 0.0021nn 0.0022 0.0021 0.0018

(2.15) (2.17) (2.20) (1.52) (1.52) (1.31)

Dummy for VC backing 0.0323nnn 0.0339nnn 0.0335nnn 0.0339nnn 0.0341nnn 0.0322nnn

(3.65) (3.94) (3.81) (3.21) (3.23) (3.10)

Initial Return (percent) 0.0003n 0.0003n 0.0003n 0.0002 0.0002 0.0002

(1.73) (1.71) (1.75) (1.19) (1.21) (1.15)

Log (IPO proceeds) �0.0426nnn�0.0436nnn

�0.0429nnn�0.0423nnn

�0.0420nnn�0.0412nnn

(�6.09) (�6.39) (�6.15) (�4.38) (�4.36) (�4.40)

Percent of Secondary Shares 0.0054 0.0060 0.0054 �0.0085 �0.0082 �0.0133

(0.32) (0.36) (0.33) (�0.37) (�0.35) (�0.60)

Market Share �0.5441 �0.5264 �0.5640 �1.7897nnn�1.7628nnn

�1.6637nnn

(�1.09) (�1.05) (�1.11) (�3.91) (�3.92) (�3.77)

Percent of Institutional Holding 0.0083 0.0055 0.0058 0.0116 0.0116 0.0110

(0.45) (0.29) (0.32) (0.54) (0.54) (0.53)

Log (firm age at IPO date) �0.0273nnn�0.0271nnn

�0.0272nnn�0.0173nnn

�0.0173nnn�0.0178nnn

(�6.54) (�6.49) (�6.48) (�3.88) (�3.86) (�3.94)

Underwriter Reputation �0.0134nnn�0.0132nnn

�0.0132nnn�0.0104nnn

�0.0104nnn�0.0105nnn

(�5.30) (�5.26) (�5.29) (�3.58) (�3.61) (�3.52)

Constant 0.3419nnn 0.3316nnn 0.3464nnn 0.1936nnn 0.1832nnn 0.1970nnn

(8.83) (8.50) (8.79) (5.34) (5.01) (5.05)

Observations 3315 3315 3315 2362 2362 2362

R-squared 0.208 0.207 0.206 0.194 0.194 0.194

T.J. Chemmanur, J. He / Journal of Financial Economics 101 (2011) 382–412406

Page 27: Author's personal copy - ITS - Boston College · ImmuLogic Pharmaceutical Corporation (B-2). To quote: The one certainty about the current open window for biotechnology initial public

Author's personal copy

The coefficients of these two measures are also negativeand statistically significant at the 1% level.

Models (4) to (6) summarize the results of multipleregressions of post-issuance ROA on measures of the orderof going public within a hot period. Model (4) providesresults with respect to the measure EARLINESS. The coeffi-cient of this measure is negative and significant at the 5%level, which is consistent with our sixth hypothesis ðH6Þ thatfirms going public earlier within a wave have better post-IPOprofitability than firms going public later in the wave. Thecoefficient of �0.0076 for EARLINESS means that a firm thatgoes public earlier in a hot period (among the first 25% offirms going public in this IPO wave) will, on average, have anROA 2.3% more than a firm that goes public later in the wave(among the last 25% of firms going public in this hot period).Given that the mean ROA in our sample is 5%, this representsa 46% difference in post-issuance ROA, which is economicallysignificant. Models (5) and (6) yield qualitatively similarresults to those in Model (4). Taken together, these empiricalresults support the hypothesis that, on average, firms goingpublic earlier in an IPO wave will yield a better post-IPOprofitability than those going public later in the wave.

In all our regressions using post-IPO ROA as the depen-dent variable, the coefficient for firm size as proxied by thelogarithm of market capital is significantly positive, whichalso holds true if we use total net assets as an alternative sizemeasure. Firm age as proxied by the logarithm of thenumber of years between a firm’s founding year and itsIPO year also exerts a significantly positive impact on firms’post-IPO operating performance. These results, consistentwith the findings of previous studies such as Mikkelson,Partch, and Shah (1997), suggest that smaller and youngerfirms may still be in their early years of operations and thusneed to incur greater setup costs or charge lower productprices to attract customers (thus earning smaller profitmargins). In line with these findings, firms’ capital expendi-ture and R&D intensity both significantly reduce the profit-ability of the same fiscal year because they represent a formof investment that would pay off only in the long run.Similarly, firms’ market share calculated based on net sales isnot statistically significant, which may be the result of twooffsetting forces. On the one hand, higher market share mayboost sales and thus increase total cash flows. On the otherhand, the firm’s expenditures to increase its market share

Dependent variable: Cash and short-term investments after the IPO scaled by assets

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)

Panel B: The cash and short-term investments after the IPO scaled by total net assets

IPONUM 0.0021nnn

(2.93)

IPONUM/Same Industry Vol. 0.8378nnn

(2.74)

IPONUM/Same Window Vol. 0.1948nn

(2.07)

EARLINESS 0.0104

(1.37)

ORDER/Median ORDER 0.0218

(1.60)

Log (ORDER) 0.0220nnn

(3.38)

Log (market cap) 0.0168nnn 0.0175nnn 0.0170nnn 0.0114n 0.0113n 0.0121n

(2.82) (2.92) (2.84) (1.75) (1.74) (1.83)

Offer Price 0.0043nn 0.0043nn 0.0043nn 0.0044nn 0.0044nn 0.0042nn

(2.44) (2.42) (2.47) (2.03) (2.04) (2.04)

Dummy for VC backing 0.0998nnn 0.1024nnn 0.1007nnn 0.1000nnn 0.1001nnn 0.0982nnn

(8.27) (8.65) (8.29) (8.19) (8.20) (7.96)

Initial Return (percent) 0.0004nnn 0.0004nnn 0.0004nnn 0.0003nn 0.0003nn 0.0003nn

(3.20) (3.09) (3.11) (2.29) (2.32) (2.22)

Log (IPO proceeds) �0.0637nnn�0.0656nnn

�0.0636nnn�0.0604nnn

�0.0603nnn�0.0594nnn

(�6.08) (�6.67) (�6.11) (�3.96) (�3.97) (�3.91)

Percent of Secondary Shares 0.0005 0.0017 0.0010 �0.0084 �0.0081 �0.0125

(0.019) (0.063) (0.037) (�0.23) (�0.23) (�0.36)

Market Share �0.6013 �0.5579 �0.6163 �2.1010nnn�2.0927nnn

�2.0575nnn

(�0.95) (�0.88) (�0.97) (�3.04) (�3.03) (�3.00)

Percent of Institutional Holding �0.0734nnn�0.0780nnn

�0.0758nnn�0.0726nn

�0.0724nn�0.0718nn

(�2.90) (�3.08) (�3.00) (�2.19) (�2.19) (�2.16)

Log (firm age at IPO date) �0.0453nnn�0.0450nnn

�0.0451nnn�0.0407nnn

�0.0406nnn�0.0407nnn

(�6.64) (�6.65) (�6.61) (�5.91) (�5.87) (�5.86)

Underwriter Reputation �0.0021 �0.0018 �0.0020 0.0030 0.0030 0.0025

(�0.56) (�0.49) (�0.52) (0.78) (0.78) (0.64)

Constant 0.4603nnn 0.4377nnn 0.4613nnn 0.4564nnn 0.4478nnn 0.4173nnn

(8.72) (8.26) (8.68) (8.23) (7.94) (7.73)

Observations 3315 3315 3315 2362 2362 2362

R-squared 0.481 0.479 0.479 0.475 0.475 0.479

Table 7 (continued)

T.J. Chemmanur, J. He / Journal of Financial Economics 101 (2011) 382–412 407

Page 28: Author's personal copy - ITS - Boston College · ImmuLogic Pharmaceutical Corporation (B-2). To quote: The one certainty about the current open window for biotechnology initial public

Author's personal copy

may lead to high operating costs, lowering the profits for thecurrent fiscal year (but may benefit long-term profits).

Everything else equal, IPOs with larger total proceedsexhibit lower post-issuance ROA, which is consistent withthe finding that larger firms (in terms of post-IPO marketcapital) tend to have better ROA. This is because, condi-tional on the level of post-IPO market cap, larger totalproceeds implies smaller pre-IPO firm size, indicating alower profitability after the IPO.41 We also find that theoffer price of an IPO is positively related to the issuer’spost-IPO operating performance, which is consistent withthe information spillover argument of Alti (2005) that ahigher offer price reveals better news about firm quality.The dummy for venture capital (VC) backing shows amoderately significant negative impact on post-IPO ROA,which may be a consequence of VC-backed firms beingable to go public when they are younger. We also find asignificantly negative relationship between initial returns(underpricing) and post-IPO operating performance,which is consistent with Ritter (1991) who finds thatinitial returns are negatively correlated with long-runstock return performance. Our results show that thepercentage of secondary shares sold in an offering ispositively related to its post-IPO ROA, which is consistentwith the finding of Mikkelson, Partch, and Shah (1997)but contradicts that of Jain and Kini (1994). This positiverelationship might be the outcome of both issuers’ andinvestment banks’ efforts to reduce the unfavorableinformation conveyed by offerings with secondary sharesales (suggested by models such as Leland and Pyle,1977): in order to successfully complete such an offering,the IPO firm must have better future prospects and ahigher level of expected post-issuance operating profits.Lastly, we find that IPO firms with more shares held byinstitutional investors and those underwritten by morereputable investment banks have a higher post-IPO ROA,which is consistent with the common intuition thatinstitutional investors and higher reputation underwritersare associated with higher-quality firms going public.

7.3.1. Robustness tests of post-IPO operating performance

analysis

In this subsection, we conduct several robustness testsregarding the above post-IPO operating performanceanalysis. As we discussed in Section 7.2.1, our findingsthat firms going public outside a wave have better post-IPO profitability than those going public within a wave

and that firms going public earlier in a wave have betterpost-IPO profitability than those going public later in thewave may also be generated by a market condition modelalong the lines of Pastor and Veronesi (2005). Hence, todistinguish our model predictions from the market con-dition model of Pastor and Veronesi (2005), we nowcontrol for short-term and long-term stock market con-ditions when empirically comparing the post-IPO operat-ing performance of on-the-wave versus off-the-wavefirms, and early-in-the-wave versus later-in-the-wavefirms.

As in Section 7.2.1, we introduce several market con-dition variables into our regressions of the effect of IPOclusteredness and the order of going public on post-IPOprofitability, mainly following Pastor and Veronesi (2005).Our results incorporating the above controls are pre-sented in Table A2 (as part of Internet Appendix Aavailable from the authors’ Web sites).42 Consistent withthe variant of the Pastor and Veronesi (2005) marketcondition theory discussed in Section 7.2.1, the coefficientof IPO Month Market Return is significantly negative inModels (1) and (6), suggesting that firms going publicduring excellent market conditions tend to be lower-quality firms, and therefore show worse post-IPO operat-ing performance. However, the significantly negativecoefficients of IPONUM/Same Industry Vol. and EARLINESS

in all model specifications show that even after control-ling for short- and long-term stock market conditions,firms going public outside a wave tend to have betterpost-IPO operating performance than those going publicwithin a wave, and firms going public earlier in a wavetend to have better post-IPO operating performance thanthose going public later in the wave. In summary, whilewe find significant support for the variant of the Pastorand Veronesi (2005) model discussed in Section 7.2.1, wealso find residual empirical support for the predictions ofour product market theory of IPO waves.43

We have also conducted a long-term post-IPO operat-ing performance analysis by using the three-year averageROA after a firm goes public.44 These results are presentedin Table A3 (as part of Internet Appendix A available fromthe authors’ Web sites). Consistent with our predictions,Models (1) to (3) show that firms going public outside a

41 In fact, the variable Log (IPO proceeds) is highly correlated with

the size variable Log (market cap) (with Pearson correlation coefficient

of 0.85), suggesting some problem of multicollinearity. However, in

unreported work, we run regressions with either one of them and obtain

both qualitatively and quantitatively similar coefficients of IPO timing

variables (measures for clusteredness and the order of going public). If

we exclude Log (market cap), then IPO proceeds will have a significantly

positive effect on post-IPO ROA if not controlling for firm age and

underwriter reputation but a significantly negative effect after we

control for firm age and underwriter reputation. If we exclude Log

(proceeds), then Log (market cap) continues to have a significantly

positive impact on post-IPO ROA in all specifications. To avoid omitted

variable bias, we thus include both of them in our current model

specifications.

42 Due to space constraints, we present these robustness tests on

the effect of IPO clusteredness and the order of going public on post-IPO

operating performance after controlling for various market condition

variables using only one measure of IPO clusteredness and one measure

of the order of going public in a wave. The results of additional

specifications using these two measures as well as our analysis based

on additional specifications using all three measures of clusteredness

and the order of going public are available upon request. These addi-

tional results are very similar to those presented in Table A2.43 As a further robustness check, we separated our sample into two

subsamples based on IPO Month Stock Return: a ‘‘hot’’ one (when IPO

Month Market Return is above the median) and a ‘‘cold’’ one (when IPO

Month Market Return is below the median). We regressed Post-IPO ROA

on the three measures of clusteredness and the three measures of the

order of going public in each subsample and found all the coefficients of

these measures to be significantly negative, consistent with our model

predictions.44 The two-year average ROA results are qualitatively similar and

are available from the authors upon request.

T.J. Chemmanur, J. He / Journal of Financial Economics 101 (2011) 382–412408

Page 29: Author's personal copy - ITS - Boston College · ImmuLogic Pharmaceutical Corporation (B-2). To quote: The one certainty about the current open window for biotechnology initial public

Author's personal copy

wave have better long-term post-IPO profitability thanfirms going public within a wave, even after controllingfor various firm and market conditions. Similarly, Models(4) to (6) show that firms going public earlier in a wavehave better long-term post-IPO profitability than firmsgoing public later in the wave, after various controls.

7.4. Cash usage, industry IPO clusteredness, and the order of

going public in a wave

In this subsection, we carry out a multivariate analysisof the different cash usage intensities between firmsgoing public in an IPO wave and those going publicoutside it (H7), and between firms going public earlier inan IPO wave and those going public later in the wave (H8).

Table 7 presents the results of multiple regressions ofpost-IPO cash balance and increases in cash holdings onmeasures of IPO timing (industry clusteredness and theorder of going public within an IPO wave). Panel Aprovides results with respect to our first cash usagemeasure: the post-IPO increase in cash and cash equiva-lents scaled by total net assets. As we can see, the increasein cash balance for firms going public in a hot period(with larger clusteredness measures) is in general morethan those going public in a cold period, and this positiverelationship is statistically significant at the 10% level forIPONUM and at the 5% level for IPONUM/Same Industry Vol.

The results with respect to the order of going public in anIPO wave are much stronger: firms going public later in anIPO wave (with larger measures for the order of goingpublic) in general have greater increases in cash balancethan those going public earlier in the wave, and thepositive relationship is significant at the 1% level for allthree measures for the order of going public. An examina-tion of other control variables shows that younger firmswith larger post-IPO market capital, smaller IPO size (interms of total proceeds), lower underwriter reputation,and those backed by venture capital have larger increasesin cash and cash equivalents.

Panel B provides results with respect to our secondcash usage measure: cash and short-term investmentsafter the IPO scaled by total net assets. As in Panel A, thepost-IPO cash balance for firms going public in an IPOwave (with larger clusteredness measures) is in generallarger than for those going public off the wave, and thispositive relationship is statistically significant at the 1%level for IPONUM and IPONUM/Same Industry Vol. More-over, firms going public later in an IPO wave (with largermeasures for the order of going public) in general have alarger balance in cash and short-term investments thanthose going public later in the wave, but the positiverelationship is significant at the 1% level only for Log(ORDER). However, although the coefficients for EARLI-

NESS and ORDER/Median ORDER are not statistically sig-nificant, the t-values are not very small (both biggerthan 1.3).

In sum, the empirical results presented in this subsec-tion broadly support our hypotheses (H7 and H8) thatafter controlling for the total amount of proceeds raised,firms going public within an IPO wave will, on average,hold more cash on hand (or, use less cash raised through

their offerings) than firms going public off the wave, andthat firms going public earlier in an IPO wave will, onaverage, hold more cash on hand than firms going publiclater in the wave.45

7.5. Post-IPO operating performance, industry

concentration, and IPO timing

In this subsection, we carry out a multivariate analysisof the influence that industry concentration exerts on therelationship between post-issuance operating perfor-mance and IPO timing variables (clusteredness as wellas the order of going public). We test whether higherindustry concentration intensifies or weakens the super-ior post-IPO profitability of firms that go public in a coldperiod or earlier in a wave, which is our ninth hypothesis(H9).

Table 8 summarizes the results of multiple regressionsof post-issuance ROA on measures of IPO timing (cluste-redness or the order of going public), the Herfindahl-Hirschman Index (HHI), and the interaction of HHI andIPO timing measures. If industry concentration amplifiesthe difference in post-IPO operating performance for firmsthat go public on the wave versus those that go public offthe wave and for firms going public earlier in a waveversus those going public later in the wave, then weexpect the coefficients before the interaction of HHI andtiming variables to be significantly negative. If, on theother hand, industry concentration weakens the relation-ship between post-IPO ROA and the timing of an IPO, thenwe expect the interaction variable to be significantlypositive. If industry concentration cannot adequatelyproxy for how IPOs enhance firms’ product market com-petitiveness or the two effects that concentration has onthe performance-timing relationship cancel each other,then the coefficient before the interaction term should beinsignificant.

Panel A provides results with respect to industry IPOclusteredness. The interaction of HHI and clusterednessmeasures is positive in all three models and statisticallysignificant when we use the measure IPONUM/Same

Window Vol. Even for Models (1) and (2) where theinteraction term is not statistically significant at the 10%level, the t-statistics are still greater than 1.0, showingweak evidence that industry concentration weakens therelationship between post-IPO ROA and the timing of anIPO. The main effect of clusteredness measures on post-issuance operating performance remains significantlynegative, consistent with our findings in Table 6 (testingH5). Nevertheless, the Herfindahl-Hirschman Index itselfhas a weak negative impact on firms’ post-IPO ROA,contradicting the common intuition that less competition(or more concentration) renders more opportunities tomanipulate price and earn higher monopoly rents.

45 By defining hot and cold periods according to total monthly IPO

volume (for all industries), Alti (2006) also finds that hot-market issuers

raise more equity than needed, adding more of the IPO proceeds to their

cash and short-term investments than to other long-term assets. How-

ever, he does not examine the cash usage of firms going public earlier

versus later within an IPO wave.

T.J. Chemmanur, J. He / Journal of Financial Economics 101 (2011) 382–412 409

Page 30: Author's personal copy - ITS - Boston College · ImmuLogic Pharmaceutical Corporation (B-2). To quote: The one certainty about the current open window for biotechnology initial public

Author's personal copy

Table 8Industry concentration, post-IPO operating performance, industry clusteredness of IPOs, and the order of going public in an IPO wave.

This table presents OLS regressions of post-IPO operating performance on industry concentration, the three measures of industry IPO clusteredness, the

three measures of the order of going public within an IPO wave, and the interaction between concentration and IPO clusteredness and order measures. The

post-IPO operating performance measure is defined as the return on assets (ROA) for the first fiscal year after the IPO date (Compustat DATA13/DATA6).

Industry concentration is the Herfindahl-Hirschman Index (HHI) calculated based on all Compustat firms’ post-IPO total net assets within a certain FF-49

industry. The sample includes IPOs between 1970 and 2006, as listed on SDC. IPOs in which the offer price is less than $5, ADRs, units, REITS, spin-offs,

reverse LBOs, foreign issues, close-end funds, finance and utilities (with FF-49 industry codes 31, 45, 46, and 48), and those offerings whose industries are

unidentified (with FF-49 industry code 49 or missing) are excluded. The three industry IPO clusteredness measures are defined as follows: ‘‘IPONUM’’ is the

total number of IPOs in the same Fama-French 49 industry within the 90-day window symmetrically surrounding each IPO issuance date; ‘‘IPONUM/Same

Industry Vol.’’ is IPONUM scaled by the total number of IPOs in the same FF-49 industry during the whole sample period; and ‘‘IPONUM/Same Window Vol.’’

is IPONUM scaled by the total number of IPOs in all FF-49 industries during the same 90-day window used to calculate IPONUM. The three measures for the

order of going public within an IPO wave are defined as follows. For any FF-49 industry, we define all IPO waves within it (according to the procedure

outlined in Section 6.1 of the paper) and rank the offerings in a particular wave in terms of their sequence of issuances. Waves whose number of IPOs is

less than five are deleted. We denote the rank by an integer variable ORDER, whose larger values indicate late occurrence in a wave. We then divide the

ranked offerings in a given wave into four groups of equal size and use a dummy variable (EARLINESS) to denote whether an IPO takes place ‘‘early’’ or

‘‘late’’ in the wave it belongs to. EARLINESS equals ‘‘3’’ if the IPO belongs to the latest batch of offerings, equals ‘‘0’’ if it falls into the earliest category, and

‘‘1’’ and ‘‘2’’ if in the middle. ‘‘ORDER/Median ORDER’’ is ORDER scaled by its median in the given wave; and ‘‘Log (ORDER)’’ is the logarithm of ORDER. The

other independent variables include: logarithm of firm’s market capital (DATA199nDATA25) at the first fiscal year-end after the IPO; IPO’s offer price; a

dummy variable showing whether the issuer is backed by venture capitalists (equals one if yes); the initial return of the IPO firm’s stock (difference

between the first closing price and the offer price, divided by the offer price); logarithm of total IPO proceeds; percentage of secondary shares sold in the

IPO; firms’ market share within the FF-49 industries based on all Compustat firms’ net sales (DATA12); percentage of shares owned by institutional

investors right after the IPO; logarithm of firm’s age at IPO date (number of years between the firm’s founding year and the IPO year); capital expenditure

scaled by firm’s net property, plant, and equipment (DATA128/DATA8); research and development expenses scaled by total net assets (DATA46/DATA6);

and the reputation for underwriters. Panel A analyzes all firms that went public during the sample period, while Panel B analyzes only firms that went

public within IPO waves that include at least five same-industry IPOs. All models control for industry (FF-49 level) and IPO-year fixed effects. White

standard errors, clustered at the industry level, adjusted for possible correlation within the cluster (Rogers standard errors) are reported. Hetero-

skedasticity-robust t-statistics are reported in parentheses. nnn, nn, and n indicate significance at the 1%, 5%, and 10% levels, respectively.

Dependent variable: ROA

(1) (2) (3)

Panel A: Industry concentration and IPO clusteredness

IPONUM �0.0020nnn

(�3.33)

Herfindahl Index n IPONUM 0.0064

(1.37)

IPONUM/Same Industry Vol. (IPONUM_1) �0.8502nn

(�2.58)

Herfindahl Index n IPONUM_1 1.5138

(1.07)

IPONUM/ Same Window Vol. (IPONUM_2) �0.3086nnn

(�4.49)

Herfindahl Index n IPONUM_2 1.1343nnn

(3.02)

Herfindahl Index �0.0730n�0.0657 �0.0966nn

(�1.84) (�0.92) (�2.34)

Log (market cap) 0.0580nnn 0.0572nnn 0.0581nnn

(8.60) (8.56) (8.61)

Offer Price 0.0033nn 0.0033nn 0.0034nn

(2.60) (2.57) (2.58)

Dummy for VC backing �0.0253nn�0.0270nn

�0.0258nn

(�2.44) (�2.56) (�2.50)

Initial Return (percent) �0.0004nnn�0.0004nnn

�0.0004nnn

(�5.21) (�5.01) (�5.12)

Log (IPO proceeds) �0.0748nnn�0.0733nnn

�0.0752nnn

(�7.76) (�7.64) (�7.73)

Percent of Secondary Shares 0.2019nnn 0.2028nnn 0.2012nnn

(7.13) (7.10) (7.04)

Market Share �0.2280 �0.2478 �0.2374

(�1.06) (�1.09) (�1.10)

Percent of Institutional Holding 0.1162nnn 0.1194nnn 0.1171nnn

(5.95) (6.02) (6.13)

Log (firm age at IPO date) 0.0317nnn 0.0312nnn 0.0315nnn

(5.56) (5.63) (5.61)

CapEx/PPE �0.0623nnn�0.0639nnn

�0.0618nnn

(�4.81) (�4.94) (�4.75)

R & D/Assets �1.0484nnn�1.0527nnn

�1.0413nnn

(�8.94) (�9.03) (�9.01)

Underwriter Reputation 0.0095nnn 0.0092nnn 0.0095nnn

(4.96) (4.82) (5.11)

Constant �0.0627n�0.0476 �0.0557

(�1.78) (�1.59) (�1.64)

T.J. Chemmanur, J. He / Journal of Financial Economics 101 (2011) 382–412410

Page 31: Author's personal copy - ITS - Boston College · ImmuLogic Pharmaceutical Corporation (B-2). To quote: The one certainty about the current open window for biotechnology initial public

Author's personal copy

Panel B presents results with respect to the order ofgoing public within a given IPO wave. Similar to Panel A,the interaction of HHI and earliness measures is positivein all three models. Moreover, the positive effect is muchmore significant than in Panel A, with all three t-statisticsexceeding 2.29. This finding strongly supports the con-clusion that industry concentration weakens the relation-ship between post-IPO ROA and the timing of an IPO. Themain effect of measures for the order of going public in awave on post-issuance operating performance remainssignificantly negative, consistent with our findings inTable 6 (testing H6). In addition, the Herfindahl-

Hirschman Index itself has a strong negative impact onfirms’ post-IPO ROA, consistent with our findings in PanelA as well as the sign of interaction variables in Panel B.

In sum, our results suggest that a public debut will addless to a firm’s product market competitiveness in highlyconcentrated industries and may thus fail to induce it togo public purely out of competition concerns. Therefore, itseems to be the case that larger firms that already have assignificant a market share in an industry as private firmsdo not have too much to gain by going public. This isbecause such firms may already have considerable cred-ibility with potential employees, customers, and suppliers

Table 8 (continued )

Dependent variable: ROA

(1) (2) (3)

Panel A: Industry concentration and IPO clusteredness

Observations 3259 3259 3259

R-squared 0.556 0.555 0.557

Dependent variable: ROA

(1) (2) (3)

Panel B: Industry concentration and the order of going public in an IPO wave

EARLINESS �0.0152nnn

(�3.62)

Herfindahl Index n EARLINESS 0.0750nnn

(3.40)

ORDER/Median ORDER (ORDER_N) �0.0271nnn

(�3.46)

Herfindahl Index nORDER_N 0.1092nn

(2.57)

Log (ORDER) �0.0143nnn

(�2.91)

Herfindahl Index n Log (ORDER) 0.0633nn

(2.29)

Herfindahl Index �0.1827nnn�0.1809nn

�0.2266nnn

(�2.96) (�2.50) (�4.05)

Log (market cap) 0.0541nnn 0.0543nnn 0.0542nnn

(8.13) (8.17) (7.96)

Offer Price 0.0034nn 0.0034nn 0.0037nn

(2.08) (2.07) (2.32)

Dummy for VC backing �0.0373nnn�0.0374nnn

�0.0370nnn

(�3.54) (�3.54) (�3.48)

Initial Return (percent) �0.0003nnn�0.0003nnn

�0.0003nnn

(�3.39) (�3.40) (�3.50)

Log (IPO proceeds) �0.0808nnn�0.0810nnn

�0.0818nnn

(�6.90) (�6.94) (�6.96)

Percent of Secondary Shares 0.2380nnn 0.2376nnn 0.2384nnn

(7.21) (7.24) (7.34)

Market Share 0.2341 0.2381 0.1824

(0.41) (0.42) (0.32)

Percent of Institutional Holding 0.1370nnn 0.1371nnn 0.1383nnn

(4.26) (4.26) (4.38)

Log (firm age at IPO date) 0.0317nnn 0.0316nnn 0.0319nnn

(5.33) (5.28) (5.33)

CapEx/PPE �0.0825nnn�0.0830nnn

�0.0818nnn

(�5.78) (�5.81) (�5.60)

R & D/Assets �1.0615nnn�1.0619nnn

�1.0519nnn

(�8.96) (�8.85) (�8.79)

Underwriter Reputation 0.0110nnn 0.0110nnn 0.0112nnn

(4.90) (4.85) (4.97)

Constant �0.1461nn�0.1400nn

�0.1438nn

(�2.46) (�2.40) (�2.31)

Observations 2321 2321 2321

R-squared 0.582 0.582 0.582

T.J. Chemmanur, J. He / Journal of Financial Economics 101 (2011) 382–412 411

Page 32: Author's personal copy - ITS - Boston College · ImmuLogic Pharmaceutical Corporation (B-2). To quote: The one certainty about the current open window for biotechnology initial public

Author's personal copy

even when they are private. Consequently, a higher level ofindustry concentration weakens the difference in post-IPOperformance for firms that go public on the wave versusthose that go public off the wave, and firms going publicearlier in a wave versus those going public later in the wave.

8. Conclusion

In this paper, we have developed a new rationale forIPO waves based on product market considerations. In ourmodel, two firms, with differing productivity levels, com-pete in an industry with a significant probability of apositive productivity shock. Going public, though costly,not only allows a firm to raise external capital cheaply,but also enables it to grab market share from its privatecompetitors. We solved for the decision of each firm to gopublic versus remain private, and the optimal timing ofgoing public. In equilibrium, even firms with sufficientinternal capital to fund their investment may go public,driven by the possibility of their product market compe-titors going public. IPO waves may arise in equilibriumeven in industries which do not experience a productivityshock. Our model predicts that firms going public duringan IPO wave will have lower productivity and post-IPOprofitability but larger cash holdings than those goingpublic off the wave; it makes similar predictions forfirms going public later versus earlier in an IPO wave.We empirically tested and found support for thesepredictions.

Appendix A. Supplementary data

Supplementary data associated with this article can befound in the online version at doi:10.1016/j.jfineco.2011.03.009.

References

Allen, F., Faulhaber, G.R., 1989. Signaling by underpricing in the IPOmarket. Journal of Financial Economics 23, 303–323.

Alti, A., 2005. IPO market timing. Review of Financial Studies 18,1105–1138.

Alti, A., 2006. How persistent is the impact of market timing on capitalstructure. Journal of Finance 61, 1681–1710.

Benveniste, L.M., Ljungqvist, A.P., Wilhelm, W.J., Yu, X., 2003. Evidence ofinformation spillovers in the production of investment bankingservices. Journal of Finance 58, 577–608.

Boot, A.W.A., Gopalan, R., Thakor, A.V., 2006. The entrepreneur’s choicebetween private and public ownership. Journal of Finance 61,803–836.

Chemmanur, T.J., 1993. The pricing of initial public offerings: a dynamicmodel with information production. Journal of Finance 48, 285–304.

Chemmanur, T.J., Yan, A., 2009. Product market advertising and newequity issues. Journal of Financial Economics 92, 40–65.

Chemmanur, T.J., Fulghieri, P., 1999. A theory of the going-publicdecision. Review of Financial Studies 12, 249–279.

Chemmanur, T.J., He, S., Nandy, D., 2010. The going public decision andthe product market. Review of Financial Studies 23, 1855–1908.

Chod, J., Lyandres, E., 2011. Strategic IPOs and product market competi-tion. Journal of Financial Economics 100, 45–67.

Grinblatt, M., Hwang, C.Y., 1989. Signaling and the pricing of new issues.Journal of Finance 44, 393–420.

Helwege, J., Liang, N., 2004. Initial public offerings in hot and cold markets.Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 39, 541–560.

Hsu, H., Reed, A.V., Rocholl, J., 2010. The new game in town: competitiveeffects of IPOs. Journal of Finance 65, 495–528.

Jain, B.A., Kini, O., 1994. The post-issue operating performance of IPOfirms. Journal of Finance 49, 1699–1726.

Khanna, N., Noe, T.H., Sonti, R., 2008. Good IPOs draw in bad: inelasticbanking capacity and hot markets. Review of Financial Studies 21,1873–1906.

Killian, L.R., Smith, K.S., Smith, K., 2001. IPOs for Everyone: the 12 Secretsof Investing in IPOs. Wiley, Indianapolis, IN.

Lanchester, F.W., 1916. Aircraft in Warfare: The Dawn of the Fourth Arm.Constable, London.

Leland, H., Pyle, D., 1977. Information asymmetries, financial structure,and financial intermediation. Journal of Finance 32, 371–387.

Lieberman, M.B., Montgomery, D.B., 1988. First-mover advantages.Strategic Management Journal 9, 41–58.

Lowry, M., 2003. Why does IPO volume fluctuate so much? Journal ofFinancial Economics 67, 3–40

Lowry, M., Schwert, G.W., 2002. IPO market cycles: bubbles or sequentiallearning? Journal of Finance 57, 1171–1200

Maksimovic, V., Pichler, P., 2001. Technological innovation and initialpublic offerings. Review of Financial Studies 14, 459–494.

Mikkelson, W.H., Partch, M.M., Shah, K., 1997. Ownership and operatingperformance of companies that go public. Journal of FinancialEconomics 44, 281–307.

Pagano, M., Panetta, F., Zingales, L., 1998. Why do companies go public?An empirical analysis. Journal of Finance 53, 27–64.

Pastor, L., Veronesi, P., 2005. Rational IPO waves. Journal of Finance 60,1713–1757.

Pastor, L., Taylor, L., Veronesi, P., 2009. Entrepreneurial learning, the IPOdecision, and the post-IPO drop in firm profitability. Review ofFinancial Studies 22, 3005–3046.

Ritter, J.R., 1984. The ‘‘hot issue’’ market of 1980. Journal of Business 57,215–240.

Ritter, J.R., 1987. The costs of going public. Journal of Financial Econom-ics 19, 269–280.

Ritter, J.R., 1991. The long-run performance of initial public offerings.Journal of Finance 46, 3–27.

Ritter, J.R., Welch, I., 2002. A review of IPO activity, pricing, andallocations. Journal of Finance 57, 1795–1828.

Robinson, W.T., Kalyanaram, G., Urban, G.L., 1994. First-mover advan-tages from pioneering new markets: a survey of empirical evidence.Review of Industrial Organization 9, 1–23.

Schmalensee, R., 1978. Entry deterrence in the ready to eat breakfastcereal industry. Bell Journal of Economics 9, 305–327.

Slovin, M.B., Sushka, M.E., Ferraro, S.R., 1995. A comparison of theinformation conveyed by equity carve-outs, spin-offs, and assetsell-offs. Journal of Financial Economics 37, 89–104.

Spence, M., 1981. The learning curve and competition. Bell Journal ofEconomics 12, 49–70.

Spiegel, M., Tookes, H., 2007. Dynamic competition, innovation andstrategic financing. Unpublished working paper, Yale University.

Stoughton, N.M., Wong, K.P., Zechner, J., 2001. IPOs and product quality.Journal of Business 74, 375–408.

Welch, I., 1989. Seasoned offerings, imitation costs, and the underpricingof initial public offerings. Journal of Finance 44, 421–449.

Wernerfelt, B., 1985. Brand loyalty and user skills. Journal of EconomicBehavior and Organization 6, 381–385.

Yung, C., C- olak, G., Wang, W., 2008. Cycles in the IPO market. Journal ofFinancial Economics 89, 192–208.

T.J. Chemmanur, J. He / Journal of Financial Economics 101 (2011) 382–412412