belussi (1)

Upload: natsmd

Post on 14-Apr-2018

215 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

  • 7/30/2019 belussi (1)

    1/24

    Knowledge creation and learning in the institutional governance of the

    Italian local production systems

    by F. Belussi and L. Pilotti - Padua University

    Second draft

    May 1999

    1

    1

  • 7/30/2019 belussi (1)

    2/24

    The theory of perfect competition is unscientific because, byassuming a world of perfect knowledge in which firms cannot

    interact to change their economic environments, such a theory

    imposes pompous preconditions on our subject matter: competitors

    are so constrained in behaviour in which they can engage....we areprecluded from understanding economic reality or developing a

    testable theory. Burton H. Klein (1977, p. 71)

    1. Introduction

    The aim of this paper is to present an overview about the various mechanisms ofknowledge creation, diffusion, and assimilation, which are found within the so-called

    Italian local production systems. For this type of analysis we use here a wide

    definition of local production systems (LPS) which includes: typical industrial

    districts, multi-sectors district areas, local systems governed by large leading firms,

    and various aggregations of productive systems in territorial clusters (Belussi, 1999).

    This paper discusses the process of knowledge creation and learning within the

    governance of the Italian LPS, and the role played by tacit and codified knowledge.

    Using the seminal contribution of Polany and Nonaka, we can trace a clear cut

    distinction between the two forms of knowledge above mentioned. Codification refers

    to a form of objectivated knowledge (a set of justified true beliefs), thus an explicit

    form of knowledge that is related to the scientific results of basic research andinnovative activity (a body of facts, information, principles and practical

    understanding of science). In turn, explicit knowledge may be classified in two ways.

    As disembodied, if refers to the progress of science and technology (laws, formulas,

    meaningful set of information articulated in clear language including numbers or

    diagrams, or scientific discoveries related to then state of organic or inorganic

    substance: new compounds, new materials, etc.). Or as embodied, if it lies within

    technological tools such as scientific instrumentation, new machinery, or new

    information and communication technology with an enlarged computational

    capability, and etc.

    Intuitively, this is opposed to tacitness1, a subjective (both individual and shared)

    property of knowledge, linked to the abilities that individual possesses on the basis ofpieces of knowledge developed through practical experience (unarticulated mental

    models, intuitions, skills).

    The idea developed in this paper, based on many pieces of empirical research

    conducted by the authors over the last decade, is that the Italian LPS may be

    categorised on the basis of the prevalence of the pool of knowledge they have access

    to. In turn, this appears in relation with the presence of various forms of learning.

    Adopting this approach we can distinguish the Italian local production systems (LPS)

    into three main categories2:

    1It is important to point out that tacit knowledge is not closely related to craftsmanship. Polanyi, the author who developed the

    concept of tacit knowledge, based his theoretical framework on the analysis of the activities performed by a group of scientists(Polanyi, 1958). See also Ryle (1949).2

    We can assume that all knowledge developed and transferred among local agents bears the characteristics of being

    contextual knowledge: a collective good whose generation and expansion is the result of a process that combines pieces of

    information and knowledge that are owned by a variety of parties and that cannot be traded as such (Antonelli, 1999b). This

    2

    2

  • 7/30/2019 belussi (1)

    3/24

    a) Systems based mainly on the horizontal expansion of a given stock of knowledge,

    historically accumulated in particular localities, where tacit knowledge among

    agents is prevailing;

    b) Systems where the specialisation of the local manufacturing structure has gone

    further, and it has activated a process of absorption of external knowledge. So, avertical and an horizontal process of knowledge expansion has occurred. Thus, the

    stock of knowledge possessed by local firms is formed by a balanced pool of tacit

    and codified knowledge.

    c) Systems organised around knowledge generating firms, where the knowledge

    creation process has enlarged the local (and the global) stock of knowledge. Here

    we assume the presence of systematic radical innovations. The trade balance of

    knowledge sees the LPS as importers of knowledge and as exporters of

    knowledge. Within this group of LPS, export flows of knowledge are more

    relevant than import flows: the clustering of innovations and the total amount of

    knowledge embedded in local firms allow us to define these LPS as technological

    districts. Here, among firms codified knowledge prevails, but tacit knowledgeremains important.

    The evolutionary pattern of Italian local production systems may be fully understood if

    the institutional complexity that exists behind these historical aggregations of

    manufacturing firms is considered. Not only local firms are active agents in

    knowledge producing, but also local institutions contribute to the process of

    information and knowledge diffusion. So, in various ways, tacit and codified

    knowledge is elaborated, recombined, transferred, and socialised as a circular process

    between the two basic typologies.

    This paper, given the debate that has arisen in recent years on codified knowledge

    versus non-codified knowledge, examines the wide ranging international debate.

    Theoretical knowledge in modern times has developed at a quite spectacular pace.

    However, in our paper, we examine the view that the process of growth of knowledge

    observable in our society might be depicted simply as a radical shift towards a

    generalised process of codification.

    The main purpose of the paper is to reassess the importance of tacit knowledge

    in modern economic systems. We address the issue of the importance of tacit

    knowledge not only in its pivotal role of (new) knowledge generation in high-tech

    sectors, as in Senker (1995), or MacKenzie and Spinardi (1995).

    The idea discussed throughout this essay is that tacit knowledge always plays a

    significant role in firms

    3

    , in all branches of economic activity. Despite its importance itis generally ignored in the economic literature. We believe that a proper understanding

    of the tacit elements of knowledge is decisive in modelling industrial dynamics. The

    role of tacit knowledge in firms is in fact central to the absorption and the practical

    utilisation of external knowledge. And, because the amount of external knowledge

    that firms require to operate is undoubtedly greater than the knowledge that they can

    reasonably afford to produce in-house, tacit knowledge become a strategic element in

    firm organisation. More specifically, in the interpretation proposed here, economic

    approach follows in part the Hayekian view, where knowledge is stated as partially private, empirical, often tacit, and not all

    gained through price signals (ODriscoll and Rizzo, 1985, p. 102). Then, the assumption of a world of perfect knowledge is

    unrealistic; what is relevant for the economic agents is the knowledge of the particular circumstances of time and place(Hayek, 1945).3The approach presented, with some variations, is similar to one employed by Nonaka, and by the stream of studies started offafter the Nonaka contribution (Nonaka, 1993; 1995; and Nonaka, Umemoto, and Senoo, 1996).

    3

    3

  • 7/30/2019 belussi (1)

    4/24

    agents, in order to have access to the existing stock of knowledge, and to put codified

    knowledge in action, need a great deal of cognitive capabilities, and informal skills.

    New ideas, and new technical solutions, are continuously generated in the world, but

    the process of knowledge transfer is much more complex than one portrayed by

    standard theory. In order to have access to novelties, firms must be aware of them, and

    then they must be able to assimilate and absorb the new knowledge generated outside.The application of new knowledge requires acceptance, adoption and inter-firm

    diffusion. All these sub-processes are related to informal learning capability (Gilbert

    and Cordey-Hayes, 1990). Thus, the successful management of knowledge transfer

    needs firstly, a re-contextualization of external knowledge (for reconverting and

    decoding the innovation), and secondly, an operational encoding of this new

    knowledge into the internal firms capabilities and organisational routines. During

    these different steps tacit knowledge is retained, accumulated, and spontaneously

    created within organisations.

    But what can we say about the relation between tacit knowledge and codified

    knowledge?

    David and Foray (1995) put forward the thesis that because the scope of whatcan be codified seems to be continually expanding (thanks to the new advances

    produced by the scientific and technological progress), the codification of knowledge

    is central to the modern process of dissemination, transfer and retention of knowledge.

    Cowan and Foray (1997), linking codification with the dynamics of the firm

    information structures, reinvigorate this thesis. A similar point is also outlined in

    Arora and Gambardella (1994).

    But should the increasing use of general and abstract knowledge mentioned

    above lead us to conclude that the amount of tacit and (practice knowledge) within the

    economic systems is destined to decrease?

    The main issue addressed here focuses on the universal importance that tacit

    knowledge still has in explaining the different performance of LPS in comparison with

    the rest of the economy. The growing awareness that a fundamental part of knowledge

    possessed by agents has a tacit form, leads us to speculate on the different composition

    of these two forms of knowledge exhibited within the LPS.

    In our view, which is based on empirical analysis, significant levels of tacit

    knowledge are still at work in the territorial model of LPS. However, among them, as

    we have tentatively classified in Fig.2, tacit knowledge has different relative weight.

    But we do not deny that within the more innovative LPS, during the last phase of

    development, a great amount of codified knowledge has not only be absorbed but also

    produced.

    So, is therefore the codification trend a plausible hypothesis that helps us toforecast the future changes of the LPS economies?

    Within the LPS investigated, a growth of codified knowledge has been

    detachable, particularly within the stronger and more organised systems. And without

    fear of being contradicted, it can be said that the growing complexity of these

    structures has multiplied the intelligent nodes (Albertini and Pilotti, 1996), where

    codified knowledge is re-elaborated and transferred. For the reasons explained in

    details in section 5, this does not occur at the expense of the stock of the existing

    tacit knowledge. Tacit knowledge, as we could investigate within the LPS, not only

    has not declined at all, in absolute terms, but, it is relatively becoming more important

    in the mapping out the evolution of firms production networks. In comparison with the

    past, the new agile relational networks built-in within the LPS during 1980s, haveexternalised and diffused the old pool of existing tacit knowledge along an enlarged

    informational circuit (Belussi and Arcangeli, 1998).

    4

    4

  • 7/30/2019 belussi (1)

    5/24

    The analysis presented in the paper places the discussion of codification of

    knowledge in a wide framework.

    1. First, we discuss the blurring boundaries of the dichotomy between codified versus

    tacit, reaffirming the fundamental role of tacit knowledge as opposed to codification.

    2. Second, we emphasises the contextualization of knowledge, a process that

    represents an opposing trend, juxtaposed to the previous one, and antagonistic to

    generalisation and abstraction that put knowledge in action, and localised it in

    specific territorial and productive contexts.

    The concept of knowledge contextualization comes near to the work of Nonaka and

    Konno (1998). They define extensively this concept on the base of their model of

    knowledge creation. Ba can be thought as a shared space for emerging

    relationships. A space that is defined in three main dimensions, structured in a

    mixture of individual and/or collective knowledge:

    a - physical (office, dispersed business space);b - virtual (e.g. electronic equipment, teleconference, e-mail);

    c - mental (e.g. shared experienced, ideas, ideals).

    The analyses of Nonaka and Konno are a useful tool which help us to describe the

    dynamics of LPS. The spatial clustering of activities (and innovation processes)

    defines the context where we see the creation of pieces of non codified knowledge

    (tacit knowledge), and where the mixture of codified and tacit knowledge embedded in

    the territory becomes a collective good, not transferable outside. However, creativity

    and innovation is not simply resident in ba, but in a complex circular process between

    codified and non codified knowledge at individual level or within collective

    organisations (firms, networks and institutions).

    The paper is organised as follows. Section 2 reviews the debate about the various

    forms of knowledge. Section 3 elaborates a taxonomy of the various forms of learning,

    distinguished as: instructive, adaptive and generative. In the following section we

    discuss the importance of contextual knowledge. Here we argue that the spiral process

    of conversion of knowledge, implied in the Nonaka model, works in part. Not all

    existing codified knowledge (external knowledge) can be absorbed from outside the

    LPS, and, conversely, the externalisation of knowledge is never complete outside the

    LPS, because attrition and protective local institutional mechanisms, that make

    localised knowledge partially tacit and difficult to replicate and imitate. In section 5

    an overview of our empirical research conducted is presented. Section 6 containssome concluding remarks.

    2. The generation and absorption of tacit and codified knowledge

    It is common knowledge that knowledge is a very complex subject to analyse.Technological knowledge involves various degrees of complexity, specificity,

    openness, cumulativeness, opportunity, transferability, appropriability, and tacitness.

    5

    5

  • 7/30/2019 belussi (1)

    6/24

    Moreover, the creation of new pieces of useful knowledge in firms, the innovation

    process, requires a great deal of endogenous expertise and exogenous sources to be

    included. Knowledge itself (Arrow, 1994) is an input into the production of other

    goods, but it also an output: it is a function of resources devoted to knowledge as well

    as a function of the existing knowledge. And it is not just the average level of

    knowledge that is relevant, but also its distribution (diffusion) among agent.Not all knowledge is of such form that can be easily transferred.

    Some personal knowledge or tacit knowledge related to abilities, routines, know-how,

    or specific practical skills, deriving from experience cannot be codified, and thus

    cannot be simply transferred.

    Knowledge in practice tends to be highly tacit in nature, while abstract

    knowledge scientific knowledge related to the theoretical understanding, and to the

    scientific principles, has the characteristic of being fully codified.

    This distinction may be clearer if we recall the Lundvall and Johnson (1994)

    metaphor. While the former type of knowledge has to do with knowing how, and

    includes some forms of active participation (knowing in action) of the knowledgeable

    agent and relational capability know-who, the latter is related to a passive andmerely conceptual understanding of knowing what and knowing-why (speculative

    awareness on the state of the world).

    These two forms of knowledge do not coincide. Routinised activities, and skills may

    be learned and reproduced without someone is being able to go back to their scientific

    rationales4. Furthermore, it is also true that to use codified knowledge we need a

    certain amount of tacit knowledge and ability. In the history of technology we observe

    a path of evolution of many specific pieces of knowledge that have become over the

    time fully codified (this includes many crafts products that were industrialised under

    the constraint of technical progress5). But, generally speaking, different degrees of

    tacitness are embodied in knowledge, in relation to the various levels of scientific and

    technological activities. In pure science knowledge is typically articulated, controlled

    by scientific advanced instrumentation, and formalised in written theories, formulae,

    and testable falsification procedures. Nearly one hundred percent of this is codified.

    The more we move away from pure science, the more we find that the degrees of

    codification decline, and tacit knowledge grows in intensity. Incremental technological

    activities and applied research normally contain high levels of tacit knowledge. All

    thing considered, because activities related to applied research and direct production

    have a large influence on the economic structure, we can infer, at least, that activities

    related to tacit knowledge- are not marginal. Given the obvious difficulty in

    measuring how much knowledge exists, either codified or tacit, these reflections

    maintain a certain degree of abstraction and inaccuracy. (One deals with affirmationsthat have no possible practical demonstration but that have strong theoretical and

    practical implications in terms of technology policy).

    The discussion about codification versus tacitness has brought out some

    important contrasts.

    In recent years the nature of technology has come under scrutiny. In particular,

    a wide-ranging debate has explored the changing nature of technological change.

    Some convincing predictions see in the nearer future a possible intensification in the

    4In regard to this, a few examples were reported by Nelson and Winter (1982). In short: the physiology of muscular movementmay be unknown to an athlete without affecting his or her performance.5 History is full of disquieting anecdotes. Expert systems have proved to be a complete disaster in running financial activitiesin stock markets, and during the black October 1987 they nearly provoked a catastrophe, but automatic pilots are commonlyused as a support and extension of human senses. In the ceramic industry, in Sassuolo, the knowledge of skilled pluggers is

    still far superior of any computer-controlled program. At the end of a very automated production cycle, human abilities governthe cocking, times and the weight of specific ingredients. The use of computer programs for translations has produced very

    poor results, while the codification of technical designs has gone further, etc.

    6

    6

  • 7/30/2019 belussi (1)

    7/24

    rate of technical change in firms, as well as an increased degree of knowledge

    codification. An era of transition has been forecast towards more universal

    technological systems, cast in frameworks and categories that relay on more

    generalised, more transmissible abstract pieces of knowledge. Some have claimed

    that, because the dominant technological paradigm is now information technology, the

    distribution of knowledge between tacit and codified has dramatically changed infavour of codification: after all, information technology is about processing, storing,

    and transmitting information and codified knowledge. This is for instance the position

    of Cowan and Foray (1997), and Arora and Gambardella (1995).

    On the contrary, more cautious remarks can be found in the contributions of

    Lundvall (1995 and 1996), Senker (1995), Dosi (1996), and Breschi and Malerba

    (1997).

    As stated by Lundvall (1996a),

    ..while the codification can go very far in the field of know-what there are important

    limitations for the codification in other fields of knowledge. Know-why can be fully codified only in

    areas where little new knowledge is currently produced or the new knowledge is purely incremental.

    When scientific principles are in a state of flux or when they are disputed within the scientific

    community they cannot easily be communicated outside a narrow group of scientists. ..The work on

    expert system is far from innocent There are skills of an intuitive kind which remain hidden and tacit

    and which cannot be incorporated when the codification takes place. Finally it is obvious that a

    register of names cannot integrate the social network of relationships which are included in the know-

    who category. (p.7)

    Arguments that oppose the codification trend are the following:

    1. The introduction of the information technology paradigm has not just increased

    the stock knowledge we can use; it has (above all) increased, to the nth degree,

    the availability of data; in turn, this has also dramatically increased the circulationof unnecessary information as well. The overload of information we observe, will

    oblige people to make ever greater use of their tacit knowledge, to select the

    relevant information they can utilise.

    2. There is a spiral of conversion of tacit into codified knowledge, but more tacit

    knowledge is needed to handle this new codified knowledge. Let us take the case

    of medicine. There are now more research centres, more scientific journals, more

    discoveries, more instrumentation, and more cures, but the specific skills of

    experts has not be undermined. So, the expansion of codified knowledge has been

    a paralleled by the expansion of tacit knowledge (also among the users of the

    services).

    3. With the contemporary trend towards a post-Fordist society, based on skilledwork, or knowledge workers, it is the entire labour market that in fact is moving

    towards activities, jobs, and tasks, where learning attributes and tacit knowledge

    are becoming more important. This implies that there is little evidence of a

    diminishing role of the tacit elements that form the reservoir of knowledge in

    society: human capital.

    4. Lundvall (1996b) has recently pointed to the dawn of the Learning Economy.

    Today we find ourselves in an economy in which the competitiveness of

    individuals, firms, and entire systems of innovation reflects their ability to learn.

    The learning economy places emphasis on interactions (user-producer

    relationships), and on knowledge sharing and networking. Both these features

    represent some tacit competencies related to the expansion of tacit knowledge.

    7

    7

  • 7/30/2019 belussi (1)

    8/24

    5. The social dimension of learning is of paramount importance. The knowledge of

    human knowledge (Tamborini, 1997) finds active elaboration of: mental

    models6, feedback mechanisms of knowledge verification and testing (based on the

    individual or on the collective experience), where, to allow the passing of the

    message, common languages, meanings, metaphors, heuristics, visions7, beliefs

    and conventions must shared among actors. Hence, in practice, as argued byLundvall, a symbiotic relation is established between the two form of knowledge.

    Codified knowledge may be utilised only through recourse to tacit knowledge. The

    decisive importance of subjective, and partial knowledge, accumulated by

    individuals is that they learn only when tacit knowledge is embodied in actions 8.

    Individuals are the constructors of empirical human knowledge. Tacit

    knowledge is used to frame the perception of their reality (Schon, 1979), to

    structure their behaviours, to select and encode the relevant information they need,

    to filter and re-assemble knowledge (abstract and tacit), to receive signals and

    elaborate their content, etc. Within the economic organisations, therefore,

    individuals experience a continuous elaboration and exchange of codified and tacit

    knowledge. But economic agents do not just act, they interact. They are able notonly to absorb codified knowledge, but also to create new knowledge (framed in a

    tacit or in an explicit setting). Generative relationships are conducive to learning

    procedures, to innovation activity, and to the establishment of new organisational

    routines (Lane, Malerba, Maxfield, and Orsenigo, 1996). The industrial networks,

    and the emerging knowledge-based organisations, must be regarded as the

    classical locus where these interactions generate a new stream of localised

    technical change (Antonelli, 1999a). Generative interactions use both tacit and

    codified knowledge, and innovation (new pieces of knowledge) takes place among

    multilevel loops, or chains, of tacit-plus-codified converting it into tacit-plus-

    codified new knowledge.

    In summary, in this section we have presented two antagonistic perspectives. On one

    hand, we have presented the view of those who believe that codification is becoming

    the essence of the economic activity, on the other hand we have put forward some

    arguments, that suggest caution, and support the apparently contradictory thesis that

    the impact of the 1990s changing will not change the balance between codified and

    tacit knowledge very much. Following the pioneering contributions of some Italian

    economists such as Antonelli, Malerba, Rullani, and Vacc, we have asserted the

    permanent influence of the mechanisms which generate tacit knowledge within the

    economic system, suggesting the growing importance of localised learning and open-

    ended processes of conversion between tacit and codified knowledge.

    3. Instructive, adaptive and generative learning

    6 As argued by Denzau and North (1994), people act in part upon the basis of myths, dogmas, ideologies, and half-backedtheories. In condition of uncertainty individuals interpretation of their environment will reflect their knowledge. Individual withcommon cultural backgrounds and experience will share their knowledge. Shared mental models guide choices and the evolution

    of political-economy. Mental models, institutions and ideologies all contribute to the process by which human beings interpret and

    order their environment.7

    In his compelling article on the existing different theories of the firm, Fransman (1994), whose aim is to describe the influenceexerted by these visions on the firm internal process of knowledge and information, presents what he calls the Ibm paradox. It isa clear case of a firm clinging to the mistaken belief in the ability of the mainframe computer to sustain profitability at least until

    1991, despite the information which it possessed (and processed), contradicting this belief.8

    The classical reference here is in Argyris and Schon (1974).. For an excellent survey see Tosoukas (1996).

    8

    8

  • 7/30/2019 belussi (1)

    9/24

    This section focuses on the diffusion of knowledge and the growth of human capital.

    The growth and diffusion of knowledge, both tacit and codified, take places in firmsand organisation through learning activities. Economic literature has tended to

    separate the growth in the stock of knowledge from its diffusion (Davies, 1979;

    Mansfield, 1961; Mahajan and Wind, 1986; Rogers, 1962). This distinction, going

    back to Schumpeter, has proved to be useful when a new piece of knowledge can be

    identified, such as a particular invention.

    However, most advances in knowledge are not achieved at once, and then slowly

    adopted by potential users (Stoneman, 1983). Rather, new technical change is the

    outcome of many building blocks, and it embodies many ideas. In the assembly of

    innovations many agents and sources are involved. Tacit and codified knowledge is

    necessary to disentangle the main research objectives, and to implement the discovery

    process. If this is so, the growth of knowledge may be portrayed essentially as aninteractive process of learning and invention.

    This new way of addressing the issue of the growth and diffusion of knowledge

    has provoked two significant consequences at intellectual level.

    Firstly, diffusion and growth may be seen as joint products: growth is often

    inseparable from diffusion. The innovation process may takes place in different steps

    and involving many actors.

    Secondly, learning activities in firms are both devolved to absorb the existing

    external knowledge (from the historically created pool of knowledge) and to create

    new knowledge9.

    The Arrows (1962) formulation of learning by doing shed lights on this analytical

    dilemma and captures the linkage of growth and diffusion. In Arrows view, learning

    (improvements in firm knowledge) is related to the accumulated experience of firms,

    measured by the proxies of a) the cumulative output and, b) the growing number of

    adopters.

    However, if we follow the Arrows tradition, we focus our attention only to the

    individual firm and its search procedures.

    What is missing is that we do not deal explicitly with differences among agents. It

    is the combination of different ideas that produces new knowledge. And different

    ideas gives rise to better ideas because knowledge (both tacit and explicit) is unevenly

    distributed among agents. If each agent knew exactly the same thing, the exchange of

    information would no produce any increase on the amount of knowledge in each firm.So, learning activities may be also portrayed as a decentralised process of diffusion of

    knowledge. Spillovers of knowledge depend in part on how hard firms are trying to

    capture new knowledge (this may be measured by the length, extension, and

    numerosity of informative channels, and by frequency with which information passes

    through them). But also by the knowledge gap: the existing differences in what firms

    know (some agents are rich of accumulated knowledge, and they may play the role of

    activators of knowledge/competencies, within the system of relationships which they

    govern).

    Spillovers and learning efforts may be analysed from a territorial perspective.

    By elaborating our research we have sketched three forms of learning, which take

    place among the firms of the LPS analysed: instructive, adaptive and generativelearning (Fig. 1).

    9This point was first treated in a satisfactory manner by Choen and Levinthal (1989).

    9

    9

  • 7/30/2019 belussi (1)

    10/24

    Fig.1 Models of learning

    Type of knowledge Instructive Adaptive Generative/creative

    Tacit

    Codified

    Instructive

    This form of learning is mainly related to the transmission of simple instructions from

    skilled workers to apprenticeship through (intra-firm) transfer of tacit knowledge or it

    refers to the technical specification provided to subcontractors (inter-district firms).Knowledge is transfer among the production networks, where firms co-operate in

    relationships more or less arm length. The modality that we have called instructive

    learning refers mainly to the transfer of tacit knowledge. This, in any case, requires the

    exchange of a lot of information and knowledge. Recourse to instructive learning

    avoids within the various LPS avoids the degradation of the existing stock of

    knowledge. This stock of knowledge, referring mainly to traditional manufacturing

    activities grows slowly. Instructive learning is bounded10 by the absence of relevant

    innovations (once the ability of perform a certain task is settled only minor

    modification may be introduced). Craft skills form the main component of the existing

    stock of knowledge that is embedded in particular LPS. These skills still seem to be

    crucial in some sectors such as clothing, footwear, furniture, etc. Here firms base theircompetitiveness on traditional craft labour force skills. Given the fact that, in the

    nineteenth century, many skills have been lost because of technological progress due

    to the introduction of mass production, large scale industrialisation, and the

    standardisation of labour tasks, the formation of the Italian LPS, and the diffusion of

    instructive learning have allowed the maintenance of these tacit skills. So, while

    world wide a loss of skills and an un-learning process (a forgetting of knowledge)

    have occurred, in the cases studied, abilities, skills, and tacit competencies have been

    kept alive thanks to this mechanism of knowledge sharing and imitating through side

    to side job training of individuals and by exchange of experience which occurs along

    the subcontracting chains.

    10On this issue see also Young (1993).

    10

    10

  • 7/30/2019 belussi (1)

    11/24

    Adaptive

    Adaptive learning characterised the type of learning that has occurred in the

    Italian industrial districts during 1970s. Is stems mainly on the reduction of

    transaction costs, and it is based on the imperative of making the firm organisational

    design flexible. It did not involve only labour force skills but also focused on

    improving product and processes. Typically it involved learning by doing, by using,

    and by interacting (client-supplier relationship). The stock of knowledge grows

    incrementally, with the ongoing industrial activities. The model of flexible

    specialisation set the boundaries of learning activities that were initiated. Firms

    learned to react and adjust to market signal, to co-operate in dense but territorially

    dispersed networks, to slightly modify product and processes. When a small new pieceof knowledge is incorporated in a firm of the LPS, very soon this new knowledge

    spread because imitative procedures. So, firms tend to balance their knowledge.

    Adaptive learning is not just limited to the growth and diffusion of tacit knowledge, it

    can involve also pieces of codified knowledge. Among firms one finds an acceleration

    in the mechanisms for absorbing external tacit and codified knowledge. The

    absorption of external knowledge may also be performed by local LPS institutions

    like training centres, or ad-hoc laboratories. R&D activities are carried out by some

    firms of the district.

    Generative learning

    Generative learning is the most creative form of learning we can find in LPS.

    Generative learning is activated by creative agents interactions and it focuses

    primarily on the creation of new knowledge. It describes the behaviour of some LPS

    during 1990s, reflecting their more complete form of learning. In these LPS thepresence of firms with built-in generative learning models increase greatly the stock

    of existing knowledge. The new knowledge produced here has the characteristic of

    being semi-private (it is shared only within the final firms production systems). New

    knowledge tends to be codified in a local rather than universal code. Generative

    learning increases both tacit knowledge and codified knowledge.

    In the most dynamic LPS high levels of knowledge creation occur in parallel with an

    institutional complexity of the industrial structure (emerging leading firms and

    dominant networks). A cognitive division of labour is emerging among firms. The

    division of innovative labour crosses the entire local industrial structure. Final firms

    or hub firms concentrate their activity on the strategic core of new product design,

    engineering, marketing and post-sale services. Manufacturing activity (routinisedactivity) is often delegated to small local producers.

    11

    11

  • 7/30/2019 belussi (1)

    12/24

    Fig. 2 describes the historical trend of the evolutionary pattern of knowledge diffusion trajectories.At the beginning, LPS are characterised by the presence of tacit knowledge. The contextualization of

    tacit knowledge prevails, as well its externalisation (among individuals or firms) through the traditional

    form of learning-by-doing and instructive learning. A permanent sharing between tacit and explicit

    knowledge characterises the second step. Here a process of re-contextualization of external (codified

    knowledge) takes place.Adaptive learningprevails in systems where there is a balance between tacit

    knowledge and codified knowledge. There is then a migration of dynamic districts towards a third level

    of transformation, where we find a type of contextual knowledge that incorporates radically new

    pieces of knowledge. This type of knowledge is prevalently codified and it can be transmitted outside,

    through a process of de-contextualization. Generative learning is here activated. The innovation

    governance of LPS is modelled by a double string:

    A - contextualization- re-contextualization and de-contextualization of knowledge;B - decodified-codified-redecodified of knowledge.

    This double string of transformation knowledge is directed to reinforce the local innovation process

    of LPS.

    In the figure we see three different types of structural evolution, depending upon the pool of

    knowledge they have access to. Where the focus is on instructive systems, the single agent or small

    firms are dominant. Where the focus is on adaptive systems, the grouping of firms prevails. Finally, the

    focus ongenerative systems is inducing a more complex structure (networks of networks), mediated by

    the presence of local or multi-localised institutions, playing the role of transferring, and re-re-

    transferring knowledge.

    This last level of evolution of contextual knowledge produces a virtuous integration between

    codified and non codified knowledge.

    The Italian LPS have experimented, firstly, a transition from a classical Smithians division of

    labour(instructive learning) to a more technically based Marshallians division of labourwith agents

    sharing atmospheres, signalling, and externalities, secondly, a more recent transition towards a post-

    Fordist organisational model, characterised by a cognitive inter-firms division of labour (with the

    sharing of tacit knowledge within the organisational nets). Leading firms, network-of-networks, and

    institutions populate these districts.

    12

    12

  • 7/30/2019 belussi (1)

    13/24

    Fig. 2 The mechanisms of knowledge creation in the Italian LPS

    13

    13

    DIFFUSION OF

    TACITKNOWLEDGE

    CREATION OF SOME

    EXPLICITKNOWLEDGE

    PREVALENCEOF EXPLICIT

    KNOLEDGE

    TACIT

    KNOWLEDGE

    BALANCE

    BETWEENCODIFIED

    KNOWLEDGE ANDTACIT

    HIGH LEVELS

    OFKNOWLEDGE

    CREATION

    CONTEXTUALIZATIONTACIT KNOWLEDGE

    SOCIALISATION

    RECONTEXTUALIZATION

    KNOWLEDGE ABSORPTION

    ABSORPTION

    DECONTEXTUALIZATIONNEW KNOWLEDGE ISCREATED AND THENCHANNELED OUTSIDE THELPS

    LOCAL

    KNOWLEDGEDIFFUSION

    AGENTSAND LEARNING

    TRAJECTORIES

    FLOWS OFEXPORTS OF

    KNOWLWDGE

    FIRMS

    LEADERS ANDGROUPING

    INSTITUTIONSAND

    NETWORKS

  • 7/30/2019 belussi (1)

    14/24

    2. From contextual to global knowledge: an incomplete mechanism of

    conversion

    It is useful at this point to introduce the concept of localised technical change(Antonelli, 1999a). Antonelli s perspective sets the theoretical basis for understanding

    the role of tacit elements in the contextualization of knowledge.

    Technological change is inherently localised in that it consists of changes in the technical capability of

    structures that are limited to a well defined set of characteristicsLocalised technological change

    builds upon structured information ..that, as a public good, is available to everybody with low, thoughnot negligible costs, of imitation and acquisition. Tacit knowledge instead is the result of lengthy

    learning processes; it is idiosyncratic and specific to the organisation and business environment of thefirm. .. Technological change is more or less localised according to the mix of internal and external,

    codified and tacit knowledge on which it depends, but neither form may be dispensed with It consistsof specific pieces of technological know-how obtained by means of learning by using and doing. It

    incorporates the experience and skills of labour as well as the opportunities of improving products andproduction processes generated by highly circumstantial factors and events Since localised

    knowledge is mainly tacit, because it is implicit and embedded in the memory of organisations and inthe economic, regional and industrial environment of each firm, it is difficult to learn, imitate, transfer,

    adopt and use. It is more proprietary and it use is more excludable than in the Arrowian tradition.(p.5-6).

    The dynamics of localised technical change provides the basis of the formation of

    contextual knowledge. Contextual knowledge is embedded in the territory and it is

    formed by elements of codified knowledge (absorbed also from the outside), and tacit

    knowledge (developed slowly within the production process in practical experience,and internally to the networks of relationships that surround that place).

    Contextual knowledge may be described as the social output of an historical

    process of accumulation of technological capabilities and skills. This occurs only if in

    a specific territory the mechanism of development is activated (for this reason

    contextual knowledge is linked with territorial industry specialisation).

    When external economic conditions are favourable, the territory becomes a

    system: the model of LPS takes-off. Knowledge creation and propagation occur as a

    consequence of the development of firms. But the creation of contextual knowledge

    is at the same time a cause and effect of growth. In other words, a circular loop

    between growth and knowledge is at work. LPS are accelerators of new technologies

    in the presence of network externalities11(Belussi, 1998).The evolutionary path of growth that originates within the LPS model starts with

    the grow of a restricted number of firms: the LPS founders. In these firms knowledge

    and technical skills become consolidated, and contextual knowledge is promoted.

    Knowledge propagation is achieved via the entrepreurialisation of technical and

    professional people. Their level of professionalism allows them to leave the firms and

    become small independent entrepreneurs. The industrial structure of LPS expands

    through a process of firms gemmation. During the first phases, instructive and

    11Technological externalities related to the rapid adoption of innovation (the bandwagon effect); externalities deriving fromthe co-ordination of investments among the firms which participate to the same production networks; externalities oftransaction costs reductions based on the social climate of trust linked to the visibility of actors, and to the social bounds of

    friendships and relationships; externalities stemming from the abundance and sharing of information; externalities related to thepresence of specific centres of research or training that offer tailored specialised services and information; and externalities

    deriving from the presence of specialised suppliers in the intermediate parts utilised from the final firms.

    14

    14

  • 7/30/2019 belussi (1)

    15/24

    adaptive learning behaviours diffuse. The exchange of information and knowledge

    occur via the transfer of personal experience and know-how.

    Subsequently, new waves of spin-offs may occur, populating the district with

    small innovative producers: the frequency of contacts, and the numerosity of

    exploratory searching lead, due to the law of large numbers, in the end to improved

    products or processes: thus, often, generative learning is activated12

    . Contextualknowledge is developed in practice by local economic agents, and new knowledge is

    generated through the interactions agents (suppliers, clients, subcontractors, and local

    institutions).

    Looking back to the extraordinary commercial success of the Italian model,

    which in our paper we have defined as the LPS, it should be saied that too much

    attention (and speculation) has been made on terms like flexibility, small firms, and

    etc. In the view shared by the authors of this paper, in the establishment of this type of

    industrial structure the process was sustained, above all, by the existence of high

    levels of contextual local knowledge. Practical and contextual knowledge was

    transmitted through apprenticeship and personal contacts.

    Practical and contextual knowledge, from this perspective, may be viewed asan existing strategic (but immaterial) resource, that is essentially territorial-specific.

    This cognitive form of social capital, historically accumulated in the LPS model, can

    be viewed as a sunk investment.

    Only agents operating in the local district have access to it, and they may

    further enlarge and exploit its profitability through strategies of entrepreneurial

    growth. This process, thus, is highly path-dependent, and built up upon a nucleus of

    original local skills and competencies.

    The development of these idiosyncratic LPS is territorial-specific. This bears an

    important consequence: the nature of contextual knowledge, therefore, is bound to the

    spatial boundaries of the systems: contextual knowledge can not be completely

    globalised. Spatial proximity and social mechanisms of sharing knowledge

    facilitate its local transmission. Over long-distance (which is relational as well

    spatial), frictions dominate13. It is obviously true that some innovations introduced by

    the firms of LPS can be clearly codified, and imitated elsewhere. So, the codified

    elements of contextual knowledge are more at risk. But, differently from what

    Nonaka claimed, the conversion of tacit knowledge, into external knowledge, is far

    more difficult. It follows, that on the whole, the contextual knowledge of the various

    LPS can never go over the LPS walls, thus it can not be completely externalised.

    The verification of this interpretation regarding the factors of competitiveness of

    LPS clearly can only be indirect. However, the imitation by other countries has proved

    difficult. And the areas of specialisation on which LPS compete internationally havenot varied very much over the last two decades. During this time, LPS have proved to

    be quite stable structures, and not foot loose organisations. They have deepened their

    roots in their territory, which is also a community of people, sharing local traditions,

    habits, language, and entrepreneurial visions. The process of globalisation have passed

    over them. LPS were already global in their market outlets. In nearly all LPS export

    12R&D-dependent radical innovations are not typically produced within the LPS, where firms are often small sized. Radical

    innovation would require the specialisation of dedication of resources to invention and innovation. But a great deal of

    innovative activity is generated trough learning by interaction.13

    A similar perspective is also developed in the Breschi and Malerba (1997)

    15

    15

  • 7/30/2019 belussi (1)

    16/24

    flows are quite high14 (typically 40-50%) of total firms sales, with some remarkable

    peaks.15

    5. A topology of Italian local production systems: towards evolutionary

    governance

    In Fig. 3 , using our tacit knowledge, we have sketched an evaluative map of the

    topological characteristics of LPS, based on their degree of formalisation of

    knowledge. The institutional complexity is placed on horizontal axis, and on the

    vertical axis the balance between tacit and codified knowledge is reported. This

    diagram presents three emerging models: a) with high tacit knowledge and few firms-horizontal linkages, and no specific role of institutions; b) with an equal balance

    between tacit and codified knowledge, and with many leading firms (presence of

    hierarchical linkages), with the addition that here many institutions provide training

    and services which are related to a process of spreading tacit and codified knowledge;

    c) with high levels of codified knowledge and many leading agents including global

    (multinational) firms as well, and the clear presence of knowledge-intensive

    institutions.

    Below a topology referring to specific LPS governance is presented.

    1. The first cluster represents systems where tacit knowledge among agents

    predominates. Tacit knowledge is mainly embodied in the labour force skills, and in

    the craft production, innovations introduced by firms are incremental. These LPS are

    mainly specialised in traditional sectors, defined here as skill-intensive industry, like

    clothing and knitting, in Carpi, Vicenza and Reggio Emilia, or glass making in

    Murano, an island near Venice, and so on.

    2 . The second cluster includes those LPS where there is a balance between tacit and

    codified knowledge. These are concentrated on mechanical engineering sectors:

    biomedical instruments in Mirandola, near Modena, water taps fittings in Varese,

    frames for eyeglasses in Cadore, near Belluno, leather upholstery producers in the

    district of Matera -Altamura-Santeramo. etc. In these LPS codified knowledge is well

    developed, the sources of innovation are more formalised and located in engineering

    and design departments, and product innovation is frequent; here many actors

    contribute to the socialisation of knowledge and to the reinforcement of codified

    knowledge, like training schools, universities or special services (supplied by the local

    authorities) for small firms (servizi reali alle imprese).

    14Considering the 50 product groups made in Italy localised in LPS (Montedison, 1998), we observe that these groups areresponsible for a huge positive balance of trade (in 1995: 148.015 billions of lire, which surpassed the total net balance of

    67.550 billion of lire; 1996: about 125.000 on a total of 39.000). Export flows were in 1995 154.294 billions of lire and in 1996

    (first nine months) 104.318. For 21 products typically manufactured in LPS, the Italian firms are first placed and Italy has thebest international trade balance, and for other 8, Italy ranks as the second or third country exporter.

    15See, for instance, the packaging machinery district in Bologna (Belussi, 1999), where about 95 % of total output is exported, or

    the Montebelluna district specialised on ski boots (Pilotti, 1999), that supplies 75% of the international markets.

    16

    16

  • 7/30/2019 belussi (1)

    17/24

    3. In the third cluster the dominant feature is the prevalence of codified knowledge

    (however, tacit knowledge is still important). Some examples are ski boots production

    Fig. 3 A topology of the Italian LP: the formation of contextual knowledge and the implementation of

    learning strategies

    ***

    **

    17

    17

    Tacit contextual

    knowled e

    Codified and tacitknowledge

    New knowledgecreation

    Instructive learning

    Atomistic agents/firms

    Adaptive learning

    Few leaders/Horizontal grouping

    Generative learning

    Open networks/institutionsNetworks-of-networks

    CARPI (knitting and clothing)

    VICENZA (jewellery)REGGIO EMILIA (agriculture

    machinery)MANZANO (chairs)

    MURANO (glasses)

    MANIAGO (knifemanufactures)

    MIRANDOLA (medicalmachinery)

    SANTERAMO(upholstered furniture)

    CADORE (frame- lasses

    MOTEBELLUNA (Ski-boots)

    BOLOGNA (packagingmachinery)

    SASSUOLO (ceramic tiles)

    Up-grading of

    processes and products

    Introduction ofrelevant innovations

    Elaboration of

    formalised knowledge(original innovations in

    processes and products)

    Radical innovations

  • 7/30/2019 belussi (1)

    18/24

    in Montebelluna, the auto-components makers in the Modena-Bologna area, or the

    packaging machinery industry in Bologna.

    Codified knowledge in these systems seems quite developed. Here many firmshave R&D departments (but often only in the engineering department where new

    product are launched). Many local institutions play the role of meta-organiser such as

    the Museo dello Scarpone in Montebelluna, or the Demo center for the quick

    prototyping of mechanical auto-components. In the most advanced systems the

    division of labour of innovative activity is quite clear-cut: only large final firms and

    local institutions devote specific resources to technical change. In the rest of the

    system generative learning occurs unintentionally as a by-product of the daily

    manufacturing activity.

    6. Conclusions: some lessons from the Italian experience

    Despite the increasing attention given to the role played by knowledge in the

    economy, the current debate among economists and technologists demonstrates a quite

    contradictory nature. On one side, as discussed by Cowan and Foray (1997), or Arora

    and Gambardella (1994), among others, the process by which knowledge and

    information evolve in the economy is described as a tendency towards a continuousprocess of knowledge codification. This is seen as the natural trajectory of scientific

    progress, and as direct consequence of the development of the ICT technological

    paradigm. The emphasis on tacit knowledge is found in another field of research. The

    importance of tacit knowledge is underlined by those who place the characteristics of

    learning, the notion of localised technical change, and the evolution of competencies

    and routines in firms (the evolutionary school) at center of their interests. In this work

    we have developed a methodology of analysis of this topic based on the verification of

    the codified vs tacit debate within the case of the Italian LPS.

    The importance of contextual knowledge has been highlighted, along with the

    symbiotic relationship between tacit and codified knowledge. In our analysis of LPS

    two key dimensions have been examined: the combined levels of tacit and codifiedknowledge and the institutional governance. Our result confirm, by an large, within

    the analysed systems the undiminished role of tacit knowledge within the systems

    analysed .

    18

    18

  • 7/30/2019 belussi (1)

    19/24

    19

    19

  • 7/30/2019 belussi (1)

    20/24

    References

    Antonelli C. (1999a),The Microdynamics of Technological Change, Routledge,

    London.

    Antonelli C. (1999b), Communication and innovation: the evidence within

    technological districts, Tser, mimeo.

    Albertini S. and Pilotti L. (1996), (eds),Reti di Reti, Cedam, Padova.

    Argyris C. and Schon (1974), Theory in practice, Jossey-Bass, San Francisco.

    Arrow K. (1962), The economic implication of learning by doing, Review of

    Economic Studies, vol. 29

    Arrow K. (1994), The production and distribution of knowledge, in Silverberg G. and

    Soete L. (eds), The Economics of Growth and Technical Change, Edward Elgar,

    Aldershot.

    Becattini G. and Rullani E. (1996), Local systems and global connections: the role of

    knowledge, in Cossentino F., pyke F., and Sengenberger W., (eds), Local regional

    response to global pressure: the case of Italy, Geneva, Italy.

    Belussi F. (1999), The generation of localised technological change through

    communication processes. The case of the packaging machinery industry in the

    Bologna district, Inloco, Mimeo.

    Belussi F. (1999), Policies for the development of knowledge-intensive local

    production systems, Cambridge Journal of Economics, forthcoming, vol. 23, n. 6.

    Belussi F. and Arcangeli F. (1998), A typology of networks: flexible and evolutionary

    firms,Research Policy, vol. 27.

    Breschi S. and Malerba F. (1997), Sectoral innovation systems: technological regimes,

    Schumpeterian dynamics and spatial boundaries, in, Edquist C., (ed), Systems of

    Innovation, Cassel, London.

    Cohen W. and Levinthal D. (1989), Innovation and learning: the two faces of R&D,

    Economic Journal, vol. 99.

    Cohen W. and Levinthal D. (1990), Absorptive capacity: a new perspective on

    learning and innovation,Administrative Science Quarterly, vol. 35.

    Cowan R. and Foray D. (1997), The economics of codification and the diffusion of

    knowledge.Industrial and Corporate Change, vol. 6, n. 3, pp. 595-622.

    Cossentino F., Pyke F., Sengenberger W. (eds), (1996), Local and regional responseto global pressure: the case of Italy and its industrial districts , Ilo, Geneva.

    20

    20

  • 7/30/2019 belussi (1)

    21/24

    David P. and Foray D (1995), Accessing and expanding the science and technology

    knowledge-based economy, STI Review, n. 16.

    Davies S. (1979), The Diffusion of Process Innovation, Cambridge Univ., Cambridge.

    Denzau A. and North D. (1994), Shared mental models: ideologies and institutions,Kyklos, vol. 47n. 1, pp. 3-31.

    Dosi G. et al. (1988), (eds), Technical Change and Economic Theory, Pinter, London.

    Edquist C. (1997), (ed), Systems of Innovation, Cassel, London.

    Foray D. and Freeman C. (1993), (eds), Technology and the Wealth of Nations. The

    Dynamics of Constructed Advantages, Pinter, London.

    Georghiou L. et al. (1986), Post Innovative Performance, Macmillan, London.

    Fransman M. (1994), Information, knowledge, vision and theories of the firm,

    Industrial and Corporate Change, vol. 3, n. 3, pp. 713-757.

    Gibbons M. and Johnston R. (1974), The role of science in technological innovation,

    Research Policy, vol. 3.

    Gilbert M and Cordey-Hayes M. (1990), Understanding the process of knowledge

    transfer to achive successful technological innovation, Technovation, vol.16, n. 6, pp.

    301-312.

    Gottardi G. (1996), Technology strategies and innovation without R&D, Journal of

    Industry studies, vol. 2., December.

    von Hayek F. (1945), The use of knowledge in society,American Economic Review,

    vol. 35, pp. 519-30.

    von Hippel E. (1988), The Sources of Innovation, Oxford Univ. Press, Oxford.

    Imai K., Nonaka I., and Takeuchi H. (1985), Managing the new production

    development, in Clark K., Hayes R., (eds), The Unease Alliance, HBS Press, Boston.

    Klein B. (1977),Dynamics Economics, Harvard Univ. Press, Mass., Cambridege.

    Kline S. and Rosenberg N. (1986), An overview of innovation, in Landau R. and

    Rosenberg N. (eds), The Positive Sum Strategy, National Academic Press,

    Washington.

    Kline S. (1990), Innovation stiles in Japan and in the United States: cultural bases,

    implication for competitiveness, The 1981 Thurston Lectures, Rep. Inn-3, Dep. of

    Mechanical Engineeering, Stanford Univ.

    Kodama F. (1992), Technology fusion and the new R&D, Harvard Business Review,July-August.

    21

    21

  • 7/30/2019 belussi (1)

    22/24

    Lissoni F. and Metcalfe (1994), Diffusion of innovation ancient and modern. A review

    of the main themes, in Dodgson M. and Rothwell R. (eds), The Handbook of

    Industrial Innovation, Edward Elgar, Gower House.

    Levin R., Klevorick A., Nelson R., and Winter S. (1987), Appropriating the returns

    from industrial research and development, Brooking Papers on Economic Actuvity,vol. 3.

    Lundvall B. (1992), National Systems of Innovation. Towards a Theory of Innovation

    and Interactive Learning, Pinter, London.

    Lundvall B. (1996a), The social dimension of the learning economy, Druid working

    papers. 96-1, pp.22.

    Lundvall B. (1996b), Information technology in the learning economy- challenges for

    development strategies, memorandum for United Nations Commission for Science

    and Technology, mimeo

    Lundvall B. and Johnson B. (1994), The Learning Economy,Industry Studies, vol. 1,

    n. 2., pp-23-42.

    MacKenzieD., and Spinardi G. (1995), Tacit knowledge, weapon design and the

    unconvention of nuclear weapons, American Journal of Sociology, vol. 101, n.1,

    pp.44-99.

    Mahajan V. and Wind Y. (1986), Innovation Diffusion of New Product Acceptance,

    Ballinger Pub., Cambridge.

    Malerba F. (1992), Learning by firms and incremental technical change, Economic

    Journal, vol. 102.

    Mansfield E. (1961), Technical change and the rate of imitation, Econometrica,

    October.

    Montedison Ufficio studi-Cranec Universit Cattolica di Milano (1998), Il ruolo dei

    distretti industriali nel made in Italy, paper presented at conference Distretti

    industriali: la via italiana al lavoro e allo sviluppo, Milano, 17th February.

    Nelson R. (1993),National Systems of Innovations, Oxford Univ. Press, Oxford.

    Nelson R. and Winter S. (1982), An Evolutionary Theory of Economic Change,

    Harvard Univ. Press, Cambridge, Mass.

    Nonaka I. (1993), On a knowledge creating organisation, mimeo, paper presented at

    the Associazione nazionale Formatori, Parma, October 23th-30.

    Nonaka I. (1995), The Knowledge Creating Company, Oxford Univ. Press, Oxford.

    Nonaka I., Umemoto K., and Senoo D. (1996), From information processing toknowldge creation: a papradigm shift in business management, Technology in Society,

    vol.18, n.2, pp.203.218.

    22

    22

  • 7/30/2019 belussi (1)

    23/24

    Nonaka I. and Konno N. (1998), The concept of Ba: building a foundation of

    knowledge creation, California Management Review, vol. 40, n. 30.

    ODriscoll G. and Rizzo M. (1985), The Economics of Time and Ignorance, Basil

    Blackwell, Oxford.

    Pavitt K. (1984), Sectoral patterns of technical change: towards a taxonomy and a

    theory,Research Policy, vol.13.

    Pilotti L (1998), I distretti innovativi del nord, Sviluppo e Organizzazione, n. 187, pp.

    15-32.

    Polanyi M. (1958),Personal knowledge, Routledge, London

    Rogers E. (1962),Diffusion of Innovations, The Free Press, New York.

    Rothwell R., Townsend J., Teubal M., and Spiller P. (1977), Some methodologicalaspects of innovation research, Omega, vol. 5., n. 4.

    Rothwell R. and Gardiner P. (1985), Invention, innovation, re-innovation and the role

    of the user: a case study of British hovercraft development, Technovation, vol. 3.

    Rothwell R. (1994), Industrial innovation: success, strategy, trends, in Dodgson M.

    and Rothwell R. (eds),Handbook of Industrial Innovation, Elgar, Gower.

    Ryle G. (1949), Knowing how and knowing that, in The Concept of Mind, Hutchinson

    University Library, London.

    Schon D. (1979), Generative Metaphor: a perspective on problem setting, in Ortony A

    (ed),Metaphor and Thought, Cup, New York.

    Senker J. (1995), Tacit knowledge and models of innovation, Industrial and

    Corporate Change, vol. 4, n. 2.

    Silberstone A. (1989), (ed) Technology and Economic Progress, Macmillan, London.

    Stoneman P. (1983), The Economic Analysis of Technological Change, Oxford Univ.

    Press, Oxford.

    Tamborini R. (1997), Knowledge and economic behaviour, A constructivist approach,

    Evolutionary Economics, vol. 7, pp. 49-72.

    Teece D. (1986), Profiting from technological innovation: implication for integration,

    collaboration, licensing and public policy,Research Policy, 6, vol. 5.

    Tsoukas H. (1996), Forms of knowledge and forms of life in organised contexts,

    Warwick Business School, n. 171, pp. 1-44

    Thirtle C and Ruttan V. (1987), The Role of Supply and Demand in the Generationand Diffusion of Technical Change, Harwood Academic Publishers, London.

    23

    23

  • 7/30/2019 belussi (1)

    24/24

    Vicari S. (1998),Limpresa creativa, Etas, Milano

    Young Y. (1993), Invention and bounded learning by doing, Journal of Political

    Economy, vol. 101, n. 3, pp. 443-466

    24