blecker, r. a. (1991). import competition, investment finance, and cumulative decline in the us...

Upload: lcr89

Post on 25-Feb-2018

213 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

  • 7/25/2019 Blecker, R. a. (1991). Import Competition, Investment Finance, And Cumulative Decline in the US Steel Industry,

    1/27

    This article was downloaded by: [University of Auckland Library]On: 14 February 2015, At: 20:20Publisher: RoutledgeInforma Ltd Registered in England and Wales Registered Number: 1072954Registered office: Mortimer House, 37-41 Mortimer Street, London W1T 3JH,UK

    International Review of Applied

    EconomicsPublication details, including instructions for authors

    and subscription information:

    http://www.tandfonline.com/loi/cira20

    Import competition, investment

    finance, and cumulative

    decline in the US steel industry,

    19621981Robert A. Blecker

    a

    aAmerican University , Washington

    Published online: 02 Nov 2006.

    To cite this article:Robert A. Blecker (1991) Import competition, investment finance,

    and cumulative decline in the US steel industry, 19621981, International Review of

    Applied Economics, 5:2, 171-195, DOI: 10.1080/758533096

    To link to this article: http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/758533096

    PLEASE SCROLL DOWN FOR ARTICLE

    Taylor & Francis makes every effort to ensure the accuracy of all theinformation (the Content) contained in the publications on our platform.However, Taylor & Francis, our agents, and our licensors make norepresentations or warranties whatsoever as to the accuracy, completeness,or suitability for any purpose of the Content. Any opinions and viewsexpressed in this publication are the opinions and views of the authors, andare not the views of or endorsed by Taylor & Francis. The accuracy of the

    Content should not be relied upon and should be independently verified withprimary sources of information. Taylor and Francis shall not be liable for anylosses, actions, claims, proceedings, demands, costs, expenses, damages,and other liabilities whatsoever or howsoever caused arising directly orindirectly in connection with, in relation to or arising out of the use of theContent.

    This article may be used for research, teaching, and private study purposes.Any substantial or systematic reproduction, redistribution, reselling, loan,

    http://www.tandfonline.com/loi/cira20http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/758533096http://www.tandfonline.com/action/showCitFormats?doi=10.1080/758533096http://www.tandfonline.com/loi/cira20
  • 7/25/2019 Blecker, R. a. (1991). Import Competition, Investment Finance, And Cumulative Decline in the US Steel Industry,

    2/27

    sub-licensing, systematic supply, or distribution in any form to anyone isexpressly forbidden. Terms & Conditions of access and use can be found athttp://www.tandfonline.com/page/terms-and-conditions

    Downloadedby[UniversityofAuckland

    Library]at20:2014Febru

    ary2015

    http://www.tandfonline.com/page/terms-and-conditions
  • 7/25/2019 Blecker, R. a. (1991). Import Competition, Investment Finance, And Cumulative Decline in the US Steel Industry,

    3/27

    Import competition investment

    finance and cumulative decline in the

    US steel industry

    1

    962-

    1

    9

    Robert A Blecker American University Washington

    This paper ana lyses the effects of imp ort com petit ion on th e financing of invest-

    ment in the US steel industry. M odel simulations show tha t impo rt penetration

    reduced average annual investment spending by about one-quarter over the

    period 1962-81, mostly as the result of a sque eze o n profit mar gins which con -

    strained internal finance. A ssuming tha t this reduction is investment caused pro-

    ductivity growth to slow down, the benefits of allowing imports for steel

    consume rs are estimated to have been relatively small in the long run. Th e

    analysis supports the concept of cumulative causation in competit iveness due

    to constraints on investment financing.

    ntroduction

    You can t stan d still in this new industrial er a. If you don t expa nd a nd m ove

    ahead you are going backward. T he longer you take to m ake u p your mind what

    you are going to d o the fur ther ahead your compet i tor has gone - and the harder

    it will be for you to m ak e up lost t ime; if you ca n. (Editorial .

    The Iron Age

    January 1956)

    This quote from the leading U S steel industry trade journal was written pro-

    phetically at a time when industry executives insisted that apart from their

    labour unions) they had no fundamental problems to worry about see

    Means, 1962; Broude, 1963). Only a few years later, the industry began to

    face an onslaught of imports which revealed a genuine loss of competi-

    tiveness, as documented by the U S Federal Trade Commission FTC, 1977),

    Anderson and Kreinin 1981), Crandall l981), and Barnett and Schorsch

    1983). The editorial suggests that a small initial competitive disadvantage

    The author would like to thank Donald Harris, Bert Hickman, Nathan Rosenberg, and Gavin

    Wright for help at various stages in this project, and David Houston, Fred Lee, and two

    anonymous referees for helpful comments on earlier drafts. Robert Crandall, Mary Deily.

    and Jerome Mark provided some of the data series. The American University and the

    Economic Policy Institute provided financial support. The author a lone is responsible for the

    views expressed here and any remaining errors.

    ,

    O Edward Arnold

    ib9l

    Downloadedby[UniversityofAuckland

    Library]at20:2014Febru

    ary2015

  • 7/25/2019 Blecker, R. a. (1991). Import Competition, Investment Finance, And Cumulative Decline in the US Steel Industry,

    4/27

    172

    Import competition investment finance and cumulative decline

    could permanently set back the development o f the affected firms. A lthoug h

    orth od ox neoclassical econom ists have traditiona lly dismissed such ideas, at

    least until recently (see, for example, Krugman, 1981), such a notion of

    fai lure breeding further decl ine appears as s imple common sense to the

    business press.

    Outside of neoclassical or tho dox y, the principle of cumu lat ive causat ion

    has long been accepted by neo-Keynesian economists, especially Kaldor

    (1970; 1972). In Kaldor s conc eption , cum ulative causatio n results fun da-

    mentally fro m increasing returns t o scale, broadly defined t o include learn-

    ing effects, induced innovation, and increasing specialization as well as

    static scale econom ies. According t o Kaldor s laws, productivity grow th in

    manufacturing depends on the rate of investment in capi tal equipment

    embod ying new technology; the rate of investment in turn d epen ds primarily

    o n the growth of dem and : Accumulat ion is f inanced out of business profits ;

    the growth of demand in turn is largely responsible for providing both the

    inducements to invest capital in industry and also the means of financing

    it. (Targe tti an d

    Thirlw all, 1989: 314).

    This Kaldo rian perspective is incom plete, however, a s i t omits the equal ly

    crucial role of the profit markup or price-cost margin. As Kalecki (1971),

    Steindl (1952), an d E ichner (1976) em phas ized, the firm generates the gross

    profits or cash flow required t o fina nce its accumu lation internally (as well

    as to at t ra ct external fu nds) largely through i ts abi li ty to maintain an ade-

    qu ate price-cost margin. T he abili ty to main tain this margin is cons trained,

    in tur n, by a num ber of factors, including interna tional com petition. Recent

    studies by Dornbusch (1987), Feinberg (1986; 1989), Karier (1988), Mann

    (1986), and H oop er an d M ann (1989) have shown that im port penetrat ion

    and currency appreciation can induce oligopolistic firms to cut profit

    margins, both in theory an d in practice. An d the work of F azzari an d M ott

    (1986-87), Fazz ari and Athey (1987), an d Fazzari

    e t a / .

    1988) has confirmed

    that financing constraints (internal cash flows) are important for l imiting

    investment spending.

    These considerations imply a mechanism of cumulative causation for

    industrial competitiveness. Industrial firms must invest in new plant and

    equipment, embodying new vintages of technology, as well as engage in

    research and development, sales promotion, and other activities required

    to remain competi t ive and to expand their markets . This implies that the

    development of an industry d epends on , amo ng other things, the abi li ty of

    the firms that co mp rise it to raise the capital fun ds required to finance their

    investment programmes and other competitiveness-enhancing activities.

    Therefore, one of the main ways in which success breeds further success is

    the abili ty of successful firms to make above-normal profits which can be

    ploughed back into further investment and innovat ion. In addit ion, f i rms

    must be able to expand their markets fast eno ugh t o justi fy continued high

    rates of accumulat ion. Correspondingly, depressed profi ts and demand

    Downloadedby[UniversityofAuckland

    Library]at20:2014Febru

    ary2015

  • 7/25/2019 Blecker, R. a. (1991). Import Competition, Investment Finance, And Cumulative Decline in the US Steel Industry,

    5/27

    Robert

    A lecker 173

    can prevent firms from making the expenditures required to restore their

    competitiveness.

    Thes e factors suggest th e possibility of 'hysteresis' in inte rna tion al com -

    peti tive advan tages or disadvantages.' In a n open econom y, the com-

    petitive position of national firms vis a vis their foreign rivals affects their

    price-cost m argins as well as the dem and for their produc ts . T he m arku p

    rate and output level together determine the internal flow of funds (given

    fixed costs). T he flow of internal funds , together with the growth of d em and

    for nat ional products , affects the am ou nt of investment an d other expen-

    ditures which firms are able and willing to make in order to improve the

    efficiency and quality of their production.' If most of th e firms in an

    industry cann ot m aintain the level of expenditures required to bolster their

    competitiveness, then they may fall into a vicious circle of cumulative

    decline.

    In principle, the mechanism described here really applies to individual

    firms rather than national industries; different firms located (or based) in

    the same nation may be affected unevenly by the same competitive forces

    depending o n their respective cost structures, mark et shares, financial posi-

    tions, etc. Nevertheless, the concept o f th e na tion al industry is a useful level

    of aggregation for US steel prod ucers for several reasons. First , global steel

    production has generally been dominated by national rather than multina-

    tional firms, a nd there was n o tendency o f US steel firms to invest overseas.

    Secondly, until the 1980s. US steel production was highly concentrated

    am on g a gro up of large oligopolistic firms with generally similar structura l

    characteristics. The largest of these, the United States Steel Corporation,

    was a declining dominant firm with no significant cost advantage in its

    steelmak ing op era tion s (Sche rer, 1980: 239-40). Alth ou gh U S steel was

    larger tha n its rival firms, its plan ts were similar in size a n d techno logy. O nly

    with th e emergence of minimills in the late 1970s an d early 1980s did th e

    industry structure become m ore heterogeneous. Th irdly, firm-level da ta are

    not available for many of the variables needed for this study.

    In a previous pa per (Blecker, 1989), con firm ed that price-cost marg ins

    for American steel products became sensitive to imports (as well as to

    demand conditions) after a structural break in 1962, when imports per-

    manently surpassed 5 of th e domest ic market . In this paper , I est imate

    how this squeeze on profit margins, along with reduced demand, affected

    the financing of capital accum ulation in the U S steel industry in the 1960s

    an d 1970s. In orde r to s tudy this effect of import penetrat ion, ad op t the

    methodology of th e 'cliometric ' e cono mic historian by simulating a model

    A

    similar argument, posed at the macro level (for the manufacturing sector as a whole), is

    found in Singh

    (1977).

    2

    Note that this implies the possibility of

    a

    trade-off, if a nation s firms can gain greater world

    market share by reducing their profit margins.

    Downloaded

    by[UniversityofAuckland

    Library]at20:2014Febru

    ary2015

  • 7/25/2019 Blecker, R. a. (1991). Import Competition, Investment Finance, And Cumulative Decline in the US Steel Industry,

    6/27

    174 Im port competition, investment finance, a n d cum ulative decline

    of industry behaviour under counterfactual assumptions about the degree

    of impo rt penetration. The m ain results which are obtained from this exer-

    cise are estimates of the cum ulative loss of investment du e to the increase

    in im ports fro m 1962 t o 1981. Specifically, it is foun d tha t im port penetra-

    tion curtailed investment in the steel industry by about one-quarter com-

    pared with the baseline forecast of the mode l.

    In the model presented in this paper, d o not endogenize the feedback

    erfects that additional investment w ould have had in raising t he industry s

    productivity. Nor do atte m pt to estimate how wages (and other input

    prices) would have behaved differently in the counte rfac tual sce narios. Unit

    labour (as well as materials) costs are taken as exogenously given in the

    estimation of the model. However, some crude estimates of the impact of

    endogenous technical progress are ma de by runnin g sim ulations in which a

    higher rate of investment is accompanied by more rapid growth of labour

    productivity, and com paring these simulations with static ones assuming

    exogenously fixed productivity gr ow th. The reasons fo r this procedu re are

    discussed below.

    In focusing on the role of im por ts in the decline of the U S steel industry,

    d o not mean t o deny that a considerable part of the industry s problems

    in the 1960s an d 1970s must be attributed to dom estic structural changes

    which slowed the growth of steel dem and , as argued by B arnett an d Schorsch

    (1983), Law rence (1983), an d G rossm an (1 986), am ong others. Nevertheless,

    in view of the continued debate over trade policy for steel, it is still worth

    investigating the mechanisms by which import competition can affect the

    development of the industry an d the consequences of doing nothing in

    response. W hat kind o f governm ent intervention, if a ny, was or is warra nted

    for the U S steel industry is a sepa rate que stion which is beyond th e scope

    of this paper.

    The rest of the paper is organized as follows. Section I1 describes the

    model of the industry and discusses the theoretical rationale for the indi-

    vidual eq uatio ns. S ection 111 discusses the results o f th e m odel s imulations

    for the effects of imports on investment financing, assuming fixed labour

    productivity. Section IV then co mpa res the results of a simula tion in which

    labour productivity is assumed to increase more rapidly when investment is

    higher. Section V concludes by considering som e of the implications of the

    analysis for both theory and policy. Diagnostic statistic on the fit of the

    model are presented in an Appendix.

    I Estimated equations of the model

    The model described in this section draws upon and extends the pre-

    vious econometric work of Mancke (1968), Rippe (1970), Jondrow (1978).

    Cran dall(1981), a nd Blecker (1989). Th e core of th e model is the price equa-

    tion, which captures the effect of import competition on the price-cost

    Downloaded

    by[UniversityofAuckland

    Library]at20:2014Febru

    ary2015

  • 7/25/2019 Blecker, R. a. (1991). Import Competition, Investment Finance, And Cumulative Decline in the US Steel Industry,

    7/27

    obertA lecker

    175

    margin. In addition, equat ions for total dem and an d import demand show

    how the growth of the internal m arket a nd th e import sh are are determined

    by relative prices an d other variables. Dem and c ond itions are then tran slated

    into domestic outp ut levels an d util ization rates. T he price-cost m argin an d

    the level of output explain the flow of internal funds, given tax rates and

    overhead costs. The flow of internal funds and the util ization rate in turn

    are the main variables used to explain investment expenditures, as accel-

    erator effects turn out to be insignificant. The model also keeps track of

    several important feedbacks, including the dividend payout rate and the

    grow th of capacity, while using dum m y variables to contro l fo r certain uni-

    que historical episodes (the Korean War, the 1959 strike).

    Estimated equations and identities for the complete model are given in

    Tab le 1. Th e model is estimated using a nn ua l industry-level t ime series for

    reasons of data availabili ty. The sample period starts in the first year for

    which the necessary lags of all th e variables ar e available, which is 1949 fo r

    most of the equat ions (see the notes t o Tab le 1 for exceptions) . Th e sample

    period en ds in 1981, just be fore the recession of 1982 which dram atically

    transfo rme d the industry s s tructure. In the crisis of 1982-83, the large,

    integrated producers accelerated their ab and onm ent o f capaci ty an d diver-

    sification out of steel, while the small, competitive mini-mills took over a

    rapidly r is ing share of the shrinking domest ic s teel market (Barnet t and

    Crandall , 1986). The proportion of nonsteel investment spending by steel

    firms rose sharply in the early 1980s as they moved to diversify m ore rapidly.

    Nonsteel capital expenditures averaged about one-third of the total in

    1979-81, an d then jumped to ab ou t one-half in 1982-84, according to

    American Iron and Steel Institute (AISI) data.

    The equations were estimated by 2SLS. except as noted in the table.

    All variables for which no e qua tion is given in Ta ble 1 we re treated a s

    exogenous; lagged endogenous variables were treated as predetermined

    (except in equation 1.8). Limited information estimation procedures were

    preferred du e to the sm all sample s ize (33 observations), an d so th at a ny

    possible errors in the specification of o ne equa tion would not bias the esti-

    mation o f the other eq uation s. Since the m ain objective is prediction, rather

    than hypothesis testing, a few variables which improved the fit of the

    baseline forecast are retained in spite of t-statistics which are low by tradi-

    tional standards.

    In discussing the individual equa tions, i t is useful to star t with the invest-

    ment functio n which is so crucial to th e results. A s discussed abov e, th e neo-

    Keynesian tradition contains two approaches to investment: one which

    emphasizes the growth of demand ( the accelerator) and one which

    emphasizes profitability (price-cost margins). In the case of the US steel

    3

    Separate steel and nonsteel investment series are not available before 1979

    Downloadedby[UniversityofAuckland

    Library]at20:2014Febru

    ary2015

  • 7/25/2019 Blecker, R. a. (1991). Import Competition, Investment Finance, And Cumulative Decline in the US Steel Industry,

    8/27

    176

    Import com petition investment finance and cumulative decline

    able

    Estimated equations of the model

    l . l)aNVEST,

    = -

    1.25

    +

    ,367 INTFUND,_, + ,361 INTFUND,_;,

    +

    1.17 CAPUTIL,

    (- 2. 09 ) (3.17 ) (3.641 (2.731

    +0.7 1 C A P U T I L ,

    ,

    + 0.73 DKOREA, + 0.73 DSTRIKE,

    _

    ,

    (1.4 2) 13.74) (4.1 3)

    Rho

    = ,635

    (4.18)

    (Adjusted R2

    =

    ,778; Durbin-Watson = 1.5831.

    1 1 . 2 ) ~og INTFUND,

    =

    6.71 + 1.17 log MARGIN, + 0.55 log OUTPUT,

    (2.651 (2. 51) (1.681

    0.6 4 log TAXRATE, 1 14 log OVERHEAD, Rho = ,488

    ( - 1 581

    1

    - 2.47) (2.69)

    Adjusted

    ~ =

    573; Durb~n-Watson

    =

    1.841

    1 3) MARGIN,

    =

    PRICE, - UNICO S TII PIN VESTI (Identity)

    1.4IC

    og

    PRICE, =

    166

    +

    .51 1 log UNITCOST, + 402 log UNITCOST,_ ,

    1-0.87)

    5.81)

    (4.11)

    + ,161 log DIVPNT, + . I 84 log OVERHEAD,

    4 06) (3.21)

    +

    ,394 (01962,

    x 10s

    CAPUTIL,) ,058 (01962, x log IMPSHARE,)

    (3 .29) ( -0 .71)

    (Adjusted R2

    =

    .995; Durbln-Watson

    =

    1.834).

    I1 5)d og DIVPNT,

    =

    - 943 + .61 1 log D I VPN T, _ , + 168 log I N TFU N D , - ,

    -

    1.71) 16.21)

    2

    18)

    +

    ,091 log UNITCOST,

    11.88)

    Adjusted R Z

    =

    ,766; Durbin s h

    =

    0.581

    (1.6) CAPUTIL, = OUTPUT,ICAPACITY,. (Identity)

    (1 7Ie

    OUTPUT, =

    1.38

    +

    1.12

    DOMCONS,

    -

    IMPORTS,)

    (0.38) (24 8)

    Adjusted R~

    =

    .951; Durbin-Watson

    =

    1.375)

    (1.8) CAPACITY,

    =

    8.61

    +

    ,893 CAPACITY,-, + 1.52 INVEST,-, + 019 OUTPUT,_,

    (4.2 7) (42 1) (4.3 4) (1.381

    Rho

    =

    ,434

    (2 371

    (Adjusted R2

    =

    ,996; Durbin s h = 0.989).

    (1 9) IMPSHARE, = IMPORTS,IDOMCONS,

    (Identity1

    (1.1019 log

    IMPORTS, =

    16.4

    +

    453 log IMPORTS,_

    ,

    + 1.42 log PRICE,

    (- 4. 69 ) 16 26) (4.53 )

    - 1.33 log IMPP91CE,

    +

    1.81 log DOMCONS, + ,735 DSTRIKE,

    - 4.671 (5.2 5) (3.16)

    (Adjusted R2 = ,966; Durbin h

    =

    1 238).

    (1.11

    )9

    log

    DOMCONS,

    =

    14 4

    -

    502 log

    PRICE,

    +

    ,453 log

    PPINFMET,

    23 . 1 ) (-4.00) (2.97)

    +

    ,777 log

    YMFR,

    ,00025 r

    17.62)

    -

    1.081

    (Adjusted

    R 2

    = .891; Durb~n-Watson

    =

    2.1 18)

    Downloaded

    by[UniversityofAuckland

    Library]at20:2014Febru

    ary2015

  • 7/25/2019 Blecker, R. a. (1991). Import Competition, Investment Finance, And Cumulative Decline in the US Steel Industry,

    9/27

    Robert A. Blecker

    177

    Notes

    All stochastic equations were estimated over 194 9-19 81 by 2SLS unless otherwise

    noted.

    Numbers in parentheses are t-statistics.

    'Log' means the natural logarithm.

    See text for definitions of variables.

    a

    Estimated over 19 51 81 by Fair's ( 1970) method. INVEST and INTFUND are measured

    in bill ions of 197 2 dollars. The sum of the coefficients on INTFUND is ,729. with a

    r-statistic of 5.23. The sum of the coefficients on CAPUTIL is 1.89, with a r-statistic of

    2 .73 .

    Estimated over 19 50-8 1 by Fair's (1 97 0) method . INTFUND is measured in millions of

    19 72 dollars; OUTPUT is based on 1977

    =

    1 O.

    The sum of the coefficients on current and lagged

    UNITCOST

    is ,913 , wit h a t-statistic of

    39 .5 for the null hypothesis that the sum equals zero. The null hypothesis that the su m equals

    unity can be rejected at the 5 level (r-statistic of 3 .7 5 ).

    Estimated by OLS INTFUND is measured in millions of 19 72 dollars.

    OUTPUT

    is based on 1977

    =

    100;

    OOMCONS

    and

    IMPORTS

    are measured in billions of

    net tons.

    Estimated over 195 1-81 by limited information two-step procedure la) in Hatanaka (19761.

    CAPACITY

    and

    OUTPUT

    are based on 197 7 output

    =

    100;

    INVEST

    is measured in billions

    of 1972 dollars.

    IMPORTS and DOMCONS are measured in thousand net tons.

    industry, accelerator effects turn out to have been statistically insignificant,

    although demand played a role through the effects of capacity utilization

    rates. O n the other h and , profitability (as measured by lagged flows of inter-

    nal funds) was highly significant in explaining steel investment. These con-

    clusions may be drawn from the fol lowing regression e q ~ a t i o n : ~

    INVEST, 1.95 004 ASHIP, 010 ASHIP,-, 001 ASHIP,-,

    ( - 1.38) -0.34) -0.74) -0.16)

    002 ASHIP,-3 + .349 INTFUND,-

    + .229 INTFUND,-2

    -0.28) 2.19) 1.39)

    +

    1.58 CAPUTIL,

    +

    1.49 CAPUTIL,- , 0.68 DKOREA,

    1.04) 1.06) 3.25)

    +

    0.84

    DSTRIKE,- , ,

    ho

    .727

    )

    4.23) 4.54)

    (Adjusted R

    =

    ,748; Durbin-Watson 1.568).

    In equation I), the depend ent variable IN V ES T is new plant and equip-

    ment expenditures in blast furnaces and steel works measured in constant

    1972 dollars (US Department of Commerce, 1985). The accelerator effect

    is represented by the distributed lag of AS HI P, w hich is the annu al increase

    in net product shipments (from AISI). Profitability is represented by INT-

    FU ND , which is internal funds (co rpo rate net income plus depreciation plus

    the change in reserves minus dividends), calculated from AISl financial

    4 The sample period is 1951 81. The equation was estimated by in strum enta l variables using

    Fair's (1970) method. Numbers in parentheses are ;-statistics.

    Downloadedb

    y[UniversityofAuckland

    Library]at20:2014Febru

    ary2015

  • 7/25/2019 Blecker, R. a. (1991). Import Competition, Investment Finance, And Cumulative Decline in the US Steel Industry,

    10/27

    178 Import competition, investment finance, and cumulative decline

    data, and expressed in constant 1972

    dollar^.^

    CAPUTIL is the Federal

    Reserve Board (FRB) index of capacity utilization in iron and steel.

    DKOREA is a dummy variable set equal to 1 in 1952 to control for the

    Korean War investment boom.

    DSTRIKE

    is a dummy variable for the 1959

    strike, which is included with a one-year lag to capture the postponement

    of investment expenditures until after the strike ended.

    Since all the coefficients on the various lags of ASHIP are negative and

    insignifi~ant,~quation (1) was rerun with these variables omitted. The

    resulting specification is shown as equation (1.1) in Table 1. Note that,

    when the accelerator terms are omitted, the coefficients on internal funds

    INTFUND)are higher and more significant, while those on the utilization

    rate are lower but also more significant.

    Internal funds are determined by the simple accounting identity:

    F

    [ P-c)x-

    ] I -

    ,

    2)

    where ?r is internal funds, P is the price, C is average variable cost (unit

    labour plus unit materials costs),

    X

    is output, F is fixed costs, and 7 is the

    corporate tax rate. Since replacement investment generally raises produc-

    tivity and thereby increases capacity, we are concerned with gross invest-

    ment. Therefore, depreciation allowances are treated as part of the cash flow

    or internal funds available to finance gross investment, rather than as part

    of fixed costs.

    The real amount of gross profit in terms of output is:

    where P C) /Pi s the price-cost margin (PCM). Alternatively, real internal

    funds can be measured in terms of their command over capital goods:

    where Pi is a price index for investment expenditures. Rearranging (2b) and

    taking natural logarithms yields:

    log

    ? r / ~ ; )

    log [ P

    c)/P;]

    log

    1 7

    log

    X

    log (1

    )

    3)

    Th e AlSl financial da ta were deflated using the implicit price deflato r for new plant and equip-

    ment expenditures in blast f urna ces and steel works

    P I N V E S T )

    based on 1972 100. Th e

    financial data were corrected fo r the varying percentage of f irm s reporting each year by

    dividing by the reporting firms' share of product shipments.

    6 The sum of the coefficients on ASHIP is -.018 with a -statistic of -0.49 , which is also

    insignificant. Th e insignificance of the accelerator ter ms in equ ation 1) probably reflects the

    flat trend of shipments in the US steel industry, which grew at a n average annua l rate of under

    I % during the sample period. Th e mean ann ual ch ange in shipments is not s ignificantly dif-

    ferent from zero at the

    5%

    level. Assuming that steel firms did not expect any long-term

    grow th of dem and , they would view increases in dema nd m erely a s cyclical fluc tuation s.

    ~ ~ p a r e n t l ~teel firms didrespond to cyclical effects, judging from the positive coefficients

    on the utilization rate.

    Downloadedb

    y[UniversityofAuckland

    Library]at20:2014Febru

    ary2015

  • 7/25/2019 Blecker, R. a. (1991). Import Competition, Investment Finance, And Cumulative Decline in the US Steel Industry,

    11/27

    Robert A. Blecker

    179

    where

    = F / P - O X .

    Although equation (3) is an accounting identity,

    consistent measures of all the variables in equation (3) are not available. I

    therefore treat equation

    (3)

    a s stochastic equ ation (1.2) in Ta ble 1.

    MARGIN

    is the constant-dollar profit margin, defined by identity (1.3) in the table.

    OUTPUT is the FRB index for the iron and steel industry (1977 = 100).

    T A X R A T E is the ave rage effective tax rate for all man ufactu ring corp o-

    r a t i o n ~ . ~

    VERHEAD,

    which is used as a proxy for f, is the ratio of the

    Bureau of Labor Statistics (BLS) index of nonproduction worker hours to

    the index for production worker hours in steel (1977 = 100).

    Identity (1.3) defines the gross profit margin in constant 1972 dollars.

    PRICE is the average realized price of all steel products, in current dollars

    per net ton, calculated from Census Bureau and AISI data. UNITCOST

    is the average direct cost of prod uctio n workers labo ur plus seven raw

    materials (iron o re, coking co al, noncoking coal, steel scrap, fuel oil, pur-

    chased electricity, and natural gas) in current price^.^

    Eq uatio n (1.4) then explains the price level, allowing chan ges in unit costs

    to be passed on over tw o years. PRICE also depends on the dividend payout

    rate, overhead costs, and after a structural break when imports became

    firmly established in the early 1960s (D l96 2 is a du m my variable equ al to

    on e in 1962-81 and zero earlier) im po rt pene tration and capacity utiliza-

    tion. Previous studies (Mancke, 1968; Crandall, 1981; Blecker, 1989) have

    confirmed the hypothesis of such a structural break, which is simply

    assumed here.

    DIVPNT

    is cash dividends paid, in current dollars per net

    ton of

    trend

    produ ct shipm ents, calculated from AISI series. Dividends

    are included as a proxy fo r the managers. sense of their firms. ma rket

    power (see Adelman, 1961; Means, 1962 .

    IMPSH RE

    is the share of

    imports in apparent supply (AISI). The price equation is not linearly

    hom ogeneous with respect to direct costs, as the sum of the coefficients o n

    UNITCOST

    is significantly below unity (see Table I, note c). Apparently,

    the combined pressures of trade union strength at home and intensifying

    TAX RA TE is the ratio of taxes paid af ter credits to income subject to tax, for total m anufac-

    turing, from US Internal Revenue Service, Storisrics of incom e corpo rurion tux returns .

    This is used as an instrument for the actual effective tax rate for the steel industry, which

    would not be independent of the industry s realized profitability .

    Th e method of calculating the average realized price was adapted from Crand all (1981),

    a s explained in Blecker (1989). D etails on the deriv ation of all th e dat a series used in this

    paper are available from the autho r o n request .

    Th e calculation of m aterials costs was based on the sources and procedures used in US FT

    (1977). with some modifications. Th e main source for physical input d ata was AISI. T he

    BLS index of production worker hours (1977

    =

    100) was used fo r the labo ur inp ut, scaled

    by the A lSl figure for wage employee hour s (divided by the percentage of f irms reporting)

    for 1977. Th e wage rate is the AlS l measure of t otal employment cost per hour for wage

    employees. Raw materials and energy prices were calculated from a variety of public and

    private sources. Details are available from the aut hor on request.

    l a

    Th e log-linear time trend of net prod uct shipme nts over 1945-83 is used fo r the den om ina tor

    o f D lV PN T to eliminate the effects of cyclical fluctuations in demand , which would be cor-

    related with CAPUTIL.

    Downloaded

    by[UniversityofAucklandLibrary]at20:2014Febru

    ary2015

  • 7/25/2019 Blecker, R. a. (1991). Import Competition, Investment Finance, And Cumulative Decline in the US Steel Industry,

    12/27

    180 Im po rt competit ion, investment f inance, a n d cumu lat ive decline

    competition from abroad prevented US steel firms from fully passing on

    their increases in direct costs.

    Th e specification of dividends in (1.5) is ada pte d fro m L intner (1956). Th e

    current payout decision is based on the past level of dividends, with

    adjustments made according to recent profitabili ty. I use one-year lagged

    IN TF UN D to represent profitabil ity, s ince using current IN TF UN D would

    result in circular reasoning in the contex t of the present mo del. Since

    DI V PN Ti s measured in nominal dollars , a l so add UNIT CO ST to cont ro l

    for inf lat ion, assuming th at f i rms try to make nominal dividend payments

    keep pace with wages and other costs (Eichner, 1976).

    Equation (1.6) is an identity for capacity util ization. CAPACITY is the

    FRB index based on 1977 ou tpu t 100. Equ ation (1.7) is used to link the

    F R B

    outp ut index to the physical da ta for s teel product d em and : domestic

    consum ption (DOM CONS), measured by 'apparent supply ' (net shipments

    plus imports minus exports) , and IMPORTS. Equation (1.8) for s teel

    capacity is based o n the presum ption tha t past capacity is adde d t o by one-

    year lagged real investment (INV ES 7). Lagged O U T P U T is also included

    as a proxy for expected changes in dem an d, which affect t he rate a t which

    old capacity is retired. Includ ing this variable improved the baseline forecast

    of the equation, in spite of the low /-statistic.

    Equat ions (1.9) to (1.11) determine the import share, import demand,

    and total d em an d, respectively. Following a suggestion of Rippe (1970: 42),

    I include lagged im ports in the imp ort de ma nd equa tion (1.10) to represent

    ' the learning process involved in the purch ase of imports ' . I M P R I C E is

    the weighted average price of imports of five major carbon steel products

    (bars, cold- and hot-rolled sheet, plate, and structurals), including esti-

    mated freight, insurance, an d custom s charges. Th e relatively high price-

    elasticity of demand for steel imports (about 1.4 in the short run and 2.6

    in the long ru n) indicates that foreign steel products were good substitutes

    fo r domest ic products . Domest ic consumption (DOM CO NS) is the total

    demand for steel products, measured by 'apparent supply' (domestic ship-

    ments plus net imports) . Th e DS TR IK E dum my is used to con trol for the

    surge of imports d uring th e 1959 str ike.

    Th e BLS producer price index fo r nonferrous metals (P PI N FM E 7) is used

    in ( I . 11) to represent the price o f substitute materials. YMFR is the FR B

    index of man ufacturin g o ut pu t, used as a proxy for the 'income' of steel con-

    sumers. Note that overall steel demand is relatively income-inelastic,

    INT FUN D is a function of MA RG IN by 1.2 ). Since MA RG IN PRICE- /TOTCOST)/

    PINVESTby

    1.3) ,

    and PR ICE is a function of D l VPNT by

    1.4).

    if DIVPN Twer e a func-

    tion of current INTFUND, then current DIVPNT would be a function of itself.

    12

    This measure was adapted and extended from data in Crandall 1981). a s explained in

    Blecker 1989). The weights are the shares of each product type in net shipments.

    13 The PPIs for concrete products and plastic materials result in similar estimated coefficients,

    but PPIN FM ET yields the best fit.

    Downloaded

    by[UniversityofAuckland

    Library]at20:2014Febru

    ary2015

  • 7/25/2019 Blecker, R. a. (1991). Import Competition, Investment Finance, And Cumulative Decline in the US Steel Industry,

    13/27

    Robert A Blecker 18 1

    which reflects the s tructu ral decline in steel usage in an advanced economy.

    The negative time-squared trend also indicates accelerating technical pro-

    gress in findin g substitutes fo r steel.I4 And the sensitivity of to tal steel

    demand to relative prices may also be conceptualized as reflecting technical

    progress. Following Rosenberg's (1976) view of rising ma terials prices as an

    'inducement mechanism' or 'focusing device' for technological innovation,

    the rising relative price of steel in the postwar US economy can be said to

    have induced a cum ulative innovative effort aimed a t reducing the steel con-

    tent of national output. The fact that innovation is required, rather than a

    costless shift along a given production function, probably accounts for the

    relative price inelasticity of total steel demand (elasticity of about 0.5).

    ffects of imports on investment financing

    Th e effects of im port penetration o n capital accumulation in the US steel

    industry are estimated using in-sample simulations of the model described

    in the previous section. Th e year 1962 is chosen as the s tarting point for the

    simulations because it is the year of th e optim al struc tural break in the price

    equation (1.4), when prices became sensitive to import penetration and

    capacity utilization. This was also the first year in which imports rose

    above 5% of domestic consumption (except for the strike year 1959). The

    simulations end in 1981 for the same reasons indicated in the previous

    section.

    A baseline simulation of the model was run assuming actual historical

    values for all the exogenous variable s, allowing all the endo genous variables

    to ad just dynamically (see the Appendix for diagnostic tests of the m odel).

    Then, the model was simulated under the counterfactual assumption that

    import penetration remained a t approximately 1962 levels throug h 1981.

    Two counterfactual scenarios were tested: (1) the share of imports in

    domestic consumption is constrained t o 5 % ; and (2) the volume of imports

    is constrained to four million net tons. In both cases, equation (1.10) for

    import demand is dropped from the model, either IMPSHARE or

    IMPORTS is set exogenously, an d identity (1.9) is used t o calculate the oth er

    import variable.

    Tables 2 and 3 give the means and growth rates, respectively, for the

    baseline and counterfactual simulations.

    The endogenous variables are

    listed in the same order a s they appear in Ta ble 1, except that the constant

    dollar margin in (1.3) is replaced by the true PCM, defined as

    (PRICE-

    UN ITCO ST)/PR ICE (expressed as a percentage). Th e two counterfactual

    l With the dependent variable measured in logs,

    steel demand decays at the rate of

    2(.00025) O.S % per year. Thi s term is included in spite of th e low -statistic because

    it improves the fit of the baseline forecast. linear time trend is not used because it would

    be collinear with log

    YMFR

    Downloadedby[UniversityofAuckland

    Library]at20:2014Febru

    ary2015

  • 7/25/2019 Blecker, R. a. (1991). Import Competition, Investment Finance, And Cumulative Decline in the US Steel Industry,

    14/27

    182 Im po rt competi t ion, investment f inance, a n d cumulat ive decline

    Table

    Sample means, 1962- 1981

    Variable

    Counterfactual S imulations

    Actual Baseline

    Data Simulat~on

    1 1

    (21

    Nores

    In billions of

    1972

    dollars, deflated by

    PINVEST.

    Price-cost margin d efined as

    I(PR1CE UNICO ST)/PR ICEI 1 0 0 .

    In current dollars per net ton of p roducts shipments.

    In current dollars per net ton of tren produc t sh~pments

    OUTPUT and CAPACITY are ~nde xes ased on 1977 output

    =

    10 0. CAPUTIL is OUTPUT

    as a percentage of CAPACITY

    Measured In per cent

    g

    Assumed lexogenously f ixed .

    In millions of net tons.

    simulations generate very similar results,

    with scenario

    2)

    the more

    restrictive assum ption generating slightly greater effects, as on e would

    expect.

    Th e average

    PCM

    fo r the period 1962-1981 would have been abo ut 10

    o r 11 higher with im po rts constrained (in scenarios

    1 )

    and (2), respec-

    tively), compared with the baseline forecast. Underlying this difference is

    a faster average annual rate of price increase:

    7 . 8

    compared with

    7 .3

    in the baseline (recall th at unit co sts are exogenously fixed). T he higher

    prices are mainly due to the direct effects of the assumed restrictions on

    imp ort competi t ion. T here is a lso an indirect d ynam ic effect operating via

    the feedback of higher lagged prof i ts ( INTFUND,- , ) on to current divi-

    dends (DIVPNT,) . In addi t ion, there is a small boost to pr ices f rom the

    higher rate of capacity utilization.

    Turning to the underlying determinants of capaci ty ut i l izat ion, output

    averages abou t 6 higher in the coun terfactual scenarios (compared with

    the baseline), while capacity averages only ab ou t

    3 higher (see Table 2).

    The increase in output is due to the fact that the restr ic t ions on imports

    mo re tha n offset the reduct ions in total s teel dem and (DOM CO NS), which

    are due in

    turn

    to the higher prices of steel products relative to substitute

    material s. Th e counter fac tua l means and growth ra tes for DO M C ON S are

    lower tha n in the baseline sim ulation, confirm ing th at th e gains for dom estic

    product ion come par t ly at the expense of domest ic s teel consumption

    Downloadedby[UniversityofAuckland

    Library]at20:2014Febru

    ary2015

  • 7/25/2019 Blecker, R. a. (1991). Import Competition, Investment Finance, And Cumulative Decline in the US Steel Industry,

    15/27

    Robert

    A

    Blecker

    183

    able

    3

    Average annual grow th rates. 196 2-1 98 1 ( i n per cent)

    Actual

    Counterfactual S imulations

    Baseline

    Variable Data Simulation (1 )

    12)

    1) INVEST

    21

    INTFUND

    3 PCM

    PRICE

    5 ) DIVPNT

    6 ) CAPUTIL

    7 ) OUTPUT

    8 ) CAPACITY

    9 ) IMPSHARE

    10 ) IMPORTS

    f l

    DOMCONS

    Nores Growth rates are calculated from OLS regressions of the natural logs on linear time

    trends except as noted.

    Variables are defined as in Table 2.

    a

    Estimated by AR1 procedure

    Not significant at the

    5

    level (two-tailed test).

    Assumed fixed.

    especially when productivity growth is taken as exogenously fixed.

    Internal funds are consistently well above the baseline levels in the

    counterfactual scenarios. IN TF U N D averages 571.3 million higher in

    scenario (1) and 653.8 million higher in scenario (2), com pared with the

    baseline, o r abo ut 27% and 319'0, respectively. Th e increased internal funds

    are due primarily to the increase in the profit margin and only secondarily

    to higher output. The higher constant-dollar

    M RGIN

    accounts for an

    average 20% rise in annual internal funds in scenario 1) and a 23% rise in

    scenario (2); higher

    OU TP UT accou nts for about a 3% rise in both scenarios

    (evaluated at the sample means in logarithms).

    Th e model also fore casts higher levels of investment spending as a result

    of the increased internal fun ds and capacity utilization in the cou nter factu al

    scenarios. Average ann ual real investment w ould have been 407.0 million

    higher in scenario (1) com pared with the baseline, and 459.8 million higher

    in (2), or a bo ut 22% and 25 % , respectively. The present value of the total

    add itiona l investment for the 20 years 1962-1981 is 7.5 billion in scenario

    (1) and 8.5 billion in scenario (2), mea sured in 1972 do llars, assuming a

    5 % discount rate.

    In ord er to apprec iate the econo mic significance of these increased expen-

    ditures on new plant and equipment due to import restrictions, it is help-

    ful to have some sense of the industry's cap ital requireme nts. O ne useful ben-

    chmark is the cost of constructing new, integrated steel plants in the

    early 1970s, aro un d the midpoint o f o ur sam ple period. C randall(19 81: 78)

    estimates that th e capital costs for a new integrated steel mill were 41 1 per

    net raw ton of capacity in 1972. Thus the total extra investment spending

    Downloadedby[UniversityofAuckland

    Library]at20:2014Febru

    ary2015

  • 7/25/2019 Blecker, R. a. (1991). Import Competition, Investment Finance, And Cumulative Decline in the US Steel Industry,

    16/27

    184

    Import competition investment finance and cumulative decline

    which would have resulted from restricting steel imports t o 5% of the market

    (or four million net tons) over a 20-year period could have purchased

    approximately 18 (or 21) million tons of new integrated capacity, repre-

    senting only about 12% (or 13%) of the total industry capacity of 156 million

    tons in 1972, as estimated by Crandall (1981: 24-25).

    Crandall (1981: 11) reports that 'the minimum efficient scale of a new

    integrated greenfield plant is somewhere between 6 and 7 million raw

    tons'. t $411 per ton, the total cost of one efficient, new integrated mill

    would therefore have been between $2.5 and $2.9 billion in 1972. If all the

    extra investment forecast in the counterfactual simulations had been devoted

    to constructing new integrated mills, about three such mills could have been

    built. While this would have quadrupled the number of new greenfield plants

    actually built in the

    US

    after 196 (the only one was Bethlehem Steel's Burns

    Harbor, Indiana plant), it would clearly not have permitted a thorough

    modernization of most US steelmaking facilities.

    From a competitive viewpoint as well, building more integrated mills

    might not have been a wise strategy, even if more capital funds had been

    available. Barnett and Schorsch (1983) and Barnett and Crandall(1986) have

    demonstrated that, by the late 1970s and 1980s. US integrated mills were

    not cost competitive with their foreign counterparts, while the nonintegrated

    minimills were still competitive. Barnett and Crandall (1986: 52-53; 65-67)

    estimate that minimills could be built at a cost of about $300 per net ton

    of capacity for bars and wire rod, or $700 for cold-rolled sheet coils, in 1985

    prices. Using the implicit price deflator for steel investment, these figures

    translate into approximately $140 and $325, respectively, in 1972 prices.

    Therefore, over the entire 20 year period 1962-81, the industry could have

    afforded about 53 million tons of additional minimill bar/rod capacity or

    23 million tons of minimill sheet capacity under scenario (I), and 60 million

    tons of barhod or 26 million tons of sheet with minimills under scenario

    (2). Clearly, the industry could have afforded much more modernization if

    it had ploughed the extra internal funds into more minimill construction,

    rather than more integrated mills.

    V Effects of allowing for increased productivity growth

    In order to demonstrate conclusively that the profits-investment link can

    lead to a cumulative improvement or worsening of competitiveness, it would

    be necessary to prove that additional investment in an industry would

    reduce its unit costs in the long run. This would require showing not only

    that more investment would increase productivity growth, but also that

    increased productivity growth would not be offset by higher input prices

    (especially wages). Since there is a close correlation between capital-labour

    ratios and labour productivity in the steel industry, after correcting for

    cyclical effects (Barnett and Schorsch, 1983: 147), we may infer that the

    Downloadedby[UniversityofAuckland

    Library]at20:2014Febru

    ary2015

  • 7/25/2019 Blecker, R. a. (1991). Import Competition, Investment Finance, And Cumulative Decline in the US Steel Industry,

    17/27

    Robert A Blecker 185

    increased investment which would have resulted from restrictions on imports

    would have enabled productivity to rise more rapidly. The likely reaction

    of wages to such restrictions is much less clear, however.

    It could be argued that unions would have taken advantage of import

    restrictions to win greater wage increases for their members. But whether

    steel workers could have obtained wage increases greater than those actually

    obtained in 1961-81 is doubtful. Steel wages rose faster than average for

    US manufacturing in 1957-77 anyway, in spite of rising imports (Anderson

    and Kreinin, 1981). Lawrence and Lawrence (1985) found striking evidence

    that, in the 1970s, employed steelworkers obtained above-average wage

    increases in a declining industry facing stiff international competition by

    playing an 'end game' over the quasi-rents from the operation of existing

    facilities. The authors found no evidence that steel wages rose more rapidly

    during the two periods of binding protection in the 1970s; the 197 1-72 volun-

    tary restraint agreements; and the 1978-79 trigger prices. It is therefore far

    from clear that wages would have risen more if the industry had suffered

    less foreign competition and had better growth prospects. Indeed, unions

    might have exercised more wage restraint if they had thought that the pro-

    spects for increased investment and job opportunities were brighter. In this

    case, unions might have believed that higher cash flows would actually be

    reinvested in the industry.

    Given the uncertain effects of protection on wages, it seems safest to

    assume that protection would have had a net negative effect on unit labour

    costs through increased labour product~vity. In order to obtain a rough

    estimate of how the results of the present simulations are affected if the

    higher investment rates would have generated more rapid productivity

    growth, the counterfactual simulations described in the previous section

    were rerun with labour productivity assumed to grow

    at a

    compounded 1

    per year more than it actually grew, starting in 1962. The 1% increase in

    the productivity growth rate was arrived a t in two ways. First, the additional

    investment forecast by the model in scenario (I), with imports constrained

    to 5% of the market, is estimated to make net capital per worker grow about

    0.8

    per year faster than in the model baseline.I6 Assuming a unitary

    elasticity of labour productivity with respect to net capital per worker, the

    1 Th e aut ho r attem pted to estimate a Kaldorian technical progress function by regressing the

    annu al growth rate of labour prod uctivity on the rate of increase in estimated) capital per

    production worker, af ter controlling f or changes in capacity utilization and o ther variables.

    While significant positive coefficients were ob tain ed, the quan tita tiv e results were very sen-

    sitive to the precise specification ch osen, a nd t hos e estim ated coefficie nts ar e not relied upon

    here. The estimation of the capital stock is described in the following note.

    6

    The net capital stock was estimated by accumulating annual real investment spending,

    assuming a 20-year service life for all steel investment and using straight-line depreciation.

    Hou rs of production workers in the counterfactual scenario were estimated by multiplying

    actual hours for each year times the ratio of counterfactual

    OUTPUT

    t o

    OUTPUT

    from

    the baseline simulation.

    Downloadedby[UniversityofAuckland

    Library]at20:2014Febru

    ary2015

  • 7/25/2019 Blecker, R. a. (1991). Import Competition, Investment Finance, And Cumulative Decline in the US Steel Industry,

    18/27

    186

    Imp ort com peti tion investment finance and cum ulative decline

    former would also rise about 0.8% faster per year. Secondly, the BLS

    index of ou tput per prod uction w orker ho ur in steel rose by ab out 0.6% per

    year slower than the average fo r a ll US m a n ~ f a c tu r i n g . ' ~ fa ir ly neut ra l

    assum ption is that protection fro m im por ts could at least have enabled the

    industry to achieve the average productivity growth rate for all manu-

    facturing (Scott, 1989). I rounded these growth differentials up to

    1

    t o

    compensate for the possible effects of additional investment in lowering

    energy and materials costs, which could not be modelled so easily due to

    the heterogeneity of these inputs.

    T he results of the simu lations with variable productivity are summ arized

    in Table 4 for scenario (l).' he ma in diffe renc e is tha t the price increases

    are much more m oderate , as lower unit costs are only partly offs et by profit

    margins which are only slightly higher. As a result, total domestic con-

    sumption and o utput are both higher, an d the costs of the hypothesized pro-

    tection to domestic steel consum ers a re greatly reduced. As Figures 1 a n d

    2 show , in the first few years after im por ts are controlled, domestic prices

    and consumption in the counterfactual simulation with increased produc-

    tivity ar e close to their trajectories in the counterfa ctual simula tion with c on-

    stant productivity. H owever, after 10-20 years have elapse d, the simulation

    with increased productivity generates forecasts closer to the model baseline

    than t o the counte rfactual simu lation with constan t productivity. By 1981,

    the final year in the sim ulations, the price is forecast to be

    566

    per net ton

    with increased productivity, about 4.6% higher tha n in the baseline forec ast

    ( 541), ut abou t 6.4% lower than in the counterfa ctual forecast with cons-

    tant productivity

    ( 605).

    imilarly,

    1981

    domestic consumption falls to only

    100.5

    million net tons in the simulation with increased productivity from

    102.8 million in the baseline, a s com pare d with 97 2 million in the c ounter-

    factual simulation with constant productivity.

    V

    Conclusions and implications

    If the US steel industry had been fully insulated from rising imports after

    1962, t would hav e benefited from the ability to raise mor e internal funds

    by setting higher pro fit m argins as well as by selling m ore o ut pu t. W ith the

    P M

    abou t 10-1 higher and ou tput a bout 6% higher, real internal funds

    would have been about 27-31 To higher and real investment expenditures

    would have been about 22-25% greater. These expenditures could have

    enabled the industry to replace or refurbish a portion of its plant and

    l Grow th rates are est imated by least squares. The index of production worker productivity

    for all manufa cturing was obtained by dividing the index of m anufac turing output by the

    index of average weekly hours of production workers

    Handbook of labor

    srarisrtcs, 1989;

    both indexes based on

    1977 100 .

    8 Results for scenario

    (2)

    were quali tat ively similar and are omitted for reasons of space.

    Downloadedby[UniversityofAuckland

    Library]at20:2014Febru

    ary2015

  • 7/25/2019 Blecker, R. a. (1991). Import Competition, Investment Finance, And Cumulative Decline in the US Steel Industry,

    19/27

    Robert A Blecker

    187

    Table

    Means and g row th rates for a lternative simulations: co nstant versus increased pro-

    ductiv ity (Scenario 1 -Impo rts Restricted to 5 of Market)

    Means

    Grow th Ratesa

    Variable Constant Increased Constant Increased

    1 INVEST

    2 INTFUND

    3 ) PCM

    4 ) PRICE

    51 DIVPNT

    6 ) CAPUTIL

    7 ) OUTPUT

    8 ) CAPACITY

    9 ) IMPSHARE

    10

    IMPORTS

    1 1)

    DOMCONS

    Notes

    Variable are defined as in Table

    2.

    Grow th rates calculated as in Table 3.

    Simulation with increased productiv ity growth assumes labour productiv ity rose by

    1

    per

    year more than it actually did.

    a In per cent per year.

    Not significant at the 5 level.

    Assumed (exogenously f ixed).

    equipment. Although the additional expenditures would not have been

    enough to mod ernize most of the industry

    -

    especially if the fu nd s had been

    spent on greenfield integrated mills the simulations d o show tha t a profit

    squeeze due to import competition significantly restricted the ability of

    firms to finance their capital expenditures. T o this extent, it may be said that

    import penetration contributed to a vicious circle of cumulative decline.

    Th e analysis in this paper su ppo rts the view th at competitive advantages

    or disadvantages, to a certain extent, can be created or lost by specific

    historical events and social institutions. It is also implied tha t artificial gains

    or losses of competitiveness (e.g., du e to tem porary undervaluation or over-

    valuation of a nation s currency) can have pe rma nen t, potentially irrever-

    sible effects. From this perspective, comparative cost advantages and

    disadvantages at any given point in time are not merely manifestations of

    inherent comparative adv antages based solely on exogenous factor endow -

    ments. T he analysis also implies that the pu tative benefits t o dom estic steel

    consum ers of allowing steel imp orts ar e exaggerated by analyses which fail

    to take account of the productivity losses engendered when investment

    finance is constrained by import competition.

    It does not necessarily follow from this analysis that more protectionism

    was actually warranted f or the

    US

    steel industry du ring the 1960s and 1970s,

    or that additional investment could have permanently averted its decline.

    For one thing, mere protection would have left steel firms free to plough

    the add itional fund s into greater diversification out of steel, in the absence

    of a m ore comprehensive industrial policy. Unless steps were taken t o en sure

    Downloadedby[UniversityofAuckland

    Library]at20:2014Febru

    ary2015

  • 7/25/2019 Blecker, R. a. (1991). Import Competition, Investment Finance, And Cumulative Decline in the US Steel Industry,

    20/27

    188

    Imp ort co mp etitio n investment finance and cumulative decline

    Downloadedby[UniversityofAuckland

    Library]at20:2014Febru

    ary2015

  • 7/25/2019 Blecker, R. a. (1991). Import Competition, Investment Finance, And Cumulative Decline in the US Steel Industry,

    21/27

    Million Net Tons

    120

    70

    1962 1964 1966 1968 1970 1972 1974 1976 1978 1980

    Figure

    US domestic steel consumption, alternative simulations, 1962-81

    Source Author's calculations. Simulations with constant and increased productivity both assume imports constrained to

    5

    of consumption.

    aseline Productivity Productivity

    I

    I

    I I

    I

    Downloadedby[UniversityofAucklandLibrary]at

    20:2014February2015

  • 7/25/2019 Blecker, R. a. (1991). Import Competition, Investment Finance, And Cumulative Decline in the US Steel Industry,

    22/27

    190 Im po rt competition investment finance and cumulative decline

    that additional profits were actually invested in raising steel productivity,

    the negative allocational effects on steel consumers emphasized in the tradi-

    tional analyses (e.g., Crandall, 198 1; 1987) might have predominated. The

    need to compel firms receiving protection (or subsidies) to reinvest in moder-

    nizing their steel operations is especially important in the light of the dif-

    ferences found in our forecasts for steel prices and consumption in the

    counterfactual simulations with constant versus increased productivity.

    Another difficulty with protecting the steel industry arises from the fact

    that steel is a mature product with a slowly growing market, especially in

    advanced industrialized countries such as the United States. For this rea-

    son, efforts to sustain large, integrated steel works in all the industrialized

    countries have only led to global excess capacity (Barnett and Schorsch,

    1983: 38-47). Our estimated total steel demand function (I . l l ) shows that

    steel demand is income-inelastic and has an accelerating negative time trend.

    And even the insignificance of accelerator terms in the investment function

    I ) can be interpreted as reflecting the poor prospects for the growth of steel

    demand. Protection simply could not have preserved the relative importance

    which steel had in the US economy in the postwar years, and excessive

    protection could have hindered necessary structural changes at high social

    costs.

    There may be situations, however, in which a more activist response to

    a loss of competitiveness in steel might be indicated. For example, macro-

    economic imbalances and exchange rate fluctuations can potentially cause

    lasting damage to domestic producers. For the period 1979- 1983, about

    55

    of the employment losses in the

    US

    steel industry have been attributed to

    the overvaluation of the dollar combined with sluggish real income growth

    (Grossman, 1986). In this situation, if profits and investment were also cur-

    tailed, a case for some kind of remedial intervention could be made.

    The connection between pricing, profitability, and investment which has

    been identified in this paper also suggests a reorientation of economic theory

    along the lines suggested (in a different context) by Heim and Mirowski

    (1987).

    In particular, this connection implies

    a

    shift in the focus of price

    theory, away from the traditional view of prices as scarcity indexes, toward

    a conception of prices as instruments in firms competitive efforts to expand

    a shift advocated earlier by Robinson (1962) and Levine (1982). In this

    light, the long-standing debate about whether industrial prices are flexible

    or rigid has missed the point. This debate has been based on the pre-

    sumption that any sign of price flexibility in response to demand conditions

    indicates a tendency toward neoclassical market-clearing pricing; thus critics

    of neoclassical price theory have been forced to claim that prices are rigid .

    An alternative approach is to view flexible prices as signalling firms chang-

    ing abilities to finance their growth along irreversible paths, rather than as

    signals inducing them to allocate resources efficiently in a preordained

    equilibrium state.

    Downloadedb

    y[UniversityofAuckland

    Library]at20:2014Febru

    ary2015

  • 7/25/2019 Blecker, R. a. (1991). Import Competition, Investment Finance, And Cumulative Decline in the US Steel Industry,

    23/27

    Robert A Blecker

    191

    This alternative app roac h would place the expand ing business firm , rather

    than the intertemporal-utility-maximizing household, at the centre of the

    analysis of ca pital accumulation. O n the o ne side, gross realized profits a re

    the main source of saving; on the other side, expected net profits are the

    principal inducement t o invest. Investment decisions, m ade at th e microlevel

    by competing firms, determine income levels and growth rates at the macro-

    level. Th e analysis in this pape r is intended t o validate the mic rofou nda-

    tions of this approac h at the industry level.

    VI References

    Ad elma n, M.A. 1961: Steel, administered prices and inflatio n. Quarterly

    Journal of Economics

    75, 16-40.

    American Iron and Steel Institute.

    Annual Statistical Report

    Various

    issues.

    An derso n, R.G. an d Kreinen, M.E. 1981 La bo ur costs in the Am erican steel

    and auto industries.

    Wo rld Economy

    4, 199-208.

    Bar nett, D.F. an d Cra ndall, R.W. 1986:

    U p from the ashes: the rise of the

    steel minimill in the United States

    Washington: Brookings.

    Barnett, D.F. and Schorsch,

    L

    1983:

    Steel: upheaval in a basic industry

    Cambridge, Mass: Ballinger.

    Blecker, R.A. 1989: M ar ku p pricing, import com petition , and the decline

    of the American steel industry.

    Journal of Post Keynesian Economics

    12, 70-87.

    Broude, H.W. 1963:

    Steel decisions and the nationa l econom y

    New Haven:

    Yale University Press.

    Crandal l, R.W. 1981

    Th e USstee l industry in recurrent crisis

    Washington:

    Brookings.

    987: Th e effects o f

    US

    trade protection f or auto s and steel.

    Brookings

    Papers on Economic Activity

    1, 271-88.

    Do rnbu sch, R. 1987: Exchange rates and prices.

    American Economic

    Review

    77, 93-106.

    Eichner, A.S. 1976:

    Th e megacorp and oligopoly

    Cambridge: Cambridge

    University Press.

    Fair, R.C. 1970: Th e estim ation of sim ultaneo us equa tion m odels with

    lagged endogenous variables and first order serially correlated errors.

    Econometrica

    38, 507-16.

    Fazzari, S.M. and Athey, M.J. 1987: Asym metric inf orm atio n, financing

    constraints, and investment.

    Review of Econom ics and Statistics

    69,

    481-87.

    Fazzari, S.M. H ub ba rd, R.G. and Peters en, B.C. 1988: Financing con-

    straints and corporate investment.

    Brookings Papers on Economic

    Activity

    1, 141-95.

    Fazzari, S.M. and Mott, T L 1986-87: T he investment theories of Kalecki

    and Keynes: an empirical study of firm data, 1970-1982.

    Journal of

    Post Keynesian Economics

    9, 17 1-87.

    Feinberg, R.M. 1986: T he interaction of foreign exchange an d mark et power

    Downloaded

    by[UniversityofAuckland

    Library]at20:2014Febru

    ary2015

  • 7/25/2019 Blecker, R. a. (1991). Import Competition, Investment Finance, And Cumulative Decline in the US Steel Industry,

    24/27

    192 Import competition investment finance and cumulative decline

    effects on German domestic prices. Journal of Industrial Economics

    35, 61-70.

    989: The effects of foreign exchange movements on US domestic

    prices.

    Review of Economics and Statistics

    71, 505-1

    1

    Grossman G.M. 1986: Imports as a cause of injury: the case of the US steel

    industry. Journal of International Economics 20, 201 -23.

    Matanaka M. 1976: Several efficient two-step estimators for the dynamic

    simultaneous equations model with autoregressive disturbances. Jour-

    nal of Econometrics 4, 189-204.

    Heim C.E. and Mirowski P. 1987: Interest rates and crowding-out during

    Britain s industrial revolution. Journal of Economic History 47, 117-

    39.

    Wooper P

    and

    Mann C.L.

    1989: Exchange rate pass-through in the 1980s:

    the case

    of

    U

    manufactures.

    Brookings

    Papers

    on Economic Activity

    1

    297-337.

    Jondrow J.M.

    1978: Effects of trade restrictions on imports of steel. In

    Dewald, W.G., editor, The impact of international trade and invest-

    ment on employment

    Washington: US Department of Labor.

    Kaldor

    N .

    1970: The case for regional policies. Scottish Journal of Political

    Economy 17.

    972: The irrelevance of equilibrium economics. Economic Journal 82,

    1237-55.

    Kalecki M.

    197 1 Selected essays in the dynamics of the capitalist economy.

    Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Karier T . 1988: New evidence on the effects of unions and imports on

    monopoly power. Journal of Post Keynesian Economics 10, 414-27.

    Krugman P.R. 1981 Trade, accumulation, and uneven development. Jour-

    nal of Development Economics 8, 149-61.

    Lawrence C.

    and

    Lawrence R.Z.

    1985: Manufacturing wage dispersion:

    an end game interpretation. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity

    1, 47-106.

    Lawrence R.Z. 1983: Is trade deindustrializing America? A medium-term

    perspective. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 1, 129-72.

    Levine D.P. 1982: Determinants of capitalist expansion.

    Economic Devel-

    opment and Cultural Change 30, 299-320.

    Lintner J.

    1956: Distribution of incomes of corporations among dividends,

    retained earnings, and taxes. American Economic Review Proceedings

    46 (May), 97-1 13.

    Mancke R. 1968: The determinants of steel prices in the U.S.: 1947-65.

    Journal of Industrial Economics 16, 147-60.

    Mann C.L.

    1986: Prices, profit margins, and exchange rates. Federal

    Reserve Bulletin 72, 366-79.

    Means G.C. 1962: Pricing power and the public interest: a study based on

    steel.

    New York: Harper.

    Rippe R.D.

    1970: Wages, prices, and imports in the American steel

    industry. Review of Economics and Statistics 52, 34-46

    Robinson J 1962: Essays in the theory of economic growth. London:

    Macmillan.

    Downloaded

    by[UniversityofAuckland

    Library]at20:2014Febru

    ary2015

  • 7/25/2019 Blecker, R. a. (1991). Import Competition, Investment Finance, And Cumulative Decline in the US Steel Industry,

    25/27

    Robe rt A. Blecker 193

    Rosenberg N . 1976: Perspectives on technology. Cambridge: Cambridge

    University Press.

    Scherer F.M.

    1980: Industrial m arket s truc ture a n d economic performance,

    second edition. Boston: Houghton Mifflin.

    Scott R.E. 1989: Trade policy, employment and the costs and benefits of

    protection. Ind ustr ial Relation s Research Association Proceedings,

    536-46.

    Steindl

    J.

    1952: M aturity a n d stagnation in Am erican capitalism. Ox ford:

    Basil Blackwell.

    Targetti F. and Thirlwall A.P. 1989: The essential Ka ldor. New York:

    Holmes Meier.

    Theil

    H.

    1966: App lied economic forecasting. Am sterdam: North -Hollan d.

    US

    Department of Com merce Bureau of Econ omic Analysis.

    1985: Survey

    of Cur ren t Business (Feb ruary ).

    US Federal Trade Comm ission (FTC ). 1977: The Un ited State s steel industry

    a n d its international rivals. Washington: GP O.

    VII Appendix

    This Appendix discusses the diagnostics of baseline simulation of the model

    presented in the text. Th e first two colum ns of Table 2 com pare the means

    of the baseline forecasts of the endog enous variables with the actu al sample

    means; growth rates are compared in Table 3. Table A-1 gives the ro ot mean

    squared errors (RMSEs) for the baseline forecasts, both in levels and in

    natural logarithms (the latter measured in percent), along with Theil's u

    (coefficient of inequality).

    For purposes

    o

    the present study, only the forecasts

    o

    the long-run

    trends of the variables are of interest, and the model does quite a good job

    of sim ulating those trends. In fact, the simulations track the annual changes

    very well for several variables (PCM, PRICE, CAPUTIL, OUTPUT, and

    DOMCONS), and moderately well for others (IMPORTS, IMPSHARE,

    INT FU ND , and IN VES T). Th e baseline forecasts of the other tw o variables

    (D IV PN Ta nd CA PAC ITY) essentially look like trends o r moving averages

    draw n throu gh the actual series. Generally speaking, the mo re the variables

    depend o n lagged endog enous variables, th e worse the m odel forecas ts their

    year-to-year fluctuations. Nevertheless, the simulations foreca st the sample

    means and growth rates quite closely for all the variables.

    The baseline forecasts of investment spending (INVEST) and internal

    funds (IN TFU ND ) both underpredict the am plitude of the cyclical swings,

    and miss some of the turning points, while approximating the long-run

    9

    Theil's 1966) u-statistic, which is 0 for perfect forecasts and for the 'naive' forecast of

    no change, was designed to evaluate how well models forecast short-term percentage

    increases. The magnitudes of these statistics in Table

    A-1

    should not be surprising for a

    20-year historical simulation.

    Downloaded

    by[UniversityofAuckland

    Library]at20:2014Febru

    ary2015

  • 7/25/2019 Blecker, R. a. (1991). Import Competition, Investment Finance, And Cumulative Decline in the US Steel Industry,

    26/27

    194 Import competition, investment finance, and cumulative decline

    able A 1 Error diagnostics of baseline forecast ( ~ nample. 1962-81)

    RMSE

    in

    RMSE

    in Theil s

    Variable Levels Loga rithms

    11

    INVEST

    2 )

    INTFUND

    3 )

    PCM

    PRICE

    5 )

    DIVPNT

    6 )

    CAPUTIL

    7 )

    OUTPUT

    8 )

    CAPACITY

    9 ) IMPSHARE

    10 IMPORTS

    1

    1

    DOMCONS

    Nores: The root mean squared error RMSEI in levels is measured In the same units as the

    variable (see Table

    2

    for mean levelsl.

    The

    RMSE

    in logarithms is expressed as a percentage.

    Theil s

    u

    IS the coefficient of inequality as de f~ ne dn Theil

    1

    9 6 6) . the ratlo of the percen-

    tage

    RMSE

    for the baseline forecast to the percentage

    RMSE

    for the na ~ ve orecast of no

    change

    trends reasonably well. The forecast of the mean level of INVEST is about

    0.5 above the actual mean, while the forecast of the mean of INTFUND

    is only about 1.5 above the actual (see Table 2). The large RMSEs for INT-

    FUND (see Table A-I) are due mainly t o the failure of the model to predict

    the wild fluctuations of this variable in just three years: 1974; 1977; and

    1981.

    The model slightly overpredicts the means for PRICE and the PCM,

    but only by about 2 in each case. The RMSEs are proportionately small

    for these variables. The baseline price series grows at about the actual

    average annual rate of 7.3 (see Table 3). The model more seriously over-

    predicts the level of dividends paid per net ton (DIVPNT), with a greater

    proportional RMSE and a Theil's u just over 1. However, since the elasticity

    of PRICE with respect to DIVPNT is only 0.16 (equation 1.4), the over-

    prediction of DIVPNT has only a slight effect on the forecasts of PRICE

    and PCM.

    The model comes within 0.4 percentage points of predicting the mean

    capacity utilization rate, with a proportionally small RMSE. The close fit

    for CAPUTIL results from the fact that while the model systematically

    underpredicts both OUTPUT and CAPACITY, it still predicts the

    OUTPUT/CAPACITY ratio quite well. Moreover, most of the year-to-year

    fluctuations in CAPUTIL are due to fluctuations in OUTPUT, which the

    model simulates very closely. While the annual forecast changes in CAPA-

    CITY are worse than naive extrapolation, according to the high Theil's u,

    the forecast of CAPACITY has the lowest logarithmic (percentage) RMSE

    Downloaded

    by[UniversityofAuckland

    Library]at20:2014Febru

    ary2015

  • 7/25/2019 Blecker, R. a. (1991). Import Competition, Investment Finance, And Cumulative Decline in the US Steel Industry,

    27/27

    Robert A. Blecker 195

    of any equation. The forecast and actual series grow at the same average

    annual rate (0.8%) for the entire period, and the forecast mean is less than

    2% below the actual.

    With regard to imports, the baseline forecasts of the means and growth

    rates of IMPORTS and IMPSHARE are very close to the corresponding

    statistics for the actual series. The RMSEs are proportionally large in the

    forecasts for these variables because the forecasts miss some of the turning

    points by one or two years, probably due to the lagged dependent variable

    in (1.10). The model predicts total domestic consumption (DOMCONS)

    much more closely. The mean for the baseline forecast is only 1% lower than

    for the actual series, and the RMSEs are not large. Domestic consumption

    grows slightly more slowly in the baseline forecast compared with the actual

    trend (1.2% per year versus 1.4%), while imports grow at the same rate

    (6.1'70).

    2

    Th e reason fo r this discrepancy is that the predicted series

    P)

    ags consistently b ehind th e

    actual series A )while the latter rises rapidly fro m 1965 to 1977; hence the predicted change

    PI A , - , ) / A , - , is negative while the actual change is positive for much of that period.

    While this in flates Theil s

    u ,

    it does not necessarily imply large RMS Es, since the pro por -

    tional difference between P, and A , is never very large.

    Downloadedby[UniversityofAuckland

    Library]at20:2014Febru

    ary2015