bubble economics and structural change: the cases of …ftp.iza.org/dp8942.pdf · bubble economics...

28
DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES Forschungsinstitut zur Zukunft der Arbeit Institute for the Study of Labor Bubble Economics and Structural Change: The Cases of Spain and France Compared IZA DP No. 8942 March 2015 Pablo Agnese Jana Hromcová

Upload: trinhmien

Post on 24-Jul-2019

213 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

DI

SC

US

SI

ON

P

AP

ER

S

ER

IE

S

Forschungsinstitut zur Zukunft der ArbeitInstitute for the Study of Labor

Bubble Economics and Structural Change:The Cases of Spain and France Compared

IZA DP No. 8942

March 2015

Pablo AgneseJana Hromcová

Bubble Economics and Structural Change: The Cases of Spain and France Compared

Pablo Agnese FH Düsseldorf

and IZA

Jana Hromcová Universitat Autònoma de Barcelona

Discussion Paper No. 8942 March 2015

IZA

P.O. Box 7240 53072 Bonn

Germany

Phone: +49-228-3894-0 Fax: +49-228-3894-180

E-mail: [email protected]

Any opinions expressed here are those of the author(s) and not those of IZA. Research published in this series may include views on policy, but the institute itself takes no institutional policy positions. The IZA research network is committed to the IZA Guiding Principles of Research Integrity. The Institute for the Study of Labor (IZA) in Bonn is a local and virtual international research center and a place of communication between science, politics and business. IZA is an independent nonprofit organization supported by Deutsche Post Foundation. The center is associated with the University of Bonn and offers a stimulating research environment through its international network, workshops and conferences, data service, project support, research visits and doctoral program. IZA engages in (i) original and internationally competitive research in all fields of labor economics, (ii) development of policy concepts, and (iii) dissemination of research results and concepts to the interested public. IZA Discussion Papers often represent preliminary work and are circulated to encourage discussion. Citation of such a paper should account for its provisional character. A revised version may be available directly from the author.

IZA Discussion Paper No. 8942 March 2015

ABSTRACT

Bubble Economics and Structural Change: The Cases of Spain and France Compared*

This paper delves into the recent events that led to the formation of the housing bubble in Spain and the resulting structural change that is arguably needed to put the economy back into the right track. For this purpose we calibrate a model with different equilibria descriptive of the labor markets in Spain and France, where the unemployment rates went from the same initial spot to very different levels. In addition to this, we run two counterfactual analyses that throw some more light on the performance of the Spanish labor market and the Spanish housing bubble. Our results suggest that the unemployment rate in Spain has jumped to much higher levels while switching between equilibria or, what is the same, because of structural change. Moreover, our counterfactuals indicate that, first, the Spanish flexibilization reform has fallen short of its own goals and, second, there has been an important misdirection of resources into the construction industry mainly fueled by excessively low real interest rates. JEL Classification: J64, O57 Keywords: structural change, bubble, unemployment, interest rate, productivity Corresponding author: Pablo Agnese FH Düsseldorf Department of Business Studies Universitätsstraße Geb. 23.32 40225 Düsseldorf Germany E-mail: [email protected]

* Financial support from the Spanish Ministry of Education and Science through grant ECO2012- 37572 is gratefully acknowledged.

1 Introduction

In this paper we aim at �nding a possible answer to the structural change that took

place in Spain in recent years, as particularly manifested by the sharp increase in the

unemployment rate to all-time record levels. Spain, unlike many other countries in the

EU, embarked, through its banking sector, in a lending spree fueled by the ECB�s lax

monetary policy that ended up in the housing bubble and the subsequent deep recession.

For this we calibrate a model that allows for di¤erent types of equilibria descriptive of

both Spain and France, the latter used as a benchmark country. We complement this

analysis with two counterfactual exercises that throw some more light on the Spanish

labor market and the making of its housing bubble. As it will become evident in the

next pages our paper will go beyond the theoretical framework and will rely, when

possible, on the available data.

Recent developments and growth �gures in Spain and France stand in stark con-

trast.1 While Spain is currently �ghting its way out of a severe and long-lasting reces-

sion, apparently with positive results that indicate a clear change in the trend, France,

on the other hand, is slowing down and even grinding to a halt. But this is just the tip

of the iceberg. Prior to these new events, however, Spain had to undo (and still has to)

much of its previous wrongdoings while aiming its guns on a di¤erent target. Indeed,

austerity measures were joined by a clear consensus that the construction industry could

no longer be the economy�s main driver.

Our contribution in this paper o¤ers a possible answer to what brought these two

countries to their current state of economic a¤airs and the diverging paths undertaken

in both cases. What we contend is that Spain, unlike France, has had to undergo (and

still has) a deep structural change in its productive model� or a switch between di¤erent

equilibria as it will become clear later. This took place basically out of the necessity

to move away from the construction industry and into other more highly value-added

activities.2 The "brick sector", as has been dubbed in Spain, was hailed as the chicken

of the golden eggs during most of the early 2000s. However, as credit became scarce

and investors and construction companies began to pull out of the sector, the economy

started on a downhill slide that was aggravated by the international crisis of 2007�08

and that made the unemployment rate hit new records� 26% in 2013 along with more

than 50% youth unemployment.

On the onset of the current crisis both countries were positioned on the same spot in

terms of unemployment. By 2006 both unemployment rates stood at virtually the same

1See Figure 1 and Table 1 below, as well as Figures 3 through 7 in the next section.2Such preference has been called out from di¤erent quarters lately, see among many, the OECD

Economic Surveys for Spain (2005, 2014), the OECD Report (2007) on competitiveness and the valuechain, the IMF multi-authored Working Paper on competitiveness in the Southern Euro Area, and theMcKinsey&Company�Fedea Growth Agenda for Spain (2010).

2

level, 8.5% according to the OECD Economic Outlook (2014). But the similarities end

right there. Higher GDP growth rates in Spain prior to the crisis were fueled by the

housing bubble which was in turn sparked by the very low interest rate policy of the

European Central Bank. Notice that this "arti�cial" growth brought the unemployment

rate down from "normal" to unprecedented low levels, equaling that of France in 2006.

We say unprecedented because the natural or equilibrium rate of unemployment in

Spain has been estimated to be around 14�20% in the years preceding the bubble (see

Estrada et al. 2000, or Mc Morrow and Roeger, 2000). We argue that the sudden

increase of the unemployment rate during and after the crisis was mainly due to a

substantial reallocation of resources. This was the natural consequence of putting all

eggs in one basket. In other words, once the need for a change in the Spanish productive

model became noticeable, it also became self-evident that the transition process towards

another kind of economy was not going to be an easy walk.

The reason we focus so eagerly on the Spanish economy responds to what we think is

a major structural change and, as a result, a change in the direction from previous years.

France will only be used as a reference for comparison purposes, mainly to highlight

the notable changes that took place recently in its next-door neighbor. It must be

noted that France, unlike Spain, has not diverted as many resources to the construction

industry during the pre-crisis years and, thus, has not experimented a swift change in

its macroeconomic fundamentals.

Figure 1 shows a clear break in the Spanish macro data before and after the crisis

in 2007.3 GDP growth took a deep plunge with the sudden halt of activity in the

construction industry while the unemployment rate rose to record highs at levels not

seen since the middle 1980s and 1990s. For its part, France remained very much stable

in comparison with clear signs of stagnation in more recent years.

Figure 1: Economic performance compared

(a) GDP growth (%) (b) Unemployment rate (%)

­4

­2

0

2

4

6

2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 2014

FranceSpain

Spain switches equilibrium

4

8

12

16

20

24

28

2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 2014

FranceSpain

Spain switches equilibrium

Source: Based on OECD Economic Outlook 96 (2014); 2014 data are projections.

3Appendix A exhibits all the data sources used in this study.

3

Table 1 highlights the economic performance of both countries in recent years and

also shows the OECD forecasts for the coming few years. According to the data it

seems that, in both cases, recovery is well under way. We remain, however, a bit

skeptical about the prospect and instead focus alone on the evident change of trend in

the Spanish economy. The year 2014 has been labeled as an in�ection point towards

the right economic path,4 as GDP growth went from negative 1.2 to positive 1.3 and

the unemployment rate dropped almost 2 p.p. from a still high 26%.5

Table 1: Economic performance, recent years

2012 2013 2014 2015 2016

(a) GDP growth (%)

France 0.367 0.384 0.371 0.764 1.452

Spain -2.089 -1.230 1.290 1.742 1.947

(b) Unemployment rate (%)

France 9.39 9.85 9.86 10.15 10.05

Spain 24.78 26.09 24.47 23.05 21.93

Source: OECD Economic Outlook 96 (2014); 2014, 2015, 2016 data are projections.

To come to grips with this reversion of the Spanish economy we make use of the equi-

librium and welfare analysis as discussed in Albrecht and Vroman (2002) and Davidson

et al. (2008). Albrecht and Vroman (2002) present a matching model with endogenous

skill requirements where employers create both high and low-skill vacancies, and where

it is also assumed that a low-skill job can be done by either type of worker yet high-skill

jobs can only be �lled by high-skill workers. The model suggests that low-skill workers

are generally better o¤ the greater the fraction of low-skill vacancies while the opposite

is true for high-skill workers. Likewise, �rms with low-skill requirements are generally

better o¤ the greater the fraction of low-skill job candidates.

Two equilibria are possible: cross-skill matching (CSM) and ex-post segmentation

(EPS). The equilibrium is of the CSM type when high-skill workers and low-skill vacan-

cies are matched, and EPS when these potential matches do not meet (e.g. high-skill

workers only work in high-skill jobs). Changing the model�s parameters can yield three

scenarios: (i) a CSM-CSM change; (ii) a CSM�EPS switch; and (iii) an EPS�EPS

change. As it will become clear later, only (ii) will be of relevance for us. We argue

that this �switch�between equilibria can be satisfactorily used to explain the structural

4See the Banco de España Annual Report (2013) for a comprehensive study on the change of coursein the Spanish economy.

5Indeed, the projected OECD 2014 �gures have been recently supported by the INE (SpanishStatistical O¢ ce) and stand at 1.4% for GDP growth and 24.45% for unemployment. French yearly�gures for 2014 by the INSEE (French Statistical O¢ ce) were not available by the time of writing thispaper.

4

change taking place in Spain during the crisis years, especially as related to the housing

bubble and the misallocation of resources that resulted from it.

2 Feeding the monkey: The Spanish bubble

Delving into the numbers of the Spanish construction and housing industries might get

us closer to the truth about the recent structural change� or switch between equilibria

to use a more technical term. A smaller economy than its bigger European partners�

with almost only half the population of Germany and three quarters the population of

countries like Italy, France, or the UK� Spain boasted as many as double the workers in

the construction sector as in Germany in 2007, right at the peak of the bubble. Table 2

shows the evolution of construction jobs in major European economies up to the critical

2007 year mark.

But what put Spain in this awkward position? What made for the pro�igacy in

the construction industry, which is clearly re�ected in the excessive number of jobs

prior to the 2007 crunch? A more than possible yet usually overlooked hypothesis is

that of the booms and busts cycles as laid out by the Austrian School, and recently

discussed by Calvo (2013) in a non-technical paper that goes over the anatomy of crises.

In setting interest rates too low for too long by way of a monetary expansion, central

banks arguably pave the way for higher asset and real estate prices and, eventually, for

overall in�ation.6 Following with this reasoning, it is contended that extremely low real

interest rates might divert resources into activities that would not have been targeted

otherwise (e.g. housing). In other words, that due to the arti�cially low cost of credit

resources can be badly allocated, turning the situation into an arti�cial boom� what

Austrians label malinvestment.

Table 2: Construction jobs pre-crisis, Spain in context

2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007

Spain 2,189,274 2,310,524 2,455,722 2,657,643 2,797,500 2,880,513

Germany 1,824,337 1,697,818 1,623,974 1,515,465 1,498,760 1,521,752

Italy 1,574,979 1,705,742 1,748,373 1,809,834 1,844,895 1,964,195

France 1,470,596 1,494,723 1,547,648 1,538,128 1,651,546 na

United Kingdom 1,307,459 1,322,636 1,347,409 1,392,009 1,393,461 na

Source: EUROSTAT and INE (2015).

6For early references on the Austrian School in relation to booms and busts cycles and monetaryexpansion see, most notably, Mises (1912) and Hayek (1931); for other more up-to-date references notnecessarily in line with the Austrians see, for example, Bordo and Landon-Lane (2013) and the onescited in Calvo (2013).

5

Even when it is not our intention here to analyze this claim further, we think it

provides with a clear and more than reasonable motivation for the structural break

the Spanish economy is currently undergoing. Figure 2 illustrates this �break�to some

extent: mortgages and construction jobs experienced a remarkable growth during the

pre-crisis period which was accompanied with negative real interest rates in most of the

years. This process is now being reverted to some degree after the de�ationary forces

have set in and have brought interest rates to a higher level. This, however, is not devoid

of serious consequences as spiralling increases in house prices have been combined with

increases in home ownership during the bubble years (see Garriga, 2010)� which, in

turn, plays against those facing mortgage obligations under the new higher interest

rate scenario. Both the long-term interest on Spanish government bonds and the 12-

month Euribor display similar patterns, which were again driven down to very low levels

during 2012�2014 (shown in Figure 3) due to further monetary expansion by the ECB

in the face of these "de�ationary threats".7 ;8

Figure 2: Housing bubble in Spain

Sources: Based on OECD Economic Outlook 96 (2014), Spanish Ministry of Development

and INE (2015), and Bank of Spain (2015).

Figure 3 clearly shows the sharp increase� from extremely low levels� of real interest

rates in Spain after 2007 in comparison to those in France. Notice too the recent drop

in both countries as a result of the loose European monetary policy. It is hardly

questionable that these exceptionally low rates have not contributed, at least in part,

7Euribor-12m, for example, is the interest rate most commonly used to calculate mortgage paymentsin Spain, where mortgages are usually of the variable rate type and are calculated as Euribor + X%with X anything between 0.75% and 2%.

8Correlation between the interest rates, on the one hand, and construction jobs or mortgages onthe other, is strongly negative as clearly inferred from the �gure.

6

to give shape to the housing bubble in Spain. We cannot assess the magnitude of this

phenomenon here, and it is not our goal; rather, we propose a fairly simple setting to

rationalize the structural change in the Spanish economy in terms of a switch between

equilibria.

Figure 3: Real interest rates compared

(a) Long-term government bonds (%) (b) Euribor-12m (%)

­1

0

1

2

3

4

5

6

2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 2014

FranceSpain

­2

­1

0

1

2

3

4

2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 2014

FranceSpain

Source: Based on OECD Economic Outlook 96 (2014) and Bank of Spain (2015).

A second point worth stressing is the meager productivity growth registered in Spain

prior to 2007. Figures 4a and 4b show the di¤erent patterns for both Spain and France

for the pre and post-crisis years. As widely known in the literature, Spain features what

has been commonly referred to as a two-tier labor market (see Bentolila et al., 2012a

and 2012b, for recent references). Such markets are usually characterized by strong

insider�outsider mechanisms where �insiders�can command relatively higher wages and

virtually lifetime employment at the expense of their fellow �outsiders�workers, who

remain poorly paid and with limited productivity gains due to the temporary character

of their contracts (see Lindbeck and Snower, 1988, in general, and Bentolila et al.,

2012b, for the Spanish case).

Spanish productivity growth was remarkably low during 2000�2007 as seen in Figure

4a while it looked much healthier once economic restructuring and the stripping down

of the construction industry began in later years. Figure 4b shows a clear recovery in

this category despite the signs of slowing down after 2012, in coincidence with further

monetary expansion and lower real interest rates. How else should we interpret the

economic growth prior to 2007 in Spain (Figure 1a) but as a result of a misdirection of

resources as revealed by low productivity growth (Figure 4a) and the resulting housing

bubble?

7

Figure 4: Labor productivity compared

(a) Growth rate, pre-crisis (%) (b) Growth rate, post-crisis (%)

­0.5

0.0

0.5

1.0

1.5

2.0

2.5

2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007

FranceSpain

­2

­1

0

1

2

3

4

2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014

FranceSpain

Source: Based on OECD Economic Outlook 96 (2014).

Another unambiguous indication of the Spanish economy being out-of-step before

2007 is given by the evolution of the unit labor costs� which can be de�ned as the

average cost of labor per unit of output. Figure 5a presupposes a real disconnect

between workers� compensations and labor productivity for too many years during

�bubble times�. Figure 5b instead reverses the previous trend as productivity growth is

now catching up with previous wage hikes.

Figure 5: Unit labor costs compared

(a) Growth rate, pre-crisis (%) (b) Growth rate, post-crisis (%)

0

1

2

3

4

5

2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007

FranceSpain

­4

­2

0

2

4

6

8

2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014

FranceSpain

Source: Based on OECD Economic Outlook 96 (2014).

Figure 6 throws more light on the major distortion within the Spanish economy.

The output gap, de�ned as the deviation of actual GDP from potential GDP, as a

percentage of potential GDP, was signi�cantly high in Spain prior to the crisis. The

potential gross domestic product is de�ned by the OECD�s Economic Outlook as the

level of output that an economy can produce at a constant in�ation rate. Producing

more than the potential level of output, as was the case of Spain before the crisis, comes

at the cost of rising in�ation, as was also the case there.9 The numbers were reversed to9China, too, has recently shown clear signs of overheating, with a housing overstock running up in

the millions, a GDP growth that hasn�t fallen below 7% in the last two decades, and rising commodityprices (especially of food).

8

negative levels in recent years and respond to the adjustment or structural change the

economy is now being undergoing; that is, partly to the de�ationary forces now being

at work.

Figure 6: Output gaps compared

­8

­6

­4

­2

0

2

4

6

2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 2014

FranceSpain

Sources: Based on OECD Economic Outlook 96 (2014).

Note: Output gap is de�ned as percent of potential GDP.

A �nal word must be said on employment before concluding this section. As ex-

plained earlier, Spain experienced several years of signi�cant growth prior to the crisis

along with low productivity rates (Figures 1a and 4a). During that same period total

employment in Spain rose by about 5 million workers� or, what is the same, an unheard

average annual rate of more than 4% for 2000�2007 (Figure 7a). With the burst of the

bubble in 2007 more than 3 million jobs were destroyed at an approximate average

rate of 2.4% in 2008�2014, reverting the previous positive trend. Self-employment� a

traditional component of the construction industry� showed a similar pattern (Figure

7b), �rst by going up by roughly 200,000 jobs and then by falling for a longer distance.

Figure 7: Employment trends compared

(a) Total employed, workers (b) Total self-employed, workers

14,000,000

16,000,000

18,000,000

20,000,000

22,000,000

24,000,000

26,000,000

2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 2014

FranceSpain

2,200,000

2,300,000

2,400,000

2,500,000

2,600,000

2,700,000

2,800,000

2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 2014

FranceSpain

Source: Based on OECD Economic Outlook 96 (2014).

9

The structural change taking place in Spain in recent years can be seen as the natural

correction of several years of diverting resources into highly unproductive activities.

Such unproductive activities (e.g. the housing boom) have been encouraged, we believe,

by a combination of EU and Spanish local policies, to wit: �rst, a very loose monetary

policy that, for many years, has been feeding the monkey of �malinvestment�by making

credit extremely cheap and easy to get; and second, a set of stringent labor market

policies that have a¤ected the already immobile Spanish labor force.

3 Model

We brie�y sum up the model in Albrecht and Vroman (2002) we use for our analysis.

It is an in�nite horizon model with many risk-neutral workers with discount rate r who

di¤er in their skills� an exogenous fraction q is low-skill, L; and 1 � q are high-skill,H: Firms are of measure one, they place vacancies at the exogenous cost c and decide

endogenously whether to operate with low or high-skill technology. Thus a fraction

� of vacancies is low-skill and a fraction 1 � � is high-skill. A high-skill worker is

allowed to take both types of jobs whereas a low-skill worker can only �ll a vacancy

that corresponds to his type. Wages are determined in the Nash bargaining process

assigning the wage wL (wH) to a worker of type L (H) working in a job of type L (H),

and wL(H) to a worker of type H working in a job of type L with wH > wL(H) > wL:

If a worker is unemployed he is entitled to the unemployment bene�t b and any worker

can refuse the job if his reservation wage is not met. Moreover, jobs are lost at an

exogenous rate �.

In the described setup two types of equilibria may be realized: the equilibrium with

cross-skill matching (CSM) and the equilibrium with ex-post segmentation (EPS). CSM

occurs when high-skill workers and low-skill vacancies match, and EPS takes place when

these potential matches do not meet, i.e. high-skill workers only work in high-skill jobs.

The type of equilibria achieved depends on the expectations of high-skill workers about

the labor market and their willingness to accept a low-skill job.

Firms and workers meet according to a matching technologyM(u; v) = 2puv where

u represents unemployed workers (unemployment rate) and v vacancies. In this process

an endogenously determined fraction of unemployed workers will be low-skill. Fur-

thermore, arrival of jobs to workers happens at a rate M(u;v)u; arrival of workers to

employers at a rate M(u;v)v; and market tightness is de�ned as � = v

u. We can write

the job arrival rate to workers as m(�) = 2p� and workers�arrival rate to �rms as

z(�) = 2p�. If the match succeeds, the worker gets a wage wi; i = L; L(H); H; with an

expected lifetime utility Wi from earning the wage wi: Any type of worker employed in

a low-skill �rm produces yL; and a high-skill worker�s production in a high technology

10

�rm produces yH : Notice that high-skill �rms are more productive than low-skill �rms,

yH > yL, and that the �rms�pro�ts depend on the level of output and the incurred

costs, namely, wages and searching. Pro�ts are de�ned as yL�wL�c and yL�wL(H)�cin the case that a low-skill �rm employs a low and high-skill worker, respectively, and

yH �wH � c in the case that a high-skill �rm employs a high-skill worker. We also havethat a �rm�s expected discounted pro�ts are Ji; i = L; L(H); H. Figure 8 sketches the

matches, wages, and output obtained under the two equilibria.

Figure 8: Possible matches between workers and �rms

If the agreement between a worker and a �rm is not achieved, the worker�s income

corresponds to the unemployment bene�t b and his lifetime expected utility is Uj; j = L;

H: In such a case, the �rm ends up with an un�lled vacancy of value Vj; j = L; H:

We thus have that Wi stands for the value of working and Uj for the value of unem-

ployment, while Ji stands for the value of the job and Vj for the value of the vacancy

for the corresponding type. There is something to bargain over if the worker obtains

a positive surplus when working WH � UH > 0; WL(H) � UH > 0 and WL � UL > 0;and when the �rm gets positive surplus by hiring the worker, i.e. JH �VH > 0; JL(H)�VL > 0 and JL � VL > 0: Wages are then chosen to maximize the weighted worker�s

and �rm�s surpluses, (WH � UH)� (JH � VH)1�� ;�WL(H) � UH

�� �JL(H) � VL

�1��and

(WL � UL)� (JL � VL)1�� ; respectively, where � represents the worker�s bargaining power.Firms enter the market as long as the value of opening a vacancy is non-negative. Once

many �rms enter the market the value of the vacancy hits zero and the process stops�

thus VL = 0 and VH = 0 hold in all periods.

11

Workers may experience spells of employment and unemployment. When the �ow

of workers into and out of each employment state coincide the steady-state equilibrium

is achieved. Previously employed workers of each type who lose their jobs coincide with

the number of unemployed workers that �nd the job

�EL = �m(�) (q � EL) ; (1)

�EH = m(�) (1� q � EH) (2)

where EL denotes employed low-skill workers EL = q � u; and EH denotes employedhigh-skill workers EH = 1� q� (1� )u: Like Albrech and Vroman (2002) we concen-trate on the steady state equilibrium results. More details on the equilibrium equations

can be found in Appendix B.

4 Results

To make sense of the model above and better understand the housing bubble and struc-

tural change that has recently taken place in Spain we propose three di¤erent exercises.

First, we calibrate the model with real data for France and Spain as these two coun-

tries�performances, especially in terms of unemployment, stand in stark contrast during

the recent crisis period. We suggest various possibilities concerning the parameters and

equilibria as to make sense of the countries�diverging unemployment rates.10 Second,

we carry out a �rst counterfactual experiment focusing on the unemployment rate in

Spain and highlighting the e¤ects of the mild �exibilization reform undertaken in recent

years. And third, we propose a second counterfactual experiment with an eye on the

interest rate and the making of the Spanish bubble.

One hard piece of evidence worth noting is that both unemployment rates went from

8.5% in 2006 to very di¤erent plateaus in 2013 at the peak of the recession� 9.9% in

France and 26.1% in Spain. This is quite a leap indeed for Spain and deserves some

thought. We can summarize our analysis below by arguing, �rst, that a change in

the productivity di¤erential in the calibrated model can lead to a change of equilibria

in Spain as to render the economy quite out of balance (e.g. the burst of bubble

and the ensuing skyrocketing unemployment); second, that the existing labor market

institutions in Spain are not suitable to deal with the unemployment problem and,

moreover, that in the Spanish experience they might have proved highly detrimental as

the economy switched between equilibria; and third, that the housing bubble was, in

all probability, behind the structural change in Spain.

10Bentolila et al. (2012a) develop a parallel analysis for France and Spain with quarterly data yetwith a focus on the transition between equilibria.

12

4.1 Calibration

We adapt and calibrate Albrecht and Vroman (2002) to �t France�s and Spain�s experi-

ences in 2000�2013. We use the following baseline parameters: the bargaining power of

workers is the same as that of the �rms, � = 0:5; the productivity of low-skill workers

is yL = 1 whereas that of high-skill is, depending on the case, either yH = 1:05 or

yH = 1:2� that is, we let both economies start from di¤erent gaps, one rather trivial

and the other not so; moreover, the two countries di¤er in parameters that character-

ize the skill composition of workers and the labor market characteristics� the low-skill

share of workers is set to the average value of q in 2000 and 2011 (the only two peri-

ods available) as qESP = 0:54 and qFRA = 0:33; the jobs last on average 10 years in

Spain and 11.7 in France, thus �ESP = 0:1 and �FRA = 0:085; unemployment bene�ts

represent about 60% of previous wages in both countries� having in mind this value

we set b to represent about 60% of average wages;11 agents discount the future at rates

rESP = 0:35% and rFRA = 1:2%, as these correspond to the averages in 2000�2013;12

and �nally, the vacancy cost is set to generate the target level of unemployment as to

mirror the values found in the data between 2000�2013.

In order to rationalize the bubble episode in Spain and the resulting structural

change, we will allow for a widening of the productivity gap once we have our baseline

calibrations done. These baseline calibrations involve two particular cases, namely:

the small (5%) and big (20%) productivity gap cases discussed below. Our goal is

to see how the model behaves in terms of how close we are to the unemployment

rates in Spain and France as derived from the real data. These two extreme cases are

useful to see the e¤ects in both economies with a certain margin of discretion, with

special focus on the Spanish bubble, since bubbles are not unambiguously accounted

for in the literature. Ventura (2002), for instance, claims that "bubbles tend to appear

and expand in countries where productivity is low relative to the rest of the world",

something which is not far from the story presented above for Spain (see, especially,

Figure 4a). Other, like Miao and Wang (2012), purport that the collapse of bubbles

leads to a recession and a fall in productivity levels� this, in part, was true for Spain

yet productivity showed strong signs of recovery (see Figure 4b above).

11We de�ne average wage under both types of equilibria as follows

�wCSM =EL

EL + EHwL +

EHEL + EH

�wL(H) +EH

EL + EH(1� �)wH ;

�wEPS =EL

EL + EH�wL +

EHEL + EH

wH :

12As discount rate we take the average for Euribor-12 since this is, we believe, closely related to thehousing bubble in Spain.

13

4.1.1 Spain vs. France: Case 1 (small gap)

We �rst analyze the case where the gap between low and high-skill workers�productiv-

ities is relatively small� for this we take a 5% gap. The values given to the parameters

in both economies are shown in Table 3 below. Moreover, the level of unemployment

bene�ts is set to be roughly 60% of average wages.

Table 3: Small productivity gap, baseline parameters

yL yH b c r q � �

Spain 1 1.05 0.30 0.50 0.0035 0.54 0.5 0.100

France 1 1.05 0.35 0.45 0.0118 0.33 0.5 0.085

For this set of parameters both economies start with a CSM equilibrium and with

approximately the same rate of unemployment, 8.5%, just to simulate the situation

in 2006. However, as soon as we allow for a wider productivity gap things turn out

di¤erently: whereas France immediately switches to an EPS equilibrium Spain stays

with the CSM for a bit longer. Under these conditions, when the productivity of

low-skill workers is allowed to go down, the rate of unemployment increases in both

countries and, besides, when Spain gets into the EPS equilibrium it is at a consistently

high unemployment rate. In other words, when Spain switches between equilibria there

seems to be a "jump" of the unemployment rate (e.g. structural change). We plot the

steady state relationship between yL and u for both countries in Figure 9.

We can also observe that the unemployment rate is less sensitive to changes in yLin France or, what is the same, that there was no structural change there. The end of

the lines to the right represent the collapse of the labor market in both countries, which

happens when yL is very low and u very high, and when �! 0, which happens when no

more low-skill jobs are o¤ered as the productivity of low-skill workers is too low to entice

�rms into hiring them. This would take place at the same productivity di¤erential in

both countries (approximately 19%) yet at a higher hypothetical unemployment rate

in Spain. Finally, in order to generate the peak in the unemployment rate of Spain, or

uESP � 0:26, the reduction in the productivity of low-skill workers should be of about15%. Notice that while the transition between equilibria is smooth in France it is more

like a "jump" for Spain. Moreover, France will be perhaps less prone to a CSM as there

is only one possible value for this to happen and many for the EPS, among which there

is also the possibility that both equilibria coexist (at a 5% gap). In addition to this,

and as commented at the start of this paragraph, France does not seem to need a jump

or structural change, according to our calibrations, to move into the more e¢ cient EPS

result. Hence, assuming that France is, and has for long been, in an EPS is not far

from reality.

14

Figure 9: Spain vs. France, small productivity gap

4.1.2 Spain vs. France: Case 2 (big gap)

Our second case depicts the more realistic event of a wider productivity di¤erential

between low and high-skill workers. We here set yH = 1:2 and yL = 1, a 20% produc-

tivity gap. Notice that the parameters used for this calibration shown in Table 4 below

slightly di¤er from those above, mainly due to the fact that we want to guarantee that

bene�ts are roughly 60% of average wages in both countries.

Table 4: Big productivity gap, baseline parameters

yL yH b c r q � �

Spain 1 1.20 0.32 0.50 0.0035 0.54 0.5 0.100

France 1 1.20 0.40 0.40 0.0118 0.33 0.5 0.085

For this set of parameters both France and Spain start in an EPS equilibrium�

the CSM equilibrium does not exist. Allowing for a 20% gap now suggests that, in

order to achieve the peaks in the unemployment rates in recent years, uESP � 0:26 anduFRA � 0:10; the drop in productivity should be of about 13% in Spain and almost

negligible in France. Figure 10 plots the new sets of equilibrium combinations between

yL and u. This is consistent with �ndings in Bentolila et al. (2012a) that the impact of

the recession in Spain was more deeply felt. Again, the end of the lines to the right (low

yL; high u) represent the collapse of the labor market as low-skill vacancies approach

zero. Notice that the Spanish labor market would collapse "earlier" and at a much

higher unemployment rate due to a smaller fraction of high-skill workers.

15

Figure 10: Spain vs. France, big productivity gap

4.2 Counterfactuals I: The Spanish labor market

We now proceed with our �rst set of counterfactuals, as we believe it will further our

understanding about the performance of the Spanish labor market after the recent �ex-

ibilization reforms. Our strategy goes as follows: we �rst derive an estimable equation

for unemployment from our model above; then we estimate the equation using the

available data; and last, we use the estimated model to obtain the contribution of the

�exibilization variable to the change of the unemployment rate during the recent years.

This contribution is computed through a dynamic simulation of the estimated model

as follows: we �rst �x the exogenous variable at the level of certain arbitrary year, then

we solve the model, and �nally we retrieve the new path of the unemployment rate. For

us, the simulation�s initial year roughly corresponds with the beginning of the global

crisis in Europe� we take 2007 as this year coincides with the lowest of unemployment

in our period of analysis.

It can be demonstrated that the unemployment rate is given by the following general

expression13

u = f (�; q; c; b; r; �; yL; )

where unemployment is dependent on �, the rate at which jobs are lost, q, the

share of low-skill workers, c, vacancy costs (more broadly interpreted here as �market

�exibility�), b, the unemployment bene�t, r, the rate at which agents discount the

future, � the bargaining power of workers, yL, the productivity of low-skill workers,

13The unemployment rate as derived from the model above is non-linear and quite burdensome forestimation purposes. The formal derivation is available on request but we will stick to the linearizedversion as this does not pose a serious drawback for our analysis.

16

and , the fraction of low-skill unemployment.

Table 5 shows the results of the estimation for a dynamic, linearized, and much

abridged version of the unemployment equation above. We can see that the estimated

equation does not display all the variables alluded to in the de�nition because of miss-

ing data. We will focus on c as this coe¢ cient is somewhat descriptive of the labor

market situation. For this we use an index on the strictness of employment protection

(OECD)� notice that such coe¢ cient is highly signi�cant (5%).

Further note that the interest rate is found to be signi�cant, possibly due to the

relatively high degree of credit dependency and the overly in�ated construction and

housing industries, as stated before. Moreover, the productivity coe¢ cient py� de�ned

here as labor productivity� can be ambiguous since the relationship between u and py

can be driven by other factors. Consequently, we should be careful with the interpreta-

tion of our results as these can be a¤ected by endogeneity.14 A dummy variable d07 for

the crisis years is also entertained (=1 in 2007�2013 and =0 otherwise). We will now

take a brief look at the simulation results.

Table 5: Unemployment equation, OLS

Dependent variable: utSpain, 1991�2013:

coe¢ cient

cnt: -6.76 [0:002]

ut�1 0.40 [0:025]

ln ct 0.07 [0:035]

ln pyt 0.62 [0:003]

d07t 0.02 [0:034]

rt 0.53 [0:042]

r2 0.952

s:e: 0.011

n 23

Note: p�values in brackets.

Figure 11 shows how our single-equation estimation tracks the changes of the unem-

ployment rate during 1991�2013. The gray shaded zone zooms in the recent recession

years and goes from 2007, the lowest for the whole period, up to 2013. We now use

the estimated model to calculate the contribution of the �exibilization variable c to the

change of the unemployment rate in 2007 through 2013.

14Introducing py in the unemployment equation answers the necessity of accounting for yL, yet theformer is a measure of aggregate productivity and the other the productivity of low-skill workers alone.

17

Figure 11: Unemployment rate (%)

4

8

12

16

20

24

28

1992 1996 2000 2004 2008 2012

Actual Fitted

We �x c to the simulation�s starting year, 2007, and solve the model accordingly.

Once we do this we are able to recover the new (simulated) path of the unemployment

rate. Figure 12 is very revealing on the �what ifs�regarding the policy measures related

to c and labor market performance in general. Figure 12 (a) shows the path of the

unemployment rate had the employment protection indicator remained at the level of

2007 (in red), along with the actual trajectory (in blue). As shown there, �exibilization

has contributed to a reduction of the unemployment rate of approximately 1.1 p.p..

Unlike a comparative statics exercise our simulation here takes account of the dynamics

occurring within the subsample 2007�2013, and therefore the �nal e¤ect on u is the

result of this summation of e¤ects� even when this is only seen from 2010 onwards,

when the �rst steps were taken in the direction of labor �exibilization. Figure 12 (b)

exhibits both the evolution of this variable as well as its simulated path �xed at 2007.

According to our analysis here the Spanish �exibilization reform has thus fallen short

of achieving a real improvement of the current conditions.

Figure 12: Labor �exibility and unemployment in Spain

(a) Unemployment rate (%) (b) Strictness indicator (0=�exible to 6=tight)

8

12

16

20

24

28

2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013

Actual trajectory

Simulated (employment protection,indicator kept at 2007­­10 value)

8.3

26.4

27.5

2.04

2.08

2.12

2.16

2.20

2.24

2.28

2.32

2.36

2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013

Actual trajectory

Fixed at 20082.35

2.04

18

4.3 Counterfactuals II: The Spanish bubble

We undertake a separate yet similar counterfactual exercise in this section to throw some

light on the role played by interest rates in the building-up of the Spanish bubble during

the early years of the current century. As before, we follow the same methodological

procedure regarding estimation and simulations, with the exception that we now have

no theoretical derivation of the estimable equation. Moreover, our database at this

point is rather limited and we should remain on the conservative side when reading

through our simulations.

Table 6 shows two similar regressions, with the share of construction jobs on total

employment being regressed upon the real interest rate and the output gap. Panel (a)

on the left has the euribor-12 as a regressor whereas panel (b) on the right has the rate

on government bonds. Both coe¢ cients are highly signi�cant and negatively signed,

something which is clearly consistent with the story related earlier� that is, very low

interest rates are a major driver behind the malinvestment and redirection of resources

into the in�ated construction industry.

In addition to the interest rate, the output gap is included as a regressor to highlight

the overheating of the Spanish economy. Signi�cant and positive coe¢ cients in both

equations are suggestive of a positive correlation between �going beyond the means�

and the housing bubble. In other words, this variable accounts for factors leading to the

housing bubble and the increase of construction employment other than those brought

about by very low interest rates.

Table 6: Construction jobs share equation, OLS

Dependent variable: st(a) Spain, 2002�2011: (b) Spain, 2002�2011:

coe¢ cient coe¢ cient

cnt: 0.11 [0:000] cnt: 0.13 [0:000]

reur12t -0.76 [0:000] rgovt -0.94 [0:001]

ogapt 0.71 [0:000] ogapt 0.24 [0:091]

r2 0.969 0.950

s:e: 0.004 0.006

n 10 10

Note: p�values in brackets.

Figure 13 exhibits the actual and �tted patterns of the construction employment

share in those key years of the housing bubble. The drop is quite remarkable after 2007

and the �t quite good for both equations in spite of the few observations involved. In

the next few paragraphs we will be using the estimated model to assess the contribution

of the exogenous variables to the drop in the construction share.

19

Figure 13: Construction jobs share

(a) Construction share (%), Euribor equation (b) Construction share (%), Gov. bonds equation

7

8

9

10

11

12

13

14

15

2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011

Actual Fitted

7

8

9

10

11

12

13

14

15

2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011

Actual Fitted

Figure 14 reveals the contributions of the real interest rates in both equations to the

drop in construction employment. In both cases the contribution was far from negligible,

especially for the rate on government bonds. Respectively, these contributions amount

to 1.8 p.p. and 5.1 p.p. for equations in panels (a) and (b).

Figure 14: Contribution of interest rates to the construction share

(a) Construction share (%), Euribor equation (b) Construction share (%), Gov. bonds equation

7

8

9

10

11

12

13

14

15

16

2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011

Actual trajectory

Simulated (euribor­12 kept at 2006 value)14

9

7.2

7

8

9

10

11

12

13

14

15

16

2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011

Actual trajectory

Simulated (gov. bonds rate kept at 2006 value)

14

12.3

7.2

Figure 15 shows the actual and simulated trajectories of the interest rates under

consideration. Notice that, for practical reasons, the simulations had to be run start-

ing in 2006� right during the time when the change in the interest rates was clearly

observed, going from negative in 2006 to positive in 2007 for both rates.

20

Figure 15: Interest rates, actual and simulated

(a) Euribor-12 (%) (b) Gov. bonds rate (%)

­0.5

0.0

0.5

1.0

1.5

2.0

2.5

3.0

2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011

Actual trajectory

Fixed at 2006

1.92

­0.44­1

0

1

2

3

4

5

6

2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011

Actual trajectory

Fixed at 2006

5.34

­0.1

The size of the contributions is switched for the next simulation, where we assess

the e¤ect of economic overheating by way of the output gap on the construction share.

While the output gap for the Euribor equation in panel (a) of Figure 16 shows a

contribution of 5.4 p.p. in the drop of the employment share, the contribution for the

government bonds equations in (b) stands at 1.8 p.p..

Figure 16: Contribution of other factors to the construction share

(a) Construction share (%), Euribor equation (b) Construction share (%), Gov. bonds equation

7

8

9

10

11

12

13

14

15

2007 2008 2009 2010 2011

Actual trajectory

Simulated (output gap kept at 2007 value)

14 12.6

7.2

7

8

9

10

11

12

13

14

15

2007 2008 2009 2010 2011

Actual trajectory

Simulated (output gap kept at 2007 value)

14

9

7.2

Further notice that if we add both contributions in each one of the equations they

roughly add to the total drop in employment� which was approximately of the order

of 7 p.p. between 2006�7 and 2011, as seen in Figure 13 above. These numbers are not

trivial since total employment in Spain went down by 2.2 millions during that period

and the employment in the construction industry shrank by 1.5 millions from almost 3

millions� or a 50% drop. Finally, Figure 17 shows the actual and simulated trajectory

of the output gap for both equations.

21

Figure 17: Output gap, actual and simulated

­4

­3

­2

­1

0

1

2

3

4

5

2007 2008 2009 2010 2011

Actual trajectory

Fixed at 20074.6

­2.99

5 Final remarks

In this paper we have tried to account for the structural change that is currently under-

way in Spain after the burst of the housing bubble of prior years. For this we have made

use of the theoretical framework in Albrecht and Vroman (2002) and have discussed, in

broad terms, the di¤erent possible equilibria that might occur. We have used France as

a yardstick as both countries stood virtually on the same spot at the peak of the bubble

in Spain. This meant an 8.5% of unemployment in 2006 in both countries� something

unheard of until then for the Spanish economy. It is worth noting that at the time of

the bubble high GDP growth rates coincided with very low productivity growth rates,

leading us to reinforce the sense of a strong misallocation of resources and the illusion

of wealth.

Our calibrations seem to point to a signi�cant switch, or rather a "jump", between

equilibria in Spain and not in France. Allowing for a small productivity gap (case 1

above) between high and low-skill workers suggests that, while the French economy

would immediately transition from a CSM to an EPS as soon as the gap becomes wider

and at an stable unemployment rate, the Spanish one would remain at an CSM for

longer just to jump sharply after a while to a higher unemployment plateau. In order to

achieve the peak of the unemployment rate in Spain at uESP � 0:26 the productivity oflow-skill workers must decrease by about 15%. Allowing now for a big productivity gap

(case 2) strengthens our claim that Spain must have necessarily undergone a notable

switch or jump between equilibria as the economy starts now at an EPS and at a

relatively high unemployment rate (14%). Achieving the uESP � 0:26 target requires

now a drop in low-skill productivity of around 13%. All in all, and regardless of the

initial productivity gap in both countries, the Spanish economy necessitates a bigger

gap than France to replicate its actual rate of unemployment� something very much

in line with the idea of strong insider�outsider mechanisms and a conspicuous two-tier

22

labor market in Spain. Arguably, Spain has jumped from a CSM to an EPS in the

post-bubble years while France has either smoothly transitioned from one to the other

(case 1) or, more likely, has always been at an EPS (case 2).

To complement our previous analysis we have carried out two sets of counterfactuals

exercises descriptive of the Spanish labor market and of the Spanish bubble episode. The

�rst results are indicative of a move in the good direction by the Spanish government,

which has however fallen short of achieving a major change for the better� �exibilization

has brought Spanish unemployment down but there is still a long way to go. The

second results stress the misdirection of resources into the construction industry that

were mainly fueled by very low (even negative) real interest rates for the most part of

the last decade. We get to explain the whole change in the construction jobs share by

way of the real interest rate and the output gap� the latter being broadly identi�ed

with additional factors pointing in the direction of economic overheating.

References

[1] Albrecht, James and Vroman, Susan, 2002. A Matching Model with Endogenous

Skill Requirements, International Economic Review 43 (1), 283�305.

[2] Banco de España, 2014. Annual Report 2013, Madrid, ISSN: 1579 - 8623 (online

edition).

[3] Bentolila, Samuel, Cahuc, Pierre, Dolado, Juan J., and Le Barbanchon, Thomas,

2012a. Two-Tier Labour Markets in the Great Recession: France Versus Spain,

The Economic Journal 122 (562), 155�187.

[4] Bentolila, Samuel, Dolado, Juan J., and Jimeno, Juan F., 2012b. Reforming an

insider-outsider labor market: The Spanish experience, IZA Journal of European

Labor Studies 1:4.

[5] Bordo, Michael D. and Landon-Lane, John, 2013. Does Expansionary Monetary

Policy Cause Asset Price Booms: Some Historical and Empirical Evidence, NBER

Working Paper No. 19585.

[6] Calvo, Guillermo, 2013. Puzzling over the Anatomy of Crises: Liquidity and the

Veil of Finance, Bank of Japan IMES Discussion Paper 13-E-09.

[7] Davidson, Carl, Matusz, J. Steven, and Shevchenko, Andrei, 2008. Outsourcing

Peter to pay Paul: High-skill Expectations and Low-skill Wages with Imperfect

Labor Markets, Macroeconomic Dynamics 12 (4), 463�479.

23

[8] Estrada, Angel, Hernando, Ignacio and López-Salido, J. David, 2000. Measuring

the NAIRU in the Spanish Economy, Banco de España Working Papers #0009.

[9] Garriga, Carlos, 2010. The role of construction in the housing boom and bust in

Spain. FEDEA Working Papers 2010-09.

[10] Hayek, Friedrich A. von, 1931, reprint 2008. Prices and Production and Other

Works OnMoney, the Business Cycle, and the Gold Standard, Auburn, AL: Ludwig

von Mises Institute.

[11] IMF (various authors), 2008. Competitiveness in the Southern Euro Area: France,

Greece, Italy, Portugal, and Spain, IMF WP 08/112.

[12] Lindbeck, Assar and Snower, Dennis, 1988. The Insider-Outsider Theory of Em-

ployment and Unemployment, MIT Press.

[13] McKinsey&Company�Fedea (various authors), 2010. A Growth Agenda for Spain.

[14] Mc Morrow, Kieran and Roeger, W., 2000. Time-Varying NAIRU/NAWRU Esti-

mates for the EU�s Member States, ECFIN Economic Paper No. 145.

[15] Miao, Jianjun, and Wang, Pengfei, 2012. Bubbles and Total Factor Productivity,

American Economic Review 102 (3), 82�87.

[16] Mises, Ludwig von, 1912, reprint 1981. The Theory of Money and Credit, Indi-

anapolis, IN: Liberty Fund.

[17] OECD Economic Surveys Spain (various authors), 2005, 2014. ISSN 0376-6438.

[18] OECD Report (various authors), 2007. Staying Competitive in the Global Econ-

omy: Moving Up the Value Chain, OECD Publishing ISBN 9264034250.

[19] Ventura, Jaume, 2002. Bubbles and Capital Flows, NBER Working Papers 9304.

24

A Appendix: Data sources

Table A: Data sources

Real GDP growth (%) OECD Economic Outlook 96 (2014).

Unemployment rate (%) OECD Economic Outlook 96 (2014).

Construction jobs EUROSTAT and INE (2015).

Mortgages INE (2015).

Real long-term interest on gov. bonds (%) OECD Economic Outlook 96 (2014).

Real Euribor�12 months (%) Bank of Spain (2015).

Labor productivity, growth rate (%) OECD Economic Outlook 96 (2014).

Unit labor costs, growth rate (%) OECD Economic Outlook 96 (2014).

Output gap (%) OECD Economic Outlook 96 (2014).

Total and self-employment data OECD Economic Outlook 96 (2014).

Note: Both real interest rates de�ated by gross domestic product de�ator, market prices (OECD).

B Appendix: CMS and EPS equations

We outline all the equations that must hold in CSM and EPS equilibria.

Cross-skill matching equilibrium:Bellman equations of employed workers are

rWL = wL � �(WL � UL); (3)

rWL(H) = wL(H) � ��WL(H) � UH

�; (4)

rWH = wH � �(WH � UH): (5)

Bellman equations that characterize the unemployed workers are

rUL = b+ �m(�) (WL � UL) ; (6)

rUH = b+m(�)[�WL(H) + (1� �)WH � UH ]: (7)

Bellman equations for the active �rms are

rJL = (yL � wL � c)� � (JL � VL) ; (8)

rJL(H) =�yL(H) � wL(H) � c

�� �[JL(H) � VL]; (9)

rJH = (yH � wH � c)� � (JH � VH) : (10)

25

Corresponding equations for inactive �rms are

rVL = �c+ z(�)� JL + (1� )JL(H) � VL

�; (11)

rVH = �c+ z(�)(1� ) (JH � VH) : (12)

Wages are set in the Nash bargaining process as

wL = �(yL � c) + (1� �)rUL; (13)

wL(H) = �(yL � c) + (1� �)rUH ; (14)

wH = �(yH � c) + (1� �)rUH : (15)

Zero vacancy conditions, VL = VH = 0, (1) and (2) must also hold. Cross-skill matching

equilibrium will exist if

yL � c > rUH : (16)

Ex-post segmentation equilibrium:Bellman equations that characterize the employed workers are (3) and (5), corre-

sponding equations for unemployed workers are (6) and

rUH = b+ (1� �)m(�) (WH � UH) : (17)

Bellman equations for the active �rms are (8) and (10), and for the inactive �rms are

rVL = �c+ z(�) (JL � VL) (18)

and (12).15 Zero vacancy conditions, VL = VH = 0, (1) and (2) must also hold. The

condition for the existence of the EPS equilibrium implies that high-skill workers are

matching only with high-skill jobs

yL � c � rUH : (19)

15Notice that equations (17) and (18) now imply that high-skill unemployed workers will only takehigh-skill jobs and low-skill �rms will ony hire low-skill workers.

26