competitive nonlinear pricing for signals

44
Introduction Model Monopoly Duopoly Conclusion Competitive Nonlinear Pricing for Signals Zhuoran Lu School of Management, Fudan University April 12, 2019

Upload: others

Post on 27-Jan-2022

5 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Competitive Nonlinear Pricing for Signals

Introduction Model Monopoly Duopoly Conclusion

Competitive Nonlinear Pricing for Signals

Zhuoran Lu

School of Management, Fudan University

April 12, 2019

Page 2: Competitive Nonlinear Pricing for Signals

Introduction Model Monopoly Duopoly Conclusion

Motivation

In many vertical markets, signaling cost can be manipulated

I Education: the tuition scheme is chosen by the university.

I Luxury good: the price schedule is chosen by the retailer.

I Advertising: the tariff is chosen by the media company.

Lu (2018) studies monopolistic nonlinear pricing for signals

I Monopolistic seller with type-independent participation.

I Price transparency leads to higher price and lower quantity.

This paper studies competitive nonlinear pricing for signals

I Solves the optimal pricing for different market structures.

I Assesses the effects of pricing transparency on signaling.

Page 3: Competitive Nonlinear Pricing for Signals

Introduction Model Monopoly Duopoly Conclusion

Overview

ModelI Sellers choose price schedules for a good with intrinsic value.

I Buyer chooses how much to purchase as a signal to receivers.

I Buyer has a two-dimensional preference over the good.

In the monopoly case

I If receivers observe prices, there is either downward distortionin allocation, or full efficiency under some certain conditions.

I If receivers do not observe prices, allocation is more dispersed.

In the duopoly case

I Competition between sellers results in larger quantities ofsignals and higher market coverage than under monopoly.

Page 4: Competitive Nonlinear Pricing for Signals

Introduction Model Monopoly Duopoly Conclusion

Literature

Classic signaling and screening models

I Spence (1973), Mussa & Rosen (1978), Maskin & Riley (1984).

Monopolistic nonlinear pricing for signals

I Rayo (2013), Lu (2018).

Competitive nonlinear pricing for non-signals

I Gilbert & Matutes (1993), Villas-Boas & Schmidt-Mohr (1999),

Armstrong & Vickers (2001), Rochet & Stole (2002), Ellison

(2005), Yang & Ye (2008), Ye & Zhang (2017).

Multi-dimensional screening models

I McAfee & McMillan (1988), Armstrong (1996), Rochet & Chone

(1998), Armstrong & Rochet (1999), Thanassoulis (2004).

Page 5: Competitive Nonlinear Pricing for Signals

Introduction Model Monopoly Duopoly Conclusion

Model

Page 6: Competitive Nonlinear Pricing for Signals

Introduction Model Monopoly Duopoly Conclusion

Model

Players and actions

I Two schools post tuition schemes Ti(z), i = 1, 2.

I A worker has a two-dimensional preference over education:

Vertical type θ ∼ U [0, 1]; horizontal type di ∼ U [0, 12 ].

I Worker chooses at most one school to attend;

Obtains productivity Q(z, θ) = γθz + z, where γ > 0.

I A competitive labor market posts wages Wi(z), i = 1, 2.

InformationI Worker’s type (θ, {di}) is privately known.

I Worker’s education choice (i, z) is publicly observed.

I In the observed case, employers observe both Ti(z).

I In the unobserved case, employers observe neither of Ti(z).

Page 7: Competitive Nonlinear Pricing for Signals

Introduction Model Monopoly Duopoly Conclusion

Worker (𝜃, 𝑑1)

School 1

School 2

𝑑1

𝑑2

A Duopoly Education Market

Page 8: Competitive Nonlinear Pricing for Signals

Introduction Model Monopoly Duopoly Conclusion

Payoffs

I School i’s expected profit Πi = E[Ti(z(θ))].

I Worker’s gross utility by attending school i

Vi(z, θ) = Wi(z)− Ti(z)− C(z, θ),

where C(z, θ) = z2/2 + (1− θ)z is the effort cost.

I Worker obtains zero utility if purchases no education.

I Surplus: S(z, θ) = (γ + 1)θz − z2/2; zfb(θ) = (γ + 1)θ.

Worker’s problem

I Worker incurs a transport cost kdi ≥ 0 if attends school i.

I Worker chooses i ∈ {∅, 1, 2} and z to maximize net utility

Ui(z, θ, di) = Vi(z, θ)− kdi.

Page 9: Competitive Nonlinear Pricing for Signals

Introduction Model Monopoly Duopoly Conclusion

A Direct Mechanism

Timing

I School i offers a contract {zi(θ), Ti(θ)} to worker.

I Labor market posts Wi(z) based on the observability of offers.

Market belief is correct if Wi(z) = E[Q(z, θ)|zi(θ)].I Worker reports a type θ to only the school he attends.

School i’s problem

I In the observed case, max. Πi s.t. IC, IR and correct belief.

I In the unobserved case, max. Πi s.t. IC and IR.

I Focus on the symmetric school-optimal separating equilibrium.

Page 10: Competitive Nonlinear Pricing for Signals

Introduction Model Monopoly Duopoly Conclusion

Preliminaries

Lemma 1.In both cases, an allocation {z(θ), V (θ)} is IC if

(i) z(θ) is non-decreasing.

(ii) Define θ0 := inf{θ|z(θ) > 0}, then for all θ > θ0,

V (θ) = V (θ0) +

∫ θ

θ0

−Cθ(z(s), s)ds = V (θ0) +

∫ θ

θ0

z(s)ds.

Market shareI School i’s market share for type θ is twice

si(θ) := min

{Vi(θ)

k,1

4+Vi(θ)− V−i(θ)

2k

}.

I The market segment switching type θ1 is given by

V1(θ1) + V2(θ1) =k

2.

Page 11: Competitive Nonlinear Pricing for Signals

Introduction Model Monopoly Duopoly Conclusion

A Bertrand-Spence Benchmark

I Suppose k = 0, Bertrand competition leads to Ti(z) ≡ 0.

I The model is translated to a Spence’s signaling game.

I In the least-cost separating equilibrium, education levels are

zs(θ) = (2γ + 1)θ ≥ (γ + 1)θ = zfb(θ).

I Define the signaling intensity as

zs(θ)− zfb(θ)zfb(θ)

γ + 1.

I The greater γ is, the more intense signaling activity is.

Page 12: Competitive Nonlinear Pricing for Signals

Introduction Model Monopoly Duopoly Conclusion

Over-Investment in Education

0 0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6 0.7 0.8 0.9 1

0

0.6

1.2

1.8

2.4

3

Assumption: γ = 1 and k = 0

Page 13: Competitive Nonlinear Pricing for Signals

Introduction Model Monopoly Duopoly Conclusion

Monopoly

Page 14: Competitive Nonlinear Pricing for Signals

Introduction Model Monopoly Duopoly Conclusion

The Observed Case

I A monopolist maximizes the joint profit of both schools.

Monopolist’s problem

I The monopolist solves

maxz(θ)

∫ θ1

θ0

[S(z, θ)− V (θ)]V (θ)

kdθ︸ ︷︷ ︸

Phase I: partially covered range

+

∫ 1

θ1

[S(z, θ)− V (θ)]1

4dθ︸ ︷︷ ︸

Phase II: fully covered range

s.t. V ′(θ) = z(θ), z′(θ) ≥ 0, V (θ1) =k

4.

I If θ0 ∈ (0, 1], then V (θ0) = 0; otherwise, V (θ0) is free.

Page 15: Competitive Nonlinear Pricing for Signals

Introduction Model Monopoly Duopoly Conclusion

Solving Monopolist’s Problem

I Define the Hamiltonian for each phase as

Phase I: H1 = [S(z, θ)− V (θ)]V (θ)

k+ λz.

Phase II: H2 = [S(z, θ)− V (θ)]1

4+ λz.

I Applying the Maximum Principle, for each phase j = 1, 2,

∂Hj

∂z= 0 and λ(θ) = −∂Hj

∂Vwith λ(1) = 0.

I Solving Phase I yields an ODE

(γ + 3)V − V V − V 2

2= 0. (1)

I Solving Phase II yields z(θ) = (γ + 2)θ − 1 for θ ∈ [θ1, 1].

Page 16: Competitive Nonlinear Pricing for Signals

Introduction Model Monopoly Duopoly Conclusion

Determining cutoff types

I Suppose θ0 > 0, then from (1), for θ ∈ [θ0, θ1),

V (θ) =γ + 3

4(θ − θ0)2, z(θ) =

γ + 3

2(θ − θ0).

I Applying smooth pasting,

θ0 =1

γ + 2− γ + 1

2(γ + 2)

√k

γ + 3, (2)

θ1 =1

γ + 2+

γ + 3

2(γ + 2)

√k

γ + 3. (3)

I Thus, θ0 > 0 if k < 4(γ+3)(γ+1)2

; θ1 < 1 if k < 4(γ+1)2

(γ+3) .

I If θ0 > 0 and θ1 = 1, then θ0 is given by λ(1) = 0.

Page 17: Competitive Nonlinear Pricing for Signals

Introduction Model Monopoly Duopoly Conclusion

Optimal Contract — Low Signaling Intensity

Proposition 1.

When γ ≤ 1, equilibrium exists. The optimal contract satisfies:

I For k ∈(

0, 4(γ+1)2

(γ+3)

],

zmo(θ) =

{γ+32 (θ − θmo

0 ) if θmo0 ≤ θ < θmo

1

(γ + 2)θ − 1 if θmo1 ≤ θ ≤ 1,

where θmo0 and θmo

1 are given by (2) and (3), respectively.

I For k > 4(γ+1)2

(γ+3) ,

zmo(θ) =γ + 3

2

(θ − θmo

0

)if θmo

0 ≤ θ ≤ 1.

where θmo0 = 1−γ

γ+3 ≥ 0.

Page 18: Competitive Nonlinear Pricing for Signals

Introduction Model Monopoly Duopoly Conclusion

Welfare Implications

Corollary 1.

I When γ < 1, θmo0 > 0 and zmo(θ) < zfb(θ) on [0, 1).

I When γ = 1 and k ≥ 4(γ+1)2

(γ+3) , zmo(θ) = zfb(θ) on [0, 1].

IdeaI Signaling can mitigate screening distortion (Lu 2018).

I Market penetration also induces higher education supply.

I When γ = 1 and k is big, the two forces offset screening.

Page 19: Competitive Nonlinear Pricing for Signals

Introduction Model Monopoly Duopoly Conclusion

Signaling Intensity and Horizontal Differentiation

(a) γ = 0.5 and k = 1

0 0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6 0.7 0.8 0.9 1

0

0.3

0.6

0.9

1.2

1.5

(b) γ = 0.5 and k = 4

0 0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6 0.7 0.8 0.9 1

0

0.3

0.6

0.9

1.2

1.5

Page 20: Competitive Nonlinear Pricing for Signals

Introduction Model Monopoly Duopoly Conclusion

Signaling Intensity and Horizontal Differentiation

(a) γ = 1 and k = 1

0 0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6 0.7 0.8 0.9 1

0

0.4

0.8

1.2

1.6

2

(b) γ = 1 and k = 4

0 0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6 0.7 0.8 0.9 1

0

0.4

0.8

1.2

1.6

2

Page 21: Competitive Nonlinear Pricing for Signals

Introduction Model Monopoly Duopoly Conclusion

Optimal Contract — High Signaling Intensity

Vertical market is partially covered

I When γ > 1, if k ≤ 4(γ+3)(γ+1)2

, θmo0 ≥ 0 and θmo

1 < 1.

I The optimal contract is characterized by Proposition 1.

Vertical market is fully covered

I When γ > 1, if k > 4(γ+3)(γ+1)2

, θmo0 = 0, meaning λ(0) = 0.

I Solving Phase I is equivalent to solving the program

(γ + 3)V − V V − V 2

2= 0.

s.t. V (0) = 0, V (θ1) =k

4, V (θ1) = (γ + 2)θ1 − 1.

I Solving Phase II follows exactly the previous steps.

Page 22: Competitive Nonlinear Pricing for Signals

Introduction Model Monopoly Duopoly Conclusion

Optimal Contract — High Signaling Intensity

Proposition 2.

When γ > 1, equilibrium exists. The optimal contract satisfies:

I For k ∈(

0, 4(γ+3)(γ+1)2

],

zmo(θ) =

{γ+32 (θ − θmo

0 ) if θmo0 ≤ θ < θmo

1

(γ + 2)θ − 1 if θmo1 ≤ θ ≤ 1,

where θmo0 and θmo

1 are given by (2) and (3), respectively.

I For k > 4(γ+1)2

(γ+3) ,

zmo(θ) =

{γ+32 θ if 0 ≤ θ < θmo

1

(γ + 2)θ − 1 if θmo1 ≤ θ ≤ 1,

where θmo1 =

√kγ+3 .

Page 23: Competitive Nonlinear Pricing for Signals

Introduction Model Monopoly Duopoly Conclusion

Signaling Intensity and Horizontal Differentiation

(a) γ = 1.5 and k = 1

0 0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6 0.7 0.8 0.9 1

0

0.5

1

1.5

2

2.5

(b) γ = 1.5 and k = 4

0 0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6 0.7 0.8 0.9 1

0

0.5

1

1.5

2

2.5

Page 24: Competitive Nonlinear Pricing for Signals

Introduction Model Monopoly Duopoly Conclusion

The Effects of Horizontal Differentiation

Corollary 2.

For k < k := min{

4(γ+1)2

(γ+3) ,4(γ+3)(γ+1)2

}, as k increases:

(i) V mo(θ) increases on (θmo0 , 1].

(ii) zmo(θ) increases on (θmo0 , θmo

1 ]; remains the same on (θmo1 , 1].

(iii) The market coverage [θmo0 , 1] extends, but [θmo

1 , 1] shrinks.

IdeaI Monopolist provides more rents to gain market share.

I This can be achieved by more education or larger coverage.

I The optimal allocation requires a balance between these two.

Page 25: Competitive Nonlinear Pricing for Signals

Introduction Model Monopoly Duopoly Conclusion

The Unobserved Case

Monopolist’s problem

I Given W (z), the monopolist solves

maxz(θ)

∫ θ1

θ0

[W (z)− C(z, θ)− V (θ)]V (θ)

kdθ︸ ︷︷ ︸

Phase I: partially covered range

+

∫ 1

θ1

[W (z)− C(z, θ)− V (θ)]1

4dθ︸ ︷︷ ︸

Phase II: fully covered range

s.t. V ′(θ) = z(θ), z′(θ) ≥ 0, V (θ1) =k

4.

I If θ0 ∈ (0, 1], then V (θ0) = 0; otherwise, V (θ0) is free.

I In equilibrium, W (z) = E[Q(z, θ)|z(θ)] using Bayes’ rule.

Page 26: Competitive Nonlinear Pricing for Signals

Introduction Model Monopoly Duopoly Conclusion

Solving Monopolist’s Problem

I Define the Hamiltonian for each phase as

Phase I: H1 ≡ [W (z)− C(z, θ)− V (θ)]V (θ)

k+ λz.

Phase II: H2 ≡ [W (z)− C(z, θ)− V (θ)]1

4+ λz.

I In equilibrium, W ′(z) = Qz(z, θ) +Qθ(z, θ) · θ′(z).

I Solving Phase I yields an ODE

(2γ + 3)V − γV V...V

V 2− V V +

γV 2

V− V 2

2= 0. (4)

I Solving Phase II with the desired initial condition yields

W (z) =γ

2(γ + 1)z2 +

2(γ + 1)

γ + 2z.

I This implies that z(θ) = 2(γ + 1)(θ − 1γ+2) for θ ∈ [θ1, 1].

Page 27: Competitive Nonlinear Pricing for Signals

Introduction Model Monopoly Duopoly Conclusion

Determining cutoff types

I Suppose θ0 > 0, then from (4), for θ ∈ [θ0, θ1),

V (θ) =4γ + 3

4(θ − θ0)2, z(θ) =

4γ + 3

2(θ − θ0).

I Applying smooth pasting,

θ0 =1

γ + 2− 1

4(γ + 1)

√k

4γ + 3, (5)

θ1 =1

γ + 2+

4γ + 3

4(γ + 1)

√k

4γ + 3. (6)

I Thus, θ0 > 0 if k < 16(γ+1)2(4γ+3)(γ+2)2

; θ1 < 1 if k < 16(γ+1)4

(4γ+3)(γ+2)2.

I If θ0 > 0 and θ1 = 1, then θ0 is given by λ(1) = 0.

Page 28: Competitive Nonlinear Pricing for Signals

Introduction Model Monopoly Duopoly Conclusion

Optimal Contract

Proposition 3.

For all γ > 0, equilibrium exists. The optimal contract satisfies:

I For k ∈(

0, 16(γ+1)4

(4γ+3)(γ+2)2

],

zmu(θ) =

4γ+32 (θ − θmu

0 ) if θmu0 ≤ θ < θmu

1

2(γ + 1)(θ − 1γ+2) if θmu

1 ≤ θ ≤ 1,

where θmu0 and θmu

1 are given by (5) and (6), respectively.

I For k > 16(γ+1)4

(4γ+3)(γ+2)2,

zmu(θ) =4γ + 3

2(θ − θmu

0 ) if θmu0 ≤ θ ≤ 1.

where θmu0 = 1

2γ+3 .

Page 29: Competitive Nonlinear Pricing for Signals

Introduction Model Monopoly Duopoly Conclusion

Education Levels are More Dispersed

Proposition 4.

(i) For all γ, k > 0, θmu0 > θmo

0 and θmu1 < θmo

1 .

(ii) There is a cutoff θ ∈ (θmu0 , θmu

1 ), such that zmu(θ) < zmo(θ)on (θmo

0 , θ); zmu(θ) > zmo(θ) on (θ, 1]. The length of theinterval (θmo

0 , θ) is increasing in k, and vanishes as k → 0.

IdeaI Education demand is more elastic due to signal jamming.

I Monopolist supplies more education in fully covered range.

I But it is not as profitable in partially covered range due to IC.

Page 30: Competitive Nonlinear Pricing for Signals

Introduction Model Monopoly Duopoly Conclusion

Comparison of Education Levels

(a) γ = 1, k = 0.5

0 0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6 0.7 0.8 0.9 1

0.00

0.53

1.07

1.60

2.13

2.67

(b) γ = 1, k = 2

0 0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6 0.7 0.8 0.9 1

0.00

0.53

1.07

1.60

2.13

2.67

Page 31: Competitive Nonlinear Pricing for Signals

Introduction Model Monopoly Duopoly Conclusion

Consumer Surplus and Tuition

Proposition 5.

(i) There is a cutoff θ ∈ (θmu0 , 1), such that V mu(θ) < V mo(θ)

on (θmo0 , θ); V mu(θ) > V mo(θ) on (θ, 1]. The length of the

interval (θmo0 , θ) is increasing in k, and vanishes as k → 0.

(ii) There is a cutoff z ∈ (0, zfb(1)), such that Tmu(z) > Tmo(z)on (0, z); Tmu(z) > Tmo(z) on (z, zfb(1)]. The length of theinterval (0, z) is increasing in k, and vanishes as k → 0.

Implication

I A lower-type who is close to either school benefits more fromthe increase in horizontal differentiation in the observed case.

Page 32: Competitive Nonlinear Pricing for Signals

Introduction Model Monopoly Duopoly Conclusion

Duopoly

Page 33: Competitive Nonlinear Pricing for Signals

Introduction Model Monopoly Duopoly Conclusion

The Observed Case

I From now on, assume that k < k so that θmo0 > 0.

School’s problem

I Given the other school’s contract, school i solves

maxzi(θ)

∫ θ1

θ0

[S(z, θ)− Vi(θ)]Vi(θ)

kdθ︸ ︷︷ ︸

Phase I: local monopoly range

+

∫ 1

θ1

[S(z, θ)− Vi(θ)][

1

4+Vi(θ)− V−i(θ)

2k

]dθ︸ ︷︷ ︸

Phase II: competition range

s.t. V ′(θ) = z(θ), z′(θ) ≥ 0, V (θ1) =k

4.

I If θ0 ∈ (0, 1], then Vi(θ0) = 0; otherwise, Vi(θ0) is free.

Page 34: Competitive Nonlinear Pricing for Signals

Introduction Model Monopoly Duopoly Conclusion

Solving School’s Problem

I Define the Hamiltonian for each phase as

Phase I: H1 = [S(z, θ)− Vi(θ)]Vi(θ)

k+ λz.

Phase II: H2 = [S(z, θ)− Vi(θ)][

1

4+Vi(θ)− V−i(θ)

2k

]+ λz.

I Solving Phase I follows exactly the same steps of monopoly.

I Solving Phase II is equivalent to solving the program

V = γ + 2− 2

k

[(γ + 1)θV − V − V 2

2

](7)

s.t. V (θ1) =k

4, V (θ1) =

√(γ + 3)k

2, V (1) = γ + 1.

Page 35: Competitive Nonlinear Pricing for Signals

Introduction Model Monopoly Duopoly Conclusion

Optimal Contract

Proposition 6.

In the observed case, the duopoly optimal contract satisfies:

zdo(θ) =

{γ+32 (θ − θdo0 ) if θdo0 ≤ θ < θdo1V do(θ) if θdo1 ≤ θ ≤ 1,

where V do(θ) and θdo1 are given by (7), and θdo0 = θdo1 −√

kγ+3 .

Equilibrium Discontinuity

I Equilibrium is discontinuous at k = 0.

I It is always optimal to exclude sufficiently low types if k > 0.

Page 36: Competitive Nonlinear Pricing for Signals

Introduction Model Monopoly Duopoly Conclusion

Education Levels and Market Coverage

Proposition 7.

If k < k, then θdo0 < θmo0 and zdo(θ) > zmo(θ) for θ ∈ (θdo0 , 1). In

contrast to the monopoly case, more worker types (in terms ofboth vertical and horizontal type) receive education, and eachparticipating type obtains higher net utility.

IdeaI Competition leads to more education in competition range.

I This relaxes IC, thus lower types also receive more education.

Page 37: Competitive Nonlinear Pricing for Signals

Introduction Model Monopoly Duopoly Conclusion

The Effects of Competition on Education Levels

(a) γ = 1 and k = 1.5

0 0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6 0.7 0.8 0.9 1

0

0.4

0.8

1.2

1.6

2

(b) γ = 1 and k = 3

0 0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6 0.7 0.8 0.9 1

0

0.4

0.8

1.2

1.6

2

Page 38: Competitive Nonlinear Pricing for Signals

Introduction Model Monopoly Duopoly Conclusion

The Effects of Competition on Market Coverage

(a) γ = 1 and k = 1.5

0 0.05 0.1 0.15 0.2 0.25

0.1

0.2

0.3

0.4

0.5

0.6

0.7

0.8

0.9

1

covered market segment

uncovered market segment

(b) γ = 1 and k = 3

0 0.05 0.1 0.15 0.2 0.250

0.1

0.2

0.3

0.4

0.5

0.6

0.7

0.8

0.9

1

covered market segment

uncovered market segment

Page 39: Competitive Nonlinear Pricing for Signals

Introduction Model Monopoly Duopoly Conclusion

The Unobserved Case

School’s problem

I Given W (z) and the other school’s contract, school i solves

maxzi(θ)

∫ θ1

θ0

[W (z)− C(z, θ)− Vi(θ)]Vi(θ)

kdθ︸ ︷︷ ︸

Phase I: local monopoly range

+

∫ 1

θ1

[W (z)− C(z, θ)− Vi(θ)][

1

4+Vi(θ)− V−i(θ)

2k

]dθ︸ ︷︷ ︸

Phase I: competition range

s.t. V ′(θ) = z(θ), z′(θ) ≥ 0, V (θ1) =k

4.

I If θ0 ∈ (0, 1], then Vi(θ0) = 0; otherwise, Vi(θ0) is free.

I In equilibrium, W (z) = E[Q(z, θ)|z(θ)] using Bayes’ rule.

Page 40: Competitive Nonlinear Pricing for Signals

Introduction Model Monopoly Duopoly Conclusion

Solving School’s Problem

I Define the Hamiltonian for each phase as

Phase I: H1 = [W (z)− C(z, θ)− Vi(θ)]Vi(θ)

k+ λz.

Phase II: H2 = [W (z)− C(z, θ)− Vi(θ)][

1

4+Vi(θ)− V−i(θ)

2k

]+ λz.

I Solving Phase I follows exactly the same steps of monopoly.

I Solving Phase II is equivalent to solving the program

...V =

V 2

γV

2(γ + 1)− 2

k

[(γ + 1)θV − V − V 2

2

] (8)

s.t. V (θ1) =k

4, V (θ1) =

√(4γ + 3)k

2,V (1)[V (1)− γ]

V (1)= γ + 1.

Page 41: Competitive Nonlinear Pricing for Signals

Introduction Model Monopoly Duopoly Conclusion

Optimal Contract

Proposition 8.

In the unobserved case, the duopoly optimal contract satisfies:

zdu(θ) =

{4γ+32 (θ − θdu0 ) if θdu0 ≤ θ < θdu1

V du(θ) if θdu1 ≤ θ ≤ 1,

where V du(θ) and θdu1 are given by (8), and θdu0 = θdu1 −√

k4γ+3 .

Equilibrium Discontinuity

I Equilibrium is discontinuous at k = 0.

I It is always optimal to exclude sufficiently low types if k > 0.

Page 42: Competitive Nonlinear Pricing for Signals

Introduction Model Monopoly Duopoly Conclusion

The Effects of Competition on Education Levels

(a) γ = 1 and k = 3.5

0 0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6 0.7 0.8 0.9 1

0.00

0.58

1.16

1.75

2.33

2.91

(b) γ = 1 and k = 3.8

0 0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6 0.7 0.8 0.9 1

0.00

0.57

1.14

1.70

2.27

2.84

Page 43: Competitive Nonlinear Pricing for Signals

Introduction Model Monopoly Duopoly Conclusion

The Effects of Competition on Market Coverage

(a) γ = 1 and k = 3.5

0 0.05 0.1 0.15 0.2 0.250

0.1

0.2

0.3

0.4

0.5

0.6

0.7

0.8

0.9

1

covered market segment

uncovered market segment

(b) γ = 1 and k = 3.8

0 0.05 0.1 0.15 0.2 0.250

0.1

0.2

0.3

0.4

0.5

0.6

0.7

0.8

0.9

1

covered market segment

uncovered market segment

Page 44: Competitive Nonlinear Pricing for Signals

Introduction Model Monopoly Duopoly Conclusion

Summary

In this paper

I We studied competitive nonlinear pricing for signals.

I We solved the optimal pricing for different market structures.

Main resultsI In the monopoly observed case, there is either downward

distortion in quantity, or full efficiency, depending on thedegrees of signaling intensity and horizontal differentiation.

I In the monopoly unobserved case, signal quantities are moredispersed due to signal jamming and market penetration.

I Market competition results in a higher market coverage andlarger quantities for both the observed and unobserved case.