corporate venture capital and incumbent firm innovation rates

33
Corporate Venture Capital and Incumbent Firm Innovation Rates Gary Dushnitsky Stern School of Business New York University 44 West 4th St. Suite 750 New York, NY 10012 Tel: (212) 998-0283 Fax: (212) 995-4235 [email protected] Michael J. Lenox Stern School of Business New York University 40 West 4th St. Suite 717 New York, NY 10012 Tel: (212) 998-0261 Fax: (212) 995-4235 [email protected] Draft: March 1 st , 2002 Working Paper. Please do not quote or cite without authors’ permission. 2002 G. Dushnitsky & M. Lenox

Upload: freddy56

Post on 20-Aug-2015

1.061 views

Category:

Economy & Finance


4 download

TRANSCRIPT

Corporate Venture Capital and Incumbent Firm Innovation Rates

Gary Dushnitsky Stern School of Business

New York University 44 West 4th St. Suite 750

New York, NY 10012 Tel: (212) 998-0283 Fax: (212) 995-4235

[email protected]

Michael J. Lenox Stern School of Business

New York University 40 West 4th St. Suite 717

New York, NY 10012 Tel: (212) 998-0261 Fax: (212) 995-4235

[email protected]

Draft: March 1st, 2002

Working Paper. Please do not quote or cite without authors’ permission.

2002 G. Dushnitsky & M. Lenox

2002 G. Dushnitsky & M. Lenox 1

Corporate Venture Capital and Incumbent Firm Innovation Rates

Abstract

In this paper, we focus on the potential strategic benefits to corporate venture capital, i.e.

equity investments in entrepreneurial ventures by incumbent firms. In particular, we ask do

firms that invest corporate venture capital learn about and appropriate new technologies and

practices from those ventures they invest? Our investigation builds on two theoretical pillars.

First, that incumbent firms operating in competitive markets are inclined towards introducing

innovations. Second, that the knowledge necessary to generate innovation may likely reside

outside the boundary of the incumbent firm and in entrepreneurial ventures. Thus, we propose

that corporate venture capital programs may be instrumental in harvesting innovations from

entrepreneurial ventures and thus an important part of a firm’s overall innovation strategy. To

this end, we directly explore the relationship between corporate venture capital and incumbent

firm innovation by analyzing a large panel of public firms that pursued venturing activity or

patented over a thirty-year period. We find that increases in corporate venture capital

investments are associated with subsequent increases in firm quality patenting. The findings of

this study have important implications for the functioning of corporate venture capital programs

and the ability of firms to innovate in general.

Keywords: corporate venture capital, innovation, knowledge, entrepreneurship

Short Title: Corporate Ventures & Innovation

2002 G. Dushnitsky & M. Lenox 2

Corporate Venture Capital and Incumbent Firm Innovation Rates

At the beginning of this new century, established corporations have become important

players in the venture capital industry. In 2000, more than 400 firms sponsored corporate

venture capital programs that invested close to $16 billion. These investments represent

approximately 15% of all venture capital investments -- a sharp increase from the relatively

meager $20 million invested by corporations in new ventures in 1993 (Venture Economics,

2001). Why are established firms investing in new ventures? Do these firms simply hope to

reap the high financial returns that venture capitalists experienced in the late 1990’s? Or, do

these firms have other strategic reasons for investing in new ventures?

In this paper, we focus on the potential strategic benefits to incumbent firms by investing

corporate venture capital (CVC). We define “corporate venture capital” as any equity investment

in an entrepreneurial venture by an incumbent firm (Gompers & Lerner, 1998). We consider

both investments in independent ventures (Gompers and Lerner, 1998) and investments in

ventures that consist of former employees (Burgelman, 1983; Garud and Van de Ven, 1992). In

particular, we are interested in whether CVC investments result in knowledge spillovers to

incumbent firms. Do firms that invest corporate venture capital learn about and appropriate new

technologies and practices from those ventures they invest? For example, do increases in CVC

investments lead to increases in incumbent firm patenting levels?

Our investigation builds on two theoretical pillars. First, that incumbent firms operating

in competitive markets are inclined towards introducing innovations (Schumpeter, 1942; Arrow,

1962). This is in part because incumbent firms need to innovate constantly in order to sustain

profitability (Roberts, 1999; Hamel, 2000). Second, that the knowledge necessary to generate

innovation may likely reside outside the boundary of the incumbent firm (Arrow, 1974; Cohen &

2002 G. Dushnitsky & M. Lenox 3

Levinthal, 1990). In particular, increases in the relative significance of human-capital (Zingales,

2000) imply that entrepreneurial startups may be a valuable source of such knowledge (Kortum

and Lerner, 2000; Shane, 2001a). Placed together, these two pillars suggest that incumbents may

seek innovation outside their organization and within competent entrepreneurial ventures. We

propose that corporate venture capital programs may be instrumental in harvesting innovations

from entrepreneurial ventures and thus an important part of a firm’s overall innovation strategy.

Previous empirical research on venture capital investments by corporations has focused

primarily on the narrow, financial returns to investing in new ventures. A number of studies

have found that investments in general in related ventures by incumbent firms had a significantly

lower return than investments by venture capitalists (Gompers & Lerner , 1998; Siegel, Siegel &

MacMillan, 1988). The ventures themselves, however, performed equally well when funded by

related incumbent firms or by venture capitalists (Gompers & Lerner , 1998; Sykes, 1990;

Shrader & Simon, 1991; Thornhill & Amit, 2000).

A handful of empirical studies do provide some evidence that corporate venturing activity

results in important strategic benefits to firms (Rind, 1981; Sykes, 1990; Block & MacMillan,

1993; Sorrentino & Williams, 1995; Shrader & Simon, 1997). Unfortunately, these studies rely

on case studies or small sample surveys and focus on either overall firm financial performance or

project-progress measures. None of these studies evaluate the effect of corporate venture capital

on incumbent firm innovation.

In this paper, we directly explore the relationship between corporate venture capital and

incumbent firm innovation. We analyze a large, unbalanced panel of U.S. public firms during

the time period 1969-1999. Of those firms in our dataset, approximately two hundred and fifty

firms engaged at least in some level of CVC investing during the time period. Data is pulled

2002 G. Dushnitsky & M. Lenox 4

from VenturExpert, Compustat, and the U.S. Patent databases. Discrete choice, fixed-effect and

random-effect models are adopted to establish a relationship between CVC investment intensity

and patenting.

Our contribution is in exploring whether increases in CVC investments lead to increases

in incumbent firm patenting levels. We find that increases in CVC investment are associated

with subsequent increases in citation-weighted, firm patenting rates. The findings of this study

have important implications for the functioning of corporate venture capital programs and the

ability of firms to innovate in general. While alternative inter-organizational forms such as

technology alliances have been extensively studied (e.g., Ahuja, 2000; Powell, Koput & Smith-

Doerr 1996), corporate venture capital has been the subject of less formal, empirical analysis.

Moreover, if knowledge spills over to incumbent firms, there are incentives for new ventures to

seek alternative sources of funding such as venture capital. The likely impacts of this on

governance will be the subject of future studies.

Theoretical Background

In his later years (and in contradiction to his earlier writings), Schumpeter (1942)

introduced the view that established firms are most likely to be innovative. According to

Schumpeter, incumbent firms possess the capital and skilled personnel necessary to produce

innovations as well as the complementary assets necessary to appropriate the resultant rents.

Subsequent research postulated that incumbent firms operating in competitive markets are

inclined towards innovating in part because of the need to continuously innovate in order to

sustain profitability (Arrow, 1962; Roberts, 1999; Hamel, 2000). A rich game theoretic literature

2002 G. Dushnitsky & M. Lenox 5

also provides evidence that, under some conditions, incumbent firms are more likely than

potential new entrants to invest in innovation (see Reinganum, 1989 for a review).

Despite this economic inclination to seek innovation by established firms, numerous

researchers have highlighted the organizational limitations of incumbents to generate innovations

internally (Henderson, 1993). The view that incumbent firms face difficulties in generating

ground breaking, radical innovations is well established (Tushman and Anderson, 1986;

Henderson, 1993). Innovation in large part requires the integration of diverse knowledge sets.

To the extent there are constraints on the creation and sharing of knowledge within a single

organization, incumbent firms may find that they lack the knowledge necessary to innovate.

Numerous remedies have been suggested. Incumbent firms may, for example, be able to

overcome their inability to internally generate innovations by exploiting knowledge external to

the firm (Cohen and Levinthal, 1990). This has been the focus of many studies that investigate

the ability to create new knowledge through the recombination of knowledge across

organizational boundaries (Henderson and Cockburn, 1994; Rosenkopf and Nerkar, 2001;

Almeida, Dokko and Rosenkopf, 2001). External knowledge can be accessed and assimilated

through different avenues including regional learning (Saxenian, 1990), recruitment of high-

human capital personnel (Almeida and Kogut, 1999), and strategic alliances (Hagedoorn &

Schakenraad, 1994; Powell, Koput & Smith-Doerr 1996).

In addition to these vehicles, we propose that corporate venture capital may be an

important component of a firm’s innovation strategy. We advance the idea that a transformation

has transpired that has induced incumbents to seek innovation outside their organization and

within competent entrepreneurial ventures. In the later half of the twentieth century, highly

skilled human capital (labor) has become more important in generating innovation than physical

2002 G. Dushnitsky & M. Lenox 6

capital (Zingales, 2000). In this new setting, the property rights literature (Grossman and Hart,

1986) predicts that skilled workers will disassociate themselves from incumbents and form

independent firms. Such disposition towards non-integration explains the proliferation of

ventures headed by independent entrepreneurs. Indeed, Shane (2001a) provides direct empirical

evidence that new venture formation is associated with underlying entrepreneurial inventions

that are technologically radical or that have high economic value. Kortum and Lerner (2000)

support these findings, observing that entrepreneurial, human-capital intensive ventures generate

high levels of patenting output.

Thus, the knowledge necessary to generate innovations may likely reside outside the

boundary of the incumbent firm and within innovative new ventures. Corporate venture capital

may provide a robust avenue to access this knowledge. Indeed, the declared goal of Nokia

Ventures, the CVC program of Nokia, is to “fuel future growth and to boost new product and

long-term business development (Business Wire, 1998).” By investing in a new venture,

incumbent firms may be able to learn about new technologies or practices. With this knowledge,

they may be able to innovate existing products or services or diversify into new lines of business.

CVC investment may allow incumbents to manage threats from potential entrants within their

core businesses especially in the crucial early stages of new technological regimes (Shane,

2001b). Additionally, learning about novel technologies before their rivals increases the

likelihood of identifying future alliance partners or acquisition targets (Ahuja, 2000).

A similar point has been made in the related technology alliances literature. To the extent

that entrepreneurial startups possess valuable knowledge, corporate venture capital may provide

a firm a window onto the operations of portfolio companies that can generate similar advantages

to those associated with having innovative alliance partners. Hagedoorn & Schakenraad (1994)

2002 G. Dushnitsky & M. Lenox 7

and Ahuja (2000) indicate that knowledge from innovative alliance partners may spillover and

positively affect the innovativeness of a firm. Stuart (2000) shows that firms patenting rates

increase the more technologically advanced are its alliance partners. Rothaermal (2001) argues

that incumbent firms that pursue alliance formation with new ventures improve their new

product development when faced with radical technological changes.

CVC investing firms may learn from new ventures in a number of ways. Anecdotal

evidence suggests that incumbent firms institute specific organizational routines to encourage

and funnel learning from the ventures they invest. Sony Corporation created two parallel and

distinct functions responsible for knowledge transfer between its portfolio companies and the

corporation (Venture Capital Investment in Israeli Companies, International Business Forum,

March 27-28, 2001). Sony’s CVC group, Sony Strategic Venture Investments, played the role of

venture-capitalist -- sitting on the venture’s board and helping manage the portfolio company. In

this role, they were exposed to the technologies and practices of the venture. In addition, Sony’s

business divisions established liaisons with the ventures. These liaisons specific goal was to

learn about and source the portfolio company’s technology.

Such organizational practices need not lead to expropriation by the incumbent and harm

to the new venture. The venture may secure entrepreneurial rents from its technology due to a

strong appropriability regime (perhaps because of tight patent protection). Any learning that

takes by the incumbent firm merely opens a window onto new technologies that leads to further

innovation. For example, Ahuja and Lampert (2001) find that experimenting by established

firms with novel, pioneering technologies increases the likelihood that they will create

subsequent breakthrough inventions. By tapping an external source of knowledge – in this case,

2002 G. Dushnitsky & M. Lenox 8

an entrepreneurial venture – a firm will become more innovative. Investments in innovative new

ventures may increase a firm’s absorptive capacity (Cohen & Levinthal, 1990).

Evidence to Date

The empirical evidence of learning from CVC investment is sparse. Previous economic

research on corporate venture capital has focused on the narrow, financial benefits to investing in

new ventures. Gompers & Lerner (1998) in a study of over thirty thousand investments rounds

found that investments in related ventures by incumbent firms had a significantly lower return

than investments by venture capitalists. However, the ventures themselves performed equally

well when funded by related incumbent firms or by venture capitalists. These results did not

hold for incumbent firms who invested in new ventures that were in unrelated businesses. The

findings of the Gompers & Lerner study are consistent with a number of other studies in the

entrepreneurship literature (Siegel et. al., 1988; Sykes, 1990; Block & MacMillan, 1993;

Sorrentino & Williams, 1995; Shrader & Simon, 1997; Thornhill & Amit, 2000).

Other researchers have looked more directly at the strategic benefits of venturing activity.

These studies attempt to explain variation in performance as a function of various corporate

venturing attributes such as the program’s objectives (Block and MacMillan, 1993; Gompers and

Lerner, 1998; Siegel et. al., 1988; Winters and Murfin, 1988); its organizational design (Maula

and Murray, 2000; Winters and Murfin, 1988) and specific characteristics of its relationships

with ventures (Thornhill and Amit, 2000; Siegel et al, 1988; Sorrentino and Williams, 1995;

Sykes, 1990).

Siegel, Siegel, and MacMillan (1988) survey 52 corporate venture programs about their

goals and conduct. They report that corporations rank “exposure to new technologies and

2002 G. Dushnitsky & M. Lenox 9

markets” as the leading objective for engaging in corporate venture capital programs. In a study

of 88 corporate sponsored ventures in the PIMS database, Sorrentino and Williams (1995) report

that relatedness between incumbent firm and the new venture does not explain the latter’s

success. However, they do find that relatedness is increasingly associated with a venture’s

success, the higher the stock of corporate intangible assets. Based on a survey of 97 Canadian

corporate ventures, Thornhill and Amit (2000) identify two distinct dimensions of relatedness:

economic fit and relational fit. They find that while a venture’s success is decreasingly

associated with the level of economic fit, relational fit remains a significant factor throughout a

venture’s life. Consistent with the notion of knowledge spillovers we advance above, relational

fit pertains not only to the contribution made by the corporation to the venture but also to

interdependence and feedback from the venture to the sponsoring corporation.

The research presented in this paper, improves on this literature in a number of ways.

Much of the existing literature relies on case studies or descriptive surveys that cannot control

for a number of competing causal factors such as firm size or industry choice. The few

multivariate analyses conducted have been cross sectional and thus have not been able to address

issues of unobserved heterogeneity and temporal precedence. We make use of extensive archival

data to build a longitudinal dataset that can allow for more sophisticated econometric models.

Finally, existing studies focus on either overall firm financial performance or project-progress

measures of CVC success. None of these studies directly evaluate the effect of corporate

venturing on incumbent firm innovation. We use patenting data to capture the innovative output

of investing firms.

2002 G. Dushnitsky & M. Lenox 10

Data & Method

In our analysis, we explore the relationship between corporate venture capital and

incumbent firm innovation rates. Specifically, we investigate whether increases in CVC

investments lead to increases in firm patenting levels. We adopt patent data as a measure of

innovation to be consistent with the latest studies on technology alliances (Baum, Calabrese and

Silverman, 2000; Stuart, 2000) and entrepreneurship (Ahuja and Lampert, 2001; Almeida,

Dokko and Rosenkopf, 2001).

Sample

To this end, we constructed a large, unbalanced panel of U.S. public firms during the

period 1969-1999. The panel includes all public firms that invested corporate venture capital or

patented during this period. The resulting dataset includes 1,240 firms and 22,496 firm-year

observations. The database contains information on firms’ venturing activity collected from

Venture Economic’s VentureXpert database, patenting activity from the Hall, Jaffe, and

Tratjenberg (2001) dataset derived from the U.S. Patent Office, and financial data from Standard

& Poor’s Compustat database.

To construct our database, we first identified the population of firms engaging in

corporate venturing activity through the VentureXpert database.1 The database contains a

comprehensive coverage of investment, exit, and performance activity in the private equity

industry from 1969 to 1999. We searched the population of all private equity investments for

1 The database is offered by Venture Economics, a division of Thomson Financial. The data are collected

through industry associations (European Venture Capital Association, the National Venture Capital Association, and other key associations in Asia and Australia) and the investment banking community. These data have been used in several academic studies on the venture capital industry (Bygrave 1989; Gompers 1995).

2002 G. Dushnitsky & M. Lenox 11

any investments by firms or their funds.2 This process yielded 1,417 distinct firms that pursued

venturing activity during that time period.3 For these firms, we collected data on the annual

amount of venturing investments (disbursements). Note, these amounts represent the actual

dollar value invested during a given year, and should not be confused with dollars committed to

venturing activity (usually reported in the professional media), which represent the total dollar

amount a fund has committed to invest over the fund’s life. We believe the former measure is

more appropriate given the focus of our study on the benefits of having a viable window onto

innovative ventures.

We augmented our CVC data with patenting data constructed by Hall, Jaffe, and

Tratjenberg (2001) (hereafter HJT) that are based on the U.S Patent Office database.4 We added

to our sample all U.S. firms within the same industries as those firms in our CVC dataset who

also patented over the time period 1969-1999.5 The HJT datasets contain detailed information

on almost 3 million U.S. patents granted between 1963 and 1999, all citations made to these

patents since 1974 (over 16 million), and a match of patents to Compustat. Standard & Poor’s

Compustat database was used to provide annual firm-level accounting and financial data thus

2 Some firms sponsor more than one venture fund. For multiple fund firms, fund-level data were simply

aggregated to the firm-level. We included the following VentureXpert categories: Non-Financial Corp Affiliate or Subsidiary Partnership, Venture/PE Subsidiary of Non-Financial Corp., Venture/PE Subsidiary of Other Companies NEC, Venture/PE Subsidiary of Service Providers, Direct Investor/Non-Financial Corp, Direct Investor/Service Provider, SBIC Affiliate with non-financial Corp. and Non-Financial Corp. Affiliate or Subsidiary.

3 We excluded programs that are associated with corporate pension funds. The amendment to the Employee

Retirement Income Security Act of 1979 allowed pension funds to invest into venture capital markets. Many corporate pension funds allocate a portion of their assets to venture capital investment as a result. However, this activity is distinct from other corporate venturing investments and is unlikely to result in strategic benefits such as knowledge spillovers.

4 Studies based on the HJT datasets have been published in economic journals including Quarterly Journal of

Economics, Review of Economics and Statistics, Economics of Innovation and New Technology and others. See Hall, Jaffe and Trajtenberg (2001).

5 Four-digit SIC classification was used to identify industry affiliation.

2002 G. Dushnitsky & M. Lenox 12

limiting our sample to publicly traded firms. An automated, matching algorithm and hand-

checking were used to link the VentureXpert data with the HJT patenting dataset and

Compustat.6

The resulting sample included 1,240 firms and 22,496 observations. 262 firms of these

firms invested corporate venture capital some time during the period 1969-1999. For each of

these firms, we collected annual financial data such as research expenditures and book value of

assets for the years 1969 to 1999 from Compustat. We established the annual patent output for

each firm using the HJT dataset. Approximately 116 firms of the 262 public firms from the

VentureXpert database were issued a patent over the 1969 to 1999 time frame.

Measures

We capture the rate of innovation within firms in two ways. Our first dependent variable

is simply the count of patents that a firm applied for in a given year (Patents). This is a common

measured utilized in innovation studies (Griliches, Pakes & Hall, 1987; Cockburn & Henderson,

1998; Stuart, 2000). For each firm, we recorded the annual number of patents for which it

applied between 1969 and 1999. Only patent applications that were later granted are included in

our count. We chose to use application year rather than grant year, because our main interest is to

record changes to the focal firm’s knowledge base rather than its ability and timing of

appropriating rents. There is a lag, commonly ranging from one to four years, between when a

patent is applied and when a patent is granted (Hall et al, 2001). As a result, the number of

patents applied for are lower for more recent years (see Figure 1). To address any potential bias,

6 The HJT database provides not only the name of the company to which the patent was assigned but also the

ultimate (parent) firm name. Therefore, a firm with a single entry in Compustat can have multiple assignee-names on the HJT database. Since the knowledge gained through a venturing activity can be put to use in different divisions and subsidiaries of the corporation, we consider every assignee-name associated with a corporation, as long as it holds more than 50% of the original assignee.

2002 G. Dushnitsky & M. Lenox 13

year dummies are included in our models for each year in our sample, 1969-1999.

Patents counts are limited as a measure of innovation in that they fail to reflect the quality

of the patents a firm receives. Some patents are far more valuable than others. To capture patent

quality, we measure the count of forward (future) citations to patents applied for in a given year

by a firm (Citations). In doing so, we build on previous studies that have found patent citations

is a good indicator of the value of the invention (Trajtenberg, 1990; Harhoff, 1999). Hall, Jaffe

and Tratjenberg (2001) report that the distribution of forward lag in citation (i.e., the number of

years between patent’s application date and later citing-patents application date) is about 3 to 4

years. Thus our citation-weighted patents variable is truncated on the right. Patents granted in

recent years have not been available long enough to be cited by future patents (See Figure 1).

Variation in citing behavior across technological fields and along years may also bias our

citation-weighted patents variable (Hall et. al., 2001). Once again, year and firm dummies are

included in our sample to address these potential biases.7

---------------------------------------------------------

Insert Figure 1 about here

---------------------------------------------------------

Our primary independent variable is annual CVC investments in millions of dollars per

million dollar of firm assets (CVC Intensity). The numerated is calculated as the sum of all

investments via all venturing funds by a firm in a year. Control variables include annual firm

research expenditures in millions of dollars per million dollar of firm assets (R&D Intensity) and

firm size measured as total firm assets in millions of dollars (Assets). We scale both CVC

7 We also followed the ‘citation-fixed-effects’ approach of Hall et. al. (2001) and rescaled our dependent variable

by dividing the absolute number of citations made to a given patent, by the average number of citations made to all patents in the same technological group and application year. Our results are robust to this specification. See Hall et. al. (2001) for a complete discussion.

2002 G. Dushnitsky & M. Lenox 14

investments and R&D expenditures to avoid confounding these effects with firm size (Hall &

Ziedonis, 2001). We would expect that larger in-house research expenditures would lead to

greater patenting output (Henderson & Cockburn, 1996). Similarly, larger firms possess greater

resources for investing in research and thus are more likely to patent more (Schumpeter, 1942;

Cohen & Levinthal, 1989). All three variables are adjusted to 1999 dollars.

In some models, we also include a measure of the stock of patents a firm has been

granted (Patent Stock). Following Blundell, Griffith and Reene (1995), we calculate this

measure by calculating the depreciated sum of all patents applied from 1963 to the current year.8

Patent Stock it = Patents it + (1-δ) Patent Stock it-1

We include this measure to partially control for possible firm-level unobserved heterogeneity

that is not fixed throughout time. Previous studies examining patenting rates have used similar

measures (Cockburn & Henderson, 1998; Stuart, 2000).

Method

Our dependent variables (Patents and Citations) are a count of the number of patents and

citation-weighted patents applied for by a firm in a given year and as such are bound at zero and

assume only integer values. We address the discrete nature of Patents and Citations by adopting

a negative binomial model. The negative binomial model is commonly used in the patenting

literature for over dispersed count data like ours (Griliches et al, 1987). The negative binomial

model is a generalized form of a Poisson model where an individual, unobserved effect is

introduced in the conditional mean (Greene, 2000). We do not adopt a Poisson model because

8 We adopted a depreciation rate of 30% as in Blundell et. al. (1995). We experimented with other values (e.g.,

0%) and received consistent results. At a depreciating rate of 30%, patents granted prior to 1963 have little impact on 1969 Patent Stock especially given the one to four year lag between patent application and granting.

2002 G. Dushnitsky & M. Lenox 15

the assumption of constant dispersion appears violated, i.e. the mean and variance of the event

count are not proportional.9 A Lagrange multiplier test of overdispersion proposed by Cameron

& Trivedi (1998) was used to test this assumption.10

In our model, we include both firm and year fixed-effects to address possible unobserved

heterogeneity. Firm fixed-effects were adopted to control for unobserved, time-invariant firm-

level characteristics that may in part be driving patent activity within the firm. Year fixed-effects

are included to control for macroeconomic trends such as economic downturns that may

ultimately affect overall patenting levels. Year fixed-effects also control for yearly variations in

patent and patent citation rates as a result of right truncation of the data.11

We assume a one-year lag between our regressors and dependent variables. In other

words, we examine the association between last year’s corporate venture capital investments and

this year’s patenting levels. This is done to provide evidence of temporal precedence between

CVC activity and firm innovation levels. We do not include lags of greater than one year

because previous research looking at the relationship between research expenditures and firm

patenting have found high within firm correlation of R&D over time (Hall & Zedonis, 2001).

Experimentation with lagged values of CVC investments for our data generated results consistent

with this finding.

In summary, we adopt a negative binomial specification with firm and year fixed-effects

and one-year lagged independent variables. The expected number of patents given a set of

9 To increase confidence in our results, we also ran our various models using a Poisson specification and found

consistent results. The Poisson models may be provided by the authors upon request. 10 The LM test was operationalized using a likelihood ratio test in Stata version 7.0. A significant χ2 statistic is

interpreted as a rejection of the base hypothesis of constant dispersion. 11 We also experimented with limiting our sample to prior to 1995 as a way to address the truncation issue and

found consistent results.

2002 G. Dushnitsky & M. Lenox 16

independent variables may be given by,

E[ Patentsit | Xit-1] = λit = exp(β’Xit-1 + αi + γt + νi + ε it)

where Xit-1 represents our set of time-variant firm characteristics including CVC Intensity, αi is a

set of firm dummies, γt is a set of year dummies, and νi is the individual, unobserved effect of the

negative binomial model.

Analysis & Results

Figure 2 presents a summary of total annual investment in new ventures by corporations

during the period 1969 to 1999. We observe that corporate venturing activity has gone through

three waves in the last thirty years. The first wave peaked in the early seventies. Activity

declined until approximately 1978, when changes in legislation led to an increase in venturing

investments by firms. This second wave peaked around 1986 with total annual investment at

approximately $250 million per year. Investments declined sharply after the stock crash of 1987

to a level of $25 million in 1993. The third wave began with the rise of the Internet in the mid-

nineteen nineties. By 1999, the last year in our sample, investments by established firms in new

ventures reached a record level of nearly $4 billion.

---------------------------------------------------------

Insert Figure 2 about here

---------------------------------------------------------

Table 1 presents a summary of the investment activity of the twenty largest venturing

firms in our sample in terms of total cumulative dollars invested. Intel leads the list with total

investments approaching $1.5 billion since 1992. The top twenty is dominated by the largest

electronics and computer concerns such as Microsoft, Sony, Motorola, AOL, and Dell. Johnson

2002 G. Dushnitsky & M. Lenox 17

& Johnson is the first pharmaceutical firm to appear in the top twenty at the thirteenth position

with cumulative investments approximating $196 million. The relatively lower investment

levels by pharmaceutical firms may simply capture the inclination of these firms towards non-

equity inter-organizational arrangements (Pisano, 1991; Baum et al, 2000; Rothaermel, 2001). A

majority of the top twenty firms have started their corporate venturing funds after 1993. A few

have been engaged in corporate venturing since the sixties including Xerox, Johnson & Johnson,

and Motorola. A handful of firms including Intel, Sony and Xerox have numerous funds with

which to distribute funds.

---------------------------------------------------------

Insert Table 1 about here

---------------------------------------------------------

Table 2 presents definitions, descriptive statistics, and the correlation matrix for the

variables in our patent count model. To make full use of our data, we examine patenting activity

over the entire panel, 1969-1999. For each of our independent variables, we use the natural log

of each of these variables. We observe that firms, on average, are granted 17.3 patents per year

and receive approximately 6 citations per patent. However, these numbers are skewed by the

relatively few firms who patent in great numbers. In general, CVC Intensity varies from 0% to

28% in absolute terms. The correlations between independents variables were not deemed high

enough to warrant concern of multicollinearity.

---------------------------------------------------------

Insert Table 2 about here

---------------------------------------------------------

2002 G. Dushnitsky & M. Lenox 18

Table 3 presents estimates from various specifications of our model. In Model 1, we

estimate a fixed-effect, negative binomial specification using Patents as our dependent variable.

For simplicity, we do not present the coefficient estimates for the firm and year dummies. We

find not surprisingly that larger firms, ln(Assets), who engage in more research, ln(RD Intensity),

have higher patenting rates in the next year. While we estimate a positive coefficient for the log

of CVC Intensity, we are not confident in this estimate at even a 90% level. Thus, we do not find

evidence that CVC investments have a significant impact on future absolute patenting levels

within firms.12

---------------------------------------------------------

Insert Table 3 about here

---------------------------------------------------------

Perhaps CVC investment does not impact the quantity of patents but rather the quality of

patents. In Model 2, we estimate a fixed-effect, negative binomial specification using Citations

as our dependent variable. We find once again that the coefficient estimates of Assets and RD

Intensity are positive and highly significant (p < 0.001). We also find, in contrast to our previous

model, that CVC Intensity has a positive, significant coefficient estimate. Interestingly, the

magnitude of the coefficient estimates suggests that CVC investments have a greater return in

term of quality patents than R&D expenditures. This provides evidence that not only do CVC

investments have a positive spillover to firm innovation but that the impact of such investment is

similar to research spending.

One of the tradeoffs in using the conditional fixed-effects, negative binomial

specification is that firms who never patented over the time period are removed from the sample.

12 We do find that the absolute level of CVC has a positive, significant coefficient on Patents. This is likely due,

however, to the correlation between CVC and Firm Assets.

2002 G. Dushnitsky & M. Lenox 19

Out of the 214 firms removed from the sample for this reason, 146 firms (68%) had conducted

some level of CVC investment during the thirty-year period. The exclusion of firms who engage

in CVC but never patent may seriously bias our results. To address this potential bias, we adopt

a random-effects specification of our negative binomial model. The random-effects specification

has the advantage that we may use the full sample in our estimation. By adopting a random-

effects specification, we assume that the regressors and the firm-specific effects are uncorrelated.

The literature exhibits no strong preference for random-effects or fixed-effects in limited,

dependent variable models such as the negative binomial (Green, 2000).

In Model 3, we estimate our model using Citations as the dependent variable and a

random-effects specification.13 Our results are consistent with the fixed-effects specification.

We find positive, significant coefficients for the log of CVC Intensity, RD Intensity, and Assets.

Once again, the coefficient estimate for CVC Intensity is greater than RD Intensity. Thus, our

estimates for the larger sample are consistent with our estimates for the reduced sample.

In Model 4, we include Patent Stock as an additional control for unobserved

heterogeneity. Previous work has proposed that the stock of previous firm patents is a good

proxy of underlying firm innovation (Blundell et. al. 1995; Henderson & Cockburn, 1996; Stuart,

2000). While our fixed and random effect specifications will pick up time-invariant firm

characteristics, there may still exist firm specific effects that vary over time. We include Patent

Stock as an additional control for these effects. Our estimates are consistent with Models 2 and

3. We once again find a significant, positive effect of CVC investments on the quality of firm

13 Our overdispersion test statistic is presented in Models 3 through 6 of Table 3. The significance of these

estimates indicate a rejection of the hypothesis of constant dispersion and a preference for negative binomial over Poisson. For comparison, Table A1 of the Appendix, presents model estimates for the Poisson model. Note that our results are strengthened with such a specification.

2002 G. Dushnitsky & M. Lenox 20

patenting. In addition, we also find once again that large firms who invest in research, patent

more. Finally, we find that Patent Stock has a significant, positive effect on future patent levels.

One potential factor that may bias our results is the possibility that firms self-select to

invest in new ventures. In the presence of self-selection, our coefficient estimates may be

overstating the direct impact of CVC investment and reflecting underlying differences between

firms who invest and those who do not. Once again, while our fixed effect specification will

control for stable firm differences, they will not control for time-variant factors that affect the

desire to pursue CVC investment and the desire to increase patenting. To directly address the

self-selection issue, in Models 5, we limit our sample only to those firms that invest corporate

venture capital during our thirty-year time period. Thus, our estimates reflect the impact greater

CVC investment has on quality patenting given that a firm chose to make CVC investments. We

once again control for firm size and R&D intensity.

In Model 5, we estimate a random-effect, negative binomial specification using Citations

as our dependent variable. We find once again a positive, significant coefficient estimate for

Citations. Thus, we first find that firms who purse corporate venture capital exhibit more quality

patenting, compared to firm’s who do not (models 2-4), and second that among those firms who

invest corporate venture capital, we find that greater CVC investment increases the future output

of quality patents (model 5). That is, a firm’s output of quality patenting is associated not only

with the existence of CVC investment effort, but also with the magnitude of the investments.

In summary, we find consistent evidence that increased corporate venture capital

investment is associated with higher future citation-weighted patenting levels. Interestingly, the

magnitudes of the coefficient estimates suggest that CVC investments may have a greater return

in terms of quality patents than R&D expenditures. This is perhaps not surprising. By investing

2002 G. Dushnitsky & M. Lenox 21

in entrepreneurial ventures, the corporation encounters novel and pioneering technologies that

they may not be exposed to from internal R&D. If firms’ experience with pioneering

technologies is associated with increases in the likelihood of creating subsequent inventions

(Ahuja et al, 2001), externally-focused CVC investment may be considered at least as effective

as firm’s internal R&D efforts in advancing the firm’s absorptive capacity.

As with all analysis, we should be cautious in interpreting our results. We cannot

guarantee that the causality does not run the other way or perhaps that patenting and corporate

venture capital are jointly determined by some unobserved, time-variant factor. We adopt

lagged independent variables and include the stock of past patents in an attempt to address these

concerns. We also examine the sub-sample of firms who pursue CVC investments as a way to

address self-selection issues.

We should be cautious in the generalizability of our findings. We must recognize, once

again, that firms self-selected to pursue CVC investments. While these firms may (as our results

suggest) see increases in their citation levels as they increase CVC investment, this does not

necessarily mean that other firms would experience similar increases if they also choose to invest

in new ventures. Firms may require certain resources or capabilities to realize the innovation

benefits from corporate venture capital.

Finally, a number of authors have proposed that the performance of corporate venture

capital programs may in part be determined by the structure of the programs themselves (Block

& MacMillan, 1993; Siegel et al, 1988; Thornhill & Amit, 2000). Firms may espouse different

goals when they establish corporate venture capital programs. For example, firms that pursue

new ventures so as to increase existing product sales (as opposed to creating a window on new

technology) have been found to elicit negative reactions from equity markets (Dushnitsky, 2001).

2002 G. Dushnitsky & M. Lenox 22

Firms may also vary in the governance structures they adopt for corporate venturing programs.

CVC investment may either be direct or indirect (e.g., as a limited partner with a venture capital

fund). In some instance, corporate venture capital programs may take the form of a wholly-

owned subsidiary, dedicated solely to new venture investments (Maula and Murray, 2000).

While we do not have data on program goals or structures, to the extent that the

governance of corporate venture capital programs is relatively constant within individual firms

across time, our fixed-effect specification should control for this unobserved heterogeneity. On

the other hand, if firms change the goals and structures of their programs over time we may fail

to observe some interesting variance in patenting outcomes as a result. We leave the exploration

of changing program structures to future study.

Conclusion

Does participation in venture capital markets allow firms to access knowledge from

entrepreneurial ventures that lead to innovation? To address this question, we explored the

relationship between corporate venture capital investment and incumbent firm innovation by

analyzing whether investments by approximately twelve hundred public firms over a thirty-year

period led to increases in firm patenting rates. Our findings suggest that the level of citation-

weighted patenting-output is positively related to the intensity of CVC investment during the

preceding year. This finding is robust to different specifications and the inclusion of firm R&D

expenditures and size. In addition, we have some evidence that the return to CVC investments in

terms of patenting is greater than for R&D. Based on these results, we posit that corporate

venture capital investment might have a greater impact on a firm’s absorptive capacity than

research and development.

2002 G. Dushnitsky & M. Lenox 23

The findings of this study raise some interesting questions about the governance of

corporate venture capital programs. If established firms are able to appropriate knowledge from

new ventures through equity investment, there are incentives for new ventures to seek alternative

sources of funding such as traditional venture capital. As a consequence, firms may have to pay

a premium to gain access to new ventures relative to other capital sources. To avoid these

premiums, firms may institute various structural mechanisms to allay fears of opportunism. The

likely impacts on governance will be the subject of future studies.

Finally, the findings of this study have important implications for the role of corporate

venture capital programs in firms’ overall innovation strategies. While alternative inter-

organizational forms such as technology alliances have been found to be important sources of

external knowledge (Powell, Koput & Smith-Doerr 1996; Stuart, 2000), corporate venture capital

programs have been the subject of little formal, empirical analysis. We conjecture that venturing

activity might serve to satisfy incumbent firms’ inclination towards introducing innovations by

accessing an increasingly important source of knowledge -- competent entrepreneurial startups.

The transformation that have transpired at the outset of the 21st century favoring human capital in

the process of knowledge generation has lead to an increasing role for entrepreneurial startups in

innovation. Corporate venture capital programs may be instrumental in harvesting innovations

from entrepreneurial ventures and thus constitute a significant part of a firm’s overall innovation

strategy. Placing our finding into the context of the greater strategy literature on established

firms’ entrepreneurial behavior (e.g., Guth and Ginsberg, 1990), corporate venturing activity has

become a vital part of a firm’s entrepreneurial toolbox.

2002 G. Dushnitsky & M. Lenox 24

References

Ahuja, G. 2000. The duality of collaboration: inducements and opportunities in the formation of interfirm linkages. Strategic Management Journal 21(3) 317-343.

Ahuja, G, C. Lampert. 2001. Entrepreneurship in the large corporation: a longitudinal study of

how established firms create breakthrough inventions. Strategic Management Journal 21 267-294.

Almeida, P., G. Dokko, L. Rosenkopf. 2002. Startup size and the mechanisms of external

learning: increasing opportunity and decreasing ability? Research Policy (Forthcoming). Almeida, P., B. Kogut. 1999. Localization of knowledge and the mobility of engineers in

regional networks. Management Science 45(7) 905-917. Arrow, K. 1962. Economic welfare and the allocation of resources for innovations. Nelson ed.,

The Rate and Direction of Incentive Activity: Economic and Social Factors. Princeton University Press: Princeton, NJ.

Arrow, K. 1974. The limits of organization. New York: Norton. Baum, J., T. Calabrese, B. Silverman. 2000. Don't go it alone: Alliance network composition

and startups' performance in Canadian biotechnology. Strategic Management Journal 21 267-294.

Block, Z., I. MacMillan. 1993. Corporate Venturing: Creating New Business Within the Firm.

Harvard Business School Press: Boston, MA. Blundell R., R. Griffith, J. Reene. 1995. Dynamic count data models of technological

innovation. Economic Journal 105 333-344. Burgelman, R. 1983. A process model of internal corporate venturing in the diversified major

firm. Administrative Science Quarterly 28 223-245. Business Wire. Nokia launches Nokia Ventures. 4/24/1998. Cameron, C., P. Trivedi. 1998. The Analysis of Count Data. New York: Cambridge University

Press, 1998. Cockburn I., R. Henderson. 1998. Absorptive capacity, coauthoring behavior, and the

organization of research in drug discovery. The Journal of Industrial Economics 46(2) 157-183

Cohen, W., D. Levinthal. 1990. Absorptive capacity: a new perspective on learning and

innovation. Administrative Science Quarterly 35(1) 128-152.

2002 G. Dushnitsky & M. Lenox 25

Dushnitsky, G. 2002. Does it pay to have a window? Corporate venturing objectives and organizational wealth creation. Mimeo.

Garud, R., A. Van de Ven. 1992. An empirical evaluation of the internal corporate venturing

process. Strategic Management Journal 13(special issue) 93-109. Gompers, P., J. Lerner. 1998. The determinants of corporate venture capital success:

organizational structure, incentives and complementarities. NBER #6725: Cambridge, MA. Greene, W. 2000. Econometric Analysis. Prentice-Hall Inc.: Upper Saddle River, NJ. Griliches, Z, A. Pakes, B. Hall. 1987. The value of patents as indicators of inventive activity.

Dasgupta, Stoneman, eds. Economic Policy and Technological Performance. Cambridge University Press: New York, NY.

Grossman, R., O. Hart. 1986. The costs and benefits of ownership: A theory of vertical and lateral integration. Journal of Political Economy 94(4) 691-719.

Guth, W., A. Ginsberg. 1990. Guest editor’s introduction: Corporate entrepreneurship. Strategic

Management Journal 11(special issue) 5-15. Hagedoorn, J., J. Schakenraad. 1994. The effect of strategic technology alliances on company

performance. Strategic Management Journal 15(4) 291-309. Hall, B., A. Jaffe, M. Tratjenberg. 2001. The NBER patent citation data file: Lessons, insights

and methodological tools. NBER Working Paper #8498. Cambridge, MA. Hall, B., R. Zedonis. 2001. The patent paradox revisited: An empirical study of patenting in the

US semiconductor industry 1979-1995. RAND Journal of Economics 32(1) 101-128. Hamel, G. 2000. Leading the Revolution. Harvard Business School Press: Boston, MA. Henderson, R. 1993. Underinvestment and incompetence as responses to radical innovation:

Evidence from the photolithographic alignment equipment industry. The Rand Journal of Economics 24(2) 248-271.

Henderson, R., I. Cockburn. 1994. Measuring competence? Exploring firm effects in

pharmaceutical research. Strategic Management Journal 15 63-84. Henderson, R., I. Cockburn. 1996. Scale, scope and spillovers: The determinants of research

productivity in drug industry. The Rand Journal of Economics 27(1) 32-59. Harhoff, D., F. Narin, F. Scherer, K. Vopel. 1999. Citation frequency and the value of patented

inventions. Review of Economics and Statistics 81(3) 511-515. Kortum, S., J. Lerner. 2000. Assessing the contribution of venture capital to innovation? The

Rand Journal of Economics 31(4) 674-692.

2002 G. Dushnitsky & M. Lenox 26

Maula, M., G. Murray. 2000. Corporate venture capital and the creation of US public companies.

Presented at the 20th Annual International Conference of The Strategic Management Society.

McGrath, R. 1999. Falling forward: Real options reasoning and entrepreneurial failure. Academy

of Management Review 24(1) 13-30. Pisano, G. 1991. The governance of innovation: Vertical integration and collaborative

arrangements in the biotechnology industry. Research Policy 20 237-249. Powell, W., K. Koput, D. Smith-Doerr. 1996. Interorganizational collaboration and the locus of

innovation: Networks of learning in biotechnology. Administrative Science Quarterly 41 116-145.

Reinganum, J. 1989. The timing of innovation: Research, development and diffusion. In R.

Schmalensee, R. Willig, eds. The Handbook of Industrial Organization. North-Holland: New York, NY.

Rind, K. W. 1981. The role of venture capital in corporate development. Strategic Management

Journal 2 169-180. Roberts, P. 1999. Product innovation, product-market competition and persistent profitability in

the US pharmaceutical industry. Strategic Management Journal 20(7) 655-670. Rosenkopf, L., A. Nerkar. 2001. Beyond local search: Boundary-spanning, exploration, and

impact in the optical disc industry. Strategic Management Journal 22 287-306. Rothaermal, F. 2001. Incumbent's advantage through exploiting complementary assets via

interfirm cooperation. Strategic Management Journal 22 687-699. Saxenian, A. 1990. Regional networks and the resurgence of silicon valley. California

Management Review 33 89-113. Schumpeter, J. 1942. Capitalism, Socialism and Democracy. Harper & Row: New York, NY. Shane, S. 2001a. Technological opportunities and new firm creation. Management Science 47(2)

205-220. Shane, S. 2001b. Technology regime and new firm formation. Management Science 47(9) 1173-

1190. Shrader, S. 1997. Corporate vs. independent new ventures: Resources, strategy and performance

differences. Journal of Business Venturing 12(1) 47-66.

2002 G. Dushnitsky & M. Lenox 27

Siegel, R., E. Siegel, I. MacMillan. 1988. Corporate venture capitalists: Autonomy, obstacles and performance. Journal of Business Venturing 3 233-247.

Sorrentino, W. 1995. Relatedness and corporate venturing: Does it really matter? Journal of

Business Venturing 10(1) 59-73. Stuart, T. 2000. Interorganizational alliances and the performance of firms: A study of growth

and innovation rates in a hi-technology industry. Strategic Management Journal 21(8) 791-811.

Stuart, T., Hoang , Hybels 1999. Interorganizational endorsements and the performance of

entrepreneurial ventures. Administrative Science Quarterly 44 315-349. Sykes, H. 1990. Corporate venture capital: Strategies for success. Journal of Business Venturing

5(1) 37-47. Teece, D. 1986. Profiting from technological innovation: Implication for integration,

collaboration, licensing and public policy. Research Policy 15 285-305. Thornhill, S., R. Amit. 2000. A dynamic perspective of internal fit in corporate venturing.

Journal of Business Venturing 16 25-50. Trajtenberg M. 1990. A penny for your quotes: Patent citations and the value of information.

RAND Journal of Economics 21 325-342. Tushman, M., P. Anderson. 1986. Technological discontinuities and organizational

environments. Administrative Science Quarterly 31(3) 439-365. Venture Capital Investment in Israeli Companies. International Business Forum. March 27-28,

2001. Venture Economics. 2001. http://www.ventureeconomics.com/. Zingales, L. 2000. In search of new foundations. Journal of Finance 55(4) 1623-53.

2002 G. Dushnitsky & M. Lenox 28

Figure 1. Total patents and citations in our sample over time

0

50000

100000

150000

200000

250000

1969

1972

1975

1978

1981

1984

1987

1990

1993

1996

1999

patents

citations

2002 G. Dushnitsky & M. Lenox 29

Figure 2. Annual corporate venture capital investments (1969-1999)

0

100

200

300

400

500

600

700

800

900

1000

1969

1971

1973

1975

1977

1979

1981

1983

1985

1987

1989

1991

1993

1995

1997

1999

Year

Con

stan

t 19

99 $

Má 3984

2002 G. Dushnitsky & M. Lenox 30

Table 1. Activity summary of twenty largest venturing firms (1969-1999)

Firm Year Began

Investing

Maximum Annual

Ventures

Total Dollars

Investeda

Maximum Annual

Investeda

Average Annual Rounds

Total Venture

Funds Intel 1992 179 1486 771 57 5

Cisco 1995 55 1056 730 19 1 Microsoft 1983 29 713 436 7 1 Comdisco 1992 70 554 334 24 2

Dell 1995 48 502 395 26 1 MCI Worldcom 1996 11 495 410 8 1

AOL 1993 39 333 169 10 2 Motorola 1963 33 315 177 11 1

Sony 1984 30 313 169 7 6 Qualcomm 1999 5 262 207 5 1 Safeguard 1983 21 231 118 6 3 Sun Micro 1999 31 204 180 19 1

J & J 1961 21 196 80 5 2 Global-Tech 1999 13 188 122 11 1

Yahoo 1997 5 186 163 3 1 Xerox 1960 30 184 24 13 6

Compaq 1992 21 182 113 5 3 Citigroup 1999 11 156 93 9 1

Ford Motor 1951 22 146 125 8 4 Comcast 1996 16 144 84 11 1

a In millions of dollars.

2002 G. Dushnitsky & M. Lenox 31

Table 2. Descriptive statistics for patent rate models

Variable Description Mean Std. Dev. Min Max 1 2 3 4 5 6 1. Patents Count of new patents applied for by a

firm in each year 16.752 68.953 0 2405 1.00

2. Citations Citation-weighted new patents applied for by a firm in each year

107.549 464.360 0 12795 0.80 * 1.00

3. ln(CVC Intensity) Natural log of total annual investment in new ventures divided by total assets

0.001 0.003 0 0.24 0.01 0.00 1.00

4. ln(RD Intensity) Natural log of total annual research expenditures divided by total assets

0.047 0.065 0 0.69 0.04 * 0.05 * 0.00 1.00

5. ln(Assets) Natural log of total assets of firm ($M)

5.953 2.233 0.47 13.47 0.33 * 0.31 * -0.02 -0.23 * 1.00

6. Patent Stock Depreciated count of patents issued to a firm from 1963 till year t

50.929 199.137 0 6142 0.96 * 0.77 * -0.01 0.03 * 0.35 * 1.00

n = 22496 * p < 0.01

32

Table 3. Firm patenting levels (1969-1999)

Specification Fixed-Effects Negative Binomial

Random-Effects Negative Binomial

Dependent Variable Patents t Citations t Citations t Citations t Citations t

Model 1 2 3 4 5

ln(CVC Intensity) t-1 10.550 * (5.095)

13.312 * (5.344)

9.394 * (5.003)

9.236 * (4.969)

9.851 * (5.539)

ln(RD Intensity) t-1 0.123 (0.164)

2.118 *** (0.147)

2.155 *** (0.145)

2.059 *** (0.144)

0.283 (0.187)

ln(Assets) t-1 0.195 *** (0.008)

0.293 *** (0.006)

0.286 *** (0.006)

0.266 *** (0.006)

0.268 *** (0.015)

Patent Stock t-1 0.001 *** (0.000)

Year dummies Included included Included included included

Observations 18503 a 18503 a 22496 22496 6403 b Firms 1026 1026 1240 1240 262 Wald χ2 2022 *** 3160 *** 3122 *** 3795 *** 849 *** Overdispersion test 18000 *** 16000 *** 6998 *** All independent variables are lagged one year. Standard errors in parentheses. * p < 0.10, ** p < 0.01, *** p < 0.001 a Sample is reduced due to the removal of firms who never patented over the time period b Sample is reduced to only those firms who make CVC investments