democracy and multilateralism: the case of vote buying in ...€¦ · 1a di erence in means test...

43
Democracy and Multilateralism: The Case of Vote Buying in the UN General Assembly David B. Carter * Princeton University Randall W. Stone University of Rochester December 13, 2012 Abstract Democracies are more supportive of U.S. positions in the UN General Assembly than non- democracies. Is this because democracies share common perspectives, or does this pattern reflect coercion? Since 1985, U.S. law has stipulated that the State Department identify important votes and that aid disbursements reflect voting decisions. Consequently, there are three plausible explanations for the democratic voting correlation: 1) democracies share common preferences and the United States prefers to aid democracies; 2) democracies are more vulnerable than autocracies to U.S. influence attempts, and 3) democracies are subject to more credible influence attempts. To unravel these alternative explanations, we introduce a strategic statistical model that allows us to estimate voting preferences, vulnerability to influence, and credibility of linkage, which are theoretical quantities of interest that are not directly observable. The results reject the first two hypotheses: poor democracies have voting preferences that are more oppositional to U.S. positions than autocracies, and they are more willing than autocracies to take symbolic stands that may cost them foreign aid. Democracies support U.S. positions, however, because U.S. aid linkages are more credible when directed towards democratic countries. Splitting the sample into Cold War and post-Cold War segments, we find that the end of the Cold War changed the way U.S. linkage strategies treated allies and left and right-leaning governments, but the effects of democracy remained constant. * Emails: [email protected], [email protected]. 1

Upload: others

Post on 07-Nov-2020

1 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Democracy and Multilateralism: The Case of Vote Buying in ...€¦ · 1A di erence in means test and a Chi-square test of independence strongly con rm the statistical signi cance

Democracy and Multilateralism:

The Case of Vote Buying in the UN General Assembly

David B. Carter∗

Princeton University

Randall W. Stone

University of Rochester

December 13, 2012

Abstract

Democracies are more supportive of U.S. positions in the UN General Assembly than non-democracies. Is this because democracies share common perspectives, or does this pattern reflectcoercion? Since 1985, U.S. law has stipulated that the State Department identify importantvotes and that aid disbursements reflect voting decisions. Consequently, there are three plausibleexplanations for the democratic voting correlation: 1) democracies share common preferencesand the United States prefers to aid democracies; 2) democracies are more vulnerable thanautocracies to U.S. influence attempts, and 3) democracies are subject to more credible influenceattempts. To unravel these alternative explanations, we introduce a strategic statistical modelthat allows us to estimate voting preferences, vulnerability to influence, and credibility of linkage,which are theoretical quantities of interest that are not directly observable. The results rejectthe first two hypotheses: poor democracies have voting preferences that are more oppositionalto U.S. positions than autocracies, and they are more willing than autocracies to take symbolicstands that may cost them foreign aid. Democracies support U.S. positions, however, becauseU.S. aid linkages are more credible when directed towards democratic countries. Splitting thesample into Cold War and post-Cold War segments, we find that the end of the Cold Warchanged the way U.S. linkage strategies treated allies and left and right-leaning governments,but the effects of democracy remained constant.

∗Emails: [email protected], [email protected].

1

Page 2: Democracy and Multilateralism: The Case of Vote Buying in ...€¦ · 1A di erence in means test and a Chi-square test of independence strongly con rm the statistical signi cance

Introduction

The relationship between multilateralism and democracy has risen in prominence in the post-

Cold War period as international organizations become increasingly influential and their members

become increasingly democratic. Delegation to international authorities involves some sacrifice of

national sovereignty, and observers frequently lament the resulting democratic deficits. Democratic

procedures ameliorate these concerns, and almost all multilateral organizations have provisions for

voting, but these formal rules are often overridden by informal procedures that reflect the influence

of powerful countries (Stone, 2011). On the other hand, multilateralism is conceived as a means

of restraining the exercise of hegemonic power (Lake, 2002), and is widely believed to strengthen

democracy. Membership in international organizations has been credited with preventing new

democracies from sliding back into authoritarianism, and with improving the quality of democratic

governance (Pevehouse, 2002; Pevehouse and Mansfield, 2006; Keohane, Macedo and Moravscik,

2009). A first step towards unraveling these questions is to investigate how democracies interact

with each other as they seek to govern multilateral organizations. As the leading state in the

international system, does the United States cooperate with other democracies, or does it attempt

to coerce them?

We use vote buying in the United Nations General Assembly as a case study. The UNGA is

among the most democratic of international institutions, and the low stakes involved in its non-

binding resolutions have made it a relatively polite diplomatic forum. Nevertheless, U.S. foreign

policy seeks to influence the vote tallies on important UN votes, so the way in which the United

States interacts with other democracies in this setting may be revealing. Since the mid-1980s,

U.S. law has required the State Department to report how countries vote in the UN on issues

that are regarded as important to U.S. interests, and has required USAID to use countries’ voting

records on these issues as a criterion for disbursing aid. Buying votes is official policy. How we

interpret this, however, may depend on whose votes are being bought, and for what reasons. We

start with the observation that democracies tend to support the United States on votes designated

by the U.S. State Department as important to U.S. interests more frequently than autocracies.

A prima facie case exists, therefore, for the interpretation that democracies support the United

2

Page 3: Democracy and Multilateralism: The Case of Vote Buying in ...€¦ · 1A di erence in means test and a Chi-square test of independence strongly con rm the statistical signi cance

States because they share common norms and a community of interests. If this is the case, the

experience of cooperating on issues of common concern at the multinational level should reinforce

those norms. There should be no tension between participation in multilateral cooperation and

faithfully representing the preferences of national constituents, and multilateral governance should

become increasingly legitimate as more of the participating governments become democratic.

Since the United States is in the market for votes, however, strategic interaction creates inference

problems. Strategic votes reflect three motivations: government preferences, the susceptibility of

particular regimes to international influence, and the credibility of the threats or promises that

are used to influence votes. Rather than reflecting similar preferences, the voting behavior of

democracies might indicate that they are more vulnerable to U.S. influence than autocracies, and

consequently are more willing to comply with U.S. influence attempts. Alternatively, democracies

might not be particularly vulnerable, but might still comply with U.S. preferences at higher rates

if U.S. threats or promises are more credible when addressed to democracies. In order to unravel

what this voting behavior means, it is essential to explicitly account for the strategic incentives

facing voters and vote buyers.

We introduce a statistical technique that allows us simultaneously to estimate voting preferences,

susceptibility to influence by the United States, and the credibility of U.S. influence attempts. We

estimate a strategic statistical model in which countries decide how to vote on an issue that has

been designated by the United States State Department as important to U.S. interests, and then

the United States decides whether to withhold a portion of committed aid, if the country has voted

against the U.S. position, or reward the aid recipient with additional aid, if the country has voted

in favor of the U.S. position. Because this model captures the strategic element of voting, we are

able to evaluate the effect of anticipated punishments or rewards on voting decisions. Furthermore,

we are able to differentiate which regimes are most susceptible to influence and which influence

attempts are most credible.

Our findings are disappointing for advocates of multilateral governance. We find that demo-

cratic countries are in fact more strongly opposed to U.S. policy preferences than non-democratic

countries, so norms or a community of interests do not explain their voting behavior. Left to their

3

Page 4: Democracy and Multilateralism: The Case of Vote Buying in ...€¦ · 1A di erence in means test and a Chi-square test of independence strongly con rm the statistical signi cance

own devices, democratic countries would oppose U.S. positions at higher rates than authoritarian

countries. Democracies are presumably more likely to oppose the United States because they are

more sensitive to the preferences of the median voter, which generally are not favorable to U.S.

foreign policy (e.g, support of Israel, the embargo of Cuba, or wars in the Middle East). This

casts U.S. efforts to cajole UN members to support its preferred positions in an unfavorable light.

Nor do democratic governments comply with U.S. wishes because they are particularly sensitive to

U.S. development aid disbursements; in fact, we find that democratic governments are more willing

than authoritarian governments to take symbolic stands that may cost them access to foreign aid.

Again, the salience of public opinion in democracies and the narrow bases of support for authori-

tarian governments are persuasive explanations. Instead, we find that democracies are more likely

to comply with U.S. influence attempts because they are the countries that are most frequently

targeted. It is costly for the United States to punish its authoritarian allies, which often depend on

aid for political survival, and generally receive aid because they are strategically important rather

than because they are deserving. Conversely, it can be politically embarrassing at home to reward

authoritarian countries for their votes. Consequently, U.S. policy tends to target democracies when

it tries to round up support. Our results indicate that the fact that U.S. threats and rewards are

more credible when they are directed at democracies accounts for the high rate of compliance with

U.S. preferences by democracies.

Additional results show that the United States punishes and rewards recipients for their votes

differently depending on the left-right political orientations of their governments, their levels of

development, and their alliance relationships, and that these variations in credibility are key to

explaining the effectiveness of U.S. influence attempts. In order to further investigate these rela-

tionships, as well as to probe the robustness of our findings about democracy, we split our data into

Cold War and post-Cold War samples. We find that the end of the Cold War was a watershed in

U.S. vote buying strategy in the UN, although vote buying occurred in both samples. Our findings

suggest that factors relevant to U.S. competition with the Soviet Union play an important role

in explaining the U.S. propensity to punish aid recipients during the Cold War, but these factors

lose explanatory power in the post-Cold War era. In particular, the United States was much more

4

Page 5: Democracy and Multilateralism: The Case of Vote Buying in ...€¦ · 1A di erence in means test and a Chi-square test of independence strongly con rm the statistical signi cance

willing to punish left-leaning governments and reward right-leaning governments during the Cold

War, but this pattern disappeared when the Cold War came to an end. Similarly, the United States

was reluctant to punish its allies during the Cold War, but became more likely to punish allies than

non-allies after the Cold War. The end of the Cold War did not have substantial effects on the

coefficients for recipient countries’ behavior. Furthermore, our central findings about the effects

of democracy are consistent during and after the Cold War. This indicates that the strategy of

coercing democracies is an enduring feature of U.S. foreign policy, rather than a consequence of

the special circumstances that prevailed during the Cold War. Finally, we provide a direct test of

whether our strategic choice model outperforms a non-strategic model using the same covariates,

which can be interpreted substantively as a test of whether recipient voting behavior is significantly

influenced by U.S. aid disbursements. The result rejects the hypothesis of no strategic effect on

voting.

1 Democracy and UN Voting

Democracies support U.S. positions on issues of importance to U.S. foreign policy in the United

Nations General Assembly 41% of the time, while non-democracies support the U.S. position only

29% of the time.1 Does this reflect a coincidence of preferences among democratic countries? Are

democracies more responsive to U.S. influence attempts? Alternatively, are democracies more likely

to support U.S. positions because they are more likely to be coerced or rewarded? We argue that

democratic governments represent preferences that are more inherently opposed to U.S. policy than

autocracies, that they are more resistant to efforts to influence their policies, but that they support

U.S. positions nevertheless because they are targeted more systematically by U.S. policymakers for

influence attempts.

The most optimistic interpretation of UN voting patterns holds that democracies vote together

because they hold similar world views and pursue complementary goals in foreign policy. This is

consistent with the observations that democracies are unlikely to engage in militarized interstate

1A difference in means test and a Chi-square test of independence strongly confirm the statistical significance ofthis difference. We classify states with a Polity score of at least six as democracies.

5

Page 6: Democracy and Multilateralism: The Case of Vote Buying in ...€¦ · 1A di erence in means test and a Chi-square test of independence strongly con rm the statistical signi cance

disputes against each other (Bennett and Stam, 2000), and that when disputes do arise between

democracies, it is almost always possible to settle them without escalation (Dixon, 1994; Huth and

Allee, 2002). The pattern of peaceful conflict resolution among democracies is widely attributed

to common values (Russett, 1993; Russett and Oneal, 2001a). Furthermore, democracies are more

likely to form alliances to support each other than to ally with non-democracies (Lai and Reiter,

2000).

Patterns of democratic affinity are not limited to security affairs. Democracies trade with each

other more intensively than with non-democracies, controlling for factors such as the size of their

economies and the distance between them, and they are more inclined to grant each other commer-

cial concessions (Mansfield, Milner and Rosendorff, 2000; Gartzke, 2007). Democracies sign more

treaties with other democracies than with non-democracies, and they share more memberships in

international organizations. Common membership in international organizations has been cred-

ited with resolving disputes and facilitating cooperation (Mitchell and Hensel, 2007). Democratic

publics have more positive assessments of other democratic countries than of non-democratic ones,

and in particular, the publics of democratic countries tend to hold more positive views of the United

States than do those of authoritarian countries.

Contradicting this rosy view is the deep division in public opinion between developed and de-

veloping countries. U.S. foreign policy is generally unpopular among democracies in the developing

world. A strong bloc of votes consistently supported the United States during the early decades of

the United Nations’ history, but by the mid-1970s the United States frequently found itself isolated,

and was on the losing side of most votes by the 1980s. Cold War themes continued to command

the allegiance of a wide range of U.S. democratic allies, but even the staunchest U.S. allies became

increasingly critical of U.S. positions on Central America, the Middle East, South Africa, and how

best to promote human rights in the Soviet bloc. Some of these disagreements were tactical and re-

solved themselves with the end of the Cold War, but new disagreements arose over how to deal with

nuclear proliferation, terrorism and the dilemmas posed by Iraq, Iran and North Korea. Meanwhile,

democracies in the developing world chafed under the Washington Consensus and became restive

under a global trade regime that appeared slanted in favor of the interests of advanced economies.

6

Page 7: Democracy and Multilateralism: The Case of Vote Buying in ...€¦ · 1A di erence in means test and a Chi-square test of independence strongly con rm the statistical signi cance

The legitimacy of the international institutions where the United States exercised decisive influence

came under question, and this was reflected in voting in the international forum that the United

States found hardest to control, the UNGA.

Furthermore, there is reason to believe that the leaders of democracies derive more benefits

than autocrats from taking symbolic stands that are critical of the United States. Democratic

leaders face re-selection through elections, so their tenure in office is intimately related to their

popularity; this connection is more tenuous for autocrats. If the United States takes a position

that is unpopular with the target country’s electorate, it may be politically costly for a democratic

leader to vote in support. Furthermore, leaders who face domestic criticism for being too closely

aligned with the United States—for example, because they have accepted IMF tutelage of their

economic policies, or have supported U.S.-led military operations—may find symbolic votes in the

UNGA a welcome opportunity to deflect criticism by demonstratively following public opinion.

Autocrats generally rely on the support of a narrow coalition of elites to retain their positions, so

they are largely insulated from the pressure to conform to public opinion (Bueno de Mesquita and

Smith, 2007).

Rather than reflecting inherent preferences, it is possible that democratic countries vote more

consistently with the United States because they are susceptible to U.S. influence. Several studies

have found associations between UN voting and U.S. foreign aid (Wittkopf, 1973; Rai, 1980; Wang,

1999; Dreher, Nunnenkamp and Thiele, 2008).2 It is plausible that foreign aid is explicitly used to

influence UN voting—at least in key votes that attract substantial attention from donors—because

we know that the distribution of aid differs from need-based allocations (Boone, 1996; Collier and

Dollar, 2002), and is strongly related to the geopolitical interests and foreign policy preferences

of the donors (e.g. Maizels and Nissanke (1984); Boone (1996); Cashel-Cordo and Craig (1997);

2In contrast, Kegley and Hook (1991) find little evidence that the explicit linkage between UNGA voting onimportant issues and aid disbursements established in the 1980s has any effect on voting behavior. Most early workdid not distinguish between important votes and ordinary votes, although Wittkopf (1973) defined “important” votesas those in which the U.S. and Soviet Union disagreed, and Wang (1999) focuses on votes identified as importantby the U.S. State department. Dreher, Nunnenkamp and Thiele (2008) disaggregate aid into categories and use aninstrumental variable approach that addresses some of the ambiguities in the previous literature, and find evidence infavor of a vote-buying hypothesis. Using an alternative identification strategy, Kuziemko and Werker (2006) narrowthe interpretation of their empirical results by focusing on temporary membership in the UN Security Council, andfind that U.S. foreign aid increases significantly when a country becomes a temporary UNSC member, and drops offagain after membership lapses.

7

Page 8: Democracy and Multilateralism: The Case of Vote Buying in ...€¦ · 1A di erence in means test and a Chi-square test of independence strongly con rm the statistical signi cance

Schraeder, Hook and Taylor (1998); Alesina and Dollar (2000); Alesina and Weder (2002); Svensson

(1999); Neumayer (2003)). In addition, a number of studies have found associations between UN

voting and aid from the IMF and World Bank, and argue that the United States uses loans from

those agencies to reward its allies (Thacker, 1999; Oatley and Yackee, 2004; Barro and Lee, 2005;

Stone, 2004; Kilby, 2010).3

Are democracies more willing than autocracies to change their positions as a result of foreign

influence, however? One strand of literature suggests that they are: democracies are more likely

than non-democracies to respond to trade sanctions by making concessions (Hufbauer et al., 2007;

McLean and Whang, 2010; Whang, 2010). It is often argued that trade sanctions affect the welfare

of ordinary citizens more than that of elites, so political regimes that are responsive to citizen

interests should be more vulnerable to trade sanctions than those that have narrow bases of support.

Saddam Hussein’s regime in Iraq is a notorious example, which resisted UN sanctions at a staggering

cost to the population, and even found ways to use the sanctions to build its clientelistic network by

rationing access to consumer goods. Intuitions from the sanctions experience do not transfer well

to foreign aid, however, because the benefits of foreign aid, particularly in authoritarian countries,

accrue more to regime insiders than to the population as a whole.

In contrast, arguments about the recalcitrance of democracies have been made in terms of

audience costs, veto players, and leaders’ reselection incentives. A prominent thread in the literature

on international conflict argues that democratic leaders are less willing to back down in crises

because they are subject to audience costs, and this has been linked to a lower incidence of these

crises involving democracies, and to a higher probability that democracies prevail in crises (Fearon,

1994; Schultz, 2001; Leventoglu and Tarar, 2005; Tomz, 2007). Similarly, the literature on two-level

games concludes that countries with constitutional limits to executive authority have increased

3UN voting is rapidly becoming recognized as an important control variable in studies that seek to explainparticipation in IMF programs, and as a useful instrument for selection-controlled studies of their effects, because UNvoting is presumably exogenous with respect to outcome variables such as economic growth (Steinwand and Stone,2008). Thacker (1999) finds that increasing the similarity of a country’s profile of votes in the United Nations GeneralAssembly to those of the United States over time is associated with a higher probability of IMF lending. Barro andLee (2005) find that IMF loans are associated with similarity to U.S. voting patterns in the UN and economic tieswith the United States. Andersen, Harr and Tarp (2006) use important UNGA votes to explain the probability thata country obtains an IMF program, Kilby (2010) uses important UNGA votes to explain the distribution of WorldBank loans, and Dreher, Sturm and Vreeland (2009) find that temporary membership in the UN Security Councilincreases World Bank loans.

8

Page 9: Democracy and Multilateralism: The Case of Vote Buying in ...€¦ · 1A di erence in means test and a Chi-square test of independence strongly con rm the statistical signi cance

bargaining power, but are more likely to fail to reach agreement under incomplete information

(Putnam, 1988; Tarar, 2001). Both effects should make democracies less likely to adjust their voting

strategies to accommodate U.S. pressure. A selectorate perspective maintains that democratic

leaders retain their tenure by providing public goods that are enjoyed by the electorate as a whole,

while autocratic leaders survive in office by providing targeted private goods to narrow coalitions of

supporters (Bueno de Mesquita et al., 2003). Symbolic actions in the United Nations are a classic

public good. The foreign aid that the United States ties to these voting decisions, on the other

hand, represents slack resources that autocratic governments tend to use to reward their supporters.

Consistent with this interpretation, recent studies have found that receipt of foreign aid significantly

increases the expected tenure of autocratic leaders, but has no similar effect on the survival of

democratic leaders (Bueno de Mesquita and Smith, 2010). Pandering to U.S. preferences is less

costly to autocrats than to democratic leaders, because they have weaker incentives to represent the

preferences of the population, and the economic support that the United States offers in return is

more valuable to autocrats, so autocrats should be more willing to accommodate U.S. preferences.

If it is not true that democracies are inherently more supportive of U.S. positions or more

vulnerable to influence, is it instead the case that they are more frequently targeted for influence

attempts? Bruce Bueno de Mesquita and Alastair Smith argue the opposite. Taking a demand-side

approach to foreign aid, they argue that aid should flow to the countries whose positions are least

expensive to buy. Since autocrats are more willing to accommodate U.S. preferences, they should

receive the lion’s share of the rewards (Bueno de Mesquita and Smith, 2007, 2009). In contrast,

we take a supply-side approach. In our view, the relevant political constraint on U.S. foreign aid is

not the aggregate size of the foreign aid budget, which in any case is small, but political support

in Congress for aid to particular countries. Because it is more popular to give aid to democracies

than to autocrats, influence strategies are more credible when directed at democracies.

Foreign aid is supported by a coalition that includes members of Congress with altruistic and

realpolitik motivations, and both sets of concerns are reflected in U.S. foreign aid allocations (Poe

and Meernik, 1995; Apodaca and Stohl, 1999; Demirel-Pegg and Moskowitz, 2009). Democratic

voters tend to support foreign aid that is need-based, development-oriented, delivered to countries

9

Page 10: Democracy and Multilateralism: The Case of Vote Buying in ...€¦ · 1A di erence in means test and a Chi-square test of independence strongly con rm the statistical signi cance

with attractive political regimes and channeled through international organizations; Republican

voters generally prefer aid that is targeted to American strategic allies, that is connected to explicit

foreign policy quid pro quos, and that is disbursed bilaterally (Milner and Tingley, 2010, 2011).

In order to achieve these multiple objectives, Congress has developed a detailed aid appropriation

process that allows members to influence foreign aid commitments, but has also delegated substan-

tial discretion to the executive branch to manipulate aid disbursements. The executive branch can

use this discretion to buy votes in the UN General Assembly, and the 1985 law authorizes it to

do so. In practice, however, some deviations from appropriated levels are more politically costly

than others, and more likely to motivate Congress to reduce executive discretion in the future. In

particular, it is controversial to provide foreign aid to some autocratic countries, so when the State

Department searches for a country whose vote it could buy by offering a short-term infusion of

foreign aid, it looks first for democracies. As a result, democracies are more likely than autocracies

to be rewarded when they vote in support of U.S. positions.

On the other hand, the domestic politics of U.S. foreign aid also ensures that it is costly to

withhold aid that has been committed to autocratic countries. Because it is more controversial

to aid autocracies, the set of autocracies that receive substantial aid commitments is limited to

countries that play particularly important roles in U.S. foreign policy. Recent examples include

Egypt under Mubarak and Pakistan under Musharraf; examples during the Cold War included Zaire

under Mubutu and the Philippines under Marcos. Many of these regimes take public postures that

are critical of U.S. foreign policy—in recent years, Pakistan and Egypt frequently voted against

the United States in the UN—but they play important roles in U.S. policy in other ways, often as

regional anchors of U.S. influence. In addition, foreign aid generally plays a key role in guaranteeing

political stability in these fragile authoritarian states, so that withdrawing it could cost the United

States a reliable regional supporter and bring a more oppositional regime to power. Under these

circumstances, the credibility of U.S. threats to withdraw support over acts of symbolic defiance

would be limited, and such threats are rarely made.

Three reasonable interpretations of democratic voting in the UN have been proposed. We argue

against the hypotheses that democracies vote with the United States because they share common

10

Page 11: Democracy and Multilateralism: The Case of Vote Buying in ...€¦ · 1A di erence in means test and a Chi-square test of independence strongly con rm the statistical signi cance

values, or because they are more vulnerable than autocracies to U.S. influence attempts. On the

contrary, we claim that the pattern arises because democracies are more likely to be punished or

rewarded for their votes. Disentangling the hypothesized effects requires that we simultaneously

estimate voting preferences, target country susceptibility to influence attempts, and the credibility

of those attempts, so we turn next to this problem.

A Strategic Estimator for UN Voting

Previous studies of UN voting have been unable to disentangle strategic and sincere voting because

they have not explicitly modeled voting as a strategic choice. There are two important methodolog-

ical issues here. First is the familiar problem of endogeneity, and the substantive concern is that

UN voting may be associated with U.S. aid either because countries comply with U.S. preferences

in order to obtain aid, or because countries that sympathize with U.S. positions in the UN are likely

to receive aid irrespective of how they vote. Our approach deals with endogeneity by estimating

equations for U.S. aid allocations and for UN voting decisions and by making identifying assump-

tions, as in an instrumental variables approach, but it takes advantage of the strategic structure of

the model as part of the identification strategy. The second issue is strategic misspecification bias,

and the substantive concern is that the relationships among preferences, voting and aid allocations

may depend upon strategic calculations. In particular, we argue that the credibility of U.S. influ-

ence strategies varies systematically across countries, which affects the relationship between aid and

UN voting. Estimators that fail to account for how the U.S. influence strategy induces strategic

recipient behavior will be biased and inconsistent; the effect is equivalent to omitted variable bias

(Signorino and Yilmaz, 2003).

Strategic effects are important because the effectiveness of U.S. influence attempts depends upon

their credibility. Suppose that the United States threatens to reduce aid to a developing country

if it votes against the U.S. position on an important vote, and we observe that the country defies

the U.S. demand. Two inferences are possible. It may be the case that the country’s leadership

is highly motivated to resist U.S. policy preferences. Alternatively, the government might not be

strongly opposed to the U.S. position, but the leadership might calculate that the U.S. threat is

11

Page 12: Democracy and Multilateralism: The Case of Vote Buying in ...€¦ · 1A di erence in means test and a Chi-square test of independence strongly con rm the statistical signi cance

unlikely to be carried out. It is impossible to accurately estimate either government preferences

or the effectiveness of influence attempts without considering the effect of variations in credibility.

Consequently, we use a strategic choice model that can capture this effect.

The structure of the statistical model we estimate is depicted in Figure 1. First, the recipient

country decides whether to vote for or against the U.S. position. If the recipient votes against the

United States on an important vote, the United States decides whether to punish it with significant

aid reductions. If the recipient’s vote coincides with the U.S. position, the United States chooses

whether to reward it with a significant increase in aid flows.4 The model imposes the simplest

possible structure that allows for strategic voting and for threats and promises to be linked to aid

flows.5

In order to convert the formal model into a statistical model, we add a stochastic component

to the utilities of the actors, which gives us a distribution over the four possible outcomes of the

model. We characterize this disturbance as agent error, which seems appropriate to our context

(Signorino, 1999, 2003). Agent error might occur in the voting stage, for example, because the UN

ambassador is not informed, or not informed in a timely manner, of the preferences of the leader,

or because disagreements within the government give the ambassador discretion to vote his or her

own preferences. Agent error might occur at the disbursement stage because of a disagreement

between the executive and legislative branches of government, because of an interagency dispute,

or because of some other intervening variable that is orthogonal to UN voting, such as the recipient

country’s policies regarding human rights, trade or the environment.

The recipient and the United States make decisions in the game by weighing their expected

utilities for each possible action. The model explicitly allows the recipient’s voting decision to be

influenced by the expected effect it will have on aid flows. We start from the last move in the game,

4Aid disbursements fluctuate for a variety of reasons that are not related to UN voting, so it would not beappropriate to use the difference between commitments and disbursements as a direct measure of punishments andrewards. Instead, we estimate an equation for predicted disbursements that includes current commitments, laggeddisbursements and fixed effects, which has an R-squared of .99. We specify punishments and rewards as dichotomous,and we use the conservative strategy of coding a case as a punishment or reward only if it is outside the 95 percentconfidence interval. The discussion of our dependent variables below provides more details.

5It is also possible to model vote choice as multinomial, where a recipient can: 1.) vote in strict accordance withthe U.S., 2.) abstain from the vote, or 3.) vote against the U.S. This model is considerably more complicated anddoes not seem substantively warranted.

12

Page 13: Democracy and Multilateralism: The Case of Vote Buying in ...€¦ · 1A di erence in means test and a Chi-square test of independence strongly con rm the statistical signi cance

Figure 1: The Voting-Aid Game

���������@@@@@@@@@

������@

@@@@@

@@@@@@�

�����

Recipient

US US

Vote With US¬ Vote With US

Reward¬ Reward¬ Punish Punish

p1 p2

p3 p5 p6p4

0

0

X14β14X24β24

β150

X16β16X26β26

the United States’ decision to punish, reward or do nothing in response to the recipient’s vote,

and move up the game tree to show the players’ expected utility calculations. For each vote, or

observation, i = 1 . . . n, the recipient decides whether to vote for or against the U.S. position. If the

recipient does not vote with the United States, the United States makes the following comparison6

pi,4 = U∗US(Pun|Disagree) > U∗US(¬Pun|Disagree) (1)

= UUS(Pun|Disagree) + ε4 > UUS(¬Pun|Disagree) + ε3. (2)

Assume the ε terms are independent and identically distributed (i.i.d.) Type 1 Extreme Value,

which yields

pi,4 =expUUS(Pun|Disagree)

expUUS(Pun|Disagree) + expUUS(¬Pun|Disagree)(3)

pi,3 = 1− pi,4. (4)

In deciding whether to reward the recipient when the recipient votes in agreement, the United

States makes a similar comparison which leads to expressions almost identical to those in equations

6Note that Pun stands for punish, Rew, for reward, Agree for agreement with the U.S. position, and Disagreefor disagreement with the U.S. position. The numbers on the probabilities and ε terms correspond to the numbersassigned to the players’ actions in figure 1.

13

Page 14: Democracy and Multilateralism: The Case of Vote Buying in ...€¦ · 1A di erence in means test and a Chi-square test of independence strongly con rm the statistical signi cance

1–4. The recipient makes its decision to vote with the U.S. position or not by calculating, with some

error, its utility for voting in agreement or disagreement with the United States. The recipient’s

utility is a function of its preferences over outcomes and the probability that the United States will

subsequently reward or punish. The comparison of the expected utilities for voting for or against

the U.S. position take the following form:

pi,2 = U∗R(Agree) > U∗R(Disagree) (5)

= UR(Agree) + ε2 > UR(Disagree) + ε1. (6)

If we again assume that the ε terms are i.i.d. Type 1 Extreme Value, we obtain

pi,2 =exp(pi,6UR(Agree,Rew)+pi,5UR(Agree,¬Rew))

exp(pi,6UR(Agree,Rew)+pi,5UR(Agree,¬Rew)) + exp(pi,4UR(Disagree,Pun)+pi,3UR(Disagree,¬Pun))(7)

pi,1 = 1− pi,2. (8)

We utilize the statistical backwards induction technique (SBI) developed by Bas, Signorino and

Walker (2007).7 The SBI technique is employed by separately estimating the logit equation for each

possible decision in the game rather than simultaneously estimating the full system of equations.

First, we estimate the probability that the United States punishes a recipient for disagreement,

i.e., pi,4. As indicated in equation 2 above, pi,4 is a function of the U.S. utility for punishing the

recipient following disagreement, which we estimate with substantive variables, i.e., X24β24. The

U.S. compares its utility for punishing disagreement in each case (X24β24) with its utility for not

punishing disagreement (β23). The United States’ utility for rewarding agreement, i.e., pi,6, is

estimated analogously, relative to not rewarding agreement. Second, we estimate the probability

that the recipient votes with the U.S. position, i.e., pi,2. The probability of agreement with the

U.S. is a function of the recipient’s utilities over all possible outcomes in the game, weighted by the

probability that each outcome will prevail (i.e., equation 7). The probabilities that the U.S. will

punish disagreement or reward agreement are obtained from the first stage logit regressions (i.e.,

pi,3–pi,6). SBI is attractive in our context because it ensures that the likelihood is concave, so our

results reflect the true maximum likelihood estimate. In addition, computational time is decreased

7Also see Carrubba, Yuen and Zorn (2007) for a very similar approach.

14

Page 15: Democracy and Multilateralism: The Case of Vote Buying in ...€¦ · 1A di erence in means test and a Chi-square test of independence strongly con rm the statistical signi cance

significantly relative to simultaneous estimation of the full system of equations. The disadvantage

of SBI is that the standard errors in the recipient’s estimates are biased downwards because the

probabilities are treated as fixed data. Following the recommendations of Bas, Signorino and

Walker (2007), we correct the standard errors using the bootstrap. Although the standard errors

for the U.S. utilities are not affected by this issue, we also bootstrap them to be conservative. 500

bootstrap iterations are run in each model.

We take several steps to ensure that the fact that there are multiple important votes in each year

is not a problem for our analysis. First, we sample by year when we calculate the bootstrapped

standard errors to ensure that the standard errors are not affected by the lack of independence

among votes in each year.8 Second, to ensure that no bias is introduced into our results by including

multiple votes in each year, we randomly sample one vote from each year for each recipient country

in the sample and estimate our model on this reduced set of votes. This leads to a sample size

that is roughly one-third the size of the overall sample, but none of the results change when we

apply this procedure. Thus, including multiple votes per year does not appear to affect either our

standard errors or estimated coefficients in any substantial way.9

Below, we specify the utilities of the recipient and the United States with some of the same

variables. Consequently, to identify the model both the recipient and the United States must have

the utility normalized to zero for at least one outcome that is possible at its initial information set

and affects its utility.10 In addition, no regressor can be estimated in every utility. We normalize

the recipient’s utility for not being punished after voting in disagreement (a sincere opposition

vote with no consequences) to zero. For the U.S., we normalize the utilities for not punishing the

recipient following a vote against the U.S. and for not rewarding the recipient following a vote

in agreement (harmony) to zero. Thus, all estimated coefficients for each player in each of the

remaining utilities are interpreted relative to these outcomes. Normalization of a player’s utility for

one possible outcome in the strategic logit model is analogous to the standard method of identifying

a multinomial logit model. This model captures strategic voting and allows threats and promises

8This is analogous to estimating clustered “robust” standard errors, although it often yields more conservativeestimates. We also tried sampling by vote, which yields similar results.

9The results of this robustness check are included in the supplemental appendix.10An initial information set for each player is the node at which it makes its first move in the game.

15

Page 16: Democracy and Multilateralism: The Case of Vote Buying in ...€¦ · 1A di erence in means test and a Chi-square test of independence strongly con rm the statistical signi cance

about important UNGA votes to be linked to aid flows.

Data

We utilize data on aid flows from the United States, voting by the United States and U.S. aid

recipients in the UNGA, and data on other variables of interest. The data on aid flows from

the United States to potential recipients are published by the OECD Development Assistance

Committee and cover 1966–2001. The data include both Official Development Assistance (ODA)

and Official Assistance (OA) disbursements in millions of U.S. dollars.

We utilize the Documenting Votes in the UN General Assembly, v2.0 data set compiled by

Voeten (2005), and we focus on votes defined as important by the U.S. State Department in its

annually published Report to Congress on Voting Practices in the United Nations. The temporal

domain starts in 1985, the year in which U.S. law first required the State Department to report how

countries vote on issues that are regarded as important to U.S. interests, and ends in 2001. The

United States is never absent for important votes. Votes in which the recipient country is absent

are excluded.

Regressors

We utilize several regressors to estimate the utilities of the recipient countries and the United States

over the outcomes in the model, including variables specific to the recipient country and variables

that characterize the relationship the recipient has with the United States.11 Our primary quantity

of interest is the effect of democracy, which we measure using Polity IV scores in the main results,

and using a dichotomous measure (Alvarez et al. 2000) as a robustness check.12 Our identification

assumptions are not restrictive, so we capture the effect of each regressor on each choice. This

allows democracy to affect the recipient’s utilities for voting with or against the United States

to capture the coincidence of interests hypothesis, the recipient’s utilities for being punished or

11A table with descriptive statistics is presented in the appendix.12We replicated our results using the dichotomous measure of democracy introduced by ACLP and updated by

Cheibub, Gandhi and Vreeland (2010) and found no substantive differences in our results. Polity scores are mostlikely to be problematic when the dependent variable measures some form of internal violent conflict, which is notthe case here (see Vreeland (2008) for details).

16

Page 17: Democracy and Multilateralism: The Case of Vote Buying in ...€¦ · 1A di erence in means test and a Chi-square test of independence strongly con rm the statistical signi cance

rewarded to capture hypotheses about the compliance or recalcitrance of democratic states, and

the U.S. utility for punishing or rewarding to capture the credibility hypothesis. Two variables

specific to the recipient are GDP per capita in 1996 U.S. dollars (Russett and Oneal, 2001a; Oneal

and Russett, 2005), and the political orientation of the executive (Keefer, 2007). We expect the level

of development to affect the domestic incentives for aid recipients to take foreign policy positions,

their vulnerability to U.S. pressure, and the amount of resources required to effectively coerce

them. Similarly, we expect the political orientation of the government to reflect its preferences

to support or oppose the United States and its willingness to resist U.S. pressure, and also to

affect the attractiveness of using sanctions or rewards from the U.S. point of view. To measure

the political orientation of the executive, we create two binary variables that indicate whether a

recipient country’s executive was left of center and whether it was right of center, respectively. The

excluded category includes governments that are centrist and those whose orientations are not clear

(Keefer, 2007).

Interdependence may affect domestic preferences over foreign policy, vulnerability of recipients

to influence, and the cost of attempting to exert influence. We measure interdependence in terms

of bilateral trade flows in millions of 1996 U.S. dollars and a variable that indicates whether the

recipient has an alliance with the United States (Oneal and Russett, 2005). We expect intensive

trade to reflect close diplomatic relations. In addition, countries that are highly dependent on

trade with the United States should be more vulnerable to influence attempts, but interdependence

should also make them more expensive to punish or reward, making them less attractive targets

from the U.S. point of view. Similarly, we expect allies to have similar preferences to the United

States and to be vulnerable to influence attempts because of the intensity of bilateral ties, but to

be unattractive targets for punishment or rewards because of security externalities.13

Finally, our model captures the specific characteristics of particular votes, by including a variable

that indicates whether the United States voted “No.” “Yes” and “No” votes are qualitatively

different, because UNGA proposals almost always pass, so “No” votes find the United States in the

minority, and usually badly isolated. In the late 1970s, after the United States lost control of the

13We also estimate a model with a variable that indicates whether the U.S. president is a Democrat or a Republican.This variable has an insignificant coefficient, and its inclusion does not alter any of the key results.

17

Page 18: Democracy and Multilateralism: The Case of Vote Buying in ...€¦ · 1A di erence in means test and a Chi-square test of independence strongly con rm the statistical signi cance

UNGA agenda to the Group of 77, the United States began to vote “No” on most roll calls, where it

had previously cast a majority of “Yes” votes. The United States votes “No” on almost 75% of State

Department-identified important votes in the sample. We include a binary variable for each vote,

which identifies whether the U.S. votes “Yes” or “No”. Thus, we are essentially including a kind

of vote-specific fixed effect, which allows us to isolate variation in the other regressors within the

substantively comparable vote type. This makes sense as the pattern of punishment and rewards

should vary across vote type, as agreement is more common on “Yes” votes. Accordingly, if voting

is strategic the effect of key variables on recipient voting behavior will also vary with vote type.14

Dependent Variables

Our dependent variables measure whether countries voted with or against the U.S. position on im-

portant votes in the UNGA and whether there were significant deviations of U.S. aid disbursements

from the trend. First, we utilize voting records on important votes and create a binary variable

that is coded 1 if the votes of the United States and the recipient country coincide on a particular

vote, and 0 otherwise.15

The important votes are distributed across fourteen frequently occurring issues and numerous

less frequent ones.16 Many of the important votes are specific to countries that have played a

key role in U.S. foreign policy, e.g., Iraq, while others address policy areas, e.g., WMD. However,

there is no one issue that dominates the set of important votes. While issues related to Israel

and Palestine are among the most frequent, comprising over 15% of the votes, several other issues

receive a similar degree of attention. Human rights issues occur most frequently, comprising almost

25% of the votes.

Next we code one variable to indicate whether the United States punished the recipient with a

14We test whether inclusion of this variable is merited with likelihood ratio tests. LR tests easily show that ourmodel specification is improved with inclusion of the variable. Additionally, inclusion of this variable significantlyimproves the predictive power of the model. However, if we separately estimate regressions on “Yes” and “No” votes,we recover results that are not substantively different.

15We treat “Abstain” as agreement with the United States position, as the United States works hard in many casesto get countries to abstain on particularly sensitive issues. Although we think this is the right choice substantively,we also tried treating abstentions as disagreements and did not find markedly different results. See the appendix forthese alternative results.

16See the appendix for details about the percentage of important votes on each issue.

18

Page 19: Democracy and Multilateralism: The Case of Vote Buying in ...€¦ · 1A di erence in means test and a Chi-square test of independence strongly con rm the statistical signi cance

significant aid reduction, and a second to indicate whether the United States rewarded the recipient

with a significant increase in disbursement. For this purpose we could have used a naive punishment

variable, such as one that takes a value of 1 if aid disbursements in a given year are lower than

aid commitments. However, such a measure would include numerous false positives, because aid

disbursements differ from commitments for a variety of reasons that are unrelated to UN voting.

Instead, we choose a conservative coding strategy to avoid imputing political motivations to random

fluctuations, coding “punishments” and “rewards” only when aid disbursements fall outside the 95%

confidence interval of the level predicted by a forecasting model. We predict aid disbursement for

each country in each year with a lagged dependent variable, country fixed effects model, using the

full time-series of aid disbursement data from 1966–2001. The procedure is fully explained in the

appendix along with a discussion of several potential methodological concerns.17

This approach has important advantages. We use aid commitments to predict disbursements,

so our variables can be interpreted as discretionary deviations by the executive branch from ap-

propriated aid levels.18 In addition, our estimation procedure controls for temporal trends in

disbursement, and the recipient country fixed effects control for unobserved country-level effects

without unnecessarily complicating our main model. Our approach is scale invariant, so the con-

struction of the dependent variable does not lead to spurious inferences, for example, that countries

that receive relatively high levels of aid (e.g., Israel) are more or less likely to receive punishments

or rewards. The model explains the variation in yearly aid disbursements across recipients very

well (R-squared ≈ 0.99), but more variance in aid disbursements remains to be explained for each

recipient over time (R-squared ≈ 0.53). The correlation between predicted and actual aid disburse-

ments is 0.85. Punishments and rewards are rare under our coding procedure, representing 3% and

2.4% of the observations, respectively, because we have defined them conservatively. However, 4.6%

of countries that vote against U.S. positions on important votes are coded as receiving punishment,

and 7% of countries that vote with the United States on important votes receive rewards.

17We replicated the analysis using 90 and 99 percent confidence intervals as robustness checks and derived the samequalitative results. These robustness checks are also included in the appendix.

18A potential concern involves cases of zero aid commitment by the U.S. Specifically, it might be the case thatcodings of rewards tend to occur when aid commitments are zero. However, there are only 38 observations of zerocommitment and reward in the data. In fact, reward is very unlikely in cases of zero aid commitment relative to caseswhere the U.S. has made a commitment. Furthermore, exclusion of these observations does not affect the results.

19

Page 20: Democracy and Multilateralism: The Case of Vote Buying in ...€¦ · 1A di erence in means test and a Chi-square test of independence strongly con rm the statistical signi cance

Results

The results of the full strategic model are presented in Table 1. The model correctly predicts over

84% of the observations, which is an improvement of 34% over predicting the modal category. All

of the columns of coefficients result from the same model, and each column in the table contains

the estimates for either the recipient’s or the U.S. utility for a particular outcome. For example,

the first column contains the estimates for the recipient’s utility for being punished after voting in

disagreement with the United States. As noted above, all estimated coefficients for the recipient

are interpreted relative to the utility for disagreement without consequences, so the coefficients

in the first column identify the cost of losing the aid that is withdrawn, holding voting behavior

constant. The significant positive coefficient for polity (2.75) indicates that punishment is less

harmful to democracies than to autocracies, which rejects the hypothesis that democracies are

more vulnerable than autocracies to U.S. influence attempts. The negative coefficient for polity

in the utility of the recipient for complying and being rewarded (-5.63) is measured relative to

non-compliance, and indicates that democracies are more likely than autocracies to prefer to defy

U.S. preferences. This rejects the hypothesis that democracies are more likely than autocracies to

share U.S. preferences. The coefficient for the United States for punishing is interpreted relative to

the utility of not punishing following recipient disagreement with the U.S., and the coefficient for

rewarding is interpreted relative to the utility for not rewarding the recipient following agreement.

Consequently, these coefficients do not reflect the cost or benefit to the United States of countries’

voting decisions. The positive coefficients for polity (0.13 and 0.05) indicate that the United States

prefers to both punish and reward democracies rather than to autocracies. In what follows, our

discussion of these results draws on the substantive effects reported in Table 2 and Figure 3, because

the substantive effects are not straightforward to interpret from the estimated coefficients in Table

1. We first discuss the U.S. utility for punishing and rewarding, and then discuss recipient behavior.

[Table 1 about here.]

20

Page 21: Democracy and Multilateralism: The Case of Vote Buying in ...€¦ · 1A di erence in means test and a Chi-square test of independence strongly con rm the statistical signi cance

1.1 Punishments and Rewards: U.S. Behavior

Table 2 contains the probability that the United States punishes following disagreement and rewards

following agreement at various levels of the statistically significant variables. The first row of Table

2 shows the conditional probability of punishment or reward when all variables are held at their

median values, and each subsequent row alters the value of one variable to isolate its effect on

the predicted probabilities. Thus, the second row shows the probability of punishment and reward

when the recipient is a highly autocratic country (Polity Score= -9) and all other variables are held

at their median values. Specifically, the third column of Table 2 shows the percentage change in the

probability of punishment relative to the median case (i.e., the first row). Columns 4-5 repeat this

procedure for the probability that the United States rewards the recipient country when it votes in

agreement. Thus, the second row indicates that a highly autocratic recipient is 33% less likely to

be punished if it opposes the United States and 63% less likely to be rewarded if it cooperates than

in the median case (Polity Score= -1). The third row indicates that a democracy (Polity Score=

9) is 69% more likely to be punished when it votes against the United States and 263% more likely

to be rewarded when it votes in support than the median case. The final two columns show the

predicted probabilities that the recipient will vote against the U.S. position (column 6) and the

associated percentage change in probability (column 7).

The baseline predicted probabilities in the first row of Table 2 reflect the fact that the United

States uses aid-based punishments and rewards sparingly, and the fact that we have defined our

reward and punishment variables conservatively. As we expected, the choice of carrots or sticks

depends on whether the United States votes “Yes” or “No.” In the baseline case, when the United

States votes “No” because it is in the minority, the probability that the United States punishes a

country that deviates from the preferred U.S. position is 0.042 when all variables are held at their

median or mean, while the probability that it rewards compliance is only 0.008. In contrast, when

the United States votes in favor of a resolution, it is more likely to reward members of its coalition

(.042) than chastise its opponents (.005). The different U.S. strategy reflects a basic difference in

the kinds of issues on which the United States finds itself in the minority: the 26.5% of important

resolutions that the United States supports are not as contentious as the 73.5% that it resists.

21

Page 22: Democracy and Multilateralism: The Case of Vote Buying in ...€¦ · 1A di erence in means test and a Chi-square test of independence strongly con rm the statistical signi cance

Important votes on which the United States votes “Yes” pass by large margins; on the other hand,

when the United States votes “No,” it is usually badly isolated, so there is great symbolic value to

attracting some support. The United States is five times more likely to use carrots than sticks when

it is trying to promote an important resolution, and eight times more likely to use sticks rather

than carrots when it is isolated and trying to resist one. The distinction between “Yes” and “No”

votes is one that the literature has not previously made, perhaps because it has not distinguished

between punishments and rewards.

[Table 2 about here.]

Our central results reveal that the United States conditions its behavior on regime type in

significant ways. The results in Table 2 indicate that U.S. promises and threats to condition aid on

UN voting are most credible when directed towards democracies. The United States is reluctant

to punish autocracies, perhaps because they are more dependent on aid flows to maintain power

(Bueno de Mesquita et al., 2003; Bueno de Mesquita and Smith, 2010), and only receive aid in

the first place if they are important to U.S. foreign policy (Schraeder, Hook and Taylor, 1998).

The United States is also reluctant to reward autocracies with increased aid, perhaps because

giving aid to dictators is unpopular in Congress. These findings stand in contrast to the argument

of Bueno de Mesquita and Smith (2007) that U.S. vote-buying strategy is directed primarily at

authoritarian countries because their narrow bases of support make it less expensive to purchase

policy concessions from them. If this were the case, autocracies should be most likely to be punished

when they oppose the United States and rewarded when they comply; but we find that democracies

are more likely to be punished for non-cooperation and rewarded for cooperation. It is a striking

finding that the United States is less nimble in its use of aid to reward and punish autocracies,

and as we discuss below, this makes them less supportive of U.S. positions. The present analysis

cannot offer a direct test of alternative mechanisms to explain this finding, but our conjecture is

that aid to autocracies is tied to particular, long-term policy goals such as regional stability or

military basing rights, and is provided primarily to prevent regime change. If this is the case, it

could be excessively costly to use this aid to influence UN voting.

22

Page 23: Democracy and Multilateralism: The Case of Vote Buying in ...€¦ · 1A di erence in means test and a Chi-square test of independence strongly con rm the statistical signi cance

[Figure 3 about here.]

The nonlinear effects of the variables allow us to probe a bit further. Figures 3(a) and 3(b) plot

the effects of varying development and regime type simultaneously.19 The estimates indicate that

a low level of development makes punishments more likely and rewards less likely. The marginal

effects reported in Table 2 indicate that when all other variables are at their medians, poor countries

are two-and-a-half times as likely to be punished as middle-income countries when they oppose the

U.S. position. This suggests that punishments are less costly to apply to weak countries, which are

unable to retaliate, and the United States prefers to use positive incentives with more developed

countries that are better able to resist. Figure 3(a) illustrates the effect of per capita GDP on

punishment while allowing polity scores to vary, and also illustrates the effect of democracy, which

makes punishment more likely. Plotting the curves together reveals an important interaction effect.

The slope of the effect of democracy on punishment is much steeper when countries are poor,

indicating that poverty is a reason for the United States to be more reluctant to punish authoritarian

countries rather than democratic ones. This may be because relatively poor autocratic regimes have

high aid dependency ratios (aid to GDP) and may be vulnerable to political instability if aid is

cut off. Consequently, this finding suggests that the U.S. disinclination to punish authoritarian

countries is attributable to concerns about political stability.

Rewards have a similar interpretation, which reflects the fact that rewards and punishments

are strategic substitutes. Table 2 indicates that the median middle-income country is almost twice

as likely as a poor country to be rewarded when it offers support, and consolidated democracies

are two-and-a-half times more likely to be rewarded than consolidated autocracies. Figure 3(b)

demonstrates that the interaction between these effects is important. Poor countries and autoc-

racies are unlikely to be rewarded under any circumstances, but the effect of development on the

probability of being rewarded increases rapidly as countries become more democratic, and the ef-

fect of being democratic increases rapidly as countries become more developed. This suggests a

political interpretation. Democratic leaders often have electoral incentives to oppose U.S. policy,

and as the level of development of their countries increases, they become increasingly resistant to

19Because this is a non-linear model, the marginal effects of our independent variables vary across the ranges ofthe other covariates. GDP per capita is measured in thousands of constant U.S. dollars.

23

Page 24: Democracy and Multilateralism: The Case of Vote Buying in ...€¦ · 1A di erence in means test and a Chi-square test of independence strongly con rm the statistical signi cance

U.S. pressure. As a result, using negative incentives becomes less attractive, and rewards increase

because they represent a substitute for sanctions.

The case of Nicaragua in the early 1990’s illustrates the way in which the United States uses aid

disbursements to punish and reward relatively poor democracies. In 1990, Nicaragua conducted

multiparty elections that were won by the conservative opposition party, led by Violeta Chamorro.

Since Nicaragua was a poor democracy (Nicaragua’s Polity score was 6 in 1990), we expect both

punishments and rewards to be more likely than in the average country. Nicaragua’s GDP per capita

hovered around $2000 in the early 1990s, which is well below the mean of $5000 in the sample,

however, so our model predicts a preference for punishments over rewards. In 1991 the Chamorro

government voted in support of the United States on resolution R/46/82A, which pertained to

the Middle East peace process, and was rewarded. The United States had taken note of a much

more cooperative Nicaraguan government (Serafino, 1990), and subsequently released additional

aid funds after observing cooperation in several areas as well as a rare instance of cooperation in

the UNGA.

In the following year, the Chamorro government took a more oppositional stance relative to U.S.

interests in the UNGA, voting against the U.S. position on all but one important vote. Chamorro’s

opposition to U.S. positions, including on votes involving Cuba, was apparently intended as part

of an effort to build bridges to the Sandinista opposition. The sole exception was a resolution that

the United States supported on the situation in Bosnia, which passed unanimously. In response to

this lack of cooperation, the United States reversed its aid policy towards Nicaragua in 1992 and

punished the Chamorro government with significant aid reductions.20 The same pattern continued

into 1993, with Nicaragua voting against a number of important resolutions and the United States

continuing to withhold aid. This reversal of fortune was particularly striking, given the history of

U.S. opposition to the preceding Sandinista government only a few years before.

Pakistan is a good case to illustrate the effects of regime changes on U.S. aid strategy, because

it experienced a transition to democracy and another back to autocracy within the time period we

study. Pakistan was autocratic from 1984–1987 (i.e., Polity score of -4 to -7), was democratic from

20“Forgotten Central America,” The New York Times, May 26, 1992: 16; Clifford Krauss, “U.S. Cooling TowardSandinistas’ Successors,” The New York Times, September 3, 1992: 3.

24

Page 25: Democracy and Multilateralism: The Case of Vote Buying in ...€¦ · 1A di erence in means test and a Chi-square test of independence strongly con rm the statistical signi cance

1988–1998 under Benazir Bhutto and Nawaz Sharif (i.e., Polity score of 7 to 8), and reverted to

autocracy after a coup led by Pervez Musharraf in 1999 (i.e., Polity score of -6). The expectation

of our model is that Pakistan should be punished and rewarded more frequently while a democracy

than while it was authoritarian. Figure 2 shows that this is indeed the case. The United States

punished or rewarded Pakistan in only one of seven years of non-democratic government, while it

punished (6 times) or rewarded (3 times) Pakistan during nine of the eleven years in which it was

a democracy.21

Pakistan was a good candidate for punishment because it frequently voted against the U.S.

position on important issues. Pakistan voted with the United States position only 24% of the

time, well below the sample mean of 35%. In the three years in which Pakistan was rewarded it

voted with the United States on several important votes that pertained to the Israeli-Palestinian

conflict (e.g., R/44/40A in 1988), and sided with the United States almost 35% of the time in

1988, 1991, and 1993. In contrast, during the six years in which it was punished, it voted with the

United States only 23% of the time on important votes. Several of the votes identified as important

by the United States during the mid-1990s condemned nuclear testing of the kind Pakistan was

conducting. For example, Pakistan voted against R/53/77G in 1997, which was one of the most

popular U.S.-supported resolutions, opposed by only 8 other countries.

1.2 The Strategy of UN Voting: Recipient Behavior

We now turn to a discussion of recipient behavior. The model allows for voting behavior to be

strategic, because voting decisions precede aid disbursements. Consequently, vote choices depend

both on governments’ underlying preferences and on U.S. disbursement strategies. The final two

columns of Table 2 present the substantive effect of each regressor on the probability that the

recipient votes in opposition to the U.S. position, which can be thought of as the net effect of

the regressor through the mechanisms of preferences, vulnerability and credibility.22 The results

21Note that 2001, when Pakistan received substantial aid because of the U.S. war with Afghanistan, is not codedas a reward because Pakistan’s voting was uncooperative.

22Note that the changes in probability are modest when expressed as a percentage because we start from a highbaseline probability of disagreement (0.880). If we focused on the probability of agreement for “No” votes, the

25

Page 26: Democracy and Multilateralism: The Case of Vote Buying in ...€¦ · 1A di erence in means test and a Chi-square test of independence strongly con rm the statistical signi cance

Figure 2: Aid Flows to Pakistan, 1984–2001

1984 1986 1988 1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000

0100

200

300

400

500

Year

Aid

Dis

burs

emen

ts in

Mill

ions

of D

olla

rs

Actual Disbursement

95% Confidence Bounds

Punishment

Reward

provide ample evidence that U.S. influence strategies affect voting. For example, countries that

trade extensively with the United States tend to have more closely aligned preferences, but they

nevertheless vote more strongly in opposition because they are less likely to be punished.23

The results in Table 2 indicate that opposition to the United States is widespread on votes that

it designates as important, but varies substantially depending on the U.S. position on particular

issues. As we discussed above, the baseline probability that an aid recipient votes against the United

States when the U.S. position is “No” is 0.88, while the probability that an aid recipient opposes

a U.S. “Yes” vote is only 0.03.24 The United States voted “No” on approximately three-quarters

of all votes that it defined as important. When the United States votes “Yes,” it finds itself in

the majority. These resolutions cover issues on which the United States takes less controversial

positions and is able to craft a compromise that it is able to support. Since voting is very different

on “Yes” and “No” votes, it is important to control for the U.S. position, which determines the

level of recipient opposition and the U.S. propensity to punish and reward recipients.

percentage change for the same variables would be considerably larger, because they would start from a low baselineprobability.

23Turing to Table 1, the positive coefficient for Trade with the United States in the recipient’s utility for complyingand being rewarded (11.46) indicates that substantial trade partners are more likely to prefer to comply. Tradepartners are more vulnerable to punishment (-15.86), but are less likely to the punished (-0.05), and the net effect isthat substantial trade partners are more oppositional in spite of their more closely aligned preferences and greatervulnerability.

24Since “No” is the median position of the United States, the first row represents a “No” vote with all othervariables at their median.

26

Page 27: Democracy and Multilateralism: The Case of Vote Buying in ...€¦ · 1A di erence in means test and a Chi-square test of independence strongly con rm the statistical signi cance

As Table 2 indicates, democracies are less likely than autocracies to oppose U.S. positions in the

UNGA. We are now in a position to answer the question with which we began: why are democracies

more supportive? Is this because democracies are more sympathetic to U.S. policy positions,

because democracies are more vulnerable to U.S. influence attempts, or because U.S. influence

attempts are more credible among the set of democracies? Our estimates indicate that democracies’

preferences are inherently more oppositional than authoritarian governments’ preferences. The

negative coefficient of -5.63 for polity in the government’s utility for being rewarded for compliance

in Table 1 indicates that as a country becomes democratic, the net benefits of opposing the United

States rather than complying increase. (The reference category is voting in opposition with no

consequences.) This rejects the hypothesis of coincidence of preferences, and is consistent with the

interpretation that democracies in developing countries are more oppositional because their publics

are critical of U.S. positions, and democratically elected leaders have incentives to cast symbolic

votes against the United States. The fact that we found a strong positive relationship between GDP

per capita and the recipient’s estimated utility for compliance also supports this interpretation. On

the other hand, democracies are less susceptible than authoritarian governments to punishments:

the positive coefficient of 2.75 in the first column of Table 1 indicates that the cost of punishment

declines as polity increases, holding voting behavior constant. This rejects the hypothesis that

democracies are more vulnerable to U.S. influence attempts than autocracies. To the contrary, it

supports the inference that autocracies are more vulnerable, because their leaders use foreign aid

as an integral part of their strategy for maintaining power. The only reason for democracies to be

more compliant than autocracies, in spite of more oppositional preferences and lower vulnerability

to sanctions, is that democracies are more likely to be punished or rewarded for their votes. This is

consistent with our argument that autocracies cannot generally be punished because the aid they

receive is tied to broader U.S. strategic objectives—Egypt under Mubarak was a classic example—

and it is much more palatable to reward democratic countries.

This logic is reflected in a non-monotonic relationship between polity and UNGA voting. Non-

monotonicity occurs in the model because of countervailing strategic incentives, and in this case,

U.S. incentives to avoid punishing or rewarding autocracies interact with the preferences of aid

27

Page 28: Democracy and Multilateralism: The Case of Vote Buying in ...€¦ · 1A di erence in means test and a Chi-square test of independence strongly con rm the statistical signi cance

recipients. The result is a non-monotonic relationship between regime type and votes against U.S.

positions, which further depends on the recipient’s level of development. The graphs in the lower

half of Figure 3 depict the relationship between wealth, regime type, and the probability of voting

in opposition to the United States. Figure 3(c) depicts the case of “Yes” votes. Aid recipients

generally support the U.S. position on important “Yes” votes, but relatively poor countries are

increasingly likely to vote against the United States if they are not democratic.25 Opposition

by authoritarian governments is maximized among very poor countries, which are most likely to

strongly oppose U.S. preferences. However, the effect of polity is non-monotonic. Very authoritar-

ian poor countries are highly compliant, because they have few institutional incentives to oppose

U.S. positions. Opposition increases and reaches a peak among weakly consolidated authoritar-

ian countries (Polity score=-4), a range in which punishments and rewards remain very unlikely,

but where public opinion has become more relevant to regime survival. As these regimes become

more democratic, however, the incentives created by the increasing probability of punishments and

rewards come to overwhelm the effects of increasing opposition and decreasing vulnerability to in-

fluence, and the probability of opposing U.S. positions again declines to very low levels. This effect

is due to strategic voting. Figure 3(d) depicts a similar non-monotonic effect in the case of “No”

votes.

Does Vote Buying Change with the End of the Cold War?

Until this point we have presented results of a model that pools data from 1985 to 2001, but we now

split the sample in order to ask whether the political economy of UN voting changed significantly

with the end of the Cold War. The end of the Cold War might not be expected to substantially

change the incentives of aid recipients, but it represented a sea change in U.S. geopolitical strategy,

so it would be surprising if there were no adjustments in aid policy. Indeed, it is often argued

that foreign aid became more development-oriented with the end of the Cold War. We divided our

25The net effects are reported in Table 2, but their interpretation depends on the coefficients in Table 1. Returningto Table 1, the positive coefficient for Recipient GDP in the recipient’s utility for complying and being rewarded(4.42) indicates that poor countries are more likely to prefer to oppose U.S. positions, in spite of the cost of forgoingrewards. Punishment is painful to poor countries (GDP per capita coefficient=9.87), and punishment is more likely(coefficient for U.S. utility for punishment=-0.09), but poor countries nevertheless resist U.S. positions at higher ratesthan middle-income aid recipients.

28

Page 29: Democracy and Multilateralism: The Case of Vote Buying in ...€¦ · 1A di erence in means test and a Chi-square test of independence strongly con rm the statistical signi cance

sample into Cold War (1985-89) and post-Cold War (1990-2001) subsamples to test the robustness

of our results, and found several differences in the samples that shed light on the interpretation of

vote buying in the United Nations.26 Our main findings remain robust across both time periods,

so we present the full results in the appendix and describe the key differences here.

[Table 3 about here.]

There are no significant differences in our estimates of recipient preferences between the post-

Cold War sample and the pooled model, which indicates that none of the pooled results described

above were driven by peculiarities of the Cold War period.27 Comparing the estimates for the Cold

War and post-Cold War periods, standard errors are larger in the smaller, Cold War sample, leading

to fewer significant coefficients. Most of the signs of coefficients are unchanged; a few coefficients

change sign as we move back to the Cold War period, but none of these is significant. These results

provide reassurance about our interpretation of the pooled results above.

On the other hand, the U.S. vote-buying strategy changed in several significant ways after the

Cold War. To illustrate these effects, Table 3 presents the marginal effects of key regressors on

U.S. punishment strategies during and after the Cold War. First, U.S. treatment of allies changed

sharply. The United States was slightly more likely to punish allies than non-allies in the pooled

sample, although this coefficient was not significant. During the Cold War, however, the United

States was significantly less willing to punish its allies, which reflected the constraints imposed by

a tense global rivalry with the Soviet Union. Alliance with the United States during the Cold War

reduced the probability of punishment after voting against the United States by over two-thirds.

After the end of the Cold War, by contrast, the United States became significantly more willing to

punish allies than non-allies, as systemic constraints relaxed. In the post-Cold War era, allies were

60 percent more likely to be punished than non-allies if they voted in opposition. The pooled results

concealed a sharp change in U.S. policy. During the Cold War the United States felt compelled to

woo its allies; after the Cold War, it expected its allies to tow the line or face the consequences.

26We also code 1991 as being the last year of the Cold War and find very similar results. See the supplementalappendix for details.

27We also estimate a model in which a Cold War variable is interacted with each regressor, and find similar results.We focus on the split-sample approach here as the full interactions model makes interpretation of a somewhatcomplicated model even more complicated. See Ai and Norton (2003) or Braumoeller (2004) for details.

29

Page 30: Democracy and Multilateralism: The Case of Vote Buying in ...€¦ · 1A di erence in means test and a Chi-square test of independence strongly con rm the statistical signi cance

During the Cold War, the United States was much more willing to punish left-leaning govern-

ments than either right-leaning or centrist governments. Left-leaning governments were 125 percent

more likely to be punished if they voted against a U.S. position than the baseline centrist category,

and they were twelve times more likely to be punished than right-leaning governments. During the

post-Cold War era, in contrast, leftist governments were treated no differently than right-leaning

governments, and were actually less likely to be punished for defying the United States than cen-

trist ones. The reduced salience of left-leaning political orientation after the end of the Cold War

reflected the collapse of the left as a global challenge to the capitalist economic model. Finally,

there is a marked shift after the end of the Cold War in the effect of wealth. During the Cold War,

the effect of wealth on the U.S. punishment strategy is only marginally significant, but it appears

to be the case that wealthier countries are punished at a higher rate than poorer ones. On the

other hand, after the Cold War poor countries are over seven times more likely to be punished than

middle-income countries if they vote against U.S. positions. It is logical to target poor countries,

since they are more dependent on foreign aid than wealthier countries, and their behavior indicates

that they are more vulnerable to influence attempts. The fact that U.S. strategy did not target

poor countries in this way until the end of the Cold War suggests that the Cold War competition

for the allegiance of the developing world undermined the credibility of U.S. influence attempts.

Our central result about the role of democracy does not change with the end of the Cold

War. In both the Cold War and the post-Cold War subsamples, as in the pooled model, the

United States is much more likely to punish and reward democracies than autocracies. There is no

statistical difference between the coefficients in the separate samples. This suggests that, although

many other features of U.S. foreign policy shifted dramatically with the end of the Cold War, the

relationship between U.S. foreign aid and authoritarian regimes did not. Certain authoritarian

regimes lost U.S. support because the Cold War ended, but the same logic applies during the Cold

War and after: autocratic regimes that receive U.S. foreign aid do so because they play key roles

in U.S. foreign policy. Consequently, they cannot be punished when they defy U.S. preferences.

The U.S. public is sympathetic towards democracies, so democracies receive foreign aid that is not

critical to foreign policy and can be used strategically to buy votes. Furthermore, it is politically

30

Page 31: Democracy and Multilateralism: The Case of Vote Buying in ...€¦ · 1A di erence in means test and a Chi-square test of independence strongly con rm the statistical signi cance

acceptable to give democracies additional aid when that becomes expedient, so it is credible to offer

to increase aid as an inducement. Consequently, it is more credible for the United States to punish

and reward democracies.

A Direct Test of Strategic Voting

The results we have presented provide substantial evidence that recipient countries vote strategically

in anticipation of aid-based punishments and rewards. However, it is possible to directly test the

proposition that the relationship between the substantive regressors and recipient voting behavior

is affected by strategic interaction in the way that we propose. Does recipient voting behavior

really depend on subsequent U.S. aid disbursement decisions? The obvious way to assess this is to

use comparative model testing methods to compare the strategic model to a non-strategic model of

recipient voting behavior that uses the same regressors (Clarke, 2001, 2003). Such a test has two key

implications. From a methodological perspective, a comparative model test will assess whether the

additional machinery that the strategic model requires improves model fit enough to be justified,

given our data. From a substantive perspective, it represents a direct test of the hypothesis that

recipient voting behavior depends on expected punishments and rewards.28

In our case, we can rely on a simple likelihood-ratio test, which is appropriate for nested

models. The model presented in Table 1 assumes that the recipient conditions its vote choice on its

anticipated effect on the U.S. aid disbursement decision. However, if it is the case that the recipient’s

voting decision is not strategic (or, equivalently, is unaffected by aid disbursement decisions), we do

not need to condition its choice on the expected response of the United States. Furthermore, if this

non-strategic model is more appropriate, the results that we attribute to strategic interaction could

be spurious. In this alternative model of recipient voting behavior we include the same substantive

regressors included in the recipient’s utilities above without conditioning their influence on U.S.

behavior. Thus, the restricted model is a logit model with each of the regressors in table 1 included

once. This simpler model is nested within the strategic estimator as the full model can be reduced

28Alternative strategic models could be formulated that might fit the data better. However, from our perspectivethe substantively interesting question is whether threatened punishments and rewards are effective at influencingUNGA voting. Therefore, the relevant null hypothesis is a model using the same covariates that assumes that this isnot the case.

31

Page 32: Democracy and Multilateralism: The Case of Vote Buying in ...€¦ · 1A di erence in means test and a Chi-square test of independence strongly con rm the statistical signi cance

to the restricted model with a set of linear restrictions (Clarke, 2001, 727–728). The likelihood

ratio test comparing the two models rejects the null hypothesis that the restricted model performs

equally well at a high level of confidence (p < 0.005).29 Thus, we conclude that the non-strategic

model is indeed misspecified, as we assumed at the outset, and that a properly specified model

must include strategic interaction. Substantively, this means that U.S. aid policy has a significant

effect on voting in the United Nations General Assembly.

The comparative model test also allows us to assess where in the data our strategic model gives

us greater leverage. In order to assess this, we classify observations according to whether the strate-

gic or the non-strategic model makes a more accurate prediction of the observed outcome. The

strategic model makes more accurate predictions in 61 percent of the observations. An additional

implication of our explanation for strategic voting by democracies is that a strategic model should

particularly improve the fit for democratic countries, because democratic countries’ votes are af-

fected more by anticipated punishments and rewards than are the votes of autocratic countries.

Table 4 presents a cross-tabulation of the results, and we find that this is indeed the case. The

strategic model improved the fit for 52 percent of observations of non-democracies. On the other

hand, over 75 percent of predictions for democratic observations improved.

We used the case of Pakistan to illustrate our argument in an earlier section, arguing that

Pakistan was a case in which punishments and rewards occurred much more frequently during

democratic regime years than during autocratic years, so it seems appropriate to return to that

example here.30 We find an improvement in our predictions in 60 percent of non-democratic

observations using our strategic model, but we find an improvement in 98.9 percent of observations

in which Pakistan had a democratic regime. Since the only difference between the models relates

to predicted voting behavior, this indicates that Pakistan’s UN voting record was in fact more

consistently influenced by the U.S. vote-buying strategy during the democratic years.

29The log-likelihood for the strategic version of the recipient vote choice model model is -4171.45, while the log-likelihood for the restricted non-strategic model is -4220.37. Since the strategic model has 8 additional parameters, thelikelihood ratio test statistic is 97.83 with 8 degrees of freedom. This indicates that the strategic model outperformsthe non-strategic version, as the Chi-Square distributed test statistic of 97.83 is significant at any conventional levelof statistical significance. The critical value for significance at the 0.005 level is 21.96.

30The data are presented in the supplemental appendix.

32

Page 33: Democracy and Multilateralism: The Case of Vote Buying in ...€¦ · 1A di erence in means test and a Chi-square test of independence strongly con rm the statistical signi cance

Conclusions

A simple strategic model reveals layers of interaction that lie beneath the radar of conventional

analysis. The empirical analysis leads to several important substantive findings. Our central finding

regards the relationship between democracy and support for U.S. foreign policy. We started with

the observation that democratic countries vote with the United States more often than autocratic

countries on important votes. Is this because democracies have inherently aligned preferences, be-

cause democracies are more vulnerable to U.S. pressure than autocracies, or because the United

States punishes and rewards democracies more frequently than autocracies? These alternative in-

terpretations have quite different normative implications, and it is impossible to distinguish among

them without a model that allows recipient governments to strategically alter their votes in antic-

ipation of punishments or rewards.

Thus, a key advantage of modeling the strategic relationship between voting and aid flows is

that it is possible to estimate important quantities of interest that are not directly observable.

Consequently, it is possible to sort out causal explanations that would otherwise be observation-

ally equivalent. Our results are inconsistent with the first two possibilities: democracies in the

developing world are in fact more critical of U.S. positions in the United Nations than autocracies,

probably because they are sensitive to public opinion, and they are less vulnerable than autocra-

cies to U.S. influence attempts, presumably because foreign aid plays a less central role in regime

survival. Nevertheless, democracies comply more with U.S. voting preferences than do autocracies,

because the United States is more likely to carry out threats and promises to manipulate aid if the

target country is a democracy. This is attributable to the credibility problems that frustrate U.S.

efforts to link aid to autocratic countries with UN voting.

These findings have profound normative implications, and they can only be disheartening for

students of U.S. foreign policy or of multilateral institutions. In a parliament of parliaments and

dictators, it is disturbing that the United States disproportionately uses changes in aid disburse-

ments to manipulate the voting behavior of poor democracies. Further, to the degree that the

legitimacy of UN decisions depends on the democratic legitimacy of its members, it is unfortunate

that U.S. foreign policy systematically coerces the votes of democracies.

33

Page 34: Democracy and Multilateralism: The Case of Vote Buying in ...€¦ · 1A di erence in means test and a Chi-square test of independence strongly con rm the statistical signi cance

On the other hand, while our results indicate that U.S. policy influences countries’ votes, they

also point to the limits of that influence. While the important resolutions that the United States

supports generally pass, these represent a small minority of important votes, and resolutions that

the United States opposes almost always pass as well. In addition to democracy, our results

suggest that economic development is a fault line in the General Assembly. The poorest members

of the General Assembly, although they are most vulnerable to sanctions, are nevertheless the

most resistant to U.S. pressure to conform. Poor countries appear to resist because they have

strongly held preferences that clash with U.S. objectives. Similarly, countries that trade intensively

with the United States are highly vulnerable to U.S. influence attempts, but are nevertheless more

resistant to U.S. influence. In this case, however, resistance is not due to deep-seated conflict of

interest, because countries that trade with the United States tend to share U.S. preferences. Instead,

countries that trade intensively vote against the United States more frequently because it is too

costly for the United States to link their votes in the UN to punishments or rewards. The fact that

many countries defy U.S. pressure indicates that the votes are regarded as sufficiently important

to justify bearing some costs, and they therefore retain substantial informational content.

Nevertheless, an important methodological implication of our findings is to draw into question

the use of UNGA voting as a straightforward index of states’ preferences (Gartzke, 2005; Russett

and Oneal, 2001b; Stone, 2004). UN voting records are a uniquely informative data source on

the policy preferences of most of the world’s countries on a wide range of issues, and previous

scholarship has frequently treated UN voting either as a measure of preferences or as an arena for

vote buying. Our innovation is to use a strategic statistical model that explicitly allows for the

possibility that voting is strategic, and we find that the U.S. policy of influencing important UNGA

votes with aid disbursements has important effects on the voting behavior of recipient countries. A

model specification test rejects the hypothesis that voting decisions are unaffected by subsequent

aid disbursement strategies with a high degree of confidence (p=.005). This result rejects the

hypothesis that UN voting on issues of political significance to major aid donors is simply a sincere

expression of country preferences.

34

Page 35: Democracy and Multilateralism: The Case of Vote Buying in ...€¦ · 1A di erence in means test and a Chi-square test of independence strongly con rm the statistical signi cance

References

Ai, Chunrong and Edward C. Norton. 2003. “Interaction Terms in Logit and Probit Models.”Economic Letters 80(1):123–129.

Alesina, Alberto and Beatrice Weder. 2002. “Do Corrupt Governments Receive Less Foreign Aid?”The American Economic Review 92(4):1126–1138.

Alesina, Alberto and David Dollar. 2000. “Who Gives Aid to Whom and Why?” Journal ofEconomic Growth 5(March):33–63.

Andersen, Thomas Barnebeck, Thomas Harr and Finn Tarp. 2006. “On US Politics and IMFLending.” European Economic Review 50(7):1843–1862.

Apodaca, Clair and Michael Stohl. 1999. “United States human rights policy and foreign assis-tance.” International Studies Quarterly 43(1):185–198.

Barro, Robert J. and Jong-Wha Lee. 2005. “IMF Programs: Who is Chosen and What are theEffects?” Journal of Monetary Economics 52:1245–1269.

Bas, Muhammet Ali, Curtis S. Signorino and Robert W. Walker. 2007. “Statistical BackwardsInduction: A Simple Method for Estimating Recursive Strategic Models.” Political Analysis16:21–41.

Bennett, D. Scott and Allan C. Stam. 2000. “Research Design and Estimator Choices in the Analysisof Interstate Dyads: When Decisions Matter.” Journal of Conflict Resolution 44(5):653–685.

Boone, Peter. 1996. “Politics and the Effectiveness of Foreign Aid.” European Economic Review40:289–329.

Braumoeller, Bear F. 2004. “Hypothesis Testing and Multiplicative Interaction Terms.” Interna-tional Organization 58(4):807–820.

Bueno de Mesquita, Bruce and Alastair Smith. 2007. “Foreign Aid and Policy Concessions.” Journalof Conflict Resolution 51(2):251–284.

Bueno de Mesquita, Bruce and Alastair Smith. 2009. “A Political Economy of Aid.” InternationalOrganization 63(2):309–340.

Bueno de Mesquita, Bruce and Alastair Smith. 2010. “Leader Survival, Revolutions, and the Natureof Government Finance.” American Journal of Political Science 54(4):936–950.

Bueno de Mesquita, Bruce, Alastair Smith, Randolph M. Siverson and James D. Morrow. 2003.The Logic of Political Survival. Boston, MA: MIT Press.

Carrubba, Clifford J., Amy Yuen and Christopher Zorn. 2007. “In Defense of Comparative Statics:Specifying Empirical Tests of Models of Strategic Interaction.” Political Analysis 15(4):465–482.

Cashel-Cordo, Peter and Steven Craig. 1997. “Donor Preferences and Recipient Fiscal Behavior:A Simultaneous Analysis of Foreign Aid.” Economic Inquiry 35:653–671.

35

Page 36: Democracy and Multilateralism: The Case of Vote Buying in ...€¦ · 1A di erence in means test and a Chi-square test of independence strongly con rm the statistical signi cance

Cheibub, Jose Antonio, Jennifer Gandhi and James Raymond Vreeland. 2010. “Democracy andDictatorship Revisited.” Public Choice 143(1-2):67–101.

Clarke, Kevin. 2001. “Testing Nonnested Models of International Relations: Reevaluating Realism.”The American Journal of Political Science 45(3):724–744.

Clarke, Kevin. 2003. “Nonparametric Model Discrimination in International Relations.” Journalof Conflict Resolution 47(1):72–93.

Collier, Paul and David Dollar. 2002. “Aid Allocation and Poverty Reduction.” European EconomicReview 46(8):1475–1500.

Demirel-Pegg, Tijen and James Moskowitz. 2009. “U.S. aid allocation: The nexus of human rights,democracy, and development.” Journal of Peace Research 46(2):181–198.

Dixon, William J. 1994. “Democracy and the Peaceful Settlement of International Conflict.” Amer-ican Political Science Review 88(1):14–32.

Dreher, Axel, Jan-Egbert Sturm and James Raymond Vreeland. 2009. “Development Aid andInternational Politics: Does Membership on the UN Security Council Influence World BankDecisions?” Journal of Development Economics 88(1):1–18.

Dreher, Axel, Peter Nunnenkamp and Rainer Thiele. 2008. “Does US aid buy UN general assemblyvotes? A disaggregated analysis.” Public Choice 136(1–2):139–164.

Fearon, James. 1994. “Domestic Political Audiences and the Escalation of International Disputes.”American Political Science Review 88:577–592.

Gartzke, Erik. 2005. The Affinity of Nations. http://www.columbia.edu/ eg589/datasets.htm.

Gartzke, Erik. 2007. “The Capitalist Peace.” American Journal of Political Science 51(1):166–191.

Hufbauer, Gary, Jeffrey Schott, Kimberly Elliott and Barbara Oegg. 2007. Economic SanctionsReconsidered (3rd edition). Washington, DC: Peterson Institute for International Economics.

Huth, Paul K. and Todd L. Allee. 2002. “Domestic Political Accountability and the Escalation andSettlement of International Disputes.” Journal of Conflict Resolution 46(6):754–790.

Keefer, Philip. 2007. “Database of Political Institutions.” Development Research Group, The WorldBank .

Kegley, Charles W. and Steven W. Hook. 1991. “U.S. Foreign Aid and U.N. Voting: Did Reagan’sLinkage Strategy Buy Deference or Defiance?” International Studies Quarterly 35(3)(3):295–312.

Keohane, Robert, Stephen Macedo and Andrew Moravscik. 2009. “Democracy-Enhancing Multi-lateralism.” International Organization 63(1):1–31.

Kilby, Christopher. 2010. “An Empirical Assessment of Informal Influence in the World Bank.”Unpublished Manuscript, Villanova University .

Kuziemko, Ilyana and Eric Werker. 2006. “How Much Is a Seat on the Security Council Worth?Foreign Aid and Bribery at the United Nations.” Journal of Political Economy 114(5):905–930.

36

Page 37: Democracy and Multilateralism: The Case of Vote Buying in ...€¦ · 1A di erence in means test and a Chi-square test of independence strongly con rm the statistical signi cance

Lai, Brian and Dan Reiter. 2000. “Democracy, Political Similarity, and International Alliances,1816–1992.” Journal of Conflict Resolution 44(2):203–227.

Lake, David A. 2002. “Rational Extremism: Understanding Terrorism in the Twenty-first Century.”International Organization Dialog-IO:15–29.

Leventoglu, Bahar and Ahmer Tarar. 2005. “Prenegotiation Public Commitment in Domestic andInternational Bargaining.” American Political Science Review 99(3):419–433.

Maizels, Alfred and Machiko K. Nissanke. 1984. “Motivations for Aid to Developing Countries.”World Development 12(9):879–900.

Mansfield, Edward D., Helen V. Milner and B. Peter Rosendorff. 2000. “Free to Trade: Democracies,Autocracies, and International Trade.” American Political Science Review 94(2):305–321.

McLean, Elena V. and Taehee Whang. 2010. “Friends or Foes? Major Trading Partners and theSuccess of Economic Sanctions.” International Studies Quarterly 54(2):427–447.

Milner, Helen and Dustin Tingley. 2010. “The Political Economy of U.S. Foreign Aid: AmericanLegislators and the Domestic Politics of Aid.” Economics and Politics 22(2):200–232.

Milner, Helen and Dustin Tingley. 2011. “The Choice for Multilateralism: Foreign Aid and Amer-ican Foreign Policy.” Working Paper .

Mitchell, Sara McLaughlin and Paul R. Hensel. 2007. “International Institutions and Compliancewith Agreements.” American Journal of Political Science 51(4):721–737.

Neumayer, Eric. 2003. “Do Human Rights Matter in Bilateral Aid Allocation: A QuantitativeAnalysis of 21 Donor Countries.” Social Science Quarterly 84(3):650–666.

Oatley, Thomas and Jason Yackee. 2004. “American Interests and IMF Lending.” InternationalPolitics 41 (September):415–429.

Oneal, John and Bruce Russett. 2005. “Rule of Three, Let It Be? When More Really Is Better.”Conflict Management and Peace Science 22:293–310.

Pevehouse, Jon C. 2002. “Democracy from the Outside-In? International Organizations and De-mocratization.” International Organization 60(1):137–167.

Pevehouse, Jon C. and Edward Mansfield. 2006. “Democratization and International Organiza-tions.” International Organization 56(3):515–549.

Poe, Steven C. and James Meernik. 1995. “U.S. military aid in the 1980s: A global analysis.”Journal of Peace Research 32(4):399–411.

Putnam, Robert D. 1988. “Diplomacy and Domestic Politics.” International Organization42(3):427–61.

Rai, Kul B. 1980. “Foreign Aid and Voting in the UN General Assembly.” Journal of Peace Research17(3):269–277.

37

Page 38: Democracy and Multilateralism: The Case of Vote Buying in ...€¦ · 1A di erence in means test and a Chi-square test of independence strongly con rm the statistical signi cance

Russett, Bruce. 1993. Grasping the Democratic Peace: Principles for a Post-Cold War World.Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

Russett, Bruce and John Oneal. 2001a. Triangulating Peace: Democracy, Interdependence, andInternational Organizations. New York, NY: W.W. Norton.

Russett, Bruce and John Oneal. 2001b. Triangulating Peace: Democracy, Interdependence, andInternational Organizations. New York, NY: Norton.

Schraeder, Peter J., Steven W. Hook and Bruce Taylor. 1998. “Clarifying the Foreign Aid Puzzle: AComparison of American, Japanese, French and Swedish Aid Flows.” World Politics 50(2):294–323.

Schultz, Kenneth A. 2001. Democracy and Coercive Diplomacy. Cambridge, UK: CambridgeUniversity Press.

Serafino, Nina M. 1990. “Nicaraguan Elections and Transition: Issues for U.S. Policy.” Congres-sional Research Service Report for Congress 90-187F.

Signorino, Curtis S. 1999. “Strategic Interaction and the Statistical Analysis of InternationalConflict.” American Political Science Review 93(2):279–297.

Signorino, Curtis S. 2003. “Structure and Uncertainty in Discrete Choice Models.” Political Analysis11(4):316–344.

Signorino, Curtis S. and Kuzey Yilmaz. 2003. “Strategic Misspecification in Regression Models.”American Journal of Political Science 47(3):551–566.

Steinwand, Martin C. and Randall W. Stone. 2008. “The International Monetary Fund: A Reviewof the Recent Evidence.” The Review of International Organizations 3(2):123–149.

Stone, Randall W. 2004. “The Political Economy of IMF Lending in Africa.” American PoliticalScience Review 98:577–591.

Stone, Randall W. 2011. Controlling Institutions: International Organizations and the GlobalEconomy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

Svensson, Jakob. 1999. “Aid, Growth and Democracy.” Economics and Politics 11(3):275–297.

Tarar, Ahmer. 2001. “International Bargaining with Two-Sided Domestic Constraints.” Journal ofConflict Resolution 45(3):320–40.

Thacker, Strom C. 1999. “The High Politics of IMF Lending.” World Politics 52:38–75.

Tomz, Michael. 2007. “Domestic Audience Costs in International Relations: An ExperimentalApproach.” International Organization 61(4):821–40.

Voeten, Erik. 2005. Documenting Votes in the UN General Assembly.http://www9.georgetown.edu/faculty/ev42/UNVoting.htm.

Vreeland, James Raymond. 2008. “The Effect of Political Regime on Civil War Unpacking Anoc-racy.” Journal of Conflict Resolution 52(3):401–25.

38

Page 39: Democracy and Multilateralism: The Case of Vote Buying in ...€¦ · 1A di erence in means test and a Chi-square test of independence strongly con rm the statistical signi cance

Wang, T. Y. 1999. “U.S. Foreign Aid and UN Voting: An Analysis of Important Issues.” Interna-tional Studies Quarterly 43(1)(1):199–210.

Whang, Taehee. 2010. “Structural Estimation of Economic Sanctions: From Initiation to Out-comes.” Journal of Peace Research 47(5):561–573.

Wittkopf, Eugene. 1973. “Foreign Aid and United Nations Votes: A Comparative Study.” AmericanPolitical Science Review 67(3):868–888.

39

Page 40: Democracy and Multilateralism: The Case of Vote Buying in ...€¦ · 1A di erence in means test and a Chi-square test of independence strongly con rm the statistical signi cance

Polit

y Sc

ore

-10

-5

0

5

10

GDP per capita

510

1520

25

Pr U.S. Punishes C

entrist Non-Ally

0.00

0.02

0.04

0.06

0.08

0.10

(a) Regime Type, Development, and Punishment

Polity

Score

-10

-5

0

5

10

GDP per capita5

10

1520

25

Pr U.S. R

ewards C

entrist Non-Ally

0.00

0.05

0.10

0.15

(b) Regime Type, Development, and Reward

GD

P pe

r cap

ita

510

15

20

25Polity Score

-10-5

0

5

10

Pr Left-Wing N

on-Ally Votes Against U.S.

0.0

0.2

0.4

0.6

0.8

1.0

(c) Regime Type, Development, and “Yes” Votes

GD

P pe

r cap

ita

510

15

20

25Polity Score

-10-5

0

5

10

Pr Left-Wing N

on-Ally Votes Against U.S.

0.0

0.2

0.4

0.6

0.8

1.0

(d) Regime Type, Development, and “No” Votes

Figure 3: Democracy and Development

40

Page 41: Democracy and Multilateralism: The Case of Vote Buying in ...€¦ · 1A di erence in means test and a Chi-square test of independence strongly con rm the statistical signi cance

Tab

le1:

Uti

liti

esfo

rS

tati

stic

alS

trat

egic

Mod

el

UR

(Punish

)UR

(¬Reward

)UR

(Reward

)UU.S.(Punish

)UU.S.(Reward

)

Con

stan

t110.53

0.32

4.94

-3.20

(19.

23)

(0.0

6)

(0.2

4)

(0.1

3)

Rec

ipie

nt

Pol

ity

2.75

-5.63

0.05

0.13

(0.6

0)

(1.2

5)

(0.0

1)

(0.0

1)

All

ies

-30.69

-2.9

90.

19-0

.17

(4.9

0)

(4.6

3)

(0.1

3)

(0.1

4)

Rec

ipie

nt

GD

P9.87

4.42

-0.0

90.06

(1.7

6)

(0.9

4)

(0.1

6)

(0.0

1)

Tra

de

-15.86

11.4

6-0.05

-0.11

(6.0

3)

(6.9

3)

(0.0

2)

(0.0

3)

Lef

t-W

ing

Exec

uti

ve-9.85

14.76

-0.0

7-0.44

(4.5

5)

(5.1

8)

(0.1

1)

(0.1

5)

Rig

ht-

Win

gE

xec

uti

ve

6.96

68.74

-0.71

-0.2

8(1

0.24

)(9

.88)

(0.1

5)

(0.1

6)

U.S

.V

otes

No

-109.71

-6.82

0.22

-0.16

(17.

89)

(1.1

5)

(0.0

2)

(0.0

1)

Boots

trapp

edSta

ndard

Err

ors

inP

are

nth

eses

Num

ber

of

Obse

rvati

ons

14337

Bold

Indic

ate

sSig

nifi

cance

at

the

.05

Lev

elP

erce

nt

Corr

ectl

yP

redic

ted:

84.9

%M

odal

Per

cent

Corr

ectl

yP

redic

ted:

63.2

%

41

Page 42: Democracy and Multilateralism: The Case of Vote Buying in ...€¦ · 1A di erence in means test and a Chi-square test of independence strongly con rm the statistical signi cance

Tab

le2:

Mar

gin

alE

ffec

tsof

Reg

ress

ors

onU

.S.

and

Rec

ipie

nt

Ch

oice

s

U.S

.P

un

ish

men

tan

dR

ewar

dD

ecis

ion

Rec

ipie

nt

Vot

ing

Dec

isio

n

Pr(Punish

)%

Ch

ange

inP

rP

r(Reward

)%

Ch

ange

inP

rP

r(VoteAgainstU.S.)

%C

han

gein

Pr

Med

ian

Valu

es0.0

42

NA

0.00

8N

A0.

880

NA

Pol

ity=

-90.0

28

-33%

0.00

3-6

3%0.

942

+7%

Pol

ity=

90.

071

+69

%0.

029

+26

3%0.

821

-7%

All

ian

ce=

10.

960

+9%

Rec

ipie

nt

GD

P=

1,0

00

0.0

51

+21

%0.

007

-13%

0.94

6+

8%

Rec

ipie

nt

GD

P=

12,0

000.

020

-52%

0.01

3+

63%

0.69

5-2

1%

Tra

de=

15

mil

lion

0.0

42+

0%0.

008

+0%

0.87

8-0

%

Tra

de=

10

bil

lion

0.0

40-5

%0.

007

-13%

0.92

8+

5%

Lef

t-W

ing

0.03

9-7

%0.

005

-38%

0.90

6+

3%

Rig

ht-

Win

g0.0

21

-50%

0.89

2+

1%

Yes

Vot

e0.

005

-88%

0.04

2+

438%

0.03

1-9

6%

Mis

sing

Cel

lsIn

dic

ate

Sta

tist

ical

Insi

gnifi

cance

42

Page 43: Democracy and Multilateralism: The Case of Vote Buying in ...€¦ · 1A di erence in means test and a Chi-square test of independence strongly con rm the statistical signi cance

Table 3: Marginal Effects of Regressors on U.S. Punishment Decision

Cold War Post-Cold WarU.S. Punishment Decision U.S. Punishment Decision

Pr(Punishment) % Change in Pr Pr(Punishment) % Change in Pr

Median Values 0.032 NA 0.038 NA

Polity=9 0.046 +44% 0.086 +100%

Polity=-9 0.024 -25% 0.020 -45%

Alliance=1 0.010 -69% 0.059 +60%

Left-Wing 0.072 +125% 0.023 -43%

Right-Wing 0.006 -81% 0.021 -40%

GDP per capita=1,000$ 0.029 -9% 0.058 +53%

GDP per capita=12,000$ 0.044 +38% 0.008 -79%

Trade=Low 0.031 -3% 0.038 +0%

Trade= High 0.038 +19% 0.039 +3%

Bold Cells Indicate Statistical Significance

43