Transcript
Page 1: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

 

 

THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES

OF

CORRUPTION  

 

 

A THESIS PRESENTED IN FULFILMENT OF THE

REQUIREMENTS FOR THE DEGREE OF

DOCTOR OF PHILOSOPHY IN ECONOMICS

 

March 2011

BIN DONG

 

 

 

 

 

School of Economics and Finance

Faculty of Business

Queensland University of Technology

Gardens Point Campus

Brisbane Australia

Page 2: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

i  

Acknowledgements

 

I would like to express my gratitude to my principal supervisor Professor Benno Torgler, for

walking me through the journey of PhD study and for being there at every step as a source of

inspiration, motivation and moral support. Professor Torgler’s excellent supervision,

invaluable guidance, suggestions, corrections and empirical skills have helped shape much of

this thesis. I would also like to extend deepest appreciation to my associate supervisor

Professor Uwe Dulleck for his invaluable guidance and encouragement throughout this study.

I extend my thanks to Dr. David Johnston for offering invaluable comments and suggestions

for empirical analysis. I also extend special thanks to the members of the administrative staff

of the School of Economics and Finance.

I am extremely grateful to China Scholarship Council and Queensland University of

technology for jointly providing me the financial support for my PhD study.

I am deeply indebted to my wife Jin Kang, who has been the motivational force in my life,

and thank her for her patience, understanding and invaluable support during the PhD study. I

am grateful to my mother, brother for their selfless and unreserved support over the years.

Finally I would like to thank Ms Ying Zhou, Mr Tony Beatton and Mr Markus Schaffner

for their assistance and support.

Page 3: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into
Page 4: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

iii  

Abstract

 

This thesis comprehensively studies the causes and consequences of corruption in both cross-

country and within-country contexts, mainly focusing on China.

The thesis commences by extensively investigating the causes of corruption. Using the

standard economic approach, this study finds that in China regions with more anti-corruption

efforts, higher education attainment, Anglo-American historic influence, higher openness,

more access to media, higher relative wages of government employees, and a greater

representation of women in legislature are markedly less corrupt; while the social

heterogeneity, deregulation and abundance of resources, substantially breed regional

corruption. Moreover, fiscal decentralization is discovered to depress corruption significantly.

This study also observes a positive relationship between corruption and the economic

development in current China that is mainly driven by the transition to a market economy.

Focusing on the influence of political institutions on corruption, the thesis then provides

evidence that a high level of political interest helps to reduce corruption within a society,

while the effect of democracy upon corruption depends on property rights protection and

income distribution. With the social economic approach, however, the thesis presents both

cross-country and within-country evidence that the social interaction plays an important role

in determining corruption.

The thesis then continues by comprehensively evaluating the consequences of corruption

in China. The study provides evidence that corruption can simultaneously have both positive

and negative effects on economic development. And it also observes that corruption

considerably increases the income inequality in China. Furthermore this study finds that

corruption in China significantly distorts public expenditures. Local corruption is also

observed to substantially reduce FDI in Chinese regions. Finally the study documents that

corruption substantially aggravates pollution probably through a loosening of the

environmental regulation, and that it also modifies the effects of trade openness and FDI on

the stringency of environmental policy.

Overall, this thesis adds to the current literature by a number of novel findings concerning

both the causes and the consequences of corruption.

Key Words: corruption, causes, consequences, China, democracy, social interaction, political

interest, economic development.

Page 5: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

iv  

Table of Contents

Acknowledgements ................................................................................................................................. i 

Statement of Original Authorship ......................................................................................................... ii 

Abstract ................................................................................................................................................. iii 

Table of Contents .................................................................................................................................. iv 

List of Tables ......................................................................................................................................... vii 

List of Figures ......................................................................................................................................... ix 

Chapter One  Introduction .................................................................................................................. 1 

1.1 Motivation of Thesis ..................................................................................................................... 1 

1.2 Content of Thesis .......................................................................................................................... 2 

1.2.1 Causes of Corruption .............................................................................................................. 2 

1.2.2 Consequences of Corruption ................................................................................................. 7 

1.2.3 Methodology issues ............................................................................................................... 8 

1.3 Structure of Thesis ....................................................................................................................... 10 

Chapter Two  Economic Determinants of Corruption: Chinese Evidence ....................................... 12 

2.1 Introduction ................................................................................................................................ 12 

2.2 Determinants of Corruption ........................................................................................................ 15 

2.3 Empirical Analysis ........................................................................................................................ 18 

2.3.1 Province‐level Analysis ......................................................................................................... 20 

2.3.2 City‐level Analysis ................................................................................................................. 35 

2.4 Conclusion ................................................................................................................................... 38 

Appendix ........................................................................................................................................... 41 

Chapter Three  Political Interest and Corruption: Cross‐country Evidence .................................. 44 

3.1 Introduction ................................................................................................................................ 44 

3.2 Political Interest .......................................................................................................................... 45 

3.2.1 Theoretical Considerations .................................................................................................. 45 

3.2.2 A Simple Model .................................................................................................................... 46 

3.3 Data ............................................................................................................................................. 48 

3.3.1 Dependent Variables ............................................................................................................ 48 

3.3.2 Measuring Political Interest ................................................................................................. 50 

3.3.3 Further Independent Variables ............................................................................................ 51 

3.4 Empirical Evidence ...................................................................................................................... 56 

3.4.1 International Evidence ......................................................................................................... 57 

Page 6: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

v  

3.4.2 Within‐Country Evidence ..................................................................................................... 70 

3.5 Conclusion ................................................................................................................................... 71 

Chapter Four  Democracy and Corruption: Cross‐country Evidence ............................................... 73 

4.1 Introduction ................................................................................................................................ 73 

4.2 Theoretical Model ....................................................................................................................... 75 

4.2.1 Model ................................................................................................................................... 76 

4.2.2 Economic Equilibrium .......................................................................................................... 77 

4.2.3 Political Equilibrium ............................................................................................................. 78 

4.3 Empirical Evidence ...................................................................................................................... 80 

4.3.1 Methodology and Data ........................................................................................................ 81 

4.3.2 Results .................................................................................................................................. 85 

4.4 Conclusion ................................................................................................................................... 92 

Appendix ........................................................................................................................................... 93 

Chapter Five  Social interaction and Corruption: Cross‐country Evidence ..................................... 94 

5.1 Introduction ................................................................................................................................. 94 

5.2 Theoretical Foundation ................................................................................................................ 96 

5.2.1 Background of the Model .................................................................................................... 98 

5.2.2 A Simple Game ................................................................................................................... 100 

5.2.3 Dynamics ............................................................................................................................ 102 

5.2.4 Conditional Corruption – Discussion and Extensions ........................................................ 102 

5.3 Data and Methodological Approach ......................................................................................... 103 

5.3.1 Micro Analysis .................................................................................................................... 103 

5.3.2 Macro Analysis ................................................................................................................... 107 

5.4 Results ....................................................................................................................................... 107 

5.4.1 Micro Level using the EVS .................................................................................................. 107 

5.4.2 Micro Level using the WVS ................................................................................................ 117 

5.4.3 Macro Level Using a Large Panel Data Set ......................................................................... 121 

5.5 Conclusion ................................................................................................................................. 125 

Chapter Six  Social interaction and Corruption: Within‐country Evidence ................................. 127 

6.1 Introduction .............................................................................................................................. 127 

6.2 Theoretical Model ..................................................................................................................... 129 

6.3 Empirical Work .......................................................................................................................... 132 

6.3.1 Data and Methodology ...................................................................................................... 132 

6.3.2 Results ................................................................................................................................ 136 

Page 7: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

vi  

6.4 Conclusion ................................................................................................................................. 139 

Appendix ......................................................................................................................................... 141 

Chapter Seven  Consequences of Corruption: Chinese Evidence ................................................ 142 

7.1 Introduction .............................................................................................................................. 142 

7.2 Literature Review ...................................................................................................................... 145 

7.3 Empirical Analysis ...................................................................................................................... 149 

7.3.1 Data and Methodology ...................................................................................................... 149 

7.3.2 Corruption, Economic Growth and Income Distribution ................................................... 153 

7.3.3 Corruption and Foreign Direct Investment ........................................................................ 160 

7.3.4 Corruption and Public Expenditures .................................................................................. 162 

7.3.5 Corruption and the Environment ....................................................................................... 164 

7.4 Conclusion ................................................................................................................................. 169 

Appendix ......................................................................................................................................... 171 

Chapter Eight  Conclusion ............................................................................................................ 172 

8.1 Summary of Findings ................................................................................................................. 172 

8.2 Policy Implications .................................................................................................................... 174 

8.3 Further Research ....................................................................................................................... 175 

References .......................................................................................................................................... 177 

Page 8: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

vii  

List of Tables

Table 2‐1 GDP (PPP) per capita of Chinese regions in 2008 (Intl. $) ..................................................... 14 

Table 2‐2 Average annual registered cases on corruption across regions in China (1998‐2007) ......... 20 

Table 2‐3 Corruption and its determinants in China: pooled OLS estimation ...................................... 32 

Table 2‐4 Corruption and its determinants in China: fixed effects OLS estimation ............................. 33 

Table 2‐5 Corruption and its determinants in China: fixed effects 2SLS estimation ............................ 34 

Table 2‐6 Corruption and its determinants in Chinese cities ................................................................ 37 

Table 2‐7 Data description .................................................................................................................... 41 

Table 2‐8 Pairwise correlation coefficients between explanatory variables in the province‐level 

analysis .................................................................................................................................................. 42 

Table 2‐9 Pairwise correlation coefficients between explanatory variables in the city‐level analysis . 42 

Table 2‐10 First‐Stage Regressions Based on Table 2‐5 ........................................................................ 43 

Table 3‐1 Justifiability of corruption and political discussion ............................................................... 59 

Table 3‐2 Perceived corruption and political discussion ...................................................................... 60 

Table 3‐3 Justifiability of corruption and interest in politics ................................................................ 61 

Table 3‐4 Perceived corruption and political interest .......................................................................... 62 

Table 3‐5 Justifiability of corruption and important of politics in life .................................................. 63 

Table 3‐6 Perceived corruption and importance of politics in life ....................................................... 64 

Table 3‐7 2SLS results ........................................................................................................................... 67 

Table 3‐8 Justifiability of corruption in Switzerland ............................................................................. 68 

Table 3‐9 Perceived corruption in Switzerland ..................................................................................... 69 

Table 4‐1  Descriptive Statistics ............................................................................................................ 84 

Table 4‐2 Effect of democracy on corruption: review and implication (fixed effects results) ............. 86 

Table 4‐3 Effect of democracy on corruption: fixed effect results ....................................................... 87 

Table 4‐4 Effect of democracy on corruption: alternative measure of democracy.............................. 88 

Table 4‐5 Effect of democracy on corruption: IV results ...................................................................... 89 

Table 4‐6 Marginal effect of democracy on corruption ........................................................................ 91 

Table 4‐7 Validity of instrument: Muslim ............................................................................................. 93 

Table 5‐1 Influence of conditional corruption (EVS) ........................................................................... 110 

Table 5‐2 Robustness test and the influence of conditional corruption using micro and macro proxies 

(EVS) .................................................................................................................................................... 113 

Table 5‐3 2SLS results (EVS) ................................................................................................................ 115 

Table 5‐4 Causality discussion (Filtering) ............................................................................................ 116 

Table 5‐5 Conditional corruption using WVS ...................................................................................... 119 

Table 5‐6 2SLS results (WVS) .............................................................................................................. 120 

Table 5‐7 Causality discussion filtering with WVS Data ...................................................................... 121 

Table 5‐8 Evidence at the macro level ................................................................................................ 125 

Table 6‐1 Literature summary ............................................................................................................ 129 

Table 6‐2 Variables description, 1998—2007 ..................................................................................... 134 

Table 6‐3 Corruption and social interaction ....................................................................................... 138 

Table 6‐4 Average annual registered cases on corruption per capita across regions in China (1998‐

2007) ................................................................................................................................................... 141 

Page 9: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

viii  

Table 6‐5 Pairwise correlation coefficients between variables .......................................................... 141 

Table 7‐1 GDP (PPP) per capita of Chinese regions in 2008 (Intl. $) ................................................... 144 

Table 7‐2 Average annual registered cases on corruption per capita across regions in China (1998‐

2007) ................................................................................................................................................... 150 

Table 7‐3 Effect of corruption on economic growth: cross‐province evidence .................................. 154 

Table 7‐4 Effect of corruption on economic growth: cross‐city evidence .......................................... 158 

Table 7‐5 Effects of corruption on income inequality ........................................................................ 159 

Table 7‐6 Effect of corruption rate on inbound FDI ............................................................................ 161 

Table 7‐7 Effects of corruption on public expenditures ..................................................................... 163 

Table 7‐8 Effect of corruption and the environment .......................................................................... 165 

Table 7‐9 Effect of corruption on environment policy ....................................................................... 168 

Table 7‐10 Data description ................................................................................................................ 171 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Page 10: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

ix  

List of Figures

Figure 1‐1 Thesis Structure ................................................................................................................... 11 

Figure 2‐1 Determinants of corruption in China ................................................................................... 38 

Figure 4‐1 Relationship between democracy and corruption .............................................................. 85 

Figure 5‐1 Correlation between Justifiability of Corruption and Perceived Corruption ....................... 96 

Figure 5‐2 Description of the Corruption Game ................................................................................. 101 

Figure 5‐3 Correlation between Justifiability of Corruption and Control of Corruption .................... 106 

Figure 7‐1 Marginal effects of trade openness on environmental stringency conditional on corruption

 ............................................................................................................................................................ 166 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Page 11: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

1  

Chapter One Introduction

 

1.1 Motivation of Thesis

Corruption, understood as ‘‘abuse of public office for private gain’’ is a persistent feature in

human societies throughout time and space. Contemporaneous corruption scandals not only

occur in developing countries such as Nigeria, India, and China where corruption is regarded

as a norm, but also in developed economies such as France, Britain and America. The sale of

parliamentary seats in ‘rotten boroughs’ in England before the Reform Act of 18321 and

‘machine politics’ in larger cities in America in the late 19th and early 20th century2 are two

famous historical examples. Even in Scandinavian countries, like Sweden and Norway, which

are supposedly free-from-corruption, managers of state owned companies have been found to

take bribes.

Corruption in the public sector is viewed as the major obstacle to economic development

(Kaufmann, 1997). Solid evidence (for example, Mauro 1995, and World Bank, 1997)

demonstrates the pernicious effects of corruption upon, among other things, investment,

economic growth, environmental quality and therefore social welfare. In effect, a country is

adversely affected by the existence of corruption, and therefore anti-corruption policies are

important.

Reducing corruption requires a precise understanding of its causes and consequences. The

development of effective anti-corruption policies is based on a thorough investigation of

corruption within and across countries. However, in current research the causes and

consequences of corruption remain poorly understood and are broadly disputed. As a result, it

is difficult for governments to design coherent policies to control corruption.

This study provides new insight into the causes and consequences of corruption. We

explore the discussed factors in a within country environment to provide evidence outside the

US and in a more controlled environment, and also provide within-country and cross-country

evidence at the micro level to explore new theories in the area of corruption such as

conditional corruption. In detail the thesis first empirically examines the theoretical causes of

corruption suggested in literature in both cross-country and within-country contexts. The

                                                            1 Pearce, R. and Stearn, R., 2000. Access to History, Government and Reform: Britain 1815-1918 (Second Edition). Hodder & Stoughton. 2 Clifford, T. P., 1975. The Political Machine: An American Institution. Vantage Press.

Page 12: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

2  

author robustly identifies the effects of its economic, political and social determinants on

corruption, employing solid statistical tools dealing with causal relationship between

observed factors. Secondly, this study comprehensively investigates the various

consequences of corruption, focusing on China, the largest developing country central to

world economy. According to my knowledge, there are few studies on the consequences of

Chinese corruption. In summary, this study is expected to make a substantial contribution to

the research of the causes and consequences of corruption, and therefore to add to effective

policy guidelines to curb corruption.

1.2 Content of Thesis

This section provides a succinct portrait of the thesis. Initially we briefly review previous

literature to build up the logical framework of the thesis (specific literature reviews are

provided in each of the individual chapters that follow). Then based on the framework that

has been introduced, the main findings of the thesis are then presented.

1.2.1 Causes of Corruption

There has been a wave of empirical studies on the causes and consequences of corruption in

recent years. With respect to the causes of corruption, this study, similar to Bardhan (2006),

points out that there are generally two different approaches to research the causes of

corruption, namely the standard economic approach and also the social economic approach.

The standard economic approach emphasizes incentives and punishments in corrupt acts

following Becker’s analytical framework (1968). According to this approach, there are three

prerequisites necessary for the incidence of corruption (Jain, 2001). First, bureaucrats have

discretionary power. Second, this power is associated with economic rents. Finally, the

deterrence to corruption, as a function of the probability of being caught and the penalty for

the corrupt act, is adequately low. The first two preconditions determine the benefit of

corruption, while the last precondition influences the cost of corruption.

Many studies adopting this approach concentrate upon economic conditions and policies

influencing the cost and/or benefit of corruption. Literature shows that regulation and

decentralization are the main determinants of the discretionary power of a government.

Economic rents, on the other hand, increase with natural resource abundance, but decrease

with economic competition proxied by trade openness. All of these factors are observed to

substantially affect the benefit of corruption (e.g. Ades and Di Tella, 1999; Fisman and Gatti,

2002a, b).

Page 13: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

3  

The deterrence of corruption is a joint function of the possibility of being detected and the

punishment once caught. High levels of economic development, education attainment and

media access have been documented to reduce corruption by raising the possibility that

corrupt acts are detected (for example, Treisman, 2000). Historical influence also plays an

important role in corruption (see also, Treisman, 2000). Furthermore corruption has also been

found to be negatively correlated with female representation in politics, possibly because

women may feel a larger probability of being caught in an act of corruption (e.g. Dollar et al.,

2001). Social and economic heterogeneity is also an indirect determinant of the probability of

corrupt acts being caught. For example, ethnical fractionalization is believed to promote

corruption since corrupt officials may be protected by their own ethnic groups for political

reasons (see also Treisman, 2000). Finally, the relatively high wage of the public sector

implies a high opportunity cost when officials are ousted due to corruption. As a proxy for

the punishment, the (relative) wage of the public sector is found to be negatively associated

with the corruption level (e.g. Van Rijkeghem and Weder, 2001)

Studies on the causes of corruption by and large perform cross-national analyses using

subjective survey data (for example, Treisman, 2000; Fisman and Gatti, 2002a). This kind of

study, although fruitful, cannot circumvent two problems. Firstly, subjective survey data

might be biased as Treisman (2007) argues: “the data do not measure corruption itself but

opinion about its prevalence” (p. 215). Secondly, cross-country analysis often suffers from

omitted variable bias. Substantial unobservable or unmeasurable differences in institution and

culture between countries make cross-country results problematic. The disadvantages

experienced by cross-national studies can be avoided if we use within-country objective data,

since objective data do not suffer the bias of subjective data. Furthermore, homogeneity

within a country also mitigates the omitted variable bias troubling the cross-country analysis.

However, current within-country data are only proxies for corruption since corruption is

actually secretive and hence difficult to measure directly. Goel and Nelson (1998), Fisman

and Gatti (2002b), and Glaeser and Saks (2006) utilize the objective data: the number of

public officials convicted for abuse of public office as an indicator of the actual levels of

corruption in American states. However, this indicator may also reflect the anti-corruption

efforts of local judiciary. As Lambsdorff (2005) point out “the appropriateness of such data

as a proxy for corruption has thus been widely disputed” (p.1). Therefore the ideal strategy

might be to investigate the causes of corruption with both the cross-country analysis using

subjective data and the within-country analysis using objective data to get complementary

results, which also makes empirical findings robust.

Page 14: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

4  

While there have been enormous cross-country studies, papers on the causes of corruption

using within-country data are few, and most of them are working with US data. This thesis

hence initially contributes to literature with a study on the causes of corruption in China. A

study of China has a unique advantage. Firstly, it is helpful to understand corruption in

developing and transitional economies where it is one of the central issues. Secondly, China

is well-suited for a study on corruption. On the one hand, China is fairly homogenous in

institutions, culture, and social structure. This helps us to mitigate the omitted variable bias in

empirical analysis. On the other hand, there are great economic differences between the

eastern and western provinces in China, which might make findings of corruption in China

more generalizable on a global level.

Chapter 2 in the thesis adopts a standard economic approach to explore the causes of

corruption in China using two different data sets, namely a province-level data set and a city-

level data set, to obtain robust results. China is a key player in the world economy and will

gain even further importance in the future. This study examines almost all cross-country

findings in a Chinese context using the regional number of registered cases on corruption as a

measure of corruption. Besides confirming most cross-country findings in a more controlled

setting, this study adds to literature in several ways. Firstly, this chapter use behavioural

variables3 rather than attitudinal variables (perceptions of corruption) to proxy for corruption.

Secondly anti-corruption efforts are always controlled in this study to isolate the component

of anticorruption efforts in our corruption measure though many studies including the small

amount of studies using a behavioural proxy for corruption have neglected this. Thirdly, this

study identifies a positive relationship between corruption and economic development (and

marketization) in China due to the transition process in China. Fourthly, this study provides

some novel within-country evidence such as the negative effect of British historic influence,

the positive effect of natural resource abundance, and the negative effect of female

representation in politics on corruption. Fifthly, this study presents solid evidence that even in

a nondemocratic country the access to controlled media still checks corruption.

There are a number of studies concentrating on the influence of political institutions on

corruption using the standard economic approach. Good political institutions help to control

and monitor the government and therefore reduce corruption. There are actually two kinds of

political institutions: Formal institutions such as democracy and informal ones such as

                                                            3 The registered cases on corruption in procurator’s offices of provinces, and the average ratios of the travel and entertainment costs relative to the sales of investigated firms in Chinese cities in the survey conducted by World Bank in 2005. 

Page 15: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

5  

political interest. Econometrically, the effect of formal institutions like democracy on

corruption can only be analysed at the macro level in the cross-country context, while

political interest is useful to analyse (informal) institutions at the micro/individual level.

Democracy is theoretically supposed to reduce corruption mainly because political

competition may provide checks against corruption. “In democratic systems, competitors for

office have an incentive to discover and publicize the incumbent’s misuse of office whenever

an election beckons.” (Treisman, 2000, p. 404) This therefore raises the possibility that

corrupt acts can be detected. However, the relationship between corruption and democracy is

empirically found to be complex. Besides the linear relationship mentioned above, a

quadratic relationship between these factors, is also supported by several theoretical and

empirical articles (e.g. Mohtadi and Roe, 2003, Rock, 2007). Moreover, some scholars such

as Treisman (2000) suggest that it may take a long time for democracy to substantially reduce

corruption. Further evidence is clearly necessary. It is worth noting however that variation in

political institution within a country is not large enough in many cases for economists to

identify the relationship between democracy and corruption. This thesis therefore mainly

utilizes cross-country data sets to examine the influence of political institutions on corruption.

The thesis, for the first time ever, investigates in Chapter 3 the relationship between

political interests: an informal aspect of political institution and corruption since citizens’

political interest contributes to the probability of their being involved in the political process

(Verba et al., 1995). Innovatively, this study uses the micro-level data from the World Values

Survey to explore the impact of political interest represented by three different proxies on

both the perception of corruption and the justifiability of corruption reflecting the social norm

of corruption. It is worth noting that unlike the macro-level analysis which is popular in the

corruption study, the micro-level study is able to measure the individual characteristics and

induce robust relationships due the large amount of observations. Furthermore, as can be seen

below, it allows researchers to explore new theories such as conditional corruption.

Specifically, this study first performs a cross-country analysis with a huge data set, and then

runs a within-country analysis focusing on Switzerland to check the robustness of cross-

country results. Both analyses clearly show that a high level of political interest helps to

reduce the level of corruption within a society.

In Chapter 4 the thesis shed new light on the relationship between democracy and

corruption. To disentangle the actual linkage from previously mixed evidence, this study first

establishes a new political economy model demonstrating that the effect of democracy on

corruption is conditional on income distribution and property rights protection. Then with a

Page 16: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

6  

cross-national panel data, this study clearly shows that the previous empirical findings lose

significance when considering the interactions between corruption, property rights protection

and income distribution. The effect of democracy upon corruption is empirically observed to

depend on the protection of property rights and income inequality. This thesis hence provides

new theoretical and empirical evidence concerning the effect of democracy on corruption.

    The social economic approach however insists that corruption to some extent arises from

social norms. It emphasizes the role of group dynamics as well as culture and history, in

determining corruption. Put simply, corrupt people will feel less guilt (moral cost) if they find

many others engaged in similar activities, and vice versa. Culture here coordinates the

expectation on others’ behaviour in a society, while history provides the initial condition.

Multiple equilibria are often expected in this circumstance. A society with an initially high

corruption level may get ‘‘locked in’’ until a ‘big push’ similar to what happened in Hong

Kong takes place (Aidt, 2003). Economists however have not focused on this approach

heretofore. Only Goel and Nelson (2007) have studied the contagion of corruption in

America.

This thesis however attempts to fill the gap with both cross-country and within-country

analyses. The study presented in Chapter 5, according to my knowledge, is the first cross-

country analysis studying the role of social interactions or social norms in corruption. This

study builds first a behavioural model to innovatively argue that engaging in corruption

results in a disutility of guilt. Guilt itself depends on a (current and past) perceived prevalence

of corruption within a society. As a novelty the empirical section presents a large amount of

evidence about the role of social interactions with two large micro level data sets and a large

macro level panel data sets covering almost 20 years. The results clearly indicate that a

willingness to be corrupt is influenced by the perceived activities of others, and the past level

of corruption. The findings above therefore underscore the relevance of social interactions on

the area of corruption. Furthermore the results also complement a large set of laboratory

experimental studies (for example, Falk, Fischbacher and Gächter, 2003) that have studied

conditional cooperation by providing evidence outside of a lab setting.

As mentioned before, the study above may suffer both omitted variable bias and

subjective data bias. Chapter 6 of this thesis then, from a different angle, turns to examine the

role of social interaction on corruption within a Chinese context using province-level panel

data. As a novelty, this study, unlike Goel and Nelson (2007), simultaneously investigates the

impacts of both the corruption level of neighbours and the corruption level in the past upon

contemporary corruption. Robust evidence is also presented that social interaction plays an

Page 17: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

7  

important role in determining corruption rates in China. The thesis therefore contributes to

literature both by cross-country and by within-country evidence on the relevance of social

interaction in corruption.

1.2.2 Consequences of Corruption

Corruption is believed to have a detrimental effect on economic development and hence

social welfare. Many studies examine the relationship between corruption and economic

growth since there is indeed a debate on the effect of corruption on economic growth. Some

scholars (for example, Leff, 1964, and Huntington, 1968) argue that corruption may improve

efficiency and hence promote economic growth by allowing enterprisers to circumvent

cumbersome regulations with bribes especially in developing countries. However, the

majority of literature insists that corruption lowers economic growth because it may reduce

the incentive of private investment (Bardhan, 1997), distort public investment decisions

(Tanzi and Davoodi, 1997), and induce talented people into rent-seeking activities (Murphy,

Shleifer and Vishny, 1991). Most empirical studies indeed support the fact that corruption

impedes economic growth mainly through channels of investment, openness and political

instability (for example, Mauro, 1995, Mo, 2001).

Specifically, corruption is found to reduce foreign direct investment (e.g. Wei, 2000a)

because high corruption in host countries may imply high expropriation risk. Moreover,

Fredriksson et al. (2003) show that corruption may influence FDI through another channel:

environmental regulation. On the other hand, corruption may distort public investment.

According to Mauro (1998), corrupt politicians may increase public expenditure easy to

collect bribes, while decreasing expenditure providing fewer bribery opportunities.

Furthermore he empirically observes that corruption significantly reduces public expenditure

on education.

Corruption also substantially affects income distribution. Gupta, Davoodi and Alonso-

Terme (2002) find that corruption significantly increases income inequality, while Li et al.

(2000) observe that corruption influences income inequality in a reversed U-shaped manner.

The adverse effects of corruption on the environment are also documented in literature.

Welsch (2004) found that corruption aggravates pollution especially in developing countries,

while Cole (2007) provides seemingly contradicting evidence. More investigation is therefore

needed. Pellegrini and Gerlagh (2006a, b) however provide solid evidence that corruption has

a substantially negative effect on the environment policy stringency, which may imply that

corruption affects pollution mainly through environment policy making. Furthermore, both

Page 18: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

8  

theoretical and empirical evidence has shown that corruption not only reduces the stringency

of environmental policy but also modifies the effects of other determinants of environment

policy (Fredriksson and Svensson, 2003, Damania et al., 2003, and Cole et al., 2006).

In Chapter 7 this thesis, for the first time, comprehensively investigates consequences of

corruption with complementary Chinese data sets and alternative corruption measures. The

study contributes to existing literature in several ways. Firstly, it suggests a novel perspective

of the influence of corruption on economic growth. Specifically, this study empirically finds

that corruption has simultaneously both positive and negative effects on the economic growth

of China. The overall impact of corruption might be the balance of the two effects, both of

which may depend on institutional environments. Secondly, this study provides, novel

within-country evidence that corruption increases income inequality, decreases FDI and

distorts public spending in China. Thirdly, this study documents that corruption substantially

aggravates pollution probably through loosening environmental regulation in China, and that

it modifies the effects of trade openness and FDI on the stringency of environmental policy in

a similar manner to that observed in literature to date.

There are still two important issues to be addressed. First, one may notice there is an

imbalance in regards to the number of papers on the causes of corruption compared to the

consequences of corruption. The current research project actually starts with the study about

the causes of Chinese corruption since a better understanding of the causes of corruption is

first of all required before one is able to analyse the consequences of corruption. The author

will however complete the project with more papers studying the consequences of Chinese

corruption (for example, from the micro/individual perspective) in the near future. Second, it

is worth noting that chapters 2 to 7 in this thesis are respectively built on independent papers

submitted to or published in academic journals. In order to retain the completeness of the

research project in each chapter, some overlap between chapters especially chapters

concerning corruption in China is allowed. Furthermore, the writing styles of chapters in the

thesis are a bit different due to the different requirements of journals the chapters submitted

to.

1.2.3 Methodology issues

This thesis attempts to reliably identify the causality between corruption and other relevant

factors. The important methodology issues which are the key to identification are briefly

discussed here. Detailed methodology will be described in the following chapters.

The first issue we need to address is how to measure corruption. Indices of perceived

Page 19: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

9  

corruption such as the Corruption Perceptions Index published by Transparency International

and a corruption rating constructed by the Political Risk Services have been often used to

measure corruption in many cross-country studies. These indices are actually based on the

subjective assessments of experts or survey respondents of the extent of corruption in various

countries. The subjective indices are indeed closely correlated with each other although they

are complied by different organizations with different methodologies, suggesting “that these

different spyglasses are aimed at a common target” (Treisman 2007, p.216). Furthermore, the

perceptions indices are proved to be highly correlated with a range of generally believed

corruption determinants, indicating that they are “a helpful contribution to the understanding

of real levels of corruption” (Lambsdorff 2004, p.6). However, as Treisman (2007) argue,

corruption perception data actually reflect impressions of corruption intensity rather than

corruption itself, meaning that the data are actually correlated with survey respondents’

beliefs and other social and economic conditions (see also, Knack 2006). Such data, therefore,

cannot be convincingly used as dependent variables because their measurement error is

associated with many other background characteristics that are affected by explanatory

variables (Bertrand and Mullainathan 2001). The objective data set, usually within-country,

however can eliminate this kind of subjective data bias. For example, using the number of

public officials convicted for abuse of public office in American states as a proxy for

corruption, Glaeser and Saks (2006) examine the causes of and consequences of corruption in

America. However Lambsdorff (2004) argue that this kind of objective data may reflect the

quality of the judiciary rather than the actual corruption level. The reasonable strategy in the

research of corruption is therefore complementally using subjective and objective data to

measure corruption.

Corruption is econometrically a messy environment to analyse. According to Leamer

(1983), sensitivity analysis is therefore required here to ensure the credibility of the current

study. The detailed strategy that this thesis adopts is conducting a lot of robustness tests, 

exploring the issue with different data sets, proxies for corruption, and specifications, and

using micro and macro, within country and cross-country evidence, to show a robust picture.

Besides, the endogeneity issue needs to be addressed when identifying the causality in the

study. Two strategies are utilized to remove the potential endogeneity bias. The first strategy

is, whenever possible, to control for unobserved individual characteristics influencing both

corruption and relevant factors by including individual fixed effects in our panel regressions.

As Mo (2001) points out, “Corruption is commonly considered to be an institutional problem

that lasts for a long period” (p. 70). Fixed effect regressions therefore are suitable for the

Page 20: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

10  

investigation of the relationship between corruption and other factors since the major source

of potential bias in our regressions might be time-invariant historical factors.

However, fixed effect regressions do not necessarily identify the causality between

corruption and other relevant factors. Fixed effects regressions cannot guarantee the causality,

since there might be time-varying omitted factors affecting both corruption and the relevant

factors. Fixed effects are not a substitute for instrumental variables. The second strategy to

address the endogeneity problem therefore is to adopt the instrumental variable approach to

identify the causality between corruption and relevant factors in our (fixed effects)

regressions. The key issue of the IV approach, the selection of instrument variables, will be

discussed in detail as the analysis proceeds.

1.3 Structure of Thesis

As mentioned before, this thesis mainly focuses on corruption in China, the largest

developing country in the world. According to the logic framework set up above, this study is

organised as follows. The first part of the thesis is Chapter 1, where an introduction of the

study is presented. The second part of the thesis is composed of Chapters 2, 3, 4, 5, and 6,

where the causes of corruption especially in China are extensively investigated. The standard

economic approach is first adopted in Chapter 2, 3 and 4. Chapter 2 examines the effects of

the economic determinants of corruption suggested by cross-country studies in China with

two different data sets. Chapter 3 and 4 analyse the political determinants of corruption with

cross-country data sets. Specifically, Chapter 3 investigates the relationship between political

interest and corruption, while Chapter 4 explores the effect of democracy upon corruption.

Findings of these two chapters may help to predict the influence of democratisation on

corruption in China although China now is an authoritarian country. Chapter 5 and 6,

however, follow the social economic approach to examine the role of social factors in

determining corruption. Both cross-country analyses and within-country analyses (China) are

performed here to make the findings solid since few studies have been previously undertaken

in this area. The third part of the thesis, namely Chapter 7, comprehensively investigates the

adverse effects of corruption on the economic development in China at a macro level. Finally

this thesis finishes with the fourth part, Chapter 8, which provides a summary of all the

findings above and some concluding remarks.

The detailed structure of this thesis is shown in Figure 1-1.

Page 21: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

11  

Figure 1-1 Thesis Structure

 

CAUSES OF CORRUPTION

CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTION

CONCLUSION

INTRODUCTION

Standard Economic Approach

Social Economic Approach

Economic determinants of corruption

Social determinants of corruption

Political determinants of corruption

Economic determinants of corruption: Chinese evidence

Political interest and corruption: cross-country evidence

Democracy and corruption: cross-country evidence

Social interaction and corruption: cross-country evidence

Social interaction and corruption: Chinese evidence

Consequences of corruption: Chinese evidence

Chapter 1

Chapter 2

Chapter 3

Chapter 4

Chapter 5

Chapter 6

Chapter 7

Chapter 8 Conclusion

Introduction

Page 22: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

12  

Chapter Two Economic Determinants of Corruption: Chinese Evidence4

 

2.1 Introduction

Since the establishment of the People’s Republic of China in 1949, corruption has vexed the

national leadership, which prior to 1978 attempted to control it primarily through mass

movements but occasionally with severe deterrents like the 1952 execution of two senior

officials, Qingshan Liu and Zishan Zhang. Since the 1978 launch of economic reform,

however, corruption has become even more widespread and according to Liu (1983), exists at

every level of China’s political system. As a result, the 1989 market price of coal, for

example, was 674 percent of the subsidized price, other producer goods sell at prices

substantially higher than those fixed by the state, and payoffs to ensure the supply of

products at state prices are very common (Rose-Ackerman 1999). Corruption in the form of

applicant bribery is also widespread in the area of enterprise licensing because industrial and

commercial enterprises in China must obtain government authorization to operate (Manion

1996). Liu (1983) thus differentiates between three types of corruption: “corrupt acts such as

embezzlement and bribes, which are common place among nations having a political system

to speak of; … appropriation of public goods, illegal trade, and housing irregularity, [which

result] from a breakdown in the central allocation system and [are] commonplace among

socialist nations … [and the] rather peculiarly Chinese Communist [practices of] illegitimate

feasting, feudal rites, false models, and illegal imprisonment and torture” (p. 603). Even the

Chinese government has admitted that corruption “is now worse than during any other period

since New China was founded in 1949. It has spread into the Party, into Government

administration and into every part of society, including politics, economy, ideology and

culture” (Liang 1994, p. 122). The seriousness of this problem is exemplified by the recent

charges against two members of the Politburo, Xitong Chen and Liangyu Chen, who accepted

huge bribes.

Not surprisingly, such rampant corruption, which seems to be a distinct feature of

contemporary China, the largest transitional and developing country, has generated much

literature, especially in sociology and political science (e.g, White 1996; Wedeman 2004;

Gong 2006). From an economics perspective, Yao (2002) argues that corruption in China is

generated by the Chinese political system, which grants and protects privileges, and Cai et al.

                                                            4 This chapter is under revision for resubmission to the Public Choice. 

Page 23: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

13  

(2009), using an innovative measure of corruption in Chinese firms, find that corruption

significantly reduces firm productivity. Nevertheless, no empirical study yet exists that

comprehensively analyses the economic underpinnings of corruption in China. Rather, the

majority of extant studies on the causes of corruption are cross-national investigations that

use subjective survey data. For instance, Treisman’s (2000) comprehensive cross-country

study employs several indices of perceived corruption to explore the causes of corruption.

These studies, although fruitful, are subject to the problems of subjective bias and omitted

variable bias. First, as Treisman (2007) admits, corruption perception data actually reflect

impressions of corruption intensity rather than corruption itself, meaning that the data are

actually correlated with survey respondents’ beliefs and other social and economic conditions

(see also, Knack 2006). Such data, therefore, cannot be convincingly used as dependent

variables because their measurement error is associated with many other background

characteristics that are affected by explanatory variables (Bertrand and Mullainathan 2001).

Second, the substantial number of unobservable or unmeasurable differences in institutions

and cultures between countries makes it difficult for cross-country analyses to solve the

omitted variable bias. Admittedly, some cross-country analysts have attempted to bypass this

bias by using fixed-effect regressions, however, as Treisman (2007) and Knack (2006) point

out, the appropriateness of using some subjective corruption indices in longitudinal analyses

remains questionable.

Such disadvantages in cross-national research can certainly be mitigated by the use of an

objective within-country data set that eliminates the subjective data bias and, despite some

regional differences, provides a higher level of homogeneity that moderates the omitted

variable bias to which cross-country analyses are subject. In this respect, studies of China

have a unique advantage: China is a centralized country with unified legal and administrative

systems and a fairly homogenous society dominated in most areas by Han ethnicity and

Confucian values. This high degree of legal and social homogeneity helps to efficiently

mitigate the omitted variable bias in any empirical analysis. On the other hand, as shown in

Table 2-1, great economic differences exist between China’s rich eastern and poor western

provinces. For example, in 2008, the GDP (PPP) per capita of Shanghai, which approximates

that of Hungary, was about nine times higher than that of Guizhou province, which resembles

that of Cameroon. Thus, a study of China can provide valuable insights into the causes of

corruption in developing and transitional economies in which corruption is a central issue.

Surprisingly, however, few studies on the causes of corruption employ within-country

data and most that do are working with U.S. data. For instance, Goel and Nelson (1998)

Page 24: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

14  

investigate the effect of government size on corruption using an American annual state-level

data set, while Fisman and Gatti (2002b) use information on the mismatch between revenue

generation and expenditure in American states to test the relationship between

decentralization and corruption. More recent studies by Leeson and Sobel (2007) and Boettke

et al. (2008) show that those American states struck most frequently by natural disasters

attract more disaster relief, creating new opportunities for political corruption comparable to

resource windfalls and therefore setting in motion rent-seeking activities. Boettke et al. (2008)

stress that the Federal Emergency Management Agency relief “is especially corrosive in

terms of corruption because of the chaotic atmosphere in which it is unavoidably deployed. In

the case of a major disaster, the combination of billions of dollars of relief being dumped

onto one location in only a short period of time, along with the confused and difficult-to-

monitor environment in which these windfalls are dispensed, create incredible temptation for

public officials to abuse their positions of power by corruptly appropriating relief funds” (p.

367).

Internationally, Svensson (2003) use firm-level data from Uganda to explore the

determinants of firm bribery payments, while Cai et al. (2009) employ firm-level data to

examine the “micro” causes of corruption in China.

                       Table 2-1 GDP (PPP) per capita of Chinese regions in 2008 (Intl. $)

Beijing 16577 Anhui 3810 Chongqing 4741

Tianjin 14590 Fujian 7922 Sichuan 4044

Hebei 6112 Jiangxi 3887 Guizhou 2321

Shanxi 5365 Shandong 8701 Yunnan 3310

Inner Mongolia 8472 Henan 5153 Tibet 3646

Liaoning 8221 Hubei 5223 Shaanxi 4799

Jilin 6184 Hunan 4608 Gansu 3185

Heilongjiang 5714 Guangdong 9886 Qinghai 4573

Shanghai 19232 Guangxi 3936 Ningxia 4706

Jiangsu 10421 Hainan 4517 Xinjiang 5232

Zhejiang 11102

In this chapter, we adopt both fixed-effect and instrumental variable (IV) approaches to

identify the causes of corruption in China using different regional data sets. Besides

confirming most cross-country findings in a more controlled setting, our study makes three

important contributions to the literature. First, we identify a positive relationship between

corruption and economic development in China, one that stems from the current transition

process. Second, we obtain novel within-country evidence on the depressive effect of the

Page 25: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

15  

Anglo-American colonial heritage, the contributory effect of abundant natural resources, and

the depressive effect of female representation in politics on corruption. Third, we find that

even in a non-democratic country, access to controlled media keeps corruption in check.

The chapter is organized as follows: Section 2.2 reviews previous research on the causes

of corruption, Section 2.3 empirically determines the causes of corruption in China, and

Section 2.4 presents our concluding remarks.

2.2 Determinants of Corruption

Previous research has identified several possible causes of corruption, including political

institutions, the judicial system and the cultural environment; however, as these factors are

homogenous among Chinese regions, we focus here on other determinants. According to Jain

(2001), there are three prerequisites for corruption: bureaucratic discretionary power, the

association of this power with economic rents, and deterrence as a function of the probability

of being caught and penalized. Whereas the first two preconditions determine the benefit of

corruption, the third influences the cost of corruption; therefore, the regional characteristics

that affect these preconditions determine its local incidence (Becker, 1968).

Bureaucratic discretionary power over the allocation of resources is particularly

important to the existence of corruption and, according to Rose-Ackerman (1978), frequently

arises during the enforcement of regulations. That is, because bureaucrats can assign

themselves the discretion to distribute resources when setting and implementing regulations,

more regulations means more discretionary power and thus more incidences of corruption. In

contrast, levels of corruption can be expected to decrease if controlled economies become

more marketized. Governmental discretionary power can also be influenced by

decentralization, although the relationship between decentralization and corruption is still

being debated. According to Brennan and Buchanan (1980) and Weingast (1995),

decentralization introduces competition between local governments, thereby reducing

bureaucratic profits from corruption. For example, the mechanism of entry and exit in U.S.

federal states provides a strong incentive to produce public services in accordance with

individual preferences (Hirschman 1970) and can be a method of government control, as

when exits threaten firms with higher mobility (Rose-Ackerman 1999). Nevertheless, because

federalism and local autonomy combine with innovation, federalism can also serve as a

laboratory for effective policy inventions (Oates 1999). On the other hand, Shleifer and

Vishny (1993) argue that since decentralization causes the dispersion of government power,

bureaucrats that are not coordinated will over-extract rents from firms. Likewise, smallness

Page 26: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

16  

and intimacy of local jurisdictions with patronage-ridden governments promote corrupt

relationships (Rose-Ackerman 1999). In fact, Treisman (2000), using a dummy variable that

reflects whether a state is federal, finds that federal states are seen as more corrupt. Fisman

and Gatti (2002a), however, provide cross-country evidence that fiscal decentralization in

government expenditure is significantly correlated with lower corruption. Using American

data, they also identify a positive relationship between corruption and the proportion of a

state’s expenditure derived from federal transfers (Fisman and Gatti 2002b).

Obviously, rational individuals pay bribes only if they can reap a higher marginal benefit

from doing so. Hence, economic rents related to discretionary powers are a necessary

condition for corruption, but corruption is unlikely to be generated by discretionary powers

without related rents. Indeed, Ades and Di Tella (1999) show that countries in which firms

have higher rents tend to be more corrupt. One concentrated and easily expropriable activity

of particularly high rents is natural resource exploitation (Sachs and Warner 2001), which

echoes Leite and Weidmann’s (1999) empirical finding that the incidence of corruption

depends significantly on natural resource abundance. Treisman (2000), on the other hand,

finds no strong evidence that fuel and mineral exports are positively correlated with

corruption level, although, intriguingly, Leeson and Sobel (2008) report that resource

windfalls generated by disaster relief in frequently affected American states raise public

corruption in much the same manner as rich natural resource endowments. Another source of

economic rents is lack of competition: economic rents decrease when economic activities are

marked by intensive competition. For instance, Ades and Di Tella (1996, 1999), using a

country’s openness – measured by share of imports in the GDP – to indicate firms’ external

competition, find that economic openness is negatively correlated with levels of corruption.

Treisman (2000) also provides evidence of a negative association between the share of

imports in GDP and corruption levels, a relationship similar to that recently identified by

Gerring and Thacker (2005) between corruption and trade openness.

Deterrence of corruption is a joint function of the probability of detection and

punishment once caught, a probability affected by several factors. First, higher income levels

accelerate the spread of education and democratic institutions and therefore enhance

individuals’ political involvement. They consequently enable private individuals to better

identify corrupt behaviours and punish official malfeasance. Hence, regions with richer and

more educated citizens are assumedly less corrupt. In fact, according to Treisman (2007), the

negative relationship between the incidence of corruption and income level is the strongest

and most consistent finding of empirical studies on corruption (see, e.g., La Porta et al. 1999;

Page 27: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

17  

Ades and Di Tella 1999; Treisman 2000). The probability of being caught also depends on

the effectiveness of the country’s legal system. For instance, La Porta et al. (1999) argue that

the common law systems in Britain and its former colonies are more effective in protecting

property rights and enforcement than civil law systems, which would imply that the

probabilities of corruption being exposed are higher in common law countries. Treisman

(2000) does indeed find that, as expected, Britain and its former colonies have substantially

lower levels of corruption than other countries; however, Pellegrini and Gerlagh (2008) find

no such linkage.

Economic and social heterogeneity may also be an indirect determinant of the probability

of detection and thereby affect corruption. For example, You and Khagram (2005) argue that

“the poor are more vulnerable to extortion and less able to monitor and hold the rich and

powerful accountable as income inequality increases” (p. 136). Thus, income inequality

enables the latter to abuse their power for private gain and, as the authors confirm through

cross-country analysis, promotes higher levels of corruption. Husted (1999), on the other

hand, finds no such relationship between income inequality and corruption. One social

heterogeneity factor with the potential to promote corruption is ethnic fractionalization,

which may lead to corrupt officials being protected for political reasons by their own ethnic

groups. Nevertheless, neither Treisman (2000) nor Pellegrini and Gerlagh (2007) find strong

evidence of such a linkage, although Glaeser and Saks’ (2006) results do show a positive

correlation between corruption levels and racial division in U.S. states.

Press freedom also plays an important role in corruption detection because independent

journalists have incentives to investigate its presence or absence. Therefore, as a particular

mechanism of external control, press freedom appears to reduce corruption: firms and

individuals can reveal corrupt behaviour to a journalist and this possibility of media reporting

increases the costs of corruption for bureaucrats (i.e., increases the probability of detection).

In other words, the media can be seen as a platform for voicing complaints (Brunetti and

Weder 2003), and, as Adsera et al. (2003) show, even the “free circulation of a daily

newspaper” (their interaction term between a democratic measure and newspaper circulation)

is negatively correlated with corruption (p. 455). Likewise, Brunetti and Weder (2003) show

empirically that a high level of press freedom is associated with a low incidence of corruption,

Chowdhury (2004) emphasizes that press freedom controls corruption via the channel of

democracy, and Freille et al. (2007), using a modified extreme bounds analysis, provide

evidence that the greater the press freedom, the lower the level of corruption.

Page 28: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

18  

Several interesting papers also address the effect of gender on corruption. For example,

Dollar et al. (2001) and Swamy et al. (2001) observe that countries with a larger share of

women in parliament or government tend to have less corruption, and Swamy et al. (2001)

provide micro evidence that women are less tolerant of bribe acceptance. In fact, according to

Paternoster and Simpson (1996), women may be more risk averse and hence perceive a larger

probability of being caught in corruption. Sung (2003), on the other hand, argues that “the

observed association between gender and corruption is spurious and mainly caused by its

context, liberal democracy – a political system that promotes gender equality and better

governance” (p. 703). Torgler and Valev (2010) thus explore whether gender matters and

whether greater equality of status and opportunities reduces gender differences. Using data

from an almost 20-year period, they find evidence of strong gender differences: even when

different time periods are investigated and opportunity factors are controlled for, women are

significantly less likely to agree that corruption is justified.

The effect of punishment on corruption levels is difficult to test because punishment is

not always comparable across countries. However, higher wages imply higher opportunity

costs when officials are ousted due to corruption, and Van Rijkeghem and Weder (2001) do

in fact find that in developing countries, a higher ratio of civil service wages to

manufacturing wages is significantly correlated with a lower level of corruption. Treisman

(2000), however, finds no clear evidence that higher government wages depress corruption.

Interestingly, even in Ancient Egypt, the pharaohs searched for ways to reduce the corruption

of their tax collectors (called scribes), who were paid high salaries to reduce their incentives

to enrich themselves by cheating taxpayers. Scribes working in the field were also controlled

by a group of special scribes in a “head office” (see Adams, 1993). However, as Rose-

Ackerman (1999) stresses, “[p]ay increases may indeed be necessary for good performance,

but only if the increases are tied to productivity and are accompanied by a reduction in the

overall level of public sector employment” (p. 87).

2.3 Empirical Analysis

Administratively, China is divided into provincial regions, prefectural regions and counties or

districts. We therefore explore the causes of corruption in China using two different regional

data sets: a province-level data set comprised of information from all 31 provincial areas in

mainland China during the 1998 to 2007 period and a city-level data set taken primarily from

a 2005 World Bank and Enterprise Survey Organization of China survey on the investment

climate of Chinese prefecture-level cities (World Bank 2006).

Page 29: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

19  

The first data set covers 22 provinces, 5 autonomous regions and 4 municipalities but

excludes data from Hongkong, Macao and Taiwan because of the substantial differences in

their political and legal systems. We derive the corruption measure for this data set – the

number of regional registered cases of corruption per 100,000 people each year – by

collecting the number of annual registered cases of corruption in the procurator’s office by

region (listed in the China Procuratorial Yearbooks) and then dividing this number by

regional population.5 To ensure comparability of the corruption data, we use only corruption

data from 1998 to 2007 because until the Fifth Session of the Eighth National People's

Congress of China passed the 1997 Criminal Law (which includes Chapter VIII: Crimes of

Embezzlement and Bribery), the definition of corruption-related crimes fluctuated. The

resulting average regional corruption data are listed in Table 2-2. We choose conviction data6

specifically because they offer a less subjective measure of corruption, enable us to work

with longer time spans, and are not subject to problems of sampling error and/or survey non-

response (Glaeser and Saks, 2006). On the other hand, the conviction rate is driven by the

quality of the detection process; this weakness, however, may not be important for our

current study because the quality of local judicial systems in China is basically homogeneous

and our regressions control for local anti-corruption efforts.

The survey from which we take our city-level data set evaluated the investment climate

of 120 cities from almost all the Chinese provinces by sampling 100 industrial firms in each

city except for four municipalities in which it sampled 200 industrial firms (World Bank

2006). As Cai et al. (2009) argue in their firm-level analysis, travel and entertainment costs

(ETC) can be an efficient measure of corruption in Chinese firms because “Chinese managers

commonly use the ETC accounting category to reimburse expenditures used to bribe

government officials, to entertain clients and suppliers, or to accommodate managerial excess”

(p. 2). They also provide strong evidence that a “firm’s ETC consists of a mix that includes

                                                            5 We also replicate our provincial analysis using an alternative corruption measure: the provincial number of officials investigated in registered cases on corruption per 100,000 population. Since this corruption measure is only available in the 2003 to 2007 period, we do not report the estimation results here; however, notably, the results are quite similar.  6 Theoretically conviction rate and the number of registered cases of corruption are different. However in China they are actually the same. In most cases in China suspect officials are first investigated by the discipline inspection commission of the Chinese Communist Party and its local branches. Only after they have obtained enough evidence, the discipline inspection commission and its local branches will refer corrupt cases to the procuratorates, and procuratorates then register the cases. Furthermore the courts and the procuratorates are both controlled by the Chinese government. Therefore in few circumstances the courts will reject public prosecutions against corrupt cases.  

Page 30: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

20  

expenditures on government officials both as ‘grease money’ and ‘protection money’,

implicit CEO pay, and managerial excesses” (p. 22). We therefore use the average travel and

entertainment costs relative to the sales of investigated firms in a city (hereafter, ETC) as a

proxy for city corruption levels on the assumption that ETC derived from representative firms

in Chinese industrialized cities indirectly reflects their overall corruption levels. Statistical

details of this variable can be found in World Bank (2006); detailed descriptions of our other

variables are given in the Appendix.

Table 2-2 Average annual registered cases on corruption across regions in China (1998-2007)

Region Average annual registered cases per 100,000 Pop.

Region Average annual registered cases per 100,000 Pop.

Region Average annual registered cases per 100,000 Pop.

Tianjin 5.01 Shaanxi 3.15 Yunnan 2.61

Heilongjiang 4.77 Qinghai 3.08 Hunan 2.59

Jilin 4.5 Ningxia 3.08 Hainan 2.59

Liaoning 4.12 Hubei 3.05 Beijing 2.59

Shanxi 3.83 Guizhou 2.95 Chongqing 2.49

Hebei 3.67 Zhejiang 2.9 Anhui 2.36

Shandong 3.61 Inner Mongolia 2.77 Sichuan 2.35

Xinjiang 3.41 Shanghai 2.77 Gansu 2.05

Fujian 3.4 Jiangsu 2.71 Guangdong 2.05

Henan 3.35 Guangxi 2.64 Tibet 1.77

Jiangxi 3.29

2.3.1 Province-level Analysis

To effectively compare corruption in China (the largest developing country) to that in

America (the largest developed country), our baseline specification for investigating the

causes of corruption resembles that of Glaeser and Saks (2006)7:

Registered Cases on Corruption = α + γ•Income + δ•Education + η•Anti-corruption

+ β • Other regional characteristics + Error term

Consistent with Glaeser and Saks (2006), this specification measures regional income,

expressed as the logarithm of real gross regional product (GRP) per capita, and educational

levels, the proportion of the regional population over 6 that has completed a college degree.

We also control for anti-corruption efforts because provincial registered cases of corruption

may reflect local government efforts to fight corruption (Treisman, 2007); that is, since the

law systems in different Chinese regions are the same, any differences in anti-corruption

                                                            7 A description of the variables is presented in Table 2-7 in the Appendix.  

Page 31: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

21  

efforts across regions stem from the individual regions’ legal enforcement. Like Goel and

Nelson (1998), we proxy regional anti-corruption efforts by the real per capita expenditure by

local government on police, procuratorate, court and judiciary. We also control for the

differences between North and South China by adding a geographic dummy (North) into the

pooled OLS regressions and whenever possible, use one-year lagged values of the

explanatory variables in our panel regressions to account for the fact that registered cases of

corruption in one year actually reflect the number of corrupt acts done previously but

detected in that year.

To identify the determinants of corruption in China, we must first address two potential

problems in our estimations: multicollinearity (see the correlation matrix in Table 2-88) and

the endogeneity problem. To alleviate the multicollinearity in our regressions, we first adopt

a basic specification that in our panel analysis controls the condition numbers and variance

inflation factors of regressions lower than 100 and 10, respectively. We therefore assume that,

as a rule of thumb, there is no serious multicollinearity in these regressions. In regressions

using the full specification in which severe multicollinearity is detected, we control

multicollinearity by dropping one or more collinear variables 9 while still retaining the

baseline specification to minimize specification bias. Admittedly, it may be argued that

dropping offending variables may produce a specification bias that is potentially worse than

multicollinearity; however, other methods for dealing with multicollinearity – for example,

model re-specification, ridge regression or data reduction techniques like principal

component analysis – are not applicable in our case. More important, our results indicate that

removing select collinear variables from the regressions has little effect on the remaining

parameter estimates, suggesting that it produces no significant specification bias and is thus a

justifiable method for mitigating multicollinearity.

To address the more important problem of endogeneity, which is key to our identification

of corruption determinants in China, we use two strategies: first, we control for unobserved

regional characteristics that influence both corruption and its determinants by including

regional fixed effects in our panel regressions and second, we adopt an IV approach

whenever necessary to identify the causal effects of the corruption determinants. As regards

the first, because Mo (2001, p.70) describes a corruption problem as “an institutional problem

that lasts for a long period” and since the major source of potential bias in our regressions

                                                            8 Table 2-9 presents the correlation matrix for the city-level analysis.  9 We here retain the condition numbers of those regressions lower than 300, which, as a rule of thumb, indicates only moderate multicollinearity. 

Page 32: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

22  

may be time-invariant historical factors, we choose fixed-effect regressions as the most

suitable tool for investigating the relationship between corruption and its determinants. Some

corruption determinants, however, as well as several instruments used for them, are

themselves historical factors and hence time invariant, so standard fixed-effect regressions do

not work in these cases. We thus develop a unified framework for identifying the causality

between corruption and its determinants. Specifically, following Li and Hou (2003),10 we

categorize Chinese provinces into eight groups (Northeastern China, Northern Coastal Areas

of Seaboard of China, Eastern Coastal Areas of China, Southern Coastal Areas of China,

Middle Reaches of the Yellow River, Middle Reaches of the Yangtze River, Southwestern

China and Northwestern China) according to their geographic similarity, natural resource

endowments, economic development, social structure and cultural traditions. We then

perform pooled OLS regressions, which include both regional fixed effects (eight areas) and

year fixed effects, to identify the causes of corruption in China.11 Because Chinese provinces,

especially neighbouring provinces, are to a large extent homogeneous, regional fixed effects

can capture most provincial characteristics while still enabling investigation of the time-

invariant determinants of corruption in China. In fact, the consistency between the results for

our standard fixed-effect regressions and those for our regional effects measure (applied

when the explanatory variables are all time variant) validates our approach.12 Fixed-effect

regressions, however, do not necessarily identify the causal effects on corruption of its

determinants; that is, they cannot guarantee causality when omitted time-variant factors affect

both corruption and its determinants. Therefore, as discussed in more detail below, we adopt

an IV approach whenever necessary to identify the causal effects of the corruption

determinants.

We first investigate the effects of determinants of corruption in China using a baseline

specification that allows comparison with the findings of Glaeser and Saks (2006), as well as

assessment of specification robustness and the importance of alternative factors in its

extension. We then further test the specification’s robustness with joint estimates that use the

                                                            10 This document is actually an official research report of the Development Research Centre of the State Council, a leading comprehensive policy research and consulting institution operating directly under the State Council of the Central Government of the People’s Republic of China. 11 For convenience, we refer to this method as the fixed-effect approach throughout the chapter (although it is not the standard fixed-effect approach).  12 To save space, we do not report the results of our standard fixed-effect regressions, but these findings are available upon request. 

Page 33: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

23  

full specification.13 It is worth noting, however, that the multicollinearity problem becomes

more serious in our 2SLS estimation (i.e., the standard errors of the estimates become large

and there is more inconsistency in the impact of some explanatory variables). Therefore, we

again gradually exclude several collinear variables from the full specification to mitigate

multicollinearity while retaining important explanatory variables to minimize specification

error. Specifically, we first remove the regulation variable which, as shown in Table 2-8, has

the highest correlation coefficient with income of all the explanatory variables. Next, we

exclude openness, which is highly correlated with several other explanatory variables, and

finally we drop education, which is also highly correlated with some other independent

variables. Even such a reduced specification, however, is still among the richest in the causes

of corruption literature.

2.3.1.1 Deterrence and Corruption

To empirically test the effect of deterrence on corruption, we first examine the effect of

income on corruption. The results for the pooled OLS, fixed-effect OLS and fixed-effect

2SLS are presented in Tables 2-3, 2-4 and 2-5, respectively14. In determining the effect of

income, to address the potential omitted variable bias and the reverse causality between

income and corruption identified by Treisman (2000) and Glaeser and Saks (2006), we must

find an instrumental variable for regional income level. Like Hall and Jones (1999) and

Rappaport and Sachs (2003), we instrument provincial income level using a geographic

characteristic, the provincial capital’s latitude (latitude), primarily because historically

China’s developed areas – namely, the middle and lower reaches of the Yellow River since

the Han Dynasty, the middle and lower reaches of the Yangtze River since the Song Dynasty,

and Northeastern provinces since the end of the Qing Dynasty – are in relatively high

latitudes. Because our results provide no evidence that our instrumental variable affects

corruption directly or through channels other than economic development, we believe that

this choice of instruments is valid. In fact, the results from different estimations and different

specifications indicate that income significantly increases corruption in Chinese provinces15

and the effect is fairly large. For example, according to the IV estimation using the baseline

                                                            13 We do not include the Gini coefficient income distribution variable in our full specification because the Gini coefficients for Chinese provinces are only available before 2001, so including them would sharply reduce our sample size. 14 The first-stage regressions are presented in Table 2-10 in the Appendix.  15 Only in two 2SLS regressions does the income variable lose its significance, but, because of multicollinearity, it still retains its sign. 

Page 34: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

24  

specification (Column (1) in Table 2-5), in terms of elasticity, a 1% increase in the GRP

logarithm raises regional registered cases of corruption per 100,000 people by about 11.02%.

At first, this positive effect of income on corruption seems puzzling because it contradicts

previous literature. However, such a result might be driven by the transitional nature of

Chinese society; that is, because “the simultaneous processes of developing a market

economy, designing new political and social institutions and redistributing social assets

[creates] fertile ground for corruption” (World Bank 2000, p. vii), countries making the

transition to a market economy often experience unprecedented corruption (Levin and

Satarov 2000; Paldam and Svendsen 2000). China specifically began its transitional process

when economic reform loosened up its economy; however, political reform has lagged

behind. Therefore, in the absence of institutional and legal constraints, government continues

to play an extensive role in China’s economic environment. One unavoidable consequence of

such involvement is corruption, a type of corruption that becomes more pervasive when

government power is widened through increased economic activity. As a result, regions with

higher income levels may be more corrupt.

On the other hand, Basu and Li (2000) predict theoretically that corruption levels in

transitional countries will decrease after these nations establish or improve institutions,

effectively checking the abuse of public office as the transition processes move on. Income

level would then have a depressing influence on corruption. This prediction has been

confirmed in several Eastern European countries (World Bank 2006). We therefore

conjecture that, with the establishment of good institutions, this phenomenon may diminish

once the Chinese transition is completed. To examine this conjecture, we split the

investigation period into two sub-periods – 1998 to 2002 and 2003 to 2007 – and create a

dummy variable (period) to represent the second sub-period (2003–2007). In the IV

regression using the rich specification (see Column (16) in Table 2-5), the interaction term

between income level and the period dummy has a significantly negative effect on corruption,

which indicates that the positive effect of income on corruption during the 2003–2007 period

is substantially lower than that during the 1998–2002 period. This decrease in the positive

effect of income on corruption in China may imply that a negative effect of income on

corruption may emerge in the future.

To further determine the direction of the causality between income and corruption, we

perform a Hausman test. Like Treisman (2007) and Gundlach and Paldam (2009), we find

that the main direction in the circular relationship between income and corruption in China is

from income to corruption, and, since the Hausman tests (see Columns (1) and (13) in Table

Page 35: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

25  

2-5) show that the IV estimates do not differ systematically from the corresponding OLS

estimates, there is no significant upward bias caused by reverse causality. This result actually

supports our explanation of the positive relationship between income and corruption.

As the tables show, we also investigate the effect of education on corruption and, contrary

to the literature, find that education has a seemingly positive effect on corruption in both the

pooled OLS and fixed-effect regressions. We then instrument provincial education attainment

by the middle-school student enrolment per 100 persons in 1952 (middle1952), which is

certainly exogenous and directly affects current education level. Our IV results (see Table 2-5)

provide moderate evidence that education lowers corruption in Chinese provinces once

income, anticorruption efforts and other variables are controlled for.16 In effect, according to

Column (1) in Table 2-5, a 1% increase in the proportion of the population over 6 that has

completed college is associated with a 0.39% decrease in registered cases of corruption per

100,000 population, a finding that is both reasonable and consistent with the literature (e.g.,

Glaeser and Saks 2006).

Interestingly, as shown in Tables 2-3, 2-4 and 2-5, our proxy for provincial anti-

corruption efforts is, as expected, negatively correlated with corruption, in most cases,

significantly and robustly. This finding suggests that we may have effectively isolated the

anti-corruption effort component from our corruption measure. It is also worth noting that our

proxy is most probably exogenous because in China, public security organs, procuratorial

organs and people’s provincial courts are all directly under central government control.

Hence, because China is typically a centralized country, the budgetary expenditures on these

organs must be approved by the central government even though most are paid out by the

provincial governments. As a result, despite obvious differences across provinces, provincial

expenditures on police, procuratorate, court and judiciary per capita are mainly exogenously

decided by the central government.

In terms of the causal effect of media on corruption, mainstream media in China,

including newspaper, radio and television, are fully controlled by the state, raising the

question of whether media can be expected to act effectively as an external control of

corruption in China (cf. the importance of a free press in Brunetti and Weder 2003).

Following Treisman (2007) and Pellegrini and Gerlagh (2008), therefore, we investigate the

effects of controlled media on corruption in China using the regional newspaper circulation

per capita as a measure. Our results, given in Tables 2-3, 2-4 and 2-5, seem encouraging. We                                                             16 In several IV regressions, education loses its significance and even its sign (see Table 2-5) due primarily to the high correlation between education and certain other explanatory variables. 

Page 36: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

26  

find consistent evidence in both the pooled OLS, fixed-effect and IV regressions that media

in China significantly depress corruption, although the media variable does lose significance

in the IV regression using the full specification, which is not free of multicollinearity issues.

However, if we drop the variables that are highly correlated with income – namely,

marketization (deregulation), education and trade openness – the media exerts a significantly

negative effect on corruption (Column (15) in Table 2-5). As before, the removal of collinear

variables from Regression (15) has little impact on the remaining parameter estimates,

suggesting the absence of any significant specification bias. We hence conclude that media in

China, even if controlled by the Chinese government, do exert negative influences on

corruption. Thus, in contrast to Adsera et al. (2003) and Chowdhury’s (2004) emphasis on the

key role of democracy in media’s effect on corruption, our findings indicate that even

government-controlled media can effectively depress corruption. Our results also suggest that

anti-corruption efforts, as long as they are held within limits, can also be in the interest of

non-democratic governments. In terms of media size and its relation to corruption, according

to Regression (2) in Table 2-5, a 1% increase in annual newspaper circulation per capita

decreases corruption by about 0.04%.

Before exploring the influence of Western colonialism, and specifically the Anglo-

American church university heritage, on corruption in China, a brief historical overview is

warranted of China’s modern history. After China was beaten in a sequence of wars against

foreign colonial powers during the last period of the Qing Dynasty (1840–1911), these

powers, headed by Britain, carved spheres of influence in China through a series of unequal

treaties. Thus, based on their own values, they influenced or even reconstructed local

administration systems, including the legal system, infrastructure and education, within the

domains they controlled. The persistence of these influences may be responsible for some of

the regional differences in current China. Education particularly, as instituted by the British

and Americans in China, may be a key point in this historical influence. For example, in 1890,

F.L. Hawks Pott, president of Saint John’s University, which was founded by the American

Episcopal Church, stated that “in our school, we trained China's future teachers and

propagators, making them the leaders and comperes in the future and casting the greatest

influences on the future China” (Yang and Ye 1993, p. 289). Likewise, Soochow University,

founded by the American Methodist Missionaries in 1900, was renowned in China for its

education in Anglo-American law. We therefore proxy this historical influence by the number

of universities founded by British and American churches in each province before 1922

(Anglo-American). According to the 1918–1921 general survey by the Special Committee on

Page 37: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

27  

Survey and Occupation’s China Continuation Committee,17 there were 14 such universities in

China before 1922, distributed among Beijing, Shanghai, Shandong Jiangsu, Fujian, Hubei,

Hunan, Guangdong and Sichuan provinces. Although forcibly incorporated into public

universities in 1952 by the Chinese government, their influence does indeed persist through

their faculty members and graduates.

All baseline specification results in 2-3, 2-4 and 2-5 show that, in line with Treisman’s

(2000) cross-country findings for British influence, provinces influenced by the Anglo-

American church university heritage have lower levels of corruption than other provinces in

China. Specifically, according to Regression (3) in Table 2-5, such provinces have 0.16 point

fewer registered cases of corruption per 100,000 people on average. However, the Anglo-

American variable, although it retains its sign, loses its significance in the fixed-effect and IV

regressions using the full specification. Besides the methodological issues discussed earlier,

one plausible interpretation for such a result is that the Anglo-American church university

heritage has such a wide influence on various aspects of Chinese provinces that in addition to

its direct influence on corruption, it also affects corruption indirectly through other corruption

determinants. Whichever the case, this variable does indeed affect corruption substantially.

We therefore provide the first within-country evidence for the effect of this Anglo-American

educational influence on corruption.

We then investigate the role of social heterogeneity in Chinese corruption. First, as shown

in the fourth columns of Tables 2-3 and 2-4, we find that higher income inequality measured

by Gini coefficients (Meng et al., 2005) significantly raises the incidence of corruption in

China. This finding is clearly supported by the results for our IV approach, reported in

Column (4) of Table 2-5, which addresses potential reverse causation by using as its

instrumental variable a lagged Gini coefficient (gini86) that represents China’s 1986

initiation of comprehensive economic reform 18 . Overall, our results indicate that a 1%

increase in Gini coefficient increases provincial corruption by about 1.62%. However, as

previously mentioned, we do not test the relationship between income inequality and

corruption in the full specification because of the sharp decrease in sample size. 19

Nevertheless, the results provide primary evidence that income equality substantially

increases corruption in China, which is in line with prior cross-country findings.                                                             17 The China Continuation Committee (2007) originally published its general survey of the numerical strength and geographic distribution of Christian forces in China in Shanghai in 1922. 18  Li et al. (2000) have provided both theoretical and empirical evidence that corruption substantially affects income distribution in a cross-country context. 19 Gini coefficient data before 2001 are only available for 30 provinces other than Tibet.  

Page 38: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

28  

Secondly, we test the impact of racial fractionalization on corruption in China, which is

home to 56 recognized ethnic groups.20 Given this diversity, even though Han ethnicity

accounted for 91.6% of China’s total population in the 2000 national census, we expect racial

fractionalization to have a significant influence on corruption. Accordingly, following Glaser

and Saks (2005), we measure the ethnic fractionalization in China using a dissimilarity index,

calculated as one minus a Herfindahl concentration index, 1-∑si2, where si is the population

share of ethnicity i from the national census in 2000. The fixed effects result in Column (8)

supports our prediction: the dissimilarity index is positively associated with local corruption

level, indicating that ethnic fractionalization significantly promotes corruption in Chinese

provinces. Since the ethnic composition of the population in Chinese provinces has emerged

historically, the provincial dissimilarity index is likely to be exogenous, meaning that our

fixed effects result captures the causal effect of ethnic fractionalization without any potential

endogeneity bias. Nevertheless, the effect, although significant, seems quantitatively small in

terms of elasticity: a 1% increase in the dissimilarity index raises corruption by only 0.11%,

which may reflect the fact that the Han ethnic majority predominates in the majority of

Chinese provinces. We therefore explain this finding of ethnic fractionalization’s

contributory effect on corruption to two factors not addressed in prevailing interpretations.

On the one hand, cadres belonging to ethnic minorities are selected mainly based on their

loyalty to the country and ability to control their own ethnic groups rather than their

incorruptibility. On the other, corrupt officials may be supported by their own ethnic groups

if they can defend group interests. This type of problem prevails especially in the five

autonomous regions and at least three provinces – Yunnan, Guizhou and Qinghai – in which

the Han nationality does not predominate.21

As regards the effect of the public sector’s relative wage, which can be seen as a proxy

for public officials’ opportunity cost for corrupt behaviour, official’s standard wages in the

Chinese provinces sampled here are set by the central government based on inter-provincial

differences in living standards and work conditions.. Therefore, our relative wage variable is

basically exogenous. Based on the results given in Tables 2-3, 2-4 and 2-5, our evidence for

the previous theoretical prediction that the relative wage is negatively correlated with the

incidence of corruption is weak. In terms of magnitude, however, as shown in columns (7)

                                                            20 In addition to the Han ethnic majority, 55 ethnic groups in China are recognized as ethnic minorities. Of these, minority groups, which like the Han majority can be found throughout the country, 18 had a population of over one million according to the 2000 national census. 21 Other Chinese provinces such as Sichuan, Hunan, Hubei, Gansu, Jilin, Guangdong and Heilongjiang also contain autonomous areas of ethnic minorities and therefore to some extent experience the same issue.  

Page 39: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

29  

and (13) of Table 2-5, a 1% increase in the public sector relative wage decreases corruption

by about 0.29%. It may be that in addition to their standard wage, Chinese officials receive

various subsidies from the government offices that employ them, subsidies that, being a type

of grey income, are not made public. Our relative wage ratios would therefore only partially

reflect the officials’ opportunity cost for corrupt behaviour and consequently would have a

weaker effect on corruption than the actual relative wage ratios in Chinese provinces.

Next, following Dollar et al. (2001), we investigate the influence on corruption of the

representation of women in the National People’s Congress (NPC), the only legislative house

in China. Using the share of female NPC members in each province as the main explanatory

variable, we find robust evidence that, consistent with the literature, Chinese provinces with a

greater representation of women in the legislature tend to have lower levels of corruption. In

terms of elasticity, a 1% increase in the representation of women in the NPC reduces

corruption by about 0.22% (Column (6) of Table 2-5). Since China’s centralized structure

means little difference in liberal democracy across Chinese provinces, this finding may

provide within-country evidence of a gender effect on corruption that is not driven by the

concerns raised by Sung (2003, p. 703) discussed beforehand. Not only are differences, if any,

controlled for by the inclusion of regional fixed effects, but the social status of women, the

main determinant of female representation in the NPC, has been established historically in

China. Therefore, our fixed-effect regressions, by controlling for economic development,

educational attainment and regional fixed effects, can identify the causal effect of gender on

corruption without any apparent time-variant factor influencing either corruption or female

representation in the NPC. In any case, corrupt officials do not necessarily discriminate

against women.

2.3.1.2 Discretionary Power, Economic Rents and Corruption

Lord Acton, the British 19th century historian, remarked that “Power tends to corrupt, and

absolute power corrupts absolutely.”22 In this subsection, therefore, we explore the influence

of discretionary power and related economic rents on corruption in China. First, to examine

the effect of fiscal decentralization on regional corruption levels, we measure fiscal

decentralization in China using the ratio of per capita provincial consolidated spending to per

capita central consolidated spending (Zhang and Zou 1998).23 As Tables 2-3, 2-4 and 2-5

show, like Fisman and Gatti (2002a, b), we provide robust evidence that fiscal

                                                            22 Lord Acton, 1887, Letter to Bishop Mandell Creighton. 23 For a detailed description of public finance in Chinese provinces, please refer to Zhang and Zou (1998).  

Page 40: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

30  

decentralization significantly decreases provincial corruption levels in China. In fact,

according to Regression 8 in Table 2-5, a 1% increase in fiscal decentralization reduces

corruption in Chinese provinces by about 0.05%. This finding is seemingly in line with

Montinola et al.’s (1995) contention that China has a unique market-preserving federal

system in which local governments have strong fiscal incentives to support local economic

development and hence restrict their own predation on local enterprises. It may as easily be

explained, however, by Bai et al.’s (2008) argument that “fiscal decentralization, one of the

centrepieces of reform policies introduced since 1979, has unleashed strong incentives on the

part of the local governments to pursue economic development. However, without proper

mechanisms to redistribute the gains from specialization and trade across regions, the same

incentives for economic development may lead to protectionist policies favouring the local

firms and industries” (p. 318). The empirical evidence of Jin et al. (2005) and Li and Zhou

(2005) also imply that local officials in China implement the protectionist policies mainly for

local business development rather than rent seeking. It is therefore plausible that fiscal

decentralization in China generally depresses local corruption. Shleifer and Vishny’s (1993)

observation that decentralization results in “excess” rent extraction because of a lack of

coordination among officials may not apply in China.

To measure the effect of government regulation on local corruption levels, we use the

relationship between the market and the government, one of the sub-indices (regulation) of

Fan et al.’s (2010) Marketilization Index of China, constructed to measure the degree of

government regulation in Chinese provinces. In effect, this index covers five main aspects of

Chinese marketization: the relationship between the market and the government; the growth

of the non-state economy; the development of the product market; the development of the

factor market; and the market environment, including intermediaries and institutional and

jurisdictional arrangements. Based on Fan et al.’s (2010) use of the sub-index on

market/government relationship to measure provincial progress on deregulation, we assume

this sub-index to be negatively correlated with the degree of government regulation in

Chinese provinces. In fact, both the pooled OLS (Table 2-3) and fixed effects (Table 2-4)

evidence shows that the (de)regulation variable is negatively associated with corruption in

Chinese provinces.

We then employ the IV approach to deal with potential endogeneity problems. Because

provinces with a larger proportion of the state-owned sector always have more regulations

and tend to make less progress on deregulation, we use the provincial employment share of

the state-owned sector in 1978 (just prior to Chinese economic reform) to instrument the

Page 41: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

31  

regulation variable. Our IV regressions provide strong evidence that deregulation reduces

provincial corruption. Specifically, as shown in Column (9) of Table 2-5, a 1% rise in the

marketilization index decreases corruption by approximately 2.72%.

To assess the role of economic rents, we test the associations between corruption level

and several factors that influence the scale of economic rents in China. The first, abundance

of natural resources, is supposed to be an inducement to corruption because of the associated

economic rents. However, since the export share of natural resources used by Ades and Di

Tella (1999) is unsuitable for measuring the regional abundance of natural resource in a

within-country analysis, we follow Xu and Wang (2006) and use the fraction of employment

in the mining and quarrying sector as a proxy for natural resource abundance in Chinese

provinces. As Tables 2-3, 2-4 and 2-5 show, like previous studies, we provide robust

evidence that the abundance of natural resources significantly increases corruption in Chinese

provinces. In Regression (9) in Table 2-5, particularly, a 1% increase in the fraction of

employment in the mining and quarrying sector is associated with about a 0.11% rise in

provincial corruption.

We then investigate the effect of trade openness, measured by the share of imports in

GRP, on corruption levels in Chinese provinces. As the fixed-effect regression results in

Table 2-4 show, trade openness significantly lowers the provincial corruption level.

Moreover, because regional fixed effects capture economic development, educational

attainment and cultural traditions, there is apparently no unobserved factor influencing

corruption and population simultaneously and the provincial population is exogenous. 24

Nevertheless, to address this potential simultaneity bias (Treisman 2000), we also perform IV

regressions that use population as the instrumental variable for openness (see Table 2-5). A

large population means a large market size and is therefore valued by foreign businesses. All

else being equal, import may thus be positively correlated with population size. Our IV

finding clearly supports the fixed effects result: openness substantially reduces corruption in

China. In fact, according to the instrumental variables regression using the baseline

specification (see Table 2-5), a 1% increase in trade openness reduces regional corruption by

nearly 0.35%.

                                                            24 We note that the one-child policy, which significantly influences regional populations in China, differs across provinces. However, this inter-provincial policy difference is exogenously determined by the central government and is mostly captured by our regional fixed-effect regressions. 

Page 42: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

32  

Table 2-3 Corruption and its determinants in China: pooled OLS estimation Annual Cases (1998-2007) (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) (10) (11) (12)

Income 0.61*** 0.54*** 0.75*** 0.98*** 0.57*** 0.55*** 0.59*** 0.60*** 1.00*** 0.64*** 0.62*** 1.02*** (0.11) (0.11) (0.16) (0.20) (0.13) (0.13) (0.11) (0.11) (0.16) (0.11) (0.11) (0.19) Education 0.045** 0.092*** 0.049*** 0.019 0.046** 0.047** 0.062*** 0.046** 0.074*** 0.050*** 0.049*** 0.13*** (0.018) (0.021) (0.018) (0.060) (0.019) (0.018) (0.018) (0.018) (0.022) (0.017) (0.019) (0.025) Anticorruption -0.0070*** -0.0071*** -0.0076*** -0.0077* -0.0069*** -0.0069*** -0.0072*** -0.0067*** -0.0095*** -0.0065*** -0.0069*** -0.010*** (0.00073) (0.00069) (0.00088) (0.0043) (0.00072) (0.00075) (0.00076) (0.00080) (0.0012) (0.00075) (0.00080) (0.0013) North 0.72*** 0.69*** 0.60*** 0.80*** 0.72*** 0.75*** 0.64*** 0.72*** 0.46*** 0.49*** 0.71*** 0.11 (0.097) (0.096) (0.11) (0.15) (0.098) (0.11) (0.098) (0.097) (0.096) (0.13) (0.10) (0.15) Media -0.0023*** -0.0022** (0.00059) (0.00086)Anglo-American -0.15* -0.16** (0.077) (0.079) Gini 7.62*** (2.55) Dissimilarity -0.16 -0.28 (0.20) (0.23) Wage 0.43 0.41 (0.39) (0.34) Female -4.27*** -2.86** (1.30) (1.40) Decentralization -0.015 -0.029*** (0.010) (0.0046) Regulation -0.14*** -0.19*** (0.030) (0.033) Resource 0.050** 0.045** (0.020) (0.019) Openness -0.0013 0.011** (0.0036) (0.0043) Constant -2.30** -1.80* -3.46*** -7.29*** -1.92* -2.32** -1.29 -2.22** -4.77*** -2.81*** -2.40** -4.49*** (0.98) (0.96) (1.32) (1.89) (1.13) (0.99) (0.91) (0.98) (1.24) (0.98) (0.96) (1.45) R-squared 0.33 0.35 0.34 0.37 0.33 0.33 0.36 0.33 0.37 0.35 0.33 0.46 Observations 310 308 310 120 310 310 310 310 307 310 310 305

Notes: a. Robust standard errors in parentheses; ***, ** and * denote significance at 1%, 5% and 10%, respectively. b. Unless otherwise noted, hereafter we use

the one-year lagged values of the explanatory variables in the panel regressions.

Page 43: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

33  

Table 2-4 Corruption and its determinants in China: fixed effects OLS estimation Annual Cases (1998-2007) (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) (10) (11) (12)

Income 0.56** 0.55*** 0.69*** 0.68* 0.64*** 0.56*** 0.39** 0.60*** 0.62*** 0.59*** 0.73*** 0.76*** (0.22) (0.20) (0.24) (0.35) (0.21) (0.21) (0.18) (0.22) (0.21) (0.21) (0.22) (0.17) Education 0.029 0.10*** 0.029 -0.062 0.0073 0.027 0.046*** 0.029 0.057** 0.023 0.065*** 0.088*** (0.020) (0.017) (0.019) (0.057) (0.021) (0.020) (0.017) (0.020) (0.023) (0.019) (0.019) (0.023) Anticorruption -0.0053*** -0.0044*** -0.0056*** -0.0011 -0.0047*** -0.0052*** -0.0048*** -0.0049*** -0.0070*** -0.0043*** -0.0029*** -0.0030** (0.00081) (0.00061) (0.00080) (0.0047) (0.00079) (0.00079) (0.00084) (0.00081) (0.0011) (0.00081) (0.00097) (0.0014) Newspaper -0.0048*** -0.0017** (0.00063) (0.00081)Anglo-American -0.21*** -0.066 (0.078) (0.073) Gini 7.12** (3.57) Dissimilarity 0.82*** 0.54** (0.23) (0.26) Wage -0.54* -0.43 (0.32) (0.32) Female -5.66*** -4.66*** (1.32) (1.29) Decentralization -0.019*** -0.025*** (0.0058) (0.0047) Regulation -0.12*** -0.090** (0.035) (0.039) Resource 0.054*** 0.055*** (0.013) (0.013) Openness -0.020*** -0.0097** (0.0037) (0.0048) Constant -2.17 -2.62 -3.36 -4.51 -3.29* -1.58 0.28 -2.51 -1.96 -2.92 -4.34** -3.21** (1.94) (1.79) (2.10) (2.94) (1.93) (1.95) (1.64) (1.95) (1.82) (1.89) (2.01) (1.58) R-squared 0.56 0.62 0.57 0.60 0.57 0.56 0.60 0.56 0.57 0.58 0.58 0.68 Observations 310 308 310 120 310 310 310 310 307 310 310 305

Note: Robust standard errors in parentheses; ***, ** and * denote significance at 1%, 5% and 10%, respectively.

Page 44: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

34  

Table 2-5 Corruption and its determinants in China: fixed effects 2SLS estimation Annual Cases (1998-2007) (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) (10) (11) (12) (13) (14) (15) (16)

Income 3.72*** 2.50** 4.14*** 0.77 3.50*** 3.11*** 4.18*** 3.44*** 3.14* 2.29*** 3.52*** 0.10 1.62** 1.11* 0.85*** 2.56** (1.02) (1.07) (1.07) (1.02) (0.98) (1.04) (1.16) (0.91) (1.78) (0.71) (0.99) (0.58) (0.74) (0.65) (0.31) (1.03) Income*period -1.53** (0.61) Education -0.22*** -0.083 -0.21*** -0.27* -0.22*** -0.17** -0.26*** -0.20*** 0.18* -0.15*** -0.013 0.17** -0.039 -0.031 -0.12 (0.075) (0.090) (0.071) (0.15) (0.074) (0.074) (0.085) (0.065) (0.10) (0.055) (0.068) (0.072) (0.066) (0.059) (0.11) Anticorruption -0.0046*** -0.0044*** -0.0063*** 0.013 -0.0040*** -0.0046*** -0.0046** -0.0040** -0.024*** -0.0025* 0.0042 -0.0096 0.0029* -0.0017* -0.0019** 0.0050* (0.0018) (0.0011) (0.0017) (0.010) (0.0015) (0.0015) (0.0019) (0.0016) (0.0088) (0.0014) (0.0030) (0.0060) (0.0017) (0.00097) (0.00083) (0.0028) Media -0.0029*** -0.0044 0.0023 -0.00066 -0.0011** -0.00054 (0.0011) (0.0029) (0.0014) (0.00099) (0.00054) (0.0022) Anglo-American -0.48*** -0.11 -0.031 -0.10 -0.084 -0.046 (0.13) (0.12) (0.084) (0.082) (0.071) (0.11) Gini 19.3*** (7.08) Dissimilarity 1.81*** -0.0087 1.23*** 1.12*** 0.99*** 1.57*** (0.49) (0.53) (0.39) (0.34) (0.21) (0.56) Female -3.04* -2.61 -7.19*** -5.02*** -4.91*** -5.51*** (1.59) (2.79) (1.68) (1.29) (1.24) (1.73) Wage -0.78 -0.10 -0.78** -0.59* -0.53* 0.13 (0.64) (0.39) (0.34) (0.33) (0.30) (0.61) Decentralization -0.034* -0.029*** -0.031*** -0.023*** -0.021*** -0.044* (0.019) (0.0084) (0.011) (0.0070) (0.0046) (0.025) Regulation -1.25*** -0.33** (0.44) (0.15) Resource 0.066*** 0.037* 0.081*** 0.067*** 0.063*** 0.098*** (0.015) (0.021) (0.016) (0.015) (0.012) (0.021) Openness -0.075*** 0.018 -0.034*** -0.012 (0.018) (0.025) (0.0093) (0.013) Constant -30.1*** -19.7** -33.8*** -8.20 -28.9*** -24.2*** -33.3*** -27.6*** -17.0 -18.0*** -30.5*** 4.33 -11.4* -6.60 -4.34 -6.94 (9.05) (9.36) (9.47) (8.03) (8.77) (9.38) (10.0) (8.00) (13.4) (6.35) (8.96) (5.54) (6.62) (5.78) (2.89) (8.90) Hausman test 16.37

[0.63] 1.59

[0.99]

Observations 310 308 310 120 310 310 310 310 307 310 310 305 308 308 308 308

Note: Robust standard errors in parentheses; p-values in brackets; ***, ** and * denote significance at 1%, 5% and 10%, respectively.

Page 45: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

35  

Overall, the empirical findings of our detailed evaluation of a substantial set of

corruption determinants in Chinese provinces are robust to a variety of specifications. One

important question does remain, however: whether our findings remain robust when applied

to a different data set. To answer this question, we replace our province-level data set with a

city-level data set.

2.3.2 City-level Analysis

To check the robustness of the above findings, we replicate the analysis using a city-level

data set and a different corruption measure, the average ratio of travel and entertainment costs

to the sales of firms in Chinese cities (ETC), which prior literature (World Bank 2006; Cai et

al. 2009) shows to be an appropriate indirect measure for corruption in Chinese cities. Such a

city-level data analysis, however, does have certain limitations. First, survey data can be

noisy and may make our estimation less precise. Second, because the 2005 World Bank

survey that originally measured ETC focuses on manufacturing enterprises, our corruption

measure may not be as comprehensive as the measure in our provincial analysis. Third, fewer

data are available at the city level, which reduces our ability to replicate all the previous

findings.

As in the province-level analysis, our specification is

ETC = α + γ•log (Income) + δ•Education + η•Anti-corruption

+ β•Other city characteristics + Error term

where the income level of a city is measured by its logarithm of GRP per capita in 2003.

Because of the unavailability of direct data, for general education level, we use a city’s local

library collections per capita in 2003. To proxy local anti-corruption efforts, because

impartial and efficient courts effectively prevent expropriation and significantly promote anti-

corruption, we use the average confidence in the courts of the local firms investigated in the

World Bank survey. We then include in our specification all the other determinants of

corruption confirmed in the provincial analysis that are available at a city level. As Table 2-9

shows, the city-level analysis raises little concern about multicollinearity.

Because city-level data on newspaper circulation is unavailable, we use the Internet

terminals per capita in a city in 2003 to measure the effect of media on corruption in Chinese

cities. This choice is particularly appropriate given the many recent cases of Internet users in

China revealing official malfeasance and corruption to force officials out of office (Freedom

House, 2009) despite government censorship of the network. As in the provincial analysis,

Page 46: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

36  

we use the number of church universities founded by Britain and America in each city before

1922 to proxy for the Anglo-American historical influence. However, our sample cities are

not at the same administrative level. There are 4 municipalities and 5 cities specifically

designated in the state plan 25 in our sample which share their revenues and expenditures

directly with the central government, while other cities are regular prefecture-level ones

which share their revenues and expenditures mainly with provincial governments. Rather

than using the ratio of per capita provincial consolidated spending to per capita central

consolidated spending to measure fiscal decentralization as in the provincial analysis, like

Fisman and Gatti (2002b), we measure fiscal decentralization in Chinese cities by the

mismatch between government budgetary revenue and budgetary expenditure, which

indicates the dependence of city-level finance on higher-level governments. Since private

enterprises can only grow quickly in cities with less regulation, we proxy government

deregulation in Chinese cities by the employment shares of the private sector in these cities in

2003. To measure their trade openness, we use the share of imports in GRP. Finally, we

include the dummy north to indicate cities in North China.

As in the provincial analysis, to identify corruption determinants at the city level, we

obtain primary results using OLS regressions and then apply an IV approach to address

potential endogeneity problems. We here still use latitude to instrument the economic

development in Chinese cities. We cannot, however, use city population as an instrument for

openness because foreign businesses in China always target province-level markets, meaning

that the market size of cities cannot be a determinant of their imports. Rather, because special

economic zones26 have more import autonomy (which reduces import cost), we instrument

trade openness in Chinese cities using a dummy variable indicating special economic zones

(econzone), with which trade openness is of course positively correlated. Because data

limitations make it difficult to find valid instruments for education and regulation at the city

level, we lag these variables by two years to minimize the endogeneity bias.

As Table 2-6 shows, in line with our provincial findings, economic development

significantly increases corruption in Chinese cities, whereas fiscal decentralization

substantially lowers it. Anti-corruption efforts also strongly deter corruption in Chinese cities,

which implies that our regressions effectively control for these efforts. Trade openness,                                                             25 A city specifically designated in the state plan is a prefecture-level city that is ruled by a province, but enjoys provincial-level economic authority since it is under direct economic guidance of the central government. The mayor of the city is equal in status to a vice-governor of a province. 26 There are actually five special economic zones in China: Shenzhen, Zhuhai, Xiamen, Shantou and Hainan capital of which is Haikou. 

Page 47: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

37  

deregulation, media and the Anglo-American church university heritage, however, perhaps

because of data noise, have only insignificantly negative effects on local corruption.

Overall, the evidence generated using city-level data supports the findings obtained with

province-level data, which thus enables a comprehensive profile of the causes of corruption

in China.

Table 2-6 Corruption and its determinants in Chinese cities 

ETC (2005) OLS 2SLS

(1) (2)

Income -0.023 0.93** (0.10) (0.48) Education 0.0012 0.0000066 (0.0014) (0.0021) Anticorruption -0.012*** -0.013*** (0.0024) (0.0033) Media -0.0020 -0.12 (0.036) (0.085) Anglo-American -0.0093 -0.057 (0.14) (0.19) Decentralization 0.0024 0.024*** (0.0032) (0.011) Regulation -0.043 -0.37 (0.33) (0.50) Openness -0.0025** -0.0016 (0.0013) (0.0059) North -0.11 -0.24 (0.087) (0.15) Constant 2.07* -7.36 (1.05) (4.69) R-squared 0.28

First Stage Regressions Instruments Latitude 0.028** (0.011) Econzone 48.05** (18.59) F test of excluded instruments Latitude 4.97

[0.01] Econzone 4.85

[0.01] Anderson canon. corr. LM statistic 9.52

[0.00] Observations 118 118

Notes: a. Standard errors in parentheses; p-values in brackets; ***, ** and * denote significance at 1%, 5% and 10%, respectively. b. We adopt values in 2003 or 2004 for the explanatory variables (i.e., lagged by a year or two because of data availability).

Page 48: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

38  

2.4 Conclusion

A comprehensive case study of a representative country may prove a helpful supplement to

cross-country analyses on corruption using subjective survey data because these latter suffer

from a number of biases. In this chapter, therefore, we present a detailed investigation of the

causes of corruption in China, which uses two different sets of objective data across various

Chinese regions. Because almost no extant studies on the causes of corruption use within-

country data and those that do employ U.S. data, our study complements previous cross-

country research by isolating possible cultural and institutional differences within a specific

country. It also complements U.S. studies such as Glaeser and Saks (2006) by using panel

data, addressing omitted variable biases with an IV approach, and exploring a larger set of

independent factors. Our use of two different data sets and different measures of corruption

also allows a robust investigation of the causes of corruption.

Figure 2-1 Determinants of corruption in China

As shown in Figure 2-1, we find that with the exception of the positive relationship

between income and corruption, the Chinese case generally retains the patterns of corruption

identified in cross-country analyses. Nevertheless, we also find evidence that in China, the

negative effect of income on corruption frequently suggested by literature may be temporarily

overwhelmed during the transition process and may only perhaps emerge after the transition

Resource abundance

Income

Education

Anglo-American tradition

Social heterogeneity

 

Relative wage

Fiscal decentralization

Regulations

Openness

Media

Ben

efit

+

+

+

+

Cost

Corruption

—Female representation in legislature

Page 49: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

39  

is completed. Our results also show that, in line with Treisman (2007) and Gundlach and

Paldam (2009), the long-run causation between income and corruption runs mainly from

income to corruption. We also obtain clear evidence that, taking into account regional income

levels, educational attainment reduces corruption in Chinese provinces, which is also

significantly depressed by anti-corruption efforts. One novel result is the relatively strong

evidence that media, even under government control, does indeed act as a control instrument

for corruption in China. Another rather unique finding is that a greater representation of

women in the legislature depresses corruption in Chinese regions. As with prior cross-country

evidence on the influence of the British colonial tradition, we find that the Anglo-American

church university heritage adversely affects corruption. Our findings also support the

hypothesis that various social heterogeneities breed corrupt practices; however, we find only

weak evidence to support the theory that relatively high relative wages within the public

sector deter officials from corruption. We also provide concrete evidence that regions with a

higher degree of deregulation appear to be less corrupt in transitional China and that fiscal

decentralization tends to discourage local corruption (cf. Fisman and Gatti 2002a, b). Finally,

we provide clear evidence that openness substantially suppresses the incidence of corruption,

whereas abundance of resources acts as a breeding ground for corruption.

Our empirical findings have significant policy implications. First, during China’s

transitional process, economic development appears to increase corruption. However, given

that economic development substantially accelerates the transitional process, it should be

encouraged. Economic development coulc depress corruption after the transition is completed.

At the same time, because the negative effects of trade openness, deregulation and fiscal

decentralization on corruption suggest that competition, either between enterprises or

governments, plays an important role in corruption control, policies that induce more

competition in either commercial or political markets could help to reduce corruption. Much

attention should also be paid to anti-corruption efforts in provinces rich in resources because

such abundance provides a breeding ground for corrupt practices. The fight against

corruption should also take into account important historical influences. Even in China,

media, although government controlled, can act as a watchdog over corruption; however,

given Brunetti and Weder’s (2003) observation that a freer press controls corruption more

effectively, more press freedom would be beneficial. Additionally, although high salary

seemingly deters officials from corruption in China, as Rose-Ackerman (1999) argues, high

public sector salaries can be justified only if sector productivity increases while its size

decreases. Otherwise, high pay in the public sector, although it may decrease individual acts

Page 50: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

40  

of corruption, is itself a form of corruption. In general, our results imply that a more educated

population and a society characterized by more income equality, gender equality and racial

equality equates with lower levels of corruption. Finally, historical influences should be

considered when fighting against corruption as they may have substantial effects on the legal

system and the moral norms (Treisman, 2000).

Page 51: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

41  

Appendix

Table 2-7 Data description Variable Description Source Mean S. D. Cases Provincial registered cases on corruption in

procurator’s office per 100,000 population China Procuratorial Yearbooks 3.09 0.94

ETC Average travel and entertainment costs relative to sales of industrial firms investigated in a city

World Bank (2006) 1.13 0.45

Anti-corruption Regional expenditure on police, procuratorate, court and judiciary per capita Confidence in courts of firms investigated in a city

China Statistical Yearbooks World Bank (2006)

112.43 63.75

103.41 16.81

Income Logarithm of per capita real GRP — province — city

China Statistical Yearbooks China City Statistical Yearbook

9.15 9.47

0.63 0.66

Education Fraction of the population over 6 with college completed Library collections per capita

China Statistical Yearbooks China City Statistical Yearbook

5.44 46.57

4.31 56.61

Wage Ratio of average government employee’ wage to the regional average wage

China Statistical Yearbooks 1.13 0.13

Openness Ratio of import to gross regional product Provincial Statistical Yearbooks China City Statistical Yearbook

14.45 21.57

22.62 43.79

Newspaper Annual newspapers circulation per capita Provincial Statistical Yearbooks 41.38 88.07 Internet Internet terminals per capita in a city China City Statistical Yearbook 0.82 1.58 Dissimilarity The dissimilarity index The Fifth National Census of China 0.18 0.20 Gini Gini coefficients Meng, Gregory R. and Wang (2005) 0.26 0.03 Resource Employment share of the mining and quarrying sector China Statistical Yearbooks 4.93 3.75 Anglo-American Regional number of church universities founded by Britain

and America before 1922 China Continuation Committee (2007)

Decentralization Ratio of per capita provincial consolidated spending to per capita central consolidated spending

China Finance Yearbooks 38.20 19.52

(Government expenditure – government revenue ) / government expenditure

China City Statistical Yearbook 37.27 18.19

Regulation Relationship between the market and the government Fan, Wang, and Zhu (2010) 6.72 2.04 Share of employment of the private firms China City Statistical Yearbook 0.39 0.12 Resource The fraction of employment in the mining sector in 2003 China City Statistical Yearbook Female Female representation in the National People’s Congress Documents of National People’s

Congress 0.22 0.041

Population Logarithm of regional population China Statistical Yearbooks 8.02 0.89 North Dummy indicating regions in North China China Statistical Yearbooks

Page 52: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

42  

Table 2-8 Pairwise correlation coefficients between explanatory variables in the province-level analysis

Income Education Anticorruption Media Openness Resource Decentralization Wage Dissimilarity AngloAmerican Female Regulation North

Income 1.00

Education 0.76 1.00

Anticorruption 0.78 0.79 1.00

Media 0.49 0.76 0.56 1.00

Openness 0.73 0.80 0.74 0.75 1.00

Resource -0.30 -0.21 -0.37 -0.26 -0.43 1.00

Decentralization -0.45 -0.33 -0.15 -0.34 -0.54 0.21 1.00

Wage 0.38 0.14 0.23 0.068 0.26 -0.31 -0.29 1.00

Dissimilarity -0.36 -0.12 -0.13 -0.19 -0.29 0.011 0.51 -0.20 1.00

Anglo-American 0.47 0.24 0.25 0.22 0.46 -0.44 -0.58 0.38 -0.41 1.00

Female 0.15 0.24 0.17 0.47 0.27 -0.12 -0.35 0.17 -0.10 0.32 1.00

Regulation 0.80 0.48 0.56 0.23 0.57 -0.35 -0.58 0.44 -0.44 0.51 0.061 1.00

North 0.090 0.26 0.0061 0.16 -0.023 0.58 0.16 -0.28 0.086 -0.41 -0.078 -0.24 1.00

Table 2-9 Pairwise correlation coefficients between explanatory variables in the city-level analysis Income Education Anticorruption Internet Decentralization Openness Regulation AngloAmerican North

Income 1.00

Education 0.50 1.00

Anticorruption 0.029 -0.18 1.00

Media 0.51 0.58 -0.018 1.00

Decentralization -0.73 -0.39 -0.086 -0.31 1.00

Openness 0.63 0.52 0.038 0.61 -0.40 1.00

Regulation 0.029 0.0089 -0.056 0.10 0.046 0.0085 1.00

Anglo-American 0.35 0.74 -0.016 0.21 -0.33 0.33 -0.044 1.00

North -0.071 -0.032 -0.181 -0.11 0.19 -0.17 -0.33 -0.15 1.00

Page 53: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

43  

Table 2-10 First-Stage Regressions Based on Table 2-5 Instruments Coefficients of corresponding instrumental variables in first stage regressions Latitude 0.037***

(0.0029) 0.037*** (0.0028)

0.035***(0.0029)

0.035***(0.0060)

0.037***(0.0030)

0.036***(0.0028)

0.038***[0.0030]

0.037*** (0.0029)

0.025***(0.0034)

0.045***(0.0031)

0.037***(0.0030)

0.027***(0.0044)

0.043***(0.0040)

0.043***(0.0037)

0.045*** (0.0036)

0.043*** (0.0042)

Middle1952 3.76***(0.37)

3.28*** (0.45)

3.89***(0.37)

2.40***(0.49)

3.71***(0.35)

3.91***(0.40)

3.83***(0.39)

3.80*** (0.38)

3.58***(0.40)

3.69***(0.38)

3.74***(0.37)

3.32***(0.56)

3.29***(0.45)

3.29***(0.45)

3.31*** (0.45)

Gini86 0.35***(0.11)

Employ1978 -6.77***(1.40)

-8.25***(1.60)

Population 4.06***(0.98)

6.56***(0.94)

6.85***(0.97)

6.87*** (0.96)

Latitude*period 0.018*** (0.0036)

Instruments F-test of excluded instrumental variables Latitude 163.81

[0.00] 122.92 [0.00]

131.70 [0.00]

12.59 [0.00]

139.81 [0.00]

167.51 [0.00]

164.20 [0.00]

157.77 [0.00]

104.27 [0.00]

195.13 [0.00]

109.05 [0.00]

48.75 [0.00]

54.51 [0.00]

80.34 [0.00]

153.24 [0.00]

40.90 [0.00]

Middle1952 81.02 [0.00]

53.49 [0.00]

86.54 [0.00]

20.79 [0.00]

115.50 [0.00]

79.47 [0.00]

80.47 [0.00]

80.73 [0.00]

44.83 [0.00]

83.67 [0.00]

59.53 [0.00]

34.14 [0.00]

59.08 [0.00]

83.26 [0.00]

44.91 [0.00]

Gini86 10.12 [0.00]

Employ1978 13.32 [0.00]

30.72 [0.00]

Population 19.44 [0.00]

16.38 [0.00]

18.89 [0.00]

14.64 [0.00]

Latitude*period 9.60 [0.00]

Instruments Partial R-squared of excluded instrumental variables Latitude 0.32 0.29 0.28 0.23 0.32 0.34 0.32 0.32 0.38 0.37 0.32 0.33 0.28 0.28 0.26 0.28 Middle1952 0.62 0.48 0.63 0.37 0.65 0.62 0.62 0.62 0.61 0.62 0.63 0.44 0.46 0.46 0.46 Gini86 0.24 Employ1978 0.21 0.45 Population 0.30 0.26 0.24 0.25 Latitude*period 0.14 Anderson canon. corr. LM statistic

19.35 [0.00]

9.33 [0.00]

18.20 [0.00]

17.87 [0.00]

21.53 [0.00]

14.16 [0.00]

20.30 [0.00]

22.23 [0.00]

9.08 [0.00]

28.97 [0.00]

20.73 [0.00]

10.57 [0.00]

17.89 [0.00]

17.58 [0.00]

80.93 [0.00]

13.92 [0.00]

Note: Robust standard errors in parentheses; p-values in brackets; ***, ** and * denote significance at 1%, 5% and 10%, respectively.

Page 54: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

44  

Chapter Three Political Interest and Corruption: Cross-country Evidence27

 

3.1 Introduction

Research into the determinants of corruption has recently intensified, with an increasing

number of studies devoted to exploring the causes and consequences of corruption at the

international level. However, most of these studies explore corruption at the macro level

while only a limited number of studies have investigated the determinants of corruption at the

individual level (see, e.g., Mocan 2004, Swamy et al. 2001, Torgler and Valev 2006). This

empirical study aims to identify the determinants of corruption at the micro level by working

with a set of individual level data covering a large number of countries. We analyze a cross-

section of individuals from the World Values Survey wave III (1995-1997) employing the

perceived corruption and the justifiability of corruption as dependent variables. .An

additional objective in this chapter is to investigate whether political interest affects

corruption by working with several different proxies of political interest, i.e. discussion

intensity, interest in politics and importance of politics in life. Despite the increasing interest

of economists in the determinants of corruption, the link between political interest and

corruption has not yet come under intense empirical investigation.

We anticipate that the use of micro-data sets will afford more insights into the corruption

literature. However, there are benefits and drawbacks of such a data set. One of the major

advantages lies in the ability to investigate a broad set of countries. On the other hand,

drawing conclusions from such a large data file could prove problematic since institutional

and cultural frameworks in certain countries might influence corruption, and such features

cannot always be controlled in a satisfactory manner. To this end, we also provide within-

country evidence focusing on Switzerland, since the institutions in this country are not

homogenous. Analyzing Swiss data is interesting because the degree of institutionalized

political participation rights varies strongly between the 26 Swiss cantons.

There are five innovative aspects to this chapter: 1) it explores the relationship between

political interest and corruption using three different proxies of political interest. Previous

studies have not explored this link, but rather have discussed the impact of formal education

without considering the impact of political interest or informal education. 2) While we

observe a large number of studies at the macro-level, we observe only a limited number of

                                                            27 This chapter is published in the Journal of Interdisciplinary Economics 2009, 21, 295-325. 

Page 55: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

45  

micro-level studies. Mocan (2004) suggests a possible cause of this deficiency in previous

studies: “because corruption data are available only at the aggregate (country) level, existing

research has focused on explaining the cross-country variation in corruption. Two exceptions

are Swamy et al. (2001) and Svensson (2003)” (p. 2). 3) Most studies at the macro level focus

on the perceived level of corruption without considering the willingness to bribe (justifiability

of corruption). This study explores both aspects in detail. It is interesting to note that by

measuring the willingness to accept corruption we are able to investigate the social norms of

compliance in a society. 4) We not only provide cross-country evidence at the micro level,

but also explore the robustness of this evidence by focusing on a country that has a certain

level of institutional variation (i.e. Switzerland). 5) We explore additional interesting factors

such as trust in institutions, voice and accountability and democratic participation rights.

Before considering these findings in detail, however, Section 3.2 aims to outline our

theoretical approach. Section 3.3 presents the data and Section 3.4 the empirical findings.

Section 3.5 finishes then with some concluding remarks.

3.2 Political Interest

3.2.1 Theoretical Considerations

Political interest influences the extent to which individuals go about collecting, processing,

and interpreting political matters. A government could operate with impunity if no-one is

motivated to analyze the information available regarding its activities (Rose-Ackerman 1999).

To a certain extent, political interest leads to better supervision and scrutiny of the

administration and governance performance and may contribute to a stronger sense of civic

awareness among citizens. This increased knowledge possibly augments the ability to acquire

political information at lower costs which in turn increases the individual incentive to be

informed and to discuss political issues. Hence this process acts as a sort of “multiplier

effect”. Rose-Ackerman (1997) states that corruption can be limited “by outside pressure

from the public” (p. 143). A politically interested population could demand a higher level of

transparency and may be able to better monitor and control politicians, potentially reducing

the perceived complexity of the political process

Politically interested citizens will associate with one another and engage in discussion.

Exchange of arguments and face-to-face interaction enhances group identification. and gives

citizens the opportunity to identify others’ preferences. As others’ preferences become visible,

the moral costs of free-riding or behaving illegally increase, reducing the justifiability of

corruption. If political discussion is common in a society, citizens are confronted with

Page 56: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

46  

arguments from both sides, those favouring and those opposing a certain political outcome,

and this increases the overall level of information. In addition, once citizens become involved

in an issue, they feel responsible for the result which may create a sense of civic duty and a

higher willingness to comply. Thus, discussion provides the opportunity to clarify benefits

and costs of political issues and thus increases co-operation among group members. This

increases the human capital involved in and developed by political matters. Mocan (2004)

stresses that a higher stock of human capital reduces the tolerance of corruption.

Several studies have found that political interest contributes to the probability of their

being involved in the political process (Verba, Schlozman, and Brady 1995). Political interest

becomes an important explanatory factor in models of political behaviors from political

sophistication (Carpini and Keeter 1996) to voting (Verba, Scholzman, and Brady 1995).

Looking at tax compliance, Alm, McClelland, and Schulze (1999) argue that there is a social

norm of compliance affecting individual reporting decisions. Their findings indicate that

communication combined with the vote influences tax compliance, so that paying taxes

becomes the accepted mode of behaviour. Discussion gives the chance to clarify benefits and

costs of a topic and thus increases co-operation among group members. In general, Alm

(1996) argues, after surveying experimental findings that “I believe that the cheap talk in

combination with vote allows individuals to change the social norms, in this case to

demonstrate that evasion will not be accepted”.

Kuenzi (2006) has empirically demonstrated that civic education (non-formal education)

has a significant positive impact on political participation. This kind of education is the result

of an informal process that is not necessarily a part of an individual’s formal education.

Nevertheless, individuals certainly invest energy, time and money on this informal education.

The expenses involved in being politically interested (represented by the costs of informal

education) may outweigh the benefits (represented by increased accountability and

transparency of the administration). In our case, we can argue that people balance the cost of

maintaining a political interest with the benefit derived from controlling and reducing

corruption, (keeping in mind the consequences of corruption). To demonstrate this aspect we

first employ a simple model that allows illustration of the relationship between political

interest and the level of corruption.

3.2.2 A Simple Model

Following the spirit of Ades and Di Tella (1997), we build a simple model to elaborate the

effect of political interest on corruption. We focus on the decision making of the risk-neutral

Page 57: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

47  

bureaucrats. We assume that the bureaucrats have ongoing wages w, and can take bribes b.

However, the probability that their corrupt acts are detected is p. This probability is mainly

determined by available information of a corrupt act. It is natural that the political interested

citizens can collect more and exploit information better than politically disinterested people.

Thus we have: ∂p∂I 0, ∂I

∂PI 0, where I denotes information and PI represents

political interest level of citizens. If a corrupt bureaucrat is detected, he will be ousted by

citizens with a loss f. Political interest may translate into stronger actions against corruption

by identifying illegal treatment and reducing the willingness to accept bribes even when the

costs of appealing are very high or the formal mechanisms of internal and external control are

not functioning effectively. Politically disinterested individuals may surrender more easily to

extortion, as they will not take into account the consequences and issues associated with

corruption. Thus, political interest may substantially reduce the costs of fighting extortive

corruption. Politically interested persons may find channels to reveal corrupt behavior or at

least raise the costs of illegal behavior by demonstrating their higher willingness to use

instruments for voicing complaints and threatening to undermine the political support for a

government. In addition, the politically interested citizens’ process of informal education will

uncover political information, helping them understand what is expected of a legitimate

government. Such understanding reduces the constraints on potential complaints and puts

pressure on the government and the bureaucrats to act in the public interest. This is especially

important in countries where other means of constraining bureaucrats and politicians may be

lacking. Rose-Ackerman (1999) points out that groups and individuals have effective avenues

for challenging official actions. Although policies that enhance accountability and openness

“are likely to be more acceptable to democratically elected leaders, these reforms can also

have an effect in undemocratic systems whose leaders nevertheless need public support to

retain power” (p. 144). However, it is possible that the government could stonewall any

process until the protest groups have exhausted their energy and resources (Rose-Ackerman

1999). Bureaucrats could ignore the threats of lobbyists and protestors in expectation of using

such a strategy.

Every bureaucrat compares his income from corruption with one from incorruption to

decide whether to be corrupt.

The corrupt income is y 1 p PI w b p PI w f 3 1

The incorrupt income is y w 3 2

He will be corrupt if y y . It means that the bureaucrat will corrupt if

Page 58: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

48  

b b p PI

1 p PIf 3 3

Assume that b is distributed according to the cumulative function F(.). Then the fraction

of bureaucrats that are corrupt is given by

P 1 F b b 1 F b p PI , f 3 4

The equation above shows that the level of corruption can be a function of the political

interest level of citizens and it is obvious that P is decreasing in PI. This model provides a

direct theoretical framework to examine the effect of political interest on corruption.

3.3 Data

The data used in the present study came from World Values Survey wave III. The World

Values Survey is a worldwide investigation of socio-cultural and political change. These

surveys have assessed the basic values and beliefs of people in many countries. The World

Values Survey was first carried out in 1981-1983, with subsequent surveys being carried out

in 1990-1993, 1995-1997 and 1999-200128. We work with the third wave, as the question

referring to individual perceived corruption has only been asked in this wave29.

For the researchers who conduct and administer the World Values Survey (WVS) in their

respective countries, it is a requirement that they follow the methodological requirements of

the World Values Association. For example, surveys in the World Values Survey set are

generally based on nationally representative samples of at least 1000 individuals of 18 years

and above (although sometimes people under the age of 18 participate). The samples are

selected using probability random methods, and the questions contained within the surveys

generally do not deviate far from the original official questionnaire (for a sample of a typical

World Values Survey see www.worldvaluessurvey.org).

3.3.1 Dependent Variables

Our dependent variables are perceived corruption, and the justifiability of corruption. To

assess the level of perceived corruption from the WVS, we use the following question:

How widespread do you think bribe taking and corruption is in this country?

Almost no public officials are engaged in it (1)

A few public officials are engaged in it (2)

                                                            28 Data from the 1999-2001 wave became available after our study was completed. 29 Countries in the sample: Armenia, Australia, Azerbaijan, Bangladesh, Belarus, Bosnia-Hercegovina, Brazil, Bulgaria, Chile, Croatia, Estonia, Finland, India, Latvia, Lithuania, Macedonia, Mexico, Moldova, Nigeria, Norway, Peru, Philippines, Russia, Serbia, Slovenia, Spain, Switzerland, Taiwan, Ukraine, Uruguay, USA, Venezuela, Germany (differentiating between East and West Germany).

Page 59: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

49  

Most public officials are engaged in it (3)

Almost all public officials are engaged in it (4)

The justifiability of corruption is measured with the following variable:

Please tell me for each of the following statements whether you think it can always be

justified, never be justified, or something in between: (...) someone accepting a bribe

in the course of their duties (1=always justified, 10= never justified).

The interpretation of this question is that a higher value leads to lower justifiability of

corruption. This variable can be seen as a proxy for social norms of compliance (see Torgler,

2007).

The two dependent variables used are not free from biases and problems. Use of

‘perceived corruption’ is in line with other indexes that employ measures of perceptions

(such as the Transparency International index). However, perceptions are not objective, nor

are they quantitative measures of the actual degree of corruption. Perceptions are rather an

indirect way of measuring corruption (Tanzi 2002). However, when analyzing the

Transparency International index, Treisman (2000, pp. 410-411) presents valid arguments as

to why data based on perceptions should be taken seriously. Components of the surveys and

ratings are highly correlated among themselves, even though they have been conducted with

different methodologies, different inputs and in different time periods. Such consistency

allows us to conclude that factors are almost free of biases such as a “temporal mood” or

guesses. There is also a consistency in the Transparency International over time, although the

construction of the index varies over time. Finally, the index is strongly correlated with other

corruption indexes such as the ICRG, the BI or the Gallup International.

A practical method by which we can test whether the World Values Survey question

about the perceived corruption is through the use of a useful proxy to check whether the

variable is correlated with other well-known indexes on corruption. Thus, we compare our

variable with the corruption indexes TI (Transparency International), International Country

Risk Guide (ICRG) and Quality of Government (Control of Corruption) developed by

Kaufmann, Kraay, and Mastruzzi (2003). The World Values Survey Corruption ratings are

highly correlated with the TI (r=-0.88), the ICRG (r=-0.68) and the Quality of Government

rating (r=-0.83)30.

The validity of the justifiability of corruption variable can be criticized as it reports a self-

reported and hypothetical choice (see Swamy et al. 2001). It can also be argued that an                                                             30 The sign is negative because for all three ratings used (TI, ICRG and Quality of Government), a higher score corresponds to a lower corruption.

Page 60: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

50  

individual who has engaged in corruption in the past will tend to cover up such behavior by

declaring a low justifiability of corruption in the survey. Furthermore, cross cultural

comparisons should be treated with some caution. In countries where corruption is

widespread and delays in transactions are long, additional payments to “speed up” the process

may be justifiable and a normal part of the administration process. The necessity of additional

payments is so pervasive in some countries that the bureaucratic mechanism does not operate

without them. De Soto (1989) and his research team conducted an experiment in which they

set up a small garment factory in Lima with the aim of complying with the bureaucratic

procedures and thus behaving in accordance with the law. He reports that 10 times they were

asked for a bribe to speed up the process and on two occasions, payment of the bribe was the

only way to continue the experiment. However, a side effect from higher justifiability of

corruption due to the ubiquitous nature of this behaviour is that the bureaucrats have a

stronger incentive to delay the transactions in order to extract further payments. Justifiability

is also correlated with most other corruption measurements: it is statistically significant at the

0.05 level but with lower r values compared to perceived corruption (TI (r=0.36), the ICRG

(r=0.19, not statistically significant), the Quality of Government rating (r=0.38), and

perceived corruption (r=-0.42)).

We have not analyzed the entire World Value Survey data set. Countries below 750

observations have not been included in the estimations to reduce possible biases due to a lack

of representativeness 31 . Furthermore, some countries do not have information on the

dependent variables or some of the independent variables. These countries are therefore not

considered. Furthermore, not all countries have information regarding the dependent and

independent variables integrated in the estimations32. For example, Sweden could not be

included as one of the control variables (education) has been coded differently.

3.3.2 Measuring Political Interest

We will use several proxies of political interest to investigate this main hypothesis, thereby

checking the robustness of the results. First of all we focus on the intensity of political

discussion by using the responses to the following survey question:

When you get together with your friends, would you say you discuss political

matters frequently (value 3), occasionally (value 2) or never (value 1)?

The second variable focuses on the interest in politics itself:

                                                            31 Thus, Montenegro and the Dominican Republic have been omitted. 32 For the estimations with the dependent variable perceived corruption: Japan, South Africa, Puerto Rico, China, Columbia. Estimation with justifiability of corruption: Japan, South Africa, Puerto Rico, Turkey and Columbia.

Page 61: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

51  

How interested would you say you are in politics? Very interested (value 3),

somewhat interested (2), not very interested (1).

The third variable measures the importance of politics in a person’s life with the following

question:

How important is politics in your life? very (4), rather( 3), not very (2), not at

all (1).

The advantages of using three different proxies are demonstrated by our ability to conduct

a robustness test while measuring different dimensions of political interest.

3.3.3 Further Independent Variables

The correlation between political interest and corruption could be influenced by other

variables that affect corruption, complicating our efforts to isolate the impact of political

interest. Thus, we control for the education level, the marital status, political trust,

institutional conditions, religion, risk attitudes, the economic situation and the employment

status.

a) Education

The variable education33 (continuous variable, 1=low, 9=high education) is related to

citizens’ knowledge about corruption. To observe the relative importance of political interest,

it necessary to control for formal education, as it is assumed that better educated individuals

are more aware of government’s activities and thus would be in a better position to assess the

degree of corruption. This may have a positive or a negative impact on the justifiability of

corruption and the perceived corruption, depending on the actions of the government. On the

other hand, they may be more strongly involved in corruption, understanding better the

opportunities of corruption. Thus, the effect of education is not clear and there is a lack of

empirical studies that investigate the correlation between education and corruption. Swamy et

al. (2001), for example, disregard the variable. Mocan (2004) found that a higher level of

                                                            33 What is the highest educational level that you have attained?

1. No formal education 2. Incomplete primary school 3. Completed primary school 4. Incomplete secondary school: technical/vocational type 5. Complete secondary school: technical/vocational type 6. Incomplete secondary: university-preparatory type 7. Complete secondary: university-preparatory type 8. Some university-level education, without degree 9. University-level education, with degree

 

Page 62: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

52  

education leads to a higher probability of being targeted for bribes, yet a more educated

population is expected to be less tolerant of corruption.

b) Age

A limited number of studies have included age in their estimations. Swamy et al. (2001)

consider age as a control variable in their estimations of the justifiability of corruption and

find a positive but non-linear effect. The authors focused on gender differences and did not

comment on this result. Mocan (2004) also uses micro data to show an effect of age on

corruption: individuals at the age of 20 to 54 are more likely to be asked for a bribe compared

to the reference group (younger than 20). Torgler and Valev (2006) explore the impact of age

on corruption, differentiating between the same cohorts over time (age effect) as well as the

same age groups in different time periods (cohort effect). The chapter observes a consistent

age effect, while a cohort effect is less obvious. There are two major concepts that explain

the correlation between age and crime: the traditional desistance theory and the age theory.

The desistance theory asserts that the decline in crime results from factors associated with age

that reduce or change the actors’ criminality, and older people are restrained from offending

due to changes in their status or the exposure to anti-criminal institutions. On the other hand,

the age theory is based on the idea that the biological aging of the organism itself has an

impact on individuals’ criminal behaviour (for an overview see Torgler and Valev 2006).

Instead of using age as a continuous variable, we have formed four classes: Age <30, Age 30-

49, Age 50-64, Age 65+, with Age <30 as reference group, to better investigate the impact of

age.

c) Gender

Research in social psychology suggests that women are more compliant and less self-

reliant than men (e.g., Tittle 1980). In the past decade, experimental research findings have

shown that gender may influence aspects of behavior such as charitable giving, bargaining,

and household decision making (see Andreoni and Vesterlund 2001, Eckel and Grossman

2001). Evidence from the tax compliance literature shows there is a tendency for men to be

less compliant and have lower tax morale than women (see Torgler 2007). Further evidence

regarding gender differences can also be found in helping behavior (see, e.g., Eagly and

Crowley 1986) or ethical decision making (Ford et al. 1994, Glover et al. 1997 and Reiss and

Mitra 1998).

The criminology literature provides one of the best sources for observing possible gender

differences. Mears et al. (2000) report that men commit more offenses than women age “at

every age, within all racial or ethnic groups examined to date, and for all but a handful of

Page 63: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

53  

offense types that are peculiarly female… sex differences in delinquency are independently

corroborated by self-report, victimization, and police data, and they appear to hold cross-

culturally as well as historically” (p. 143). Torgler and Valev (2007) find strong evidence that

women report a lower justifiability of committing illegal activities than men. The results

remain robust after investigating different time periods and extending the specification with

several opportunity factors such as education, employment status or income.

d) Marital status

Marital status is a further control variable (dummy variable, value 1 if the respondent is

married). Married people may be more compliant than others, especially compared to singles

because they are more constrained by their social network (Tittle 1980). It is also argued that

marriage alters public behaviour (Swamy et al. 2001). Tittle (1980) found significant

differences between the different marital statuses, with the greatest evidence for the singles,

followed by the separated or divorced. However, controlling for age, the results show that the

association between deviance and marital status was a reflection of age difference, as older

persons are more likely to be married or widowed and age was a strong predictor concerning

the deviance. Gottfredson and Hirschi (1990) also point out that the literature on crime finds

that marital status does not seem to have an impact on the likelihood of crime.

e) Economic situation

As a proxy for income we use the economic situation of an individual (dummies upper

class, middle and lower class are in the reference group). Using the exact income would

produce biases, because of difficulties comparing this variable across different countries.

Individuals with a higher income are more likely to be asked for a bribe, as are those with a

better education. Individuals with a lower income might have lower social “stakes” or

restrictions but are less in a position to take risks, because of a high marginal utility loss

(wealth reduction) if they are caught and penalized.

f) Occupation status

Another variable is the occupation status as it affects whether the respondent is in a

position to benefit from corruption (see Swamy et al. 2001). We will use a dummy variable

for self-employed individuals as they might be in the best position to invest in bribing and

benefit from corruption. Such a status may have an impact on the norms regarding bribery.

Page 64: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

54  

g) Risk attitudes

We include a dummy variable that measures risk aversion34 as individual willingness to

behave illegally could also be a function of risk attitudes. It is interesting that few prior

survey studies have controlled for risk attitudes, since risk aversion reduces the incentive to

act illegally. Furthermore, controlling for risk attitudes affords better insights regarding the

variables of age, gender, or economic situation. It could be argued that the observed

difference between women and men or between different age groups is influenced by

different risk attitudes functions.

h) Urbanization

Mocan (2004) stresses that in larger cities the extent of bribery may be higher since the

scale of economic activities is larger and more varied in scope, resulting in increased contact

with the government. Moreover, government officials may be less personal compared to

those in smaller cities: this may reduce the opportunity costs of bribing. We use town size as

a proxy for urbanization.35

i) Religion

Religion might influence people’s habits and act as a restriction on engaging in illegal

activities (Torgler 2006). We take the frequency of church attendance (Church Attendance36)

as the religious variable, showing approximately how much time individuals devote to

                                                            34 Now I would like to ask you something about the things which would seem to you personally, most important if you were looking a job. Here are some of the things many people take into account in relation to their work. Regardless of whether you’re actually looking for a job, which one would you, personally, place first if you were looking for a job?

1. A good income so that you do not have any worries about money 2. A safe job with no risk of closing down or unemployment 3. Working with people you like 4. Doing an important job which gives you a feeling of accomplishment

And what would be your second choice? A dummy variable was built with the value 1, if someone has chosen 2 as first or as second choice. 35 V232. Size of town: 1. Under 2,000 2. 2,000 - 5,000 3. 5 - 10,000 4. 10 - 20,000 5. 20 - 50,000 6. 50 - 100,000 7. 100 - 500,000 8. 500,000 and more. 36 Apart from weddings, funerals, and christenings, about how often do you attend religious services these days? More than once a week, once a week, once a month, only on special holy days, once a year, less often, never or practically never. (7 = more than once a week to 1 = never or practically never).

Page 65: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

55  

religion. It is anticipated that this variable tells more about behaviour than self-reported

religious attitudes.

j) Political trust

Economists have recently started to pay attention to the determinants of trust through the

literature on compliance (e.g. Torgler 2007). Trust in the state might influence citizens’

positive attitudes and commitment to the rules of a society, which ultimately has a negative

effect on illegal activities. Those institutions perceived by citizens as trustworthy, fair and

efficient could act as constraints on corruption. We are exploring several different dimensions

of trust, namely trust in the legal system 37 , trust in the government 38 , and trust in the

parliament39. The analysis will therefore cover trust at the constitutional and current politico-

economic level. Controlling for this variable will better check the impact of political interest

since individuals with a lower level of political trust might be frustrated and therefore less

interested in following politics.

k) Voice, Accountability and Democratic Rights

We also control for institutional conditions. In particular, it is important to control for the

citizens’ opportunity to translate their political interest into political actions; i.e. whether they

have a meaningful ‘voice’ in influencing the state (e.g., through voting processes). Holding

such institutional conditions constant allows analysis of how strong political interest can affect

corruption. In general, the greater the ‘voice’ of citizens, the less we expect to observe

corruption, all other things being equal. A progressive government can attempt to increase or

initiate co-operation and generate trust by developing functioning institutions. Furthermore,

co-operation is enhanced when citizens are satisfied with the way they are treated. On the

other hand, if certain sectors of the government are not benevolent, strong institutional

instruments have the potential to control politicians’ discretionary power. Voter power helps

limit the abuse of political power by selfish politicians especially since citizens cannot

completely foresee the incumbents’ preferences. The elements of direct democracy can also

empower citizens with an instrument for controlling the government. Such control has an ex

ante effect on policy formulation by elected incumbents in that they must always take into

                                                            37 Could you tell me how much confidence you have in the legal system: is it a great deal of confidence, quite a lot of confidence, not very much confidence or none at all? (4= a great deal to 1=none at all). 38 Could you tell me how much confidence you have in the government in your capital: is it a great deal of confidence, quite a lot of confidence, not very much confidence or none at all? (4= a great deal to 1=none at all). 39 Could you tell me how much confidence you have in parliament: Do you have a great deal of confidence, quite a lot of confidence, not very much confidence or no confidence at all? (4=a great deal of confidence to 1=no confidence at all).

Page 66: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

56  

account possible voter intervention. Levi (1988) points out that a possible consequence of

creating or maintaining compliance is to provide reassurance by the government. A

government that precommits itself with democratic rules imposes self-restraints on its own

power and thus sends a signal that taxpayers are seen as responsible persons. Furthermore,

direct democratic rules signal that citizens are not ignorant or uncomprehending voters, which

might create or maintain a certain social capital stock that should also affect the justifiability of

corruption.

In the cross-country study we use Kaufmann et al. (2003) variable Voice And

Accountability for the year 1996. The variable measures the political process, civil liberties,

and political rights of a country. We are going to use an index of the degree of direct

democracy developed by Stutzer (1999) and applied in papers such as Frey and Stutzer (2000,

2002), Frey and Feld (2002), Torgler (2005), Schaltegger and Torgler (2007) when exploring

Switzerland. The index reflects the extent of direct democratic participation (1= lowest and 6=

highest degree of participation) at the cantonal level.

l) Regions

We will also control for regional differences considering the dummies CEE and FSU

(Central Eastern and Former Soviet Union countries), Latin America, Asia and Africa40. The

reference group consists of Western Europe + USA + Australia. It can be assumed that there

are regional differences in the perceived corruption and justifiability of corruption. We expect

a lower perceived corruption in the reference group countries, based on a historically high

standard of rule of law and accountable systems of governance. Furthermore, it is possible

that a higher justifiability of corruption exists in countries where these important factors are

lacking.

3.4 Empirical Evidence

We will use a weighted ordered probit estimation to correct the samples and thus to get a

reflection of the national distribution. In estimations where several countries are pooled we

have integrated an additional weighting variable. To obtain an equal number of weighted

observations (around 1500) for each survey, the original weight variable was multiplied by a

constant for each country41. The ordered probit models are relevant in such an analysis

insofar as they help to analyse the ranking information of the scaled dependent variable.

However, since equations in the ordered probit estimation have a nonlinear form, only the                                                             40 Only one country represents Africa (Nigeria). 41 The World Values Survey provides the weighting variables.

Page 67: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

57  

sign of the coefficient can be directly interpreted and not its size. Calculating the marginal

effects is therefore a method to find the quantitative effect of a variable on our dependent

variable. The marginal effect indicates the change in the share of individuals (or the

probability of) belonging to a specific perceived corruption (justifiability) level, when the

independent variable increases by one unit. In all estimations the marginal effects are

presented only for the highest value. Furthermore, it should be noticed that answers such as

“don’t know” and missing values have been eliminated in all estimations.

3.4.1 International Evidence

Tables 3-1 to 3-6 present the first results. Tables 3- 1, 3-3 and 3-5 explore the justifiability of

corruption as dependent variable, while Tables 3-2, 3-4, and 3-6 analyse the perceived

corruption. Tables 3-1 and 3-2 investigate the impact of political discussion. Tables 3-3 and

3-4 take a look at the interest in politics and Tables 3-5 and 3-6 report the findings focusing

on the importance of politics. In all tables we present four specifications. This provides a

robustness check of our main variable while taking into account that the number of

observations decreases from one estimation to the other. The baseline specification is

presented in the first regression. In a next step we add variables that measure individuals’

economic situation. In a third regression we include also the three variables on political trust.

Finally, we report a fourth regression that controls for institutional conditions within a

country, focusing on voice and accountability. The results clearly indicate that political

interest matters: in 19 out of 20 regressions the coefficient is statistically significant. We

observe that a higher level of political interest leads to a lower justifiability of corruption and

also to a lower perceived level of corruption. The marginal effects vary between 0.4

percentage points to 3.7 percentage points. Focusing on the justifiability of corruption, we

were not able to observe a decrease in the impact of political interest when controlling for

political trust and voice and accountability. On the contrary, we observe an increase in the

marginal effects. For example, in Table 3-1 we observe that an increase in the political

discussion level by one unit increases the probability of stating that corruption is never

justifiable by 1.3 percentage points. Looking at perceived corruption, we observe a decrease

in the marginal effects. However, the results still indicate that the effects are not at all

negligible. For example, specification (8) in Table 3-2 indicates that an increase in the

political discussion scale by one unit reduces the probability of reporting the highest level of

corruption by 1.6 percentage points.

Page 68: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

58  

While we observe that political interest matters, we cannot observe a statistically

significant correlation between education and our two dependent variables (showing a

negative sign in both cases). Thus, informal education seems to be much more important than

education. This finding suggests that it is important to generate “political human capital”

rather than just generalized human capital.

Interestingly, we observe that voice and accountability reduces the justifiability of

corruption and the perceived level of corruption. The coefficient is highly statistically

significant in all specifications while also reporting large marginal effects. Thus, the findings

indicate that a more legitimate and responsive state is an essential factor for a lower level of

corruption. Similarly, political trust has a negative impact on the justifiability of corruption

and the perceived level of corruption. The joint role played by political trust can be

investigated using a Wald-test for coefficient restrictions to test for joint significance. In all

cases we can observe that the null hypothesis is rejected, meaning that the political trust

variables play a significant role in the determination of countries’ corruption level. Trust in

the legal system provides the most consistent result in all the tables. Thus, trust at the

constitutional level seems to be more important than trust at the current politico-economic

level. The marginal effects are quite substantial, particularly for the perceived corruption

regressions.

Looking at the other variables we observe that all age groups from 30 to 65+ have a

significantly lower justifiability of corruption than the reference group below 30.

Interestingly, we can observe that the marginal effects increase consistently with an increase

of the age group.

Page 69: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

59  

Table 3-1 Justifiability of corruption and political discussion Weighted Ordered Probit Coeff z-Stat. Marg. Coeff. z-Stat. Marg. Coeff. z-Stat. Marg. Coeff. z-Stat. Marg.

(1) (2) (3) (4)

Politicial Discussion 0.026** 2.29 0.008 0.031*** 2.62 0.010 0.035*** 2.91 0.011 0.052*** 3.28 0.017 Formal Education 0.001 0.20 0.0002 0.002 0.64 0.001 0.006* 1.68 0.002 0.005 0.93 0.001 Age 30-49 0.19*** 10.06 0.059 0.19*** 9.86 0.059 0.19*** 9.70 0.060 0.17*** 6.67 0.054 Age 50-64 0.38*** 15.96 0.11 0.39*** 15.82 0.11 0.39*** 15.27 0.11 0.36*** 10.76 0.11 Age 65+ 0.50*** 15.44 0.14 0.52*** 15.50 0.14 0.53*** 14.97 0.14 0.52*** 11.30 0.14 Female 0.14*** 9.67 0.044 0.14*** 9.57 0.045 0.14*** 9.36 0.045 0.16*** 7.79 0.050 Married 0.12*** 6.46 0.039 0.12*** 6.16 0.038 0.12*** 6.16 0.040 0.12*** 4.49 0.038 Widowed 0.15*** 4.32 0.047 0.15*** 3.96 0.044 0.14*** 3.59 0.042 0.10** 2.09 0.031 Divorced 0.016 0.42 0.005 0.006 0.16 0.002 0.008 0.21 0.003 0.013 0.27 0.004 Separated 0.068 1.29 0.021 0.076 1.43 0.024 0.095* 1.72 0.029 0.082 1.15 0.025 Upper Class -0.19*** -3.57 -0.065 -0.18*** -3.20 -0.061 -0.14** -2.00 -0.048 Upper Middle Class -0.019 -0.97 -0.006 -0.032 -1.58 -0.010 -0.026 -0.93 -0.008 Selfemployed -0.062** -2.37 -0.020 -0.068** -2.52 -0.022 -0.057** -2.06 -0.019 -0.096*** -2.76 -0.031 Risk Averse 0.077*** 4.99 0.024 0.073*** 4.57 0.023 0.073*** 4.46 0.023 0.077*** 3.47 0.024 Urbanization -0.007** -2.53 -0.002 -0.006** -2.24 -0.002 -0.005 -1.55 -0.001 -0.009** -2.34 -0.003 Church Attendance 0.012*** 3.09 0.004 0.009** 2.21 0.003 0.006 1.49 0.002 -0.001 -0.13 0.000 Legal System 0.040*** 4.07 0.013 0.071*** 5.46 0.023 Government -0.007 -0.58 -0.002 0.041*** 2.78 0.013 Parliament 0.022* 1.87 0.007 0.015 1.01 0.005 Voice And Accountability. 0.11*** 7.43 0.036 CEE And FSU -0.38*** -20.50 -0.12 -0.38*** -19.87 -0.12 -0.38*** -18.88 -0.12 Latin America -0.43*** -17.92 -0.15 -0.43*** -17.50 -0.15 -0.42*** -16.56 -0.14 -0.26*** -5.82 -0.084 Asia 0.20*** 6.31 0.061 0.35*** 9.64 0.098 0.36*** 9.28 0.10 -0.030 -0.68 -0.009 Africa -0.23*** -3.91 -0.078 -0.19*** -3.17 -0.065 -0.23*** -3.60 -0.077 0.61*** 11.26 0.16 Wald-test joint sign. polit. trust 30.66 Pseudo R2 0.025 0.027 0.027 0.034 Number of observations 41714 39669 36726 20373 Prob > chi2 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00

Notes: In the reference group are Age<30, Man, Single, Lower Middle And Lower Class, Other Employment Status, Risk Taker, Western Europe + USA + Australia. ***, ** and * denote significance at 1%, 5% and 10%, respectively. Marginal effect = highest score (10, never justifiable). The higher the value the lower the justifiability. CEE: Central Eastern European Countries, FSU: Former Soviet Union Countries.

Page 70: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

60  

Table 3-2 Perceived corruption and political discussion Weighted Ordered Probit Coeff z-Stat. Marg. Coeff. z-Stat. Marg. Coeff. z-Stat. Marg. Coeff. z-Stat. Marg.

(5) (6) (7) (8)

Political Discussion -0.030*** -2.94 -0.009 -0.030*** -2.89 -0.009 -0.024** -2.27 -0.007 -0.028* -1.95 -0.008 Formal Education -0.009*** -3.19 -0.003 0.000 0.06 0.0001 -0.003 -0.91 -0.001 -0.011** -2.56 -0.003 Age 30-49 -0.039** -2.29 -0.012 -0.049*** -2.82 -0.015 -0.064*** -3.55 -0.019 -0.024 -1.03 -0.007 Age 50-64 -0.092*** -4.35 -0.028 -0.095*** -4.40 -0.029 -0.088*** -3.90 -0.026 -0.025 -0.84 -0.007 Age 65+ -0.16*** -5.94 -0.048 -0.16*** -5.76 -0.047 -0.13*** -4.37 -0.037 -0.083** -2.07 -0.023 Female 0.020 1.54 0.006 0.027** 2.03 0.008 0.015 1.10 0.005 0.001 0.05 0.000 Married 0.011 0.65 0.004 0.011 0.60 0.003 0.026 1.39 0.008 -0.024 -0.93 -0.007 Widowed -0.028 -0.92 -0.009 -0.041 -1.33 -0.013 -0.012 -0.36 -0.004 -0.10** -2.43 -0.028 Divorced 0.069** 2.09 0.022 0.061* 1.78 0.019 0.058 1.64 0.018 0.096** 2.03 0.028 Separated 0.054 1.17 0.017 0.047 1.00 0.015 0.052 1.05 0.016 0.029 0.45 0.008 Upper Class -0.009 -0.17 -0.003 0.046 0.86 0.014 -0.12* -1.93 -0.034 Upper Middle Class -0.24*** -13.63 -0.070 -0.19*** -10.58 -0.055 -0.17*** -6.50 -0.045 Selfemployed 0.037 1.51 0.012 0.052** 2.09 0.016 0.019 0.73 0.006 0.044 1.41 0.013 Risk Averse 0.024* 1.75 0.007 0.011 0.80 0.003 0.006 0.40 0.002 0.011 0.55 0.003 Urbanization 0.034*** 13.54 0.011 0.035*** 13.53 0.011 0.024*** 9.06 0.007 0.005 1.31 0.001 Church Attendance 0.003 0.88 0.001 0.005 1.29 0.001 0.019*** 5.21 0.006 0.012** 2.27 0.003 Legal System -0.15*** -16.84 -0.046 -0.16*** -13.20 -0.046 Government -0.12*** -12.23 -0.038 -0.13*** -9.71 -0.037 Parliament -0.17*** -16.20 -0.053 -0.16*** -11.77 -0.047 Voice And Accountability -0.16*** -11.240 -0.045 CEE And FSU 0.94*** 58.66 0.29 0.89*** 53.98 0.28 0.92*** 53.36 0.28 0.98*** 24.51 0.29 Latin America 0.68*** 30.80 0.24 0.64*** 28.18 0.22 0.63*** 27.17 0.21 0.59*** 14.88 0.18 Asia 0.54*** 20.52 0.19 0.52*** 19.37 0.19 0.76*** 25.67 0.27 0.89*** 20.39 0.31 Africa 1.28*** 21.64 0.48 1.25*** 20.26 0.47 1.32*** 19.67 0.49 Wald-test joint sign. polit. trust 1867.92 Pseudo R2 0.025 0.027 0.027 0.11 Number of observations 41714 39669 36726 18942 Prob > chi2 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00

Notes: In the reference group are Age<30, Man, Single, Lower Middle And Lower Class, Other Employment Status, Risk Taker, Western Europe + USA + Australia. ***, ** and * denote significance at 1%, 5% and 10%, respectively. Marginal effect = highest score (4). The higher the value the lower the justifiability. CEE: Central Eastern European Countries, FSU: Former Soviet Union Countries.

Page 71: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

61  

Table 3-3 Justifiability of corruption and interest in politics Weighted Ordered Probit Coeff z-Stat. Marg. Coeff. z-Stat. Marg. Coeff. z-Stat. Marg. Coeff. z-Stat. Marg.

(9) (10) (11) (12)

Interest Politics 0.013 1.57 0.004 0.018** 2.22 0.006 0.016* 1.87 0.005 0.041*** 3.58 0.013 Formal Education 0.001 0.24 0.0003 0.002 0.66 0.001 0.007* 1.82 0.002 0.004 0.73 0.001 Age 30-49 0.19*** 10.30 0.060 0.19*** 10.05 0.060 0.19*** 9.91 0.061 0.18*** 6.96 0.056 Age 50-64 0.39*** 16.32 0.11 0.40*** 16.19 0.12 0.40*** 15.64 0.12 0.37*** 11.13 0.11 Age 65+ 0.50*** 15.54 0.14 0.53*** 15.66 0.14 0.53*** 15.10 0.14 0.53*** 11.40 0.14 Female 0.14*** 9.50 0.043 0.14*** 9.47 0.044 0.14*** 9.06 0.044 0.15*** 7.56 0.048 Married 0.12*** 6.50 0.039 0.12*** 6.16 0.038 0.12*** 6.24 0.040 0.12*** 4.52 0.038 Widowed 0.15*** 4.11 0.044 0.14*** 3.70 0.041 0.13*** 3.45 0.040 0.088* 1.81 0.027 Divorced 0.016 0.44 0.005 0.006 0.17 0.002 0.012 0.32 0.004 0.015 0.29 0.005 Separated 0.068 1.28 0.021 0.075 1.40 0.023 0.097* 1.76 0.030 0.083 1.15 0.025 Upper Class -0.20*** -3.82 -0.069 -0.19*** -3.46 -0.065 -0.16** -2.22 -0.052 Upper Middle Class -0.021 -1.04 -0.007 -0.033 -1.62 -0.011 -0.033 -1.15 -0.010 Selfemployed -0.065** -2.48 -0.021 -0.070*** -2.62 -0.023 -0.063** -2.27 -0.020 -0.098*** -2.82 -0.032 Risk Averse 0.077*** 4.97 0.024 0.072*** 4.53 0.023 0.074*** 4.48 0.023 0.078*** 3.52 0.024 Urbanization -0.006** -2.29 -0.002 -0.006** -2.05 -0.002 -0.004 -1.48 -0.001 -0.008* -1.94 -0.002 Church Attendance 0.010*** 2.67 0.003 0.007* 1.72 0.002 0.005 1.19 0.002 -0.001 -0.22 0.000 Legal System 0.039*** 3.94 0.012 0.069*** 5.34 0.022 Government -0.009 -0.78 -0.003 0.036** 2.46 0.011 Parliament 0.021* 1.76 0.007 0.014 0.92 0.004 Voice And Accountability -0.38*** -18.84 -0.12 0.12*** 7.71 0.037 CEE And FSU -0.38*** -20.45 -0.12 -0.38*** -19.78 -0.12 -0.42*** -16.47 -0.14 -0.25*** -5.58 -0.080 Latin America -0.43*** -17.86 -0.15 -0.43*** -17.29 -0.15 0.37*** 9.55 0.10 -0.020 -0.47 -0.006 Asia 0.21*** 6.57 0.063 0.36*** 9.96 0.10 -0.21*** -3.40 -0.072 0.62*** 11.51 0.16 Africa -0.23*** -3.90 -0.077 -0.18*** -3.08 -0.062 Wald-test joint sign. polit. trust 26.80*** Pseudo R2 0.025 0.027 0.027 0.034 Number of observations 42056 40002 37018 20576 Prob > chi2 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00

Notes: In the reference group are AGE<30, Man, Single, Lower Middle And Lower Class, Other Employment Status, Risk Taker, Western Europe + USA + Australia. ***, ** and * denote significance at 1%, 5% and 10%, respectively. Marginal effect = highest score (10, never justifiable). The higher the value the lower the justifiability. CEE: Central Eastern European Countries, FSU: Former Soviet Union Countries.

Page 72: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

62  

Table 3-4 Perceived corruption and political interest Weighted Ordered Probit Coeff z-Stat. Marg. Coeff. z-Stat. Marg. Coeff. z-Stat. Marg. Coeff. z-Stat. Marg.

(13) (14) (15) (16)

Interest In Politics -0.090*** -12.31 -0.028 -0.087*** -11.80 -0.027 -0.053*** -6.80 -0.016 -0.055*** -5.28 -0.016 Formal Education -0.003 -0.89 -0.001 0.006** 2.13 0.002 0.0003 0.09 0.0001 -0.009** -2.06 -0.003 Age 30-49 -0.027 -1.58 -0.008 -0.037** -2.17 -0.012 -0.058*** -3.22 -0.018 -0.021 -0.90 -0.006 Age 50-64 -0.068*** -3.27 -0.021 -0.073*** -3.43 -0.023 -0.076*** -3.38 -0.023 -0.018 -0.60 -0.005 Age 65+ -0.14*** -5.09 -0.041 -0.14*** -4.97 -0.041 -0.12*** -4.03 -0.034 -0.076* -1.90 -0.021 Female 0.002 0.13 0.001 0.009 0.67 0.003 0.006 0.43 0.002 -0.007 -0.36 -0.002 Married 0.012 0.69 0.004 0.012 0.65 0.004 0.026 1.40 0.008 -0.023 -0.91 -0.007 Widowed -0.022 -0.73 -0.007 -0.036 -1.17 -0.011 -0.008 -0.25 -0.002 -0.096** -2.31 -0.027 Divorced 0.076** 2.31 0.024 0.069** 2.02 0.022 0.068* 1.94 0.021 0.11** 2.21 0.031 Separated 0.075 1.63 0.024 0.070 1.49 0.022 0.075 1.55 0.023 0.050 0.79 0.015 Upper Class -0.018 -0.36 -0.006 0.033 0.63 0.010 -0.14** -2.21 -0.038 Upper Middle Class -0.23*** -13.16 -0.067 -0.19*** -10.40 -0.054 -0.16*** -6.40 -0.044 Selfemployed 0.037 1.51 0.012 0.050** 2.05 0.016 0.016 0.61 0.005 0.039 1.27 0.011 Risk Averse 0.017 1.25 0.005 0.005 0.36 0.002 0.001 0.07 0.000 0.007 0.35 0.002 Urbanization 0.034*** 13.61 0.011 0.035*** 13.56 0.011 0.025*** 9.16 0.007 0.005 1.45 0.001 Church Attendance 0.003 0.85 0.001 0.004 1.27 0.001 0.019*** 5.08 0.006 0.010** 1.99 0.003 Legal System -0.15*** -17.05 -0.047 -0.16*** -13.15 -0.046 Government -0.12*** -12.17 -0.037 -0.13*** -9.81 -0.037 Parliament -0.17*** -15.59 -0.050 -0.15*** -11.07 -0.044 Voice And Accountability. -0.16*** -11.480 -0.047 CEE And FSU 0.92*** 57.45 0.29 0.88*** 53.05 0.28 0.91*** 52.68 0.28 0.97*** 24.21 0.29 Latin America 0.64*** 28.98 0.223 0.60*** 26.60 0.21 0.62*** 26.29 0.21 0.57*** 14.46 0.18 Asia 0.55*** 21.00 0.20 0.53*** 19.84 0.19 0.77*** 26.22 0.28 0.90*** 20.71 0.32 Africa 1.27*** 21.93 0.47 1.25*** 20.53 0.47 1.32*** 19.86 0.49 Wald-test joint sign. polit. trust 1801.40 Pseudo R2 0.058 0.059 0.090 0.11 Number of observations 38646 37245 34752 19136 Prob > chi2 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00

Notes: In the reference group are Age<30, Man, Single, Lower Middle And Lower Class, Other Employment Status, Risk Taker, Western Europe + USA + Australia. ***, ** and * denote significance at 1%, 5% and 10%, respectively. Marginal effect = highest score (4). The higher the value the lower the justifiability. CEE: Central Eastern European Countries, FSU: Former Soviet Union Countries.

Page 73: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

63  

Table 3-5 Justifiability of corruption and important of politics in life

Weighted Ordered Probit Coeff z-Stat. Marg. Coeff. z-Stat. Marg. Coeff. z-Stat. Marg. Coeff. z-Stat. Marg.

(17) (18) (19) (20)

Importance Of Politics 0.023*** 2.95 0.007 0.027*** 3.33 0.008 0.026*** 3.10 0.008 0.055*** 4.90 0.017 Formal Education 0.001 0.22 0.0002 0.002 0.71 0.001 0.006* 1.79 0.002 0.004 0.84 0.001 Age 30-49 0.18*** 9.98 0.058 0.19*** 9.83 0.058 0.192*** 9.82 0.060 0.17*** 6.67 0.054 Age 50-64 0.38*** 16.00 0.11 0.39*** 15.99 0.11 0.396*** 15.55 0.115 0.36*** 10.77 0.11 Age 65+ 0.51*** 15.53 0.14 0.53*** 15.59 0.14 0.531*** 15.08 0.143 0.53*** 11.32 0.14 Female 0.14*** 9.45 0.043 0.14*** 9.31 0.043 0.136*** 8.97 0.043 0.15*** 7.49 0.047 Married 0.13*** 6.74 0.041 0.12*** 6.30 0.039 0.126*** 6.31 0.040 0.12*** 4.65 0.039 Widowed 0.15*** 4.26 0.046 0.14*** 3.75 0.042 0.134*** 3.47 0.041 0.097*** 1.99 0.030 Divorced 0.017 0.46 0.005 0.006 0.15 0.002 0.009 0.22 0.003 0.012 0.25 0.004 Separated 0.068 1.29 0.021 0.075 1.40 0.023 0.084 1.54 0.026 0.064 0.90 0.020 Upper Class -0.20*** -3.70 -0.067 -0.186*** -3.32 -0.063 -0.15** -2.04 -0.048 Upper Middle Class -0.019*** -0.93 -0.006 -0.031 -1.51 -0.010 -0.028 -0.97 -0.009 Selfemployed -0.060*** -2.28 -0.019 -0.064** -2.38 -0.021 -0.055** -2.00 -0.018 -0.089** -2.55 -0.029 Risk Averse 0.075*** 4.81 0.023 0.071*** 4.47 0.022 0.073*** 4.42 0.023 0.077*** 3.48 0.024 Urbanization -0.006** -2.30 -0.002 -0.006** -2.05 -0.002 -0.004 -1.47 -0.001 -0.007* -1.84 -0.002 Church Attendance 0.011*** 2.80 0.003 0.008** 1.97 0.002 0.006 1.38 0.002 -0.001 -0.12 0.000 Legal System 0.040*** 4.09 0.013 0.070*** 5.32 0.022 Government -0.009 -0.80 -0.003 0.035** 2.36 0.011 Parliament 0.018 1.51 0.006 0.008 0.54 0.003 Voice And Accountability. -0.38*** -19.72 -0.12 -0.373*** -18.65 -0.119 0.13*** 8.56 0.042 CEE And FSU -0.38*** -20.48 -0.12 -0.44*** -17.73 -0.15 -0.425*** -16.85 -0.146 -0.23*** -4.98 -0.072 Latin America -0.44*** -18.23 -0.15 0.35*** 9.83 0.10 0.367*** 9.50 0.103 -0.027 -0.62 -0.009 Asia 0.21*** 6.56 0.063 -0.22*** -3.60 -0.073 -0.245*** -3.91 -0.084 0.63*** 11.67 0.16 Africa -0.25*** -4.28 -0.085 Wald-test joint sign. polit. trust 26.16*** Pseudo R2 0.025 0.027 0.027 0.034 Number of observations 41631 39614 36720 20410 Prob > chi2 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00

Notes: In the reference group are Age<30, Man, Single, Lower Middle And Lower Class, Other Employment Status, Risk Taker, Western Europe + USA + Australia. ***, ** and * denote significance at 1%, 5% and 10%, respectively. Marginal effect = highest score (10, never justifiable). The higher the value the lower the justifiability. CEE: Central Eastern European Countries, FSU: Former Soviet Union Countries.

Page 74: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

64  

Table 3-6 Perceived corruption and importance of politics in life Weighted Ordered Probit Coeff z-Stat. Marg. Coeff. z-Stat. Marg. Coeff. z-Stat. Marg. Coeff. z-Stat. Marg.

(21) (22) (23) (24)

Importance Of Politics -0.047*** -6.59 -0.015 -0.045*** -6.23 -0.014 -0.001 -0.15 -0.0003 -0.031*** -3.01 -0.009 Formal Education -0.007** -2.52 -0.002 0.002 0.70 0.001 -0.004 -1.27 -0.001 -0.011** -2.54 -0.003 Age 30-49 -0.036** -2.16 -0.011 -0.048*** -2.77 -0.015 -0.067*** -3.71 -0.020 -0.023 -0.99 -0.007 Age 50-64 -0.085*** -4.04 -0.026 -0.090*** -4.19 -0.028 -0.091*** -4.08 -0.027 -0.021 -0.71 -0.006 Age 65+ -0.15*** -5.62 -0.045 -0.15*** -5.52 -0.046 -0.13*** -4.52 -0.038 -0.078* -1.94 -0.022 Female 0.018 1.38 0.006 0.024* 1.84 0.008 0.020 1.45 0.006 0.002 0.08 0.000 Married 0.011 0.62 0.003 0.011 0.61 0.003 0.026 1.36 0.008 -0.026 -1.02 -0.007 Widowed -0.033 -1.11 -0.010 -0.045 -1.45 -0.014 -0.016 -0.48 -0.005 -0.11*** -2.64 -0.030 Divorced 0.076** 2.30 0.024 0.068** 2.02 0.022 0.067* 1.89 0.021 0.101** 2.12 0.030 Separated 0.060 1.29 0.019 0.054 1.13 0.017 0.061 1.24 0.019 0.031 0.49 0.009 Upper Class -0.026 -0.51 -0.008 0.022 0.43 0.007 -0.16** -2.52 -0.042 Upper Middle Class -0.24*** -13.75 -0.070 -0.20*** -10.88 -0.056 -0.17*** -6.72 -0.046 Selfemployed 0.032 1.31 0.010 0.047* 1.91 0.015 0.015 0.58 0.005 0.036 1.17 0.011 Risk Averse 0.018 1.31 0.006 0.005 0.37 0.002 0.003 0.22 0.001 0.005 0.28 0.002 Urbanization 0.034*** 13.43 0.011 0.035*** 13.43 0.011 0.024*** 8.97 0.007 0.005 1.40 0.001 Church Attendance 0.004 1.02 0.001 0.005 1.42 0.002 0.019*** 5.12 0.006 0.012** 2.27 0.003 Legal System -0.15*** -16.99 -0.047 -0.16*** -13.13 -0.046 Government -0.12*** -12.18 -0.037 -0.13*** -9.70 -0.037 Parliament -0.17*** -16.03 -0.052 -0.16*** -11.15 -0.045 Voice And Accountability. -0.16*** -11.480 -0.047 CEE And FSU 0.93*** 57.43 0.29 0.88*** 52.91 0.28 0.92*** 52.73 0.28 0.97*** 24.02 0.29 Latin America 0.68*** 31.10 0.24 0.64*** 28.49 0.22 0.64*** 27.69 0.22 0.60*** 15.13 0.19 Asia 0.58*** 21.99 0.21 0.56*** 20.87 0.20 0.79*** 27.02 0.29 0.91*** 21.09 0.32 Africa 1.31*** 22.13 0.49 1.28*** 20.78 0.48 1.33*** 19.87 0.49 Wald-test joint sign. polit. trust 1828.52 Pseudo R2 0.057 0.058 0.090 0.11 Number of observations 38277 36899 34476 18979 Prob > chi2 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00

Notes: In the reference group are Age<30, Man, Single, Lower Middle And Lower Class, Other Employment Status, Risk Taker, Western Europe + USA + Australia. ***, ** and * denote significance at 1%, 5% and 10%, respectively. Marginal effect = highest score (4). The higher the value the lower the justifiability. CEE: Central Eastern European Countries, FSU: Former Soviet Union Countries.

Page 75: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

65  

However, looking at the variable perceived corruption, the coefficient is negative and

statistically significant with marginal effects varying between 2.2 and 4.9 percentage points

and increasing with age. Thus, the level of perceived corruption decreases with an increase in

age. Furthermore, the results also indicate that there are gender differences. Being female

rather than male increases the probability of a person stating that accepting a bribe is never

justifiable. This result indicates that women’s norms regarding bribery differs from the norms

held by men. However, the perceived corruption coefficient is positive and statistically

significant, indicating that women perceive corruption to be more widespread than men.

Moreover, married people are more sensitive to the social norm regarding bribery than

individuals with any other marital status. However, the coefficient is only statistically

significant for the estimations using justifiability of corruption as the dependent variable. We

observe that being in a higher income class leads to a lower justifiability of corruption and

surprisingly, we also observe a negative correlation when focusing on perceived corruption.

Self-employed people are more tolerant towards corruption and perceive corruption to be

more common. Being risk averse is correlated with a lower justifiability of corruption. The

coefficient is statistically significant in all the regressions. On the other hand, we don’t

observe a statistically significant relationship between perceived corruption and political

interest. In line with our expectations we also observe a negative relationship between

urbanization and justifiability of corruption and a negative between urbanization and

perceived corruption. The results also show that church attendance is enforcing the norm of

compliance. The correlation between church attendance and justifiability of corruption is

positive, although the coefficient is not always statistically significant and the marginal

effects are not that large. Not surprisingly, we find strong regional differences. Moreover,

inhabitants of CEE and FSU, Latin America and Africa 42 countries report a higher

justifiability of bribing when compared to the reference group. Thus, the findings show that

the social norm regarding bribery is unambiguously higher in Western Europe, USA and

Australia. We also observe that the reference group has the lowest perceived level of

corruption.

In sum, the estimation results presented in Table 3-1 to 3-6 suggest that political interest

matters, controlling in a multivariate analysis for additional factors. This is consistent with

the theoretical argument developed in Section II. It is interesting to observe the importance of

political trust and voice and accountability in this context.                                                             42 As mentioned, Africa only covers the country Nigeria. This explains why in some regressions Africa is no longer reported (variable not collected this survey).  

Page 76: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

66  

It is reasonable to question the direction of causality in the results, and therefore our main

hypothesis can be criticized. One can argue that a higher level of perceived corruption may

lead to frustration with the lack of representative administration, and therefore to a lower

willingness to invest in the maintenance of political interest. Similarly, a higher justifiability

of corruption may induce individuals to be less interested in what happens in politics,

although the causality problem may be more severe when focusing on individuals’ perceived

level of corruption. Thus, to evaluate the direct effect of political interest on corruption it is

useful to investigate any potential causality problems through use of an instrumental variable

technique. We present in Table 3-7 six 2SLS estimations providing also detailed diagnostic

tests to check the robustness of the results. For simplicity (and due to less causality problems)

we will work with the second regression in the previous tables. The results remain robust

when considering a broader specification. In the first three specifications we focus on the

justifiability of corruption and the last three on the perceived corruption. The results indicate

that all three political interest proxies are statistically significant with a positive sign.

Political interest is instrumented through an index that measures the importance of private

interests43. We report the first-stage regression results of the instrumental variables and the F-

tests of the exclusion of the instruments. Overall, the instrument used is effective in

explaining political interest. The instrument is always statistically significant at the 1% level,

as are the F-tests for the instrument exclusion set in the first-stage regressions. On the other

hand, the variable is not correlated with our dependent variable. We also report the Anderson

canonical correlations LR test for the relevance of the instruments. A rejection of the null

hypothesis indicates that the model is identified and that the instruments are relevant (see

Hall, Rudebusch and Wilcox 1996). Moreover, we also report the Anderson-Rubin test that

the endogenous variables are jointly statistically significant. The test has the advantage of

being robust to the presence of weak instruments. Table 3-7 reports that in all cases the

Anderson canonical correlations LR test shows rejection of the null hypothesis, which

indicates that the models are identified and that the instruments are relevant. The Anderson-

Rubin test is also statistically significant. In all the cases, this test fails to reject the null

hypothesis that our instruments are valid. Thus, the 2SLS specifications also provide support

that political interest matters.

                                                            43 Mean value of the following three questions: Please say, for each of the following, how important it is in your life: family, friends, leisure (very 4), (rather 3), not very (2), not at all (1).

Page 77: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

67  

Table 3-7 2SLS results Weighted Ordered Probit Justifiability Of Corruption Perceived Corruption

Coeff. (25)

t-stat.

Coeff. (26)

t-stat.

Coeff. (27)

t-stat.

Coeff. (28)

t-stat.

Coeff. (29)

t-stat.

Coeff. (30)

t-stat.

Political Discussion 1.52*** 4.33 -0.35*** -2.74 Interest In Politics 1.00** 4.32 -0.23*** -2.69 Importance Of Politics 0.32*** 4.67 -0.080*** -2.76 Formal Education -0.077*** -3.95 -0.086*** -4.00 -0.021*** -2.90 0.017** 2.40 0.019** 2.42 0.005 1.53 Age 30-49 0.098* 1.87 0.13*** 2.63 0.25*** 7.86 -0.0001 0.00 -0.003 -0.17 -0.033*** -2.67 Age 50-64 0.22*** 2.82 0.25*** 3.31 0.45*** 11.98 -0.008 -0.26 -0.008 -0.28 -0.057*** -3.54 Age 65+ 0.42*** 7.01 0.35*** 4.77 0.52*** 11.97 -0.083*** -3.30 -0.060* -1.96 -0.11*** -5.13 Female 0.45*** 6.71 0.42*** 6.85 0.22*** 9.36 -0.039 -1.62 -0.035 -1.55 0.010 0.94 Married 0.098*** 2.58 0.12*** 3.26 0.16*** 5.04 0.027* 1.88 0.020 1.50 0.013 1.02 Widowed 0.18*** 3.55 0.14*** 2.76 0.17*** 3.84 -0.024 -1.02 -0.016 -0.70 -0.026 -1.17 Divorced -0.043 -0.66 -0.005 -0.08 0.024 0.42 0.061** 2.40 0.058** 2.33 0.051** 2.14 Separated 0.12 1.33 0.080 0.92 0.15* 1.93 0.038 1.11 0.057 1.68 0.034 1.01 Upper Class -0.31*** -3.02 -0.35*** -3.52 -0.30*** -3.30 0.012 0.31 0.009 0.23 -0.006 -0.15 Upper Middle Class -0.10*** -2.80 -0.14*** -3.35 -0.037 -1.32 -0.15*** -10.73 -0.14*** -8.80 -0.17*** -13.26 Selfemployed -0.057 -1.23 -0.063 -1.38 -0.055 -1.31 0.034* 1.87 0.032* 1.79 0.033* 1.89 Risk Averse 0.10*** 4.20 0.13*** 5.21 0.11*** 5.01 0.000 -0.01 -0.008 -0.78 -0.003 -0.26 Urbanization -0.010** -2.09 -0.004 -0.92 -0.006 -1.50 0.025*** 13.12 0.024*** 12.81 0.024*** 13.23 Church Attendance 0.016*** 2.65 0.005 0.88 0.007 1.26 0.002 0.82 0.004 1.63 0.004* 1.69 CEE And FSU -0.39*** -14.01 -0.22*** -4.01 -0.36*** -12.53 0.64*** 54.03 0.60*** 28.09 0.63*** 47.63 Latin America -0.32*** -3.24 -0.19 -1.49 -0.65*** -16.68 0.38*** 10.82 0.35*** 7.66 0.46*** 28.02 Asia 0.39*** 7.87 0.42*** 7.86 0.25*** 8.30 0.35*** 15.60 0.36*** 15.08 0.41*** 21.15 Africa -0.10 -1.08 -0.13 -1.32 -0.34*** -4.10 0.85*** 21.08 0.86*** 21.78 0.91*** 23.21 First stage regressions: Political Interest Private Interests 0.079*** 9.87 0.12*** 10.34 0.36*** 30.15 0.083*** 10.03 0.12*** 10.23 0.36*** 29.39 F-Test of excluded instruments 97.46*** 107.02*** 909.31*** 100.60*** 104.73*** 863.69*** Anderson canon. corr. likelihood ratio stat. 121.05*** 134.29*** 1166.46*** 213.87*** 131.41*** 1104.95*** Anderson-Rubin test 24.02*** 23.09*** 22.29*** 7.92*** 7.46*** 7.64*** Number of observations 38888 39212 39008 36232 36530 36354 Prob > F 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00

Notes: In the reference group are Age<30, Man, Single, Lower Middle And Lower Class, Other Employment Status, Risk Taker, Western Europe + USA + Australia. ***, ** and * denote significance at 1%, 5% and 10%, respectively. CEE: Central Eastern European Countries, FSU: Former Soviet Union Countries.

Page 78: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

68  

Table 3-8 Justifiability of corruption in Switzerland Weighted Ordered Probit Coeff z-Stat. Marg. Coeff. z-Stat. Marg. Coeff. z-Stat. Marg.

(31) (32) (33)

Political Discussion 0.177** 2.32 0.049

Interest In Politics 0.12* 1.92 0.032

Importance Of Politics 0.20*** 3.30 0.053

Formal Education -0.039 -1.28 -0.011 -0.040 -1.30 -0.011 -0.041 -1.31 -0.011

Age 30-49 0.300** 2.26 0.082 0.30** 2.26 0.083 0.27** 2.04 0.073

Age 50-64 0.43** 2.48 0.11 0.42** 2.42 0.10 0.45*** 2.61 0.11

Age 65+ 0.59*** 2.90 0.14 0.57*** 2.79 0.13 0.55*** 2.69 0.13

Female 0.53*** 5.49 0.15 0.53*** 5.48 0.15 0.52*** 5.42 0.14

Married 0.26* 1.96 0.073 0.27** 2.00 0.075 0.29** 2.14 0.080

Widowed -0.066 -0.28 -0.019 -0.070 -0.30 -0.020 -0.057 -0.24 -0.016

Divorced -0.092 -0.46 -0.026 -0.063 -0.32 -0.018 -0.001 0.00 0.000

Separated -0.089 -0.25 -0.026 -0.053 -0.15 -0.015 -0.024 -0.06 -0.007

Selfemployed -0.051 -0.29 -0.015 -0.037 -0.21 -0.010 -0.045 -0.24 -0.012

Risk Averse 0.11 1.07 0.030 0.11 1.05 0.029 0.10 0.99 0.027

Urbanization -0.005 -0.20 -0.001 -0.005 -0.20 -0.001 -0.013 -0.53 -0.004

Church Attendance -0.008 -0.30 -0.002 -0.008 -0.29 -0.002 -0.022 -0.80 -0.006

Legal System 0.12* 1.69 0.032 0.11 1.58 0.030 0.13* 1.83 0.034

Democracy 0.030 0.79 0.008 0.027 0.72 0.008 0.013 0.35 0.004

Pseudo R2 0.049 0.048 0.055

Number of observations 1086 1086 1075

Prob > chi2 0.00 0.00 0.00

Notes: In the reference group are Age<30, Man, Single, Other Employment Status, Risk Taker, ***, ** and * denote significance at 1%, 5% and 10%, respectively.

Page 79: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

69  

                       Table 3-9 Perceived corruption in Switzerland Weighted Ordered Probit Coeff z-Stat. Marg. Coeff. z-Stat. Marg. Coeff. z-Stat. Marg.

(34) (35) (36)

Political Discussion -0.067 -0.97 -0.008

Interest In Politics -0.114** -2.19 -0.014

Importance Of Politics -0.10** -2.00 -0.012

Formal Education -0.057** -2.30 -0.007 -0.049* -1.94 -0.006 -0.053** -2.12 -0.007

Age 30-49 0.066 0.52 0.008 0.078 0.62 0.010 0.096 0.75 0.012

Age 50-64 -0.050 -0.33 -0.006 -0.022 -0.15 -0.003 -0.032 -0.21 -0.004

Age 65+ -0.25 -1.42 -0.027 -0.21 -1.23 -0.024 -0.20 -1.12 -0.022

Female -0.25*** -2.88 -0.031 -0.27*** -3.00 -0.033 -0.25*** -2.88 -0.031

Married 0.025 0.21 0.003 0.016 0.14 0.002 0.007 0.06 0.001

Widowed -0.45* -1.91 -0.042 -0.46* -1.92 -0.042 -0.46* -1.92 -0.041

Divorced -0.098 -0.44 -0.011 -0.13 -0.58 -0.015 -0.12 -0.52 -0.013

Separated -0.27 -0.62 -0.028 -0.27 -0.61 -0.027 -0.31 -0.68 -0.030

Selfemployed -0.010 -0.07 -0.001 -0.014 -0.09 -0.002 -0.057 -0.40 -0.007

Risk Averse -0.18* -1.90 -0.021 -0.18*** -1.97 -0.022 -0.16* -1.71 -0.018

Urbanization -0.036 -1.54 -0.005 -0.034 -1.43 -0.004 -0.037 -1.56 -0.005

Church Attendance -0.051** -2.21 -0.006 -0.049** -2.13 -0.006 -0.047** -2.00 -0.006

Legal System -0.48*** -7.30 -0.060 -0.48*** -7.31 -0.059 -0.47*** -7.11 -0.057

Direct Democracy -0.10*** -3.00 -0.013 -0.098*** -2.87 -0.012 -0.099*** -2.88 -0.012

Pseudo R2 0.077 0.080 0.077

Number of observations 1019 1018 1008

Prob > chi2 0.00 0.00 0.00

Notes: In the reference group are Age<30, Man, Single, Other Employment Status, Risk Taker, ***, ** and * denote significance at 1%, 5% and 10%, respectively.

Page 80: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

70  

3.4.2 Within-Country Evidence

In general, drawing conclusions from cross-cultural comparisons is difficult because not all

features specific to a country can always be controlled in a satisfactory manner. Thus, we

extend our study, focusing on within-country data from Switzerland at the state (cantonal)

level to investigate the impact of tax morale and institutional quality. As mentioned

previously, analyses of Swiss data are interesting because Switzerland’s institutions are not

homogeneous. The degree of institutionalized political participation rights varies strongly

between the 26 Swiss cantons. In line with the previous regressions, we are going to

investigate the third wave. This is the latest available data set for Switzerland as the country

did not participate in the fourth wave. Table 3-8 and 3- 9 present the results. We make one

small change to the specification structure: instead of voice and accountability we are going

to include a democracy index 44 measured at the cantonal level. The degree of direct

democratic participation rights is measured with an index developed by Stutzer (1999). To

maximize the number of available observations we first run regressions without the variable

income45 as this variable would reduce the number of observations by almost 200 subjects.

However, in a second step we are going to discuss the results of regressions where we include

income as a control variable.

We observe that political interest also matters for Switzerland, and the quantitative effects

are quite substantial. For example, increase in the political discussion scale by one unit raises

the probability of stating that corruption is never justifiable by 4.9 percentage points. The

effect is even more relevant in further specifications. For example, if we include income in

the regression, we observe the coefficient for interest in politics in Table 3-8 is statistically

                                                            44 It should be noticed that the Swiss World Value Survey was not random-random but quota-random, based on a random sample of communes and then on quotas in terms of sex, age, etc. in the selected communes. Thus, the smallest cantons are not necessarily represented (not represented are: Appenzell a. Rh., Glarus, Jura, Nidwalden, Uri, and Zug). On the other hand, the ISSP data set contains all 26 cantons. 45 Here is a scale of incomes (1-10). We would like to know in what group your household is, counting all wages, salaries, pensions and other incomes that come in. Just give the letter of the group your household falls into, before taxes and other deductions.

1. Less than 20’000 Swiss Francs 2. 20’000-26’999 3. 27’000-31’999 4. 32’000-37’999 5. 38’000-44’999 6. 45’000-51’999 7. 52’000-59’999 8. 60’000-69’999 9. 70’000-89’999 10. More than 90’000

Page 81: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

   71

significant at the 1% level (t-value=2.15). Interestingly, we observe that a higher level of

direct democracy is positively correlated with a lower justifiability of corruption. We also

observe the tendency that trust in the legal system matters, particularly when focusing on the

perceived level of corruption. We have only included this political trust variable in the

specification as it had the strongest impact on corruption in the previous six tables. In

addition, it allows us to avoid a decrease in the number of observations. As in the previous

approach, we also observe that age, gender and marital status (being married) matter for

justifiability of corruption. On the other hand, risk attitudes are relevant when focusing on the

perceived corruption rather than on the justifiability of corruption. Similarly, urbanization

and self-employment status are not relevant at all. Moreover, religion is only relevant when

focusing on perceived corruption. It is also worthwhile to note that we did not find a

significant relationship between income and political interest in Switzerland. Finally, in line

with the previous findings we observe that overall, formal education is less relevant than

informal education or political interest. The coefficient is only statistically significant in

Table 3-9 and the marginal effects are below the values found for political interest. Thus,

here we find additional support that human capital is mainly relevant in a specialized form.

3.5 Conclusion

In recent years the topic of corruption has attracted a great deal of attention. However, there

is still a lack of empirical evidence about the determinants of corruption at the micro level.

Moreover, there are still interesting variables that have not been investigated in the past. This

empirical study analyses a cross-section of individuals using data from the World Values

Survey, investigating the determinants of corruption with two dependent variables: perceived

corruption and the justifiability of corruption. Both variables are strongly correlated with

other commonly used measurements of corruption such as the Transparency International

Corruption Perception Index, the International Country Risk Guide Index or the Quality of

Government Corruption Index. The major aim in the chapter was to investigate whether

political interest matters. Despite economists’ increasing interest in the determinants of

corruption, this factor has been widely neglected in the literature. Thus, it was highly relevant

that we investigated empirically the possible connections between political interest and

corruption.

To check the robustness we explored the relationship between political interest and

corruption using three different proxies of political interest. The results clearly indicate that

use of an education variable does not reflect the accumulation and stock of human capital. A

Page 82: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

   72

further strength of the chapter is to focus not only on the perceived level of corruption, (as is

commonly the case in the current literature), but also to consider the justifiability of bribery.

Moreover, we have provided cross-country and within-country evidence at the micro level,

controlling for the state of relevant institutional conditions. In this study, our focus on

political interest required that we control for voice and accountability and direct democratic

rights.

The econometric estimates also suggest that strength of social norms regarding bribery is

higher and the perceived level of corruption lower in the reference group (region Western

Europe, USA and Austria) compared to CEE and FSU countries, Latin America, Asia and

Africa.

All in all, the results suggest some interesting political implications. Increasing the level

of interest in politics may help to reduce the level of corruption in a society. The results also

suggest that it may be important to place more emphasis on institutions that enhance voice

and accountability and democratic participation rights. This helps to increase individuals’

social norm and perception of compliance. Thus, the results presented in this chapter mirror

those in previous studies and underscore the importance of accountability as an essential

aspect for the efficient functioning of a government and the existing institutional architecture.

However, understanding how corruption can be reduced and how government can foster

political interest remains a fruitful field for further research.

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Page 83: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

   73

Chapter Four Democracy and Corruption: Cross-country Evidence46

 

4.1 Introduction

Rose-Ackerman (1999, p.127) stresses: “Democracies based on strong legal foundation

provide a stable framework for economic activity. For this framework to operate efficiently,

however, politicians must seek reelection and must feel insecure about their prospects, but

not too insecure. This leads to a ‘paradox of stability’. Too much security of tenure can

further corrupt arrangements. Too much insecurity can have the same effect.” Interestingly,

prior literature on the relationship between democracy and corruption provides mixed

evidence. Ades and Di Tella (1999) find that fewer political rights are correlated to low

corruption levels. Ades and Di Tella (1997) and Fisman and Gatti (2002), however, fail to

find any substantial effects on corruption of political rights and civil liberties respectively.

Triesman (2000) does not find a significant direct effect of democracy on corruption either,

however he documents that the duration of democracy significantly reduces corruption. On

the other hand, Goldsmith (1999) reports that political democratization is associated with a

lower degree of political corruption. Chowdhury (2004) also finds that the presence of

democracy can reduce the level of corruption significantly. From a slightly different angle,

Bohara, Mitchell and Mittendorff (2004) highlight that citizens’ participation in competitive

elections increases the control of corruption. Recently, Goel and Nelson (2005) provide

empirical evidence that less democratic countries always have a higher incidence of

corruption. Emerson (2006) also shows that more political rights have a depressing effect on

corruption. Billger and Goel (2009), however, document in their quantile regressions that

democracy significantly reduces corruption only in the most corrupt countries.

Instead of exclusively testing the linear democracy-corruption association, Montinola and

Jackman (2002) provide evidence that the effect of political competition on corruption is

nonlinear. Corruption is lower in dictatorial countries than in ones partially democratized. It

will, however, decline with the democratic level after a threshold. Sung (2003), on the other

hand, reports that the cubic function best fits the cross-national data on the relationship

between democracy and corruption.

Inconsistent empirical results suggest the demand of theoretical guidance. Unfortunately

there is little theoretical evidence on the relationship except Mohatdi and Roe (2003). They

                                                            46 This chapter has been submitted to Journal of Development Economics 

Page 84: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

   74

build a two-sector endogenous growth model where agents switch between rent seeking and

production. A reversed-U effect of democratization on corruption is then derived: rents and

hence levels of corruption increase in the young democracies but decrease in the mature

democracies. However, it is questionable whether their longitudinal section mechanism,

though enlightening, is able to explain existing cross-section evidence of the nexus between

democracy and corruption.

Currently, two empirical articles more related to our study have emerged. Rock (2007)

utilizes the instrument variable approach to empirically show an inverted U relationship

between democracy and corruption. Saha et al. (2009), however, perform fixed-effect

regressions to find that economic freedom always reduces corruption, while democracy

increases corruption under weak economic freedom and decreases corruption under strong

economic freedom. Both papers document the complexity of the nexus between democracy

and corruption. However, the corruption indices that both papers use are actually not suitable

for panel analysis. This will be discussed later. Furthermore the economic freedom index in

Saha et al. (2009) contains eight components ranging from micro business freedom to macro

monetary freedom. This has the disadvantage that it is difficult to identify a clear mechanism

for the interactions between democracy, economic freedom and corruption from their results.

Indeed Goel and Nelson (2005) have found that different components of economic freedom

influence corruption in different ways.

This chapter attempts to clarify miscellaneousness in past research with a uniform

framework, and therefore contribute to the literature on the linkage between democracy and

corruption. We first develop a theoretical model that incorporates the effects of property

rights protection and income distribution into the relationship between democracy and

corruption. The final effect of democracy on corruption depends on the combination of

property rights protection and income distribution in a country. For example, Uslaner (2008)

stresses that the transition to democracy and a market economy in Eastern Europe brought

great instability and rising levels of inequality. Then we utilize a large panel sample including

about 108 countries from 1995-2006 to examine the conclusion of the theory. With two

alternative measures of democracy, our empirical analysis adopts the fixed-effect approach

and then the instrumental variable approach to validate important aspects of the theoretical

model. We find in our empirical analysis that the effect of democracy on corruption

obviously depends on the level of property rights protection and income equality. The

democracy’s effect is different under different property right protection and income equality

conditions. The finding is particularly robust for property rights protection. We therefore

Page 85: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

   75

provide an insightful mechanism for the nexus between democracy and corruption, both

theoretically and empirically.

The rest of the chapter is organised as follows. Section 4.2 presents the theoretical model.

Section 4.3 provides the corresponding empirical analysis. Section 4.4 concludes with some

comments.

4.2 Theoretical Model

Current conflicting linear and nonlinear evidence of the linkage between democracy and

corruption may imply that further factors need to be taken into account in order to thoroughly

understand the relationship. From our point of view, the impact of democracy on corruption

is conditional on income distribution and property rights protection, which can be seen in the

model that follows.

According to our knowledge, there are only two recent theoretical studies related to ours.

As discussed above, Mohatdi and Roe (2003) modelled the association between democracy

and corruption. Alesina and Angeletos (2005), with a non-overlapping-generation model,

document the existence of multiple steady states in the levels of inequality, redistribution and

corruption. It seems that no work, however, has explicitly explored the nexus between

democracy, income distribution, property rights and corruption. We are therefore attempting

to fill the void.

Mohatdi and Roe (2003) assume that “democracy is about the flow of information and

access to the government” (p. 450). We, however, follow Dahl (1974) to stress that from a

constitutional perspective the essence of democracy is electoral participation and political

competition. In line with Murphy et al. (1993) and Alesina and Angeletos (2005), we treat

corruption as a rent-seeking activity.

The political economy mechanism provided here is closely related to Persson and

Tabellini (1994). The pivotal voter in a country determines the redistribution policy. The

redistributive decision therefore hinges on the difference between the income of the pivotal

voter and the average income in the society. Unequal societies where the income of the

pivotal voter is lower than the average income consequently have more redistribution from

the rich to the poor than equal ones. Rent-seeking activities and hence corruption emerges in

the allocation of the redistributive tax revenue. Furthermore, in the absence of property rights

protection, the rich are likely to gain more from appropriation of the redistributive tax

revenue than the poor though all have the access to the appropriation (rent-seeking)

technology (Gradstein, 2007). Redistribution thus cannot mitigate income inequality as

Page 86: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

   76

expected. As a result, high levels of corruption and income inequality might be self-

sustaining in democracies with unsecure property rights. Oligarchies, however, may avoid

this situation because their “pivotal agents” are often richer than the average. The situation

can also be mitigated or even eliminated in democracies with equal income distribution

and/or secure property rights. In summary, it can be seen that democracy in our setting may

breed corruption due to intensive redistribution, especially in countries that lack income

equality and property rights protection. Below we will discuss this in detail. It is worth noting

that unlike some prior studies, we treat democracy here as an exogenous variable in order to

focus on studying the relationship between democracy and corruption.

4.2.1 Model

We consider a non-overlapping-generations model where altruistic individuals with

monotonic preferences live only for one period. Each generation comprises a large number of

individuals distributed uniformly over 0,1 . Similar to Gradstein (2007), each member in

generation has the following utility:

4‐1

where is his own consumption, is the income in next period accrued to his child. The

budget constraint is,

4‐2

where is the income of individual from his parent, is his productive capital and

is his unproductive capital in rent seeking. For convenience we further assume

4‐3

where is the average income of generation . , and its distribution therefore

indicates the degree of income inequality in the model economy. The production function

without government is

, 0, 0 1. 4‐4

which exhibits diminishing returns to scale.

Following Alesina and Angeletos (2005), we assume that the government levies a flat tax

on individual capital to fund a lump-sum transfer across all individuals. The tax rate is

which has been decided by a prior process of voting. Then the sum of the transfer

is . However, the distribution of the transfer among individuals is determined by

rent seeking activities. Similar to Sonin (2003) and Gradstein (2007), we suppose that the

share of the transfer which the individual can grab is

Page 87: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

   77

4 5

which implies that given the level of public property rights protection 0), the share of

transfer an individual can get increases with his own input and decreases with the competing

inputs of the others. According to Alesina and Angeletos (2005), the corruption level is

plausibly assumed to increases with the amount of transfer.

Then the net capital endowment of individual after redistribution is given by productive

and unproductive investments:

1 4 6

And the output produced by individual in period t+1 is

1 4 7

Therefore the utility of individual can be expressed as following,

1 4 8

Similar to Sonin (2003) and Gradstein (2007), we assume that and

are exogenous to any individual since there are numerous individuals in each generation.

4.2.2 Economic Equilibrium

Given the policy, each individual makes his optimal decision47.

, ,

. .

In the economic equilibrium, individual hence has

1

2 11

4 9

2 1

1 4 10

2 1

1 1 4 11

                                                            47 Following the spirit of Gradstein (2007),  we do not include taxation into the budget constraint because the government does not consume any in our simple model. And taxation here is a component of the technology 4-7 that agents employ. There are actually two stages in the technology. In the first stage agents obtain their net capital endowment by paying taxes and rent seeking. Agents then produce output with their net capital endowment. 

Page 88: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

   78

where we let

,

Here we can easily find that and decrease while increases when rises,

which is consistent with prior findings. The optimal utility of individual hence is

2 1 ln1

4 12

where denotes the constant term,

2 1 ln 2 1 2

4.2.3 Political Equilibrium

The optimal tax rate to individual must satisfy

0

So is solved as

1

1 4 13

If the tax rate is determined by a majority vote in the society, the pivotal voter will

eventually decide the tax rate.

1

1 4 14

Not losing generality, we suppose that , where is the average income of

individuals in time and hence indicates income inequality in the economy. Then

1

e 1 4 15

As in Alesina and Angeletos (2005), the tax rate in our model indicates the corruption

level because the increase in tax rate leads to the enhancement of rent-seeking for tax revenue

and hence the rise of corruption levels, or vice versa. Therefore, we first can conclude from

equation 4-15 that the effect of democracy on corruption depends on property rights

protection, income inequality and economic development of a society. Under some

circumstances democracy may even increase corruption. However, one should note that we

use a simplistic notion of democratization where the process is mainly the delegation of

power by a pivotal voter in the previous enfranchised group (the elite) to another citizen, who

Page 89: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

   79

turns out to be the pivotal voter in the extended enfranchised group 48 . The extended

enfranchised group is therefore, as historical evidence suggests, often poorer than the

previous enfranchised group on average. The income level of the pivotal voter, namely the

median voter, in the extended enfranchised group hence is lower than that of the previous

pivotal voter, which means that democratization tends to make a poorer citizen be the pivotal

voter. According to 4-15, democratization may raise the tax rate due to more demand for

redistribution and eventually results in corruption, other things equal. The effect of

democracy will be aggravated in countries with income inequality and inefficient protection

of property. This finding is similar in spirit to Cervellati et al. (2008) who contend that under

high income inequality, democracy causes social conflict while oligarchy can avoid it.

The second conclusion deduced from 4-15 is that ceteris paribus, income inequality

causes corruption. When there is high income inequality in a country: 0, the pivotal

voter’s income is below the average and he therefore tends to choose a high tax rate for more

redistribution, which in turn results in more corruption. When income distribution is,

however, more equal in a society: 0, the pivotal voter with his income above average

will select a low tax rate due to his reluctance in redistribution, which therefore reduces

corruption. In summary, income inequality is a fertile ground for corruption, especially in

democracies. Glaeser et al. (2003) and Sonin (2003) have even claimed that unequal income

distribution is a hotbed of poor governance.

The conclusions above are in a similar spirit to the “tyranny of the majority”, which

Tocqueville (1835) warned may occur in democracies. Tyranny of the majority refers to the

circumstance where the majority might use its strength in a democracy to place its interests

above those of the minority. Specifically, if income distribution is unequal in a country, the

democratic system providing more political equality might lead to excessive redistribution or

even public expropriation, which can weaken property rights protection and cause corruption.

This danger, however, will not appear in the ideal state with prefect equality and freedom as

depicted by Tocqueville.

                                                            48  For example, the model disregards positive externalities derived in a direct-democratic environment via referenda and initiative. Being able to renegotiate and shape the political environments can lead to an increase in civic virtues. The more citizens can participate in political decision making by popular rights, the more the “political contract” is based on trust between state/public officials and the citizens which may promote civic duty. Citizens are in this case treated as “citizens” with extensive rights and obligations (Frey, 2003). The voting procedure, especially public discussions prior to votes, creates a sense of civic duty, as citizens become aware of the importance to follow the endogenously generated rules. The possibility to vote promotes social norms of compliance and therefore may reduce corruption.

Page 90: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

   80

It is obviously that property rights protection is negatively correlated with corruption in

our model. This is reasonable since secure property rights limit expropriation (Besley and

Ghatak, 2009). In 4-15 decreases when increases, which suggests that property

rights protection depresses corruption. We can confirm this result from below

0, 4 16

As we know, is negatively correlated with the level of property rights protection

since rational individuals will invest more on expropriation under weaker protection of

property rights, other things being equal. ⁄ therefore reflects the security of property

rights. Inequality 4-16 shows that secure property rights check corruption, which coincides

with the above finding. We can further deduce from equation 4-15 that property rights

protection may act as a multiplier of democracy and income inequality in terms of influence

over corruption. In addition, democracy might influence property rights protection via the tax

rate. However, the mechanism here is somewhat indirect: voting decides the tax rate

hence affects and , and through the channel it finally influences property rights

protection ⁄ .

It is worth noting that as Cervellati et al. (2008) argue, democracy is neither sufficient nor

necessary for the protection of property rights, although it has often been found to promote

property rights protection. Actually Glaeser et al. (2004) have observed secure property rights

in oligarchies.

Last but not least, based on the inequality derived from 4-15: ⁄ 0, we can

demonstrate the basic fact that the average income level, namely economic development,

controls corruption, which has been verified by most empirical studies (Treisman, 2007).

To summarize, our theoretical finding is that corruption level is jointly determined by

democracy, property rights protection, income and income inequality. Specifically, the effect

of political democracy on corruption depends on other social and economic conditions:

property rights protection, income and income inequality.

4.3 Empirical Evidence

Our empirical analysis employs data from a large sample of 108 countries during the period

1995–2006. We first discuss the methodology and data used and report the results afterwards.

Page 91: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

   81

4.3.1 Methodology and Data

Our empirical analysis aims to examine our theoretical predictions to shed new light on the

causal effect of democracy on corruption. We are aware of the potential bias in OLS

identification due to the endogeneity problem that omitted historical factors might influence

both corruption and democracy. We therefore employ two strategies to address the

endogeneity problem. Our first strategy is to use fixed effects regressions to remove the

potential bias since the omitted variables here affecting both corruption and democracy are

generally country-specific, institutional factors which are approximately time-invariant.

However, the conventional fixed effects approach is not applicable in the current situation.

As seen below, key explanatory variables such as democracy and property rights protection

in our regressions rarely changes and hence are nearly time-invariant. Standard fixed effects

regression is inefficient in estimating the effect of minutely varying variables. According to

Plumper and Troeger (2007, p.125), “An inefficient estimation is not merely a nuisance

leading to somewhat higher SEs. Inefficiency leads to highly unreliable point estimates and

may thus cause wrong inferences in the same way a biased estimator could.” We therefore

adopt a common strategy utilized by economists and political scientists in their empirical

analyses concerning institutions. Specifically, we group countries and areas in our study by

the UN standard country and area codes classifications to generate regional dummies49. Then

we use OLS estimation including regional fixed effect dummies and time fixed effect

dummies to identify the impact of democracy on corruption. With this approach we can raise

the efficiency of our estimation by increasing the “within variance” while still controlling for

most of the omitted country-specific factors which may affect both corruption and democracy

since countries in the same category are to a large extent homogenous. For convenience, the

approach is still called a fixed-effects approach in the current chapter although it is not the

conventional one.

The fixed effects approach, however, is not a substitute for the instrumental variables

approach indeed. Our second strategy therefore is to use the instrumental variables approach

to identify the causal effect of democracy on corruption in case that there are still some time-

                                                            49 There are originally 22 categories in the UN standard country and area codes classifications: Eastern Africa, Middle Africa, Northern Africa, Southern Africa, Western Africa, Caribbean, Central America, South America, Northern America, Central Asia, Eastern Asia, Southern Asia, South-Eastern Asia, Western Asia, Eastern Europe, Northern Europe, Southern Europe, Western Europe, Australia and New Zealand, Melanesia, Micronesia, Polynesia. We however treat Israel, the only Jewish state in the world, as an independent category since it is obviously different from neighbouring Arabic countries (see, Anderson, Seibert, and Wagner 2006). Therefore we actually categorize countries into 23 groups.

Page 92: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

   82

variant omitted country characteristics influencing both democracy and income, which cannot

be controlled for by the fixed effects. Previous studies have made great efforts to address the

endogeneity problem with instruments. Hall and Jones (1999) use the distance from the

equator and the share of population speaking major European languages as instruments for

institutional quality. Acemoglou et al. (2001), however, suggest that European settler

mortality and aboriginal population density in 1500 can be employed as instruments for

current institutions in ex-colonies. When studying the effect of democracy on corruption,

Rock (2007) uses the population fraction of protestant and the latitude of a country’s capital

as instruments for democracy. All of these instruments are intended to capture the western

influence on current institutional quality. However, because the western influence is manifold

and correlated with many aspects of institution, it is difficult to declare what specifically

these variables instrument for. As we know, corruption level reflects institution quality. If we

use these instruments for democracy in our case, they may influence corruption through not

only the channel of democracy but also many other institutional channels. This would violate

the exclusion restriction. We therefore need to choose a more specific instrument for

democracy to guarantee the validity of our IV approach. Following Mobarak (2005), we

construct a dummy indicating any country with the largest proportion of population

practicing Islam (CIA, the World Factbook 200050) as an instrument for democracy. The

distribution of Muslims is of course exogenous, especially in our time horizon. Huntington

(1991, p. 307) argued: “To the extent that government legitimacy and policy flow from

religious doctrine and religious expertise, Islamic concepts of politics differ from and

contradict the premises of democratic politics.” Treisman (2000) and Paldam (2001), on the

other hand, have found that the direct effect of Islam on corruption is insignificant. We

therefore can plausibly suppose that the Islamic religion influences the corruption level only

through the channel of democracy. This validates our instrumental variable.

We now describe the data we use in our empirical analysis. To secure robustness, we

attempt to employ alternative measures of key variables in our regressions. However, we

cannot find more than one corruption measures suitable for panel analysis. Many researchers

such as Treisman (2007) have pointed out that two corruption indices often used in research:

Corruption Perception Index (CPI) compiled by Transparency International (TI) and Control

of Corruption Indicator (CC) constructed by the World Bank51, are actually inappropriate for

                                                            50 http://www.umsl.edu/services/govdocs/wofact2000/index.html 51 Saha et al. (2009) and Rock (2007) use the two indices respectively. 

Page 93: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

   83

panel analysis. Both indices have altered their constructing methodologies and data sources

over the years. Annual variations of both indices may reflect changes in the methodologies

and data sources rather than actual corruption perceptions. Kaufmann and Kraay (2002)

acknowledge that about 50% of the across-time variance of the CC index originates in

changes in data sources and weights assigned to each data source. We hence need to choose

another common corruption measure: the rating of corruption in the International Country

Risk Guide (ICRG), to perform our panel regressions. The ICRG corruption index, ranging

from 0 (most corrupt) to 6 (least corrupt), measures the degree of corruption within the

political system (e.g., demand of special payments, bribes connected with import and export

licenses, exchange controls, tax assessment, police protection, or loans) prevailing in

countries on the basis of the experts’ assessment. The ICRG index provides comparable

corruption data over time and across countries, and hence is the only corruption data set

available for the panel analysis. To obtain a proxy for corruption rather than the lack of

corruption we use negative values of the ICRG index in our estimations (-ICRG).

In line with the role democracy plays in our theoretical model, our first measure of

democracy is the Polity Regime Index: Polity2, the difference between the Polity Democracy

Indicator and the Polity Autocracy Indicator in Polity IV database. It is coded on an

evaluation of the competitiveness of political participation, the competitiveness and openness

of executive recruitment and constraints on the chief executive and ranges from -10 (full

autocracy) to 10 (full democracy). The second measure of democracy we use is the Political

Rights Index from Freedom House. This index measures the degree to which citizens in a

country have control over governors by a checklist of 10 questions about electoral process,

political pluralism and participation and functioning of government. It ranges from 1 (highest

political rights) to 7 (lowest political rights). We use this index mainly as the robustness

check since one of its ten checklist questions assesses national corruption levels, which, as

Rock (2007) points out, might lead to the problem regressing corruption on itself. To keep the

consistency with the Polity2, we use negative values of the Political Rights Index in our

regressions.

We use the property rights rating in the Index of Economic Freedom produced by the

Heritage Foundation and the Wall Street Journal, commonly utilized in previous research, to

measure the security of property rights in our analysis. This index, ranging from 0 (no

protection of property rights) to 100 (full protection of property rights), mainly assesses the

degree to which the laws of a country protect private property rights and the degree to which

its government enforces those laws. According to our knowledge, no further data source of

Page 94: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

   84

property rights protection covers our investigating period. The Index of Protection of

Property Rights compiled by the Fraser Institute, used in some priori studies, only covers

2000-2006 hence cannot be employed in our analysis.

We do not construct the actual Gini coefficient series to measure income inequality over

time and across countries since there is not a complete time series in many countries in the

World Income Inequality Database. More importantly Gini coefficients available in WIID

often seem incomparable across countries and/or over time due to their differences in survey

base (income/expenditure), income/expenditure concept, population/area coverage as well as

several other aspects. As income equality in most countries does not change dramatically in

the time perspective of a decade, we instead construct a dummy to indicate income equality

in countries by reviewing all available WIID data in our investigating period. The dummy

equals to 0 if a country passes the international warning line for the Gini coefficient: 0.40 and

1 otherwise. In this simple way, we reduce measurement error of income equality data and

make them comparable. It is worth noting that we only consider income-based Gini

coefficients in the dummy construction. Following Deininger and Squire's (1996), we add 6.6

to the expenditure-based Gini coefficients if there are no income-based ones available in a

country.

We also include other determinants of corruption identified by previous research in our

regressions. GDP per capita, population, openness proxied by import volume in percent of

GDP and natural resource abundance proxied by fuel exports in percent of merchandise

exports are all derived from the World Development Indicators. Adult literacy rates,

reflecting education attainments of countries, are gathered from the UN Human Development

Reports (1998-2009). Ethnolinguistic fractionalization data come from Alesina et al. (2003).

The detailed description of our data is provided in Table 4-1.

Table 4-1 Descriptive Statistics Variable Observations Mean Standard DeviationCorruption (ICRG) 1299 3.05 1.25 Democracy (Polity IV) 1510 4.51 5.96 Democracy (Freedom House) 1560 3.21 2.03 Property Rights (Index) 1476 52.40 22.89 Income Equality (Dummy) 1560 0.45 0.50 GDP per capita 1541 6.38 9.90 Literacy Rate 1534 82.06 27.16 Resource abundance (Fuel export / Commodity export) 1289 12.16 21.74 Openness (Import / GDP) 1513 44.76 25.83 Ethnic fractionalization 1560 0.42 0.25 Population 1548 0.45 1.45

Page 95: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

   85

4.3.2 Results

To obtain intuitions directing econometric analysis, we first plot the relationship between

democracy and corruption in Figure 4-1. It seems that both the linear negative effect and

quadratic effect of democracy on corruption documented in the literature are reasonable.

Such a descriptive analysis however only gives us information about the raw effects and not

the partial effects. We then test the relationship between democracy and corruption in a

multivariate analysis.

Figure 4-1 Relationship between democracy and corruption

We first briefly examine previous findings with (regional) fixed-effects panel regressions.

Column (1) and (2) in Table 4-2 successfully replicate previous results, supporting the

findings that democracy reduces corruption (see Goldsmith 1999 and Rock 2009). When we

take into account effects of property rights protection and income inequality on corruption,

the linear effect of democracy in column (3) loses its significance, which appears to be in line

with Ades and Di Tella (1997), and Fisman and Gatti (2002). The quadratic effect of

democracy in column (4), however, remains statistically significant. It seems that the

nonlinear effect of democracy is robust, as Rock (2009) argues. However, in column (5) the

quadratic term of democracy lose its significance when we consider the interactions between

property rights protection, income distribution and democracy. The results actually indicate

that the effect of democracy on corruption is modified by property rights protection and

income distribution as can be seen looking at the interaction terms. The overall effect of

democracy on corruption therefore depends on the combination of income equality and

Page 96: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

   86

security of property rights in a country, as predicted by our theoretical model. The positive

coefficient of democracy can be interpreted as the effect of democracy of corruption when

property rights and income equality are 0. Thus, in countries with no property rights and a

very high income inequality democracy induces corruption. The results of the two interaction

terms also indicate that a high level of property rights and income equality promote the

controlling effect of democracy on corruption.

Table 4-2 Effect of democracy on corruption: review and implication (fixed effects results) Corruption level (-ICRG)

Fixed effects (1) (2) (3) (4) (5)

Democracy -0.020*** -0.0071 -0.0077 0.0017 0.047*** (0.0060) (0.0068) (0.0067) (0.0073) (0.016) Democracy2 -0.0049*** -0.0038*** -0.0018 (0.0013) (0.0014) (0.0015) GDP per capita -0.062*** -0.058*** -0.044*** -0.042*** -0.039*** (0.0052) (0.0055) (0.0059) (0.0060) (0.0062) Literacy rate -0.0024*** -0.0022*** -0.0026*** -0.0025*** -0.0024** (0.00076) (0.00080) (0.00089) (0.00092) (0.00010) Resource abundance 0.0055*** 0.0048*** 0.0031*** 0.0027** 0.0030*** (0.0011) (0.0011) (0.0012) (0.0012) (0.0011) Openness -0.0054*** -0.0060*** -0.0035** -0.0041*** -0.0045*** (0.0013) (0.0014) (0.0014) (0.0015) (0.0016) Ethnic fractionalization -0.15 -0.21 -0.16 -0.20 -0.26* (0.15) (0.15) (0.15) (0.14) (0.15) Population 0.015 0.027 0.0023 0.012 0.018 (0.018) (0.018) (0.017) (0.017) (0.018) Property rights -0.013*** -0.012*** -0.0076*** (0.0021) (0.0021) (0.0028) Income equality -0.28*** -0.26*** -0.18*** (0.063) (0.063) (0.064) Democracy* Property rights -0.00086*** (0.00033) Democracy* Income equality -0.037*** (0.013) Constant -2.90*** -2.66*** -2.13*** -1.99*** -2.21*** (0.16) (0.17) (0.19) (0.19) (0.21)

R-squared 0.65 0.65 0.66 0.66 0.66 Observations 1107 1107 1089 1089 1089

Notes: Robust standard errors in parentheses, ***, ** and * denote significance at 1%, 5% and 10% respectively. Regional and time fixed effects are controlled for in all regressions.

It makes sense to provide more evidence to consolidate our new finding. Table 4-3

supplies fixed-effect results as expected. We first get preliminary results in column (1) and (2)

with pooled-OLS regressions. Then we use regressions including regional and time fixed

effects to obtain further results in column (3) and (4). Protection of property rights

substantially reduces corruption as expected, while income inequality is an important source

Page 97: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

   87

of corruption, which also coincides with our prediction. The coefficients are statistically

significant in all four estimations. More importantly, the effect of democracy on corruption is

observed to be significantly modified by property rights protection and income distribution.

Both interaction terms are statistically significant with a negative sign. As to other controls,

income level and education attainment are observed to significantly reduce corruption, which

is in line with prior studies. Also consistent with literature, openness is found to decrease

corruption, while resource abundance is observed to increase corruption.

Table 4-3 Effect of democracy on corruption: fixed effect results

Corruption level (-ICRG)

Pooled OLS Fixed Effects (1) (2) (3) (4)

Democracy 0.034*** 0.031** 0.038*** 0.050*** (0.013) (0.015) (0.014) (0.015) Property rights -0.023*** -0.020*** -0.017*** -0.0072*** (0.0021) (0.0025) (0.0023) (0.0027) Income equality -0.23*** -0.17** -0.23*** -0.18*** (0.065) (0.070) (0.062) (0.063) Democracy* Property rights -0.00095*** -0.00062** -0.00065** -0.0010*** (0.00024) (0.00028) (0.00028) (0.00030) Democracy* Income equality -0.034*** -0.032*** -0.046*** -0.040*** (0.0092) (0.010) (0.012) (0.013) GDP per capita -0.023*** -0.040*** (0.0053) (0.0061) Literacy rate -0.0038*** -0.0024** (0.0012) (0.00099) Resource abundance 0.0012 0.0032*** (0.0013) (0.0011) Openness 0.0019 -0.0043*** (0.0013) (0.0016) Ethnic fractionalization -0.062 -0.26* (0.12) (0.15) Population 0.069*** 0.014 (0.015) (0.018) Constant -1.39*** -1.34*** -2.41*** -2.29*** (0.10) (0.19) (0.15) (0.20)

R-squared 0.50 0.54 0.63 0.66 Observations 1232 1089 1232 1089

Notes: Robust standard errors in parentheses, ***, ** and * denote significance at 1%, 5% and 10% respectively.

As a further robustness test, we rerun the regressions in Table 4-4 with an alternative

measure of democracy, namely the Political Rights Index. Results in Table 4-4 generally

support those in Table 4-3, only the interaction term between democracy and income equality

in Table 4-4 loses statistical significance in the fixed-effect regressions showing, however,

the expected sign. Moreover, the results for the control variables remain robust.

Page 98: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

   88

Table 4-4 Effect of democracy on corruption: alternative measure of democracy Corruption level (-ICRG)

Pooled OLS Fixed Effects (1) (2) (3) (4)

Democracy 0.11*** 0.10** 0.055 0.14*** (0.038) (0.048) (0.041) (0.051) Property rights -0.038*** -0.030*** -0.027*** -0.024*** (0.0024) (0.0033) (0.0030) (0.0032) Income equality -0.50*** -0.44*** -0.28 -0.38** (0.11) (0.12) (0.17) (0.18) Democracy* Property rights -0.0036*** -0.0028*** -0.0021*** -0.0039*** (0.00070) (0.00088) (0.00081) (0.00092) Democracy* Income equality -0.064** -0.058* -0.018 -0.046 (0.028) (0.031) (0.037) (0.040) GDP per capita -0.022*** -0.037*** (0.0044) (0.0051) Literacy rate -0.0034*** -0.0024*** (0.0012) (0.00093) Resource abundance 0.0011 0.0031*** (0.0013) (0.0011) Openness 0.0012 -0.0046*** (0.0011) (0.0012) Ethnic fractionalization -0.083 -0.26* (0.11) (0.14) Population 0.059*** 0.016 (0.015) (0.017) Constant -0.95*** -0.91*** -2.17*** -1.68*** (0.15) (0.23) (0.22) (0.26)

R-squared 0.52 0.55 0.63 0.67 Observations 1269 1119 1269 1119

Notes: Robust standard errors in parentheses, ***, ** and * denote significance at 1%, 5% and 10% respectively.

The previous regressions do not necessarily identify the causal effect of democracy on

corruption since both democracy and corruption might be influenced by an omitted time-

varying factor. We therefore introduce IV regressions to deal with potential endogeneity

problems. As discussed before, we utilize the Muslim dummy to instrument democracy in our

2SLS regressions. The results obtained in Table 4-5 generally support our prior results. The

interaction term between democracy and property rights protection remains statistically

significant reporting the same sign. However, the product of democracy and income equality

loses its statistical significance while retaining its expected sign. This result reflects the fact

that the interaction between democracy and income equality is a bit weaker than the one

between democracy and property rights protection, as our theoretical model reveals.

In general, the effect of democracy on corruption remains conditional on the protection

level of property rights and on the income distribution in IV regressions. The overall effect of

democracy on corruption stays positive in countries with insecure property rights and unequal

income distribution, while it turns negative in countries with secure property rights and equal

Page 99: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

   89

income distribution. Control variables in IV regressions also have similar signs and

significances to those in the previous regressions.

Table 4-5 Effect of democracy on corruption: IV results Corruption level (-ICRG) (1) (2) (3) (4)

Democracy 0.13*** 0.090** (Polity IV) (0.040) (0.044) Democracy 0.30*** 0.19* (Political Rights Index) (0.099) (0.11) Property rights -0.0031 -0.000097 -0.052*** -0.032*** (0.0044) (0.0048) (0.0068) (0.0075) Income equality -0.20** -0.19** -0.039 -0.23 (0.087) (0.088) (0.26) (0.22) Democracy* Property rights -0.0036*** -0.0026*** (Polity IV) (0.00085) (0.00092) Democracy* Income equality -0.0089 -0.011 (Polity IV) (0.020) (0.020) Democracy* Property rights -0.0098*** -0.0063*** (Political Rights Index) (0.0019) (0.0021) Democracy* Income equality 0.029 -0.016 (Political Rights Index) (0.062) (0.057) GDP per capita -0.031*** -0.029*** (0.0061) (0.0051) Literacy rate -0.0023* -0.0025** (0.0013) (0.0010) Resource abundance 0.00073 0.00041 (0.0012) (0.0013) Openness -0.0045** -0.0038** (0.0020) (0.0015) Ethnic fractionalization -0.28** -0.19** (0.11) (0.097) Population 0.057*** 0.048*** (0.017) (0.016) Constant -2.72*** -2.47*** -1.22*** -1.55*** (0.22) (0.24) (0.41) (0.48)

First stage regressions

F test of excluded IVs

Democracy 102.77[0.00] 65.92[0.00] 142.89[0.00] 108.21[0.00] Democracy* Property rights 157.27[0.00] 80.25[0.00] 284.95[0.00] 165.40[0.00] Democracy* Income equality 183.99[0.00] 162.47[0.00] 324.67[0.00] 280.51[0.00]

Anderson canon. corr. LM statistic 97.62[0.00] 84.79[0.00] 116.78[0.00] 100.36[0.00]

R-squared 0.52 0.60 0.56 0.63 Observations 1232 1089 1269 1119

Notes: Robust standard errors in parentheses, p-value in brackets, ***, ** and * denote significance at 1%, 5% and 10% respectively.

IV regressions can be justified only if the instrumental variable is valid. We therefore

need to check the validity of our instrument. On the bottom of Table 4-5 we can see that the

Muslim dummy satisfies the relevance condition. We then run original regressions explicitly

including the Muslim dummy. We find that the coefficient of the Muslim dummy is small

and statistically insignificant in Table 4-7 in the Appendix. This suggests that the Muslim

Page 100: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

   90

dummy satisfies the exogeneity condition: it influences corruption only through the channel

of democracy. The validity of our instrumental variable is thus confirmed.

In all regressions above, economic development significantly depresses corruption, which

is consistent with our theoretical prediction and previous empirical results. We are not

specifically concerned with the potential simultaneity between corruption and economic

development because Treisman (2000) and Gundlach and Paldam (2009) have documented

with the IV approach that the causality in the cross-country analysis is generally from

economic development to corruption. As for the effects of other controls in our regressions,

education attainment and trade openness significantly and robustly decrease corruption as

contended in prior literature, while resource abundance and country size (population) appear

to increase corruption, which is also in line with earlier research. Ethnic diversity, however,

counter- intuitively reduces corruption in our regressions. Treisman (2000) has observed that

the originally positive effect of ethnic division on corruption becomes negative and

insignificant when controlling for economic development in cross-country regressions. His

interpretation that ethnic diversity only influences corruption indirectly by reducing

development seems irrelevant to our negative and significant results. Our theoretical model,

however, provides us with a plausible explanation. There is always at least one ethnic group

dominant in politics in an ethnically divided country. The pivotal voter in this kind of country

therefore belongs to the dominant ethnic group(s). In practice, these ethnic groups are often

richer than others due to the power in their hands. Ceteris paribus, the pivotal voter in an

ethnically divided country, according to our model, will choose a relatively low tax rate since

he is comparatively rich. This country then will have a low corruption level according to our

mechanism. In other words the seemingly counterfactual effect of ethnic division in our

regressions actually provides a substantial support to our theoretical modeling.

To show the overall effect of democracy on corruption, we calculate the marginal effect

of democracy on corruption. In our specification, the marginal effect of democracy can be

expressed as

4 18

where , , and are corruption, democracy, property rights protection and income

distribution indicators of country in period t respectively, while , and

are the coefficients of democracy, the interaction term between democracy and

property rights protection, and the interaction term between democracy and income equality.

Page 101: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

   91

The average marginal effects of democracy computed from regressions with prior

specification have been listed in Table 4-6. We find that the overall effect of democracy on

corruption is significantly negative. This supports the notion that democracy reduces

corruption. However, we also observe in Table 4-6 that both marginal effects of democracy

in IV regressions are, though not by much, obviously smaller than those in fixed-effect

regressions. The most plausible explanation for this is that there might be an unobserved

time-variant variable causing: , 0 ( is the error term in equation 4-16).

Fixed effects estimators hence are biased upwards. If this is the case, we can treat our fixed

effects results as upper bounds of the causal effect of democracy on corruption as Acemoglu

et al. (2008) suggest.

Table 4-6 Marginal effect of democracy on corruption

Democracy Measures Polity IV Index Political Rights Index FE IV FE IV Marginal Effects -0.021*** -0.053*** -0.083*** -0.15*** (0.0080) (0.013) (0.023) (0.037) Observations 1089 1089 1119 1119

Notes: Standard errors in parentheses, ***, ** and * denote significance at 1%, 5% and 10% respectively.

More importantly, with marginal effects in Table 4-6 we can reinterpret previous

empirical research from a new angle. Most previous studies adopt the linear-additive model

without interaction terms to study the relationship between democracy and corruption. The

coefficient on democracy in their linear-additive models actually represents the (weighted)

average marginal effect of democracy in our interaction model (Brambor et al. 2006). The

results obtained in Table 4-6 hence are consistent with most previous empirical papers which

support a negative linear effect of democracy on corruption. Our results also show that

corruption is, in fact, a nonlinear function of several variables including democracy, property

rights and income inequality. As in Sung (2004) and Rock (2009), higher degree terms of

democracy such as the quadratic or cubic term in regression can partially reflect the actual

nonlinear relationship between democracy and corruption and hence might be significant in

some cases though this kind of polynomial approximation is not very appropriate. In

summary, without considering the interactions between democracy, property rights protection

and income distribution, previous studies only partially capture the actual effect of

democracy on corruption.

Page 102: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

   92

4.4 Conclusion

Democracy is believed to have many beneficial effects on countries. However, does it

prevent corruption? Rose-Ackerman (1999, p. 142) stresses: “Democratic elections are not

invariably a cure for corruption. Instead, some electoral systems are more vulnerable to

special influence than others. When narrow groups wield power, some use legal means, and

others are corrupt”. Previous literature provides mixed evidence, which still leaves the

problem open. In this study we find strong evidence that the effect of democracy on

corruption depends upon other variables such as property rights or income inequality. In

particular, we provide a theoretical and empirical investigation of the causal nexus between

democracy and corruption. The theoretical model offers a mechanism via which democracy

influences corruption. It extends previous models implementing property rights and income

distribution into the theoretical framework. Our empirical results are consistent with the

theoretical model. The effect of democracy on corruption is conditional on income

distribution and property rights protection. The findings indicate that democracy is able to

work better as a control of corruption if the property right system works and if there is a low

level of income inequality. On the other hand if property rights are not secured and there is

strong income inequality, democracy may even lead to an increase of corruption.

Page 103: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

   93

Appendix

Table 4-7 Validity of instrument: Muslim Corruption level (-ICRG)

(1) (2)

Democracy 0.030**

(Polity IV) (0.014)

Democracy 0.11**

(Political Rights Index) (0.044)

Property rights -0.0098*** -0.025***

(0.0025) (0.0030)

Income equality -0.18*** -0.38***

(0.063) (0.10)

Democracy* Property rights -0.00084***

(Polity IV) (0.00027)

Democracy* Income equality -0.028***

(Polity IV) (0.0090)

Democracy* Property rights -0.0039***

(Political Rights Index) (0.00082)

Democracy* Income equality -0.046*

(Political Rights Index) (0.027)

GDP per capita -0.037*** -0.032***

(0.0052) (0.0042)

Literacy rate -0.0027*** -0.0027***

(0.0010) (0.00095)

Resource abundance 0.00043 0.00024

(0.0011) (0.0011)

Openness -0.0023* -0.0025**

(0.0013) (0.0011)

Ethnic fractionalization -0.16 -0.17*

(0.10) (0.096)

Population 0.062*** 0.052***

(0.014) (0.013)

Muslim dummy 0.094 0.041

(0.065) (0.060)

Constant -2.23*** -1.80***

(0.21) (0.23)

R-squared 0.62 0.63

Observations 1089 1119

Notes: Robust standard errors in parentheses, ***, ** and * denote significance at 1%, 5% and 10% respectively.

Page 104: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

   94

Chapter Five Social interaction and Corruption: Cross-country Evidence52

 

5.1 Introduction

Corruption is seen by many as one of the main impediments of the development of an

efficient government system. Corruption can be seen as a “symptom that something has gone

wrong in the management of the state” (Rose-Ackerman 1999, p. 9). It is a phenomenon that

is apparent throughout human history. For example, pharaohs in Ancient Egypt provided high

salaries to the tax collectors (called scribes) to increase the opportunity costs of enriching

themselves by cheating taxpayers (Adam 1993). According to Jain (2001), existence of

corruption requires three preconditions: discretionary power related to regulations (see also

Rose-Ackerman 1978), economic rents linked to the power and sufficiently low punishment.

The growing interest in institutional issues such as the transformation process of socialist

economies has led to an increase in the number of studies devoted to exploring the detailed

causes of corruption at the international level. Research has shown that a political economic

approach stressing the importance of institutions has proved to be a powerful tool in

understanding corruption (Bardhan 1997, Rose-Ackerman 1997, Abed and Gupta 2002). For

example, Kunicova and Rose-Ackerman (2005) found that electoral rules and constitutional

structures substantially affect the corruption level. Countries tend to achieve an equilibrium

position that is driven by the balance of political forces and institutions (Bird, Martinez-

Vazquez and Torgler 2006, 2008). However, most of these studies explore corruption at the

macro level while only a limited number of studies have investigated the determinants of

corruption at the individual level (see, e.g., Mocan 2008, Swamy et al. 2001, Torgler and

Valev 2006, Dong and Torgler 2009). Among the individual studies, Gordon (2009)

intriguingly observed partisan bias in federal public corruption prosecutions in America

which influences the punishment for corruption. Such studies mainly take into account the

vertical interrelationship between citizen and the state. Our study, on the other hand,

implements a horizontal perspective using a behavioral economics approach hypothesizing

that social interactions matter. In particular we stress that the own willingness be corrupt

depends on the corruption level of other individuals in a society and that current corruption is

affected by the past corruption levels. In other words, we are going to explore whether

conditional corruption matters and whether corruption is contagious. The willingness to be

                                                            52 This chapter has been submitted to the American Political Science Review. 

Page 105: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

   95

corrupt is influenced by the perceived activities of peers and other individuals. Thus, a

person’s willingness to be corrupt depends on the pro-social behavior of other citizens. The

more that others are perceived to be corrupt, the higher the willingness to be corrupt. The

study therefore emphasizes the relevance of social context in understanding corruption.

Theories of contagion or pro-social behavior, which take the impact of behavior or the

preferences of others into account, are used as a starting point in the theoretical approach.

Contagion effects have been observed in other illegal activities such as assassinations,

hijackings, kidnappings, and serial murders as referred to by Bikhchandi, Hirshleifer and

Welch (1998). The relevance of social interaction and crime is explored by Glaeser,

Sacerdote and Scheinkman (1996) who focus on the United States in their analysis both

across cities and across precincts in New York. The results indicate that social interaction

models provide a framework for understanding variances of cross-city crime rates.

Individuals are more likely to commit crimes when those around them do. Frey and Torgler

(2007) have found empirical evidence of conditional cooperation in the area of tax

compliance. Kahan (1998) suggests that the decision to commit crimes is highly

interdependent, based on the perceived behavior of others: “When they perceive that many of

their peers are committing crimes, individuals infer that the odds of escaping punishment are

high and the stigma of criminality is low. To the extent that many persons simultaneously

draw these inferences and act on them, moreover, their perceptions become a self-fulfilling

reality” (p. 394). As a consequence, individuals’ beliefs about crime is altered, suggesting

that social influence affects criminality and the propensity to commit crimes.

Figure 5-1 illustrates our argument: the higher the levels of perceived corruption in a

society, the more citizens see it as justified. We first provide a simple theoretical explanation

of this observation and then check whether a more thorough study of the data supports the

initial evidence suggested by the figure.

To our knowledge, our study provides findings not yet discussed in the corruption

literature. There are not many studies that investigate the relevance of conditional

cooperation and a contagion effect in regards to corruption. We use the notion of “conditional

corruption” for these effects. In particular, there is a lack of empirical evidence at the

international level. The chapter also complements a large set of laboratory experimental

studies that have studied conditional cooperation by providing evidence outside of a lab

setting. We will first conduct a micro analysis using data from two wide-ranging surveys,

namely the European Values Survey and the World Values Survey. Despite the increasing

interest of economists in the determinants of corruption, research at the micro level has not

Page 106: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

   96

yet come under intense empirical investigation. The micro analysis is complemented by a

macro analysis working with a large international data set that covers almost 20 years. Before

considering these findings in detail, however, Section 5.2 presents a theoretical model.

Section 5.3 introduces the empirical part discussing the data and Section 5.4 provides the

empirical findings. Section 5.5 finishes with some concluding remarks.

Figure 5-1 Correlation between Justifiability of Corruption and Perceived Corruption

Note: Pearson r = - 0.42. More countries than in the regression analysis.

5.2 Theoretical Foundation

In this section, we theoretically investigate conditional cooperation in a corruption

framework. We therefore use the notion of “conditional corruption” instead of conditional

cooperation. Individuals condition their corruption on the behaviour of other individuals. An

individual is prone to be corrupt if there are a sufficient number of corrupt individuals around

him. The reason put forward in the literature is one that can be called reinforcing corruption

Aidt (2003), i.e. the incentive structures of a society together with the presence of corrupt

individuals determines whether corruption is worthwhile for an individual. Either the direct

potential benefits or the direct cost of engaging in corrupt activity are lower if the number of

corrupt people in an individual’s environment or society is larger. Andvig and Moene (1990),

Murphy et al. (1991), Acemoglu (1995) and Sah (2007) stress that the return to corruption for

an individual depends on the number of individuals expected to be corrupt in the same

organisation or society. Sah (1988, 2007) also mentions learning - a corrupt official continues

ARG

ARM

AUS

AZE

BGD

BLR

BIH

BRA

BGR

CHL

HRV

ESTFIN

GEO

IND

LVALTU

MKD

MEXMDA

NGA

NOR

PER

PHL

POL

RUSYUG

SVN

KORESP

CHE

TWNUKR

URYUSA

VEN

DEU

1.5

22

.53

2 2.5 3 3.5perceived corruption (PLC)

95% CI Fitted valuesjustifiability of corruption 0-3, 3=never justified)

Page 107: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

   97

to be corrupt if she has interacted with a sufficient number of corrupt officials in the past as

she knows that looking for bribes will be worthwhile. At the same time the cost to be caught

in a corrupt act are lower because corruption is more difficult to detect in societies where it is

more common (Lui 1986, Cadot 1987). Tirole (1996) assumes that individuals are members

of different groups and also argues with the cost of detection, namely the potential exclusion

from a group. He allows for a society with corrupt and non-corrupt individuals, where the

latter have long term advantages. Group membership acts as a signal. The cost of engaging in

corrupt activities decreases for an individual if more members of that group are corrupt as the

threat of exclusion from the group becomes weaker as group membership loses its function to

signal non-corrupt behavior To summarize, all these theories use pure income maximization

as the motive to engage in corruption. The presence of corrupt individuals in a society,

together with its institutions provides the incentives that determine individuals’ behaviour.

Several theories have been put forward to explain what constitutes conditional

cooperation in the area of behavioural economics. Most papers in the literature (Rabin, 1998

and Falk and Fehr, 2002) explain conditional cooperation in terms of reciprocity. In a

corruption context, reciprocity means, that if corruption within a society is very prevalent,

citizens feel less guilt when engaging in extra-legal activities, and are likely to act

accordingly. Several laboratory experimental studies (mainly public good experiments)

provide evidence on pro-social behaviour (for an overview, see Gächter, 2006). For example,

Fischbacher, Gächter and Fehr (2001) find that 50 percent of the subjects were conditionally

cooperative. Falk, Fischbacher and Gächter (2003) create a laboratory situation in which each

subject is a member of two economically identical groups, where only the group members are

different. They observe that the same subjects contribute different amounts, depending on the

behavior of the group. Contributions are larger when group cooperation is higher.

Alternatively, the concept of conformity (Henrich, 2004) has been used to explain conditional

cooperation. Conformity means that the motivation of behaving in a conditionally

cooperative way may be influenced by the people’s wish to fulfill the social norm of not

being corrupt and behaving according to society’s rules. While several early studies provide

evidence of conditional cooperation within a laboratory setting, an increasing number of

studies have been conducted to check the validity of such studies outside of a laboratory

setting using, for example, field experiments (see Frey and Meier, 2004a; 2004b; Heldt, 2005;

Shang and Croson, 2005, Martin and Randal 2005). The study of a contagion effect and pro-

social behavior resulting from a perceived level of corruption is an area that has largely been

Page 108: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

   98

ignored in the empirically oriented corruption literature, despite its potential to affect the

level of corruption even further.

5.2.1 Background of the Model

While the existing theoretical literature concentrates on the direct costs and benefits of

engaging in corrupt activities, we want to introduce moral costs that affect the decision to

engage in corruption. We assume that these moral costs are independent of the number of

corrupt individuals. Even under this assumption one can show that the decision to engage in

corruption depends on the attitudes of possible partners in corruption. This is what we refer to

as conditional corruption.

Since Akerlof (1980) emphasized the persistent effect of social norms on human

behaviour, interesting approaches based on the concept social norms have been developed

that help explain conditional cooperation in human activities. One way to accommodate such

behaviour is to allow for a guilt disutility if a citizen engages in an activity that is

contradicting social norms. The social customs literature provides a motive for the reason

why there can be a utility loss by the act of evading taxes (see Naylor 1989). The essence of

this approach is that violation of social norms will bring forth moral cost. In a tax compliance

framework, Gordon (1989) modifies the standard economics of crime model by including

non-pecuniary costs of evasion. Non-pecuniary or psychic cost increases as evasion increases.

The model he developed can explain why some taxpayers refuse a favorable evasion gamble.

Furthermore, dishonesty is endogenized as reputation cost. Non-pecuniary costs have a

dynamic component, varying inversely with the number of individuals having evaded in the

previous period. Other researchers such as Myles and Naylor (1996) criticize this approach,

stating that the level of evasion or non-compliance is irrelevant. Once a social custom is

broken, all utility from it is lost. In line with this argument we will also assume that once a

person breaks the social norm, the fact of doing so is what counts, not the magnitude of the

transgression. We assume in our model that incorruption is regarded as a prevailing norm in

societies (consistent with long-held moral standards), while corruption violates this social

norm. Corruption and therefore the violation of this social norm generate guilt or shame

(Elster 1989). The sentiments of guilt and shame may influence compliance behavior,

reducing the perceived benefits of corruption. According to Lewis (1982), guilt arises when

individuals realize that they have acted irresponsibly and in violation of an internalized rule

or social norm. Since incorruption is an accepted social norm, it makes sense that individuals

who choose to be corrupt feel guilty or ashamed. According to Spichtig and Traxler (2007),

Page 109: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

   99

this internal sanction against violation will be more powerful if more individuals stick to the

norm. In our case this means that when corruption is rare in a society, individuals tend to be

incorrupt since the cost of violating social norm is very high. When corruption becomes more

prevalent, more individuals become corrupt since the cost to infringe the norm declines.

Rege (2004) stresses that a social norm for cooperation can generate conditional

cooperative behaviour since the sanction for a norm deviation will force people to stick to the

norm. Andvig and Moene (1990) also incorporate moral cost associated with social norms

into traditional cost-benefit analysis developed by Becker (1976), deducing multiple self-

fulfilling equilibria. The authors stress that the probability of corruption is related to its

established frequency. On the other hand, Mishra’s (2006) model uses an evolutionary game

framework deriving multiple evolutionary stable states in corruption level. However, many

previous corruption models have the limitation that they only consider the behavioral

implications in regards to bureaucrats instead of focusing on the entire society53. Both parties,

bureaucrats and citizens, are players in the corruption game. Only analysing the behaviour of

one side is not enough to explain any phenomenon related to corruption, especially in our

context that focuses on conditional corruption.

Social norms consist of a pattern of behaviour that must be shared by other people and

sustained by their approval and disapproval (Elster 1989). Coleman (1990) stresses that social

norms are rules of conduct enforced by external or internal sanction. Polinsky and Shavell

(2000), who present a survey of the economic theory of public enforcement of law,

emphasize the aspect of social norms for future research. Social norms can be seen as a

general alternative to law enforcement in channeling individuals’ behavior. The violation of

social norms has consequences like internal sanctions (guilt, remorse) or external legal and

social sanctions as gossip and ostracism. As Polinsky and Shavel (2000) state there is an

expanding literature on social norms because of the influence social norms have on behavior,

their role as a substitute for and supplement to formal laws and the possibility that laws

themselves can influence social norms54. Fehr and Gächter (1997) define social norm as:

“behaviour regularity that is based on a socially shared belief how one ought to behave which

triggers the enforcement of the prescribed behaviour by informal social sanctions” (p. 12).

                                                            53 Mauro (2004) employed two models to analyze the behavior of bureaucrats and citizens respectively. His results, however, are not convincible since he did not investigate behavior of both sides simultaneously. 54 Posner (1997, pp. 365-366) looks at the incentives for obeying norms. He finds four: (i) norms that are self-enforcing because obedience confers private benefits, (ii) norms that are enforced by emotions, iii) milder sanctions by expressions of disapproval or ridicule and (iv) internalized norms, out of a sense of guilt or shame. 

Page 110: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

   100

5.2.2 A Simple Game

We consider a simple model of corruption. A citizen C (he) can attempt to bribe bureaucrat B

(she) to earn an extra-legal profit . C and B have utility functions depending on (expected)

income and the potential disutility if they engage in corruption. Let R be the income from any

type of activity and c an index that is equal to 1 if this activity involves corruption (0

otherwise) and the disutility felt when engaged in corruption. The utility function is then

given as:

U(R,c) = R - c

We concentrate on a citizen’s decision whether to engage in projects that involve corruption.

Such projects generate an additional profit of over the best non-corrupt project. This could

be, for example, a project that would have not received a public license according to the law

or it may extend a project past the limits set by the law, or it may simply speed up the normal

process. In all cases the gain represents an additional profit over the profit earned under

normal proceedings. If this activity does not take place, all parties involved in a potential

corruptive activity receive a default payoff that is normalized to 0. For simplicity of

presentation, we assume that B accepts the bribe if indifferent and C bribes if indifferent.

Bribing and accepting a bribe incurs a cost of c for C and b for B. These costs represent

guilt felt when engaging in bribing. Thus a low value of represents a high tendency to be

corrupt. Before the game starts is drawn from a distribution function F and C and B draw a

value of c, b; we denote by c, b respectively the random variables and assume that both

are distributed independently according to an identical distribution function G. We assume

that when interacting, C knows B’s guilt parameter, i.e. at least b is common knowledge

between the two players. The timing of the game is as follows: 1. Nature draws , c,b; 2. C

decides whether to attempt a bribe or not and if he bribes he chooses an amount b; 3. B

decides whether to accept the bribe. Figure 5-2 summarizes the description of this game.

It has a unique sub-game perfect Nash-Equilibrium in pure strategies: B accepts all bribes

with b b. C bribes B if c+b paying a bribe of b=b as this bribe is accepted by B; if

< c+b then C does not bribe.

Page 111: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

   101

Figure 5-2 Description of the Corruption Game

Given the equilibrium the conditional probability for C to engage in corruption depends

on his guilt parameter and the expected value of the guilt parameter of a bureaucrat, he may

interact with: Pr(c+bc). This probability is decreasing in E(b). If we believe that

people tend to justify their behaviour then this conditional probability will determine how

justifiable C would judge participation in corruption or bribery. Corruption is less justifiable

for C the higher c and the higher E(b). In this respect we observe conditional corruption – a

low guilt cost in a society will induce even citizens with relatively high guilt cost to engage in

corrupt activities. In the empirical section we use a large survey data set to explore this

justifiability of corruption.

Hypothesis 1: Citizens find corruption less justifiable if they perceive their society less

corrupt.

We intentionally did not discuss . In the present model is exogenous. It may depend

on the opportunities that open up only by bribery, hence a society with better institutions

should allow most beneficial activities without bribes, hence may be lower, while a society

with weak institutions would have higher as profitable activities are accessible only when

one bribes bureaucrats.

Note, this model’s innovation is to emphasize the importance of guilt that people

experience engaging in corrupt activities, arguing that guilt levels depend on the perceived

prevalence of corruption within a society. From a modelling perspective the model is similar

to a model where c and b represent expected costs of giving and receiving bribes, for

example because ex post investigations can reveal bribes as well as attempted bribes. We do

believe that guilt has indeed a similar effect as an expected monetary punishment (with low

Citizen 

 Bureaucrat 

Bribe

Do not bribe

Reject  Accept

(0‐c, 0)        (‐b‐c, b‐b) 

(0, 0)

b

c, b, 

Nature 

Page 112: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

   102

probabilities of detection) may have. The important difference is that this guilt parameters

can and will vary across different people and that an individual’s expectation to find person

with a high propensity to engage in corruption will determine how active this individual will

become in looking for opportunities to corrupt.

5.2.3 Dynamics

The second issue we address is the question how a tendency towards corrupt or non-corrupt

behaviour. To do so we assume a simple overlapping generation model with a constant

population model. We denote by an upper index t a generation’s respective values. Each

generation has one offspring and this offspring’s guilt parameter t+1 decreases if the parent

was involved in an act of corruption and it increases if the parent was not involved in an act

of corruption. We assume that on average the absolute change in the parameter in both

directions is of the same magnitude. If this is the case then if more (less) than half of the

population is involved in corruption the median and the average increases (decreases) with

the next generation:

Pr(2t) 1/2 0.5t+1 0.5

t and E(t+1) E(t).

Hypothesis 2 Corruption is contagious: A society experiencing a high (low) level of

corruption will have increased (decreased) levels of corruption in the future.

Again, the arguments with respect to hold, a higher - which may be due to weak

institutions – will increase the spread of corruption over time. Strong institutions that allow

all profitable activities to be undertaken legally will decrease corruption and hence over time

will increase the guilt felt by citizens if they engage in corruption.

5.2.4 Conditional Corruption – Discussion and Extensions

The conditionality of corruption in our model comes from the fact that low guilt costs in

society make it more likely that a citizen engages in corruption. The proposed dynamics

imply that this leads to lower guilt costs within a society.

An alternative model giving rise to similar hypotheses is one where the individual’s guilt

cost depends on the frequency of corruption within a society. In this case =f(Pr(2E())

with f’(.)<0. In this case an equilibrium can be defined as a fixed-point of this function and,

depending on the explicit assumption on the distribution function, could give rise to two or

more equilibria where some are characterized by self-confirming on average high values of

and others by self-confirming low values of . Spichtig and Traxler (2007) provide a model

for conditional cooperation in this spirit.

Page 113: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

   103

5.3 Data and Methodological Approach

5.3.1 Micro Analysis

In the first stage we are going to work with survey data at the micro level to explore our first

hypothesis. This allows us to work with a representative set of individuals, which is not often

the case in previous (experimental) studies that have explored conditional cooperation

primarily by using students as participants55. We are going to use two micro data sets. First

we are going to work with the European Values Survey (EVS) 1999/2000, which is a

European-wide investigation of socio-cultural and political change. Next, we are going to

explore the World Values Survey (WVS), a worldwide data set that investigates socio-

cultural and political change. The WVS was first carried out in 1981-83, with subsequent

surveys being carried out in 1990-1993, 1995-1997 and 1999-2001.

5.3.1.1 European Values Survey

The EVS assesses the basic values and beliefs of people throughout Europe. The EVS

was first carried out from 1981 to 1983, then in 1990 to 1991 and again in 1999 through 2001,

with an increasing number of countries participating over time. The EVS methodological

approach is explained in detail in the European Values Survey (1999) source book, which

provides information on response rates, the stages of sampling procedures, the translation of

the questionnaire, and field work, along with measures of coding reliability, and data checks.

All country surveys were carried out by experienced professional survey organizations, (with

the exception of the one in Greece), and were performed through face-to-face interviews

among samples of adult citizens aged 18 years and older. Tilburg University coordinated the

project and provided the guidelines to guarantee the use of standardized information in the

surveys and the national representativeness of the data. To avoid framing biases, the

questions were asked in the prescribed order. The response rate varies from one country to

another; in general, the average response rate was around 60%.

Because the EVS asks an identical set of questions to people in various European

countries, the survey provides a unique opportunity to examine whether conditional

corruption matters. Our study considers representative national samples of at least 1000

individuals in each country.

                                                            55 Fehr et al. (2003) report that the problem with using students is that they have a higher level of education and a higher IQ than average citizens. In addition, they often come from families with a higher than average income and their age range is limited.  

Page 114: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

   104

Our dependent variable is justifiability of corruption assessed using the following

question:

Please tell me for each of the following statements whether you think it can always be

justified, never be justified, or something in between: (…) someone accepting a bribe

in the course of their duties (1=always justified, 10= never justified).

The interpretation of this question is that higher values are in line with a lower justifiability

of corruption. This variable can be seen as a proxy for social norms of compliance (see

Torgler 2007). We use the following question to investigate the influence of conditional

corruption:

“According to you, how many of your compatriots do the following: Accepting a

bribe in the course of their duties?” (4=almost all, 1=almost none)

5.3.1.2 World Values Survey

We are going to work with the third WVS wave as the question referring to individual

conditional corruption has only been asked in this wave. For the researchers who conduct and

administer the World Values Survey (WVS) in their respective countries, it is a requirement

that they follow the methodological requirements of the World Values Association. For

example, surveys in the World Values Survey set are generally based on nationally

representative samples of at least 1000 individuals of 18 years and above (although

sometimes people under the age of 18 participate). The samples are selected using probability

random methods, and the questions contained within the surveys generally do not deviate far

from the original official questionnaire (for a sample of a typical World Values Survey see

www.worldvaluessurvey.org). We have not analysed the entire World Value Survey data set:

countries below 750 observations have not been included in the estimations to reduce

possible biases due to a lack of representativeness56. Furthermore, some countries do not have

information on the dependent variables or some of the independent variables. These countries

are therefore not considered.57.

We use the same dependent variable as previously, namely the justifiability of corruption.

On the other hand, we assess the relevance of conditional corruption using an alternative

question that measures perceived corruption:

                                                            56 Thus, Montenegro and the Dominican Republic have been omitted.  57 Japan, South Africa, Puerto Rico, Turkey and Columbia. Moreover, Sweden could not be included as one of the control variables (education) has been coded differently.  

Page 115: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

   105

How widespread do you think bribe taking and corruption is in this country?

Almost no public officials are engaged in it (1)

A few public officials are engaged in it (2)

Most public officials are engaged in it (3)

Almost all public officials are engaged in it (4)

5.3.1.3 Addressing the Limitations of Survey Data

Two main limitations of survey data are often raised: a self-reporting bias and cognitive

biases. We address these issues in turns.

First, the validity of the justifiability of corruption variable can be criticized as it reports a

self-reported and hypothetical choice (see Swamy et al. 2001). It can also be argued that an

individual who has engaged in corruption in the past will tend to cover up such behaviour by

declaring a low justifiability of corruption in the survey. Furthermore, cross cultural

comparisons should be treated with some caution. In countries where corruption is

widespread and delays in transactions are long, additional payments to “speed up” the

process may be justifiable and a normal part of the administration process. The necessity of

additional payments is so pervasive in some countries that the bureaucratic mechanism does

not operate without them (De Soto 1989). However Torgler and Valev (2006), show that

survey data on corruption is highly correlated with other available proxies of corruption

(Transparency International, Kaufmann, Kraay, and Mastruzzi, 2004 (KKM) and ICRG

(Knack, 1999)).

Moreover, one should note that the survey contains no information on the perceived

activities of peers (e.g., friends, work colleagues or neighbours). One can argue that a

reference group has a stronger effect on our behaviour than the overall population.

Another aspect of the self-reporting bias is that cultural differences play a role. To control

for this we extend our study by also adding a country’s overall corruption values into the

micro data set. We use the control of corruption variable developed by KKM due to the large

number of countries included in this data set. The proxy measure is driven by the traditional

notion of corruption namely “the exercise of public power for private gain” covering a

variety of aspects ranging from the frequency of “additional payments to get things done” to

the effects on the business environment (p. 8). The values lie between –2.5 and 2.5, with

higher scores corresponding to a lower level of corruption. Figure 5-3 illustrates our

argument with respect to the self-reporting bias. It shows that justifiability of corruption is

highly correlated with other more frequently used measures of corruption.

Page 116: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

   106

Figure 5-3 Correlation between Justifiability of Corruption and Control of Corruption

Note: Pearson r= 0.38. More countries than in the regression analysis.

Second, Bertrand and Mullainathan (2001) argue that cognitive problems arise – the

experimental literature has shown that manipulations (e.g., order of the question, wording or

scales) can affect how people process and interpret questions. The problem is that

“respondents may make little mental effort in answering the question, such as by not

attempting to recall all the relevant information or by not reading through the whole list of

alternative responses” (Bertrand and Mullainathan, p. 68). To control for such problems, we

explore the correlation between two similar questions asked in the EVS (WVS) in different

parts of the interview: How interested would you say you are in politics? (IP) Very interested

(value 1), somewhat interested (2), not very interested (3), not at all interested). How

important is politics in your life? (INP) Very (1), (rather 2), not very (3), not at all (4). The

correlation at the micro level is 0.614 (0.544). Moreover, we also explore the correlation with

the following question: When you get together with your friends, would you say you discuss

political matters frequently (value 3), occasionally (value 2) or never (value 1)? (DP). The

correlation between INP and DP is 0.45 (0.53) and between IP and DP 0.56 (0.38). Thus, the

variables are highly correlated. Face-to-face interviews may also help to guarantee that

subjects are aware of the whole list of alternative responses. The EVS (WVS) has also the

advantage of being a wide-ranging survey covering a large amount of different topics. Thus,

our corruption question was only part of a larger survey, which may reduce framing biases.

ARG

ARM

AUS

AZE

BGD

BLR

BIH

BRA

BGR

CHL

CHN

HRV

ESTFIN

GEO

IND

LVALTU

MKD

MEXMDA

NGA

NOR

PER

PHL

POL

RUSYUG

SVN

KORESP

CHE

TWNUKR

URY USA

VEN

DEU

1.5

22

.53

-1 0 1 2 3control of corruption (KKM)

95% CI Fitted valuesjustifiability of corruption 0-3, 3=never justified)

Page 117: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

   107

5.3.2 Macro Analysis

To address our second hypothesis, the analysis will be complemented by use of a large

international panel macro data set: the ICRG data (see Knack 1999) covering 18 years (1986

till 2003). We use ICRG as KKM has only been collected for a limited number of years

(1996, 1998, 2000, 2002), and while ICRG allows us to study fewer countries, it provides

panel data for a longer time period. The political risk rating provided by ICRG aims to assess

the political stability of the included countries. The corruption variable is an assessment of

corruption within the political system. The measure is concerned with actual or potential

corruption in the form of excessive patronage, nepotism, job reservations, “favor-for-favors”,

secret party funding, and suspiciously close ties between politics and business. The macro

data set has the great advantage of being able to explore the importance of a contagion effect

over time.

5.4 Results

5.4.1 Micro Level using the EVS

The micro analysis will allow us to explore our first hypothesis. One can argue that the

potential conditional corruption effect could be influenced by other variables that affect

corruption. Thus, we control in our multivariate analysis for variables such as education

level58, political interest59, religion60, risk attitudes61, the economic situation62, urbanization63

                                                            58 EVS: Formal education: At what age did you complete or will you complete your full time education, either at school or at an institution of higher education? Please exclude apprenticeships. WVS: What is the highest educational level that you have attained?

10. No formal education 11. Incomplete primary school 12. Completed primary school 13. Incomplete secondary school: technical/vocational type 14. Complete secondary school: technical/vocational type 15. Incomplete secondary: university-preparatory type 16. Complete secondary: university-preparatory type 17. Some university-level education, without degree 18. University-level education, with degree

59 EVS/WVS: How important is politics in your life? very (4), (rather 3), not very (2), not at all (1). 60 EVS: Apart from weddings, funerals and christenings, how often do you attend religious services these days? More than once a week, once a week, once a month, only on special holy days, once a year, less often, practically never or never(8= more than once a week to 1=practically never or never). WVS: Apart from weddings, funerals, and christenings, about how often do you attend religious services these days? More than once a week, once a week, once a month, only on special holy days, once a year, less often, never or practically never. (7 = more than once a week to 1 = never or practically never). 61 EVS: Here are some aspects of a job that people say are important. Please look at them and tell me which ones you personally think are important in a job? (15 items). Risk aversion: Good job security (1=mentioned).

Page 118: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

   108

and the employment and marital status. Previous tax compliance and corruption studies

demonstrate the relevance of considering these factors (see, e.g., Torgler 2007, Dong and

Torgler 2009).

Table 5-1 presents the first results obtained by working with the European Values Survey.

In the first specification we recode the original dependent variable into a four-point scale (0,

1, 2, 3), with the value 3 standing for “never justified”. Responses 4 through 10 were

combined into a value 0 due to a lack of variance among them. This approach is consistent

with previous studies (see, e.g., Torgler and Valev 2006, Torgler 2007). In the second

specification we use the original 10-point scale. In both cases we are going to use an ordered

probit model. The ordered probit models are relevant in such an analysis insofar as they help

analyze the ranking information of the scaled dependent variable. The data structure indicates

that we have a natural cut-off point. A large amount of respondents assert that corruption is

“never justified” (71 percent of the cases). Our dependent variable therefore takes in the

following specifications: the value 1 if the respondent says that bribing is “never justified”

and 0 otherwise. This requires the use of a probit model in most of the specifications (see also

Table 5-3). We also use weighted (ordered) probit estimations to correct the samples and thus

to get a reflection of the national distribution. Moreover, since equations have a nonlinear

form, only the sign of the coefficient can be directly interpreted and not its size. We therefore

also calculate the marginal effects to find the quantitative effect of a variable on our

                                                                                                                                                                                         WVS: Now I would like to ask you something about the things which would seem to you personally, most important if you were looking a job. Here are some of the things many people take into account in relation to their work. Regardless of whether you’re actually looking for a job, which one would you, personally, place first if you were looking for a job?

5. A good income so that you do not have any worries about money 6. A safe job with no risk of closing down or unemployment 7. Working with people you like 8. Doing an important job which gives you a feeling of accomplishment

And what would be your second choice? A dummy variable was built with the value 1, if someone has chosen 2 as first or as second choice. 62 EVS and WVS: Here is a scale of incomes and we would like to know in what group your household is, counting all wages, salaries, pensions and other incomes that come in. Just give the letter of the group your household falls into, after taxes and other deductions (scale from 1 to 10).. 63 EVS and WVS: Size of town: 1. Under 2,000 2. 2,000 - 5,000 3. 5 - 10,000 4. 10 - 20,000 5. 20 - 50,000 6. 50 - 100,000 7. 100 - 500,000 8. 500,000 and more.

Page 119: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

   109

dependent variable. The marginal effect indicates the change in the share of individuals (or

the probability of) belonging to a specific justifiability level, when the independent variable

increases by one unit64. In all estimations the marginal effects are presented only for the

highest value. Furthermore, it should be noted that answers such as “don’t know” and

missing values have been eliminated in all estimations.

First, we differentiate between Western and Eastern Europe as the reform process in the

transition countries has resulted in disorientation and a heavy economic burden (Kasper and

Streit (1999) and Gërxhani (2002)). The rapid collapse of institutional structures produced a

vacuum in many countries that led to large social costs, especially in terms of worsening

income inequality and poverty rates and bad institutional conditions based on uncertainty and

high transaction costs. Alm, Martinez-Vazquez and Torgler (2006) report that governments

faced difficult policy choices in this new era regarding the role of the public sector in general

and the structure of the tax system in particular. Furthermore, Kornai (1990) and Martinez-

Vazquez and McNab (2000) report that citizens in many transition countries were not used to

paying taxes at the beginning of the transition process. Thus, taxpayers may have reacted

strongly to the tax policy changes necessary for the transition from a centrally controlled

economy to a market economy. Moreover, rather than using a dummy variable to

differentiate between Western and Eastern Europe, we consider also consider country fixed

effects in specification (4).

Table 5-1 shows that the higher is the perceived corruption of other persons, the higher is

the justifiability of corruption. The coefficient is always statistically significant at the 1%

level and the size of the effect is substantial; if perceived corruption rises by one unit, the

percentage of persons reporting that corruption is never justified falls between 3.8 and 5.1

percentage points. Thus, we find support that conditional corruption matters.

                                                            64 Again, it should be noted that higher values are connected to a lower justifiability of corruption.  

Page 120: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

    110

Table 5-1 Influence of conditional corruption (EVS) Dependent Variable: Justifiability Of Corruption (Highest Value = Never Justified)

Coeff Z-Stat. Marg. Coeff. Z-Stat. Marg. Coeff. Z-Stat. Marg. Coeff. Z-Stat. Marg. Coeff. Z-Stat. Marg.

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5)

Models Weighted Ordered Probit (0-3)A

Weighted Ordered Probit (1-10)A

Weighted Probit Weighted Probit Weighted Probit (9,10=1), Else 0

Conditional Corruption Perceived Share Of Compatriots Accepting A Bribe (SAB)

-0.13*** -8.61 -0.046 -0.14*** -9.29 -0.049 -0.110*** -6.85 -0.038 -0.151*** -8.79 -0.051 -0.184*** -9.62 -0.045

Formal And Informal Education Formal 0.006*** 3.07 0.002 0.007*** 3.24 0.002 0.006*** 2.95 0.002 0.004* 1.67 0.001 0.008*** 2.77 0.002 Political Interest 0.063*** 5.11 0.022 0.061*** 5.07 0.021 0.050*** 3.95 0.017 0.045*** 3.38 0.015 0.075*** 4.92 0.018 Demographic Factors Age 30-39 0.20*** 5.85 0.066 0.19*** 5.87 0.065 0.20*** 5.55 0.066 0.22*** 5.99 0.073 0.24*** 5.84 0.053 Age 40-49 0.30*** 8.16 0.098 0.29*** 8.01 0.095 0.30*** 7.78 0.098 0.36*** 8.83 0.11 0.36*** 8.16 0.078 Age 50-59 0.34*** 8.49 0.11 0.34*** 8.56 0.11 0.34*** 8.17 0.11 0.43*** 9.79 0.13 0.43*** 8.84 0.088 Age 60-69 0.50*** 11.9 0.15 0.50*** 11.76 0.15 0.50*** 11.22 0.15 0.61*** 13.17 0.18 0.60*** 11.90 0.12 Age 70+ 0.59*** 11.37 0.17 0.57*** 11.04 0.17 0.57*** 10.43 0.17 0.71*** 12.64 0.19 0.75*** 11.59 0.13 Female 0.13*** 5.99 0.046 0.13*** 6.15 0.046 0.14*** 6.01 0.048 0.16*** 6.82 0.055 0.15*** 5.48 0.035 Marital Status Married 0.13*** 4.09 0.044 0.13*** 4.2 0.045 0.15*** 4.43 0.051 0.12*** 3.51 0.041 0.097*** 2.60 0.024 Widowed 0.15*** 2.78 0.049 0.15*** 2.84 0.049 0.16*** 2.8 0.052 0.11* 1.83 0.035 0.11* 1.79 0.026 Divorced 0.024 0.52 0.008 0.018 0.39 0.006 0.049 1.01 0.017 0.036 0.73 0.012 0.015 0.27 0.004 Separated 0.0002 0 0.0001 -0.052 -0.52 -0.018 0.066 0.67 0.022 0.001 0.01 0 -0.11 -1.00 -0.027 Employment Status Selfemployed 0.031 0.69 0.01 0.032 0.75 0.011 0.036 0.77 0.012 -0.12** -2.51 -0.043 -0.12** -2.13 -0.030 Risk Attitudes Risk Averse 0.24*** 10.56 0.083 0.23*** 10.61 0.081 0.24*** 10.12 0.084 0.090*** 3.58 0.031 0.069** 2.49 0.017 Urbanization Urbanization -0.009** -2.09 -0.003 -0.008* -1.91 -0.003 -0.010** -2.06 -0.003 -0.009* -1.74 -0.003 -0.009* -1.69 -0.002 Religiosity Church Attendance 0.042*** 9.45 0.015 0.042*** 9.54 0.014 0.041*** 8.7 0.014 0.013** 2.48 0.005 0.024*** 3.94 0.006 Geographic Region Western Europe 0.17*** 7.49 0.058 0.17*** 7.82 0.059 0.16*** 6.83 0.056 Country Fixed Effects NO NO NO YES YES

Pseudo R2 0.036 0.031 0.047 0.099 0.11 Number Of Observations 18168 18168 18168 18168 18168 Prob > Chi2 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00

Notes: The reference group consists of Age<30, Man, Single/Living Together, Other Employment Status. ***, ** and * denote significance at 1%, 5% and 10%, respectively. a marginal effects for the highest value reported (never justified). Robust standard errors.

Page 121: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

111  

Looking at the other variables we find support for results from previous studies in the

literature. In line with Dong and Torgler (2009) we observe that political interest is

negatively correlated with the justifiability of corruption. An increase in the political interest

scale by one unit increases the probability of stating that taking bribes is never justified by

around 1.5 percentage points. There is also a positive correlation between education and the

social norm of compliance. However, the effect is less strong (see, e.g., specification (4)).

Moreover, we also observe that older people and women exhibit a higher willingness to

comply. These results support previous findings that explored in detail a potential age65 and

gender effect66. Married and widowed people report the lowest justifiability of corruption.

The coefficients are statistically significant in relation to the control group (singles). On, the

other hand, we do not observe that the employment status matters. However, religion is

correlated with corruption. The church as an institution induces behavioural norms and moral

constraints among their community (Torgler 2006). Religiosity seems to affect the degree of

rule breaking. Religiosity can thus be a restriction on engaging in corrupt activities.

Interestingly, we also observe that risk aversion matters. Risk averse people are less likely to

justify corruption which is consistent with suggestions in the compliance literature that risk

aversion reduces the incentive to act illegally. In our model it can be explained by

introducing risk aversion and some uncertainty of C with respect to b. Controlling for risk

attitudes allows for better insights regarding the variables of age, gender, or economic

situation. For example, it could be argued that the obtained difference between women and

men or between different age groups is influenced by different risk attitudes functions.

Hartog et al. (2002), e.g., conducted an empirical survey analysis and found that an increase

in income reduces risk aversion. The estimated coefficient for the Western Europe dummy

suggests that the institutional crisis in many transition countries in Eastern Europe after the

collapse of communism tended to have a positive effect on citizens’ justifiability of

corruption. The marginal effects indicate that being a citizen of a Western European country

rather than an Eastern European country increases the probability of responding that

corruption is never justified by more than 5 percentage points. Finally, we also explore

                                                            65 For example, Torgler and Valev (2006) investigate the willingness of being corrupt of the same cohorts over time (age effect) as well as and the same age groups in different time periods (cohort effect). All in all they observe a consistent age effect. On the other hand, a cohort effect is less obvious. 66 Torgler and Valev (2007) explored whether gender matters and whether a decrease of gender differences with greater equality of status and better opportunities affects their willingness to comply. They find evidence for strong gender differences. Women are significantly less likely to agree that corruption and cheating on taxes can

Page 122: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

   112

whether urbanization matters. It has been argued that corruption may be higher in larger cities

due to the fact that the scale of economic activities is larger and more varied in scope

resulting in a higher level of government contacts. Moreover, government officials may be

less personal compared to those in smaller cities which may reduce the opportunity costs of

bribing (Mocan 2008). Table 5-1 shows that the coefficient is statistically significant at the 5

or 10% percent level with a marginal effect of 0.3 percentage points. Thus, this relationship

cannot be rejected although it should be noted that the effect is smaller in relation to other

factors.

In the last specification in Table 5-1 we go beyond the original probit model (1=never

justified) as the answer to the question might be biased by experimenter demand. It is

obvious that the “socially correct” answer would be “never justified”. Such a concern arises if

a large number people who think that bribing is justified were to instead claim that bribing is

never justified. Thus, in other words, if the respondent wants to give the “socially acceptable”

answer he would say “1” and if not he would answer truthfully. In this latter case, an answer

of “0” might be indicative of a much higher social norm than an answer of “1”. In this case

we would have a problem that respondents want to avoid looking bad in front of the

interviewer (Bertrand and Mullainathan 2001). It would also indicate that we would observe

systematic biases rather than just random errors. We therefore try a different cut-off point.

We report a probit model where we convert the values 1 and 2 to 1 (all the other values = 0).

The results in Table 5-1 indicate that conditional corruption matters showing similar

quantitative effects.

In Table 5-2 we conduct further robustness checks. We report only the findings using a

probit model as Table 5-1 has shown that the probit model provides higher Pseudo R2 values.

First, we try to better isolate a conditional cooperative effect by adding Generalized Trust as

a variable.67 Specification (5) shows that the trust coefficient is not statistically significant.

On the other hand, our conditional corruption variable (SAB) remains highly statistically

significant with a marginal effect of 5 percentage points. In a next step we add income68 as a

further variable. We have added the variable sequentially in the specification as the number

of observations decreases once you control for household income. Also here we

                                                                                                                                                                                         be justified. The results remain robust after investigating different time periods and extending the specification with several opportunity factors.  67 Generally speaking, would you say that most people can be trusted or that you can’t be too careful in your dealings with people? (1=most people can be trusted, 0=can’t be too careful.). 68 As discussed this is a ten-point income scale from 1 to 10 (10-quantiles).  

Page 123: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

    113

Table 5-2 Robustness test and the influence of conditional corruption using micro and macro proxies (EVS) Dependent Variable:

Justifiability Of Corruption Probit

Coeff z-Stat. Marg. Coeff. z-Stat. Marg. Coeff. z-Stat. Marg. Coeff. z-Stat. Marg. Coeff. z-Stat. Marg. (6) (7) (8) (9) (10)

Clustering on countries Clustering on countries Clustering on countries

Conditional Corruption SAB -0.15*** -8.39 -0.050 -0.16*** -8.56 -0.054 -0.16*** -6.65 -0.054 Control of Corruption 0.21*** 31.59 0.069 0.22*** 41.70 0.073 0.24*** 52.11 0.080 Formal And Informal Education Formal 0.004 1.60 0.001 0.004 1.41 0.001 0.004 0.89 0.001 0.001 0.47 0.000 0.003 0.87 0.001 Political Interest 0.047*** 3.49 0.016 0.056*** 3.85 0.019 0.056*** 5.36 0.019 0.041*** 4.34 0.014 0.032*** 3.05 0.011 Demographic Factors Age 30-39 0.21*** 5.60 0.069 0.21*** 5.12 0.067 0.21*** 6.05 0.067 0.18*** 6.35 0.059 0.19*** 6.01 0.060 Age 40-49 0.35*** 8.57 0.11 0.36*** 8.20 0.11 0.36*** 8.74 0.11 0.27*** 7.23 0.085 0.28*** 7.99 0.086 Age 50-59 0.42*** 9.40 0.13 0.43*** 9.09 0.13 0.43*** 9.12 0.13 0.38*** 9.21 0.12 0.36*** 8.38 0.11 Age 60-69 0.61*** 13.01 0.18 0.61*** 11.98 0.17 0.61*** 10.09 0.17 0.51*** 10.71 0.15 0.51*** 10.52 0.15 Age 70+ 0.72*** 12.68 0.19 0.71*** 11.63 0.19 0.71*** 8.33 0.19 0.62*** 10.01 0.17 0.62*** 10.49 0.17 Female 0.16*** 6.68 0.054 0.15*** 5.70 0.049 0.15*** 7.78 0.049 0.16*** 10.05 0.054 0.18*** 12.45 0.058 Marital Status Married 0.12*** 3.41 0.041 0.13*** 3.37 0.043 0.13*** 3.30 0.043 0.14*** 4.67 0.047 0.14*** 5.12 0.045 Widowed 0.10* 1.73 0.033 0.079 1.28 0.026 0.079 1.61 0.026 0.13*** 3.27 0.041 0.12*** 3.09 0.038 Divorced 0.027 0.54 0.009 0.029 0.53 0.009 0.029 0.47 0.009 0.029 0.74 0.009 0.024 0.65 0.008 Separated 0.000 0.00 0.000 -0.044 -0.41 -0.015 -0.044 -0.58 -0.015 0.035 0.49 0.012 0.059 1.01 0.019 Employment Status Selfemployed -0.13** -2.54 -0.044 -0.10* -1.78 -0.034 -0.10 -1.25 -0.034 -0.092* -1.79 -0.031 -0.12*** -2.72 -0.039 Risk Attitudes Risk Averse 0.090*** 3.49 0.031 0.12*** 4.42 0.041 0.12*** 3.49 0.041 0.087*** 3.01 0.029 0.071*** 2.60 0.024 Urbanization Urbanization -0.008 -1.55 -0.003 -0.001 -0.27 0.000 -0.001 -0.20 0.000 -0.010* -1.72 -0.003 -0.012** -2.27 -0.004 Religiosity Church Attendance 0.014** 2.50 0.005 0.015** 2.53 0.005 0.015** 1.98 0.005 0.011* 1.91 0.003 0.011** 2.06 0.004 Trust Generalized Trust -0.024 -0.90 -0.008 -0.025 -0.89 -0.008 -0.025 -0.78 -0.008 -0.019 -0.78 -0.006 -0.024 -1.01 -0.008 Economic Situation Income -0.021*** -3.65 -0.007 -0.021** -2.40 -0.007 -0.012 -1.58 -0.004 Geographic Region Country Fixed Effects YES YES YES YES YES Pseudo R2 0.10 0.11 0.11 0.10 0.098 Number of observations 17537 15395 15395 28989 34475 Prob > chi2 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00

Notes: The reference group consists of Age<30, Man, Single/Living Together, Other Employment Status. ***, ** and * denote significance at 1%, 5% and 10%, respectively. Robust standard errors.

Page 124: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

114  

observe a robust result. The variable SAB is statistically significant at the 1% level and the

quantitative effect even increases. Income is also statistically significant with a negative sign.

In specifications (8) to (10) we provide an interesting extension. We introduce a further

corruption variable into the specification. However, compared to SAB, Control of Corruption

measures the perceived level of corruption at the macro level69. As it can be criticized that

including an aggregated variable in a micro data set may produce downward biased standard

errors, we provide estimations with standard errors adjusted to clustering on countries.

Specification (8) shows that both corruption variables are statistically significant at the 1%

level with high marginal effects. An increase in the Control of Corruption scale by one unit

increases the probability of reporting that corruption is never justified by 6.9 percentage

points. On the other hand, the marginal effect for the SAB is consistent with the previous

findings. In specification (9) we do not include SAB to maximize the number of available

countries in the data set as SAB has not been collected in all the countries that participated in

the EVS 70 . In specification (10) we also neglect Income, to increase the number of

observations. The results are robust and the marginal effects are even higher (between 7.3

and 8.0 percentage points).

Causality remains an issue because one’s own justifiability of corruption may lead to the

expectation that others behave in the same way. However, results from strategy method

experiments done by Fischbacher et al. (2001) and Fischbacher and Gächter (2006) that

carefully investigate the causality problem suggest that causality goes from beliefs about

others’ cheating to one’s own behaviour rather than vice versa. In our empirical work, we

also present several two-stage least squares (2SLS) estimations with different instruments and

include several diagnostic tests to deal with the causality problem. However, we test for the

relevance and validity of the instruments and the overidentifying restrictions. Moreover, we

try to filter out a possible systematic bias in our conditional corruption effect by correcting

for differences between what an individual thinks and what that individual projects on others.

This provides a possible way of correcting parts of such a potential bias.

                                                            69 Again, higher values are in line with a lower level of corruption. 70 This allows to move from 15 to 30 countries.  

Page 125: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

   115

Table 5-3 2SLS results (EVS) Dependent Variable:

Justifiability Of Corruption Coeff

(11) t-Stat. Coeff.

(12)t-Stat. Coeff.

(13) t-Stat. Coeff.

(14)t-Stat.

Conditional Corruption Perceived Share Of Compatriots Accepting A Bribe (SAB)

-0.093*** -6.87 -0.091*** -6.63 -0.094*** -6.58 -0.036** -2.24

Formal And Informal Education

Formal 0.001 1.18 0.001 1.12 0.001 0.78 0.001 1.49

Political Interest 0.014*** 3.24 0.014*** 3.25 0.017*** 3.73 0.018*** 3.95

Demographic Factors

Age 30-39 0.064*** 4.81 0.060*** 4.37 0.058*** 4.03 0.062*** 4.40

Age 40-49 0.11*** 7.81 0.11*** 7.51 0.11*** 7.17 0.11*** 7.91

Age 50-59 0.12*** 7.97 0.12*** 7.49 0.12*** 7.42 0.13*** 8.28

Age 60-69 0.18*** 11.56 0.18*** 11.41 0.17*** 10.46 0.18*** 11.53

Age 70+ 0.20*** 10.98 0.20*** 10.89 0.19*** 9.88 0.21*** 11.13

Female 0.055*** 6.87 0.056*** 6.81 0.050*** 5.83 0.050*** 6.01

Marital Status

Married 0.053*** 4.25 0.053*** 4.23 0.059*** 4.35 0.052*** 3.95

Widowed 0.042** 2.23 0.042** 2.18 0.040** 1.98 0.037* 1.92

Divorced 0.030* 1.67 0.030 1.64 0.034* 1.78 0.017 0.91

Separated 0.025 0.71 0.026 0.71 0.018 0.48 -0.002 -0.06

Employment Status

Selfemployed -0.037** -2.31 -0.037** -2.27 -0.027 -1.53 -0.032* -1.90

Risk Attitudes

Risk Averse 0.036*** 4.02 0.038*** 4.17 0.050*** 5.07 0.047*** 4.95

Urbanization

Urbanization -0.003 -1.64 -0.003 -1.52 -0.001 -0.35 -0.002 -0.95

Religiosity

Church Attendance 0.006*** 3.46 0.006*** 3.48 0.006*** 3.31 0.006*** 3.33

Economic Situation

Income -0.006*** -3.01 -0.006*** -3.25

Geographic Region

Country Fixed Effects YES YES YES YES

First stage regressions:

Index of Perceived Honesty I 0.74*** 52.91 0.73*** 51.63 0.73*** 48.67

Index of Perceived Honesty II 0.54*** 38.89

Generalized Trust -0.054*** -4.54 -0.058*** -4.57 -0.068*** -5.30

F-Test of excluded instruments 2799*** 1364*** 1214*** 784***

Anderson canon. corr. likelihood ratio stat.

3481*** 3388*** 2991*** 2105***

Anderson-Rubin test 47.60*** 47.05*** 45.96*** 5.44*

Hansen J statistic 1.80 1.59 0.36

Number of observations 15755 15248 13331 14281

Prob > F 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00

Notes: The reference group consists of Age<30, Man, Single/Living Together, Other Employment Status. ***, ** and * denote significance at 1%, 5% and 10%, respectively. Robust standard errors.

To check for robustness, we are going to use a variety of instruments in our 2SLS

regressions reported in Table 5-3. In specification (11), we use an index of perceived honesty

Page 126: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

   116

as an instrument for SAB71. In the second one, we also use Generalized Trust as an instrument.

A seen previously, generalized trust did not affect the justifiability of corruption. However, as

Table 5-3 shows generalized trust is a good instrument for conditional corruption. Next, we

also consider a second index of perceived honesty72. The results indicate that the variable

SAB remains statistically significant in all the 2SLS. Table 5-3 also reports the results of the

Anderson canonical correlation likelihood-ratio test to test whether the equation is identified

as a measure of instrument relevance. The test shows that the null hypothesis can be rejected,

indicating that the model is identified and the instruments are relevant in all cases. Table 5-3

further shows that the F-tests for the instrument exclusion set in the first-stage regression are

statistically significant in all cases. In addition, we test for the validity of the instruments

using a Hansen test of overidentifying restrictions. Table 5-3 indicates that the null

hypothesis that the excluded instruments are not correlated with the error term cannot be

rejected. Thus, the results confirm the validity of the instruments.

Table 5-4 Causality discussion (Filtering) Depend. V.: Justifiability of Corruption Coeff. z-Stat. Marg. Effects

(Highest Value = Never Justified) Weighted Probit

INDEPENDENT V. (see specifications) Specification (15)

Filtered SAB using specification (4) -0.090*** -5.21 -0.030

Specification (16)

Filtered SAB using specification (5) -0.086*** -4.89 -0.029

Specification (17)

Filtered SAB using specification (6) -0.10*** -5.33 -0.034

Specification (18)

Filtered SAB using specification (7) -0.10*** -5.25 -0.034

Control of Corruption 0.21*** 32.32 0.071

Notes: Summary of four regressions. The reference group consists of Age<30, Man, Single/Living Together, Other Employment Status. ***, ** and * denote significance at 1%, 5% and 10%, respectively. Robust standard errors.

                                                            71  Index covering the average value of the following questions: According to you, how many of your compatriots do the following: Claiming state benefits to which they are not entitled. Cheating on tax if they have the chance. Paying cash for services to avoid taxes. Speeding over the limit in built-up areas. Taking the drug marijuana or hash. Driving under the influence of alcohol (scale from 1 to 4). 72 Index covering the average value of the following questions: Speeding over the limit in built-up areas. Taking the drug marijuana or hash. Driving under the influence of alcohol (scale from 1 to 4).   

Page 127: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

   117

In addition, to deal with a potential causality problem, we filter out a possible bias in the

conditional cooperative effect. Again, the causality problem may arise because an

individual’s justifiability of bribing might lead to the expectation that others behave in the

same way. Thus, individuals with a higher social norm of compliance have a lower

perception that others are bribing. To deal with this possibility, we calculate first the average

perceived corruption for each country. In the next step, we calculate the average perceived

corruption in each country for individuals having the lowest justifiability of corruption. In a

further step, we build the difference between both average values. This variable may measure

a particular bias in perceived corruption due to the level of social norms. In a last step, we

add this bias to the individual values of the group with the lowest justifiability of corruption

values. As a consequence, each of the individuals with the highest social norm of compliance

now has higher perceived corruption values. Hence, the values between the group with the

higher and lower justifiability of corruption values are brought closer together, depending on

the perceived corruption situation in each country. This procedure may help to better isolate

the existence of a conditional corruption. Table 5-4 presents the results for the filtered

perceived corruption variable using specifications in line with Table 5-1 and 5-2. The

coefficient remains highly statistically significant and, although the marginal effects have (in

general) decreased from previous estimates, they still are very high.

5.4.2 Micro Level using the WVS

In a next step we are going to use an alternative data source to check whether the previously

obtained results remain robust. As discussed, we are using a slightly different proxy for

conditional corruption. The WVS provides the possibility to explore a large set of countries

and further regions. This also provides the opportunity to explore the relevance of conditional

corruption at the macro level. We work with average values within each country using for our

dependent variable the 4 point scale (0 to 3). Figure 5-1 shows a relatively strong negative

correlation (Pearson r=-0.42), significant at the 0.01 level. Looking at the linear relationship

in a simple regression shows that conditional corruption can explain 18 percent of the total

variance of the justifiability of corruption.

In general, empirical support for a theoretical foundation depends not only on the validity

of the theory but also on the quality of the data. It is not possible to ascertain with survey data

whether respondents are truthful in their answers as truth is not observable by the

interviewers (Kanazawa 2005). To validate statements one could explore the correlation

between respondents’ statements and the Control of Corruption variable at the macro level

Page 128: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

   118

using country averages. Figure 5-3 shows an expected positive correlation (Pearson r=0.38)

statistically significant at the 0.05

Working with the WVS we are also able to control for the similar independent

variables73. Table 5-5 presents the first results. We explore regressions with regional or

country fixed effects. Moreover, we provide evidence with and without the income variable.

In addition, we also include sequentially the macro corruption variable Control of Corruption.

In all the specifications the variable Perceived Level of Corruption is statistically significant

with marginal effects between 0.6 and 3.5 percentage points. In addition, the macro variable

Control of Corruption is also statistically significant with marginal effects close to 6

percentage points. To deal with the social desirability problem we also change the cut-off

point (see last specification in Table 5- 1). The values 1 and 2 in the original scale have been

coded as 1 and all other values as 0. The coefficient is highly statistically significant,

reporting even larger marginal effects than comparable results in specification (20). Thus, we

can conclude that conditional corruption is also observable when using alternative data

sources. The control variables show similar tendencies. A higher level of political interest is

correlated with a lower justifiability of corruption. Risk averse and married people are also

less inclined to justify corruption. On the other hand, self-employed individuals are more

likely to justify corruption. Similarly, we also observe an age and gender effect. However, the

effects of religiosity, urbanization and income are less strong.

                                                            73 See definition of the variables in previous footnotes.  

Page 129: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

119  

Table 5-5 Conditional corruption using WVS Dependent Variable: Justifiability Of Corruption Weighted Probit

Coeff z-Stat. Marg. Coeff. z-Stat. Marg. Coeff. z-Stat. Marg. Coeff. z-Stat. Marg. Coeff. z-Stat. Marg. Coeff. z-Stat. Marg.

(19) (20) (21) (22) (23) (24) Change of cut-off point

Conditional Corruption Perceived Level Of Corruption (Plc)

-0.112*** -11.90 -0.035 -0.020* -1.81 -0.006 -0.034*** -2.81 -0.010 -0.035** -2.50 -0.011 -0.043*** -2.95 -0.013 -0.041*** -3.35 -0.009

Control Of Corruption 0.19*** 15.18 0.059 0.19*** 14.09 0.058 Formal And Informal Education Politicial Interest 0.025*** 3.02 0.008 0.031*** 3.55 0.010 0.021** 2.17 0.006 0.036*** 3.15 0.011 0.030** 2.52 0.009 0.051*** 5.18 0.011 Formal -0.002 -0.64 -0.001 0.003 0.77 0.001 0.006 1.25 0.002 0.005 0.95 0.002 0.010* 1.75 0.003 0.006 1.34 0.001 Demographic Factors Age 30-49 0.20*** 9.91 0.064 0.20*** 9.20 0.059 0.19*** 8.51 0.059 0.18*** 6.52 0.055 0.18*** 6.43 0.057 0.19*** 8.36 0.043 Age 50-64 0.41*** 15.37 0.12 0.40*** 14.46 0.11 0.40*** 13.50 0.11 0.38*** 10.83 0.11 0.38*** 10.23 0.11 0.39*** 12.87 0.077 Age 65+ 0.57*** 16.11 0.15 0.53*** 14.45 0.14 0.53*** 13.04 0.14 0.55*** 11.50 0.14 0.53*** 10.71 0.14 0.53*** 12.55 0.094 Female 0.14*** 8.89 0.045 0.14*** 8.67 0.044 0.13*** 7.40 0.041 0.16*** 7.58 0.051 0.15*** 6.83 0.048 0.16*** 8.61 0.035 Marital Status Married 0.10*** 4.99 0.033 0.12*** 5.67 0.038 0.14*** 5.81 0.042 0.13*** 4.64 0.041 0.13*** 4.53 0.042 0.13*** 5.35 0.029 Widowed 0.086** 2.18 0.026 0.084** 2.01 0.025 0.092** 2.04 0.028 0.095* 1.87 0.029 0.072 1.36 0.022 0.098** 2.08 0.021 Divorced 0.020 0.48 0.006 -0.001 -0.02 0.000 0.029 0.64 0.009 0.026 0.49 0.008 0.024 0.43 0.007 -0.0001 0.00 0.000 Separated 0.069 1.22 0.021 0.015 0.26 0.005 0.008 0.14 0.003 0.066 0.87 0.020 0.054 0.69 0.017 -0.0002 0.00 0.000 Employment Status Selfemployed -0.078*** -2.64 -0.025 -0.088*** -2.87 -0.028 -0.10*** -3.09 -0.032 -0.098*** -2.65 -0.032 -0.11*** -2.70 -0.034 -0.087** -2.59 -0.020 Risk Attitudes Risk Averse 0.084*** 4.95 0.026 0.071*** 4.03 0.022 0.068*** 3.49 0.021 0.080*** 3.43 0.025 0.075*** 3.07 0.023 0.073*** 3.70 0.016 Urbanization Urbanization 0.001 0.40 0.000 -0.008** -2.30 -0.002 -0.007* -1.80 -0.002 -0.010** -2.40 -0.003 -0.008* -1.77 -0.002 -0.005 -1.23 -0.001 Religiosity Church Attendance 0.0002 0.04 0.0001 0.018*** 3.86 0.006 0.017*** 3.40 0.005 -0.003 -0.58 -0.001 -0.005 -0.86 -0.002 0.021*** 4.02 0.005 Economic Situation Income -0.006 -1.42 -0.002 -0.011** -2.48 -0.004 Regional Fixed Effects YES NO NO YES YES NO Country Fixed Effects NO YES YES NO NO YES

Pseudo R2 0.038 0.082 0.11 0.059 0.058 0.099 Number of observations 37759 37759 32096 20793 18914 37759 Prob > chi2 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00

Notes: The reference group consists of Age<30, Man, Single/Living Together, Other Employment Status. ***, ** and * denote significance at 1%, 5% and 10%, respectively. Robust standard errors.

Page 130: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

120  

Table 5-6 2SLS results (WVS)

Dependent Variable: Justifiability of Corruption Coeff t-Stat. Coeff. t-Stat.

(25) (26)

Conditional Corruption Perceived Corruption (PLC) -0.044** -2.43 -0.061*** -3.04

Formal And Informal Education

Political Interest 0.007** 2.35 0.003 0.84

Formal -0.001 -0.94 0.000 -0.29

Demographic Factors

Age 30-49 0.07*** 9.32 0.066*** 8.53 Age 50-64 0.13*** 14.96 0.13*** 14.19

Age 65+ 0.17*** 16.23 0.17*** 14.87

Female 0.045*** 8.85 0.042*** 7.66

Marital Status

Married 0.039*** 5.27 0.042*** 5.28

Widowed 0.032*** 2.83 0.040*** 3.35

Divorced 0.012 0.89 0.027* 1.94

Separated 0.031* 1.67 0.033* 1.68

Employment Status

Selfemployed -0.024** -2.43 -0.031*** -2.94

Risk Attitudes

Risk Averse 0.027*** 5.14 0.022*** 3.79

Urbanization

Urbanization 0.001 0.81 0.001 0.91

Religiosity

Church Attendance -0.0002 -0.15 -0.002 -1.16

Economic Situation

Income 0.0004 0.34

Country Fixed Effects YES YES

First stage regressions:

Generalized Trust -0.30*** -28.14 -0.30*** -25.68

F-Test of excluded instruments 791.73*** 659.46***

Anderson canon. corr. likelihood ratio stat. 956.50*** 810.50***

Anderson-Rubin test 5.88** 9.20***

Number of observations 36296 30968

Prob > F 0.00 0.00

Notes: The reference group consists of Age<30, Man, Single/Living Together, Other Employment Status. ***, ** and * denote significance at 1%, 5% and 10%, respectively. Robust standard errors.

Table 5-6 presents 2SLS estimations using generalized trust as an instrument for perceived

corruption (in line with Table 5-3). Looking at the first stage regressions and the diagnostic

tests we can conclude that generalized trust is a good instrument74. The results also show that

Perceived Corruption (PLC) remains statistically significant, providing therefore further

support for previous findings. We report additional findings in Table 5-7 obtained with a

filtered PLC variable using previous specifications. Also here we observe that the PLC

coefficient is always statistically significant with a negative sign. Thus, even after filtering we

can conclude that conditional corruption matters.                                                             74 The WVS does not provide the possibility to consider an index of perceived honesty.  

Page 131: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

  

121

Table 5-7 Causality discussion filtering with WVS Data

Depend. V.: Justifiability of Corruption (Highest Value = Never Justified) Weighted Probit

Coeff. z-Stat. Marg. Effects

INDEPENDENT V. (see specifications) Specification (27)

Filtered PLC using specification (19) -0.13*** -12.87 -0.041

Specification (28)

Filtered PLC using specification (20) -0.020* -1.75 -0.006

Specification (29)

Filtered PLC using specification (21) -0.026** -2.08 -0.008

Specification (30)

Filtered PLC using specification (22) -0.035** -2.50 -0.011

Control of Corruption 0.19*** 15.18 0.059

Specification (31)

Filtered PLC using specification (23) -0.043*** -2.95 -0.013

Control of Corruption 0.19*** 14.09 0.058

Notes: Summary of four regressions. The reference group consists of Age<30, Man, Single/Living Together, Other Employment Status. ***, ** and * denote significance at 1%, 5% and 10%, respectively. Robust standard errors.

We conduct a further robustness test to deal with a potential “social desirability” bias using

the EVS and WVS. We run a two-stage approach where the previous estimations were just the

first stage. First, respondents decide whether or not to answer that corruption is never justified

(“socially correct response”). In a second stage, given the decision to answer something other

than the socially correct response, individuals report a value from the remaining scale (1 to 9).

The results are not reported in a table but indicate that our conditional corruption variable is

always statistically significant. Despite trying to check the causality relationship one should

note that providing a clear causality relationship is quite problematic working with such micro

survey data. To some extent we see these results as more precisely estimated partial

correlations and not fully precise estimates of a causal relationship (see also Guiso et al. 2003).

In the next stage we are going to explore the importance of conditional corruption at the

macro level over time in order to explore hypothesis 2.

5.4.3 Macro Level Using a Large Panel Data Set

In the previous analysis we were only able to explore conditional corruption in a cross-sectional

setting. In this next step, it is highly relevant to bring in the time dimension to see the potential

dynamics of conditional corruption. This requires the use of a panel data set. Therefore, we are

going to work with a large international panel data set that covers 18 years (1986 till 2003). As

Page 132: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

  

122

discussed previously, we use the ICRG data to get a measurement of (perceived) corruption.

The panel analysis will help us to see whether corruption is contagious. Sah (2005, p. 6), e.g.,

stresses “If past experiences have convinced some citizens that corruption is more pervasive in

the economy, then they are more likely to cheat. Likewise, if their past experiences have

convinced some bureaucrats that cheating is more pervasive in the economy, then they are more

likely to choose to be corrupt…Through these dynamic relationships, future levels of cheating

and corruption in the economy become explicitly linked to past levels of cheating and

corruption in the economy…”. A contagion effect can increase the demand for corruption as

individuals perceive additional opportunities for bribing (Goel and Nelson 2007). It can also

affect the supply of corruption as potentially corrupt bureaucrats are aware of the high

probability that one can be corrupt without being caught and penalized. Moreover, bureaucrats

could also try to introduce lax enforcement and punishment strategies for corruption (Goel and

Nelson 2007). Similarly, the criminal literature has stressed that the prevalence of a given type

of criminal behaviour may change the propensity of others to engage in that same behaviour. It

affects the perceptions about the net return of such a behaviour (information function) and also

the probability of arrests or constraints (Ludwig and Kling 2006, Cook and Goss, 1996; Becker

and Murphy, 2000; Manski, 1993, 2000). A contagion effect in crimes has been observed in the

areas of assassinations, hijackings, kidnappings, and serial murders (Bikhchandi, Hirshleifer

and Welch 1998). However, only a limited number of studies have provided empirical evidence

focusing on corruption. Evidence is mainly available from the US. Goel and Nelson (2007), use

state-level U.S. data in a cross-sectional analysis data over the period 1995–2004, and find that

the effect of neighbouring corruption is positive and statistically significant - showing therefore

that corruption does appear to be contagious. A 10% increase in corruption in neighbouring

states appears to increase corruption in a state somewhere in the range of 4–11%. Our study

adds to the literature by using panel data and exploring a contagion effect at the international

level. In line with studies on contagion in general, we are going to use lagged values to explore

its importance75. To isolate such an effect we are going to control for further factors such as law

and order76, democratic accountability77, economic performance, or the level of openness.

Discretion in the application of rules enhances corruption. On the other hand, a strong legal

system that penalizes deviance reduces the incentives to act illegally (high Law and Order                                                             75 Similarly, Becker (1996) stresses in a general framework that individual’s consumption (Ci) depends on that of other individuals in the past (Cjt-1) and on individual I consumption in a previous period (Cit-1).  76 The ‘law’ sub-component measures the strength and impartiality of the legal system, while the ‘order’ sub-component is an assessment of popular observance of the law. 77 Measures how responsive the government is with its people.  

Page 133: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

  

123

value). In addition, a more encompassing and legitimate state increases the willingness to

contribute. If citizens perceive that their interests (preferences) are properly represented in

political institutions and they receive an adequate voice, their identification with the state

increases, their willingness to be corrupt decreases (high Democratic Accountability value).

Moreover democratic accountability helps to limit the abuse of political power by selfish

politicians, when citizens cannot completely foresee incumbents’ preferences, elements of

direct democracy also empower them with an instrument for controlling the government. Levi

(1988) points out that a possible method of creating or maintaining compliance is t provide

reassurance by the government. A government that precommits itself with direct democratic

rules imposes restraints on its own power and thus sends a signal that taxpayers are seen as

responsible persons. Voting possibilities also provide utility in themselves. Citizens value the

right to participate, because it produces a kind of procedural utility as the opportunity set

increases which fosters the moral costs of behaving illegally and enhances rule obedience

(Torgler and Schneider 2009). Moreover, political involvement and political attention is

correlated with income as political attention may be a luxury good and therefore people pay

more attention to corrupt activities and are better able to take actions against these officials

(Glaeser and Saks 2006). Thus we would observe a negative correlation between GDP per

capita and corruption. Moreover, economic rents will decrease with a higher level of economic

competition. Ades and Di Tella (1999) find that corruption is higher in countries where

domestic firms are protected from foreign competition. We use data provided by Dreher (2006)

that measure three main dimensions of openness: economic, social and political globalization.

The overall index of globalization covers not less than 23 variables.

Thus, to test our second hypothesis, we propose the following baseline equations:

CRit = + 1 CTRLit +2 CRi(t-1) +3 LOit+ 4 DAit + 4 GLit + TDt +REGIONi + it

where i indexes the countries in the sample and t denotes the time period. CRit denotes the level

of corruption (higher values=lower level corruption) and CRi(t-1) is the one year lag of

corruption. LOit is our law and order variable, DAit the proxy for democratic accountability and

GLit the proxy for globalization. The regressions also contain several control variables, CTRLit,

including GDP per capita and the population size. We control for time as well as regional

invariant factors including fixed time, TDt, and fixed regional effects, REGIONi78. it denotes

the error term.

                                                            78 We differentiate between Europe, Latin America, North America, North Africa, Sub Saharan Africa, Pacific, Asia, Caribbean and Australia. 

Page 134: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

  

124

Table 5-8 presents the results. We report beta or standardized regression coefficients to

compare magnitude, which reveals the relative importance of the variables used. To obtain

robust standard errors in these estimations, we use the Huber/White/Sandwich estimators of

standard errors. First we only include our lagged corruption variable. The coefficient is highly

statistically significant with a high beta coefficient. We observe that the lagged corruption value

together with time and regional fixed effects already explain more than 60 percent of the total

variance of the variable corruption. In the next regression, we add our control variables together

with the globalization index as independent variables. The results show that the coefficient for

Corruption(t-1) (CRi(t-1)) is still statistically significant at the 1% level reporting the highest beta

coefficients among the used independent variables. Table 5-8 also shows that economic

development and globalization have a negative influence on corruption. However, it should be

noted that this effect disappears once you control for governance/institutional factors in the

third specification reported in Table 5-8. An increase in Globalization and GDP per capita leads

to a decrease in corruption. Moreover, a faster growing population has a positive effect on

corruption. The third specification introduces governance and institutional factors. We find that

both factors, Law and Order (LOit) and Democratic Accountability (DAit), are statistically

significant. Also here we find that the past level of corruption has the strongest relationship

with our dependent variable, followed by institutional/governance variables and globalization.

Thus, the macro results show that corruption is not independent of the past experiences.

However, one should note that such macro analysis has the disadvantage that we may not only

measure a potential contagion effect but also path-dependency that may not be directly related

to conditional corruption.

In sum, the micro and macro evidence generated in this chapter suggests that social forces

and past experiences matter. Conditional corruption is a key factor in understanding corruption.

Page 135: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

  

125

Table 5-8 Evidence at the macro level Dependent Variable: Corruption (higher values = lower level of corruption)

Beta (32)

t-stat.

Beta (33)

t-stat.

Beta (34)

t-stat.

Corruption (t-1) 0.60*** 19.80 0.55*** 15.17 0.46*** 12.78

Rule of Law 0.20*** 7.85

Democratic Accountability 0.18*** 7.52

Log (GDP per capita) 0.11*** 3.39 -0.048 -1.46

Log(population) -0.042*** -2.68 -0.056*** -3.98

Globalization Index 0.22*** 3.13 0.19*** 3.08

Region Fixed Effects Yes Yes Yes

Time Fixed Effects Yes Yes Yes Prob > F 0.00 0.00 0.00

R2 0.67 0.71 0.75 Number of observations 1439 1059 1059

Notes: Estimations with robust standard errors. OLS coefficients = standardized/beta coefficients. *, ** and *** denote significance at the 10%, 5% and 1% level, respectively.

5.5 Conclusion

Traditional economics assumes that preferences are independent of the behavior of everyone

else and also independent of past and future consumption. Therefore choices affect only the

agents directly involved. However, in the last few decades economists have paid more attention

to the structure of preferences. For example, social interactions, an aspect that has long been

discussed by important figures such as Adam Smith (1759/1976), Karl Marx (1849), Thorstein

Veblen (1899) or James Duesenberry (1949), have gained importance in economics. In this

chapter we explore whether and to what extent group dynamics or social forces and past

experiences affect corruption. In other words, we explore theoretically and empirically whether

conditional cooperation matters (hypothesis 1) and whether corruption is contagious

(hypothesis 2). We use the notion of “conditional corruption” for these effects. The

experimental economics literature has explored (pro-)social preferences through designs that

implement own and others’ material payoffs. We observe models of reciprocity, inequity

aversion, or altruism in the literature (see Rabin 1993, Charness and Rabin 2002, Fehr and

Schmidt 1999, Bolton and Ockenfels 2000, Andreoni and Miller 2002). We have presented a

theoretical framework that allows derivation of these two hypotheses. The theoretical part is

supplemented with empirical evidence on conditional corruption and contagion. Interestingly,

only a limited number of studies on corruption have explored this question. Similar discussions

Page 136: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

  

126

on social interactions can be found in the crime literature or more specifically in the literature

on information cascades, network externalities, fads, herd behaviour or bandwagon effects (see,

e.g., Banerjee 1992, Bikchandani, Hirshleifer, and Welch 1992, 1998, Katz and Shapiro 1985).

However, as a novelty we present a large amount of empirical evidence that explores this

question in the area of corruption. First we use two data sets at the micro level followed by a

large international panel data set at macro level covering almost 20 years. The results clearly

indicate that the willingness to be corrupt is influenced by the perceived activities of peers and

other individuals. Moreover, the panel data set at the macro level also indicates that the past

level of corruption has a strong influence on the current corruption level which indicates that

contagion matters. The results clearly show that conditional corruption matters. The findings

therefore underscore the relevance of social interactions. The results are of particular

importance in politics as genuine information is weak and incentives to collect information are

limited due to the possibility of free-riding (Wintrobe 2006). When developing policy strategies

it is recommended to take into account that individuals are not acting in isolation. Social

interactions and group dynamics are highly relevant in the understanding of corruption. A

critical mass of cooperative individuals is required to induce a positive dynamic process of

conditional cooperation. On the other hand, a society which has many non-compliant

individuals will inherit a weak social norm which leads to a shift to a non-cooperative situation

similar to a “corruption trap”. Thus, policies should take into account that we may observe a

path-dependent process within a society.

 

Page 137: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

  

127

Chapter Six Social interaction and Corruption: Within-country Evidence79

 

6.1 Introduction

Corruption is a widespread phenomenon affecting human societies throughout time and space.

Contemporaneous corruption scandals not only occur in developing countries such as Nigeria,

India, and China but also in developed economies such as France, Germany and United States.

Even in Scandinavian countries, like Sweden and Norway, supposedly free-from-corruption,

managers of state owned companies have been found to be taking bribes (for an overview see

Rose-Ackerman, 1999).

Corruption in the public sector is recognised to be the greatest obstacle to development

(Kaufmann, 1997). A higher level corruption is associated with lower investment and economic

growth (Mauro 1995; World Bank, 1997). Corruption weakens the effect of industrial policies

and induces private sectors to violate tax and regulatory laws. Foreign direct investment is also

depressed by a high level of corruption (Wei, 2000). Anticorruption policies are therefore very

important since corruption can induce great harm to countries. Some stress that bribery may

increase the overall efficiency of an economic system (e.g., Lui, 1985). However, Rose-

Ackerman (1999) argues that issues such as tax evasion, violation of environmental rules,

certification of unqualified people for public benefits, and grants of immunity to organized

crime do not have such an effect. In addition, bureaucrats have an incentive to delay

transactions in order to extract higher payments (see Rose-Ackerman, 1997)

Reducing corruption requires a thorough understanding of its causes. Sizable literature has

emerged to investigate the determinants of corruption. Current research associates corruption

with cultural tradition, economic development, political institutions and government policies.

For example, in his comprehensive cross-country study, Treisman (2000) finds that Protestant

traditions, history of British rule, long exposure to democracy, higher average income and high

levels of imports depress corruption, while decentralization encourages it. Brunetti and Weder

(2003) present evidence that press freedom can control corruption. Using a within-country data

set, Glaeser and Saks (2006) document that economic development and education decrease

corruption while income inequality and racial fractionalization may increase corruption in

America. However, few have explored the impact of social interaction on corruption. A notable

exception is Goel and Nelson (2007) who, with state-level U.S. data between 1995 and 2004,

                                                            79 This chapter has been submitted to the Journal of Policy Modelling. 

Page 138: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

  

128

show that the effect of neighbouring corruption on local corruption is significantly positive. In

other words, corruption is contagious. Contagion effects have been observed in other illegal

activities such as assassinations, hijackings, kidnappings, and serial murders as referred to by

Bikhchandi, Hirshleifer and Welch (1998). The relevance of social interaction and crime is

explored by Glaeser, Sacerdote and Scheinkman (1996) who focus on the United States (across

cities and across precincts in New York). The results indicate that social interaction models

provide a framework for understanding variances of cross-city crime rates. Individuals are more

likely to commit crimes when those around them do. Focusing on corruption, Dong, Dulleck

and Torgler (2008) find using cross-sectional micro data that conditional cooperation matters.

The willingness to engage in corruption is influenced by the perceived activities of other

individuals.

In this chapter we explore the effect of social interaction on the incidence of corruption both

theoretically and empirically in the context of China. China is an interesting country to analyse,

not only because it is the largest transitional and developing country, but also because

corruption has become more rampant in China since the economic reform was launched in 1978.

Even the Chinese government has admitted that corruption “is now worse than during any other

period since New China was founded in 1949. It has spread into the Party, into government

administration and into every part of society, including politics, economy, ideology and culture”

(Liang, 1994, p. 122). Such widespread corruption has caused severe consequences in China,

including economic losses estimated to have been between 13.2 and 16.8% of China’s GDP in

the late 1990s (Hu 2001). Not surprisingly, such rampant corruption has generated much

literature, especially in sociology and political science (e.g., White, 1996, and Gong, 2006).

From an economic perspective, Yao (2002) argues that corruption in China is generated by the

Chinese political system, which grants and protects privileges. With a unique corruption

measure, Cai, Fang and Xu (2009) find that corruption has a substantially negative effect on the

productivity of Chinese firms. Nevertheless, there is a lack of studies that comprehensively

analyse the economic underpinnings of corruption in China. We therefore explicitly study the

impact of social interaction on the incidence of corruption, and find a statistically significant

relationship between social interaction and corruption. This suggests that like other crimes, the

incidence of corruption is significantly affected by social interaction. The rest of this chapter is

structured as follows: Section 6.2 presents a theoretical model. Section 6.3 describes our

empirical analysis and results. Section 6.4 concludes the chapter.

Page 139: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

  

129

6.2 Theoretical Model

In this section we investigate theoretically social interaction in the context of corruption.

Following Aidt’s survey (2003), we identify three related theoretical articles, which are

summarized in Table 6-1 below. These articles, though providing stylized facts related to social

interaction, cannot explain thoroughly the effect of social interaction on the incidence of

corruption because they do not introduce social interaction explicitly into their models. In terms

of social interaction theory, Sah (1988, 2007) and Avdvig and Moene (1990) only study the

effect of local interaction, while Lui (1986) simply investigates the effect of global interaction80.

Table 6-1 Literature summary

Crucial point Approach Stylized fact

Lui (1986) It is harder to audit corrupt officials in societies where corruption is more prevalent.

The overlapping-generations model

The different levels of corruption across regions under the same deterrence scheme

Sah (1988, 2007)

An individual’s perception of the corruption level is stochastically influenced by the real level that he faced in the past, and this perception affects his current and future corrupt act, which in turn exert stochastic influences on the current and future real corruption level.

The overlapping-generations model

The different levels of corruption across regions

Avdvig and Moene (1990) The probability of corruption is related to its established frequency.

Simple dynamic model The different levels of corruption across regions

Nevertheless, a growing body of research considering the role of social interaction in

economic outcomes has emerged during the last two decades. According to Zanelia (2004, p. 4),

social interaction is the “direct interdependences, not mediated by markets and enforceable

contracts, between individual decisions and the decisions and characteristics of others within a

common sociological group”. Economic models that have embedded social interactions “seem

particularly adept to solve a pervasive problem in the social science, namely the observation of

large differences in outcomes in the absence of commensurate differences in fundamentals”

(Scheinkman, 2008, p. 2). Sah (1991) states that an individual’s environment influences her

propensity for crime and thereby explains the obvious difference between the crime

participation rates of societal groups with similar economic fundamentals. With two models of

social interaction, Glaeser, Sacerdote and Scheinkman (1996) provide a framework to interpret

the cross-city variation in crime rates.

In line with social interaction research we employ the interactions-based approach (Blume

and Durlauf, 2004) to explore bureaucratic corruption. Specifically, we use the binary choice

                                                            80 We will discuss these terms later. 

Page 140: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

  

130

model with social interactions developed by Brock and Durlauf (1995) to model corrupt

behaviour.

We consider a population of I homogenous bureaucrats. In the presence of social

interactions, each bureaucrat chooses one of two actions: corruption or non-corruption, which is

coded by 1, 1 . The space of all possible sets of actions by the population is denoted

by , , . Thus , , , , , represents the choices of all

bureaucrats other than i.

The utility of the bureaucrat i is assumed to be

, 6 1

Here U ωi i ωi is a private component of the utility. U ωi is the deterministic private

utility decided by the bureaucrat i’s choice, which is expressed below, as:

, 1, 1

6 2

Here represents the bureaucrat’s wage, is the bribe a corrupt bureaucrat accepts and the

probability that his corrupt act is not detected. A corrupt bureaucrat will lose his job and hence

all his income if his corrupt act is detected. Let and , we can

easily rewrite into the form

6 3

is the random private utility independently and identically distributed across bureaucrats.

In our model it represents the moral shock (moral cost) of taking one of the actions. Following

Brock and Durlauf (2001) and Glaeser and Scheinkman (2002), we further assume that is

extreme-value distributed. Thus the difference between 1 and 1 is logistically

distributed,

1 1 11 ; 0 6 4

, in (1), however, is the social component of the utility, namely social utility

associated with a bureaucrat’s choice. We assume that it captures a pure conformity effect,

hence,

, ,

2

, 1

, 1 6 5

Page 141: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

  

131

Here , >0 are measures of the disutility of nonconformity. denotes the bureaucrat i’s

subjective expectation of the bureaucrat j’s choice. With the above assumptions we have,

1 1 1

2 2 ,

1

1 exp 2 ∑ , 6 6

Since the bureaucrats are homogenous, we can assume that , 0 , and

. Thus,

11

1 exp 2 6 7

1 · 1 1 · 1

6 8

The joint set of choices obeys (because is independently distributed),

1

1 exp 2 6 9

It is obvious that the corrupt decision of a bureaucrat depends on his expectation of others’

decisions. However, there are two different ways in which each bureaucrat interacts with others,

namely local interaction and global interaction. According to Brock and Durlauf (2001), local

interaction means that each bureaucrat interacts directly only with his neighbourhood in the

population, while global interaction implies that each bureaucrat interacts directly with every

other bureaucrat of the population. Actually, people often interact with each other in both ways

though they assign different weights to these interactions. To reflect this fact, we assume,

1 , 0 1 6 10

where the expectation formed from the local interaction can be further expressed as,

1

, 1, … , 6 11 

is the number of bureaucrat i’s neighbours. And the expectation formed from the global

interaction, on the other hand, can be expressed as,

1

1, 1, … , 6 12

We eventually have the following equations

Page 142: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

  

132

11

1 exp 2 1 6 13

1 6 14

From above we can deduce,

1

0; 0 6 15

1

0;

0 6 16

We therefore conclude that the social interaction, including local interaction and global

interaction, does matter in a corrupt act. As can be seen in 6-15 and 6-16 the incidence of

corruption is positively related to both local interaction and global interaction.

6.3 Empirical Work

The model above generates two testable implications on the relationship between the incidence

of corruption and the social interaction, presented in equations 6-15 and 6-16. We plan to test

these implications using within-country panel data from China.

6.3.1 Data and Methodology

Among related studies, Goel and Nelson (2007) use the cross-sectional within-country data of

America, while Attila (2008) and Dong, Dulleck and Torgler (2008) employ cross-country data

sets. We prefer within-country panel data in such a context. Studies on corruption could have

attributed the different levels of corruption to the cultural and institutional difference across

regions rather than the social interactions. In addition, one can stress that social interactions are

triggered by the institutional condition within a country. Thus, it is difficult to estimate the

importance of social interaction in explaining the different corruption levels across countries. If

we use cross-country data set, cultural and institutional variations across countries are hard to

be proxied and fully controlled. Using within-country data, especially those of a country

homogenous in culture and institutions like China, however, can mitigate this kind of problem.

Moreover, we can further control for regional heterogeneity when using within-country panel

data since it allows us to control for the state- and time- invariant variables in the econometric

analysis (Hisao, 2003).

Goel and Nelson (1998), Fisman and Gatti (2002) and Glaeser and Saks (2006) use the

corruption convictions of states to measure state-level corruption in America. We use a similar

measure, namely the registered cases on corruption in the procurator’s offices of provinces, to

Page 143: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

  

133

proxy the provincial corruption level in China. Using conviction data81 has the strength of

dealing with a less subjective measure of corruption offering also the opportunity to work with

longer time spans. In addition, they are not subjected to the problems of sampling error and

survey non-response (Glaeser and Saks, 2006). On the other hand, there is the disadvantage that

the conviction rate is driven by the quality of the detection process. This weakness, however,

will not trouble us in our current study since the quality of local judicial systems in China is

basically homogeneous. In addition, we will control local anti-corruption efforts in our

regressions.

Following the definition of global interaction, we use the average of the corruption levels in

the neighbour provinces to measure the global interaction between the bureaucrats, which

therefore can also be called the neighbouring effect. According to the definition of local

interaction, we need to find the average corruption level of closely interacting bureaucrats at the

beginning of a period when a bureaucrat makes a corrupt decision. We assume that closely

interacting bureaucrats are bureaucrats within the same province. We therefore choose the

corruption level of this province in the last period to proxy the local interaction between

bureaucrats in the province, which hence can be also referred to as the historical effect. Sah

(2005, p. 6), e.g., stresses “(…) if their past experiences have convinced some bureaucrats that

cheating is more pervasive in the economy, then they are more likely to choose to be

corrupt…Through these dynamic relationships, future levels of cheating and corruption in the

economy become explicitly linked to past levels of cheating and corruption in the economy…”.

Besides the key variables discussed above we also employ a set of control variables which

are commonly used in corruption regressions to minimize omitted variable bias. Treisman

(2000) suggested that corruption is associated with historical and cultural traditions, levels of

economic development, political institutions and government policies. Since there are no

substantial differences in history, culture and institutions between Chinese provinces, we only

focus here on the economic and policy controls. Similar to Goel and Nelson (1998), we use

provincial per capita expenditures for police, procuratorate, court and judiciary to proxy

anticorruption efforts of each province. This is insofar also important as we are focusing on

                                                            81  Theoretically conviction rates and the number of registered cases of corruption are different. However in China they are actually the same. In most cases in China suspect officials are first investigated by the discipline inspection commission of the Chinese Communist Party and its local branches. Only after they have obtained enough evidence, the discipline inspection commissions will refer corrupt cases to the procuratorates, and procuratorates then register the cases. Furthermore the courts and the procuratorates are both controlled by the Chinese government. Therefore in few circumstances the courts will reject public prosecutions against corrupt cases.  

Page 144: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

  

134

registered cases on corruption (influenced by regional anticorruption efforts). According to the

two comprehensive studies on the causes of corruption, Treisman (2000) and Glaeser and Saks

(2005), more educated and richer areas have less corruption. These studies also suggest

government regulation and the relative wage of the public sector as potential determinants of

corruption. Ades and Di Tella (1999) show the tendency that an increase in economic rents, due

to the resource abundance or a decrease in competition, leads to an increase in corruption.

Furthermore, Fisman and Gatti (2002) find that, contrary to Treisman (2000), fiscal

decentralization depresses corruption in America. As mentioned in the introduction, Brunetti,

and Weder (2003) also show that the media substantially controls corruption. Finally, Swamy,

Knack, Lee and Azfar (2001) find that countries with more parliamentary seats held by women

tend to have less corruption. We therefore control for such potential determinants of corruption.

The detailed description of all the explanatory variables is presented in Table 6-2. We measure

the female representation in politics in Chinese provinces with the female representation in the

National People’s Congress, the only legislative house in China. In line with Zhang and Zou

(1998) we use the ratio of per capita provincial government expenditure to per capital central

government expenditure to proxy fiscal decentralization among provinces.

Because the definition and thus statistical calibre of the crime of corruption and bribery was

changed with a 1997 amendment to China’s criminal law, we ensure comparability by

collecting data only for 1998 to 2007. Looking at the summary of corruption levels by region,

there is a fairly wide degree of regional variation that ranges from 1.77 in Tibet to 5.01 in

Tianjin (see Table 6-4 in the Appendix).

Table 6-2 Variables description, 1998—2007 Variable Description Mean Std. Dev. Source

Cases Provincial registered cases on corruption in the procurator’s office per 100,000 population

3.14 0.96 China Procuratorial Yearbook

Border Unweighted average of Cases in neighbouring provinces 3.04 0.64 Anticorruption Per capita expenditure for police, procuratorate, court and

judiciary 112.43 103.41

China Statistical Yearbook

Income Logarithm of the per capita gross provincial product 9.15 0.63 Education Fraction of the population over 6 with college completed 5.44 4.31 Wage Ratio of the government employee’ wage to the average

wage 1.13 0.13

Openness Ratio of export to gross provincial product 14.45 22.62 Decentralization Ratio of per capita provincial consolidated spending to per

capita central consolidated spending 38.20 19.52

Resource The fraction of employment in the mining sector 4.93 3.75 Regulation Relationship between the market and the government 6.72 2.04 Fan, Wang, and Zhu

(2010) Media Annual newspapers circulation per capita 41.38 88.07 China Statistical

Yearbook Female Female representation in the National People’s Congress 0.22 0.041

Page 145: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

  

135

Our basic specification is as follows:

, =α Casesi,t-1 + , + ,′ β , 6 17

where i and t denote provinces and years respectively and j is the lag value. however

indicates unobserved province fixed effects. The vector , includes all control variables

discussed above. We choose one-year lagged values for explanatory variables because there

must be intensive investigations before the corruption cases are registered in the procurator’s

offices.

We first perform pooled OLS to obtain primary results. However, to identify the causal

effect of social interaction on corruption, we need to address the endogeneity problem in our

estimation. We first include province fixed effects in our panel regressions to control for the

unobserved provincial characteristics influencing both corruption and its determinants

especially social interaction to deal with potential endogeneity biases. Mo (2001, p. 70)

describes a corruption problem as “an institutional problem that lasts for a long period”. Thus,

since the major source of potential bias in our regressions may be time-invariant historical

factors, we choose fixed-effect regressions as the most suitable tool for investigating the

relationship between corruption and social interactions.

However, fixed effect regressions do not necessarily estimate the causal effect of social

interaction on corruption. First, fixed effects regressions cannot remove endogeneity biases

generated by time-varying omitted factors affecting both corruption and its determinants

(especially social interaction). Second, the lagged independent variable Casesi,t-1 is indeed

correlated with , for s , which according to Wooldridge (2002), biases our fixed effects

OLS estimation. The standard strategy to deal with such potential biases is the instrumental

variables method. Anderson and Hsiao (1981) suggest to first-difference the equation like 6-17

to remove individual effects:

∆ , =α ∆Casesi,t-1 + ∆ , +∆ ,′ β ∆ , 6 18

Casesi,t-2 is then used as the instrument for ∆Casesi,t-1 to obtain more consistent estimates since

it is uncorrelated with ∆ , as long as , are not serially correlated. However, the instrumental

variable estimator suggested by Anderson and Hsiao (1981) is not efficient because all further

lags of , can also be used as additional instruments since they are uncorrelated with ∆ , .

Arellano and Bond (1991) therefore derive a GMM estimator with all these instruments to

estimate the model more efficiently than the Anderson and Hsiao (1981) estimator.

Furthermore, based on Arellano and Bover (1995), Blundell and Bond (1998) develop a system

GMM estimator since the above lagged-level instruments in the Arellano and Bond (1991)

Page 146: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

  

136

estimator becomes weak when the autoregressive process is too persistent in the dynamic

model. In their system estimator lagged differences are used as instruments for the level

equation such as 6-17 while the lagged levels are used as instruments for an equation such as 6-

18. We therefore estimate our model with this Arellano-Bover/Blundel-Bond system estimator.

In our case the lags of , are used as its instruments since there might be a reverse

causality between , and , . Using the same method we instrument some of other

corruption determinants, namely income, education, openness and regulation which might

potentially be endogenous.

The correlation matrix (Table 6-5) in the Appendix indicates potential multicollinearity

issues. To minimize the consequence of multicollinearity, we first adopt a parsimonious

specification including only measures of social interactions and anticorruption efforts. Then

some control variables which are not highly correlated with each other are added into the

specification. Finally we run regressions with all the discussed control variables. The process

allows us also to better check the robustness of the results.

6.3.2 Results

The findings are presented in Table 6-3. We start with OLS estimation to obtain primary results

(see specification (1), (4), and (7)). Then fixed effects regressions are performed to deal with a

potential endogeneity bias (see specification (2), (5) and (8)). Finally, the Arellano-

Bover/Blundel-Bond system estimator is used to get the results (see (3), (6), and (9)). In the

first three result columns of Table 6-3 we run regressions with a parsimonious specification

where corruption mainly depends on social interaction when anticorruption efforts are

controlled. In the second three columns we only include control variables which are not highly

correlated with other explanatory variables into our specification to minimize multicollinearity.

In the third three columns of Table 6-3, results of the full specification are presented.

Overall the results presented in Table 6-3 indicate that there is a positive and highly

statistically significant relationship between social interactions and corruption. Both, global and

local interactions matter and the findings are quite robust through all the specifications.

Furthermore, the effect of social interaction on corruption is sizable. Other things being equal,

one standard deviation increase in local interaction ( , ) raises provincial registered

cases on corruption per 100,000 people between 41% and 78% of a standard deviation, while

an increment of global interaction , by one standard deviation is associated with an

extra 11% to23% increase of a standard deviation in provincial registered cases on corruption

Page 147: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

  

137

per 100,000 people. Thus, it looks as if social interaction is a key element in understanding

corruption.

Besides the social interaction, other explanatory variables are also observed to generally

have the expected effects on corruption in our econometric analysis82 . The results in the

regressions indicate that anticorruption efforts and fiscal decentralization significantly decrease

corruption, while resource abundance is observed to substantially increase corruption.

According to the Arellano-Bover/Blundell-Bond estimation in Column (6) and (9), though

insignificant, deregulation, the relative wage of the public sector and female representation in

the National People’s Congress are negatively correlated with corruption.. In Column (9),

education reduces corruption, while higher income is weakly correlated with the higher

incidence of corruption (not statistically significant), which seems to contradict most previous

studies. Such a result might be driven by the transitional nature of Chinese society. Actually

countries making the transition to a market economy often experience unprecedented corruption

(Levin and Satarov 2000; Paldam and Svendsen 2000). China specifically began its transitional

process when economic reform loosened up its economy; however, political reform has lagged

behind. Therefore, in the absence of institutional and legal constraints, the government

continues to play an extensive role in China’s economic environment. One unavoidable

consequence of such an involvement is corruption, a type of corruption that becomes more

pervasive when government power is widened through increased economic activity. As a result,

regions with higher income levels may be more corrupt. Trade openness and media variables in

our regression (9) had an unexpected sign, which might be due to multicollinearity. In effect, in

Column (10) and (11) when trade openness and media are included without other highly

correlated variables, they both have expected signs and are even statistically significant.

                                                            82 Although some are not statistically significant.  

Page 148: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

138  

Table 6-3 Corruption and social interaction Annual Cases (1998—2007)

Pooled OLS

Fixed effects OLS

Arellano-Bond GMM

Pooled OLS

Fixed effects OLS

Arellano- Bond GMM

Pooled OLS

Fixed effects OLS

Arellano-Bond GMM

Arellano-Bond GMM

Arellano-Bond GMM

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) (10) (11)

Casest-1 0.81*** 0.43*** 0.64*** 0.78*** 0.41*** 0.58*** 0.74*** 0.41*** 0.52*** 0.64*** 0.64*** (0.040) (0.064) (0.11) (0.043) (0.063) (0.11) (0.046) (0.064) (0.078) (0.12) (0.11) Bordert 0.16*** 0.35*** 0.31*** 0.17*** 0.23** 0.34*** 0.12** 0.22* 0.24** 0.42*** 0.34** (0.044) (0.11) (0.11) (0.046) (0.12) (0.092) (0.049) (0.12) (0.10) (0.15) (0.14) Anticorruptiont-1 -0.0014*** -0.0021*** -0.0018*** -0.00089*** -0.0016* -0.00027 -0.0029*** -0.0015 -0.0017 (0.00029) (0.00071) (0.00043) (0.00033) (0.00087) (0.00077) (0.00094) (0.0017) (0.0020) Resourcet-1 0.011 0.072** 0.075** 0.015 0.072** 0.090*** (0.0098) (0.031) (0.036) (0.0100) (0.032) (0.029) Decentralizationt-1 -0.014** -0.025*** -0.020*** -0.018*** -0.025*** -0.020*** -0.020** -0.021*** (0.0060) (0.0035) (0.0062) (0.0041) (0.0039) (0.0070) (0.0085) (0.0074) Regulationt-1 -0.015 -0.063* -0.043 -0.052** -0.035 -0.071 (0.012) (0.035) (0.046) (0.022) (0.040) (0.048) Femalet-1 -0.52 0.57 -0.48 -0.79 0.43 -2.79 -0.75 -0.071 (0.95) (1.15) (2.11) (1.02) (1.21) (1.99) (2.53) (1.92) Waget-1 0.021 0.43 -0.23 -0.077 0.37 -0.32 -0.88 -0.74 (0.20) (0.37) (0.59) (0.23) (0.38) (0.45) (0.64) (0.59) Incomet-1 0.17 -0.065 0.073 (0.11) (0.22) (0.26) Educationt-1 0.0100 -0.027 -0.052* (0.018) (0.031) (0.031) Opennesst-1 0.0062** 0.0037 0.020** -0.0046* (0.0027) (0.0051) (0.0085) (0.0025) Mediat-1 -0.000026 -0.0037 0.000044 -0.0024* (0.00060) (0.0030) (0.0012) (0.0015) Constant 0.23 0.91** 0.35 0.40 0.82 0.62 -0.36 1.62 1.33 0.81 1.05 (0.15) (0.37) (0.28) (0.30) (0.69) (1.03) (0.77) (2.06) (2.19) (0.92) (0.80) AR(2)Test [0.21] [0.18] [0.20] [0.17] [0.16] R-squared 0.77 0.83 0.78 0.84 0.78 0.85 Observations 279 279 279 277 277 277 276 276 276 278

Notes: Robust standard errors in parentheses; p-values in brackets; ***, **, and * denote significance at 1%, 5%, and 10%, respectively.

Page 149: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

139  

6.4 Conclusion

In this chapter, we explore both theoretically and empirically whether social interaction

influences the incidence of corruption in China. We first present an interaction-based model on

corruption that leads to the theoretical prediction that corruption is positively associated with

social interaction. We differentiate in the chapter between local interaction (proxied as the

lagged corruption values as closely interacting bureaucrats are bureaucrats within the same

region), and global interaction (average of corruption levels in neighbour provinces). Then we

test the theoretical prediction applying an empirical analysis using province-level data in China

over the period 1998 to2007. Empirical evidence clearly indicates that social interactions, both

local and global interaction, have a significantly positive effect on the corruption rate in China.

Our findings therefore underscore the relevance of social interaction, an aspect that has long

been discussed in economics (see, e.g., Smith, 1759/1976, Veblen, 1899 and Duesenberry,

1949). Interestingly, many traditional models have treated cooperation or compliance with rules

as an isolated case. However, individuals do not normally act as isolated individuals playing a

game against nature.. The behaviour of others (individuals or regions) is important to

understand compliance. Hence, theories of pro-social behaviour, which take the impact of

behaviour or the preferences of others into account, are promising. The concept of pro-social

behaviour can be widely applied in daily life. For example, the broken windows theory suggests

that “signs of inappropriate behaviour like graffiti or broken windows lead to other

inappropriate behaviour (e.g. litter or stealing)” (Keizer et al. 2008, p.1685). The theory has

strongly influenced law enforcement strategies in several US cities such as New York, Chicago,

Baltimore, Boston and Los Angeles aiming at maintaining order by dealing more aggressively

with minor offenses (Harcourt and Ludwig 2006).

There are important policy implications based on our findings. Regional corruption is

affected by neighbourhood corruption. Successful anti-corruption activities in one area have

positive spillover effects on reducing corruption in other (contiguous) areas. To efficiently

control corruption neighbouring areas should either coordinate their individual anti-corruption

efforts with regional agreements or policy makers should take spillover effects into account

when allocating resources. This is particularly relevant when corruption is widespread. On the

other hand, a critical mass of cooperative behaviour (low level of corruption) can induce a

positive dynamic process of conditional cooperation. Moreover, previous corruption levels have

a significant effect on the current corruption level. Evolution of corruption is a path-dependent

process. Policies should take such path-dependent processes within a society into account. The

Page 150: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

  

140

closer a region is to the threshold or tipping point, the easier it is to influence the dynamic

conditional cooperative processes. However, identifying such a tipping point is not without

problems. A possibility is to change underlying institutional conditions at the local level. In

general, rigorous anti-corruption measures need to be carried out over a long period to control

corruption in areas where corruption is pandemic. As suggested by Aidt (2003), a “big push”

like the one that took place in Hong Kong in the 1970s, might be needed to address the

corruption levels in areas where previous corruption rates have been high.

Page 151: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

141  

Appendix

Table 6-4 Average annual registered cases on corruption per capita across regions in China (1998-2007)

Region Average annual registered cases per 100,000 Pop.

Region Average annual registered cases per 100,000 Pop.

Region Average annual registered cases per 100,000 Pop.

Tianjin 5.01 Shaanxi 3.15 Yunnan 2.61

Heilongjiang 4.77 Qinghai 3.08 Hunan 2.59

Jilin 4.50 Ningxia 3.08 Hainan 2.59

Liaoning 4.12 Hubei 3.05 Beijing 2.59

Shanxi 3.83 Guizhou 2.95 Chongqing 2.49

Hebei 3.67 Zhejiang 2.91 Anhui 2.36

Shandong 3.62 Inner Mongolia

2.77 Sichuan 2.35

Xinjiang 3.41 Shanghai 2.77 Gansu 2.05

Fujian 3.40 Jiangsu 2.71 Guangdong 2.05

Henan 3.35 Guangxi 2.64 Tibet 1.77

Jiangxi 3.29

Table 6-5 Pairwise correlation coefficients between variables Corruption Border Anticorruption Income Education Wage Openness Regulation Media Resource Female Decentralization

Corruption 1.00 Border 0.32 1.00 Anticorruption -0.20 0.25 1.00 Income 0.04 0.34 0.78 1.00 Education 0.06 0.44 0.79 0.75 1.00 Wage -0.05 0.01 0.23 0.38 0.14 1.00 Openness -0.08 0.42 0.76 0.75 0.81 0.27 1.00 Regulation -0.15 -0.03 0.25 0.54 0.33 0.31 0.39 1.00 Media -0.06 0.40 0.58 0.51 0.78 0.09 0.75 0.15 1.00 Resource 0.39 0.04 -0.37 -0.30 -0.22 -0.33 -0.43 -0.27 -0.26 1.00 Female -0.24 0.23 0.19 0.14 0.24 0.20 0.29 0.08 0.49 -0.15 1.00 Decentralization -0.08 0.28 0.52 0.39 0.46 0.01 0.46 -0.08 0.41 -0.18 0.17 1.00

Page 152: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

142  

Chapter Seven Consequences of Corruption: Chinese Evidence83

 

7.1 Introduction

States, whether they are benevolent or repressive are in a position of having control over the

distribution of benefits and costs and therefore hold a certain level of discretionary power

which can in turn lead to corruption (Rose-Ackerman, 1999). Thus, corruption is a widely

observed phenomenon in all manner of different societies. In this chapter we are going to focus

on China. It has been stressed that corruption has become more rampant in China since

economic reform was launched in 1978. The Chinese Government has admitted that corruption

“is now worse than during any other period since New China was founded in 1949. It has

spread into the Party, into government administration and into every part of society, including

politics, economy, ideology and culture” (Guoqing Liang, 1994, p. 122). Widespread

corruption has caused severe consequences in China. According to Hu (2001), the economic

loss due to corruption in China was estimated in the late 1990s to be between 13.2 and 16.8%

of Chinese’s GDP. Although many articles have emerged about corruption in China (e.g.,

Yao’s 2002 theoretical paper and Cai, Fang and Xu’s 2009 empirical paper), there is still a lack

of systematic analysis on the consequences of corruption in China. Such a shortcoming reduces

the possibility for policy makers to assess the exact magnitude of the harmfulness of corruption

in China and therefore to derive anti-corruption strategies that are suitable for China.

In general, there has been an increasing number of economic studies on the consequences of

corruption since the 1990s, most of which focus on the effect of corruption on economic

development. The transformation of the socialist economies was one of the main reasons for

this surge in interest since institutional weaknesses and corruption surfaced as major obstacles

to market reforms and economic development (Abed and Gupta, 2002). Studies have emerged

which explored the relationship between economic growth and corruption (Mauro, 1995). Most

of these studies work with cross-sectional data using common corruption proxies such as the TI,

the ICRG and the World Bank Quality of Governance ratings (control of corruption). Such

indices reflect an indirect way of measuring corruption focusing mainly as Tanzi (2002, p. 39)

stresses on “perceptions and not objective and quantitative measures of corruption”. Naturally,

one can therefore criticize that such data is subject to many biases. Treisman (2007), for

example, pointed out that corruption perception data actually reflects impressions of the

                                                            83 This chapter has been submitted to the China Journal. 

Page 153: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

  

143

intensity of corruption instead of the corruption phenomenon itself. They measure beliefs that

may be driven by other social and economic conditions (see also Knack, 2006). In other words,

if the meaning of corruption is subjective, the values can vary among countries consequently

reducing the possibility of comparing the level of corruption among countries (Glaeser and

Saks, 2006). This, therefore, also reduces the effectiveness of statistical analysis. Cross-

country estimations may also be affected by omitted variable biases. Enormous unobservable or

unmeasurable differences in institutions and cultures between countries may also induce

estimation biases. Institutional and cultural frameworks that typify specific countries might

influence the size of corruption. Such features cannot always be controlled in a satisfactory

manner. In other words homogeneity reduces omitted variable biases. It may be useful to

complement such studies with within-country data. We therefore present within country

evidence focusing on China. Interestingly, not many studies have used within country data. It

certainly requires there to exist a significant level of within country variation as well as a

regional institutional structure. The U.S. with its 50 states provides, for example, an interesting

case study. Glaeser and Saks (2006) therefore explore corruption in America using information

on the amount of corruption in each of the states in the U.S. to explore state characteristics that

are associated with corruption and how corruption affects the economic development at the

state level. Once one focuses on within country data, alternative proxies of corruption can be

evaluated. The strength is the ability to focus on more concrete measures of corruption. Glaeser

and Saks (2006) use the number of government officials convicted for corruption practices

through the Federal justice department. The obvious shortcoming of such a variable is that the

proxy is driven by the quality and efficiency of the judicial system itself. If the judicial system

is inefficient or even corrupt, a large share of corrupt activities remains unobserved. Regional

differences in the efficiency of the judicial system may also bias within country comparisons.

One way to deal with this problem is to focus, as done by Glaeser and Saks (2006), on federal

convictions where one can assume that the federal judicial system is relatively isolated from

local corruption, therefore treating similar people across regions or in their case across states.

Nevertheless, it is still unclear whether and to what extent local information and efforts have

helped to reveal corruption that was treated at the federal judicial system.

Studying China may provide obvious advantages. On the one hand, China is a centralized

country with unified legal and administrative systems, which is dominated by the Han

nationality with Confucian values in most of its regions (for the detailed evidence, see

http://english.gov.cn/about.htm). Specifically, in China the heads of local governments are

actually determined by the central government and their promotions depend mainly on whether

Page 154: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

  

144

they can faithfully carry out the regulations and policies of the central government. Furthermore,

the Supreme People's Court supervises local people's courts and actually exerts crucial

influence on the appointment and removal of the presidents and vice presidents of local people's

courts. In addition to this the Supreme People's Procuratorate has a similar but an even stronger

impact on local people's procuratorates. All of these factors ensure the homogeneity of the

Chinese political and judicial systems across the various regions. It therefore also minimizes the

potentially omitted-variable bias in the econometric analysis. On the other hand, there are great

economic differences between the rich Eastern provinces and the poor Western provinces. The

American data, which focuses on states, reduces the possibility of generalizing the results to

global differences in corruption and on the economic development across countries. Glaeser

and Saks (2006, p. 1054), for example, state: “No state today is as poor or as corrupt as many

countries in the developing world, and so relying on variation across the states in the US limits

research to a small part of the distribution of both independent and dependent variables”.

Compared to the U.S., we observe in China a stronger variance in the economic conditions

which may help to increase the generalizability of the results. Table 7-1, for example, shows

that the GDP per capita of Shanghai, which is close to that of Hungary, is nearly nine times as

high as the GDP per capita of Guizhou province, which approximates that of Cameroon.

Table 7-1 GDP (PPP) per capita of Chinese regions in 2008 (Intl. $)

Beijing 16577 Anhui 3810 Chongqing 4741

Tianjin 14590 Fujian 7922 Sichuan 4044

Hebei 6112 Jiangxi 3887 Guizhou 2321

Shanxi 5365 Shandong 8701 Yunnan 3310

Inner Mongolia 8472 Henan 5153 Tibet 3646

Liaoning 8221 Hubei 5223 Shaanxi 4799

Jilin 6184 Hunan 4608 Gansu 3185

Heilongjiang 5714 Guangdong 9886 Qinghai 4573

Shanghai 19232 Guangxi 3936 Ningxia 4706

Jiangsu 10421 Hainan 4517 Xinjiang 5232

Zhejiang 11102

The key innovative aspect of this chapter is hence to provide within country rather than

cross-country evidence, focusing on the impact of corruption on the development in China

using both provincial and city-level data. The diversity of China allows us to explore corruption

in a within-country environment. This allows, compared to cross-country studies, a better

control for unobserved culture or institutional differences, since it holds them constant. In

addition, we are going to explore how corruption affects a large set of factors such as economic

development, income inequality, public expenditures, foreign direct investment, and pollution.

Page 155: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

  

145

Glaeser and Saks (2006) found a weak negative association between corruption and

economic growth in the US. Fisman and Svensson (2007), using the survey data from Ugandan

firms, found that bribery is negatively correlated with firm growth. With a survey of Chinese

firms (World Bank, 2006), Cai, Fang and Xu (2009) employed the entertainment and travel cost

of Chinese firms as a proxy for corruption measure and found that corruption substantially

decreases firm performance in China. We will conduct a similar empirical approach as Glaeser

and Saks (2006) to increase the comparability of the results. The chapter is structured as

follows: Section 7.2 reviews related literature. Section 7.3 presents empirical analysis. Section

7.4 concludes.

7.2 Literature Review

Corruption has significant influences on many aspects of societies (Lambsdorff, 2005). We will

focus here on its impact on economic development, which is a major concern in China since it

is the largest developing country in the world. According to Deardorff (2006), and Myint and

Krueger (2009)84, economic development is the increase in the economic, political, and social

well-being of people in a country with sustained growth from a simple, poor country into a

modern, prosperous country. Its scope includes economic growth, income distribution, public

goods (public expenditures) and environmental quality. Here we will provide a short literature

review on the influence of corruption in these subareas of economic development.

Economic growth is a fundamental part of economic development. Economic growth

always improves the living standard of the public by increasing both private income and social

services. Poor countries may experience economic growth without development in some cases.

No country, however, can sustain economic development without growth. It is therefore

important to investigate the impact of corruption on economic growth when studying the

relationship between corruption and economic development. There is indeed an existing

theoretical debate on the effect of corruption on economic growth. Some authors emphasize

that corruption can promote economic growth (“grease the wheels”). Leff (1964) and

Huntington (1968) argue that bribes can be used as an incentive instrument to influence public

officials, inducing an improvement in the quality of civil services. Lui (1985) also shows in his

model that bribes can efficiently accelerate the bureaucratic process. However, one can criticize

that bureaucrats have an incentive to delay transactions in order to extract higher payments (see

                                                            84    Deardorff, A., 2006. Economic development. Deardorff’s Glossary of International Economics.

(http://www-personal.umich.edu/~alandear/glossary/e.html) Myint, H., Krueger, A.O., 2009. Economic development. Encyclopædia Britannica. (http://www.britannica.com/EBchecked/topic/178361/economic-development) 

Page 156: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

  

146

Rose-Ackerman, 1997). Other researchers stress that corruption decreases economic growth

(“sand the wheels”). For example, Murphy, Shleifer and Vishny (1991) point out that most

talented people are allocated into rent-seeking activities instead of productive ones in corrupt

societies. It therefore lowers economic growth since the unproductive rent seeking activities

only bring positive returns to the rent seekers instead of to the whole society (Krueger, 1974).

From a different angle, Shleifer and Vishny (1993) stated that corrupt officials may distort

investment projects to those offering better opportunities for corruption. In other words, corrupt

bureaucracy will not award the services to the most efficient producers, but instead to the

producer who offers the largest bribes. In general, most of the empirical literature supports a

negative association between corruption and economic growth. Mauro (1995) finds empirically

that corruption lowers productive investment significantly thus also reducing economic growth.

Mo (2001) reports further that through the channels of political instability, the level of human

capital and the share of private investment, corruption significantly hinders economic growth.

Pellegrini and Gerlagh (2004) also provide evidence that corruption reduces economic growth

via its effect on investment and trade policy. Recently, a number of studies stress that the

correlation between corruption and growth is conditional on the institutional quality. Meon and

Sekkat (2005) observe that corruption depresses economic growth especially in countries with a

low quality of governance. However, Mendez and Sepulveda (2006) find a quadratic

relationship between corruption and growth in free countries instead of not-free ones, which

implies the existence of the growth maximizing level of corruption. Aidt, Dutta and Sena (2008)

using a threshold model report that corruption exerts a significant negative effect on economic

growth in regimes with good governance, while having no effect on growth in regimes with

poor governance. Moreover, Meon and Weill (2008) provide empirical evidence using a panel

of 54 countries that corruption is beneficial (or at least less harmful) in countries with weak

institutions. These papers provide indirect evidence that supports the “grease the wheels”

hypothesis insofar as corruption is only beneficial in weak institutions while being harmful

elsewhere (Aidt, 2009).

As an engine of economic growth, foreign direct investment is suggested to be negatively

correlated with corruption in previous literature. Field, Sosa and Wu (2006) employed a Nash

bargaining game to find that the corruption in a host country influences the competitiveness of

foreign firms and thus also affects their expected profits in the host market. Consequently the

decisions of foreign firms to invest in a country are affected by the corruption level of the host.

Empirically, using two-year bilateral flows between 14 source and 45 host countries, Wei

(2000a) found a significantly negative association between perceived corruption in hosts and

Page 157: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

  

147

inbound foreign direct investment. Corruption acts like a tax on FDI reducing the attractiveness

of FDI. Smarzynska and Wei (2000) also provided firm-level evidence that corruption impedes

inbound FDI and moves the ownership structure to joint ventures. Habib and Zurawicki (2002)

utilized a sample of 89 countries to find the negative effect of corruption on FDI, while Akcay

(2001) failed to identify a statistically significant link between corruption and FDI.

Furthermore, Egger and Winner (2005) analysed the impact of corruption on FDI with a sample

of 73 countries and detected a clear positive relationship between corruption and inward FDI.

However, noting that FDI is an indicator of openness, Larrain and Tavares (2004, 2007)

presented cross-country evidence that there exists reverse causation between corruption and

FDI. Due to the regional data and regional differences in China researchers may be able to

explore the relationship between corruption and FDI within a country rather than focusing on

cross-country evidence. Cole, Elliott and Zhang (2009) indeed have found that FDI is attracted

to the provinces with greater anti-corruption efforts in their within China analysis.

Being an important indicator of economic development, income distribution also influences

economic growth (Barro, 2000). Corruption, however, is observed to significantly affect the

income distribution. As discussed, better connected people in society have increased

opportunity and incentives to bribe and belong mainly to the high-income groups within a

country (Tanzi, 1995). This could lead to a reduction in the level of social services available to

the poor (Rose-Ackerman, 1999). For example, in China under the Mandarins, as in medieval

Europe, wealthy individuals in society choose their principal career in government services

where it was possible to generate bribes and tax revenues for private benefits (Baumol, 1990).

Dabla-Norris and Wade (2002) show that in the absence of credit markets only wealthy agents

have the chance to overcome the nonconvexity in income-earning possibilities (“born into rent-

seeking”, p. 454). Li, Xu and Zou (2000) used a variant of the rent-seeking model developed by

Murphy, Shleifer and Vishny (1993) to conclude that corruption influences income inequality

in a reversed U-shape way. Furthermore, they presented empirical evidence to support this

although the quadratic terms of corruption indicators were not significant in most of their

specifications (Begovic, 2006). In general, however, we still observe a lack of empirical

evidence on how corruption affects income inequality. Based on the discussion about the

channels through which corruption influences income inequality, Gupta, Davoodi and Alonso-

Terme (2002) provided robust cross-country evidence that corruption monotonically increases

income inequality. We add to the literature an analysis that uses within country data instead of

cross-country data to better isolate the unobserved institutional and cultural factors.

 

Page 158: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

  

148

Public expenditures actually have a twofold effect on economic development. On the one

hand, Public expenditures such as those on infrastructure, education and science stimulate

economic growth. On the other hand, public expenditures such as those on health and other

social services improve the social wellbeing of the public. Corruption can substantially

influence public expenditures. It can “adversely affect the provision of publicly provided social

services” (Gupta, Davoodi, and Tiongson, 2002, p. 245). Mauro (1998) stresses that measuring

the effects of corruption on the composition of government expenditure may help to quantify

the severity of the principal-agent problem between citizens and politicians. He argued that

corrupt politicians may increase the government expenditure that it is easier to collect bribes

from and decrease the expenditure which provides fewer bribery opportunities. For example,

corrupt officials will choose goods whose exact value is difficult to monitor to maintain secrecy.

Moreover, classical rents such as the allocation of transfer and welfare payments enjoy

substantial discretionary power. Mauro (1998) presented evidence that corruption significantly

reduces government expenditure on education due to the fact that education does not provide as

many lucrative opportunities for corrupt officials compared to other spending components.

Corruption also reduces spending on operations and maintenance and increases large

government capital spending (Tanzi and Davoodi, 1997). On the other hand, Gupta, de Mello

and Sharan (2001) using a panel of 120 countries during 1985–1998, found that corruption is

positively correlated with government spending on the military.

Now we turn to the relationship between corruption and the environment quality, an

important qualitative indicator of economic development. Lopez and Mitra (2000) studied

cooperative and non-cooperative interactions between government and private firms and

conclude that introducing corruption moves the Kuznets environmental curve up: the pollution

level corresponding to every income level is constantly above the socially optimal level due to

corruption. Considering both the direct effect of corruption on pollution and the indirect effect

of corruption which influences pollution by reducing per capita income, Welsch (2004) found

with simultaneous equations that the direct effect of corruption on pollution was positive while

the indirect effect of corruption is either positive or negative and was also numerically smaller.

Therefore corruption aggravates pollution overall, especially in developing countries. However,

with the similar empirical strategy but controlling the endogeneity problems in regressions,

Cole (2007) provides cross-country evidence that the positive direct impact of corruption on air

pollution emissions is dominated by the negative indirect impact of corruption. The total effect

of corruption on air pollution emissions is hence negative in the countries that are not the

Page 159: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

  

149

richest. This contradicting evidence demands an investigation into the actual mechanism for the

relationship between corruption and pollution.

It is quite possible that bureaucratic corruption affects pollution mainly through

environment policy making since special interest groups often exert undue influence on policy

makers by lobbying and offering bribes. This is another symptom of corruption. Several studies

about the influence of corruption on the formation of environment policy have therefore

emerged. Pellegrini and Gerlagh (2006a, b) found empirically with cross sectional samples that

corruption has a substantially negative effect which is more significant and larger in magnitude

than that of income and democracy on the stringency of the environment policy. Considering

the interactions between corruption and political stability, trade liberalization and FDI

respectively, Fredriksson and Svensson (2003), Damania, Fredriksson and List (2003) and Cole,

Elliott and Fredriksson (2006) provided both theoretical evidence from the lobbying models

and empirical evidence from the cross-country analyses that corruption not only significantly

reduces the stringency of environmental policy but also modifies the effects of other

determinants of environment policy such as political stability, trade liberalization and FDI.

Furthermore Fredriksson, Vollebergh and Dijkgraaf (2004) adopted a similar approach to find

theoretically and empirically that corruption reduces the stringency of energy policy thus

lowering energy efficiency. Indeed, the existing literature on the linkage between corruption

and the stringency of environmental policy concludes that institutional quality influences the

way policy makers respond to environmental concerns. Since the formation of environmental

policy is likely to be ‘representative of many other forms of government decision making’

(Fredriksson and Svensson, 2003), results here might be illuminative in the research of the

relationship between corruption and other public policies.

7.3 Empirical Analysis

7.3.1 Data and Methodology

China is administratively divided into 22 provinces, 5 autonomous regions and 4 municipalities,

all of which are placed directly under the Central Government. A province or an autonomous

region is subdivided into (autonomous) prefectures and/or prefecture-level cities. In this chapter

we will use two different regional data sets to explore the causes of corruption in China. The

first one is a province-level data set which consists of all 31 provincial areas in the mainland of

China. To ensure the comparability of the data, we collected data only from 1998 to 2007 as the

definition and hence the statistical calibre of the crime of corruption and bribery was changed in

1997 due to an amendment to the Criminal Law of China. It should also be noted that we have

Page 160: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

  

150

not included data from Hongkong, Macao and Taiwan due to the obvious differences in the

political and legal systems between these areas and other parts of China.

In this dataset, corruption data are derived from the China Procuratorial Yearbooks. We

collected the number of annual registered cases on corruption in procurator’s office by region.

Glaeser and Saks (2006, p. 1058) state: “Because the conviction data are less subjective, cover

a longer time span, and are not subject to the problems of sampling error and survey non-

response, we believe that using these data has distinct advantages over the survey-based

evidence”. We then divided these registered cases by the regional population in order to obtain

the regional registered corruption cases rate per 100,000 people. An overview of ranking

corruption levels by region is presented in Table 7-2. We can observe there is a fairly wide

degree of variation across regions ranging from 1.77 in Tibet to 5.01 in Tianjin85.

Table 7-2 Average annual registered cases on corruption per capita across regions in China (1998-2007)

Region Average annual registered cases per 100,000 Pop.

Region Average annual registered cases per 100,000 Pop.

Region Average annual registered cases per 100,000 Pop.

Tianjin 5.01 Shaanxi 3.15 Yunnan 2.61

Heilongjiang 4.77 Qinghai 3.08 Hunan 2.59

Jilin 4.50 Ningxia 3.08 Hainan 2.59

Liaoning 4.12 Hubei 3.05 Beijing 2.59

Shanxi 3.83 Guizhou 2.95 Chongqing 2.49

Hebei 3.67 Zhejiang 2.91 Anhui 2.36

Shandong 3.62 Inner Mongolia

2.77 Sichuan 2.35

Xinjiang 3.41 Shanghai 2.77 Gansu 2.05

Fujian 3.40 Jiangsu 2.71 Guangdong 2.05

Henan 3.35 Guangxi 2.64 Tibet 1.77

Jiangxi 3.29

Glaeser and Saks (2006) have shown that the conviction rates they used are positively

correlated with the survey of state house reporters’ perception of public corruption. In our case,

we check the robustness by using an alternative proxy for corruption. The second data set we

use is a data set of 120 prefecture-level cities in China which comes mainly from the survey on

the investment climate of Chinese prefecture-level cities conducted by World Bank and the

                                                            85 We here do not use the provincial number of officials investigated in registered cases on corruption per 100,000 population to measure the regional corruption levels in China, which might be closer to the approach of Glaeser and Saks (2006) since this corruption measure is only available in the period from 2003 to 2007. However, the extremely high correlation between this measure and the provincial number of registered cases on corruption per 100,000 population ensures the qualification of the provincial number of registered cases on corruption per 100,000 population as a measure of regional corruption levels in China. 

Page 161: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

  

151

Enterprise Survey Organization of China in 2005 (World Bank, 2006). The survey sampled 100

industrial firms in each city (except in four municipalities where 200 industrial firms were

sampled) to evaluate the investment climate of 120 cities covering almost all of the Chinese

provinces. In their paper, Cai, Fang and Xu (2009) used the entertainment and travel costs

relative to the sales of firms as an indirect measure of corruption in Chinese firms since

“Chinese managers commonly use the entertainment and travel costs accounting category to

reimburse expenditures used to bribe government officials, to entertain clients and suppliers, or

to accommodate managerial excess” (Cai, Fang and Xu, 2009, p.1). Similar to them, we will, in

our second data set, utilize the average value of this measure of firms investigated in the above

survey in a city as a proxy for the corruption level of the city. We refer to World Bank (2006)

for the detailed description of this measure. Other variables in our two datasets are described in

Table 7-10 in the Appendix.

To identify the casual effect of corruption, we need to address the endogeneity problem in

our econometric analysis. Our first strategy to deal with a potential endogeneity bias is to

control for unobservable province-specific factors influencing both corruption and our

dependent variables by including province fixed effects and year fixed effects in our first data

set. Mo (2001, p.70) concluded: “Corruption is commonly considered an institutional problem

that lasts for a long period.” Fixed effect regressions are therefore suitable for the investigation

of the relationship between corruption and our explained variables since the major source of

potential bias in our regressions is mainly province-specific, historical factors which are time-

invariant.

However, fixed effects regressions do not necessarily identify the causality between

corruption and our dependent variables when there are time-variant omitted factors influencing

both corruption and our dependant variables. Our second strategy hence is to adopt the

instrumental variable approach to estimate the causal effect of corruption in both data sets we

have. Commonly use instruments for corruption in the literature are, e.g., ethnolinguistic

fragmentation (for example, Mauro, 1995), origins of the country's legal system or colonial

history (for example, Wei, 2000b), and even regional dummies (for example, Mo, 2001).

However, Andrei Shleifer and William Dickens pointed out, when commenting on Wei (2000b),

that these instruments are not sufficient even if they are exogenous because they are actually

associated with all aspects of institutional quality other than corruption (p.351, Wei, 2000b).

We therefore follow the spirit of Fisman and Svensson (2007) and Cai, Fang and Xu (2009) and

use averages of corruption levels in neighbouring regions as the instrument for local corruption

levels as we are working with within-country data. This kind of approach has been widely used

Page 162: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

  

152

in various economic areas such as empirical industry organization (for example, Hausman,

Leonard and Zona, 1994, Nevo, 2001). As mentioned before, political and legal institutions in

Chinese regions are determined by the central government and hence homogeneously.

Although China is a large country, economic development and social conventions are similar in

neighbouring regions. For example, Confucian culture dominates in most Chinese regions. We

hence are able to follow previous studies to decompose a regional corruption level C into two

terms: one area-specific: C (the area here includes the region and its neighbours), and the other

particular to the region: u

  C C u

where i indicates areas, and j represents regions in one area. The first term C is a function of

the common economic, institutional, cultural and social factors in the area and can be expressed

by the average corruption values in neighbouring regions. The second term u however is the

idiosyncratic component determined by the regional characteristics. As main regional attributes

such as income, education, population, urbanization and openness are controlled in our

regressions we can plausibly assume that C is uncorrelated withu . We therefore use the

average of corruption levels in neighbouring regions C as the instrument for the regional

corruption level C . However, there is still a possibility in our provincial analysis that C is

correlated with u since Dong and Torgler (2010a) provide empirical evidence that corruption

is contagious among Chinese provinces, which implies that C also affects C in our case. We

therefore use a lagged variable: average corruption value of neighbouring regions in 1998 to

instrument the regional corruption during 1998-2007 in our provincial analysis to exclude the

possibility since provincial corruption levels in the following years cannot affect corruption

levels of their neighbouring provinces in 1998.

Because our instrument is time-invariant in the investigation period, we cannot control for

province fixed effects in our IV regressions. We instead follow Dong and Torgler (2010b) to

divide Chinese into eight areas (Northeastern China, Northern Coastal Areas of Seaboard of

China, Eastern Coastal Areas of China, Southern Coastal Areas of China, Middle Reaches of

the Yellow River, Middle Reaches of the Yangtze River, Southwestern China and Northwestern

China) and then include both area and year fixed effects in our IV regressions. Since Chinese

provinces in the same area are to a large extent homogeneous, the area fixed effects therefore

can capture most provincial characteristics.

Page 163: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

  

153

The other important identification issue that we need to address is the influence of the data

noise especially in our first provincial data set. Glaeser and Saks (2006) found “the annual

fluctuations in convictions to be too noisy to identify any interesting relationships” (p. 1062).

To mitigate the impact of data noise, we have included time fixed effects in our panel

regressions. More importantly, since the data noise, largely measurement error, is idiosyncratic

to the region (see Angrist and Krueger, 2001), using grouped averages as instruments can

provide a more consistent estimation even in the presence of measurement error.

7.3.2 Corruption, Economic Growth and Income Distribution

We first test the effect of corruption upon economic growth. Levine and Renelt (1992)

identified in their cross-country analysis three robust variables in determining growth: the

initial level of real GDP per capita related to the conditional convergence hypothesis, the

average share of investment in GDP, and education attainment as a proxy for human capital.

Demurger (2001), however, observed that trade openness and infrastructure endowment

significantly influences economic performance in Chinese provinces. Since China is now a

newly industrialized country, the difference in industrialization among the Chinese regions may

be an important reason for the difference in economic growth across them. We therefore

include all those factors as control variables in the specification when investigating the impact

of corruption upon economic growth in China. Specifically, we measure regional trade

openness using the ratio of import and export to the Gross Regional Product (GRP henceforth)

and regional education attainment as the regional share of the population how completed

college. The infrastructure endowment of Chinese regions is proxied by the average regional

road mileage per 10000 people.

We perform the provincial analysis at first. We start with a commonly used specification

that does not consider corruption to test the appropriateness of our baseline specification for the

explanation of economic growth. Then, we focus on the relationship between corruption and

economic growth. We first run pooled-OLS regressions to obtain the primary results, followed

by fixed effects regressions with province and year dummies to deal with the potential

endogeneity problem. We also adopt the IV approach is to deal with a potential endogeneity

bias using as discussed the average level of corruption in neighbouring provinces in 1998 as an

instrument for provincial corruption.

Results in Table 7-3 are in line with the consensus in growth regressions (Levine and Renelt,

1992), which justifies our specification. The negative parameter on initial income level

indicates income convergence among provinces in China. Investment and industrialization

Page 164: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

  

154

strongly encourage economic development, while education and openness insignificantly

promote economic growth. The provincial infrastructure endowment seems negatively

correlated with economic growth because high endowment of infrastructure might lead to low

infrastructure investment (a part of total investment) which is positively associated with

economic growth. More importantly, provincial corruption is observed to have a negative effect

on economic growth in China. Previous literature such as Mo (2001) and Glaeser and Saks

(2006) also provided evidence that corruption retards economic growth.

Table 7-3 Effect of corruption on economic growth: cross-province evidence

Annual Growth Rate of GRP per capita (1998—2007)

Pooled OLS

Fixed effects OLS

Pooled OLS

Fixed effects OLS

Fixed effects 2SLS

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5)

Corruption -0.00021 0.0044 -0.024*** (0.0021) (0.0029) (0.0090) Income -0.0022 -0.18*** -0.0022 -0.18*** -0.018** (0.0059) (0.029) (0.0059) (0.029) (0.0088) Education 0.0083* 0.0058 0.0084* 0.0059 0.0060 (0.0043) (0.0077) (0.0044) (0.0077) (0.0050) Investment 0.13*** 0.13*** 0.13*** 0.13*** 0.13*** (0.014) (0.023) (0.015) (0.023) (0.023) Openness -0.0027 0.011 -0.0029 0.014 0.0040 (0.0077) (0.016) (0.0081) (0.016) (0.013) Industrialisation 0.080*** 0.29*** 0.081*** 0.29*** 0.13*** (0.022) (0.080) (0.023) (0.081) (0.050) Infrastructure -0.031 -0.056** -0.031 -0.058** -0.035 (0.020) (0.024) (0.020) (0.024) (0.026) Constant 0.042 1.45*** 0.043 1.46*** 0.19** (0.044) (0.24) (0.044) (0.24) (0.077) R-squared 0.28 0.67 0.28 0.68

First stage F test of excluded IV 23.98[0.00] Anderson canon. Corr. LM statistic 22.07[0.00] Observations 310 310 310 310 310

Notes: Robust standard errors in parentheses, p-values in brackets, ***, **and * denote significance at 1%, 5% and 10% respectively. The education attainment is henceforth expressed in logarithm. All explanatory variables are hereafter lagged by one year in our panel estimations except that income variable in Columns (5) & (6) of the table is lagged by two years.

Next we check the result with the city-level dataset. We use as an alternative corruption

measure, namely the average entertainment and travel costs relative to the sales of sample firms

in Chinese cities (ETC hereafter) to re-examine the relationship between corruption and

economic growth in China. Cai, Fang and Xu (2009) found that “ETC is a mix that includes

‘grease money’ to get better government services, ‘protection money’ to lower tax rates” (p.2),

as well as other expenditures. They observed that some components of ETC promote firm

performance though the overall effect of ETC is negative. They, however, recognize that their

firm-level findings do not necessarily mean that ETC expenditures are socially “grease the

Page 165: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

  

155

wheels” or “sands the wheels”. We here attempt to locate the social influence of ETC as an

indirect corruption measure by exploring its effect on regional economic growth.

We directly investigate the effect of corruption on economic growth in Chinese cities with a

specification similar to the above. Since the corruption measure here comes from industrial

firms, we therefore focus on its effect on the growth rate of the industrial output per capita in

cities, which is highly correlated with the growth rate of GRP per capita. Following Fisman and

Svensson (2007), we add the average tax burden of firms in cities, measured by the average

taxes and fees relative to firm sales, as a control in our previous specification. Due to the lack

of education data, we however employ local public library collections per 100 people in 2003 to

proxy for general education levels in cities. Similar to the provincial analysis, we start with the

OLS regression and run the 2SLS regression afterwards. The instrumental variable we use in

the city-level analysis is the average corruption levels of other cities within the same province

(neighbouring cities)86.

Results in first three columns of Table 7-4 generally support those in Table 7-3. The

coefficient of initial industrial output per capita is significantly negative. Investment and

industrialization substantially promote economic growth, while education and trade openness

insignificantly encourage economic development. Consistent with Fisman and Svensson (2007),

the average tax burden here, though not robust, appears to lowers economic growth, while the

effect of regional infrastructure stock on economic growth seems ambiguous. More importantly,

similar to our finding in Table 7-3, corruption measured by ETC also has a negative effect on

economic growth though it is statistically insignificant. It is worth noting that our instrument

seems weak in the IV regression in Column (3). However, Imbens (2008) point out that even

with very weak instruments, 2SLS in the just-identified case is not substantively misleading

though its confidence intervals tend to be wide: “In this case better estimators are generally not

available”, while “improved methods for confidence intervals based on inverting test statistics

have been developed” (p.1). We therefore use a conditional likelihood ratio (CLR) test

proposed by Moreira (2003) which is robust to weak instruments to construct confidence

intervals. According to CLR test, the p-value of the corruption variable in Regression (3) is

0.22, which support our original finding.

Till now we only have weak evidence about the effect of corruption on economic growth.

We are therefore looking for further evidence in the next columns of Table 7-4. We utilize the

shares of firms which believe in the need for informal payment to obtain bank loans in cities                                                             86 For the four municipalities in our city-level data set, we use averages of corruption levels of their neighbour cities to instrument their corruption levels respectively. 

Page 166: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

  

156

(Loan pay) as another (indirect) corruption measure though it is constrained to the credit area.

However, most banks in China are controlled by the government. Bank managers hence act as

if they were government officials. Interestingly, this corruption measure is observed to have a

significantly positive effect on economic growth (“greases the wheels”). As discussed

previously, the informal payment to obtain bank loans is one of the “grease money”

components of the ETC measure. Its positive effect is reasonable because the larger share of

firms which believe in the need for informal payment to obtain bank loans in Chinese cities

reflects a larger opportunity for firms there to circumvent the appraisals of government banks

with bribery to obtain loans. Compared to those in cities where (government) banks are

incorrupt but bureaucratic, the firms in cities with corrupt banks make more informal payment

to bank officials and hence have easier access to bank loans though at some cost. They

consequently grow faster.

Furthermore, we also found that government red tape proxied by the average days per year

that enterprise staff must spend interacting with government bureaucracies in cities (Red tape)

significantly impedes economic growth. It is natural that firms in cities with more bureaucratic

red tape have to spend more time and money to go through or circumvent the red tape. The

money that firms have spent on red tape is of course one of the “protection money” parts of

ETC. This kind of “protection money” has a socially negative effect on economic performance

(“sands the wheels”) by a wasting productive resource although an individual firm might

benefit from it. It hence can also be labelled as the “sand money”.

Though ETC includes both “grease money” and “sand money” (“protection money”) as

discussed before, it is difficult to thoroughly isolate the two components of ETC since we do

not know the detailed composition of ETC in each firm. We nonetheless utilize a two-stage

estimation procedure to explore ETC greases and sands the wheels simultaneously in Chinese

cities. As discussed above the Loan pay variable and the Red tape variable are highly correlated

with the “grease” component and the “sand” component of ETC respectively. We hence first

run two regressions where ETC is a dependent variable and the Loan pay (grease aspect) and

the Red tape (sand component) are the independent factors respectively (see Column (4) and (5)

in Table 7-4). Then we put the fitted values of ETC in the two regressions as proxies for the

“grease” and “sand” component of ETC respectively into the previous growth regressions to

test their effects on economic growth. Results in Column (8) to (9) confirm previous

conjunctures. The proxy for the “grease” component of the ETC does have a significant

positive effect on the economic growth of Chinese cities, while the proxy for the “sand” part of

ETC indeed has a substantially negative impact on economic growth. Including the two

Page 167: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

  

157

components simultaneously into Regression (10), we find a positive and negative effect on

economic growth respectively, and the positive effect seems slightly stronger when looking at

the standardized (beta) coefficients. Such a result is consistent with our previous finding that

the corruption measured by ETC has an overall (insignificantly) negative effect on growth.

It is worth noting that the corruption measure in our first province-level data set (regional

registered cases on corruption in procurator’s office) may also be a comprehensive corruption

measure indeed since officials involved in corruption cases probably accept “grease money”

and/or “sand money”. The insignificant effect of this measure on growth supports our inference.

We, however, cannot decompose this measure as what we have done to the ETC due to the lack

of detailed information.

Above results indicate that corruption greases and sands the wheels simultaneously. The

overall effect of corruption on growth depends on which effect dominates. It appears that the

relationship between growth and corruption is not robust or even not significant in some

scenarios in China. This has also been observed by Mauro (1995) and Mo (2001), among others

in cross-country analysis. Recently, Mendez and Sepulveda (2006) and Adit, Dutta and Sena

(2008) documented in their empirical studies that the effect of corruption on economic growth

depends on the quality of institutions. We therefore may be able to plausible conclude that

corruption can have both, positive and negative effects, and the overall effect may depend on

the balance between components, which is probably determined by the institutional quality. In

sum, previous studies fail to explore single elements of corruption. An analysis as the one done

here through decomposing potential elements can provide new insights in the literature.

Page 168: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

158  

Table 7-4 Effect of corruption on economic growth: cross-city evidence Average growth rate of industrial output per capita (2004-2007) ETC Average growth rate of industrial output per capita (2004-2007) OLS OLS 2SLS OLS OLS OLS OLS OLS OLS OLS

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) (10)

ETC -0.019 -0.30 (0.040) (0.31) Loan pay 0.0051* 0.12*** (0.0031) (0.0085) Red tape -0.0011* 0.017*** (0.00065) (0.00087) Grease component 0.043* 0.052** {0.160} (0.026) (0.026) Sand component -0.067* -0.082** {-0.161} (0.039) (0.041) industrial output per capita -0.13*** -0.13*** -0.10*** -0.13*** -0.12*** -0.13*** -0.12*** -0.12*** (0.031) (0.031) (0.038) (0.033) (0.030) (0.033) (0.030) (0.031) Tax -0.040*** -0.037** 0.012 -0.041*** -0.035** -0.041*** -0.035** -0.035** (0.014) (0.016) (0.057) (0.014) (0.015) (0.014) (0.015) (0.015) Education 0.00031 0.00030 0.00013 0.00033 0.00034 0.00033 0.00034 0.00037 (0.00023) (0.00023) (0.00030) (0.00022) (0.00025) (0.00022) (0.00025) (0.00025) Investment 0.37*** 0.38*** 0.47*** 0.41*** 0.39*** 0.41*** 0.39*** 0.44*** (0.12) (0.12) (0.17) (0.12) (0.12) (0.12) (0.12) (0.13) Openness 0.015 0.015 0.0060 0.019 0.013 0.019 0.013 0.017 (0.032) (0.031) (0.033) (0.031) (0.031) (0.031) (0.031) (0.031) Industrialisation 0.64*** 0.60** 0.017 0.67*** 0.60*** 0.67*** 0.60*** 0.62*** (0.22) (0.24) (0.62) (0.21) (0.23) (0.21) (0.23) (0.22) Infrastructure 0.0046 0.0035 -0.013 0.0098 -0.00041 0.0098 -0.00041 0.0048 (0.039) (0.039) (0.041) (0.039) (0.039) (0.039) (0.039) (0.038) Constant 1.65*** 1.66*** 1.78*** 1.55*** 1.64*** 1.55*** 1.64*** 1.52*** (0.25) (0.25) (0.29) (0.27) (0.25) (0.27) (0.25) (0.27) R-squared 0.32 0.32 0.33 0.33 0.71 0.79 0.33 0.33 0.35

First Stage F test of excluded IV 3.17[0.078] Anderson canon. corr. LM statistic 3.33[0.068] Observations 118 118 118 118 118 120 120 118 118 118

Notes: Robust standard errors in parentheses, p-values in brackets, beta coefficients in braces. ***, **and * denote significance at 1%, 5% and 10% respectively. ETC, Loan pay, Red tape, and Tax are derived from World Bank (2006). Investment, Openness, and Industrialization are measured by their averages in the period 2004-2007 respectively. Education and Infrastructure are henceforth represented by their values in 2003 and 2004 respectively. And we use the 2004 value of Industrial output per capita in regressions.

Page 169: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

159  

An important issue that closely relates to economic growth is income distribution. This is

also a key aspect of economic development. Since we only have the Gini coefficients of

Chinese provinces before 2001, we have to find an alternative measure of income inequality in

our analysis. Kanbur and Zhang (1999) and Sicular, Yue, Gustafsson and Li (2007) concluded

that the urban-rural income gap is a main source of the overall inequality in China. We

therefore use the ratio of the per capita income of urban households to that of rural households

to proxy for income inequality in Chinese regions.

We adopt a specification similar to Li, Xu and Zou (2000) to examine the relationship

between corruption and income inequality. To address the reverse causality from income

inequality to corruption we adopt the IV approach in both province-level and city-level

analyses using the same instrument for corruption as in the previous regressions. It should be

noted that the results in Table 7-5 are consistent with Li, Xu and Zou (2000) and Gupta,

Davoodi and Alonso-Terme (2002) in that corruption substantially increases income inequality.

Furthermore, income, though weakly, has a negative impact on income equality, which is also

in line with previous findings such as Lundberg and Squire (2003).

Table 7-5 Effects of corruption on income inequality

Urban-rural income ratio

Province level City level

Pooled OLS

Fixed effects OLS

Fixed effects 2SLS

OLS 2SLS

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5)

Corruption -0.19*** 0.0019 0.22** 0.97* 5.82* (0.025) (0.022) (0.096) (0.58) (3.31) Income -0.55*** -0.59** -0.090 -0.55 -0.54 (0.090) (0.24) (0.11) (0.42) (0.70) Education 0.10 -0.16 -0.25*** 0.0062* 0.0062 (0.10) (0.11) (0.095) (0.0033) (0.0052) Expenditure 4.09*** -1.72 1.75*** -0.0022 -5.26 (0.41) (1.20) (0.56) (7.54) (13.38) Industrialisation 1.55*** 3.94*** -0.36 8.16 15.57 (0.34) (0.89) (0.49) (7.88) (10.21) Urbanization 0.19 -0.0035 0.72*** 0.19 -1.01 (0.18) (0.097) (0.18) (1.08) (1.98) Constant 7.19*** 6.79*** 4.00*** 2.32 -5.87 (0.67) (2.00) (0.93) (3.58) (8.29)

R-squared 0.63 0.94 0.10 First stage

F test of excluded IV 41.07[0.00] 9.88[0.00] Anderson canon. corr. LM statistic 32.71[0.00] 10.05[0.00] Observations 284 284 284 113 113

Notes: Robust standard errors in parentheses, p-values in brackets. ***, **and * denote significance at 1%, 5% and 10% respectively. In city-level analysis, Urbanization and Expenditure are hereafter represented by their values in 2003, and Income is represented by its value in 2004 henceforth.

Page 170: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

  

160  

7.3.3 Corruption and Foreign Direct Investment

Mauro (1995), Mo (2001), and Pellegrini and Gerlagh (2004) have documented the fact that

investment is the main channel through which corruption influences economic growth:

“Corruption is found to lower investment, thereby lowering economic growth” (Mauro, 1995, p.

681). We will focus here on the effect of corruption upon a special kind of investment, namely

foreign direct investment. Does corruption deter inward foreign direct investment in China as

some prior literature suggested? According to Wei (2000a, b), China seems to be a puzzle in

terms of its relationship between corruption and FDI inflows. China has been the largest

developing host of FDI for 16 consecutive years while simultaneously being reported in

international surveys as being severely corrupt. Wei (2000b) performs a cross-country analysis

including a Chinese dummy and concludes that “corruption is just as damaging to FDI into

China as it is elsewhere” (p. 321) basing this statement on the fact that coefficients on the

corruption variable and the Chinese dummy in regressions are significantly negative. This

insightful finding, however, is not fully convincing. The negative coefficient on corruption in

their cross-country analysis does not necessarily mean that corruption significantly deters FDI

inflows in China since China-related data only cover 2% of the sample used. Moreover the

negative coefficient on the China dummy might be due to some unobservable factors rather

than on corruption since country corruption levels have been controlled simultaneously in the

regressions. To try to generate a solid finding of the linkage between corruption and FDI

inflows in China, we perform a within-country analysis here, controlling for the endogeneity

problem with both the fixed-effects and instrumental variable approaches.

Similar to Harms and Ursprung (2002), we use the regional average annual FDI inflow per

capita as the dependent variable. Besides corruption, we, following (Wei, 2000a, b) and Egger

and Winner (2005), introduce several common controls such as income level and education

attainment in our regressions. We first perform the provincial analysis. We start with pooled-

OLS regressions. To address the omitted variable bias and the reverse causation between

corruption and FDI that Larraín and Tavares (2003, 2007) pointed out, we then adopt the fixed

effects and the IV approaches. To check the robustness of our provincial results, we also

perform the city-level analysis. Similarly, we run the OLS regression and then the IV regression

in the city-level analysis.

Page 171: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

  

161  

Table 7-6 Effect of corruption rate on inbound FDI FDI per capita Province level City level

Pooled OLS

Fixed effects OLS

Fixed effects 2SLS

OLS 2SLS

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5)

Corruption -0.66*** -0.84** -2.45** -8.74** -12.55 (0.23) (0.37) (0.96) (3.45) (8.08) Income 7.11*** 7.97*** 3.12*** 14.1*** 14.01*** (0.93) (3.03) (0.91) (3.91) (3.71) Education -0.66 1.05* 1.67*** 0.032 0.033 (0.45) (0.55) (0.49) (0.050) (0.047) Population -1.03*** 8.56* -1.74** -7.95* -8.40* (0.37) (4.63) (0.72) (4.43) (4.32) Industrialisation -0.0019 -0.19*** 0.21*** -16.54 -24.76 (0.029) (0.064) (0.068) (17.45) (25.24) Expenditure -0.052 -0.075 0.042 0.80* 0.80* (0.038) (0.073) (0.047) (0.46) (0.45) Wage -3.55*** 9.00*** 2.78 10.3* 10.4* (1.13) (2.98) (2.07) (5.96) (5.62) Infrastructure 0.26*** 0.14*** 0.23*** -9.42** -9.32** (0.029) (0.031) (0.033) (4.41) (4.17) Constant -17.4*** -207*** -50.5*** -113* -101 (5.71) (50.2) (17.7) (63.3) (69.6) R-squared 0.82 0.93 0.60

First stage F test of excluded IV 15.37[0.00] 12.34[0.00] Anderson canon. corr. LM statistic 13.43[0.00] 11.83[0.00] Observations 303 303 303 116 116

Notes: Robust standard errors in parentheses, p-values in brackets. ***, **and * denote significance

at 1%, 5% and 10% respectively. The Wage variable is expressed in logarithm. In our city-level

analysis, Population are henceforth measured by their values in 2004.

Table 7-6 shows results consistent with previous findings. In general corruption hinders

inward foreign direct investment significantly in China87. Hence the nexus of corruption and

FDI in China, which has seemed to be perplexing in our cross-country comparison, does indeed

not contradict prior theoretical and empirical findings. In this sense, China is a normal country.

Additionally, we observe that FDI is substantially attracted to the provinces with higher income

level and education attainment, which is also in line with previous literature. Average wage has

a weak positive effect on FDI inflows in Chinese regions, which may reflect the fact that

foreign investors in China prefer developed regions with better investment climate to

underdeveloped regions with lower wage levels.

We notice that Cole, Elliott and Zhang (2009) found in Chinese provinces a positive

relationship between FDI and annual registered corruption cases per 100,000 persons which

they interpret as a measure for provincial anti-corruption efforts. Their identification, however,

                                                            87 In regression (5) in Table 7-6 corruption is significant at 12% level. 

Page 172: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

  

162  

seems problematic since they did not effectively address both the endogeneity bias and the

potential bias introduced by the presence of the lagged dependent variable. Furthermore, it is

not appropriate for them to interpret the provincial registered corruption cases per 100,000

persons as regional anticorruption efforts. There are actually not substantial differences among

provincial anticorruption efforts in China because principal anti-corruption laws and policies in

China are actually made by the Central Government and the provincial leaders including the

local anticorruption leaders are also all appointed by the Central. A local anti-corruption leader

will be replaced if he is obviously incompetent to control local corruption (Wu, 2008).

Following the spirit of Fisman and Gatti (2002), and Glaeser and Saks (2006), we stress that

this kind of measure mainly indicates the level of local corruption rather than provincial

anticorruption effort, or it cannot vary as much as they showed across provinces.

7.3.4 Corruption and Public Expenditures

Bureaucratic corruption also affects the supply of public goods. Following Tanzi and Davoodi

(1997) and Mauro (1998), we examine the effects of corruption on public expenditures in

Chinese regions. We explore whether regional corruption influences the composition of

government expenditure with a specification richer than those in prior studies. Similar to Mauro

(1998), we use ratios of public expenditures to GDP as dependent variables in our regressions.

Results are reported in Table 7-7. Consistent with those in Tanzi and Davoodi (1997) and

Mauro (1998), corruption significantly decreases government expenditures on education and

science, while substantially increases public expenditure on social security. According to

Mauro (1998)’s theoretical analysis, our findings are reasonable. For example, “it seems easier

to hand out a disability pension to a healthy person than to give a teaching job to an unqualified

person.” (Mauro, 1998, p. 264)

We then retest provincial findings with the city-level data. We add a dummy to indicate

municipalities in city level regressions since province-level cities have more autonomy in

public expenditures than others cities in our sample which are prefecture-level. We conduct

first OLS and then IV regressions to investigate the effect of ETC upon government

expenditures. From Table 7-7 we can find that our city-level results generally support the cross-

province findings.

Page 173: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

  

163  

Table 7-7 Effects of corruption on public expenditures Expenditure on social security/GRP Expenditure on science /GRP Expenditure on education /GRP

Province level (1998-2007) City level (2005) Province level (1998-2007) City level (2005) Province level (1998-2007) City level (2005) Pooled

OLS FE

OLS FE

2SLS OLS 2SLS Pooled

OLS FE

OLS FE

2SLS OLS 2SLS Pooled

OLS FE

OLS FE

2SLS OLS 2SLS

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) (10) (11) (12) (13) (14) (15)

Corruption 0.077 -0.19*** 0.32*** 0.32*** 1.20*** -0.0012 0.0086 -0.10*** -0.0046 -0.023* -0.17*** -0.020 -0.35*** -0.017 -0.47 (0.047) (0.055) (0.12) (0.11) (0.46) (0.0054) (0.0073) (0.035) (0.0038) (0.014) (0.034) (0.031) (0.11) (0.11) (0.41) Income -0.75*** -1.14** -0.50*** -0.55*** -0.34** 0.0068 -0.10* 0.034 -0.0012 -0.0024 -0.39*** -1.24*** -0.47** -0.70*** -0.80*** (0.11) (0.44) (0.13) (0.10) (0.16) (0.015) (0.055) (0.030) (0.0034) (0.0042) (0.15) (0.36) (0.22) (0.098) (0.13) Education 0.37*** 0.036 0.012 -0.00029 -0.0012 -0.015 -0.011 -0.014 0.00019*** 0.00018*** -0.32** 0.21 -0.58*** (0.10) (0.11) (0.089) (0.0011) (0.0014) (0.012) (0.014) (0.014) (0.000067) (0.000069) (0.14) (0.13) (0.11) Population -0.47*** -2.09** -0.36*** -0.11 -0.094 -0.071*** 0.20 -0.10*** -0.0023 -0.0037 -1.00*** 0.39 -0.74*** -0.19* -0.21** (0.060) (0.86) (0.053) (0.12) (0.14) (0.0067) (0.13) (0.023) (0.0037) (0.0045) (0.14) (0.84) (0.13) (0.099) (0.099) Urbanization -0.40 -0.44 0.65*** 0.84 0.42 -0.028 0.028 0.11*** 0.016 0.020 0.0068 0.57*** 0.60*** -0.031 0.23 (0.30) (0.38) (0.23) (0.54) (0.51) (0.030) (0.041) (0.039) (0.019) (0.020) (0.22) (0.21) (0.21) (0.26) (0.39) Industrialisation 0.28*** -0.075 0.94*** -0.020 -0.053* (0.082) (0.15) (0.25) (0.022) (0.032) Researchers 0.0045*** -0.0050** -0.00049 0.0017 0.0057 (0.00093) (0.0025) (0.0021) (0.017) (0.015) Students 0.0015*** 0.00026 0.00023 -0.011 -0.034 (0.00046) (0.00060) (0.00044) (0.036) (0.047) Municipality 0.77** 0.89** 0.068** 0.066** 1.05*** 1.03*** (0.30) (0.39) (0.027) (0.027) (0.27) (0.31) Constant 11.4*** 29.9*** 8.86*** 6.06*** 3.20 0.62*** -0.47 0.60 0.057 0.11* 14.4*** 9.29 14.8*** 9.51*** 11.1*** (1.22) (7.48) (1.54) (1.49) (2.41) (0.13) (1.04) (0.37) (0.042) (0.069) (1.61) (7.21) (2.41) (1.53) (2.05)

R-squared 0.35 0.87 0.29 0.37 0.86 0.62 0.95 0.47 First stage

F test of excluded IV 37.58[0.00] 12.63[0.00] 8.37[0.00] 8.60[0.00] 36.26[0.00] 10.12[0.00] Anderson canon. corr. LM statistic 31.74[0.00] 12.00[0.00] 9.90[0.00] 9.24[0.00] 33.61[0.00] 10.18[0.00] Observations 228 228 228 120 120 228 228 228 228 228 228 120 120

Notes: Robust standard errors in parentheses, p-values in brackets. ***, **and * denote significance at 1%, 5% and 10% respectively. In city-level analysis, we use 2005 values of Population, Students, Researchers and Industrialization.

Page 174: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

164  

7.3.5 Corruption and the Environment

In this section we will turn to the impact of corruption on the environment. We first

investigate the effect of corruption upon pollution. Welsch (2004) and Cole (2007) apply

simultaneous equations to estimate the effect of corruption on the pollution as they assume

that besides its direct effect on pollution, corruption also has an indirect impact on pollution

through lowering income level. However, according to Glaeser and Saks (2006), Gundlach

and Paldam (2009) and Dong and Torgler (2010b), the causality between income and

corruption is mainly from income to corruption. We therefore are able to estimate the effect

of corruption on pollution with a single equation. We use SO2 emission per capita and soot

emission per capita as alternative measures for pollution emissions. Due to the existence of

the environmental Kuznets curve (Dasgupta, Wang and Wheeler, 2002), we include income

per capita, its quadratic term and even its cubic term in our specification. Following

Fredriksson, Vollebergh and Dijkgraaf (2004), we also investigate the influence of corruption

on energy efficiency, an important determinant of the environment in China. We employ the

energy intensity index (energy consumption per unit of gross regional product) to measure

regional energy efficiency. We set up a specification similar to the previous study and use the

same estimation procedure and instrumental variable as above.

Provincial results in Table 7-8 show that corruption exerts a positive effect on per capita

emissions. It is in line with the findings of Welsch (2004) and Cole (2007) on the direct effect

of corruption on pollution. Furthermore, similar to Fredriksson, Vollebergh and Dijkgraaf

(2004), we also observe that corruption significantly enhances energy intensity and thus

reduces energy efficiency in China.

We then check the provincial findings with the city-level data. Here we employ SO2

emission by industry per capita and soot emission by industry per capita as alternative

measures for pollution emissions as corruption measure here (ETC) is drawn from the survey

of industrial firms in Chinese cities. We therefore control for industrialization of Chinese

cities in the city-level regressions. We run OLS regressions and 2SLS regressions with the

same instrument as that in the previous city-level analysis. Our city-level findings clearly

support the positive influence of corruption on pollution emissions in China.

Page 175: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

165  

Table 7-8 Effect of corruption and the environment SO2 emission per capita Soot emission per capita Energy efficiency

Province level City level (2005) Province level City level (2005) Province level

Pooled OLS

FE OLS

FE 2SLS

OLS 2SLS Pooled OLS

FE OLS

FE 2SLS

OLS 2SLS Pooled OLS

FE OLS

FE 2SLS

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) (10) (11) (12) (13)

Corruption 0.0093 0.0040 0.072*** 0.0017 0.054 0.022*** -0.0032 0.043*** 0.019 0.090* 0.0022** 0.00018 0.0051** (0.0062) (0.0047) (0.022) (0.034) (0.096) (0.0037) (0.0022) (0.010) (0.016) (0.047) (0.00092) (0.00019) (0.0023) Income -17.49*** -10.2*** -13.56*** 22.88** 15.79* -4.01** -3.29*** -13.51*** 2.92 6.43 -0.0067*** -0.0038** -0.0051* (4.77) (1.76) (4.43) (11.10) (8.99) (2.04) (0.92) (3.08) (3.22) (4.07) (0.0016) (0.0015) (0.0029) Income2 1.87*** 1.16*** 1.50*** -2.59** -1.79* 0.43* 0.36*** 1.45*** -0.32 -0.72 (0.52) (0.19) (0.47) (1.26) (1.02) (0.22) (0.10) (0.33) (0.36) (0.46) Income3 -0.066*** -0.043*** -0.055*** 0.097** 0.067* -0.016* -0.013*** -0.052*** 0.011 0.027 (0.019) (0.0070) (0.016) (0.048) (0.039) (0.0080) (0.0037) (0.011) (0.014) (0.017) Education 0.0053 0.0086*** 0.010*** -0.00013 -0.00021 0.0019 0.00059 0.0040** -0.00010 -0.00020 -0.00017 0.000084 0.000085 (0.0046) (0.0024) (0.0039) (0.00031) (0.00033) (0.0020) (0.0012) (0.0016) (0.00014) (0.00015) (0.00018) (0.000051) (0.00024) Population -0.0086 0.21** -0.0019 -0.12*** -0.11*** -0.0066 0.016 -0.0047 -0.036** -0.031** -0.0048*** 0.0015 -0.00082 (0.0100) (0.090) (0.012) (0.039) (0.040) (0.0043) (0.036) (0.0058) (0.014) (0.015) (0.0012) (0.0017) (0.0012) Urbanization 0.035 0.027 -0.053 0.059 0.084 0.046 0.023 -0.036 0.058 0.033 0.0021 0.0015** -0.0019 (0.048) (0.031) (0.055) (0.14) (0.12) (0.031) (0.022) (0.031) (0.065) (0.058) (0.0035) (0.00065) (0.0044) Openness -0.050 0.0025 0.093** -0.0013 -0.016 -0.043*** -0.012 0.0082 -0.028 -0.033* (0.032) (0.028) (0.037) (0.039) (0.039) (0.015) (0.012) (0.017) (0.018) (0.019) Constant 54.58*** 27.47*** 40.75*** -66.20** -45.53* 12.40** 10.00*** 41.68*** -8.65 -18.97 0.11*** 0.038** 0.069*** (14.62) (5.15) (13.98) (32.35) (26.24) (6.23) (2.70) (9.65) (9.53) (12.10) (0.016) (0.018) (0.026) R-squared 0.084 0.94 0.38 0.20 0.95 0.18 0.49 0.99

First stage F test of excluded IV 74.32[0.00] 13.23[0.00] 74.32[0.00] 13.23[0.00] 23.87[0.00] Anderson canon. corr. LM statistic

53.53[0.00] 12.89[0.00] 53.53[0.00] 12.89[0.00] 15.78[0.00]

Observations 284 284 284 120 120 284 284 284 120 120 108 108 108

Notes: Robust standard errors are in parentheses. The significant levels of 1%, 5% and 10% are noted by ***, **and *. Industrialization here is measured with their values in 2005 in the city-level analysis. Openness is measured by its value in 2004.

Page 176: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

166  

We proceeded to investigate the mechanism through which corruption affects pollution or

environmental quality. Fredriksson and Millimet (2004) suggested that political institutions

influence the formation of economic policy including environmental policy. It is therefore

plausible to conjecture that corruption affects environmental quality mainly through the

channel of environmental policy formation. We measure the stringency of environment

policy with the ratio of industrial waste water meeting discharge standards in Chinese regions.

Then we examine our conjecture using routine estimation procedures. Regional corruption is

observed to substantially loosen environmental regulations in China (see first five columns in

Table 7-9). Moreover, trade openness also appears to decrease environmental policy

stringency. In addition, Damania, Fredriksson and List (2003) argued that corruption not only

directly influences environmental regulation but also modifies the effects of other

determinants of environmental policy such as trade openness. Detailedly, Damania,

Fredriksson and List (2003) developed a lobbying model with the endogenous formation of

environmental regulation and concluded that when government corruption is high, trade

openness tends to raise local environmental policy stringency if trade policy is protective,

which was confirmed by their cross-country empirical analysis. With the specification similar

to Damania, Fredriksson and List (2003), we look here for the within-country evidence that

corruption indirectly influences the environmental policy stringency through the channel of

trade openness. We in turn perform Pooled OLS, fixed effects and fixed effects-IV

regressions. The results in the last five columns of Table 7-9 show that regional corruption

has an overall negative effect on the stringency of environmental policy (at the mean level of

regional trade openness), which is consistent with our previous findings.

Figure 7-1 Marginal effects of trade openness on environmental stringency conditional on corruption

Note: Marginal effect is calculated with the 2SLS results in Column (8) of Table 7-9

Corruption

Mar

gina

l eff

ect o

f op

enne

ss

-1.06

3.530

Page 177: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

167  

Similar to Damania, Fredriksson and List (2003), the effect of trade openness on the

provincial environmental policy stringency are substantially modified by provincial

corruption levels. However, we do not obtain significant city-level evidence probably due to

data noise. As shown in Figure 7-1, the marginal effects of trade openness on the

environmental policy stringency, which are initially negative, increase with local corruption

level and become positive at within-sample levels of corruption. However, the mechanism

that Damania, Fredriksson and List (2003) suggested is not applicable in China since

lobbying is not allowed in China. A plausible interpretation of our results may be consistent

with Li and Zhou (2005) who observed that the probability of promotion or termination of

local leaders depends mainly on their economic performance in China, where the central

government essentially controls the mobility of local government leaders. We therefore

assume that local leaders in China may consider both, promotion benefits and corrupt

incomes, when they maximize their utilities. Moreover, the regional corruption level

determines the relative importance of bribery vs. promotion to the leaders. The local

environmental policy to some extent becomes a tool of the provincial leaders in China. When

the local level of corruption is low, implying the difficulty in engaging in corrupt activities,

the regional leader’s weight on promotion relative to bribery is added. Since exports are an

important source of economic growth in China, the local leader is likely to loosen the local

environmental policy under the pressure of the export industries which play an important role

in the local economy in order to encourage regional economic growth to earn a promotion for

himself. In a highly corrupt region, however, the relative importance of bribery versus

promotion to the local leader rises. He may have an incentive to extort bribes from local firms

including export-oriented firms by the reinforcement of local government regulations

including environmental ones, provided that there are enough local firms especially those

export-oriented so that he can extort lots of bribes without destroying the local economy

which may cause his termination. According to this mechanism, trade openness increases the

stringency of environmental policy if the local corruption level is high, while it decreases the

stringency of environmental policy if the local corruption level is low. Our interpretation

based on the unique Chinese political system with centralized personnel control, one of the

“Chinese characteristics”, can therefore explain our empirical results. Finally, we conclude

that corruption affects environmental quality mainly by influencing regional environmental

policy stringency directly and indirectly in China.

Page 178: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

168  

Table 7-9 Effect of corruption on environment policy Ratio of industrial waste water meeting discharge standards Province level City level (2005) Province level City level (2005)

Pooled OLS

Fixed effects OLS

Fixed effects 2SLS

OLS 2SLS Pooled OLS

Fixed effects OLS

Fixed effects 2SLS

OLS 2SLS

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) (10)

Corruption 0.023*** 0.0092 -0.14** 0.18 -6.96* 0.0063 0.018* -0.16*** -0.38 -7.05* (0.0077) (0.0079) (0.056) (1.68) (4.22) (0.0098) (0.010) (0.052) (1.82) (4.22) Openness -0.053** -0.18*** -0.34*** 1.99** 0.97 -0.16*** -0.12* -1.06*** 0.87 2.74 (0.026) (0.063) (0.060) (0.89) (1.19) (0.041) (0.070) (0.27) (1.43) (3.53) Corruption* Openness 0.045*** -0.028** 0.30*** 100.5 -321.1 (0.016) (0.013) (0.11) (126.3) (461.0) Income -5.72 -1.24 4.40 -254 -573 -1.68 -2.28 31.6*** -89.3 -706 (4.45) (3.95) (5.32) (335) (423) (4.56) (4.08) (12.0) (330) (579) Income2 0.74 0.21 -0.38 33.4 69.6 0.30 0.32 -3.39** 14.5 84.6 (0.48) (0.44) (0.57) (36.9) (46.9) (0.49) (0.45) (1.32) (36.5) (64.9) Income3 -0.030* -0.0099 0.010 -1.41 -2.77 -0.015 -0.014 0.12** -0.69 -3.33 (0.017) (0.016) (0.020) (1.35) (1.73) (0.018) (0.016) (0.048) (1.34) (2.42) Education 0.075** 0.042* 0.075*** -0.014 -0.0084 0.079** 0.040 0.10*** -0.012 -0.0015 (0.031) (0.024) (0.021) (0.011) (0.013) (0.031) (0.024) (0.022) (0.011) (0.015) Urbanization -0.041 -0.093** 0.017 -3.18 -2.18 -0.035 -0.089** 0.10* -2.57 1.63 (0.035) (0.046) (0.048) (3.06) (3.32) (0.035) (0.045) (0.055) (2.99) (4.44) Industrialisation -0.39*** -0.40 1.28*** 14.28 1.23 -0.37*** -0.41 0.66 15.58 4.30 (0.12) (0.49) (0.38) (9.60) (13.21) (0.12) (0.49) (0.45) (9.54) (12.99) Population 0.100*** -0.032 -0.023 2.81* 1.92 0.11*** -0.063 0.084 1.91 0.62 (0.011) (0.22) (0.033) (1.50) (1.78) (0.012) (0.22) (0.053) (1.17) (1.62) Infrastructure 0.0062*** 0.0034*** 0.0073*** -2.81* -3.32** 0.0053*** 0.0034*** 0.000056 -1.89 -2.05 (0.00098) (0.0012) (0.0013) (1.66) (1.60) (0.0011) (0.0012) (0.0033) (1.41) (1.40) Municipality 1.87 1.73 2.31 4.22 (2.95) (3.38) (2.81) (3.65) Constant 13.9 2.52 -16.0 673 1629 1.51 5.98 -98.1*** 206 2033 (13.8) (11.6) (16.4) (1004) (1263) (14.1) (12.2) (36.3) (987) (1714) R-squared 0.61 0.85 0.36 0.62 0.85 0.33

First stage F test of excluded IVs Corruption 8.06[0.00] 8.51[0.00] 4.07[0.02] 4.81[0.01]Corruption* Openness 3.92[0.02] 1.02[0.36]Anderson canon. corr. LM statistic 9.17[0.00] 9.45[0.00] 5.61[0.02] 10.72[0.00]Observations 277 277 277 120 120 277 277 277 118 118

Notes: Robust standard errors in parentheses, p-values in brackets. ***, **and * denote significance at 1%, 5% and 10% respectively.

Page 179: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

169  

7.4 Conclusion

Cross-country analyses in corruption with subjective survey data are suffering from a number

of biases. A comprehensive case study of a representative country may provide a helpful

supplement to these studies. Limited information is available outside the US. In this chapter,

we investigate the consequences of corruption using two objective data sets and alternative

corruption measures across Chinese regions. Glaeser and Saks (2006) pointed out that the

noise of corruption data, the small sample size and the narrow variation in cross regions make

it difficult for researchers to identify relationships between corruption and other variables in a

within-country analysis. The relatively great regional disparity in China mitigates the

problem of narrow variation across sub-nations in within-country analysis. We also employ

both the fixed effects approach and the instrumental variables approach to address potential

endogeneity problem which may bias our estimation. The fact that our results are basically

consistent with prior findings somehow validates our analysis. Furthermore, two

complementary data sets and alternative corruption measures in our analysis contribute to the

robustness of our findings.

Our research identifies adverse influences of corruption on economic development which

have been observed in cross-country studies. Like prior studies, we first observe that

corruption appears to lower economic growth. Unlike previous research, we subsequently

obtain solid evidence that corruption has simultaneously positive and negative effects on

economic growth. The impact of corruption detected in literature, either negative or positive,

might be the balance of the two simultaneous effects in a specific institutional environment.

Corruption also affects the income distribution in China which is an important aspect of

economic development. Similar to cross-country analyses, we find that corruption

considerably increases income inequality in China. We also find that regional corruption

significantly reduces inbound foreign direct investment, a main source of economic growth in

Chinese regions. This finding sheds new light on the “China puzzle” (Wei, 2000b): the

seemingly positive relationship between corruption and FDI inflows in China in previous

cross-country comparisons. As to the impact of corruption on public expenditures, we

observe that corruption significantly decreases government spending on education and

science, while increases public expenditure on social security. Turning to the nexus between

corruption and the environment, we observe that corruption substantially aggravates pollution

mainly through loosening environment regulations. Furthermore, corruption in China is also

Page 180: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

170  

observed to modify the effect of trade openness on the environment policy stringency in the

similar way to that suggested in previous studies.

In summary, our study casts new light in a broadly manner on the consequences of

corruption especially in developing countries and hence is a constructive complement to

previous research about the consequences of corruption.

Page 181: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

171  

Appendix

Table 7-10 Data description Variable Data Description Source Mean S.D.

Corruption Regional registered cases on corruption in procurator’s office per 100,000 population

China Procuratorial Yearbooks 3.09 0.94

Average entertainment and travel costs relative to sales of investigated firms in cities

World Bank (2006) 1.13 0.45

Income Logarithm of per capita real gross regional product China Statistical Yearbooks China City Statistical Yearbooks

9.21 9.47

0.65 0.66

Education Provincial fraction of the population over 6 with college completed Public library collections per 100 people in a city

China Statistical Yearbooks China City Statistical Yearbooks

5.44 46.57

4.31 56.61

Openness Regional ratio of import and export to gross regional product

China Statistical Yearbooks China City Statistical Yearbooks

0.30 0.39

0.37 0.72

Industrialization Regional industrial contribution to gross regional product

China Statistical Yearbooks China City Statistical Yearbooks

0.37 0.48

0.10 0.091

Expenditure Ratio of regional government expenditure to gross regional product

China Statistical Yearbooks China City Statistical Yearbooks

0.16 0.086

0.11 0.030

FDI Regional inward foreign direct investment per capita China Statistical Yearbooks China City Statistical Yearbooks

4.65 12.34

6.68 20.06

Urbanization Regional share of urban population China Statistical Yearbooks China City Statistical Yearbooks

0.32 0.38

0.16 0.19

Investment Regional investment in the fixed assets/ gross regional product

China Statistical Yearbooks 0.41 0.14

Infrastructure Regional road mileage per 10000 people China Statistical Yearbooks World Bank (2006)

9.49 2.41

14.22 0.52

Loan pay Average investigated firms’ expectation of informal payments for loans in a city

World Bank (2006) 7.22 4.72

Tax Average taxes and fees relative to firms’ sales of firms investigated in a city

World Bank (2006) 4.94 1.40

Red tape Average days per year that enterprise staff must spend interacting with four major government bureaucracies (tax administration, public security, environmental protection, and labour and social security)

World Bank (2006) 60.54 21.39

Population Logarithm of regional population (ten millions) (million (city))

China Statistical Yearbooks China City Statistical Yearbooks

8.03 8.48

0.89 0.56

Municipality Dummy which equals 1if a city is among 4 municipalities, 0 otherwise

Others Regional number of middle school students China Statistical Yearbooks China City Statistical Yearbooks

Regional number of research workers China Statistical Yearbooks China City Statistical Yearbooks

Industrial output and employment China City Statistical Yearbooks regional public expenditures China Statistical Yearbooks

China City Statistical Yearbooks

All environmental data China Statistical Yearbooks China City Statistical Yearbooks

Page 182: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

172  

Chapter Eight Conclusion

8.1 Summary of Findings

This thesis comprehensively studies the causes and consequences of corruption in both cross-

country and within-country contexts, mainly focusing on China. The thesis commences by

extensively investigating the causes of corruption in chapters 2, 3, 4, 5 and 6.

Chapter 2 adopts the standard economic approach to explore the causes of corruption in

China using two different sets of data at regional levels (provinces and cities). It is observed

that regions with more anti-corruption efforts, higher education attainment, Anglo-American

historic influence, higher openness, more access to media, higher relative wages of

government employees, and a greater representation of women in legislature are markedly

less corrupt; while the social heterogeneity, deregulation and abundance of resources,

substantially breed regional corruption. Moreover, fiscal decentralization is discovered to

depress corruption significantly. This study also finds that there is currently a positive

relationship between corruption and the economic development in China that is mainly driven

by the transition to a market economy. The findings above are fairly conceivable since this

study has addressed the potential endogeneity bias using the IV approach, and checked their

robustness with different specifications and data sets.

In Chapter 3 this thesis investigates the relationship between one of the informal aspects

of political institution. Specifically, this study uses the micro-level data from the World

Values Survey to explore the impact of political interest on corruption. To obtain robust

results, this study utilizes alternative measures for corruption: perceived corruption and the

justifiability of corruption, and three different proxies for political interest in the empirical

analysis. With the weighted ordered probit estimation (including 2SLS), this study presents

both cross-country and within-country evidence that a high level of political interest helps to

reduce the level of corruption within a society.

This thesis then continues by exploring the influence of democracy on corruption in

Chapter 4. To make the results more solid, this study establishes a political economy model

demonstrating that the effect of democracy on corruption is conditional on income

distribution and property rights protection. Then a cross-national panel data is constructed.

Employing fixed-effect and instrumental variable approaches, this study provides empirical

evidence that the effect of democracy upon corruption depends on the level of property rights

Page 183: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

173  

protection and income inequality, which suggests that in order to effectively control

corruption we may highlight protection property rights and the mitigation of income

inequality rather than just democratization.

Chapter 5, using the social economic approach, performs a cross-country analysis to test

whether social interaction or social norms plays an important role in determining corruption

in a cross-country context. The study first builds a simple behavioural model to explain why

engaging in corruption results in a disutility of guilt. Guilt itself depends on the average guilt

levels of others within a country. This model also explores whether - and to what extent -

group dynamics or socialization and past experiences affect corruption. The empirical section

presents evidence using two data sets at a micro level and a large macro level panel data set

covering almost 20 years. The results indicate that the willingness to engage in corruption is

influenced by the perceived activities of peers and other individuals. Moreover, the panel data

set at the macro level indicates that past levels of corruption have a strong impact on the

current corruption level.

The thesis, however, turns to examine with the objective data whether the above findings

hold within the Chinese context in Chapter 6. Using Chinese province-level panel data, this

study clearly indicates that social interaction has a significantly positive effect on the

corruption rate in China. Therefore both cross-country and within-country findings

underscore the relevance of social interaction in corruption.

Chapter 7, however, comprehensively evaluates the consequences of corruption with

complementary Chinese data sets and alternative corruption measures. Adopting a novel

approach it provides solid evidence that corruption can simultaneously have both positive and

negative effects on economic development. The overall impact of corruption might be the

balance of the two effects, which may depend on the specific institutional environment.

Corruption is also observed to considerably increase the income inequality in China.

Furthermore this study also finds that corruption in China significantly decreases government

spending on education, science and public health, while it significantly increases public

expenditure on social security. And local corruption is observed to significantly reduce FDI

in Chinese regions. This finding sheds new light on the “China puzzle” that China is the

largest developing host of FDI while it is appears to be very corrupt. Finally the study

documents that corruption substantially aggravates pollution probably through a loosening of

the environmental regulation, and that it modifies the effects of trade openness and FDI on

Page 184: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

174  

the stringency of environmental policy in a manner similar to that observed in literature to

date.

Overall, this thesis adds to the current literature by a number of novel findings concerning

both the causes and the consequences of corruption.

8.2 Policy Implications

The policy implications are discussed in the context of China. The wide-ranging adverse

effects of corruption on Chinese society disclosed in the thesis call for effective policies to

curb corruption. Based on the findings regarding the causes of corruption in this study, this

study provides some suggestions to design coherent anti-corruption measures in China.

Economic development and marketization appear to increase corruption during the

transitional process of China. However, considering the fact that economic development and

marketization substantially determine Chinese transition, our policy suggestion would be to

promote economic growth and marketization in order to accelerate this transitional process.

Corruption may be depressed by the economic development and marketization in China after

the accomplishment of the transition, which destroys the foundation of business-government

collusion.

The results here also highlight the view that an equal society, namely one with income

equality, gender equality and racial equality, has less corruption. A reduction in corruption is

an additional benefit of a society with more socio-economic equality. Furthermore, one of the

beneficial aspects of a more educated population is to decrease corruption.

The negative effects of trade openness and fiscal decentralization on corruption suggest

that competition, either between enterprises or governments, plays an important role in

controlling corruption. Policies inducing more competition in either commercial or political

markets are encouraged while any “marketization” policies leading to a monopoly due to the

government-business collusion are undesirable. Moreover, breeding corruption is one of the

detrimental aspects of the resource curse. Much attention should be paid to the role of

anticorruption in the resourceful provinces.

The media in China, though controlled by the government, acts as a watchdog over

corruption. More press freedom is however expected since according to Brunetti and Weder

(2003), freer press controls corruption more effectively. Additionally, although high salary

significantly prevents officials from corruption in China, as Rose-Ackerman (1999) argued, a

high salary of the public sector can be justified only if its productivity increases while its size

Page 185: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

175  

decreases. Otherwise high pay in the public sector itself is a kind of corruption though

individual corruption acts may decrease in the public sector with high salary.

Social interactions however are found to be highly relevant in the incidence of corruption.

Regional corruption is affected by neighbourhood corruption. Anti-corruption in an area has a

positive spillover effect in reducing corruption in contiguous areas. This requires either

neighbouring areas to coordinate their individual anti-corruption efforts with regional

agreements or policy makers should take spillover effects into account when allocating

resources to corruption controls. Moreover, previous corruption levels have a significant

effect on the current corruption level. The evolution of corruption is a path-dependent process.

Rigorous anti-corruption measures need to be carried out for a long period to control

corruption in areas where corruption is pandemic. As suggested by Aidt (2003), a “big push”

like the one that took place in Hong Kong in the 1970s, might be needed to address the

corruption levels in areas where previous corruption rates have been high.

China is now on the track for democratisation. Some scholars insist that democratisation

can always curb corruption. However, this study argues that democracy is not a panacea for

corruption. The effect of democracy actually depends on the level of property rights and on

income inequality. To control corruption, protection of property rights, mitigation of income

inequality and economic development might be more essential, especially in poor countries.

8.3 Further Research

The validity of the findings on corruption to a large extent depends on the accuracy of

corruption measures that the researchers have. As discussed before, both the subjective cross-

country data and the objective within-country data that are currently utilized in the research

of corruption have their own inherent constrains. “If we cannot correctly measure corruption,

our ability to conduct empirical tests is severely impaired” (Banerjee et al., 2009, p.1).

However, measuring corruption accurately is a large challenge for economists as corruption

is illicit and hence secretive. One of the tasks of the next wave of research is therefore the

enhancement of our ability to measure corruption precisely.

A major innovative method developed recently in measuring corruption is to use quasi-

experimental and experimental approaches to measure corruption. This can facilitate us in our

attempts to better understand the causes and consequences of corruption at the micro level.

For example, Bertrand et al. (2007) carried out a field experiment to investigate the process

of obtaining the driving license in India. In their experiment, some applicants are observed to

make extralegal payments and to obtain licenses without attending the driving test. The

Page 186: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

176  

results of their experiment show that corruption does distort resource allocation. Barron and

Olken (2007) also designed a field study in which surveyors accompanied truck drivers on

304 trips in two Indonesian provinces. The surveyors observed more than 6,000 illegal

payments to the traffic police, soldiers, and weigh station attendants during these trips. With

the data, they empirically show that as Shleifer and Vishny (1993) suggest, market structure

substantially influences the level of bribes. These studies allow us to measure corruption

more accurately and are also very helpful in testing the micro-theories of corruption.

However, no field experiment on corruption has been performed in a Chinese context. To

further understand the causes and consequences of corruption in China, a series of field

experiments measuring corruption needs to be carried out in order to test corruption theories

within the unique context of China. Actually there are many interesting candidates for field

experiments in China. For example, to obtain an entrance into key schools for their children,

parents in Chinese cities often have to make extralegal payments to these schools and to their

principals. Furthermore patients in China usually have to send their doctors red envelopes if

they hoped to be better treated. These are some potential field experiments that the author

plans to explore in future work.

 

 

 

Page 187: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

177  

References

Abed, G.T., and Gupta, S., 2002. Governance, Corruption & Economic Performance. International

Monetary Fund.

Acemoglu, D., 1995. Reward Structures and the Allocation of Talent. European Economic Review 39,

17-33.

Acemoglou, D., Johnson, S., Robinson, J.A., 2001. The Colonial Origins of Comparative

Development: An Empirical Investigation. American Economic Review 91, 1369–1401.

Adam, C., 1993. Testing for Regime Shifts in Short-Sample African Macroeconomic Data: A Survey

of Some Monte Carlo Evidence. Working Paper 93.1, The Study of African Economies, University

of Oxford.

Adams, C. 1993. For Good and Evil. The Impact of Taxes on the Course of Civilization. Madison

Books, London.

Adams, J.S., 1965. Inequity in Social Exchange. In Advances in Experimental Social Psychology, eds.

Berkowitz, Leonard. New York: Academic Press, 167-299.

Ades, A., Di Tella, R., 1996. The Causes and Consequences of Corruption. IDS Bulletin 27 (2), 6–10.

Ades, A., Di Tella, R., 1997. The New Economics of Corruption: A Survey and Some New Results.

Political Studies 45, 496-515.

Ades, A., Di Tella, R., 1999. Rents, Competition and Corruption. American Economic Review 89,

982-993.

Adsera, A., Boix, C. and Payne, M., 2003. Are You Being Served? Political Accountability and

Quality of Government. Journal of Law, Economics and Organization 19, 445-490.

Aidt, T.S., 2003. Economic Analysis of Corruption: A Survey. The Economic Journal 113, 632-652.

Aidt, T.S., 2009. Corruption, Institutions, and Economic Development. Oxford Review of Economic

Policy 25, 271-291.

Aidt, T.S., Dutta, J. and Sena, V., 2008. Governance Regimes, Corruption and Growth: Theory and

Evidence. Journal of Comparative Economics 36, 195-220.

Akcay, S., 2001. Is Corruption an Obstacle for Foreign Investors in Developing Countries? a Cross-

Country Evidence. Yapi Kredi Economic Review 12, 27-34.

Akerlof, G.A., 1980. A Theory of Social Custom, of Which Unemployment May be One

Consequence. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 94, 749-75.

Alesina, A., Angeletos, G.M., 2005. Corruption, Inequality, and Fairness. Journal of Monetary

Economics 52, 1227-1244.

Alesina, A., Devleeschauwer, A., Easterly, W., Kurlat, S., Wazciarg, R., 2003. Fractionalization.

Journal of Economic Growth 8, 155–194.

Alm, J., 1996. Explaining Tax Compliance. In Exploring the Underground Economy, Susan Pozo, ed.

Kalamazoo: W. E. Upjohn Institute for Employment Research, 103-128.

Page 188: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

178  

Alm, J., Martinez-Vazquez, J. and Torgler, B. 2006. Russian Attitudes Toward Paying Taxes- Before,

During, and After the Transition. International Journal of Social Economics 33, 832-857.

Alm, J., McClelland, G. H., and Schulze, W. D., 1999. Changing the Social Norm of Tax Compliance

by Voting, KYKLOS 52, 141-171.

Anderson, T., and Hsiao, C., 1981. Estimation of Dynamic Models with Error Components. Journal of

the American Statistical Association 76, 598-606.

Andreoni, J. and Miller, J., 2002. Giving According to GARP: An Experimental Test of the

Consistency of Preferences for Altruism. Econometrica 70, 737-753.

Andreoni, J. and Vesterlund, L., 2001. Which Is the Fair Sex? Gender Differences in Altruism,

Quarterly Journal of Economics 116, 293-312.

Andvig, J.C. and Moene, K.O., 1990. How Corruption May Corrupt. Journal of Economic Behaviours

& Organization 13, 63-76.

Angrist, J.D., Krueger, A.B., 2001. Instrumental Variables and the Search for Identification: From

Supply and Demand to Natural Experiments. Journal of Economic Perspectives 15, 69-85.

Arellano, M., and Bond, S., 1991. Some Tests of Specification for Panel Data: Monte Carlo Evidence

and an Application to Employment Equations. Review of Economic Studies 58, 277-297.

Arellano, M.., and Bover, O., 1995. Another Look at the Instrumental-Variable Estimation of Error-

Components Models. Journal of Econometrics 68, 29-51.

Attila, G., 2008. Is Corruption Contagious? An Econometric Analysis. Norwegian Institute of

International Affairs Working Paper, No. 742.

Banerjee, A.V., 1992. A Simple Model of Herd Behavior. Quarterly Journal of Economics 107, 797-

817.

Banerjee, A., Hanna, R., and Mullainathan, S., 2009. Corruption. Prepared for the Handbook of

Organizational Economics.

Banfield, E.C., 1958. The Moral Basis of a Backward Society. New York: Free Press.

Bardhan, P. and Mookherjee, D., 2006. Decentralization, Corruption and Government Accountability.

In: Rose-Ackerman, S. (Eds.), International Handbook on the Economics of Corruption.

Cheltenham: Edward Elgar. pp. 161-188.

Barro, R., 2000. Inequality and Growth in a Panel of Countries. Journal of Economic Growth 5, 5-32.

Barron, P. and Olken, B.A., 2009. The Simple Economics of Extortion: Evidence from Trucking in

Aceh. Journal of Political Economy 117, 417-252.

Basu, S. and Li, D., 2000. A Theory of the Reform of Bureaucratic Institutions. Econometric Society

World Congress 2000 Contributed Papers no. 1271.

Baumol, W. J., 1990, “Entrepreneurship: Productive, Unproductive, and Destructive. Journal of

Political Economy. 98, 893-921.

Becker, G.S., 1968. Crime and Punishment: An Economic Approach. Journal of Political Economy 76,

169-217.

Page 189: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

179  

Becker, G.S. 1976. The Economic Approach to Human Behavior. Chicago: The University of

Chicago Press.

Becker, G.S. 1996. Accounting for Tastes. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

Becker, G.S. and Murphy, K.M., 2000. Social Economics: Market Behaviour in a Social Environment.

Cambridge, MA: Belknap / Harvard Press.

Begovic, B., 2006. Economic Inequality and Corruption. Working paper, Center for Liberal-

Democratic Studies,

Belgrade, Serbia.

Berninghaus, S.K. and Güth, W., 2002. Buying Versus Hiring - An Indirect Evolutionary Approach.

Discussion Papers on Strategic Interaction 2002-39, Strategic Interaction Group, Max Planck

Institute of Economics.

Besley, T., Ghatak, M., 2009. Improvement and Extension of Property Rights. In: Rodrik, D. and

Rosenzweig, M.R. (Eds.), Handbook of Development Economics 5, Elsevier, Burlington.

Bertrand, M., Djankov, S., Hanna, R., and Mullainathan, S., 2007. Obtaining a Driver's License in

India: An Experimental Approach to Studying Corruption. The Quarterly Journal of Economics

122, 1639-1676.

Bertrand, M., and Mullainathan, S., 2001. Do People Mean What They Say? Implications for

Subjective Survey Data. American Economic Review 91, 67-72.

Bikhchandani, S., Hirshleifer, D. and Welch, I. 1992. A Theory of Fads, Fashion, Custom, and

Cultural Change as Informational Cascades. Journal of Political Economy 100, 992-1026.

Bikhchandani, S., Hirshleifer, D. and Welch, I., 1998. Learning from the Behavior of Others:

Conformity, Fads, and Informational Cascades.” Journal of Economic Perspectives 12, 151-170.

Billger, S.M., Goel, R.K., 2009. Do Existing Corruption Levels Matter in Controlling Corruption?

Cross-Country Quantile Regression Estimates. Journal of Development Economics 90, 299-305.

Bird, R.M., Martinez-Vazquez, J. and Torgler, B., 2006. Societal Institutions and Tax Effort in

Developing Countries. In The Challenges of Tax Reform in the Global Economy, eds. Alm, James,

Jorge Martinez-Vazquez and Mark Rider. New York: Springer, 283-338.

Bird, R.M., Martinez-Vazquez, J., and Torgler, B., 2008. Tax Effort in Developing Countries and

High Income Countries: The Impact of Corruption, Voice and Accountability. Economic Analysis

& Policy 38. 55-71.

Blume, L. E. and Durlauf, S.N., 2004. The Interactions-Based Approach to Socioeconomic Behaviour.

In Social Dynamics, Steven N. Durlauf, H. Peyton Young (eds.), The MIT Press.

Blundell, R.W., and Bond, S.R., 1998. Initial Conditions and Moment Restrictions in Dynamic Panel

Data Models. Journal of Econometrics 87, 115-143.

Boettke, P., Chamlee-Wright, E., Gordon, P., Ikeda, S., Leeson, P.T., and Sobel, R., 2007. The

political, economic, and social aspects of Katrina. Southern Economic Journal 74, 363–376.

Page 190: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

180  

Bohara, A.K., Mitchell, N.J., Mittendorff, C.F., 2004. Compound Democracy and the Control of

Corruption: A Cross-Country Investigation. Policy Studies Journal 32, 481-499.

Bolton, G.E. and Ockenfels, A., 2000. ERC: Theory of Equity, Reciprocity, and Competition.

American Economic Review 90, 166-193.

Boyce, C. J., 2010. Understanding Fixed Effects in Human Well-Being. Journal of Economic

Psychology 31, 1–16.

Bradhan, P., 1997. Corruption and Development: A Review of Issues. Journal of Economic Literature

35, 1320-1346.

Brambor, T., Clark, W.R., Golder, M., 2006. Understanding Interaction Models: Improving Empirical

Analyses. Political Analysis 14, 63-82.

Brock, W. A. and Durlauf, S.N., 1995. Discrete Choice with Social Interactions I: Theory. NBER

Working Papers No. 5291.

Brock, W. A. and Durlauf, S.N., 2001. Discrete Choice with Social Interactions. The Review of

Economic Studies 68, 235-260.

Brunetti, A. and Weder, B., 2003. A Free Press is Bad News for Corruption. Journal of Public

Economics 87, 1801-1824.

Cadot, O., 1987. Corruption as a Gamble. Journal of Public Economics 33, 223-244.

Cai, H., Fang, H. and Xu, C.L., 2009. Eat, Drink, Firms and Government: An Investigation of

Corruption from Entertainment and Travel Costs of Chinese Firms. Journal of Law and Economics,

forthcoming.

Carpini, D. and Keeter, S., 1996. What Americans Know about Politics and Why It Matters. New

Haven, CT: Yale University Press.

Charness, G. and Rabin, M., 2002. Understanding Social Preferences with Simple Tests. The

Quarterly Journal of Economics 117, 817-869.

Cervellati, M., Fortunato, P., Sunde, U., 2008. Hobbes to Rousseau: Inequality, Institutions And

Development. Economic Journal 118, 1354-1384.

China Continuation Committee (2007), Christian Occupation of China. Beijing, China: Chinese

Social Science Press.

Chowdhury, S., 2004. The Effect of Democracy and Press Freedom on Corruption: An Empirical Test.

Economics Letters 85, 93-101.

Cole. M.A., 2007. Corruption, Income and the Environment: an Empirical Analysis. Ecological

Economics 62, 637-647.

Cole, M.A., Elliott, R.J.R., Fredriksson, P., 2006. Endogenous Pollution Havens: Does FDI Influence

Environmental Regulations? Scandinavian Journal of Economics 108, 157-178.

Cole, M.A., Elliott, R.J.R., Zhang, J., 2006. Corruption, Governance and FDI Location in China: A

Province-Level Analysis. Journal of Development Studies 45, 1494-1512.

Coleman, J.S., 1990. Foundations of Social Theory. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

Page 191: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

181  

Cook, P.J., and Goss, K.A., 1996. A Selective Review of the Social-Contagion Literature. Working

paper, Sanford Institute of Policy Studies, Duke University.

Dabla-Norris, E. and Wade, P., 2002. Production, Rent Seeking, and Wealth Distribution. in

Governance, Corruption, and Economic Performance, ed. by G. T. Abed and S. Gupta.

International Monetary Fund, Washington.

Dahl, R. A., 1974. Who Governs? Yale University Press, New Haven.

Damania, R., Fredriksson, P.G., List, J.A., 2003. Trade Liberalization, Corruption, and Environmental

Policy Formation: Theory and Evidence. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management

46, 490–512.

Dasgupta, S., Wang, H., Wheeler, D., 2002. Confronting the environmental Kuznets curve. Journal of

Economic Perspectives 16, 147–168.

Davoodi, H.R. and Tanzi, V., 1997. Corruption, Public Investment, and Growth. IMF Working Paper,

WP/97/139.

Deininger, K., Squire, L., 1996. A New Data Set Measuring Income Inequality. World Bank

Economic Review 10, 565-591.

Demurger, S., 2001. Infrastructure Development and Economic Growth: An Explanation for Regional

Disparities in China? Journal of Comparative Economics 29, 95-117.

De Soto, H., 1989. The Other Path: The Invisible Revolution in the Third World. New York: Harper&

Row.

Dollar, D., Fisman, R. and Gatti, R., 2001. Are Women Really the "Fairer" Sex? Corruption and

Women in Government. Journal of Economic Behaviours and Organization 46, 423-429.

Dong, B. and Torgler, B., 2009. Corruption and Political Interest: Empirical Evidence at the Micro

Level. Journal of Interdisciplinary Economics 21, 295-325.

Dong, B., Dulleck, U. and Torgler, B., 2008. Conditional Corruption. CREMA Working Paper Series

2008-29.

Dong, B. and Torgler, B., 2010a. Social Interaction and Corruption: Evidence from China, draft,

Queensland University of Technology.

Dong, B. and Torgler, B., 2010b. The Causes of Corruption: Evidence from China. Working Paper

series No. 257, School of Economics and Finance, Queensland University of Technology.

Dreher, A., 2006. Does Globalization Affect Growth? Evidence from a New Index of Globalization.

Applied Economics 38, 1091-110.

Duesenberry, J.S., 1949. Income, Saving, and the Theory of Consumer Behavior. Cambridge, MA:

Harvard University Press.

Eagly, A. H. and Crowley, M., 1986. Gender and Helping Behavior: A Meta-Analytic Review of the

Social Psychological Literature. Psychological Bulletin 100, 283-308.

Eberhard, W., 1965. Chinese Regional Stereotypes. Asian Survey 5, 596-608.

Page 192: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

182  

Eckel, C. C. and Grossman, P. J., 2001. Chivalry and Solidarity in Ultimatum Games. Economic

Inquiry 39, 171-188.

Egger, P. and Winner, H., 2005. Evidence on Corruption as an Incentive for Foreign Direct

Investment European Journal of Political Economy 21, 932– 952.

Elster, J. 1989. The Cement of Society: A Study of Social Order. Cambridge: Cambridge University

Press.

Elster, J. 1989. Social Norms and Economic Theory. Journal of Economic Perspectives 3, 99-117.

Emerson, P.M., 2006. Corruption, Competition and Democracy. Journal of Development Economics

81, 193-212.

European Values Questionnaire. 1999. Tilburg University, The Netherlands.

Falk, A., and Fehr, E., 2002. Psychological Foundations of Incentives. European Economic Review

46, 687-724.

Falk, A, Fischbacher, U. and Gächter, S., 2003. Living in Two Neighborhoods – Social Interaction in

the Lab. CESifo Working Paper No. 954, Munich.

Fan, G., Wang, X. and Zhu, H., 2010. The Marketilization Index of China: 2009 Report on the

Relative Progress of Marketization in Different Regions. Beijing: Economic Science Publishing

House.

Fehr, E., Fischbacher, U., von Rosenbladt, B., Schupp, J, and Wagner, G.G. 2003. A Nation-Wide

Laboratory Examining Trust and Trustworthiness by Integrating Behavioral Experiments into

Representative Surveys. CESifo Working Paper No. 866, Munich.

Fehr, E., and Gächter, S. 1997. Reciprocity and Economics: The Economic Implications of Homo

Reciprocans. Working Paper, University of Zurich.

Fehr, E., and Schmidt, K.M.., 1999. A Theory of Fairness, Competition, and Cooperation. The

Quarterly Journal of Economics 114, 817–868.

Field, A., Sosa, L., and Wu, X., 2006, Impacts of Endogenous Bribes on Foreign Direct Investment.

Manuscript, Department of Economics, University of North Carolina, Chapel Hill.

Fischbacher, U., and Gächter, S. 2006. “Heterogeneous Social Preferences and the Dynamics of Free

Riding in Public Goods.” CeDEx Discussion Paper No. 2006-01, Centre for Decision Research

and Experimental Economics, Nottingham.

Fischbacher, U., Gächter, S., and Fehr, E., 2001. Are People Conditionally Cooperative? Evidence

from a Public Goods Experiment. Economics Letters 71, 397–404.

Fisman, R. and Gatti, R., 2002a. Decentralization and Corruption: Evidence across Countries. Journal

of Public Economics 83, 325-345.

Fisman, R. and Gatti, R., 2002b. Decentralization and Corruption: Evidence from U.S. Federal

Transfer Programs. Public Choice 113, 25–35.

Fisman, R. and Svensson, J., 2007. Are Corruption and Taxation Really Harmful to Growth? Firm

Level Evidence. Journal of Development Economics 83, 63-75.

Page 193: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

183  

Ford, R. C. and Woodrow, D. R., 1994. Ethical Decision Making: A Review of the Empirical

Literature. Journal of Business Ethics 13, 205–221.

Fredriksson, G. and Svensson, J., 2003. Political Instability, Corruption and Policy Formation: The

Case of Environmental Policy. Journal of Public Economics 87, 1383-1405.

Fredriksson, Per G., List, J. and Millimet, D.L., 2003. Bureaucratic Corruption, Environmental Policy

and Inbound US FDI: Theory and Evidence. Journal of Public Economics 87, 1407-1430.

Fredriksson, Per G., and Millimet, D.L., 2004. Comparative Politics and Environmental Taxation.

Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 48, 705-722.

Fredriksson, P., Vollebergh, H.R.J. and Dijkgraaf, E., 2004. Corruption and Energy Efficiency in

OECD Countries: Theory and Evidence. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management

47, 207–231.

Freedom House, 2009. Freedom on the Net: A Global Assessment of Internet and Digital Media.

Freille, S., Haque, M.E. and Kneller, R., 2007. A Contribution to the Empirics of Press Freedom and

Corruption. European Journal of Political Economy 23, 838-862.

Frey, B. S. and Feld, L. P., 2002. Deterrence and Morale in Taxation: An Empirical Analysis, CESifo

Working Paper No. 760.

Frey, B.S., and Meier, S., 2004a. Pro-social Behavior in a Natural Setting. Journal of Economic

Behavior and Organization 54, 65-88.

Frey, B.S., and Meier, S., 2004b. Social Comparisons and Pro-social Behavior: Testing ‘Conditional

Cooperation’ in a Field Experiment. American Economic Review 94, 1717-1722.

Frey, B. S., and Stutzer, A., 2000. Happiness, Economy and Institutions. Economic Journal 110, 918-

938.

Frey, B. S., and Stutzer, A., 2002. Happiness and Economics. Princeton University Press, Princeton.

Frey, B.S., and Torgler, B., 2007. Tax Morale and Conditional Cooperation. Journal of Comparative

Economics 35, 136–159.

Gächter, S., 2006. Conditional Cooperation: Behavioral Regularities from the Lab and the Field and

Their Policy Implications. unpublished manuscript, University of Nottingham.

Gerring, J. and Thacker, S.C., 2005. Do Neoliberal Policies Deter Political Corruption? International

Organization 59, 233-254.

Gërxhani, K., 2002. Tax Evasion in Albania: An Institutional Vacuum?” paper presented at the

Annual Meeting of the European Public Choice Society, Belgirate.

Glaeser, E.L., LaPorta, R., Lopez-De-Silanes, F., Shleifer, A., 2004. Do Institutions Cause Growth?

Journal of Economic Growth 9, 271-303.

Glaeser, E.L., Sacerdote, B. and Scheinkman, J.A., 1996. Crime and Social Interactions. The

Quarterly Journal of Economics 111, 507-548.

Glaeser, E.L. and Saks, R.E., 2006. Corruption in America. Journal of Public Economics 90, 1053-

1072.

Page 194: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

184  

Glaeser, E.L. and Scheinkman, J.A., 2002. Non-Market Interactions. in Advances in Economics and

Econometrics: Theory and Applications, Eight World Congress, M. Dewatripont, L.P. Hansen, and

S. Turnovsky (eds.), Cambridge University Press.

Glaeser, E.L., Scheinkman, J., Shleifer, A., 2003. The Injustice of Inequality. Journal of Monetary

Economics 50, 199-222.

Glover, S. H., Bumpus, M. A., Logan, J. E. and Ciesla, J. R., 1997. Reexamining the Influence of

Individual Values on Ethical Decisionmaking. Journal of Business Ethics 16, 1319-1329.

Goel, R.K. and Nelson, M.A., 1998. Corruption and Government Size: A Disaggregated Analysis.

Public Choice 97, 107-120.

Goel, R.K., Nelson, M.A., 2005. Economic Freedom versus Political Freedom: Cross-Country

Influences on Corruption. Australian Economic Papers 44, 121-133.

Goel, R.K., and Nelson, M.A., 2007. Are Corrupt Acts Contagious? Evidence from the United States.

Journal of Policy Modeling 29, 839-850.

Goldsmith, A.A., 1999. Slapping the Grasping Hand: Correlates of Political Corruption in Emerging

Markets. American Journal of Economics and Sociology 58, 865-883.

Gong, T., 2006. Corruption and Local Governance: the Double Identity of Chinese Local

Governments in Market Reform. The Pacific Review 19, 85-102.

Gordon, J.P.P., 1989. Individual Morality and Reputation Costs as Deterrents to Tax Evasion.

European Economic Review 33, 797-805.

Gordon, S.C., 2009. Assessing Partisan Bias in Federal Public Corruption Prosecutions. American

Political Science Review 103, 534-554.

Gottfredson, M. R. and Hirschi, T., 1990. A General Theory of Crime. Stanford: Stanford University

Press.

Gradstein, M., 2007. Inequality, Democracy and the Protection of Property Rights. The Economic

Journal 117, 252-269.

Guiso, L., Sapienza, P. and Zingales, L., 2004. The Role of Social Capital in Financial Development.

American Economic Review 94, 526-556.

Gundlach, E. and Paldam, M., 2009. The Transition of Corruption: From Poverty to Honesty.

Economics Letters 103, 146-148.

Gupta, S., Davoodi, H.R., and Alonso-Termé, R., 2002. Does Corruption Affect Income Inequality

and Poverty? Economics of Governance 3, 23-45

Gupta, S., Davoodi, H.R., and Tiongson,E.R., 2002. Corruption and the Provision of Health Care and

Education Services, in Governance, Corruption, and Economic Performance, ed. by G. T. Abed

and S. Gupta, International Monetary Fund, Washington.

Gupta, S., de Mello, L. and Sharan, R., 2001. Corruption and Military Spending. European Journal of

Political Economy 17, 749–777.

Page 195: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

185  

Güth, W, and Yaari, M.E., 1992. Explaining Reciprocal Behavior in Simple Strategic Games: An

Evolutionary Approach. in Explaining Process and Change: Approaches to Evolutionary

Economics, eds, Witt Ulrich, Michigan University Press, 23-34.

Habib, M. and Zurawicki, L., 2002. Corruption and Foreign Direct Investment. Journal of

International Business Studies 33, 291-307.

Hall, R.E., and Jones, C.I., 1999. Why do Some Countries Produce so Much More Output per Worker

than Others? Quarterly Journal of Economics 114, 83-116.

Harms, P. and Ursprung, H.W., 2002. Do Civil and Political Repression Really Boost Foreign Direct

Investments? Economic Inquiry 40, 651-663.

Harcourt, B.E., and Ludwig, J., 2006. Broken Windows: New Evidence from New York City and a

Five-City Social Experiment. University of Chicago Law Review 73, 271-320.

Hartog, J., Ferrer-i-Carbonell, A. and Jonker, N., 2002. Linking Measured Risk Aversion to

Individual Characteristics. Kyklos 55, 3-26.

Hayek, F.A., 1960. The Constitution of Liberty. University of Chicago Press, Chicago.

Heldt, T., 2005. Conditional Cooperation in the Field: Cross-Country Skiers? Behavior in Sweden.

unpublished manuscript, Uppsala University.

Henrich, J.. 2004. Cultural Group Selection, Coevolutionary Processes and Large-Scale Cooperation.

Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 53, 3-35.

Hirschman, A. O. 1970. Exit, Voice, and Loyalty. Cambridge (Mass.): Harvard University Press.

Hooper, J., 1995. The New Spaniards. London: Penguin Books.

Hofstede, G. and Hofstede, G.J., 2005. Cultures and Organizations: Software of the Mind. New York:

McGraw Hill.

Hsiao, C., 2003. Analysis of Panel Data. Cambridge University Press, New York.

Hu, A., 2001. Corruption and Social Inequality. Jiangsu Social Sciences 2001(3), 51-53.

Huntington, S.P., 1968. Political Order in Changing Societies. New Haven, Yale University Press.

Huntington, S.P., 1991. The Third Wave: Democratization in the Late Twentieth Century. University

of Oklahoma Press, Norman.

Inglehart, R. et al., 2000. Codebook for World Values Survey. Ann Arbor: Institute for Social

Research.

Jain, A.K., 2001. Corruption: A Review. Journal of Economic Surveys 15, 71-121.

Jensen, P.S., Paldam, M., 2007. The Pattern of Democracy in the 20th Century: A Study of the Polity

Index. In: Casas, J. and Schwartz, P. (Eds.), Public Choice and the Challenges of Democracy.

Edward Elgar, Cheltenham.

Junger, M., 1994. Accidents. in: T. Hirschi and M. R. Gottfredson (eds.), The Generality of Deviance.

New Brunswick: Transaction Publishers: 81-112.

Kahan, D.M., 1998. Social Meaning and the Economic Analysis of Crime. The Journal of Legal

Studies 27, 609-622.

Page 196: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

186  

Kahneman, D. and Tversky, A., 1979. Prospect Theory: An Analysis of Decision under Risk,

Econometrica 47, 263-291.

Kanazawa, S., 2005. Who Lies on Surveys, and What Can We Do About It? Journal of Social,

Political and Economic Studies 30, 361-370.

Kanbur, R and Zhang, X., 1999. Which Regional Inequality? The Evolution of Rural–Urban and

Inland–Coastal Inequality in China from 1983 to 1995. Journal of Comparative Economics 27,

686–701.

Kasper, W., and Streit, M. 1999. Institutional Economics: Social Order and Public Policy.

Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar.

Katz, M. and Shapiro, C., 1985. Network Externalities, Competition, and Compatibility. American

Economic Review 75, 424-440.

Kaufmann, D., 1997. Corruption: The Facts. Foreign Policy 107, 114-131.

Kaufmann, D., and Kraay, A., 2002. Growth without Governance. Policy Research Working Paper

Series 2928, World Bank.

Kaufmann, D., Kraay, A., and Mastruzzi, M., 2003. Governance Matters III: Governance Indicators

for 1996-2002. World Bank Economic Review 18, 253-287.

Keser, C., and van Winden, F., 2000. Conditional Cooperation and Voluntary Contributions to Public

Goods. Scandinavian Journal of Economics 102, 23-39.

Keizer, K., Lindenberg, S., and Steg, L., 2008. The Spreading of Disorder. Science 322, 1681–1685.

Kim, C.K., 1994. The Effects of Public Transfers and Tax Rate Changes on Reported Income:

Experimental Evidence. Ph.D. dissertation, University of Pittsburgh.

Klitgaard, R., 1988. Controlling Corruption. Berkeley, CA: University of California Press.

Knack, S. 1999. Aid Dependence and the Quality of Governance. IRIS Center, Working

Paper,University of Maryland.

Knack, S., 2006. Measuring Corruption in Eastern Europe and Central Asia: A Critique of the Cross-

country Indicators. Policy Research Working Paper Series 3968, World Bank.

Kornai, J., 1990. The Affinity between Ownership Forms and Coordination Mechanism: The

Common Experience of Reform in Socialistic Countries. Journal of Economic Perspective 4, 131-

147.

Krueger, A. O., 1974. The Political Economy of the Rent-Seeking Society, American Economic

Review, 64, 291-303.

Kuenzi, M., 2006. Non-Formal Education and Community Development in Senegal, Community

Development Journal 41, 210-222.

Kunicova, J., and Rose-Ackerman, S. 2005. Electoral Rules and Constitutional Structures as

Constraints on Corruption. British Journal of Political Science 35, 573-606.

Page 197: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

187  

Kurzban, R., McCabe, K., Smith, V.L. and Wilson, B.J., 2001. Incremental Commitment and

Reciprocity in A Real-Time Public Goods Game. Personality and Social Psychology Bulletin 27,

1662-1673.

Lambsdorff , J.G., 2004. Background paper to the 2004 Corruption Perceptions Index.

http://www.icgg.org/downloads/CPI_Methodology.pdf

Lambsdorff, J.G., 2005. Consequences and Causes of Corruption – What do We Know from a Cross-

Section of Countries? Discussion Papers no. V-34-05. Department of Economics, University of

Passau.

Landman, T. and Larizza, M., 2009. Inequality and Human Rights: Who Controls What, When, and

How. International Studies Quarterly 53, 715–736.

LaPalombara, J., 1994. Structural and Institutional Aspects of Corruption. Social Research 61, 325-50.

La Porta, R., Lopez-De-Silanes, F., Shleifer, A. and Vishny, R.W., 1999. The Quality of Government.

The Journal of Law, Economics and Organization 15, 222-279.

Larraín, B.F. and Tavares, J., 2004. Does Foreign Direct Investment Decrease Corruption? Latin

American Journal of Economics 41: 217-230.

Larraín, B.F. and Tavares, J., 2007. Can Openness Deter Corruption? The Role of Foreign Direct

Investment. CEPR Discussion Papers no. 6488.

Leff, N.H., 1964. Economic Development through Bureaucratic Corruption. American Behavioural

Scientist 8, 8-14.

Leeson, P.T. and Sobel, R.S., 2008. Weathering Corruption. Journal of Law and Economics 51, 667-

681.

Leite, C. and Weidmann, J., 1999. Does Mother Nature Corrupt? Natural Resources, Corruption and

Economic Growth. IMF Working Paper no. 99/85.

Lenin, V.I., 1916. The Socialist Revolution and the Right of Nations to Self-Determination.

Vorbote 2.

Lewis, A. 1982. The Psychology of Taxation. Oxford: Martin Robertson.

Levi, M., 1988. Rules and Revenue. Berkeley/Los Angeles/London: University of California Press.

Levine, R. and Renelt, D., 1992. Sensitivity Analysis of Cross-Country Growth Regressions.

American Economic Review 82, 942-963.

Levin, M. and Satarov, G., 2000. Corruption and institutions in Russia. European Journal of Political

Economy 16, 113-132.

Li, H., and Zhou, L.-A., 2005. Political Turnover and Economic Performance: the Incentive role of

Personnel Control in China. Journal of Public Economics 89, 1743-1762.

Li, S.-M., 2001. Regional Development in China: States, Globalization and Inequality. China Review

International 8, 572-578.

Li, H., Xu, L.C., and Zou, H., 2000. Corruption, Income Distribution, and Growth. Economics and

Politics 12, 155-182.

Page 198: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

188  

Li, S. and Hou, Y., 2003. Analysis on Socio-economic Characteristics of Chinese Regions. Research

Report, Department of Development Strategy and Regional Economy, Development Research

Centre of the State Council.

Liang, G., 1994. The Practical Encyclopaedia of Anti-Corruption in China and Foreign Countries.

Beijing: Xinhua Press.

Liu, A. P. L., 1983. The Politics of Corruption in the People’s Republic of China. American Political

Science Review 77, 602-623.

Lopez, R. and Mitra, S., 2000. Corruption, Pollution, and the Kuznets Environment Curve. Journal of

Environmental Economics and Management 40, 137-150.

Lu, Y., Png, I.P.L., and Tao, Z., 2010. Do Institutions not Matter in China? Evidence from

Manufacturing Enterprises. http://www.comp.nus.edu.sg/~ipng/research/instn.pdf.

Ludwig, J., and Kling, J.R., 2006. Is Crime Contagious? Working Papers Series 85, Center for

Economic Policy Studies, Department of Economics, Princeton University.

Lui, F.T. 1986. A Dynamic Model of Corruption Deterrence. Journal of Public Economics 31, 215-

236.

Lui, F.T., 1985. An Equilibrium Queuing Model of Bribery. Journal of Political Economy 93, 760-

781.

Lundberg, M., and Squire, L., 2003. The Simultaneous Evolution of Growth and Inequality.

Economic Journal, 113, 326–344.

Manion, M., 1996. Corruption by Design: Bribery in Chinese Enterprise Licensing. Journal of Law,

Economics, & Organization 12, 167-195.

Mauro, P., 1995. Corruption and growth. Quarterly Journal of Economics 110, 681-712.

Mauro, P., 1998. Corruption and the Composition of Government Expenditure. Journal of Public

Economics 69, 263–279.

Mauro, P., 2004. The Persistence of Corruption and Slow Economic Growth. IMF Staff Papers 51, 1.

Manski, C.F., 1993. Identification of Endogenous Social Effects: The Reflection Problem. Review of

Economic Studies 60, 531-542.

Manski, C.F., 2000. Economic Analysis of Social Interactions. Journal of Economic Perspectives 14,

115-136.

Martin, R., and Randal, J., 2005. Voluntary Contribution to a Public Good: A Natural Field

Experiment. unpublished manuscript, Victoria University of Wellington, Wellington.

Martinez-Vazquez, J., and McNab, R.M., 2000. The Tax Reform Experiment in Transition Countries.

National Tax Journal 53, 273-298.

Marx, K. 1849. Wage Labor and Capital. in K. Marx and F. Engels, Selected Works, Vol.1,

Moscow: Progress Publishers.

Mason, R. and Calvin, L. D., 1984. Public Confidence and Admitted Tax Evasion. National Tax

Journal 37, 490-496.

Page 199: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

189  

Mears, D. P., Ploeger, M. and Warr, M., 2000. Explaining the Gender Gap in Delinquency: Peer

Influence and Moral Evaluations of Behavior, in: R. D. Crutchfield, G. S. Bridges, J. G. Weis and

C. Kubrin, Crime Readings. Thousand Oaks: Pine Forge Press: 143-148.

Mendez, F., and Sepulveda, F., 2006. Corruption, Growth and Political Regimes: Cross Country

Evidence. European Journal of Political Economy 22, 82-98.

Meng, X., Gregory R. and Wang Y., 2005. Poverty, inequality, and growth in urban China, 1986–

2000. Journal of Comparative Economics 33, 710-729.

Méon, P.-G. and Sekkat, K., 2005. Does Corruption Grease or Sand the Wheels of Growth? Public

Choice 122, 69-97.

Méon, P.-G. and Weill, L., 2008. Is Corruption an Efficient Grease? Bank of Finland, Institute for

Economies in Transition, BOFIT Discussion Papers 20/2008.

Mishra, A., 2006. Persistence of Corruption: Some Theoretical Perspectives. World Development 34,

349–358.

Mo, P.H., 2001. Corruption and Economic Growth. Journal of Comparative Economics 29, 66-79.

Mobarak, A.M., 2005. Democracy, Volatility and Development. The Review of Economics and

Statistics 87, 348-361.

Mocan, N., 2008. What Determines Corruption? International Evidence from Microdata. Economic

Inquiry 46, 493-510.

Mohtadi, H., Roe, T.L., 2003. Democracy, Rent Seeking, Public Spending and Growth. Journal of

Public Economics 87, 445-466.

Montinola, G.R., Jackman, R.W., 2001. Sources of Corruption: A Cross-Country Study. British

Journal of Political Science 32, 147-170.

Montinola, G. Qian, Y. and Weingast, B.R., 1995. Federalism, Chinese Style: The Political Basis for

Economic Success in China. World Politics 48, 50-81.

Murphy, K.M., Shleifer, A., and Vishny, R.W., 1991. The Allocation of Talent: Implications for

Growth. Quarterly Journal of Economics 106, 503-530.

Murphy, K.M., Shleifer, A., and Vishny, R.W., 1993. Why is Rent-Seeking so Costly to Growth?

American Economic Review 83, 409-414.

Myles, G.D. and Naylor, R.A., 1996. A Model of Tax Evasion with Group Conformity and Social

Custom. European Journal of Political Economy 12, 49-66.

Naylor, R.A., 1989. Strikes, Free Riders and Social Customs. Quarterly Journal of Economics 104,

771-805.

Nevo, A., 2001. Measuring Market Power in the Ready-to-Eat Cereal Industry. Econometrica 69,

307-442.

Nowell, C. and Tinkler, S., 1994. The Influence of Gender on the Provision of a Public Good. Journal

of Economic Behavior and Organization 25, 25-36.

Oates, W. E. 1999. An Essay on Fiscal Federalism. Journal of Economic Literature 37, 1120-1149.

Page 200: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

190  

Ostrom, E., 2000. Collective Action and the Evolution of Social Norms. Journal of Economic

Perspectives 14, 137-158.

Paldam, M., 2001. Corruption and Religion: Adding to the Economic Model. Kyklos 54, 383-413.

Paldam, M. and Svendsen, G.T., 2000. Missing Social Capital and the Transition in Eastern Europe.

Working Papers 00-5, Aarhus School of Business, Department of Economics.

Pappaport, J. and Sachs, J.D., 2003. The United States as a Coastal Nation. Journal of Economic

Growth 8, 5-46.

Paternoster, R., Simpson, S., 1996. Sanction Threats and Appeals to Morality: Testing a Rational

Choice Model of Corporate Crime. Law and Society Review 30, 549-583.

Pellegrini, L. and Gerlagh, R., 2004. Corruption's Effect on Growth and its Transmission Channels.

Kyklos 57, 429-456.

Pelligrini, L. and Gerlagh, R., 2006a. Corruption, Democracy and Environmental Policy: An

Empirical Contribution to the Debate. Journal of Environment and Development 15, 332-354.

Pelligrini, L. and Gerlagh, R., 2006b. Corruption and Environmental Policies: What are the

Implications for the Enlarged EU? European Environment 16, 139-154.

Pellegrini, L. and Gerlagh, R., 2008. Causes of Corruption: A Survey of Cross-Country Analyses and

Extended Results. Economics of Governance 9, 245–263.

Persson, T., Tabellini, G., 1994. Is Inequality Harmful for Growth? American Economic Review 84,

600-621.

Plümper, T. and Troeger, V., 2007. Efficient Estimation of Time-Invariant and Rarely Changing

Variables in Finite Sample Panel Analyses with Unit Fixed Effects. Political Analysis 15, 124–139.

Polinsky, M.A. and Shavell, S., 1999. Corruption and Optimal Law Enforcement. Working Paper 171,

John M. Olin Program in Law and Economics, Stanford Law School.

Polinsky, M.A. and Shavell, S. 2000. The Economic Theory of Public Enforcement of Law. Journal

of Economic Literature 38, 45-76.

Posner, R.A., 1997. Social Norms and the Law: An Economic Approach. American Economic

Review 87, 365-369.

Rabin, M., 1993. Incorporating Fairness into Game Theory and Economics. American Economic

Review 83, 1281-1302.

Rabin, M., 1998. Psychology and Economics. Journal of Economic Literature 36, 11-46.

Rappaport, J. and Sachs, J., 2003. The United States as a Coastal Nation. Journal of Economic Growth

8, 5 –46.

Rege, M., 2004. Social Norms and Private Provision of Public Goods. Journal of Public Economic

Theory 6, 65-77.

Reiss, M. C. and Mitra, K., 1998. The Effects of Individual Difference Factors o the Acceptability of

Ethical and Unethical Workplace Behaviors. Journal of Business Ethics 17, 1581-1593.

Rock, M.T., 2009. Corruption and Democracy. Journal of Development Studies 45, 55 – 75.

Page 201: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

191  

Rose-Ackerman, S., 1978. Corruption: A Study in Political Economy. New York: Academic Press.

Rose-Ackerman, S. 1997. The Political Economy of Corruption, in: K. A. Elliott (ed.). Corruption and

the Global Economy. Washington D.C.: Institute for International Economics: 31-60.

Rose-Ackerman, S., 1999. Corruption and Government: Causes, Consequences, and Reform.

Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

Sachs, J.D. and Warner, A.M., 2001. The Curse of Natural Resources. European Economic Review 45,

827-838.

Sah, R.K., 1988. Persistence and Pervasiveness of Corruption: New Perspectives. Working Paper

Series, 560, Economic Growth Center, Yale University.

Sah, R., 1991. Social Osmosis and Pattern of Crime. Journal of Political Economy 99, 1272-1295.

Sah, R.. (2005). Large and Persistent Differences in Corruption across Countries and Regions.

Working Paper (http://www.economics.smu.edu.sg/events/Paper/Sah2.pdf)

Sah, R., 2007. Corruption across Countries and Regions: Some Consequences of Local Osmosis.

Journal of Economic Dynamics & Control 31, 2573–2598.

Saha, S., Gounder, R., Su, J.-J., 2009. The Interaction Effect of Economic Freedom and Democracy

on Corruption: A Panel Cross-Country Analysis. Economics Letters 105, 173-176.

Shang, J., and Croson, R., 2005. Field Experiment in Charitable Contribution: The Impact of Social

Influence on the Voluntary Provision of Public Goods. unpublished manuscript, University of

Pennsylvania, Philadelphia.

Scheinkman, J. A., 2008. Social Interactions. in The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics (2nd ed.),

S. Durlauf and L. Blume (eds.), Palgrave Macmillan.

Shleifer, A., Vishny, R.W., 1993. Corruption. Quarterly Journal of Economics 108, 599–617.

Sicular, T., Yue, X., Gustafsson, B. and Li, S., 2007. The Urban–Rural Income Gap and Inequality in

China. Review of Income and Wealth 53, 93 – 126.

Smarzynska, B.K. and Wei, S.-J., 2000, Corruption and the Composition of Foreign Direct Investment:

Firm-Level Evidence. World Bank Discussion Paper no. 2360.

Smith, A. 1759/1976. The Theory of Moral Sentiments. Oxford: Clarendon Press.

Sonin, K., 2003. Why the Rich May Prefer Poor Protection Of Property Rights. Journal of

Comparative Economics 31, 715-31.

Spichtig, M., and Traxler, C., 2007. Social Norms and the Evolution of Conditional Cooperation.

Discussion Papers in Economics 1398, University of Munich, Department of Economics.

Stutzer, A., 1999. Demokratieindizes für die Kantone der Schweiz. Working Paper No. 23. Institute

for Empirical Research in Economics, University of Zurich.

Sung, H., 2003. Fairer Sex or Fairer System? Gender and Corruption Revisited. Social Forces 82,

703-723.

Sung, H.-E., 2004. Democracy and Political Corruption: A Cross-National Comparison. Crime, Law

& Social Change 41, 179–194.

Page 202: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

192  

Svensson, J., 2003. Who Must Pay Bribes and How Much? Evidence from a Cross Section of Firms.

Quarterly Journal of Economics 118, 207-230.

Swamy, A., Knack, S., Lee, Y. and Azfar, O., 2001. Gender and Corruption. Journal of Development

Economics 64, 25-55.

Tanzi, V., 1995. Corruption: Arm’s-Length Relationship and Markets, in: G. Fiorentini and S.

Peltzman (ed.), The Economics of Organized Crime. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

Tanzi, V., 2002. Corruption Around the World: Causes, Consequences, Scope, and Cures, in: G. T.

Abed and S. Gupta (eds.), Governance, Corruption and Economic Performance. Washington:

International Monetary Fund: 19-58.

Tanzi, V. and Davoodi, H., 1997., Corruption, Public Spending and Growth. IMF Working Paper,

WP/97/139.

Taylor, P.D., 1979. Evolutionarily Stable Strategies with Two Types of Player. Journal of Applied

Probability 16, 76-83.

Tirole, J., 1996. A Theory of Collective Reputation (with applications to the persistence of corruption

and to firm quality). Review of Economic Studies, 1-22.

Tittle, C., 1980. Sanctions and Social Deviance: The Question of Deterrence. New York: Praeger.

Tocqueville, A.de, 1835. Democracy in America.

http://ebooks.adelaide.edu.au/t/tocqueville/alexis/democracy/.

Torgler, B., 2005. Tax Morale and Direct Democracy. European Journal of Political Economy 21,

525-531.

Torgler, B., 2006. “The Importance of Faith: Tax Morale and Religiosity.” Journal of Economic

Behavior and Organization 61: 81-109.

Torgler, B., 2007. Tax Compliance and Tax Morale: A Theoretical and Empirical Analysis.

Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar.

Torgler, B., and Schneider, F., 2009. The Impact of Tax Morale and Institutional Quality on the

Shadow Economy. Journal of Economic Psychology 30, 228-245.

Torgler, B., and Valev, N.T., 2006. Corruption and Age. Journal of Bioeconomics 8, 133-145.

Torgler, B. and Valev, N. T. 2007. Public Attitudes Toward Corruption and Tax Evasion:

Investigating the Role of Gender Over Time. School of Economics and Finance Discussion Papers

and Working Papers Series 214, Queensland University of Technology

Traxler, C., 2006. Social Norms and Conditional Cooperative Taxpayers. Discussion Papers in

Economics 1202, Department of Economics, University of Munich.

Treisman, D., 2000. The Causes of Corruption: A Cross-National Study. Journal of Public Economics

76, 399-457.

Treisman, D., 2007. What Have We Learned About the Causes of Corruption From Ten Years of

Cross-National Empirical Research? Annual Review of Political Science 10, 211–244.

Page 203: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

193  

van Rijckeghem, C. and Weder, B., 2001. Bureaucratic Corruption and the Rate of Temptation: Do

Wages in the Civil Service affect Corruption, and by How Much? Journal of Development

Economics 65, 307-331.

Veblen, T. 1899. The Theory of the Leisure Class. New York: MacMillan.

Verba, S., Schlozman, K. H. and Brady, H., 1995. Voice and Equality: Civic Voluntarism in

American Politics. Cambridge: Harvad University Press.

Wedeman, A., 2004. The Intensification of Corruption in China. The China Quarterly 180, 895-921.

Wei, S.-J., 2000a. How Taxing is Corruption on International Investors. Review of Economics and

Statistics 82, 1-11.

Wei, S.-J., 2000b. Local Corruption and Global Capital Flows. Brookings Papers on Economic

Activity, 2000(2), 303-354.

Weingast, B., 1995. The Economic Role of Political Institutions: Market-Preserving Federalism and

Economic Development. Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization 11, 1-31.

Welsch, H., 2004. Corruption, Growth, and the Environment: a Cross-Country Analysis.

Environment and Development Economics 9, 663–693.

White, G., 1996. Corruption and the Transition from Socialism in China. Journal of Law and society

23, 149-169.

Wintrobe, R., 2006. Rational Extremism: The Political Economy of Radicalism. Cambridge

University Press: Cambridge.

Wooldridge, J.M. (2002). Econometric Analysis of Cross Section and Panel Data. MIT Press:

Cambridge.

World Bank, 1997. Helping Countries Combat Corruption: The Role of the World Bank. Poverty

Reduction and Economic Management, World Bank.

World Bank, 2000. Anticorruption in Transition: A Contribution to the Policy Debate. World Bank

Publication. Washington D.C.: World Bank.

World Bank, 2006. Governance, Investment Climate and Harmonious Society. Washington D.C.:

World Bank.

Wu, Y., 2008. Fiscal Decentralization, Corruption and Governance. China Economic Quarterly 7,

1045-1060.

Xu, K.-N. and Wang, J., 2006. An Empirical Study of a Linkage between Natural Resource

Abundance and Economic Development. Economic Research Journal 2006(1), 78-89.

Yang, Z. and Ye, F., 1993. Studies on Semi-colonization of Qing Dynasty. Beijing: Higher Education

Press.

Yao, S., 2002. Privilege and Corruption: The Problems of China's Socialist Market Economy.

American Journal of Economics and Sociology 61, 279-299.

You, J.-S. and Khagram, S., 2005. Inequality and Corruption. American Sociological Review 70, 136-

157.

Page 204: THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF CORRUPTIONeprints.qut.edu.au/44126/1/Bin_Dong_Thesis.pdf · The thesis then continues by ... human societies ... This study provides new insight into

 

194  

Zager, M. A., 1994. Gender and Crime, in: T. Hirschi and M. R. Gottfredson (eds.), The Generality of

Deviance. New Brunswick: Transaction Publishers: 71-80.

Zanella, G., 2004. Social Interactions and Economic Behaviour. Working paper No. 411, Department

of Economics, University of Siena.

Zhang, T. and Zou, H.-F., 1998. Fiscal Decentralization, Public Spending, and Economic Growth in

China. Journal of Public Economics 67, 221-240.


Top Related