dri clarissa

Upload: credenciais

Post on 04-Apr-2018

237 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

  • 7/31/2019 DRI Clarissa

    1/33

    The Mercosur Parliament: democracy and integration

    on European patterns?

    Clarissa Franzoi Dri

    PhD Candidate - IEP de Bordeaux

    [email protected]

    Summary: 1. The role of ideas in political mimesis.2. Democracy in EU: the place of the European Parliament. 3. Regionalism after Europe:

    a parliament rises in Mercosur. 3.1. Traces of the Joint Parliamentary Committee.3.2. The Mercosur Parliament gets up on the wrong side of the bed.

    Conclusion. Bibliographical references.

    The presidents of Mercosur member states signed in December 2005

    the Constitutive Protocol of the Mercosur Parliament (Parlasur)1. The new assembly

    was officially installed in December 2006 and began its work sessions in May 2007.

    Although Parliaments functions and competences are not large in comparison to

    national chambers, it will be formed by directly elected representatives. Three main

    reasons allow the assumption that the decision to create this assembly was not

    fortuitous, ingenuous ou merely symbolic: 1. the delay and the difficult negotiations

    that preceded it; 2. the contradiction of the Mercosur objective to constitute no more

    than a common market2 and 3. the absence of a parliamentary assembly in the

    previous essays for integration in which participated Mercosur countries (Oliveira,

    2003 : 53-73). How, then, to interpret it?

    According to the Constitutive Protocol, the Parliament should answer

    to a double necessity: 1. reinforcing the integration process through a balanced and

    efficient institutional structure and 2. deepening democracy within Mercosur by

    constructing a space of plurality, participation and interest representation3. The paper

    aims at examining both purposes from the international relations perspective. More

    Paper prepared for the 3rd GARNET Annual Conference - Mapping integration and regionalism in aglobal world: the EU and regional governance outside the EU, Bordeaux, September 17-20th 2008,workshop Parliaments in regional integrations, coordinated by Olivier Costa and Julien Navarro. Draftversion.1 The abbreviation Parlasur is not official, but its formal use has been increasing among media andParliaments civil servants and deputies. This is the reason for its adoption in the paper.2

    Article 1 of the Asuncin Treaty. Available in www.mercosur.int.3 Preamble of the Constitutive Protocol (CMC Decision 23/05). The document is available inwww.parlamentodelmercosur.org.

    mailto:[email protected]://www.mercosur.int/http://www.mercosur.int/http://www.parlamentodelmercosur.org/mailto:[email protected]://www.mercosur.int/http://www.parlamentodelmercosur.org/
  • 7/31/2019 DRI Clarissa

    2/33

  • 7/31/2019 DRI Clarissa

    3/33

    rather than to transfer processes. It means this paper focuses more in Mercosur

    expectations and movements towards the EU than in specific European transfer

    policies on parliamentary issues. This choice corresponds to the ideational approach

    that supports the main hypothesis. A deeper analysis of the concrete actions carried

    out by the European Union towards the Mercosur Parliament deserves further

    research.

    The qualitative study is mainly based on public written documents

    produced by the Joint Parliamentary Committee, the Mercosur Parliament and other

    Mercosur institutions. Minutes of the Brazilian representation meetings and

    newspaper reports and interviews constitute an additional source. These data

    provide elements for the approach of the following questions: was the creation of theMercosur Parliament inspired in democratic ideas similar to those supported by the

    EU? Did the European idea of integration guide the creation of the assembly as it did

    with the Mercosur creation itself? In what measure European Unions actions

    affected this decision? Do deputies use the European Parliament as a model to

    Parlasurs institutionalization? Has the EP contributed to the democratic legitimation

    of the EU in such a way that it can be considered as a paradigm for Mercosur

    Parliaments builders? Moreover, does the European model fit in Latin American

    political context? Would it help to strengthen integration and development within the

    region?

    1. The role of ideas in political mimesis

    Several studies conducted mainly from the nineties on (Goldstein,

    1988; Hall, 1989; Sikkink, 1991; Risse-Kappen, 1994; Vennesson, 2004; Madrid,

    2005; Thomas, 2005) show that ideas, defined as beliefs shared by individuals, have

    an influence over policy-making (Goldstein and Keohane, 1993 : 3). In terms of

    European integration, authors point out, for instance, the role of the united Europe

    ideal in the communitarian construction (Garrett and Weingast, 1993 : 205); the

    significance of political leaders beliefs about macroeconomic strategy in the

    evolution of the monetary cooperation (McNamarra, 1998); and the weight of the

    democratic ideology in the progressive reinforcement of European Parliaments

    3

  • 7/31/2019 DRI Clarissa

    4/33

    powers (Costa and Magnette, 2003). In fact, ideas constitute active ingredients in the

    organization of experience and in the interplay of political positions and, therefore,

    are closely implicated in political argument, understanding and action (Foley, 1994 :

    1).

    The ideas studied in this article may be understood as causal beliefs,

    in the sense that they provide guides for actors on how to achieve their objectives

    (Goldstein and Keohane, 1993 : 10). But causal beliefs imply strategies for the

    attainment of goals only understandable within the context of broader world views,

    which define the universe of possibilities for action (Ibid : 8). The conceptions of

    integration and democracy built by the European Union would be part of the

    desirable alternatives for political conduction to some actors in Mercosur. Concretely,the European Parliament would be seen as a source of inspiration on how to proceed

    in order to achieve the aims compatible to the mentioned perspective. In this case,

    these ideas could provide a consensual response to the lack of a project in Mercosur.

    As focal points, ideas alleviate coordination problems arising from the absence of

    unique equilibrium solutions. For the close actors of the Parlasur creation, these

    ideas could serve as well as road maps: causal ideas help determine which of many

    means will be used to reach desired goals and therefore help to provide actors with

    strategies with which to further their objectives; embodied in institutions, they shape

    the solution for problems (Ibid : 13-14).

    Considering the role of ideas in political outcomes is not to say that

    they are the most important explaining elements ; it is only to recognize that they are

    also important. This is confirmed by the assumption that ideas often become

    politically efficacious when in conjunction with other changes, either in material

    interests or in power relationships (Ibid : 25). Besides, probably not only beliefs

    derived from the European experience have influenced the creation of the Parlasur.

    Nevertheless, analysing these additional factors is beyond the scope of this paper. Its

    goal is simply to question if certain European ideals integration and democracy

    affected the process of rise of the new South American assembly.

    But avoiding reducionism requires at least to mention why these

    ideas would have enough force in order to be considered in the context of Mercosur.

    The conditions that allow the play of ideas are highly dependent on an array ofenabling circumstances related to institutional arrangements, place, timing, history,

    4

  • 7/31/2019 DRI Clarissa

    5/33

    economics and culture (Risse-Kappen, 1994 : 187; Ikenberry, 1993 : 85; Garrett,

    1993 : 203; Hall, 1989 : 362; Weir, 1989 : 56-59). The analysis developed in the

    following sections will hopefully contribute to the understanding of reasons such as

    the European colonization in Latin America (LA), the industrialization process in

    Argentina and Brazil during the seventies, the financial, technical and political

    investment of the European Union in Mercosur, the wave of left-wing government

    elections in South America from the end of the 1990s on, the increasing popular

    questioning of the United States influence in Latin America, the failure of the

    negotiations for the Free Trade Area of the Americas (FTAA) and the knowledge on

    the European system by scholars who active participate in Mercosur debates.

    The ideas under analysis may have led Mercosur to a process ofreproduction of the institutional framework of the European Union. Institutional

    mimicry can be defined as a form of social engineering distinguished by the

    importation of external institutional technologies which are rebuilt by exporters and

    importers and constantly reinterpreted by competing political strategies (Darbon,

    1993 : 119-120). Three main elements emerge from this conception. First,

    institutional mimesis is almost always an affair of elites, who have material

    possibilities to get in touch with foreign practices. These exchanges are facilitated by

    informal networks of experts, scholars and policy-makers from different continents

    who share similar references and values (Mny, 1993 : 20-22). Second, the

    envisaged model is often an ideal one, engendered by the representation held by

    importers. The difficulties and limitations of the institution in its original environment

    are frequently neglected (Darbon, 1993 : 120). Finally, the mechanism of mimesis

    implies transformation and adjustment to the new context. Local needs and previous

    experiences will define the process of institutional appropriation and reinvention

    (Mny, 1993 : 10). Like a graft, the imported technology is progressively rejected or

    assimilated by the organism. If there is no reaction regarding the strange body, it

    becomes ineffective after a process of deviation or escapism (Darbon, 1993 : 120).

    Mimetic processes are among the means defined by DiMaggio and

    Powell through which institutional isomorphic change occurs. When organizational

    technologies are poorly understood, when goals are ambiguous or when the

    environment creates symbolic uncertainty, organizations may model themselves on

    other organizations (1983 : 151). As a response to uncertainty, the Mercosur

    5

  • 7/31/2019 DRI Clarissa

    6/33

    Parliament may be based in a sort of modeling. Institutional convergence can

    contribute efficiently and in a cheap manner to the achievement of desirable similar

    results (Mny, 1993 : 17-18). In addition, the dependence on the support from a

    single institution and the reduced number of available institutional models may

    explain isomorphism in this case (DiMaggio and Powell, 1983 : 155).

    Every political system tends to search for inspiration in existent

    models. If institutions rise and change in a world already full of them, the conditioning

    by previous frameworks is inevitable (Hall and Taylor, 1997 : 490). Institutional

    mimesis can thus occur among systems either with similar or different political

    standards and levels of industrialization. The last situation was historically verified

    during the processes of decolonization: in general, ex-colonies mirrored their newregimes in the features of colonizer countries. This context of unequal rapports

    revealed antagonisms between modernity and lack of civilization, cultural

    refinement and uncultivated usages. Institutional mimicry allowed the construction

    of legitimizing ideologies which opposed dominant models and imperfect copies

    (Darbon, 1993 : 114). Contemporary, in spite of the proclaimed respect to cultural

    diversity, the occidental state still claims a universalistic vocation which produces

    cultural dependency and defines the current international order (Badie, 1992). The

    institutional mimesis potentially developed by the Mercosur Parliament vis--vis the

    European Union corresponds to this logic. Yet Latin America oscillates between its

    occidental pretensions and its indigenous origins, the differences regarding Europe

    do not concur to a horizontal relationship. The Europeanization phenomenon,

    irrefutable in some aspects of national life within member states and applicant states

    (Featherstone, 2003), has perhaps surpassed the continent. Most forms of

    cooperation among states can be classified after the European style, which is

    probably the case of Mercosur. In this case, challenges concern the risks of

    implementing political technologies invented for a diverse reality, more important in

    asymmetrical transfers than in symmetrical ones. Next sections conceptualize both

    democracy and integration, ideas that may have encouraged this institutional

    mimesis within the Mercosur Parliament.

    2.

    Democracy in EU: the place of the European Parliament

    6

  • 7/31/2019 DRI Clarissa

    7/33

    The first registers of democracy date from Antiquity, but it is possible

    that some practices have taken place even before Greece and Rome. The classical

    theory on democracy was also born in Europe during the rise of the modern state. A2500 year-old subject could not be new to the European Community (EC). In fact,

    academic analysis is vast in this field, although it was not central to the political

    debate until the seventies. Before that, the economic nature of the Community limited

    its necessity of democratic legitimacy to the national ambit (Tel, 1995 : 7). The EC

    was mainly understood as part of the foreign policy of each state, due to the logics of

    cooperation and sectorial integration. Another reason, of theological nature, eluded

    the legitimacy debate: the consensus that integration was the most efficient methodto achieve peace and development in Europe (Magnette, 2000 : 174). Avoid future

    wars and launch prosperity are ideals which based the European construction and

    reached to unify national leaders positions (Weiler, 1995). As the project should be

    supported by its ends, questions about its means became secondary.

    The inclusion of the Common Assembly (CA) in the European Coal

    and Steel Community (ECSC) Treaty, in 1952, confirms that efforts for democracy at

    the supranational level were feeble at the time. There was a consensus that the HighAuthority should be controlled: transferring competencies to the Community required

    accountability mechanisms. But governments agreed that the CA would not be able

    to exercise legislative or policy-influencing powers. Democracy was accepted in the

    form of the CA, but it should not make a difference (Rittberger, 2005 : 106). In

    addition, the intergovernmental branch (the Council) should allow state

    representation and, consequently, afford possibility for national parliaments actions.

    The situation started to change when both economic and theologicalpremises were questioned. The recession period revealed the fragilities of a simply

    common market, and peace became more a fact than a concern. When finalities

    missed, attentions turned back to procedures and institutions, which intended to be

    functional and efficient, but not necessarily democratic. Therefore, the debate on

    democracy was opened in Europe through the democratic deficit assumptions. The

    Community was challenged to address directly to the people to seek for support.

    Since then, Europe has been trying to convince citizens of its conformity to theirvalues and aspirations. Enlarged competences and direct elected representatives

    7

  • 7/31/2019 DRI Clarissa

    8/33

    were considered key elements to achieve political legitimacy. Nonetheless, the

    European elections of 1979 did not beat its partisans expectations. The level of

    participation was considered weak and went down progressively at each new

    election (see Blondel et al, 1998). The electoral campaign remained centered in

    national questions. Even if the direct suffrage contributed to expand the studies on

    the Community and to warrant a triple organic, institutional and political

    independence to the EP (Costa, 2001 : 35-37), it was not able to substantially

    improve individuals perception on the integration.

    With the signature of the Maastricht Treaty, in 1992, the democratic

    discourse entered more emphatically in the supranational arena. As the European

    Single Act of 1986 was judged too economic to face some political rearrangements ofthe 1990s (the German reunification and the end of the communist era in the USSR),

    Maastricht was conceived to advance deeper and faster forward the political

    integration (Wolton, 1993 : 27). New concepts and ideas were introduced mainly

    the European citizenship, the monetary union and the denomination European

    Union but democracy was treated more like a symbol than a practice, even during

    the negotiations for the Treaty. The outputs remained a central element of legitimacy,

    whilst the inputs, as the organization of citizens participation on decisions, were not

    developed (Magnette, 2000, p. 184). Once more, the reinforcement of the European

    Parliaments powers should cover the gap. Parliamentary competences were

    enlarged, like in 1985, and a new legislative procedure was added to the Single Act

    cooperation: the co-decision. It gave the deputies the same political weight as the

    Council, due to the necessity of agreement between both institutions to approve a

    project. The Amsterdam Treaty, of 1999, expanded the areas of co-decision and

    simplified the procedure, besides confirming the investiture of the Commission by the

    Parliament. However, the increase of formal legitimacy did not avoid a decline of

    public opinion legitimacy (Tel, 1995 : 18).

    Like the previous ones, the following treaties were not able not give

    efficient responses to the democratic deficit question. The Nice Treaty, signed in

    2001, increased the parliamentary features of EUs political system mainly through

    the limitation of the number of commissars, the extension of the majoritarian vote

    field in the Council and the improvement of EPs powers (enlargement of the co-

    decision procedure and possibilities to act in the Court of Justice). The project of the

    8

  • 7/31/2019 DRI Clarissa

    9/33

    European Constitution (2004) offered an important position to the dialogue with civil

    society, but it would not strongly affect the ancient institutional logic (Costa, 2004 :

    279). Some of its previsions would also make the EU system more similar to the

    nation-state: the parliamentary election of the president of the Commission, the two-

    year presidency of the Council and the creation of the Foreign Affairs representative.

    After the rejection of the Constitution in France and the Netherlands, the Lisbon

    Treaty (2007) should simplify and assure efficacy to an institutional arrangement

    capable to deal with the challenges of the enlarged Europe. But this federal belief,

    according to which treaties should warrant Europe more democracy, is apparently

    more risky than adopting a functional approach and advance integration through

    punctual discussions (Costa and Magnette, 2007a).

    Theoretically, the European Union meets Dahls criteria for a large-

    scale democracy: elected officials; free, fair and frequent elections; freedom of

    expression; access to alternative sources of information; associational autonomy and

    inclusive citizenship (1998 : 85-86). The dysfunctions rely on the differences of this

    special large-scale democracy from the traditional nation-state features (Magnette,

    2000 : 200). First, the community method (Quermonne, 2001 : 50), searching for a

    balance between the intergovernmental and supranational branches, does not point

    one central and hierarchical authority. Instead, the logic of cooperation among

    institutions prevails. Second, parties and other traditional political actors do not fit

    well in the highly consensual and non-ideological European style. Sectorial actors

    strategies (lobby, interest groups, specialized organizations) seem more appropriate

    to deal with the fragmentation of European policies. Third, the existence of a

    European public space, understood as a symbolic or material place of political

    communication (Sintomer, 2003 : 179), is vigorously questioned. In general, citizens

    attitudes towards UE vary between indifference and suspicion and they cannot be

    considered to form an European society (Smith, 2004 : 46). Political cleavages and

    the sovereignty principle, fundamental characteristics of occidental democracies, can

    barely be reproduced in the European Union. This situation helps to explain the

    perceived elitism in the European construction (Costa and Magnette, 2007b) and

    may confirm Dahls prevision that democracy, as states conceive it, is unlikely to

    move up to the international level (1998 : 117).

    9

  • 7/31/2019 DRI Clarissa

    10/33

    The European Parliament is directly affected by the chronic lack of

    legitimacy of the supranational level. If EU contradicts national logics of decision-

    making and interest representation, an elected assembly inspired in the national

    chambers cannot warrant a general democratic reliance on the Union (Costa, 2001 :

    63). In spite of it, one of the reasons to the significant increase of powers achieved by

    the EP since its creation was governments expectative to minimize the democratic

    deficit (Costa and Magnette, 2003; Rittberger, 2005). Parliaments creation and

    empowerment are connected to democratic needs, but the communitarian logic limits

    its role in promoting democracy. This is why the European political system can

    neither be considered exactly parliamentary nor presidential: the process of

    parliamentarization at the regional scale corresponded to the specificities and

    originality of the EU, not to the nation-state model (Costa, 2004; Magnette, 1999).

    If the European Parliament itself is not able to surpass the

    supranational democratic deficit, why could it be a source of democratic inspiration to

    the Mercosur Parliament? A broad analytical register allows some answers which

    might have motivated the involved actors.

    1. The European Union has been, since its origins, the most democratic process of

    regional integration with ambitions which surpassed the establishment of a free tradearea. Its difficulties to improve democracy cannot be denied, but tensions among

    descriptive and prescriptive practices are inherent to a democratic system.

    Democracy results from, and is shaped by, the interactions between its ideals and

    its reality, the pull of an oughtand the resistance of an is (Sartori, 1987 : 8). As

    Mercosur itself was partially inspired in the European model, it is intelligible that EUs

    institutions and procedures are considered a possible source for the democratization

    process in the South American bloc.

    2. Even if Latin American experiences of democracy are able to inspire a democratic

    construction beyond the nation-state, some of its shapes are considered a sort of

    delegative democracy (ODonnell, 1994), also called low-intensity, poor or

    democracy or democracy by default. Political institutions used to be too weak to

    ensure the representation of diverse interests, constitutional supremacy, the rule of

    law, constraint of executive authority, accountability among powers or programmatic

    rather than personalistic projects situation that still persists in some countries. The

    10

  • 7/31/2019 DRI Clarissa

    11/33

    reproduction of the European institutional arrangement may constitute an essay to

    build up a more efficient and deeper democracy in Mercosur.

    3. The European democratic deficit does not impede the Parliament to effectively

    influence communitarian decisions. In Mercosur, presidents, ministers and diplomatshave always negotiated and defined most of the policies without consulting the

    parliamentary branch. The Mercosur Parliament may contribute to democracy in the

    regional level just by promoting an effective parliamentary representation in the

    decision-making process.

    4. In the same direction, EPs power to control the Commission may inspire the idea

    of accountability in Mercosur. As an intergovernmental organization, Mercosur is

    generally understood as an element of States foreign policy, which should becontrolled with national mechanisms. But many decisions taken by the Common

    Market Group (CMG), the executive branch, do not need to be ratified by national

    chambers for being part of the internal functioning of Mercosur. On the other side, the

    internalization of norms, when necessary, can take several years, due to the gap

    between what governments decide in the regional level and the priorities of national

    parliaments. The development of strategies to control CMG by the Mercosur

    Parliament could improve transparency in the bloc as well as the amount of validlegislation.

    5. Transparency could also be increased if the Mercosur Parliament acts, as its

    European homologous, like a catalyst of regional demands from social organizations

    and interest groups. Industry associations and productive sectors are almost the only

    groups to be able to make their positions known by CMG. The Parliament, despite of

    its reduced powers, is already seen by several actors as a unique ally in promoting

    and draining their demands through the establishment of work programs favorable totheir claims.

    6. After the agenda-setting, the effectiveness of such a catalysis role depends on

    parliamentary deliberation. Although the deliberation on the European Parliament is

    distinguished by a sort of apoliticization resultant from the pursuit of efficiency

    (Costa, 1996) and particular supranational and federal constraints (Costa, 2001 :

    85-93), it reflects the different logics of pluralism which support the communitarian

    political system (Costa, 2001 : 107). Deliberation procedures in the Mercosur

    11

  • 7/31/2019 DRI Clarissa

    12/33

    Parliament including interest representation from various actors and institutions

    (associations of all kinds, Mercosur institutions, governments, national and local

    parliaments, municipalities) may contribute to democratic pluralism in the regional

    level.

    The proclaimed consensus about the need of democracy in Mercosur

    has several origins from different natures. Internally, it cannot be understood without

    considering the colonial period, the dictatorships which persisted until the end of the

    20th century in Latin America and parliamentarians interest in maximizing their

    political power. Externally, the concern for regulating globalization and the

    supranationality debate also imply consequences for democracy. But the argument

    presented in this paper refers to another external reason: the influence of theEuropean Union. The next section shows how the European integration determined

    some demarches in Mercosur. Many of its institutions and policies were built on and

    with financial and technical support of the EU. Therefore, the idea of integration is not

    enough to explain the creation of the Parliament. Democratic ideals derived from the

    communitarian example are essential to understand why an assembly was born

    among other institutional options.

    3. Regionalism after Europe : a parliament rises in Mercosur

    Since the 1960s, its constructors and theoreticians started to

    consider European integration as a model with a potential for being exported to other

    continents. Paradoxically, the critique of the ambiguities and the debilities of the

    European example of integration has always been followed by a strong optimism

    about its potential virtues to other regions of the world (Costa and Foret, 2005 :

    507-508). Therefore, EC institutions progressively developed an exportation policy of

    their conceptions and mechanisms, due to technical and financial support from the

    states desiring to embark on the regional venture. In the case of Mercosur (as well as

    in the Andean Community), these actions led to the rise of a representative assembly

    which replaced the intergovernamental parliamentary committee. The first part of this

    section explains the context in which Mercosur was born and its basic structure. It

    also points out some strategies of the Community to spread its integration ideal. The

    12

  • 7/31/2019 DRI Clarissa

    13/33

    second part analyses some reasons for the importation of both democracy and

    integration ideas by the Mercosur Parliament.

    3.1. Traces of the Joint Parliamentary Committee

    Fostering regional cooperation was one of the first initiatives of the

    European Community in the international field (Smith, 2008 : 76), which reflects the

    absence of a clear distinction between foreign policy and external economic policy at

    the time (Yakemtchouk, 2005 : 56). These activities were carried out by the

    Commission within the external relations framework provided by the Rome Treaty

    (1957), mainly through the Common Commercial Policy and the power to conclude

    association agreements with third countries and groups of states. The Council

    discussed broader issues in an informal and intergovernmental manner (Dumond

    and Setton, 1999 : 5). The Ministers of Foreign Affairs started in 1959 to conduct

    regular meetings, which led to a process referred to as European Political

    Cooperation (EPC). It was institutionalized only in 1970 and formalized with the

    European Single Act. At the outset, the Community drew its attention to African ex-

    colonies, so that Latin America was not chosen as a priority (Mayall, 2005; Grilli,

    1993 : 227). The first concrete attempt towards regionalism in Latin America in the

    20th century, the Latin American Free Trade Association (LAFTA), emerged thus

    based on developmental assumptions derived from the North American influence on

    the region (Santander, 2007 : 123-124) and as a reaction to the European external

    tariff and agricultural protectionism (Mattli, 1999 : 140).

    LAFTA was born in 1960 with the Montevideo Treaty. The

    negotiations were sponsored by the Economic Commission for Latin America

    (ECLA), an agency of the Economic and Social Council of the United Nations. In

    1967, LAFTA was composed by Argentina, Brazil, Mexico, Paraguay, Peru, Uruguay,

    Colombia, Equador, Venezuela and Bolivia. Its formal objective was not only to

    achieve a free trade area but also to construct a long-term development model

    attentive to social issues. Nonetheless, the absence of delegate powers and the

    reduced institutional framework did not encourage more than an economic-oriented

    organization. The formation of a continental free trade area was biased by difficulties

    13

  • 7/31/2019 DRI Clarissa

    14/33

    regarding the asymmetric levels of industrialization among states and changes in

    national political regimes (nationalist and authoritarian forces governed many Latin

    America countries during the 1960s and 1970s). Consequently, LAFTA was

    replaced by the Latin American Integration Association (LAIA), created in 1980 by the

    second Montevideo Treaty signed by the same states, plus Chile and Cuba. The

    general objective of this new association is also to promote trade liberalization in the

    region, but through less ambitious and more flexible means. Its relatively complex

    institutional design and stable Secretariat contributed to increase commercial

    negotiations among its members, which guided to the signature of bilateral and

    multilateral agreements. The Asuncin Treaty (1991), constitutive of Mercosur, is one

    of them (Bonilla, 1991 : 84-86).

    By the time of the creation of LAIA, the European Community started

    to establish deeper relations with Central and Andean Americas. The Central

    America Common Market (CACM) had been founded in 1960 and was economically

    more successful than LAFTA in its first decade. In 1984, after the military crisis

    evolving Nicaragua and El Salvador, EC took part on the negotiations to the

    pacification and democratization of the region and proposed a cooperation

    agreement, signed in 1985. In 1983, a trade and cooperation agreement was

    reached with the Andean Community, created in 1969 and today composed by

    Bolvia, Colombia, Equador and Peru. During the 1970s, bilateral trade agreements

    were concluded with Argentina, Uruguay, Brazil and Mexico. But it was after the

    adhesion of Portugal and Spain (1986) and the foundation of Mercosur (1991) that

    ties linking the Community and the South Cone were strengthened. The Maastricht

    Treaty was signed in this period, implementing the Common Foreign and Security

    Policy (CFSP) as the second pillar of EU, which tried to improve former coordination

    procedures. The CFSP is more complex than the EPC and has gradually developed

    communitarian characteristics yet not necessarily equal to the ones of the first pillar

    (Nuttall, 2000; Neuilly, 2005), but Unions external relations continued to be handled

    on an intergovernmental basis. Many scholars would still agree that the CFSP has a

    relatively small importance for the foreign policies of EUs member states and is not a

    truly comprehensive external policy (Peterson and Sjursen, 1998 : 169).

    In terms of cooperation for regionalism, the CFSP intervenes chiefly

    through political dialogue. Since 1999, five summits of European and Latin American

    14

  • 7/31/2019 DRI Clarissa

    15/33

    heads of state were organized by the Council. However, the unified and active role

    played by EU over the years in this field is actually due to the economic instruments

    of the first pillar, or the civil actions of the Union (Tel, 2005 : 176). Trade,

    cooperation and association agreements are the leading means driven by the

    Commission to stimulate integration worldwide. Actually, CFSP has been following

    economic external policies, which are highly unified and have been progressively

    politicized (Smith, 1998). This assumption corresponds to the evidence that

    economical integration goes faster than the political one in the EU. Regarding the

    European Parliament, its competences in external relations are not large but have

    been increasing4. In general, deputies support biregional initiatives of the

    Commission and even complement them by playing a special role in

    interparliamentary relations.

    Mercosur was founded in the context of LAIA negotiations by

    Argentina, Brazil, Paraguay and Uruguay. Chile, Bolivia, Equador, Peru and

    Colombia are associated countries. Venezuelas Adhesion Protocol was approved in

    2005 and waits for parliamentary ratification in Brazil and Paraguay. In addition to the

    Asuncin Treaty, the Ouro Preto Protocol (1994) and the Olivos Protocol (2002)

    define the objectives and the institutional framework of the bloc. The creation of a

    common market, the promotion of social and economic development and the

    maintenance of democracy within the member states are among Mercosur goals.

    The leading institutions are the following:

    4 The Parliament can influence trade and enlargement agreements through the assent procedure,which does not allow amendments. The co-decision is used for ordinary legislation coveringdevelopment aid. Besides, the Minister of Foreign Affairs of the current presidency answers oral

    questions in the assembly once a session. The EP can adopt resolutions on external policy, which arerarely discussed by the Council. There is also the need to approve the annual budget, which allowsthe EP a general control on Unions external actions, as well as on other subjects.

    15

    Common Market GroupCMC

    ParliamentPermanent Revision Court

    PRCCommon Market Group

    CMG

    Consultative Economic and Social ForumCESF

    Secretariat

    Mercosur Commerce CommitteeMCC

  • 7/31/2019 DRI Clarissa

    16/33

    The CMC is responsible for the main political decisions and it is

    constituted by the ministers of foreign affairs and economy of the member states.

    CMG and MCC are the executive branches, formed by diplomats and officials from

    ministries and central banks. The latter assists the former in policy-making regarding

    commercial issues. CMGs structure includes a large number of thematic committees

    and workgroups. The CESF represents the economic and social sectors of Mercosur.

    It is formed by an equal number of representatives of each member state, usually

    from labor unions, enterprise syndicates and productive sectors associations. It can

    present recommendations to CMG. The Permanent Revision Court seats in

    Asuncin. It is integrated by five arbitrators who can be requested any time to review

    Ad Hoc Courts judgments or directly decide on conflicts among member states. The

    Mercosur Secretariat, placed in Montevideo, is an organ of the CMGs structure that

    accomplishes the main administrative and technical responsibilities.

    The creation of Mercosur was generally inspired in the European

    experience (Camargo, 1999; Medeiros, 2000) and influenced by EUs exportation

    policies. The EU has promoted its own example through a double passive and active

    behavior towards Mercosur for most of the 1990s (Lenz, 2008). In the first role, EU

    fosters its ideal of integration simply by existing as a model. In the second, EU acts in

    order to diffuse the model. In the case of Mercosur, the actor-strategy includes trade,

    economic relations, political dialogue and cooperation (Lenz, 2006 : 7-9). Through

    technical assistance, facilitation measures, transfer of know-how and direct financial

    aid to institutions, EU has tried to shape Mercosur according to its own programs and

    values. In this area, the Union seems to be capable of surpassing the usual gap

    between the first and second pillars and develop a relatively successful soft

    diplomacy (Petiteville, 2005 : 137).

    Nevertheless, important points of dissonance remain between both

    integration attempts. The absence of sectorial supranationality in Mercosur is one of

    them. Governments did not transfer sovereignty to the regional level; all decisions

    are taken by consensus. Regional law does not prime over national rules nor can be

    applied to individuals or states without internalization in the national juridical systems.

    Consequently, its binding character is precarious (Ventura, 1996 : 59). In economic

    terms, it is currently seen as an imperfect customs union because of the various

    products excluded from the common external tariff. Even so the institutional structure

    16

  • 7/31/2019 DRI Clarissa

    17/33

    is gradually becoming more alike to the European Union, as shown by the rise of

    Parlasur. This event corresponds to the progressive or developmental discourse

    about Mercosur, in contrast to the realistic or liberal perspective according to which

    higher functional integration should supersede the establishment of participative or

    representative institutions (Malamud, 2006 : 6).

    The Parliament replaces from 2007 on the Joint Parliamentary

    Committee (JPC), which represented national parliaments and had consultative

    functions. Although LAFTA and LAIA did not display representative institutions, the

    Treaty for Cooperation, Development and Integration signed by Brazil and Argentina

    in 1988 comprised a parliamentary committee to follow negotiations. The Asuncin

    Treaty barely failed in including the JPC: it is not mentioned among the institutionalstructure, but at the very end, in the general provisions. The purpose of this last-

    moment organ was to accelerate the ratification of the Treaty in national chambers

    and to assure the procedure in the future, considering that more parliamentary

    consents would be necessary until the implementation of the common market. JPC

    approved its internal rules in 1991: it would be formed by 16 deputies from each

    national congress and would meet twice a year. One of its statutory attributions was

    to develop the required actions to the installation of the Mercosur Parliament.

    Since its beginning, JPC searched for closer relations with the

    European Parliament, which actively corresponded to the contacts. Until 1997, three

    meetings between both institutions have been organized (table 1), resulting in

    declarations on cooperation and on the creation of a parliamentary assembly in

    Mercosur. Four Interparliamentary Conferences EU LA have also been carried out

    in the period, whose agenda embraced the integration initiatives rising in Latin

    America and, consequently, sub-regional interparliamentary dialogue (table 2). In

    addition, in December 1995 Mercosur and EU signed the Interregional Framework

    Cooperation Agreement, which included technical assistance and interinstitutional

    cooperation to foster integration in the new bloc and formalized the basis for the

    political dialogue between the parties. However, the behavior of Mercosur deputies

    was not, in general, similar to their European colleagues: instead of questioning

    CMCs positions or trying to achieve more influence in the decision-making process,

    the parliamentarians adjusted themselves to the feeble functions of the JPC

    (Vigevani et al, 2000 : 271).

    17

  • 7/31/2019 DRI Clarissa

    18/33

    The Permanent Administrative Parliamentary Secretariat (PAPS),

    established in 1997, was responsible for introducing a new breath in the Committees

    activities. It was created after a demand of the European Commission, which asked

    in 1996 for an organ of contact to negotiate the cooperation project. In spite of the

    reduced number of the staff, the Secretariat centralized JPCs structure in

    Montevideo and offered administrative support for the meetings. In 1999, it helped to

    establish the first agenda for the institutionalization of a Parliament in Mercosur5. The

    agreement with EU was implemented in 2000 and offered JPC a budget of 960

    thousand euros, which substantially changed the dynamics of work in the

    Secretariat6.

    Based on PAPSs plan of 1999, JPC started to discuss moreconcretely the idea of creating a Parliament. The Secretariat organized seminars7

    and deputies agreed on new actions regarding the subject8. Several activities were

    financed or supported by the European Commission, and exchanges with members

    of the European Parliament continued (tables 1 and 2)9. In 2004, a permanent group

    to discuss the relations between the blocs was created. Meanwhile, explicit

    references to the European experience were common among the Brazilian

    delegation to JPC and diplomatic body10. In 2003, Argentinean and Brazilian sections

    5 JPC Provision 14/99. Most of Mercosur documents referring to the creation of the Parliament may befound in Konrad Adenauer Stiftung and Comisin Parlamentaria Conjunta. Hacia el Parlamento delMercosur. 2. ed. Montevideo: KAS Uruguay, 2006.6 Oscar Casal, former secretary of JPC, interview on July 13th 2004, Montevideo.7 JPC Provisions 11 e 12/00.8 For instance, CPC Provisions 35/00 and 05/02 (calendars for the institutionalization of theParliament), Recommendation 25/02 (creation of an ad hoc committee to work on the project) andProvision 08/03 (institutional agreement between CPC and CMC as a first step to the Parliament).9 Besides the occasions indicated in the tables, delegates from both institutions have met in theConference of Speakers of EU Parliaments, Rome, September 22-24 th 2000; Visit of members of theEuropean Parliament to Brazil, June 20th 2001; Workshop La Consulta Parlamentaria, de su concepto

    a su prctica, Buenos Aires, September 18th

    2003 (declaration reaffirming the decision to create theParliament); I Encuentro de Presidentes de las Cmaras de los Poderes Legislativos de los EstadosPartes del Mercosur, Montevideo, September 22nd 2003 (report from the work group on the creation ofthe Parliament); Workshop Parlamento do Mercosul e Integrao Fronteiria, Foz do Iguau,November 3-4th 2003; Visit of members of the European Parliament to Uruguay and Paraguay,November 21-26th 2005; Visit of members of the European Parliament to Argentina, April 17-22th 2006;Visit of members of the European Parliament to Uruguay and Paraguay and participation in the firstplenary meeting of Parlasur, May 1-8th 2007; Visit of members of the European Parliament toArgentina, March 30th April 4th 2008.10 For instance, Brazilian proposal to an agenda for the institutionalization of the Mercosur Parliament,Porto Alegre, November 9th 2000; Ney Lopes (deputy - Partido da Frente Liberal), Samuel PinheiroGuimares and Jos Botafogo Gonalves, open meeting about FTAA and Mercosur, Braslia,September 9th 2001; Confucio Moura (deputy - Partido do Movimento Democrtico Brasileiro),

    ordinary meeting of the Brazilian section of JPC, Braslia, September 18 th 2001; Dr. Rosinha (deputy -Partido dos Trabalhadores), Workshop Parlamento do Mercosul e Integrao Fronteiria, Foz doIguau, November 3-4th 2003. The reference to the European Union when Mercosur is mentioned is

    18

  • 7/31/2019 DRI Clarissa

    19/33

    presented the first written proposals concerning the Parliament, and in 2004 JPC

    arrived at a first version of the project of Constitutive Protocol, already mentioned in

    the Mercosur Work Program 2004-200611. Before that, in 2002, the Common Market

    Council decided to create the Technical Assistance Sector (TAS) within the Mercosur

    Secretariat, which would by formed by one specialist from each member state

    chosen by public concourse. The Sector should offer juridical and economical

    support to Mercosur institutions with the aim to constitute a space of common

    reflection about the development and consolidation of the bloc12. Among the four

    candidates selected, three had studied regional integration in European universities.

    They have actively participated in the processes of discussion and negotiation

    concerning the Parliament13.

    Committees members expected the approval of the draft Protocol in

    the XXVII CMC Meeting in Ouro Preto in December 2004, which would celebrate the

    10th anniversary of the Ouro Preto Protocol. But the presidents decided JPC should

    pursue the debates on the subject14. A team of specialists and civil servants of

    Mercosur and national parliaments was thus formed to technically improve the

    proposal in order to support further political discussions15. The Constitutive Protocol

    of the Mercosur Parliament was finally approved by CMC in December 200516 and

    during 2006 it was gradually ratified in each member state.

    also usual in academic sectors and media of all member states.11 JPC Provision 01/04 and CMC Decision 26/03.12 CMC Decision 30/02.13 Notably, TAS has organized seminars with Latin American and European specialists andrepresentatives from national chambers and governments. For instance, Desafos institucionales parael Mercosur: las relaciones entre Estados, instituciones e organizaciones de la sociedad, Montevideo,September 2004 (with Friedrich Ebert Stiftung) and La gobernanza democrtica en el Mercosur,Montevideo, November 2004 (with Konrad Adenauer Stiftung and Universidad Catlica del Uruguay).14

    CMC Decision 49/04.15 JPC Provision 03/05.16 CMC Decision 23/05.

    19

  • 7/31/2019 DRI Clarissa

    20/33

    Table I. Interparliamentary Meetings JPC/Mercosur Parliament Delegation for Relationswith South America/Mercosur of the European Parliament

    Where WhenEP Presidency invitation Brussels March 1994I Meeting Brussels June 1996Bureau Meeting Florianpolis October 1996II Meeting Brussels November 1998III Meeting Buenos Aires June 2000IV Meeting Strasbourg November 2001Bureau Meeting Madrid May 2002V Meeting Brussels March 2003VI Meeting Strasbourg and Luxembourg February 2004VII Meeting Buenos Aires November 2004

    VIII Meeting Brussels April 2005IX Meeting Braslia May 2005X Meeting Montevideo November 2005Meeting Brussels May 2008Meeting to be confirmed Rio de Janeiro September 2008

    Table II. Participation of JPC/Mercosur Parliament in Interparliamentary Conferences

    European Union Latin AmericaWhere When

    X Interparliamentary Conference Seville April 1991

    XI Interparliamentary Conference So Paulo May 1993XII Interparliamentary Conference Brussels June 1995XIII Interparliamentary Conference Caracas May 1997XIV Interparliamentary Conference Brussels March 1999XV Interparliamentary Conference Santiago April 2001XVI Interparliamentary Conference Brussels May 2003Meeting of Regional Integration Parliaments Puebla March 2004XVII Interparliamentary Conference Lima June 2005Meeting of Regional Integration Parliaments Trujillo October 2005Meeting of Regional Integration Parliaments Bregenz April 2006I Plenary Session of EUROLAT Brussels December 2007II Plenary Session of EUROLAT Lima April 2008

    3.2. The Mercosur Parliament gets up on the wrong side of the bed

    These are the words used by the Uruguayan newspaper El

    Observador and the website of the Mercosur Parliament itself to refer to the first

    plenary session of the new assembly17. The headline is due to the position of political

    sectors in Uruguay which petitioned the Supreme Court for the unconstitutionality of17 Available inwww.observa.com.uyand www.parlamentodelmercosur.org, May 7th 2007.

    20

    http://www.observa.com.uy/http://www.observa.com.uy/http://www.observa.com.uy/http://www.parlamentodelmercosur.org/http://www.parlamentodelmercosur.org/http://www.observa.com.uy/http://www.parlamentodelmercosur.org/
  • 7/31/2019 DRI Clarissa

    21/33

    Parlasur. They argued direct elections for this organ are against the Uruguayan

    Constitution, underlining that a political association with bigger countries do not

    correspond to the interests of Uruguay. But more than a legal conflict, the situation

    issued from a political dissonance between the left-winged majority and the

    opposition parties. The ex-president Luis Lacalle (Partido Nacional) affirmed the

    conformation of this organ is related to circumstantial political motivations, in an

    explicit reference to ideological affinities existent among Mercosur governments18. As

    the empirical results show, this point of view derives from a clear-sighted appraisal of

    political struggle in the region.

    In the end of the 1990s, the negotiations for the Free Trade Area of

    the Americas were progressing and were frequently mentioned in national debatesand institutions related to Mercosur. The Brazilian governments sympathy to the idea

    was well-known, as well as the incompatibility of FTAA with a stronger Mercosur or

    with the agreement Mercosur-EU19. On the other side, the popular mobilization was

    substantial: social movements and left-wing parties organized periodic

    demonstrations and even an informal national plebiscite which rejected the

    agreement with the United States. But to some politicians, the only way to revert the

    tendency was the election of a different government. It happened in 2002 with Luiz

    Incio Lula da Silva (Partido dos Trabalhadores). At the same time, historical

    opposition parties arrived at the government in Argentina and Uruguay, respectively

    with Nstor Kirchner (Partido Justicialista) in 2003 and Tabar Vzquez (Frente

    Amplia) in 2004. These governments are convergent in the promotion of social

    questions, like the fight against hungriness, poverty and inequality. They do not think

    only about economic growth, but also in distributing resources20.

    Among the team in charge of the foreign policy of his government,

    Lula nominated diplomats and politicians who have supported the non-participation of

    Brazil in FTAA and who have kept close contacts with other left-wing South American

    parties. In an open meeting organized in the Chamber of Deputies in 2001, the

    current secretary-general of the Ministry of Foreign Affairs compared the FTAA and

    UE models and concluded Mercosur would be the best option if it envisages

    18 El Parlamento naci con el pi izquierdo, El Observador, Montevideo, May 7th 2007.19 Samuel Pinheiro Guimares and Jos Botafogo Gonalves (diplomats) and Confucio Moura (deputy

    - Partido do Movimento Democrtico Brasileiro), open meeting about FTAA and Mercosur, Braslia,September 9th 2001; Dr. Rosinha (Partido dos Trabalhadores), Cartilha Mercosul um ABC, 2007.20 Luiz Incio Lula da Silva, Tengo mi conciencia tranquila, El Pas, Montevideo, October 1st 2006.

    21

  • 7/31/2019 DRI Clarissa

    22/33

    economic union, free movement of workers, structural funds, supranational

    institutions and other European features. Mercosur was also defined as a priority to

    the other governments21. In 2005, during the forth Summit of the Americas, Mercosur

    countries decided not to continue with the negotiations for the Free Trade Area of the

    Americas, refusing to negotiate a deal where the United States do not limit barriers

    and subsidies to their agricultural industry. The adhesion of Venezuela to Mercosur

    after the reelection of Hugo Chvez (Movimiento V Repblica/Partido Socialista

    Unido da Venezuela) in 2006 and the election of Fernando Lugo (Alianza Patritica

    para el Cambio) in Paraguay in 2008 may enlarge the distance of the bloc from the

    FTAA. In this context, the approximation with the European Union appears as an

    alternative to the North American influence through the reinforcement of integration

    (Santander, 2008 : 138-139; Tel, 2005 : 185). Mercosur governments seem to

    concur to the world viewaccording to which following European Unions steps and

    reaching a bi-regional agreement have a strategic importance to the project of

    strengthening Mercosur22.

    The year of 2003 was decisive in the conformation of Parlasur. It was

    when deputies rejected the proposal of a merely decorative Parliament23 and

    presidents said a more ambitious idea was possible24. But the consolidation of the

    project was postponed to 2005, when, besides Lula and Kirchner, Tabar was in the

    presidency. Nonetheless, this broad ideological perspective shared by governments

    is framed by their geopolitical and economic interests. If a deep regional integration

    process was always desired by Paraguay and Uruguay, the smaller and less

    industrialized countries of Mercosur, Argentina and Brazil have been more reluctant.

    Their weight in the international arena has been increasing, as well as the

    21

    Nstor Kirchner, Kirchner assume e faz duro discurso, poca, Rio de Janeiro, May 26th

    2003;Gobierno electo y partidos acuerdan la poltica exterior, El Pas, Montevideo, February 4th 2005;Canciller afirma que Uruguay priorizar el Mercosur y la Comunidad Sudamericana, La Repblica,March 1st 2005; Dr. Rosinha (deputy - Partido dos Trabalhadores), ordinary meeting of the Braziliansection of JPC, Braslia, April 28th 2005; Tabar Vazquez, Presidente uruguayo invita a pasesrabes a aumentar su comercio con la regin, La Repblica, Montevideo, May 11th 2005; TabarVazquez, Presidente de Uruguay pide mayor voz para su pas y Paraguay en el Mercosur, El Pas,Montevideo, May 13th 2005; Marco Aurlio Garcia (special assistant of the Brazilian presidency forforeign affairs), Asesor del presidente brasileo reconoce reclamos del Uruguay por asimetras, LaRepblica, Montevideo, March 2nd 2007.22 Danilo Astori (Uruguayan minister of economy), Uruguay propuso que el Mercosur instrumentearmonizacin tributaria, El Pas, Montevideo, June 19th 2005.23 Roberto Conde (Uruguayan senator Frente Amplia), Nace el Parlamento del Mercosur: Estamos

    ante a un cambio de poca, La Repblica, Montevideo, May 6th 2007.24 Alfredo Atanasof (Argentinean deputy Partido Justicialista), verbatim report of the III PlenarySession of Parlasur, Montevideo, June 25th 2007.

    22

  • 7/31/2019 DRI Clarissa

    23/33

    possibilities to see their demands listened in bilateral or multilateral commercial

    negotiations. They want Mercosur insofar as they can at times put it aside to protect

    their economy or to maximize their individual international pretensions. At the time of

    Parlasur creation, Brazil was sending troops to Haiti to coordinate the humanitarian

    mission of United Nations and fostering the debate about a permanent seat in the

    Security Council, which raised assumptions about its leadership intentions in South

    America. Argentina had publicly disapproved the Uruguayan governments decision

    to install cellulose industries close to the Uruguay River, and border Argentinean

    citizens started to block bridges linking both countries in order to obstruct the way of

    people and goods into Uruguay. Among other bilateral arrangements, Brazil and

    Argentina signed, out of the Mercosur ambit, the Mechanism for Competitive

    Adaptation, which allows the taxation of certain commodities if national productive

    sectors are in risk. This behavior clearly disliked Paraguay and Uruguay, which

    entailed negotiations for bilateral free trade agreements with the United States

    showing the same disregard for Mercosur treaties as the bigger partners. In this

    conflictive scenario, the plan concerning the Parliament rose as a focal point, an

    option that reached the assent of all parts despite their different motivations. Indeed,

    Brazil and Argentina found in the idea a way to demonstrate they were still interested

    in Mercosur without deepening the economic integration25; Uruguay and Paraguay

    expect the assembly to be able to compel their neighbors to invest more in the

    regional project (Caetano et al, 2006).

    This last prospect also motivated some deputies, civil servants and

    specialists who were responsible for detailing the Parliament proposal. The general

    knowledge about the European Parliaments role in pushing forward the European

    integration, in controlling the executive organs and in calling the attention of citizens

    supported a belief about a cause-effect relationship between the Mercosur

    Parliament and the reinforcement of integration and democracy in the bloc26. This

    causal belief stimulated the use of the EP model as a road map which offered

    strategies to guide the action. Regional integration may be driven by the25 Rgis Arslanian (Brazilian embassador to ALADI and Mercosur), Banco del Sur podra ser el primerpaso para una moneda comn en el Mercosur, La Repblica, Montevideo, May 28th 2007; SamuelPinheiro Guimares (secretary-general of the Brazilian ministry of foreign affairs), Opinin Cmose define el Mercosur actual?, El Pas, Montevideo, December 10th 2007; Srgio Abreu (ex-ministerof foreign affairs of Uruguay), Opinin Cmo se define el Mercosur actual?, El Pas, Montevideo,

    December 10th 2007.26 Oscar Casal (former secretary of JPC), Parlamento del Mercosur: sin levantar vuelo, MercosurABC, Buenos Aires, May 9th 2008.

    23

  • 7/31/2019 DRI Clarissa

    24/33

    convergence of interests (Malamud and Schmitter, 2007 : 9), but in this case ideas

    pointed out where to drive.

    The European world view is manifest in another policy choice from

    the same period: the creation of the Mercosur Convergence Fund (FOCEM)27

    . TheFund should finance programs to promote competitiveness and social cohesion of

    the smaller and less developed economies, besides supporting the institutions and

    the reinforcement of integration. It meets ancient demands from Paraguay and

    Uruguay concerning the consideration of asymmetries within the bloc. Along with the

    Parliament, FOCEM also responds to some critics from the European Commission in

    regards to the limits of the economic integration. That is, instead of improving free

    trade or legislation efficacy

    28

    , Mercosur opts for indirect measures which are able toindicate a relative commitment to the project in order to continue the negotiation of

    cooperation and commercial agreements.

    The EU not only instigates more integration in Mercosur but also

    finances it. According to the Commission, the Union is by far the largest supplier of

    assistance to the region29. According to Romano Prodi, Mercosur is a political and

    economic priority to the Commission not only because of strategic reasons, but also

    for cultural and historical motivations. The European Union will always support theregional integration in Mercosur as an important source of prosperity to our people

    and as a contribution to peace, security and sustainable development in Latin

    America30. In the Regional Strategy Paper 2002-2006, the EC presented an

    indicative contribution of 48 millions to support financial, technical and economic

    cooperation within Mercosur, including broad institutionalization and specific aid to

    the Parliamentary Committee. The report clarifies that although Mercosur is inspired

    by the EU, the progress and the modalities of the institutional architecture are a

    sovereign right of the states participating in Mercosur. For this very reason, our co-

    operation in this area has to be particularly sensitive, respectful and always at

    27 CMC Decisions 45/04, 18/05 and 17/06.28 These were areas criticized by Pascal Lamy, former European Commissioner for Trade, and KarlFalkenberg, former Director for Free Trade Agreements, Trade Directorate-General of the EuropeanCommission, who said Mercosur risked to become an incomplete pregnancy or more a vision than areality. Funcionario europeo remarca demoras en armado legal del Mercosur, La Nacin, BuenosAires, March 15th 2004; Editorial Brasil cedeu, mas reforou o Mercosul, Valor Econmico, SoPaulo, December 18th 2003.29

    Available inwww.ec.europa.eu/external_relations/mercosur/.30 European Commission. Unin Europea Mercosur: una asociacin para el futuro. Montevideo, May2002.

    24

    http://ec.europa.eu/external_relations/mercosur/http://ec.europa.eu/external_relations/mercosur/http://ec.europa.eu/external_relations/mercosur/
  • 7/31/2019 DRI Clarissa

    25/33

    request of Mercosur31. This technical and financial aid was thus formally requested

    by JPC as a continuum of the former accord32. In 2005 both institutions celebrated a

    convention to support the installation of the Mercosur Parliament, which dedicated

    900.000 to the activities of the new assembly. According to JPC, this project would

    allow Mercosur and EU to work together and to benefit from the mutual experience

    in terms of parliamentary integration33. In 2007 EC defined Mercosur

    institutionalization as the first priority to the Regional Indicative Programme

    2007-2013, which assured this area 10% of the 50 millions dedicated to cooperation

    with Mercosur. This cooperation is closely related to institutional mimesis, as JPC

    was under permanent pressure of its main resource supplier.

    In a broader sense, Mercosur has been influenced by the EuropeanUnion since its creation, as both parts searched for contacts and agreements from

    the beginning of the 1990s on. In addition, EU may shadow other examples because

    it is certainly the most significant and far-reaching attempt at regionalism (Malamud

    and Schmitter, 2007 : 4). The European model has always been more or less present

    in the imaginary of elites who conduct Mercosur. Ideas related to this single

    experience were thus available at the moment of conceiving a parliament (Weir, 1989

    : 54).

    UEs policies to foster regional cooperation are recently connected

    with an essay to export values worldwide through the emergence of a soft

    diplomacy combining economic resources with political ambitions (Petiteville, 2005 :

    128). In fact, democracy, the rule of law, human rights and fundamental freedoms are

    expressly mentioned by the Maastricht Treaty among the goals of the Common

    Foreign and Security Policy. The promotion of respect for human rights was included

    in EUs foreign policy agenda in the 1970s, while democracy and good governance

    became a clear objective after the 1990s. Some reasons for such a policy are the

    belief that these principles are desirable ends in themselves and they can further

    social and economic development (Smith, 2008 : 151-152). These motivations are

    explicit in the speech of Srgio Sousa Pinto, the chairman of the Delegation for

    relations with Mercosur of the EP, during the first plenary session of Parlasur. He

    31 European Commission, External Relations Directorate-General, Mercosur Unit. Mercosur European Community Strategy Paper 2002-2006, Brussels, 2005. p. 26.32

    JPC Provision 10/03.33 JPC Recommendation 01/06 (Informe de actividades del primer semestre de 2006 de la Agenda deInstalacin del Parlamento del Mercosur).

    25

  • 7/31/2019 DRI Clarissa

    26/33

    stated that common values like the perspective of an international order based on

    democratic regulation, international law and fundamental rights unite Europeans and

    Latin Americans. The deputy also affirmed EU has contributed with regionalism

    worldwide for believing in its advantages and needs Mercosur to construct a more

    balanced international order34.

    Democracy in particular has constituted more a reactive than a

    proactive policy in the European Union (Smith, 2008 : 168), differently from the

    promotion of regional integration. The transmission of the democratic values abroad

    remains an ad hoc policy with a low priority relative to more traditional foreign policy

    goals, although adherence to these principles serves as one of the prerequisites of

    the EU membership (Olsen, 2002 : 313). More than that, the construction ofEuropean integration itself is based on democracy: the European Convention for the

    Protection of Human Rights and Fundamental Freedoms was adopted in 1950 by all

    members of the Council of Europe. The influence of this idea in the Southern Cone is

    thus due to the passive role of the European model combined with an active behavior

    of European deputies in advancing the parliamentary example. Indeed, in 1998

    Mercosur parties signed the Ushuaia Protocol, which recognizes democracy as a

    condition to take part in the bloc and establishes measures to be taken in case of

    rupture of democratic institutionality in any member state or associated member.

    Although the commitment with democracy had already been declared by presidents

    during Las Leas summit of 1992, the risk of coup dtat in Paraguay in 1996 led

    CMC to state more emphatically this principle and the consequences of its violation.

    The Interregional Framework Cooperation Agreement signed with the European

    Union in 1995 also comprises a democratic clause. The Constitutive Protocol of the

    Mercosur Parliament refers to the Ushuaia Protocol and, in consequence, connects

    the new institution with democratic standards introduced in integration processes by

    Europe.

    The EU has been lately conceived as a civilian power which would

    influence other regions rather by the means of its socio-economic model and its

    peace and human rights principles than through its military capacity (Tel, 2007). On

    one hand, the European way may effectively represent an alternative for regulating

    globalization in order to minimize its negative effects. On the other, EUs policies for

    34 Verbatim report of the I Plenary Session of Parlasur, Montevideo, May 7th 2007.

    26

  • 7/31/2019 DRI Clarissa

    27/33

    transferring its model seeks to create enlarged markets on terms that are favorable to

    its own industry (Lenz, 2008 : 8). That is, regionalism exportation may reflect the

    attachment of EU to its values and the desire to promote a multipolar international

    order to further development worldwide, but it indicates as well the intention to

    stimulate trade between Europe and the new integrated regions. That is why the EU

    needs to have important economic interests at stake in order to get involved in the

    integrative efforts of other countries (Lenz, 2008 : 7).

    The problem is the European model is hardly exportable. As the

    consociational approach reveals, the European integration is characterized by

    multiple layers of conflicting interests and a great variety of actors which implies its

    reproduction involves more than institutional engineering and cooperation amongelites (Costa and Foret, 2005 : 502-503). In fact, it would require similar historical and

    cultural conditions which based the project of a unified Europe. Additionally, the

    European supranational political system is relatively desirable. Its limitations rely on

    the gap between the failing model of the nation state - which it cannot duplicate -

    and a logic of international organization which lacks any real popular legitimacy

    (Costa and Foret, 2005 : 513). As a consequence, the transplant of single institutions

    born in the European Union into Mercosur encloses a double risk. First, copying an

    institution out of its context will probably produce effects different from the ones

    verified in the original case. Second, the expected effects may derive from an

    idealization of the model due to the ignorance of its real conditions.

    In the case of Parlasur, both risks seem to be at stake. The latter is

    reflected in contradictory declarations of authorities about the outcomes of the

    European example and the role of the European Parliament. It has been used to

    justify as well as to oppose the FTAA, to defend the reinforcement of integration and

    to refrain it. Even the general idea, according to which Parlasur will strengthen

    democracy in Mercosur and thus contribute to integration, suffers from lack of precise

    information about the means which facilitated or limited this result in Europe. It is

    early to infer if this outcome is to be confirmed, but empirical analysis show

    significative differences in the organization of both assemblies and in the behavior of

    the members, which is occasioned exactly by historical, economic and political

    disparities between European Union and Mercosur. Therefore, these procedural

    asymmetries do not tend to produce similar political effects. For instance, in spite of a

    27

  • 7/31/2019 DRI Clarissa

    28/33

    general inspiration in the rules of procedure of the European Parliament, the

    organization of Parlasur committees is closer to national parliaments than to the EP;

    during plenary sessions, deputies seat according to nationality, not according

    ideological affinity; the only organized political group is formed just by Uruguayan

    deputies; bureaucratic work in the secretariat is marked by national differences; the

    bureau changes every six months, according to the temporal presidency of Mercosur;

    and parliamentary powers are not explored in almost two years, Parlasur has not

    proposed any bills to CMC or national parliaments nor has discussed Mercosur

    budget or addressed questions to decisional organs. It means for now the European

    Parliament remains more an abstract model than a daily source of inspiration. It

    influenced the creation of Parlasur, but so far its process of institutionalization has

    corresponded to Mercosur practices (national divisions) combined with national

    chambers traditions (legislative power as secondary).

    Beyond these implications of institutional mimesis, Parlasur faces a

    more complicated one. Some of the actions carried out reveal a critical attitude

    towards its model. At times, parliamentarians exalt the European example in the

    same speech they condemn Europe for the colonization process and other historical

    and contemporary events. In addition, institutional manifestations have not spared

    certain European policies. In June 2008, the plenary voted a declaration in favor of

    the human rights of migrants, which firmly disapproves the Return Directive of the

    European Union35. The document asks the European Parliament to review, based on

    Europes civilian values, this mistaken and unfruitful decision which dishonors the

    image of the European Union. In the context of Doha Round, deputies also

    manifested their support to the position of Mercosur states in negotiating an

    agreement that could assure agricultural access in developed markets and correct

    the serious asymmetries that characterize international trade36. This behavior does

    not necessarily imply a structural questioning of the model, but it certainly reflects

    economic and ideological dissonances circumstantial or not. More than that, it

    means international issues that affect integration processes are becoming to be

    discussed in the assembly. But this situation can denote not only the increasing

    interest of deputies for new subjects but also the weakness of the assembly, insofar

    as it is simpler to find a consensus to comment on Europe than to propose measures

    35 Parlasur Declaration 10/08.36 Parlasur Declaration 11/08.

    28

  • 7/31/2019 DRI Clarissa

    29/33

    to improve the common market. This kind of international output is not enough to

    make Parlasur comparable to the European Parliament if deputies do not work on the

    inputs. In this case, isomorphism risks inducing the model to offer a false mirror to

    the new institution. Besides commenting EPs decisions and searching to influence

    the external relations of the bloc, Mercosur deputies face the challenge of identifying

    their internal limits and focusing on how to surpass them.

    Conclusion

    The paper intended to analyze the role of ideas conceived within the

    European Union in the creation of Parlasur. The hypothesis according to which

    European conceptions of integration and democracy had a special influence in the

    process that led to the rise of the Mercosur assembly is confirmed. It is possible to

    infer that integration prevailed upon democracy in this institutional mimesis, although

    both arguments are necessary to explain the Parliament. That is, from an

    international perspective, the rise of Parlasur is more connected to a general view of

    integration than to a concern for democracy, which is also due to the active behavior

    of EU in promoting regional cooperation. But both ideas concurred to the focal point

    which conducted to the conformation of a representative assembly. Integration alone

    would not be enough to explain why a parliament was created at the expense of

    alternative institutions or mechanisms.

    Yet further research is required to evaluate more concretely the

    relations between EP and Parlasur and to identify additional elements that converged

    to the building of the latter, the influence of European values remains clear. Ideas

    coming from more developed systems were always common in the construction of

    South American economic, political and legal arrangements. Dependent countries

    may opt for copying existent models than creating their own way so they can better fit

    in the global economic system. This situation can indicate ideas have a greater

    potential of explanation in comparisons center-periphery than they usually have in

    analyses between developed countries or regions.

    Furthermore, the current political orientation of Mercosur national

    governments contributed to an approximation with the European Union. But it does

    29

  • 7/31/2019 DRI Clarissa

    30/33

    not necessarily mean the European model is considered a left-wing alternative; it is

    above all an alternative to the United States influence. Integration is commonly a way

    of facing domination risks: the European Community also represented a response to

    the Soviet menace. But in the case of Mercosur, it seems useful to question at what

    extend the region is choosing to replace one form of imperialism for another. Are the

    European intentions towards South America comparable to the North American ones

    after the colonial period? Or is Europe, as a civilian power, capable of encouraging

    horizontal and fruitful forms of cooperation among economically unequal regions?

    Bibliographical references

    BADIE, Bertrand (1992). LEtat import: essai sur loccidentalisation de lordre politique. Paris:Fayard.

    BLONDEL, Jean; SINNOTT, Richard; SVENSSON, Palle (1998). People and Parliament in theEuropean Union: participation, democracy, legitimacy. Oxford: Clarendon.

    CAETANO, Gerardo; COURIEL, Alberto; QUIJANO, Jos (2006). Nuestro deber es salir a sealarque se cometer un error grave. La Repblica, interview with Raul Legnani, September 14th 2006.

    CAMARGO, Sonia de (1999). Unio Europia: uma referncia indispensvel para o Mercosul.Contexto Internacional, v. 21, n. 1, p. 83-119.

    COSTA, Olivier (1996). Le Parlement europen entre efficacit fonctionnelle et dficit politique. In:

    DUPRAT, Gerard (org). LUnion europenne: droit, politique, dmocratie. Paris: PUF.COSTA, Olivier (2001). Le Parlement europen, assemble dlibrante. Bruxelles: ditions de

    lUniversit de Bruxelles.

    COSTA, Olivier (2004). Le parlementarisme au-del de lEtat: le cas de lUnion europenne. In:COSTA, Olivier; KERROUCHE, Eric; MAGNETTE, Paul. Vers un renouveau du parlementarisme enEurope? Bruxelles: Editions de lUniversit de Bruxelles. p. 271-294.

    COSTA, Olivier; FORET, Franois (2005). The European consociation, an exportable model?Institutional design and relations between politics and religion, European Foreign Affairs Review, v. 10,n. 4, p. 501-516.

    COSTA, Olivier; MAGNETTE, Paul (2003). Idologies et changement institutionel dans lUnioneuropenne: porquoi les gouvernements ont-ils constamment renforc le Parlament europen?

    Politique Europenne, n. 9, p. 49-75.COSTA, Olivier; MAGNETTE, Paul (2007a). Le non au rfrendum europen est un chec utile.

    Libration, interview with Jean Quatremer, June 9th 2007.

    COSTA, Olivier, MAGNETTE, Paul (2007b) (eds). Une Europe des lites? Rflexions sur lafracture dmocratique de lUnion europenne. Bruxelles: Editions de lUniversit de Bruxelles.

    DAHL, Robert (1998). On democracy. New Haven: Yale University Press.

    DARBON, Dominique (1993). A qui profite le mime? Le mimtisme institutionnel confront sesreprsentations en Afrique. In: MNY, Yves (ed). Les politiques du mimtisme institutionnel: la greffeet le rejet. Paris: LHarmattan. p. 113-137.

    DIMMAGGIO, Paul; POWELL, Walter (1983). The iron cage revisited: institutional isomorphism

    and collective rationality in organizational fields.American Sociological Review, v. 48, p. 147-160.

    30

  • 7/31/2019 DRI Clarissa

    31/33

    DUMOND, Jean-Michel; SETTON, Philippe (1999). La politique trangre et de scuritcommune. Paris: La documentation franaise.

    FEATHERSTONE, Kevin (2003). Introduction: in the name of Europe. In: FEATHERSTONE,Kevin; RADAELLI, Claudio (eds). The politics of europeanization. Oxford: Oxford University Press. p.3-26.

    FOLEY, Michael (1994). Introduction. In: FOLEY, Michael (ed). Ideas that shape politics.Manchester: Manchester University Press. p. 1-4.

    GARRETT, Geoffrey; WEINGAST, Barry (1993). Ideas, interests and institutions: constructing theEuropean Communitys internal market. In: GOLDSTEIN, Judith; KEOHANE, Robert (eds). Ideas andforeign policy: beliefs, institutions, and political change. Ithaca: Cornel University Press. p. 173-206.

    GOLDSTEIN, Judith (1988). Ideas, institutions, and American trade policy. InternationalOrganization, v. 42, n. 1, p. 179-217.

    GOLDSTEIN, Judith; KEOHANE, Robert (1993). Ideas and foreign policy: an analyticalframework. In: GOLDSTEIN, Judith; KEOHANE, Robert (eds). Ideas and foreign policy: beliefs,institutions, and political change. Ithaca: Cornel University Press. p. 3-30.

    GRILLI, Enzo (1993). The European Community and the developing countries. Cambridge:

    Cambridge University Press.HALL, Peter (1989). Conclusion: the politics of Keynesian ideas. In: HALL, Peter (ed). The political

    power of economic ideas: keynesianism across nations. Princeton: Princeton University Press. p.361-391.

    HALL, Peter; TAYLOR, Rosemary (1997). La science politique et les trois no-institutionnalismes.Revue Franaise de Science Politique, v. 47, n. 3-4, p. 469-496.

    IKENBERRY, John (1993). Creating yesterdays new world order: Keynesian new thinking andthe Anglo-American postwar settlement. In: GOLDSTEIN, Judith; KEOHANE, Robert (eds). Ideas andforeign policy: beliefs, institutions, and political change. Ithaca: Cornel University Press. p. 57-86.

    LENZ, Tobias (2006). Governance through policy transfer in the external relations of the EuropeanUnion: the case of Mercosur. Paper presented in the Student Conference on the European Union -

    The Challenge for Europe: Governance, Economics and Multiculturalism, University of Pittsburgh.LENZ, Tobias (2008). Problematizing the EUs model export to Mercosur: strategies and

    motivations. Paper presented in the GARNET conference The European Union in International Affairs,Universit Libre de Bruxelles.

    MADRID, Ral (2005). Ideas, economic pressures and pension privatization. Latin AmericanPolitics and Society, v. 47, n. 2, p. 23-50.

    MAGNETTE, Paul (1999). LUnion europenne: un rgime semi-parlementaire. In: DELWIT,Pascal; DE WAELE, Jean-Michel; MAGNETTE, Paul. quoi sert le Parlement europen? Stratgieset pouvoirs dune assemble transnationale. Bruxelles: Complexe. p. 25-54.

    MAGNETTE, Paul (2000). LEurope, ltat et la dmocratie: le Souverain apprivois. Bruxelles:Complexe.

    MALAMUD, Andrs (2006). A neighborhood policy for South America? Some critical notes, SoPaulo, OBREAL/EULARO Specialist Papers.

    MALAMUD, Andrs; SCHMITTER, Philippe (2007). The experience of European integration andthe potential for integration in South America, Barcelona, IBEI Working Papers.

    MATTLI, Walter (1999). The logic of regional integration: Europe and beyond. Cambridge:Cambridge University Press.

    MAYALL, James (2005). The shadow of empire: The EU and the former colonial world. In: HILL,Christopher; SMITH, Michael (eds). International Relations and the European Union. Oxford: OxfordUniversity Press. p. 292-315.

    McNAMARRA, Kathleen (1998). The currency of ideas: monetary politics in the European Union.

    Ithaca: Cornell University Press.MEDEIROS, Marcelo (2000). La gense du Mercosur. Paris: LHarmattan.

    31

  • 7/31/2019 DRI Clarissa

    32/33

    MNY, Yves (1993). La greffe et le rejet. In: MNY, Yves (ed). Les politiques du mimtismeinstitutionnel: la greffe et le rejet. Paris: LHarmattan. p. 7-38.

    NEUILLY, Yves (2005). LEurope de la politique trangre. Paris: Economica.

    NUTTALL, Simon (2000). European Foreign Policy. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    ODONNELL, Guillermo (1994). Delegative Democracy. Journal of Democracy, v. 5, n. 1, p. 55-69.

    OLIVEIRA, Marcelo (2003). Mercosul: atores polticos e grupos de interesse brasileiros. SoPaulo: UNESP.

    OLSEN, Gorm Rye (2002). The European Union: an ad hoc policy with a low priority. In:SCHRAEDER, Peter. Exporting democracy: rethoric vs. Reality. London: Lynne Rienner. p. 131-145.

    PETERSON, John; SJURSEN, Helene (1998). Conclusion: the myth of the CFSP? In:PETERSON, John; SJURSEN, Helene (eds).A common foreign policy for Europe? Competing visionsof the CFSP. London: Routledge. p. 169-185.

    PETITEVILLE, Franck (2005). Exporting values? EU external co-operation as a soft diplomacy.In: KNODT, Michle; PRINCEN, Sebastian (eds). Undestanting the European Unions ExternalRelations. London: Routledge/ECPR Studies in European Political Science. p. 127-141.

    QUERMONNE, Jean-Louis (2001). LEurope en qute de lgitimit. Paris: Presses de SciencesPo.

    RISSE-KAPPEN, Thomas (1994). Ideas do not float freely: transnational coalitions, domesticstructures and the end of the cold war. International Organization, v. 48, n. 2, p. 185-214.

    RITTBERGER, Berthold (2005). Building Europe's Parliament: democratic representation beyondthe Nation State. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    SANTANDER, Sebastin (2007). Le rgionalisme sud-amricain, lUnion europenne et les Etats-Unis. Bruxelles: Editions de lUniversit de Bruxelles.

    SARTORI, Giovanni (1987). The theory of democracy revisited. New Jersey: Chatham.

    SIKKINK, Kathryn (1991). Ideas and institutions: developmentalism in Brazil and Argentina.

    Ithaca: Cornel University Press.SINTOMER, Yves (2003). Lespace public europen: les ambivalentes dune notion. In:

    MERCIER, Arnaud. Vers un espace public europen? Recherches sur lEurope en construction. Paris:lHarmattan. p. 179-189.

    SMITH, Andy (2004). Le gouvernement de lUnion europenne: une sociologie politique. Paris:Maison des Sciences de lHomme; LGDJ.

    SMITH, Karen (2008). European Union foreign policy in a changing world. 2. ed. Cambridge:Polity.

    SMITH, Michael (1998). Does the flag follow trade? Politicisation and the emergence of aEuropean foreign policy. In: PETERSON, John; SJURSEN, Helene (eds).A common foreign policy forEurope? Competing visions of the CFSP. London: Routledge. p. 77-94.

    TEL, Mario (1995). Dmocratie internationale et dmocratie supranationale en Europe. In:TEL, Mario (dir). Dmocratie et construction europenne. Bruxelles: Editions de lUniversit deBruxelles. p. 1-70.

    TEL, Mario (2005). LEtat et lEurope: histoire des ides politiques et des institutionseuropennes. Bruxelles: Labor.

    TEL, Mario (2007). Europe: a civilian power. European Union, global governance and worldorder. London: Palgrave.

    THOMAS, Daniel (2005). Human rights ideas, the demise of communism, and the end of the coldwar. Journal of Cold War Studies, v. 7, n. 2, p. 110141.

    VENNESSON, Pascal (2004). Ides, politiques de defense et stratgie: enjeux et niveaux

    danalyse. Revue franaise de science politique, v. 54, n. 5, p. 749-760.

    32

  • 7/31/2019 DRI Clarissa

    33/33

    VIGEVANI, Tullo; MARIANO, Karina; OLIVEIRA, Marcelo Fernandes de (2000). Democracia eatores polticos no Mercosul. In: LIMA, Marcos Costa; MEDEIROS,