economics of input and product substitution chapter 7

105
Introduction to Agricultural Economics, 5 th ed Penson, Capps, Rosson, and Woodward © 2010 Pearson Higher Education, Upper Saddle River, NJ 07458. • All Rights Reserved. Economics of Input and Product Substitution Chapter 7

Upload: fatima-fares

Post on 31-Mar-2015

261 views

Category:

Documents


3 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Economics of Input and Product Substitution Chapter 7

Economics of Inputand ProductSubstitution

Chapter 7

Page 2: Economics of Input and Product Substitution Chapter 7

Topics of DiscussionConcept of isoquant curveConcept of an iso-cost lineLeast-cost use of inputs Long-run expansion path of input useEconomics of business expansion and

contractionProduction possibilities frontierProfit maximizing combination of

products

2

Page 3: Economics of Input and Product Substitution Chapter 7

Physical Relationships

3

Page 4: Economics of Input and Product Substitution Chapter 7

Use of Multiple InputsIn Ch. 6 we finished by examining profit

maximizing use of a single input

Lets extend this model to where we have multiple variable inputsLabor, machinery rental, fertilizer

application, pesticide application, energy use, etc.

4

Page 5: Economics of Input and Product Substitution Chapter 7

Use of Multiple InputsOur general single input production

function looked like the following: Output = f(labor | capital, land, energy, etc)

Lets extend this to a two input production function Output = f(labor, capital | land, energy, etc)

Variable InputFixed Inputs

Fixed InputsVariable Inputs

5

Page 6: Economics of Input and Product Substitution Chapter 7

Use of Multiple Inputs

Output (i.e. Corn Yield)

250

Nitrogen Fert.

Phos. Fert.

6

Page 7: Economics of Input and Product Substitution Chapter 7

Use of Multiple InputsIf we take a slice at a level

of output we obtain what is referred as an isoquantSimilar to the indifference

curve we covered when we reviewed consumer theory

Shows collection of multiple inputs that generates the same level of output

There is one isoquant for each output level

7

250

Page 8: Economics of Input and Product Substitution Chapter 7

Page 107

Isoquant means “equal quantity”Isoquant means “equal quantity”

Two inputs

8

Output isidentical alongan isoquant and different across isoquants

Output isidentical alongan isoquant and different across isoquants

Page 9: Economics of Input and Product Substitution Chapter 7

Slope of an IsoquantThe slope of an isoquant is referred to

as the Marginal Rate of Technical Substitution (MRTS) Similar in concept to the MRS we talked

about in consumer theory The value of the MRTS in our example is

given by: MRTS = Capital ÷ Labor Provides a quantitative measure of the

changes in input use as one moves along a particular isoquant

Pages 106-1079

Page 10: Economics of Input and Product Substitution Chapter 7

Slope of an Isoquant

The slope of an isoquant is the Marginal Rate of Technical Substitution (MRTS) Output remains unchanged

along an isoquant The ↓ in output from

decreasing labor must be identical to the ↑ in output from adding capital as you move along an isoquant

Pages 106-107

Labor

Capital

Q=Q*

L*

K*

10

A

Slope of an isoquant =Slope of the linetangent at a point

Page 11: Economics of Input and Product Substitution Chapter 7

Page 107

MRTSKL here is– 4 ÷ 1 = – 4

MRTSKL here is– 4 ÷ 1 = – 4

11

MRTSKL = ∆K/∆L

Page 12: Economics of Input and Product Substitution Chapter 7

Page 107

What is the slope overrange B?

MRTS here is–1 ÷ 1 = –1

MRTS here is–1 ÷ 1 = –1

12

Page 13: Economics of Input and Product Substitution Chapter 7

Page 107

What is the slope overrange C?

What is the slope overrange C?

MRTS here is–.5 ÷ 1 = –.5

MRTS here is–.5 ÷ 1 = –.5

13

Page 14: Economics of Input and Product Substitution Chapter 7

Slope of an IsoquantSince the MRTS is the slope of the

isoquant, the MRTS typically changes as you move along a particular isoquantMRTS becomes less negative as shown

above as you move down an isoquant

Pages 106-10714

Page 15: Economics of Input and Product Substitution Chapter 7

Slope of an IsoquantLets derive the slope of the isoquant

like we did for the indifference curve under consumer theory

∆Q = 0 along an isoquant →

Pages 106-10715

ΔQ ΔQQ f L,K ΔQ ΔL + ΔK

ΔL ΔK

ΔQ ΔQ0 ΔL + ΔK

ΔL ΔKΔQ ΔQ ΔK ΔQ ΔQ

ΔK ΔLΔL ΔKΔK ΔL ΔL

Page 16: Economics of Input and Product Substitution Chapter 7

Slope of an Isoquant

Pages 106-10716

LKL

K

MPPΔK ΔQ ΔQMRTS

ΔL ΔKΔL MPP

Labor

Capital

Q=Q*

L*

K*

MRTSKL = –MPPL*/MPPK*

Page 17: Economics of Input and Product Substitution Chapter 7

Slope of an Isoquant

Pages 106-10717

Labor

Capital

Q = Q*

L*

K*A

BK**

L**

What is the impact on theMRTS as input combinationchanges from A to B? Why?

Page 18: Economics of Input and Product Substitution Chapter 7

Introducing Input Prices

18

Page 19: Economics of Input and Product Substitution Chapter 7

Plotting the Iso-Cost LineLets assume we have the following

Wage Rate is $10/hour Capital Rental Rate is $100/hour

What are the combinations of Labor and Capital that can be purchased for $1000 Similar to the Budget Line in consumer

theory Referred to as the Iso-Cost Line when we

are talking about production

Pages 106-10719

Page 20: Economics of Input and Product Substitution Chapter 7

Plotting the Iso-Cost Line

Page 109

Labor

Capital

10

100

Firm can afford 100 hour of labor at a wage rate of $10/hour for a budget of $1,000

Firm can afford 100 hour of labor at a wage rate of $10/hour for a budget of $1,000

Firm can afford 10 hours ofcapital at a rental rate of $100/hr with a budget of $1,000

Firm can afford 10 hours ofcapital at a rental rate of $100/hr with a budget of $1,000

Combination of Capital and Labor costing $1,000 Referred to as the

$1,000 Iso-Cost Line

Combination of Capital and Labor costing $1,000 Referred to as the

$1,000 Iso-Cost Line20

Page 21: Economics of Input and Product Substitution Chapter 7

Plotting the Iso-Cost Line

Page 109

How can we define the equation of this iso-cost line? Given a $1000 total cost we have:

$1000 = PK x Capital + PL x Labor → Capital =

(1000÷PK) – (PL÷ PK) x Labor

→The slope of an iso-cost in our example is given by:

Slope = –PL ÷ PK

(i.e., the negative of the ratio of the prices of the two inputs)

21

Page 22: Economics of Input and Product Substitution Chapter 7

Plotting the Iso-Cost Line

Page 109

Labor

Capital

20

200

10

5

10050

Doubling of Cost

Note: Parallel cost linesgiven constant prices

Original Cost Line

2,000÷PK

500 ÷ PK

Halving of Cost

500 ÷ PL 2000 ÷ PL22

Page 23: Economics of Input and Product Substitution Chapter 7

Plotting the Iso-Cost Line

Page 109

Labor

Capital

10

10050 200

$1,000 Iso-Cost Line

Iso-Cost Slope = – PL ÷ PK

PL = $5PL = $10

PL = $20

23

Page 24: Economics of Input and Product Substitution Chapter 7

Plotting the Iso-Cost Line

Page 109

Labor

Capital

10

10050 200

$1,000 Iso-Cost Line

Iso-Cost Slope = – PL ÷ PK

20

5

PK = $200

PK = $100

PK = $50

24

Page 25: Economics of Input and Product Substitution Chapter 7

Least Cost Combinationof Inputs

25

Page 26: Economics of Input and Product Substitution Chapter 7

Least Cost Input Combination

Page 109

Labor

CapitalTVC are predefined Iso-Cost Lines

TVC*

TVC**

TVC***

TVC*** > TVC** > TVC*

A

B

C

Pt. C: Combination of inputs that cannot produce Q*

Pt. A: Combination of inputs that have the highest of the two costs of producing Q*

Pt. B: Least cost combination of inputs to produce Q*

Q*

26

Page 27: Economics of Input and Product Substitution Chapter 7

Least Cost Decision RuleThe least cost combination of two inputs

(i.e., labor and capital) to produce a certain output level Occurs where the iso-cost line is tangent to

the isoquant Lowest possible cost for producing that

level of output represented by that isoquant This tangency point implies the slope of the

isoquant = the slope of that iso-cost curve at that combination of inputs

Page 11127

Page 28: Economics of Input and Product Substitution Chapter 7

Least Cost Decision RuleWhen the slope of the iso-cost = slope of the

isoquant and the iso-cost is just tangent to the isoquant

–MPPL ÷ MPPK = – (PL ÷ PK)

We can rearrange this equality to the following

Page 111

Isoquant Slope

Isoquant Slope

Iso-cost Line Slope

Iso-cost Line Slope

28

Page 29: Economics of Input and Product Substitution Chapter 7

Least Cost Decision Rule

Page 111

=

L K

L k

MPP MPP

P P

MPP per dollar spent on labor

MPP per dollar spent on labor

MPP per dollar spent on capital

MPP per dollar spent on capital

29

Page 30: Economics of Input and Product Substitution Chapter 7

Least Cost Decision Rule

Page 111

The above decision rule holds for all variable inputs• For example, with 5 inputs we would have the

following

3 51 2 4

1 2 3 4 5

MPP MPPMPP MPP MPP

P P P P P

MPP1 per $ spent on Input 1

MPP1 per $ spent on Input 1

= MPP2 per $ spent on Input 2

MPP2 per $ spent on Input 2

= …… =MPP5 per $ spent on Input 5

MPP5 per $ spent on Input 5=

30

Page 31: Economics of Input and Product Substitution Chapter 7

Page 111

Least Cost Input Choice for 100 Units of OutputLeast Cost Input Choice for 100 Units of Output

7

60

Point G represents 7 hrs of capital and 60 hrs of labor

Wage rate is $10/hr and rental rate is $100/hr

→ at G cost is $1,300 = ($100×7) + ($10×60)

31

Page 32: Economics of Input and Product Substitution Chapter 7

Page 111

7

60

G represents a total cost of $1,300 every input combination on the iso-cost line costs $1,300

With $10 wage rate → B* represent 130 units of labor: $1,300$10 = 130

G represents a total cost of $1,300 every input combination on the iso-cost line costs $1,300

With $10 wage rate → B* represent 130 units of labor: $1,300$10 = 130

130

Least Cost Input Choice for 100 Units of OutputLeast Cost Input Choice for 100 Units of Output

32

Page 33: Economics of Input and Product Substitution Chapter 7

Page 111

130

Capital rental rate is $100/hr→ A* represents 13 hrs of

capital, $1,300 $100 = 13

Capital rental rate is $100/hr→ A* represents 13 hrs of

capital, $1,300 $100 = 1313

Least Cost Input Choice for 100 Units of OutputLeast Cost Input Choice for 100 Units of Output

33

Page 34: Economics of Input and Product Substitution Chapter 7

What Happens if the Price of an Input

Changes?

34

Page 35: Economics of Input and Product Substitution Chapter 7

Page 112

What Happens if Wage Rate Declines?What Happens if Wage Rate Declines?

Assume initial wage rate and cost of capital result in iso-cost line AB

Assume initial wage rate and cost of capital result in iso-cost line AB

35

Page 36: Economics of Input and Product Substitution Chapter 7

Page 112

What Happens if Wage Rate Declines?What Happens if Wage Rate Declines?

Wage rate ↓ means the firm can now afford B* instead of B amount of labor if all costs allocated to labor

Wage rate ↓ means the firm can now afford B* instead of B amount of labor if all costs allocated to labor

36

Page 37: Economics of Input and Product Substitution Chapter 7

Page 112

What Happens if Wage Rate Declines?What Happens if Wage Rate Declines?

The new point of tangencyoccurs at H rather than G

The new point of tangencyoccurs at H rather than G

The firm would desire to use more labor and less capital as labor became relatively less expensive

The firm would desire to use more labor and less capital as labor became relatively less expensive

37

What is the minimum cost ofproducing 100 units of output?

Page 38: Economics of Input and Product Substitution Chapter 7

Least Cost Combination of Inputs and Outputfor a Specific Budget

38

Page 39: Economics of Input and Product Substitution Chapter 7

What Inputs to Use for a Specific Budget?What Inputs to Use for a Specific Budget?

M

N

Labor

Capital

An iso-cost line fora specific budget

An iso-cost line fora specific budget

Page 11339

Page 40: Economics of Input and Product Substitution Chapter 7

Page 113

What Inputs to Use for a Specific Budget?What Inputs to Use for a Specific Budget?

A set of isoquants for different output levels

A set of isoquants for different output levels

40

Page 41: Economics of Input and Product Substitution Chapter 7

Page 113

What Inputs to Use for a Specific Budget?What Inputs to Use for a Specific Budget?

Firm can afford to produce 75 units of output using C3 units of capital and L3 units of labor

Firm can afford to produce 75 units of output using C3 units of capital and L3 units of labor

41

Page 42: Economics of Input and Product Substitution Chapter 7

Page 113

What Inputs to Use for a Specific Budget?What Inputs to Use for a Specific Budget?

The firm’s budget not large enough to produce more than 75 units

The firm’s budget not large enough to produce more than 75 units

42

Page 43: Economics of Input and Product Substitution Chapter 7

Page 113

On any point on this isoquant thefirm is not spending available budget here

On any point on this isoquant thefirm is not spending available budget here

What Inputs to Use for a Specific Budget?What Inputs to Use for a Specific Budget?

43

Page 44: Economics of Input and Product Substitution Chapter 7

Economics ofBusiness Expansion

44

Page 45: Economics of Input and Product Substitution Chapter 7

Long-Run Input Use

During the short run some costs are fixed and other costs are variable

As you increase the planning horizon, more costs become variableEventually over a long-enough time

period all costs are variable

Page 11445

Page 46: Economics of Input and Product Substitution Chapter 7

Long-Run Input Use

Page 114

SACA

SACB

SACC

Fixed costs in short run ensure the U-Shaped SAC curves 3 different size firmsA is the smallest, C the

largest

A B CA*A firm wanting to minimize costOperate at size A if production

is in 0A rangeOperate at size B if production

is in AB range

Cost/unit

Output

46

Page 47: Economics of Input and Product Substitution Chapter 7

The Planning Curve

The long run average cost (LAC) curvePoints of tangency with a series of short run average

total cost (SAC) curvesTangency not usually at minimum of each SAC curve

Page 114

SACA

SACB

SACC

Output

Tangency Points

LAC

LAC sometimes referred to as Long Run Planning Curve

Cos

t/u

nit

47

Page 48: Economics of Input and Product Substitution Chapter 7

Economies of SizeTypical LAC curve

What causes the LAC curve to decline, become relatively flat and then increase?Due to what economists refer to as

economies of size Page 114

Output

Cos

t/u

nit

48

Page 49: Economics of Input and Product Substitution Chapter 7

Economies of SizeConstant returns to size

↑(↓) in output is proportional to the ↑(↓) in input use

i.e., double input use → doubling outputDecreasing returns to size

↑ (↓)in output is less than proportional to the ↑(↓) in input use

i.e., double input use → less than double output Increasing returns to size

↑ (↓)in output is more than proportional to the ↑(↓) in input use

i.e., double input use → more than double output Page 11449

Page 50: Economics of Input and Product Substitution Chapter 7

Economies of Size

Decreasing returns to size → Firm’s LAC curve are increasing as firm is expanded

Increasing returns to size → Firm’s LAC curve are decreasing as firm is expanded

Page 11550

Page 51: Economics of Input and Product Substitution Chapter 7

Economies of SizeReasons for increasing returns of size

Dimensional in nature Double cheese vat size Eventually the gains are reduced

Indivisibility of inputs Equipment available in fixed sizes As firm gets larger can use larger

more efficient equipment Specialization of effort

Labor as well as equipment Volume discounts on large purchases

on productive inputsPage 11651

Page 52: Economics of Input and Product Substitution Chapter 7

Economies of SizeDecreasing returns of size

LRC is ↑ → the LRC is tangent to the collection of SAC curves to the right of their minimum

Page 116

SACA

SACB

SACC

Output

Cos

t/u

nit SACD

52

Page 53: Economics of Input and Product Substitution Chapter 7

Economies of SizeThe minimum point on the LRC is the

only point that is tangent to the minimum of a particular SAC

Page 116

SAC*

Output

Cos

t/u

nit

LRC

Q*

C*

C* is minimum point on SAC* and on LRC

Only plant size and quantity output where this occurs

53

Page 54: Economics of Input and Product Substitution Chapter 7

The Planning Curve

Page 117

SAC1

SAC2

SAC3

Cos

t/u

nit

Output

In the long run, the firm has time to expand or contract the size of their operation Each SAC curve for each size plant has associated

short run marginal cost curve (MC) SACi = SMCi when SACi is at its minimum

SAC4SMC4

SMC3

SMC2

SMC1

54

Page 55: Economics of Input and Product Substitution Chapter 7

The Planning Curve

Page 117

SAC1

SAC2

SAC3

Output

SAC4SMC4

SMC3

SMC2

SMC1

Assume the market price for the product is P Assume the firm is of size i The firm maximizes profit by producing where P=MCi

What can you say about the performance of these 4 firms?

P

55

Page 56: Economics of Input and Product Substitution Chapter 7

The Planning Curve

Page 117

SAC1

Output

SMC1

Firm 1 would lose money with output price = P Produce where P = SMC1 → Q* At Q*, P < SAC1

P

Q*

56

Page 57: Economics of Input and Product Substitution Chapter 7

The Planning Curve

Page 117

SAC2

SAC3

Output

SAC4SMC4

SMC3SMC2

Firms of sizes 2, 3 and 4 would make a positive profit when output price is PP > SAC at profit maximizing levelP-SAC = per unit profit

P

Q2* Q3* Q4*

Per unit profit

57

Page 58: Economics of Input and Product Substitution Chapter 7

The Planning Curve

Page 117

SAC2

SAC3

Output

SAC4SMC4

SMC3SMC2

Firm 2’s total profit Per unit profit x Q2*

P

Q2* Q3* Q4*

Firm 2’s Total Profit

58

Page 59: Economics of Input and Product Substitution Chapter 7

The Planning Curve

Page 117

SAC2

SAC3

Output

SAC4SMC4

SMC3SMC2

Firm 3’s total profit Per unit profit x Q3*

P

Q2* Q3* Q4*

Firm 3’s Total Profit

59

Page 60: Economics of Input and Product Substitution Chapter 7

The Planning Curve

Page 117

SAC2

SAC3

Output

SAC4SMC4

SMC3SMC2

Firm 4’s total profit Per unit profit x Q4*

P

Q2* Q3* Q4*

60

Firm 4’s Total Profit

Page 61: Economics of Input and Product Substitution Chapter 7

The Planning Curve

Page 117

SAC1

SAC2

SAC3

Output

SAC4SMC4

SMC3

SMC2

SMC1

Assume the product price falls to PLR

Only Firm 3 will not lose money It only breaks even as PLR=SAC3 (=MC3) For other firms, the price is less than any point on

the other SAC curves Firm 4 would have to reduce its size

P

PLR

61

Page 62: Economics of Input and Product Substitution Chapter 7

Page 118

Optimal inputcombinationfor output=10

Optimal inputcombinationfor output=10

How to Expand Firm’s CapacityHow to Expand Firm’s Capacity

62

Page 63: Economics of Input and Product Substitution Chapter 7

Page 118

Two options: 1. Point B ?

Two options: 1. Point B ?

How Can the Firm Expand Its Capacity?

63

Page 64: Economics of Input and Product Substitution Chapter 7

Page 118

How Can the Firm Expand Its Capacity?

Two options: 1. Point B?2. Point C?

Two options: 1. Point B?2. Point C?

64

Page 65: Economics of Input and Product Substitution Chapter 7

Page 118

Optimal inputcombinationfor output=10with budget DE

Optimal inputcombinationfor output=10with budget DE

Optimal input combination for output = 20 with budget represented by FG

Optimal input combination for output = 20 with budget represented by FG

How Can the Firm Expand Its Capacity?

65

Page 66: Economics of Input and Product Substitution Chapter 7

Page 118

How Can the Firm Expand Its Capacity?

This combination of inuts costs more to produce 20 units of output since budget HI exceeds budget FG

This combination of inuts costs more to produce 20 units of output since budget HI exceeds budget FG

66

Page 67: Economics of Input and Product Substitution Chapter 7

Producing More than One Output

Most agricultural operations produce more than one type of outputFor example a grain farm in Southern

Wisconsin Produces wheat, oats, barley and some

alfalfa hay Raises some cattle on the side

Production of these outputs requires a set of inputsEach output is competing for the use of

limited inputs (e.g. labor, tractor time, etc)67

Page 68: Economics of Input and Product Substitution Chapter 7

Producing More than One Output

Lets first address the production decision from a technical perspective Similar to our examination of production

of a single output via the isoquant

68

Page 69: Economics of Input and Product Substitution Chapter 7

For a single output we defined an isoquant as the collection input combinations that has the same maximum output represented by that isoquant

Lets now define the collection of output combinations that could be produced with a fixed supply of inputs

Producing More than One Output

69

Page 70: Economics of Input and Product Substitution Chapter 7

The collection of outputs technically feasible with a fixed amount of inputs is referred to as the production possibilities set

The boundary of that set is referred to as the production possibilities frontier (PPF)

Producing More than One Output

70

Page 71: Economics of Input and Product Substitution Chapter 7

Output combinations within the frontier (boundary) are technically possible but inefficient Can produce more of at least one of the

outputs Again remember that the amount of

inputs available for production is assumed fixed

Producing More than One Output

71

Page 72: Economics of Input and Product Substitution Chapter 7

Output combinations on the frontier are technically efficient Can not produce more of at least one

output unless less is produced of at least one of the other outputs

Remember the assumption: The amount of inputs available for production is fixed

Producing More than One Output

72

Page 73: Economics of Input and Product Substitution Chapter 7

Page 120

Producing More than One Output

73

Page 74: Economics of Input and Product Substitution Chapter 7

Page 120

Points A → J are on the PPF Note axis labels What happens when firm changes

output mix from B to E?

128

10

95

74

Page 75: Economics of Input and Product Substitution Chapter 7

Page 120

Level of outputunattainable withwith firm’s existingresources

Level of outputunattainable withwith firm’s existingresources

Inefficient use of firm’s existing resources

Inefficient use of firm’s existing resources

K*

PPF represents maximum attainable products given fixed amount of inputs

75

Page 76: Economics of Input and Product Substitution Chapter 7

Slope of the PPF

The slope of the production possibilities curve is referred to as the Marginal Rate of Product Transformation (MRPT)In the above example, the MRPT is given by:

In general we have:

What sign will the MRPT possess?

Page 119

Canned FruitMRPT

Canned Veg.

2

1

YMRPT

Y

Y1

Y2

PPF

76

Page 77: Economics of Input and Product Substitution Chapter 7

Page 120

Using slope definitionMRPT = ∆Y2 ÷ ∆Y1

Slope between D and E is –1.30 = – 13 10

Using slope definitionMRPT = ∆Y2 ÷ ∆Y1

Slope between D and E is –1.30 = – 13 10

↑ from30 to 40

↑ from30 to 40

↓ from 108 to 95

↓ from 108 to 95

77

Page 78: Economics of Input and Product Substitution Chapter 7

Page 148

95,000- 108,000 -13,000

40,000- 30,000 10,000

÷ - 1.30 =

78

Page 79: Economics of Input and Product Substitution Chapter 7

Accounting forProduct Prices

79

Page 80: Economics of Input and Product Substitution Chapter 7

Economic Efficiency and Multiple Outputs

Page 122

Up to this point we have only considered technical efficiency, i.e., the PPF

Lets now introduce prices (both output and input) to the modelEnables us to discuss the concept of

economic efficiency in the context of multiple outputs

80

Page 81: Economics of Input and Product Substitution Chapter 7

Economic Efficiency and Multiple Outputs

Page 122

Lets start with introducing output prices Assume we have two outputs: canned fruits

(CF) and canned vegetables (CV) PCF and PCV = the prices received for CV

and CV, respectively

What would be the combinations of CF and CV production that would generate $1 million in total revenue (TR)? Collection of these combinations generates

an iso-revenue line

81

Page 82: Economics of Input and Product Substitution Chapter 7

Plotting the Iso-Revenue Line

Cases of CF

Cases ofCV

PCF = $33.33/case → 30,000 cases of CF generates revenue of $1 million

PCF = $33.33/case → 30,000 cases of CF generates revenue of $1 million

Page 122

30,000

40,000

Assume PCF=$33.33/case, PCV=$25.00/case

PCV = $25.00/case → 40,000 cases of CV generates revenue of $1 million

PCV = $25.00/case → 40,000 cases of CV generates revenue of $1 million

$1 Mil Iso-Revenue Line$1 Mil Iso-Revenue Line82

Page 83: Economics of Input and Product Substitution Chapter 7

Plotting the Iso-Revenue Line

Page 122

Y2

Y1

What is the equation that can be used to identify the R* iso-revenue line?We have 2 products (Y1, Y2) and

associated product prices (PY1,PY2)The R* iso-revenue line is defined via:

R* = PY1Y1 + PY2Y2

→ PY2Y2 = R* – PY1Y1

→ Y2 = (R*÷PY2) – (PY1÷PY2)Y1 General equation for the

R* iso-revenue line

*

Y2

R

P

*

Y1

R

P Y1

Y2

PSlope

P83

Page 84: Economics of Input and Product Substitution Chapter 7

Plotting the Iso-Revenue Line

Line AB is original iso-revenue linePCF= $33.33/case, PCV= $25.00/case Combination of outputs that generate the

same amount of revenue

Line AB is original iso-revenue linePCF= $33.33/case, PCV= $25.00/case Combination of outputs that generate the

same amount of revenue

Slope = $25.00 ÷ $33.33 = 0.75

Page 122

CV

CF

PSlope

P

84

Page 85: Economics of Input and Product Substitution Chapter 7

Page 122

Plotting the Iso-Revenue LineIso-revenue line would shift out to EF

If the revenue target doubled orOutput prices decrease by 50%

The line would shift in to CD If revenue targets are halved orOutput prices are doubled

Iso-revenue line would shift out to EFIf the revenue target doubled orOutput prices decrease by 50%

The line would shift in to CD If revenue targets are halved orOutput prices are doubled

Note: Slopedoes not change

CV

CF

PSlope

P

85

Page 86: Economics of Input and Product Substitution Chapter 7

Page 122

Iso-revenue line would rotate:Out to line BC if PCF ↓ by 50%In to line BD if PCF doubled

Iso-revenue line would rotate:Out to line BC if PCF ↓ by 50%In to line BD if PCF doubled

Plotting the Iso-Revenue Line

Note: Slope is changing

CV

CF

PSlope

P

86

Page 87: Economics of Input and Product Substitution Chapter 7

Page 122

Plotting the Iso-Revenue Line

Iso-revenue line would rotate Out to line AD if PCV ↓ by 50% In to line AC if PCV doubled

Iso-revenue line would rotate Out to line AD if PCV ↓ by 50% In to line AC if PCV doubled

Note: Slope is changing

CV

CF

PSlope

P

87

Page 88: Economics of Input and Product Substitution Chapter 7

Determining the Profit Maximizing

Combination ofProducts

88

Page 89: Economics of Input and Product Substitution Chapter 7

Profit MaximizingCombination of Products

In the cost minimization problem where we produce one productThe input combination that minimizes the cost

of producing a given output level is where The slope of the isocost curve equals the

slope of the isoquant → the isocost curve is just tangent to the

isoquantLets develop a similar decision rule but

this time withMultiple outputsFixed supply of inputs

Page 12489

Page 90: Economics of Input and Product Substitution Chapter 7

Page 124

20

40

60

80

100

120

140

20 40 60 80 100 120 140

Canned Veg. (1,000 Cases)

Can

ned

Fru

it (

1,00

0 C

ases

)

What is the profit (π) maximizing combination of fruit and veg. to can given current PCF and PCV values?

Remember we have a fixed amount of inputs available Determines location of the PPF → All costs are fixed → Maximizing revenue will

maximize profit

90

Page 91: Economics of Input and Product Substitution Chapter 7

Page 124

20

40

60

80

100

120

140

20 40 60 80 100 120 140

Canned Veg. (1,000 Cases)

Can

ned

Fru

it (

1,00

0 C

ases

) Lets place on this PPF the $1 Mil. iso-revenue line, AB

Profit MaximizingCombination of Products

A

B

91

Page 92: Economics of Input and Product Substitution Chapter 7

Page 124

20

40

60

80

100

120

140

20 40 60 80 100 120 140

Canned Veg. (1,000 Cases)

Can

ned

Fru

it (

1,00

0 C

ases

)Profit Maximizing

Combination of Products

The further from the origin the iso-revenue line, the greater the level of revenueR*

1<R*2<R*

3

Why are the iso-revenue lines parallel in this model?

R*2

R*3R*

1

92

Page 93: Economics of Input and Product Substitution Chapter 7

Page 124

20

40

60

80

100

120

140

20 40 60 80 100 120 140

Canned Veg. (1,000 Cases)

Can

ned

Fru

it (

1,00

0 C

ases

)Profit Maximizing

Combination of Products

R*2

R*3R*

1

To find the maximum revenue attainable given available inputs Lets find the iso-revenue line that is

just tangent to the PPF At the tangency point it is physically

possible to produce that combination of outputs given our fixed input base

93

Page 94: Economics of Input and Product Substitution Chapter 7

Page 124

20

40

60

80

100

120

140

20 40 60 80 100 120 140

Canned Veg. (1,000 Cases)

Can

ned

Fru

it (

1,00

0 C

ases

)Profit Maximizing

Combination of Products

Shifting line AB out in a parallel fashion holds both prices constant

Shifting line AB out in a parallel fashion holds both prices constant

CV

CF

CF CV

CV CF

PAt M MRPT =

P

Y P=

Y P

Slope of an PPF curve

Slope of an PPF curve

Slope of theIso-cost line

Slope of theIso-cost line

M

94

Page 95: Economics of Input and Product Substitution Chapter 7

In summary:The profit maximizing combination of two products is found where the slope of the PPF is equal to the slope of the iso-revenue line and on the highest iso revenue curve possible given the limited inputs

Page 124

Profit MaximizingCombination of Products

95

Page 96: Economics of Input and Product Substitution Chapter 7

MRPTequals-0.75

MRPTequals-0.75

125,000 cases of

fruit

125,000 cases of

fruit

Price ratio = -($25.00 ÷ $33.33) = - 0.75Price ratio = -($25.00 ÷ $33.33) = - 0.75

Profit MaximizingCombination of Products

Page 120

18,000 cases of

veg.

18,000 cases of

veg.

96

Page 97: Economics of Input and Product Substitution Chapter 7

Doing the Math…Let’s assume PCF is $33.33 and PCV is $25.00

If point M represents 125,000 cases of fruit and 18,000 cases of vegetables, then total revenue at point M is:

Revenue = 125,000 × $33.33 + 18,000 × $25.00 = $4,166,250 + $450,000 = $4,616,250

97

Page 98: Economics of Input and Product Substitution Chapter 7

Doing the Math…At these same prices, if we instead produce

108,000 cases of fruit and and 30,000 cases of vegetables→ total revenue would fall

Revenue = (108,000 × $33.33) + (30,000 × $25.00) = $3,599,640 + $750,000 = $4,349,640

• $266,610 less than $4,616,250 earned at M

98

Page 99: Economics of Input and Product Substitution Chapter 7

Effects of a Changein the Price of One Product

99

Page 100: Economics of Input and Product Substitution Chapter 7

Page 125

Profit MaximizingCombination of Products

PCF reduced by 50% Firm must sell twice as many

cases of CF to earn a particular level of revenue

20

40

60

80

100

120

140

20 40 60 80 100 120 140

Canned Veg. (1,000 Cases)

Can

ned

Fru

it (

1,00

0 C

ases

)

A

B

This gives us a new iso-revenue curve… line CB

This gives us a new iso-revenue curve… line CB

C

M

100

Page 101: Economics of Input and Product Substitution Chapter 7

Page 125

Profit MaximizingCombination of Products

20

40

60

80

100

120

140

20 40 60 80 100 120 140

Canned Veg. (1,000 Cases)

Can

ned

Fru

it (

1,00

0 C

ases

)

A

B

C

MTo determine the effects of this

price change on the product mix Shift out the new iso-revenue

curve Until it is just tangent to the PPF

curve

101

Page 102: Economics of Input and Product Substitution Chapter 7

Page 125

Profit MaximizingCombination of Products

20

40

60

80

100

120

140

20 40 60 80 100 120 140

Canned Veg. (1,000 Cases)

Can

ned

Fru

it (

1,00

0 C

ases

)

A

B

C

M

N

As a result of a ↓ in PCF

→Firm would shift from M to N

To maximize profit → firm would ↓ production of CF and ↑ production of CV

102

Page 103: Economics of Input and Product Substitution Chapter 7

Summary #1Concepts of iso-cost line and isoquantsMarginal rate of technical substitution

(MRTS)Least cost combination of inputs for a specific

output levelEffects of change in input priceLevel of output and combination of inputs for

a specific budgetKey decision rule …seek point where MRTS =

ratio of input prices, or where MPP per dollar spent on inputs are equal

103

Page 104: Economics of Input and Product Substitution Chapter 7

Summary #2Concepts of iso-revenue line and the

production possibilities frontierMarginal rate of product transformation

(MRPT)Concept of profit maximizing

combination of productsEffects of change in product priceKey decision rule – maximize profits

where MRPT -ratio of the product prices

104

Page 105: Economics of Input and Product Substitution Chapter 7

Chapter 8 focuses on market equilibrium conditions under perfect competition….

105