effect of ethnic diversity on economic …libproject.hkbu.edu.hk/trsimage/hp/02005018.pdfdirect...

36
EFFECT OF ETHNIC DIVERSITY ON ECONOMIC GROWTH BY Liu Ka Ho 02005018 Applied Economics Option An Honours Degree Project Submitted to the School of Business in Partial Fulfillment Of the Graduation Requirement for the Degree of Bachelor of Business Administration (Honours) Hong Kong Baptist University Hong Kong April 2005

Upload: lamxuyen

Post on 28-Mar-2018

218 views

Category:

Documents


1 download

TRANSCRIPT

EFFECT OF ETHNIC DIVERSITY ON

ECONOMIC GROWTH

BY

Liu Ka Ho

02005018

Applied Economics Option

An Honours Degree Project Submitted to the

School of Business in Partial Fulfillment

Of the Graduation Requirement for the Degree of

Bachelor of Business Administration (Honours)

Hong Kong Baptist University

Hong Kong

April 2005

Acknowledgement

I would like to express my genuine gratitude to my supervisor Dr. Mo. His valuable

advice and research finding not only guided me to do my project smoothly, but also

enrich my economic sense. His support initiates me to do my best in this project.

At the same time, I have to thank all the parties who gave their considerable comment

to my project.

1

Abstract

This paper employs a framework developed by Mo(2000) to study the role of ethnic

diversity in economic growth. We use ordinary least squares method to estimate the

direct effect of ethnic diversity on growth and indirect effects of ethnicity diversity on

growth through the transmission channels. We find that one-unit increase in the index

of ethnic diversity (i.e. change from complete homogeneity to complete

heterogeneity), the real GDP growth rate reduces by 2.67 percentage points, or

express differently, a 1% increase in the ethnicity index reduces the growth rate by

about 0.306%. The direct effect contributes 38% to the total effect, while among the

transmission channels, the most important one is the investment channel, followed by

the human capital channel, government consumption channel and political instability

channel.

2

Table of Contents

Acknowledgement……………………………………………………………….… 1

Abstract……………………………………………………………………………. 2

Table of Contents………………………………………………………….………. 3

1. Introduction……………………………………………………………………... 4

2. Literature Review………………………………………………….……………. 6

3. Analytical Framework…………………………………..………………………. 9

4. Data and Descriptive Statistics……………………………….………….……… 11

5. Empirical Analysis……………………………………...……………….……… 14

6. The Transmission Channels…………………………….…………….………… 17

7. Limitation………………………………………………….………….………… 26

8. Conclusion……………………………………………...………….…………… 28

Appendix………………………………………………………………….……….. 29

References……………………………………………………………….………… 34

3

1. Introduction

Economic growth is one of the most important research topics among economists.

From the studies of researchers, we know that many factors such as investment,

education, government policy, political stability, exchange rate are related to the

economic growth. By studying the relationship of these factors and GDP growth,

economists can explain or predict a country’s economic growth.

In the 1960s, World Bank’s chief economist predicted that seven of the African

countries would “clearly have the potential to reach or surpass” a 7% growth rate.

However, the result turned out was that those countries have a negative growth and

the overall real GDP per capita in Africa did not grow during the period of 1965-1990.

On the other hand, the developing countries in East Asia had a per capita GDP growth

over 5% in that period.

What happened to make the economists falsely estimate the growth of those African

countries? If it is because of the result of poor policies, poor investment, poor political

instability and low investment, is there any cause for it? Ethnic diversity (we simply

call ethnicity in following parts) maybe the answer. In this paper, we will estimate

4

how ethnicity influences the economic growth, its direct effect on growth and indirect

effects through other economic factors.

The paper is organized as follows. Literature review about ethnicity is shown in the

next section. In section 3, we introduce the analytical framework of this paper. The

data and descriptive statistics are shown in section 4. Section 5 is the report of our

regression results. Section 6 shows the effect of ethnicity on different transmission

variables. Section 7 shows the limitation of this paper. The last section is the

conclusion.

5

2. Literature Review

Ethnicity is a variable which is quite new to the economists. Before 1990s, ethnicity is

just a variable commonly used in social science literature. Mauro (1995) brings

ethnicity to the attention of economists by using it as an instrumental variable for

corruption while arguing that corruption causes slower growth and investment. After

that, effects of ethnicity start to be a research topic among economic studies.

Easterly and Levine (1997) conclude that Africa’s growth tragedy is caused by poor

public policies, while the Africa’s high ethnicity can explain a significant part of why

countries have chosen the poor policies. They find that high ethnicity is closely

associated with low schooling, underdeveloped financial systems, distorted foreign

exchange markets, and insufficient infrastructure. La Porta R. Lopez de Silanes, F.

Shleifer, and R. Vishiny (1999) also show that that ethnicity has a negative effect on

several indices of the quality of government (measured as property rights protection,

the extent of corruption, etc)

Beside public policies, Easterly with other researchers find that a variety of public

goods such as roads, schools, trash pickup, libraries worsen or receive less funding

6

with higher ethnicity in a sample of US cities (Alesina, Baqir, and Easterly, 1997).

Some researchers further differentiate the term ethnicity into ethnic fragmentation and

ethnic polarization. For instance, Montalvo and Reynal-Querol (2000) show that

ethnic fractionalization has a direct negative effect on economic development while

religious and ethnic polarization have a negative effect on growth through the

reduction of investment, the increase in government expenditure and the increase in

the probability of civil wars.

However, not all the researchers agree all the effects of ethnicity which we mentioned

above. Arcand JL, Guillaumont P, Guillaumont Jeanneney S (2000) question the paper

of Easterly and Levine (1997) about the Africa’s growth tragedy. They conclude that

the results in the paper of Easterly and Levine (1997) are both debatable and weak

from an econometric point of view. They also raise an interesting question: if ethnicity

is the cause of Africa’s growth tragedy, then there is very little, if anything can be

done, to change the tragedy, and the tragedy will become the fate of Africa. Other

researchers, such as Sachs and Warner (1997), Rodrik (1998), Guillaumont et al.

(1998) also find insignificant results for ethnicity in the growth regression models.

7

If ethnicity is the cause of the Africa’s tragedy, is there really nothing can be done?

Collier (1999) and Bluedorn (2001) may give us the solution. They suggest that

democracy can diminish the negative effect of ethnic diversity on economic

development, which means that the effect of ethnicity is not unavoidable.

8

3. Analytical Framework

In this paper, we employ a framework developed in Mo(2000) to investigate the effect

of ethnicity on economics growth. The framework starts with the input-output

relationship, which is characterized by the general production function,

(1) ),( LKTfY =

where Y is the total output level, T is total factor productivity, K is the capital stock, L

is the labor.

Total differentiation of Y:

(2) )( dLfdKfTfdTdY LK ++=

Divide (2) by Y, the equation becomes:

(3) L

dLfLf

YdKTf

TdT

YdY L

K ++=

We simplify the function as:

(4) [ ]dLLIYFGR ,,γ=

where GR represents the real GDP growth rate, γis the growth rate of total factor

productivity, IY is the investment output ratio and dLL is the growth rate of labor.

According to Levine and Renelt(1992), the share of investment in GDP, the rate of

population growth, the initial level of real GDP, and a proxy for human capital are the

four variables that robust in determining growth. The first two variables belong to the

9

growth component, which is related to the factor availability. The last two variables

belong to the development component, which is related to the effect of social and

technological changes. We include all these variables into our model, and we further

define the rate of productivity growth as:

(5) ),0,( HUMANyETHNICγγ =

where ETHNIC is an index for the level of ethnicity, y0 is the initial GDP per capital

and HUMAN is an index for human capital stock.

Therefore, our economic growth model becomes:

(6) [ ]dLLIYHUMANyETHNICFGR ,),,0,(γ=

In the next section, the data and descriptive statistics are shown in detail.

10

4. Data and Descriptive Statistics

Except the ethnicity index, all the data in our model are obtained from the panel data

set assembled by Robert Barro and Jong-Wha Lee. Most of the data in Barro’s and

Lee’s data set are from 1960-1985, covering 138 countries. Some of the data are also

available up to 1990. The data are usually presented as an averaged five years’

sub-period, i.e. there are 5 five-year-averaged observations for a variable in the period

1960-1985.

Due to the fact that there are quite a lot missing observations for the period before

1970 and after 1985, in order to have a more accurate and meaningful estimation, we

only use the data from the period of 1970 to 1985 in our model. The reason that we

choose a fifteen-year-period is that a longer period is better for studying the

determinants of the growths in total factor productivity and capital stock.

We use the same definition of ethnicity as Easterly and Levine(1997) used in their

paper. They primarily defined ethnicity as ethnolinguistic fragmentation, which was

constructed in 1960 by a team of 70 researchers at the Miklukho-Maklai Ethnological

Institute in the Soviet Union and printed in the 1964 Atlas Narodov Mira (Atlas of

11

Peoples of the World). It measures the probability that two randomly selected

individuals in a country will belong to different ethnolinguistic groups. This variable

ranges from 0 to 1. The larger number of ethnolinguistic groups and the closer the

sizes of the groups are, the larger the index is. For instance, when there is only one

ethnic group, the index equals to 0. The index equals to 1 when there are infinite

number of ethnic groups. When there are only two ethnic groups with the same size,

the index equals to 0.5. The ethnic index modified by Easterly and Levine covers 109

countries.

All the data included in our regression model are closely related to the analytical

framework except the growth rate of labor. We use the growth rate of population as a

proxy for the growth rate of labor. Although the growth rate of population is different

from the growth rate of labor and might have different effects to the GDP growth, the

quality of the data on population growth is better. It is because different countries

have different definitions of labor and the measurements of labor growth are also not

identical. It makes the labor growth rates become incomparable. Therefore, it is

common for researchers to use population growth as a proxy.

The average schooling years in the total population over age 25 is used as a proxy for

12

human capital stock. We also add the variable, political instability, into our model to

capture the political effect. Political instability is defined as average of the number of

assassinations per million population per year and the number of revolutions per year

over the period. The annual growth rate of a variable is approximated by finding the

compound interest rate over the period 1970-1985.1

The correlation coefficients and descriptive statistics of variables are presented in

table 1.

TABLE 1

Correlation Coefficients and Descriptive Statistics GR ETHNIC y0 POPG IY HUM GOV INSTABGR 1.00 ETHNIC -0.15 1.00 y0 -0.22 -0.42 1.00 POPG 0.17 0.48 -0.70 1.00 IY 0.38 -0.41 0.43 -0.42 1.00 HUM -0.03 -0.45 0.86 -0.73 0.50 1.00 GOV -0.18 0.25 -0.25 0.20 -0.26 -0.15 1.00 INSTAB -0.21 0.20 -0.31 0.18 -0.28 -0.26 0.02 1.00 Mean 0.0365 0.4176 2953 0.0229 0.1474 4.470 0.1850 0.3079

Std. Dev. 0.0245 0.2984 4261 0.0150 0.0566 2.771 0.0701 0.4018

Note. GR = growth rate of real GDP, ETHNIC = index for ethnicity, y0 = real GDP per capita at 1970,

POPG = population growth rate, IY = ratio of private investment to real GDP, HUM = average

schooling years in the total population over age 25, GOV = share of government consumption in real

GDP, INSTAB = index for political instability.

1 For instance, the annual real GDP growth rate over 1970 to 1985 is estimated by finding r in the formula, GDP1970*(1+r)15=GDP1985

13

5. Empirical Analysis

We use the ordinary least squares method (OLS) for regressions to estimate the effect

of ethnicity on the economic growth and the White Heteroskedasticity-adjusted t

statistics are reported. The results are shown in the following table:

TABLE 2

The Effect of Ethnicity on the Growth Rate

Estimation: B1 B2 B3 B4 Dependent variables Independent variables

GR GR GR GR

ETHNIC -0.026734

(-3.05)

-0.012226

(-1.40)

-0.022437

(-2.45)

-0.023886

(-2.81)

y0 -1.41E-06

(-1.00)

-3.66E-06

(-2.48)

-6.86E-06

(-3.93)

-2.31E-06

(-1.60)

POPG 0.445710

(1.16)

0.386919

(1.09)

0.651735

(1.75)

0.433959

(1.19)

IY 0.231886

(5.43)

HUMAN 0.006225

(3.99)

GOV -0.103126

(-3.08)

INSTAB

Constant 0.041128

(3.74)

0.008782

(0.83) 0.023839

(2.02)

0.061687

(4.81) R2 0.11 0.33 0.24 0.18 No of obs. 109 101 88 109 Note: White heteroskedasticity-adjusted t statistics are reported. The t statistics are in parentheses.

14

TABLE 2 (Con’t) The Effect of Ethnicity on the Growth Rate

Estimation: B5 B6 B7 B8 Dependent variables Independent variables

GR GR GR GR

ETHNIC -0.023391

(-2.83)

-0.011328

(-1.19)

-0.014949

(-1.67)

-0.010084

(-1.07)

y0 -2.96E-06

(-2.09)

-7.44E-06

(-3.73)

-8.84E-06

(-5.08)

-8.11E-06

(-4.00)

POPG 0.361387

(0.98)

0.762692

(2.31)

0.587392

(1.72)

0.694660

(2.06)

IY 0.206686

(4.01)

0.189851

(3.80)

HUMAN 0.004835

(3.14)

0.006431

(4.48)

0.004768

(3.08)

GOV -0.079699

(-2.93)

-0.110497

(-3.32)

-0.081973

(-2.99)

INSTAB -0.019035

(-4.07)

-0.018608

(-4.31)

-0.014341

(-3.84)

Constant 0.053045

(4.82) 0.008031

(0.64)

0.052554

(4.18)

0.018307

(1.44)

R2 0.23 0.45 0.38 0.49 No of obs. 104 84 86 83 Note: White heteroskedasticity-adjusted t statistics are reported. The t statistics are in parentheses.

In table 2, estimation B1 indicates that ethnicity has a significant negative effect on

the real GDP growth rate when all the transmission channels are excluded in the

regression. Estimations B2 to B5 show the effects of ethnicity to the real GDP growth

rate when the possible transmission channels, which are the share of investment,

human capital stock, share of government consumption and political instability, are

added to the regression independently. As expected, the magnitude and significant

15

levels of the ETHNIC coefficient in B2 to B5 are smaller that in B1. This shows that

there may be muticollinearity problems between ethnic and the mentioned

transmission channels.

From estimation B1 to B2, B6, B8, we can observe that when more and more

variables are added to the estimations, the coefficients and significant levels of

ETHNIC decrease continuously. The magnitude and the significant level of the

ETHNIC coefficient are the lowest in estimation B8 when all the possible

transmission channels are included.

In the next section, we will estimate the direct effect of ethnicity and the indirect

effect of the transmission channels caused by ethnicity to the GDP growth.

16

6. The Transmission Channels

There are four transmission channels in our model, they are: the Investment Channel,

the Human Capital Channel, the Government Consumption Channel and the Political

Instability Channel. We will estimate each channel individually first and then analyze

their effects when they are all included in the regression.

6.1 The Investment Channel

When ethnicity is high (e.g. many ethnic groups of same size), in rent-seeking models,

the resources spent by each group in order to obtain political influence (e.g. time,

labor, etc.) can be considered as a social cost that has a negative effect on economic

growth because it implies a non-productive usage of these inputs. This would clearly

reduce the investment in the productive sector (Montalvo and Reynal-Querol, 2003).

If the growth rate of real GDP depends on the share of investment and the share of

investment is affected by ethnicity, the effect of ethnicity on the real GDP growth rate

can be decomposed as:

(7) ⎟⎠⎞

⎜⎝⎛

∂∂

∂∂

+∂

∂=

ETHNICIY

IYGR

ETHNICGR

dETHNICdGR

To find out the effect of ethnicity to share of investment, we estimate the effect of

ethnicity on share of investment together with the non-transmission variables by OLS

17

method:

(8) IY = -0.044320 ETHNIC + 9.05E-06 y70 + 0.197330 POPG + 0.141319 (-2.61) (3.32) (0.24) (6.20) R2 = 0.26 No. of observations = 101

Equation (8) indicates that ethnicity has a negative effect on the share of investment.

The direct effect of ethnicity on the real GDP growth rate is shown in the coefficient

of ETHNIC in estimation B2, while that in B1 incorporates the direct effect and the

indirect effect from the share of investment. As the indirect effect from the investment

channel is captured in estimation B2, the magnitude of the coefficient in B2 is

expected to be smaller than that in B1.

Base on equation (8), regression B1 and B2, we can calculate the role of the share of

investment by using equation (7). The results are reported in Table 3. We can see that

about 38% of the growth rate reduction is due to the investment channel.

TABLE 3

The Investment Channel Direct Effect Investment channel(a) Total effect(b) (a)/(b)-0.012226 0.231886*(-0.044320) = -0.010277 -0.026734 0.384

[-0.012226+(a)=-0.022503] Note: The summation inside the brackets […] is calculated total effect based on Equation (8) and B2,

while the estimated total effect is drawn from the result in B1.

18

6.2 The Human Capital Channel

As the ethnic group which controls the government usually chooses the policy which

favors its own ethnic group (Easterly and Levine, 1997), public good such as

schooling brings less satisfaction to everyone in a high ethnicity country because of

the preferences for language of instruction, curriculum, location, etc. Therefore, less

of the public good is chosen by society (Alesina and Spolaore, 1997). Alesina, Baqir,

and Easterly (1997) also found that a variety of public goods including schools and

libraries worsened or received less funding with higher ethnicity in a sample of U.S.

cities. Obviously, ethnicity has a negative effect to human capital stock. If the real

GDP growth rate is affected by human capital stock, the effect of ethnicity can be

decomposed as:

(9) ⎟⎠⎞

⎜⎝⎛

∂∂

∂∂

+∂

∂=

ETHNICHUMAN

HUMANGR

ETHNICGR

dETHNICdGR

We estimate the effect of ethnicity on human capital by following regression:

(10) HUMAN = -0.651840 ETHNIC + 0.000725 y70 - 58.63595 POPG + 3.871830

(-1.22) (6.91) (-2.63) (5.31) R2 = 0.76 No. of observations = 88

As we expected, equation (10) indicates that ethnicity has a negative effect on the

level of human capital. The direct effect of ethnicity on the real GDP growth rate is

shown in the coefficient of ETHNIC in estimation B3, while that in B1 incorporates

19

the direct effect and the indirect effect from the human capital channel. As the indirect

effect from the human capital channel is captured in estimation B3, the magnitude of

the coefficient in B3 is expected to be smaller than that in B1.

Base on equation (10), regression B1 and B3, we can calculate the role of the human

capital by using equation (9). The results are reported in Table 4, showing that the

human capital channel account for about 15% of the effect of ethnicity.2

TABLE 4 The Human Capital Channel

Direct Effect Human capital channel(a) Total effect(b) (a)/(b)-0.022437 0.006225*(-0.651840) = -0.004058 -0.026734 0.152

[-0.022437+(a)=-0.026495]

Note: The summation inside the brackets […] is calculated total effect based on Equation (10) and B3,

while the estimated total effect is drawn from the result in B1.

6.3 The Government Consumption Channel

When ethnicity is high, government increases public expenditure in order to mitigate

potential conflict. It contributes a negative effect on economic growth since it diverts

resources from the private sector. (Montalvo and Reynal-Querol, 2003). Therefore, if

the real GDP growth rate is affected by share of government consumption to real GDP 2 We use the estimated effect of ethnicity on human capital in equation (10) for calculation in Table 4, although the coefficient is statistically insignificant. Statistical insignificance may be due to the absence of a functional relationship between the variables or to multicollinearity among the independent variables or because the relationship is relatively small. Since the estimated result is consistent with the calculated results shown in Table 4, we adopt the last interpretation.

20

and share of government consumption to real GDP is affected by ethnicity, we can

decompose the effect by:

(11) ⎟⎠⎞

⎜⎝⎛

∂∂

∂∂

+∂

∂=

ETHNICGOV

GOVGR

ETHNICGR

dETHNICdGR

To find out the indirect effect of ethnicity to share of government consumption, we

estimate the effect by following regression:

(12) GOV = 0.027619 ETHNIC -8.65E-06 y70 -0.113950 POPG + 0.199360

(1.17) (-2.65) (-0.13) (9.00) R2 = 0.13 No. of observations = 109

Equation (12) indicates that ethnicity has a positive effect on the share of government

consumption. The direct effect of ethnicity on the real GDP growth rate is shown in

the coefficient of ETHNIC in estimation B4, while that in B1 incorporates the direct

effect and the indirect effect from the share of government consumption. As the

indirect effect from the government consumption channel is captured in estimation B4,

the magnitude of the coefficient in B4 is expected to be smaller than that in B1.

Base on equation (12), regression B1 and B4, we can calculate the role of the share of

government consumption by using equation (11). According to the results reported in

Table 5, the government consumption channel contributes about 11% of the growth

21

rate reduction.3

TABLE 5 The Government Consumption Channel

Direct Effect Government consumption channel(a) Total effect(b) (a)/(b)-0.023886 -0.103126*(0.027619) = -0.002848 -0.026734 0.107

[-0.023886+(a)=-0.026734]

Note: The summation inside the brackets […] is calculated total effect based on Equation (12) and B4,

while the estimated total effect is drawn from the result in B1.

6.4 The Political Instability Channel

Some researchers show that religious and ethnic polarization have a negative effect on

growth through the increase in the probability of civil wars (Montalvo and

Reynal-Querol, 2000). Although we do not include the effect of civil wars in our

definition of political instability, it is conceivable that ethnicity make the overall

political environment more instable. If the real GDP growth rate is affected by

political instability, we can decompose the effect of ethnicity to political instability by

equation (13):

(13) ⎟⎠⎞

⎜⎝⎛

∂∂

∂∂

+∂

∂=

ETHNICINSTAB

INSTABGR

ETHNICGR

dETHNICdGR

We estimate the effect of ethnicity on political instability by following regression:

(14) INSTAB = 0.166554 ETHNIC - 6.77E-05 y70 -7.101680 POPG + 0.559634 (1.35) (-4.44) (-1.74) (4.02) R2 = 0.13 No. of observations = 104 3 The reason to use the insignificant result in equation (12) is similar to footnote 2

22

Equation (14) indicates that ethnicity has a positive effect on the political instability.

The direct effect of ethnicity on the real GDP growth rate is shown in the coefficient

of ETHNIC in estimation B5, while that in B1 incorporates the direct effect and the

indirect effect from the political instability channel. As the indirect effect from the

political instability channel is captured in estimation B5, the magnitude of the

coefficient in B4 is expected to be smaller than that in B1.

Base on equation (14), regression B1 and B5, we can calculate the role of the share of

government consumption by using equation (13). The results are reported in Table 6.

It indicates that about 12% of the growth rate reduction is due to the political

instability channel.4

TABLE 6

The Political Instability Channel Direct Effect Political instability channel(a) Total effect(b) (a)/(b)-0.023391 -0.019035*(0.166554) = -0.003223 -0.026734 0.121

[-0.023391+(a)=-0.026614]

Note: The summation inside the brackets […] is calculated total effect based on Equation (14) and B5,

while the estimated total effect is drawn from the result in B1.

4 The reason to use the insignificant result in equation (14) is similar to footnote 2

23

6.5 Decomposition of the Transmission Channels

Since the share of investment, the human capital level, the share of government

consumption and the political instability level are not independent of each other,

analyzing the channels individually will lead to biased results. Therefore, we should

analyze all the plausible channels simultaneously. The effects of ethnicity and

different channels can be calculated by following equation:

(15) ∑ ⎟⎠⎞

⎜⎝⎛

∂∂

∂∂

+∂

∂=

TV ETHNICTV

TVGR

ETHNICGR

dETHNICdGR

where TV = IY, HUMAN, GOV and INSTAB.

Refer to the results of estimation B1, B8 and equations (8), (10), (12), (14), the direct

impact of ethnicity, effects of the four different channels are shown in table 7:

TABLE 7

Decomposition of the Transmission Channels

Model Direct Impact(a) Investment channel(b) Human Capital Channel

(c) B8 -0.010084 0.189851*(-0.044320) 0.004768*(-0.651840)

{0.377} = -0.008414 {0.321} =-0.003108 {0.137}

Government

consumption Channel(d) Political Instability

Channel(e) Overall Effect

-0.081973*0.027619 -0.0114341*0.166554 -0.026734

=-0.002264 {0.088} =-0.002389 {0.094} [-0.026259]

Note: The number inside the brackets […] is the calculated total effect that is equal to the summation of

(a), (b), (c), (d), (e), while that inside the braces {…} is the ratio of the respective channel to the overall

effect.

24

According to regression B1, the overall effect of ethnicity on the real GDP growth

rate is -0.0267 or 0.306 in elasticity terms. This overall effect can be decomposed into:

(1) the direct impact, which accounts for 37.7% of overall effect; (2) investment

channel, which account for 32.1% of overall effect; (3) human capital channel, which

account for 13.7% of overall effect; (4) government investment channel, which

account for 8.8% of overall effect, and; (5) political instability channel, account for

9.4% of overall effect.

25

7. Limitation

In this paper, we use the same definition of ethnicity as Easterly and Levine(1997).

However, there are some critiques among this index.

Firstly, some researchers argued that Easterly and Levine did not consider the

difference between ethnic fragmentation and ethnic polarization (Arcand JL,

Guillaumont P, Guillaumont Jeanneney S, 2000). Ethic polarization refers to the case

when there are two ethnic groups with the same size (the ethnicity index = 0.5).

Montalvo and Reynal-Querol (2000) showed that ethnic fractionalization has a direct

negative effect on economic development while religious and ethnic polarization have

a negative effect on growth through the reduction of investment, the increase in

government expenditure and the increase in the probability of civil wars.

Secondly, this index is a bit outdated. The index is basically formed in 1964, which is

40 years ago. Ethnicity may have changed due to factors including the education

policy, the language of instruction, and the change of official language. So the data

may not be able to reflect the real situation of ethnicity.

26

The reason why we insist in using the definition of ethnicity as Easterly and Levine is

that we want to keep our model simple, so we did not consider differentiating the

concept between ethnic fragmentation and ethnic polarization. Also, the data in our

model started at 1970, the time difference between other variables and the ethnicity

index is acceptable.

Besides the index of ethnicity, the definition of political instability is also arguable.

Different researchers have different definitions on political instability. Since all the

variables except ethnicity are in the same data set assembled by Robert Barro and

Jong-Wha Lee, we also choose the political instability in this data set for the reason of

simplicity. However, this data may not be the best data reflecting political instability.

27

8. Conclusion

Ethnicity is indeed an important and complex factor to growth. As stated in the part of

limitation, this report certainly does not give a complete and perfect framework about

the effect of ethnicity on growth. However, we have tried to show that ethnicity has a

direct effect and an indirect effect through the four transmission channels: the

investment channel, the human capital channel, the government consumption channel

and the political instability channel.

We find that with one-unit increase in the ethnicity (i.e. change from complete

homogeneity to complete heterogeneity), the real GDP growth rate reduces by 2.67

percentage points, or express differently, a 1% increase in the ethnicity index

reduces the growth rate by about 0.306%. The direct effect accounts for about 38% of

overall effect. Among the transmission channels, the most important one is the

investment channel, which accounts for 32%, and then followed by the human capital

channel, political instability channel and government consumption channel

respectively. These four channels are what we are interested in our model. However,

we do not mean that ethnicity is solely related to these four channels. For other

possible channels, they are out of the scope of this paper.

28

Appendix

A. Data Source:

Variables Involved Code Source Real GDP per capita GDPSH4 Summers and Heston (1988) Total population POP Summers and Heston (1988) Average schooling years in the total population over age 25

HUMAN Barro and Lee

Measure of political instability PINSTAB Barro and Lee Ratio of nominal domestic investment to nominal GDP

INVWB World Bank

Ratio of nominal public domestic investment to nominal GDP

INVPUB World Bank

Ratio of nominal government consumption expenditure to nominal GDP

GOVWB World Bank

Index of ethnolinguistic fractionalization

ELF60 Atlas Narodov Mira(1964)

29

B. Data Set

Obs. Country Name GR ETHNIC y0 POPG IY HUM GOV INSTAB

1 Algeria 0.053618 NA 1551 0.031184 0.090267 1.54275 0.170833 0

2 Angola -0.01215 0.78 1146 0.030378 NA NA 0.258867 NA

3 Benin 0.020738 NA 571 0.02647 0.081333 NA 0.1817 NA

4 Botswana 0.086621 NA 881 0.037551 0.283367 2.292 0.2513 0

5 Burkina Faso 0.038183 0.31 305 0.023618 0.1034 NA 0.247067 0.5

6 Burundi 0.026073 NA 315 0.019869 0.030133 NA 0.203233 0.3286

7 Cameroon 0.059167 0.32 703 0.028333 0.091767 NA 0.1695 0.1

8 Cape verde NA 0.13 NA 0.012983 NA NA NA NA

9 Central African Rep. 0.01309 0.04 511 0.024181 0.046933 0.73 0.287533 0.4

10 Chad -0.01909 0.55 466 0.02141 NA NA 0.332233 1.3476

11 Comoros NA 0.62 NA 0.035592 NA NA NA NA

12 Congo 0.049723 NA 992 0.028991 NA NA 0.236933 0.52

13 Egypt 0.062745 NA 671 0.023033 0.1591 NA 0.247067 0.202815

14 Ethiopia 0.01654 NA 341 0.023019 0.063 NA 0.188 1.6347

15 Gabon 0.073875 NA 2082 0.045684 0.251533 NA 0.127333 0

16 Gambia 0.02704 NA 566 0.03207 0.066933 NA 0.280667 0.1

17 Ghana -0.00583 0.68 568 0.02698 0.047167 2.42625 0.171967 0.6

18 Guinea 0.027279 0.07 386 0.016526 NA NA 0.201467 0.36125

19 Guinea-Bissau NA 0.22 NA 0.034484 NA NA NA NA

20 Cote d'Ivoire 0.032338 NA 1028 0.040006 0.133667 NA 0.248433 0

21 Kenya 0.043478 NA 552 0.037925 0.152733 2.06775 0.250867 0.1073

22 Lesotho 0.078246 0.47 360 0.024867 0.128833 3.137 0.260667 0.17

23 Liberia 0.006441 0.51 708 0.0313 0.1413 1.2515 0.253633 0.4

24 Madagascar 0.007662 0.69 673 0.028235 0.093633 NA 0.174467 NA

25 Malawi 0.050331 0.75 301 0.03288 0.156267 2.247 0.2529 0.01465

26 Mali 0.032527 0.5 317 0.024763 0.1451 0.4645 0.2922 0.3

27 Mauritania 0.066786 0.14 1025 0.024908 0.1549 NA 0.158633 0.4

28 Mauritius 0.036865 NA 876 0.014164 0.1647 3.9855 0.217433 0

29 Morocco 0.022104 0.86 570 0.024541 0.121033 NA 0.321333 0.2062

30 Mozambique -0.01852 0.89 1020 0.025522 NA 0.85875 0.211267 NA

31 Niger 0.0359 0.66 401 0.031249 0.111133 0.53125 0.166 0.2

32 Nigeria 0.02739 0.06 630 0.032951 0.1109 NA 0.136567 0.501305

33 Rwanda 0.050125 NA 268 0.033395 0.091667 NA 0.167967 0.2

30

34 Senegal 0.028356 NA 760 0.0289 0.1167 1.989 0.264767 0

35 Seychelles NA 0.07 NA NA NA NA NA NA

36 Sierra Leone 0.019285 NA 459 0.021699 0.078167 1.43725 0.170867 0.137

37 Somalia 0.032511 0.35 374 0.037482 0.242867 NA 0.319767 0.4

38 South africa 0.028 NA 3609 0.022962 0.1557 4.641 0.147133 0.12304

39 Sudan 0.014711 0.03 683 0.030728 0.097033 0.59825 0.231067 1.207

40 Swaziland 0.063884 NA 743 0.03117 NA 2.906 0.219467 0.1

41 Tanzania 0.051096 NA 283 0.035332 0.116667 2.192 0.328367 0.1069

42 Togo 0.008669 0.05 644 0.027354 0.147933 1.29425 0.1825 0.1

43 Tunisia 0.068411 0.04 1076 0.023471 0.125533 1.63675 0.167 0

44 Uganda 0.030659 0.43 352 0.031643 0.0657 1.467 0.199733 0.76355

45 Zaire -0.00685 0.53 358 0.029099 0.073267 1.60875 0.1731 0.404465

46 Zambia 0.014331 0.04 789 0.034882 0.045333 3.1215 0.366133 0.1

47 Zimbabwe 0.041677 0.44 810 0.030809 0.1298 2.25625 0.1631 0.6981

48 Bahamas, The NA 0.69 NA NA NA NA NA NA

49 Barbados 0.038139 0.16 3147 0.003802 0.173433 7.8985 0.1556 0

50 Canada 0.03636 NA 8495 0.011674 0.1984 9.6445 0.134933 0.0094

51 Costa Rica 0.03835 0.26 2300 0.02859 0.168233 4.5595 0.219833 0

52 Dominica NA 0.69 NA NA NA NA NA NA

53 Dominican Rep. 0.049497 0.32 1232 0.025108 0.176867 3.5165 0.0874 0.222

54 El Salvador 0.010655 0.71 1358 0.019136 0.145167 2.93575 0.206833 1.8525

55 Grenada NA 0.75 NA NA NA NA NA NA

56 Guatemala 0.031001 NA 1544 0.028213 0.111133 2.133 0.0764 1.613

57 Haiti 0.026933 0.73 550 0.01757 0.123933 1.3025 0.151567 0.3198

58 Honduras 0.033515 NA 927 0.034715 0.128133 2.5745 0.159767 0.3

59 Jamaica -0.00844 NA 2422 0.014252 0.141433 3.59475 0.2146 0.191

60 Mexico 0.045775 0.1 3063 0.027589 0.137733 3.67675 0.086933 0.004505

61 Nicaragua 0.021856 NA 2292 0.031561 NA 2.8235 0.181967 0.5905

62 Panama 0.046631 0.64 2093 0.02384 0.175233 5.49425 0.262633 0.0655

63 St.Lucia NA 0.58 NA NA NA NA NA NA

64 St.Vincent & Grens. NA 0.02 NA NA NA NA NA NA

65 Trinidad & Tobago 0.012254 0.16 6957 0.012966 0.160433 5.7405 0.0949 0.1

66 United States 0.029473 0.01 9459 0.010346 0.1376 11.14725 0.1526 0.002288

67 Argentina 0.006532 NA 4002 0.015838 0.1149 6.30575 0.091433 1.1085

68 Bolivia 0.017479 0.68 1237 0.026159 0.126967 3.91425 0.198333 1.686

69 Brazil 0.065908 0.76 1782 0.023382 0.130333 3.0405 0.121767 0

70 Chile 0.012562 0.89 3687 0.016353 0.080233 5.84325 0.200533 0.41455

71 Colombia 0.051529 0.04 1711 0.022628 0.119933 3.96375 0.110167 0.0387

31

72 Ecuador 0.066309 0.05 1403 0.029192 0.144633 4.51825 0.154533 0.5

73 Guyana -0.00646 0.2 1546 0.007238 0.117067 4.51 0.3383 0.658

74 Paraguay 0.066777 0.04 1189 0.030564 0.202067 4.32925 0.119033 0

75 Peru 0.020792 0.05 2285 0.026099 0.1534 4.83525 0.161267 0.2217

76 Suriname 0.028903 0.05 2365 0.001945 NA NA 0.2563 NA

77 Uruguay 0.004772 0.01 3453 0.004597 0.088967 5.6815 0.167567 0.142

78 Venezuela -0.00872 0.83 6608 0.033238 0.191467 4.24825 0.1307 0.0076

79 Afghanistan NA NA 664 0.004256 NA 0.837 0.103 0.938

80 Bahrain NA NA NA 0.045528 NA 3.094 0.126867 0.1

81 Bangladesh 0.052132 NA 458 0.028177 0.063033 1.38025 0.087433 0.40465

82 Myanmar (Burma) 0.045123 0 398 0.021965 NA 1.39775 0.192033 0.7

83 China NA NA NA 0.016355 0.137633 NA NA 0.1

84 Hong Kong 0.087932 NA 3555 0.021905 0.2387 6.257 0.046767 0

85 India 0.040151 0.83 576 0.022007 0.139933 2.51625 0.207567 0.101376

86 Indonesia 0.085695 NA 490 0.022255 0.150167 2.938 0.1147 0.1

87 Iran, I.R. of 0.053618 NA 2816 0.030603 NA 2.17525 0.172767 0.56495

88 Iraq 0.024657 0.47 3317 0.035977 NA 2.115 0.218033 0.72885

89 Israel 0.041334 0.22 4861 0.023813 0.205433 8.57925 0.383767 0.05705

90 Japan 0.046973 0.15 5496 0.00984 0.245933 7.67875 0.0789 0.00183

91 Jordan 0.054086 0.53 1421 0.026571 0.1527 2.90175 0.3007 0.5715

92 Korea 0.082529 0.06 1189 0.016501 0.215867 6.55275 0.14 0.605555

93 Kuwait 0.000679 NA 34024 0.057459 0.064133 4.54 0.076267 0.082

94 Malaysia 0.081406 0.3 1525 0.02482 0.175567 4.324 0.157267 0.10815

95 Nepal 0.028784 0.78 506 0.026129 0.0915 0.45 0.095267 0

96 Oman 0.048157 0.08 7308 0.043685 NA NA 0.3383 NA

97 Pakistan 0.056264 NA 797 0.030578 0.071767 1.75725 0.151067 0.60837

98 Philippines 0.040984 0.65 1094 0.025939 0.2027 5.6815 0.178433 1.13897

99 Saudi Arabia 0.033 0.33 7405 0.047929 0.091 NA 0.1392 0.0138

100 Singapore 0.100843 NA 2869 0.014049 0.3237 4.0215 0.0999 0

101 Sri Lanka 0.045392 NA 1018 0.016982 0.1159 5.14375 0.208133 0.2128

102 Syria 0.077536 0.58 1581 0.034826 0.0781 2.76025 0.157967 0.65835

103 Taiwan 0.07843 0.62 1514 0.018279 0.1645 5.68425 0.207467 0.1068

104 Thailand 0.065236 0.72 1063 0.024781 0.185067 4.0375 0.126967 0.702295

105 United Arab Emirates 0.079145 NA 23937 0.127493 NA NA 0.070667 0.9395

106 Yemen, N.Arab 0.074178 0.73 527 0.0308 0.138533 NA 0.220567 0.5051

107 Austria 0.029505 0.87 5843 0.000808 0.229233 6.2205 0.156233 0

108 Belgium 0.026002 0.18 6750 0.001381 0.1785 8.50525 0.133533 0

109 Cyprus 0.04358 0.1 3028 0.005225 0.2314 6.7745 0.157033 0.854

32

110 Denmark 0.025292 0.04 7776 0.002564 0.174567 10.00225 0.219133 0

111 Finland 0.031325 0.7 6186 0.004161 0.2495 9.061 0.150267 0

112 France 0.028425 0.37 7078 0.005554 0.210533 5.61925 0.1245 0.00751

113 Germany, West 0.024963 0.42 7443 0.000409 0.190567 8.3375 0.1597 0.206465

114 Greece 0.03635 0.64 2952 0.008167 0.202867 6.07925 0.141067 0.22125

115 Hungary NA 0.28 NA NA 0.056633 9.42475 NA 0

116 Iceland 0.037376 0.59 6157 0.011174 0.2156 7.131 0.083667 0

117 Ireland 0.037021 0.74 3628 0.012366 0.2367 7.21525 0.185867 0.06255

118 Italy 0.030432 0.42 5028 0.003997 0.213833 5.65875 0.148833 0.1606

119 Luxembourg 0.025188 NA 7857 0.005305 0.203067 NA 0.103533 0

120 Malta 0.068828 NA 2068 0.003589 0.1876 6.15725 0.198133 0

121 Netherlands 0.025612 0.01 6915 0.007067 0.169833 8.085 0.127033 0

122 Norway 0.043843 0.14 7104 0.004595 0.2035 9.4115 0.189167 0

123 Poland NA NA NA NA NA 8.16775 NA NA

124 Portugal 0.032955 0.14 2575 0.007767 0.185133 2.58375 0.1776 0.5

125 Spain 0.035185 0.73 4379 0.008937 0.218567 4.9795 0.099733 0.310575

126 Sweden 0.022161 0.72 7401 0.0025 0.163867 8.5695 0.271733 0

127 Switzerland 0.013022 0.42 9164 0.002986 NA 7.8085 0.076233 0

128 Turkey 0.051413 NA 1702 0.023909 0.098933 2.49925 0.164567 0.23904

129 United Kingdom 0.022469 0.77 6319 0.001172 0.1253 8.1195 0.2245 0.61776

130 Yugoslavia NA 0.17 NA 0.008486 0.1662 6.22425 NA 0

131 Australia 0.027985 0.08 7344 0.01528 0.165733 10.10425 0.1389 0.0073

132 Fiji 0.038676 NA 2201 0.019917 0.158567 5.752 0.174833 0

133 New Zealand 0.022525 NA 6595 0.009444 0.190433 11.25775 0.2172 0

134 Papua New Guinea 0.011073 0.08 1664 0.024063 0.176467 1.06425 0.3191 NA

135 Solomon Islands NA NA NA NA NA NA NA NA

136 Tonga NA NA NA NA NA NA NA NA

137 Vanuatu NA 0.22 NA NA NA NA NA NA

138 Western Samoa NA 0.83 NA NA NA NA NA NA

Note. GR = growth rate of real GDP, ETHNIC = index for ethnicity, y0 = real GDP per capita at 1970,

POPG = population growth rate, IY = ratio of private investment to GDP, HUM = average schooling

years in the total population over age 25, GOV = share of government consumption in GDP, INSTAB =

index for political instability.

33

REFERENCES Alesina, Alberto, and Enrico Spolaore, (1997), “On the Number and Size of Nations,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, CII (1997), 1027–1056. Alesina, Alberto, Reza Baqir, and William Easterly, (1997), “Public Goods and Ethnic

Divisions”, Harvard University and World Bank mimeo, March 1997. Annett Anthony, (2001), “Social Fractionalization, Political Instability, and the Size

of Government”, IMF Staff Papers, Vol. 48, No. 3, pp. 561-592 Arcand JL, Guillaumont P, Guillaumont Jeanneney S, (2000), “How to make a

Tragedy: on the Alleged Effect of Ethnicity on Growth”, Journal of International Development, J. Int. Dev. 12, pp. 925-938

Bluedorn, J. C., (2001), “Can Democracy Help? Growth and ethnic divisions”,

Economics Letters 70, 121-126. Collier P., (1999), “The Political Economy of Ethnicity“, in: B. Plleskovic, J. E.

Stiglitz (Eds.), Annual World Bank Conference on Development Economics, 1998. Easterly, William and Ross Levine, (1997), “Africa’s Growth Tragedy: Politics and

Ethnic, Divisions,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 112, pp. 1203–50. Guillaumont P, Guillaumont Jeanneney S, Brun J-F, 1999, “How instability lowers

African growth”, Journal of African Economies, March: 87-107 La Porta R. Lopez de Silanes, F. Shleifer, and R. Vishiny, (1999), “The Quality of

Government”, Journal of Law Economics and Organization 15, 1, 222-279 Levine, Ross, and David Renelt, (1992), “A Sensitivity Analysis of Cross-Country

Growth Regressions”, American Economic Review 82: 942-63 Mauro, Paolo, (1995), “Corruption and Growth,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, CX

(1995), 681–712 Mo, Pak Hung, (2001), “Corruption and Economic Growth”, Journal of Comparative

Economics 29, pp66-79

34

Mo, Pak Hung, (2002), “Human Capital and Economic Growth: Alternative Estimation Methods”, BRC Working Papers, Hong Kong Baptist University

Montalvo, J. G., and Reynal-Querol, M., (2000), “The Effect of Ethnic and Religious

Conflict on Growth”, IVIE Working Paper. Montalvo, J. G., and Reynal-Querol, M., (2003), “Ethnic diversity, political systems

and conflict”, WeltTrends, 38:44–60, 2003a. Rodrik D., (1998), “Trade policy and economic performance in sub-Sharan Africa”,

NBER Working Paper No. 6562 Sachs J, Warner A, (1997), “Sources of slow growth in African economies”, Journal

of African Economies 6:335-376

35