eric neumayer is good governance rewarded?: a cross ...eprints.lse.ac.uk/17883/1/is good governance...

42
Eric Neumayer Is good governance rewarded?: a cross- sectional analysis of debt forgiveness Article (Accepted version) (Refereed) Original citation: Neumayer, Eric (2002) Is good governance rewarded?: a cross-sectional analysis of debt forgiveness. World development, 30 (6). pp. 913-930. ISSN 0305-750X DOI: 10.1016/S0305-750X(02)00018-9 © 2002 Elsevier This version available at: http://eprints.lse.ac.uk/17883/ Available in LSE Research Online: September 2012 LSE has developed LSE Research Online so that users may access research output of the School. Copyright © and Moral Rights for the papers on this site are retained by the individual authors and/or other copyright owners. Users may download and/or print one copy of any article(s) in LSE Research Online to facilitate their private study or for non-commercial research. You may not engage in further distribution of the material or use it for any profit-making activities or any commercial gain. You may freely distribute the URL (http://eprints.lse.ac.uk) of the LSE Research Online website. This document is the author’s final manuscript accepted version of the journal article, incorporating any revisions agreed during the peer review process. Some differences between this version and the published version may remain. You are advised to consult the publisher’s version if you wish to cite from it.

Upload: others

Post on 05-Oct-2020

10 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Eric Neumayer Is good governance rewarded?: a cross ...eprints.lse.ac.uk/17883/1/Is good governance rewarded...debt forgiveness (for a brief exposition see, for example, Daseking and

Eric Neumayer Is good governance rewarded?: a cross-sectional analysis of debt forgiveness Article (Accepted version) (Refereed) Original citation: Neumayer, Eric (2002) Is good governance rewarded?: a cross-sectional analysis of debt forgiveness. World development, 30 (6). pp. 913-930. ISSN 0305-750X DOI: 10.1016/S0305-750X(02)00018-9 © 2002 Elsevier This version available at: http://eprints.lse.ac.uk/17883/ Available in LSE Research Online: September 2012 LSE has developed LSE Research Online so that users may access research output of the School. Copyright © and Moral Rights for the papers on this site are retained by the individual authors and/or other copyright owners. Users may download and/or print one copy of any article(s) in LSE Research Online to facilitate their private study or for non-commercial research. You may not engage in further distribution of the material or use it for any profit-making activities or any commercial gain. You may freely distribute the URL (http://eprints.lse.ac.uk) of the LSE Research Online website. This document is the author’s final manuscript accepted version of the journal article, incorporating any revisions agreed during the peer review process. Some differences between this version and the published version may remain. You are advised to consult the publisher’s version if you wish to cite from it.

Page 2: Eric Neumayer Is good governance rewarded?: a cross ...eprints.lse.ac.uk/17883/1/Is good governance rewarded...debt forgiveness (for a brief exposition see, for example, Daseking and

1

Is good governance rewarded?

A cross-national analysis of debt forgiveness

ERIC NEUMAYER∗

London School of Economics

Published in:

World Development, 30 (6), 2002, pp. 913-930

Eric Neumayer

Department of Geography and Environment, London School of Economics and Political

Science, Houghton Street, London WC2A 2AE, UK

Phone: 0207-955-7598. Fax: 0207-955-7412. Email: [email protected]

∗ I am grateful to an anonymous referee for many helpful suggestions. Thanks also to the participants of an invited seminar presentation at the World Bank, in particular William Easterly, Stephen Knack and Gunnar Eskeland. All errors are mine.

Page 3: Eric Neumayer Is good governance rewarded?: a cross ...eprints.lse.ac.uk/17883/1/Is good governance rewarded...debt forgiveness (for a brief exposition see, for example, Daseking and

2

Summary. – This article analyses which factors determine the allocation of debt forgiveness.

In particular, it is examined what role various aspects of governance play. The results indicate

that countries’ need is a powerful determinant for debt forgiveness, whereas creditors’

political interest is not, apart from United States military interests. Of the various aspects of

governance, only the extent to which governments are accountable, respect democratic rights

as well as refrain from imposing burdens on business has a statistically significant influence.

In order to set the right incentives and to ensure effectiveness of scarce financial resources,

countries with good governance should be rewarded with a higher share of total debt

forgiveness in the future.

Key words: aid, debt, democracy, governance, regulatory burden

1. INTRODUCTION

The question of debt forgiveness for indebted developing countries has generated an

enormous amount of political as well as academic interest. The political campaign by the

Jubilee 2000 network has been dubbed by a World Bank spokesman ‘one of the most

effective global lobbying campaigns I have ever seen’ (cited in Hanlon, 2000, p. 878). An all-

encompassing coalition from popstars, non-governmental organizations and churches to the

World Bank and even the International Monetary Fund (IMF) seemingly united behind a call

for major debt forgiveness. Of course, hidden behind this apparent convergence of views lies

a great dispute about the exact details and the amount of debt to be forgiven. This is not the

place to discuss either the economic, political and ethical aspects of a call for debt forgiveness

or the total amount of debt that should be forgiven (see, for example, Adams, 1991;

Mikkelsen, 1991; Hanlon, 2000; Roodman, 2001). Nor is this the place to tell the history of

Page 4: Eric Neumayer Is good governance rewarded?: a cross ...eprints.lse.ac.uk/17883/1/Is good governance rewarded...debt forgiveness (for a brief exposition see, for example, Daseking and

3

debt forgiveness (for a brief exposition see, for example, Daseking and Powell, 1999).

Instead, this article provides a quantitative analysis of the determinants of the allocation of

debt forgiveness among recipient countries in the past.

Not many studies exist that have analyzed the allocation of debt forgiveness. That there is

a dearth of empirical studies is somewhat surprising on at least two accounts. First, in some

sense debt forgiveness can be interpreted as foreign aid or official development assistance

(ODA). As Bauer (1991, p. 57) points out: ‘When the Third World’s creditors relieve the

sovereign debtors of meeting their obligations wholly or in part, they in effect provide a form

of foreign aid. Foreign aid involves a positive flow of funds to recipient Third World

governments. Debt relief involves the avoidance of a negative flow.’1 The vast majority of

countries receiving debt forgiveness also receive foreign aid. Debt forgiveness can therefore

even be accompanied by a reduction in foreign aid if donor countries are not willing to

increase the net flow of resources to recipient countries. The point is that many authors

(including the present one) have examined the determinants of the allocation of aid flows, but

– despite their close links – not the determinants of the allocation of debt forgiveness (see, for

example, Boone, 1996; Svensson, 1999; Alesina and Dollar, 2000; Neumayer, 2001a, 2001b,

2001c, 2002). Second, there is a mounting literature suggesting that the effects of aid flows

(and consequently debt forgiveness as well) heavily depend on the quality of governance,

broadly understood, in the recipient country (see, for example, Burnside and Dollar, 1997;

World Bank, 1998; Svensson, 1999; Bräutigam, 2000; Knack, 2000). This is not an

uncontested proposition (see, for example, Hermes and Lensink, 2001). However, if this

proposition is correct, then the question whether more debt forgiveness has been allocated to

countries with good governance assumes great importance. If the quality of governance was

found to play no role in the allocation of debt forgiveness then the beneficial effects of debt

forgiveness would be put into great doubt.

Page 5: Eric Neumayer Is good governance rewarded?: a cross ...eprints.lse.ac.uk/17883/1/Is good governance rewarded...debt forgiveness (for a brief exposition see, for example, Daseking and

4

Section 2 reviews the literature and section 3 shows why rewarding governance

performance might be the only way to ensure that debt forgiveness becomes more effective.

Section 4 presents the research design and section 5 discusses some pertinent statistical issues.

Results are reported and discussed in section 6 with some sensitivity analyses undertaken in

section 7. Section 8 concludes.

2. LITERATURE REVIEW

As mentioned, not many empirical studies have addressed the question what variables, if any,

can explain the allocation of debt forgiveness. Bauer (1991, p. 63) suggests that the allocation

of debt forgiveness ‘does not reflect the usual criteria on which official aid purports to be

allocated among recipient governments, namely the level of incomes per head and the

development prospects of the recipient countries. The beneficiaries of debt relief are simply

those governments that have decided not to honor their obligations and have been allowed to

do so very largely unscathed.’ However, he does not provide a systematic quantitative

analysis to back up this claim.

Hernández and Katada (1996) undertake very simple descriptive analysis of the criteria of

debt forgiveness on ODA (not including official non-concessional loans) for African

countries only. Dividing these countries into three groups according to the level of ODA debt

forgiveness they find that neither absolute poverty as measured by gross national product

(GNP) per capita nor lack of access to foreign exchange seem to have been determinants of

the allocation of ODA debt forgiveness. Such debt forgiveness is correlated with relative

indebtedness as measured by debt per gross domestic product (GDP), but the middle group of

countries received much less debt forgiveness than the high group in spite of being severely

more indebted.

Page 6: Eric Neumayer Is good governance rewarded?: a cross ...eprints.lse.ac.uk/17883/1/Is good governance rewarded...debt forgiveness (for a brief exposition see, for example, Daseking and

5

Alesina and Weder (2000) provide a multivariate ordinary least squares (OLS) estimate on

the sum of debt relief between 1989 and 1997 for 68 countries, controlling for a range of

variables, all measured as 1990 to 1995 averages.2 Alesina and Weder (2000) find that initial

debt per GDP, the natural log of population size as well as the extent of a country’s voting in

concurrence with Japan in the United Nations (UN) general assembly are statistically

significant explanatory variables. A country’s openness towards trade (interpreted by Alesina

and Weder as a proxy for a good policy track record), the natural log of its initial income per

capita, its extent of respect for political rights, the number of years it has been a colony of one

of the Organization of Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD) countries and the

extent of its voting in concurrence with the United States in the UN general assembly are all

insignificant. The coefficient of an added control variable for the extent of a country’s

corruption is positive, but highly insignificant.

This paper analyses more comprehensively the role governance plays in the allocation of

debt forgiveness. The quality of governance has assumed great importance in recent studies

looking at the effectiveness of both aid and debt forgiveness. Knack (2000), for example,

argues that aid flows to countries with a bad policy record might further weaken the quality of

governance. Foreign aid can drag the more talented and skilled workers away to the donor

organizations, which usually pay a higher salary. More importantly, foreign aid can

exacerbate existing corruption: ‘Aid is commonly used for patronage purposes, by subsidizing

employment in the public sector, or in state-operated enterprises, as foreign aid can provide

funds for government to undertake investment that would otherwise be made by private

investors’ (Knack, 2000, p. 5). In OLS estimation he finds evidence that those countries that

received a greater share of aid tend to experience a decline in the quality of governance over

time. He suggests as a possible policy approach that ‘a larger fraction of aid could be tied or

dedicated to improvements in the quality of governance, for example, in the form of programs

Page 7: Eric Neumayer Is good governance rewarded?: a cross ...eprints.lse.ac.uk/17883/1/Is good governance rewarded...debt forgiveness (for a brief exposition see, for example, Daseking and

6

to establish meritocratic bureaucracies and strong, independent court systems’ (Knack, 2000,

p. 22).

In panel growth regressions, Burnside and Dollar (1997) find that aid has a positive effect

on economic growth in recipient countries only if these are characterized by good governance

in terms of good fiscal, monetary and trade policies. They estimate that the mean growth rate

in their sample of poor developing countries would rise from 1.10% to 1.44% if the same

amount of aid had been allocated in greater accordance with the policy record of recipient

countries. Addressing more political aspects of governance, Svensson (1999, p. 293) finds

that foreign aid has a long-term positive growth impact on recipient countries only if these

respect political and civil liberties: ‘Aid has a positive impact on growth in countries with an

institutionalized check on governmental power; that is, in more democratic countries’.

Easterly (2000) examines why successive rounds of past debt forgiveness might not have

had a substantial positive effect on the recipient countries. In short, he argues that the

recipient countries might reveal behavior that is consistent with a high discount rate and a

preference for high debt, thus substituting new borrowing for forgiven debt. He suggests that

‘the granting of progressively more favorable terms for debt forgiveness may also have

perverse incentive effects, as countries borrow in anticipation of debt forgiveness and delay

policy reforms waiting for the best deal’ (Easterly, 2000, p. 6). For a simple cross-sectional

OLS analysis of a sample of 41 HIPC countries which have benefited from several past

rounds of debt forgiveness he finds some evidence that might suggest that these HIPCs dis-

invested in their productive potential at the same time as they accumulated high debts. He

further concludes that those countries became highly indebted because of bad policies, not

because of external shocks to their economies. He also finds that those countries that received

most debt forgiveness among the HIPCs also borrowed most anew. Easterly (2000, p. 30)

demands that ‘some track record of low discount rate behavior should be required prior to

Page 8: Eric Neumayer Is good governance rewarded?: a cross ...eprints.lse.ac.uk/17883/1/Is good governance rewarded...debt forgiveness (for a brief exposition see, for example, Daseking and

7

granting debt forgiveness’. Otherwise the whole idea of debt forgiveness would become

problematic since more resources were to go to ‘countries with bad policies’ rather than to

‘poor countries with good policies’ (ibid., p. 31).

Allen and Weinhold (2000), using a panel data fixed effects approach instead to test

Easterly’s hypothesis, fail to find evidence that countries who benefited most from debt

cancellation, rescheduling or refinancing had higher inflation rates and a lower share of

government spending on capital. Thus they fail to confirm that these countries can be

regarded as exhibiting high discount behavior. However, they as well recognize the need to

allocate debt forgiveness according to some criteria related to the quality of governance. As

Allen and Weinhold (2000, p. 870) point out, if all impoverished countries received debt

forgiveness independent of their policy record, then this would in many cases provide finance

for ‘manifestly corrupt, unaccountable, inefficient and oppressive governments, with little

interest in promoting social welfare’.

3. MAKING DEBT FORGIVENESS MORE EFFECTIVE

To ensure that debt forgiveness is more effective creditor countries have basically two options

available: First, they can impose conditions on the countries receiving debt forgiveness to the

effect that they reform their policies, use the freed resources for particular purposes and

succumb to specified criteria of transparency and accountability. A strong proponent of this

option is, for example, the London-based Centre for Accountability and Debt Forgiveness

(CADRE) (see Theobald, 1997). One minimum condition usually imposed on countries

receiving debt forgiveness is that they follow a program imposed by the IMF. Second,

creditor countries can try to allocate non-conditional debt forgiveness mainly to countries that

have revealed good governance in the past.

Page 9: Eric Neumayer Is good governance rewarded?: a cross ...eprints.lse.ac.uk/17883/1/Is good governance rewarded...debt forgiveness (for a brief exposition see, for example, Daseking and

8

The first option is problematic for a range of reasons: First, it interferes with the

sovereignty of the recipient country and is therefore bound to be met with the same kind of

hostility as IMF conditionality for structural adjustment programs. Second, recipient countries

will do their best to merely create the image of compliance with the conditions imposed and

revert to their old policies as soon as the creditors turn away their attention. In principle,

promised funds could be revoked once the cheating becomes detected, but, as Allen and

Weinhold (2000, p. 861) observe, it is very difficult for the IMF and the World Bank to

withhold funds ex post if recipient countries do not comply (fully) with the ex ante agreed

upon conditionality. Third, it is doubtful at least whether good governance can be externally

imposed via conditions. Bad governance is usually deeply entrenched in a country’s political

system. It can only be overcome slowly and with the full support of the governing elite.

Fourth, for the reasons just mentioned conditionality often does not and cannot tackle the root

causes of bad governance, but merely requires the recipient country to change its spending

pattern.3 For example, in the so-called enhanced initiative by the IMF and the World Bank for

highly indebted poor countries (HIPCs) freed resources were supposed to be spent on poverty

reduction. If countries did obey this kind of conditionality, however, the economic effect of

debt forgiveness might be zero or even negative. Burnside and Fanizza (2001, p. 1) argue that

the conditionality of the enhanced HIPC initiative ‘implies that it provides no net relaxation of

the government’s lifetime budget constraint’ and that, worse still, ‘an increase in aid resources

spent domestically may produce short-run inflationary consequences that could hurt growth

and destabilize output’. Perversely, given the conditionality on government spending, the

recipient country can only keep inflation under control if it negates the debt forgiveness effect

in issuing new debt substituting for the old forgiven debt.

The first option is therefore problematic on various accounts. Remains the second option:

give more debt forgiveness to countries that have shown good governance in the past with the

Page 10: Eric Neumayer Is good governance rewarded?: a cross ...eprints.lse.ac.uk/17883/1/Is good governance rewarded...debt forgiveness (for a brief exposition see, for example, Daseking and

9

hope that in rewarding past good governance these countries will strive to maintain good

governance in the future. This is where the analysis of this article comes in. It aspires to

provide an answer to the question which variables have determined the allocation of debt

forgiveness in the past and, in particular, whether countries with good governance have been

rewarded with higher debt forgiveness.

4. RESEARCH DESIGN

(a) The dependent variable

Data on debt forgiveness, the dependent variable, were derived from the Global Development

Finance database of the World Bank (World Bank, 2000a). It is defined as the change in debt

stock due to debt forgiveness. It does not include debt conversion schemes such as debt

buybacks or debt for equity swaps. Note that the World Bank data recognize debt forgiveness

only as a change in stock and no flow transactions are recorded (World Bank, 2000b, p. 79).

If debt forgiveness is measured as cash-flow relief instead, often debt-service payments that

are rescheduled or deferred are counted as debt forgiveness as well, which is somewhat

misleading since the net present value of the outstanding debt stock is not reduced. The

available data comprise the period 1989 to 1998. Ideally, one would like to make use of both

the cross-section and the time-series dimension of these data. However, debt forgiveness,

unlike ODA, occurs in a rather discontinuous fashion. For this reason it was necessary to

discard the time-series information and to take the sum of debt forgiveness between 1989 and

1998 as the basis for the dependent variable. For the countries in our sample the total sum of

debt forgiven amounts to about US$50 billion.

In the next step the debt forgiveness data have to be made comparable across countries.

Two possible ways of doing this are to transform total debt forgiveness into a per capita

Page 11: Eric Neumayer Is good governance rewarded?: a cross ...eprints.lse.ac.uk/17883/1/Is good governance rewarded...debt forgiveness (for a brief exposition see, for example, Daseking and

10

variable or to look at debt forgiveness per unit of GDP. In the main regressions reported

below we will use GDP as the denominator. Population as the denominator is used in

sensitivity analysis. Both population and GDP data in purchasing power parity came from

World Bank (2001).

(b) The independent variables

As concerns the explanatory variables, let us start with governance, our major variable of

interest. Governance is of course a very broad term. I define it here as the way in which policy

makers are empowered to make decisions, the way in which policy decisions are formulated

and implemented and the extent of which governmental discretion is allowed to encroach into

the rights of citizens. To operationalize this definition of governance I use two different

groups of variables. The first group comprises a set of six aggregate indicators that capture

different aspects of governance. These indicators, developed by World Bank staff, are based

on several different sources, partly polls of experts, partly surveys of residents and

entrepreneurs within a country (Kaufmann, Kraay and Zoido-Lobatón, 1999a, 1999b). A

linear unobserved components model is used to aggregate these various sources into one

aggregate indicator. The advantage of such aggregation is that the underlying concept is

measured with higher reliability and data become available for many more countries than

would be possible if using one source only.

Each indicator provides a subjective assessment of some aspect of a country’s quality of

governance. The indicators are normalized such that they range from around -2.5 to 2.5 and

have a mean of zero and a standard deviation of one. Higher values signal better governance.

The six aggregate indicators address the following aspects (headings followed by a short

description of the major components):

Page 12: Eric Neumayer Is good governance rewarded?: a cross ...eprints.lse.ac.uk/17883/1/Is good governance rewarded...debt forgiveness (for a brief exposition see, for example, Daseking and

11

• Voice and accountability: respect for political rights and civil liberties, public

participation in the process of electing policy makers, independence of media,

accountability and transparency of government decisions.

• Political instability and violence: political and social tension and unrest, instability of

government.

• Government effectiveness: stability, predictability and efficiency of governmental

decisions.

• Regulatory burden: burden on business via quantitative regulations, price controls and

other interventions into the economy.

• Rule of law: respect for law and order, predictability and effectiveness of judiciary

system, enforceability of contracts.

• Graft: corruption, that is, the acceptance of money for providing extra-legal favours.

Note that of these five dimensions of governance, “regulatory burden” is probably the

most contested and problematic one. It is strongly related to a particular neo-liberal view on

economic policy, whereas the other aspects of governance are more consensually accepted

across the political spectrum. Indeed, as we will see later, one of the components of this

variable derives from assessments of the Heritage Foundation, a conservative U.S.-based

think tank.

I will use each indicator in isolation since they all measure different aspects of governance

and it is interesting to see what aspect of governance, if any, has an impact upon the

allocation of debt forgiveness. In addition, I use a measure of general governance that is the

average of the individual indicators – six in number for most countries, fewer for countries for

which not all indicators were available.4 The idea is to see whether governance more

generally is a determinant of debt forgiveness allocation.

Page 13: Eric Neumayer Is good governance rewarded?: a cross ...eprints.lse.ac.uk/17883/1/Is good governance rewarded...debt forgiveness (for a brief exposition see, for example, Daseking and

12

As mentioned, two of the major advantages of the World Bank indicator set are that it is

available for many countries due to the aggregation of information from different sources

with differing coverage of countries and that it is perhaps more representative since it derives

from a broad set of sources. At the same time, it suffers from a number of disadvantages as

well. For example, while the quality of governance is of course not a constant but evolves

over time, all data entering the governance indicators stem from a single, but varying time

period around the mid-1990s. One could argue that the bias introduced is likely to be small.

First, the source data refer to subjective assessments for which respondents will have taken

into account the quality of governance over a range of past years rather than just for the year

they were surveyed. Second, the quality of certain aspects of governance in most countries is

not likely to change much from year to year. This is probably true for such aspects as

government effectiveness, rule of law and graft. However, other aspects of governance might

change quite rapidly.

The second group of proxy variables for governance has the advantage of varying over

time. It consists of three variables from the International Country Risk Guide (ICRG) as well

as one variable each from Freedom House and the Heritage Foundation. Whilst data from the

private company, which provides the ICRG to international business, are normally

prohibitively expensive to get for researchers, data covering the period 1989 to 1995 were

made freely available by King and Zeng (2001). The ICRG (2002) website describes the

variables used as follows:

• Bureaucratic quality: institutional strength and quality of the bureaucracy; its capacity to

govern without drastic changes in policy or interruptions in government services; its

autonomy from political pressure.

Page 14: Eric Neumayer Is good governance rewarded?: a cross ...eprints.lse.ac.uk/17883/1/Is good governance rewarded...debt forgiveness (for a brief exposition see, for example, Daseking and

13

• Law and order: strength and impartiality of the legal system together with the extent of

popular observance of the law.

• Corruption: excessive patronage, nepotism, job reservations, ‘favor-for-favors’, secret

party funding, and suspiciously close ties between politics and business.

Note that “Bureaucratic quality” is conceptually roughly comparable to “Government

effectiveness” from the World Bank indicator set and indeed forms one of its components.

The same is true of “Law and order” and “Rule of law” and “Corruption” and “Graft”,

respectively. In addition, I use the “Civil Liberties” and “Political Rights” data from Freedom

House (2000) over the period 1989 to 1998, which is conceptually roughly comparable to and

forms one component of the “Voice and accountability” indicator from the World Bank.

Finally, I use the simple average of the “trade policy”, “government intervention”, “capital

flows and foreign investment”, “wage and price controls” and “regulation” components of the

Heritage Foundation’s (2002) Index of Economic Freedom as a further variable, also called

“regulatory burden”. This variable is conceptually roughly comparable and forms one

component of the “regulatory burden” variable of the World Bank indicator set.

Unfortunately, the Heritage Foundation did not publish its index before 1995 so that the data

cover the period 1995 to 1998 only. No time varying data were available that are conceptually

comparable to the “Political instability and violence” indicator of the World Bank indicator

set.

“Corruption” and “Law and order” are measured by the ICRG on a zero to six points and

“Bureaucratic Quality” on a zero to four points scale. The higher the points the better a

country fares with respect to the variable. The assessment is based on expert analysis from a

worldwide network and is subjected to a peer review. The Freedom House data are based on

expert assessments of the extent to which a country effectively provides for political rights

Page 15: Eric Neumayer Is good governance rewarded?: a cross ...eprints.lse.ac.uk/17883/1/Is good governance rewarded...debt forgiveness (for a brief exposition see, for example, Daseking and

14

and civil liberties (Karatnycky 1999, pp. 546-553). “Political rights” refer to, for example, the

existence and fairness of elections, existence of opposition and the possibility to take over

power via elections. “Civil liberties” refer to, for example, the freedom of assembly, the right

to open and free discussion, the independence of media, protection from political terror and

the prevalence of the rule of law. Both are measured on a one to seven points scale and I

added the two variables for the purpose of analysis. The higher the score the better rights and

liberties are protected. The Heritage Foundation (2002) data derive from partly objective,

partly subjective assessments of pre-specified criteria. Their indices are measured on a one to

five point scale. For the purpose of this article, the data were reversed such that a higher score

indicates less “regulatory burden”. Since the time-varying proxy variables for governance

stem from different sources no attempt was made to provide an aggregate or average time-

varying governance indicator.

Besides governance, which other variables are likely to have explanatory power? In

accordance with the ODA allocation literature, I will look at two groups of variables. One

group is supposed to measure the recipient country’s need for debt forgiveness. The other

group proxies the political interest of the creditors. The first group comprises three variables:

For rather obvious reasons the first two – total debt per GNP and debt service divided by the

value of exports of goods and services – are often regarded as a good proxy for a country’s

need for debt forgiveness (data from World Bank, 2000a).5 Note that this does not mean that

creditors themselves might not have an economic interest in forgiving debt for countries in

dire need for debt forgiveness. While not uncontested, a huge amount of theoretical and

empirical literature, as summarized comprehensively by Cline (1995, chapter 4), suggests that

severe so-called debt overhang might cripple a country’s economy to an extent that debt

forgiveness can be in the economic interest of creditors as well if it leads to a stimulation of

the economy and therefore to a higher prospect of servicing and paying back of the

Page 16: Eric Neumayer Is good governance rewarded?: a cross ...eprints.lse.ac.uk/17883/1/Is good governance rewarded...debt forgiveness (for a brief exposition see, for example, Daseking and

15

outstanding debt. As a third variable for a recipient country’s need for debt forgiveness we

will consider the natural log of GDP per capita in purchasing power parity (data from World

Bank, 2001) since, all other things equal, a poorer country is more in need of debt forgiveness

than a richer one.

Political interest of the creditors is measured by five variables. The first is the number of

years the recipient country has been a former colony of an OECD country (data taken from

Dollar and Alesina, 2000).6 Creditors might favor their former colonies in part at least

because of a political interest in maintaining their influence on those countries. The second

variable is the natural log of the minimum distance in kilometers between the capital city of

an indebted developing country to either New York, Rotterdam or Tokyo (data taken from

Gallup and Sachs, 1999).7 The idea is that donor countries might give more aid to

geographically close countries for reasons of strategic-political interest. This variable is

supposed to proxy this interest for the major creditor countries: The US and Canada, the

European Union countries as well as Japan. The third variable is arms imports as a percentage

of total imports (data taken from World Bank, 2001). Many creditor countries are major arms

exporters and might have an interest in forgiving debt of major arms importers.

Perhaps none of the variables listed so far truly captures the political interests of the

United States, the major national creditor and arguably the most important power in such

multilateral institutions as the World Bank and the IMF.8 The United States has few ex-

colonies and its political interests are global in nature. To capture some of the political interest

the United States has in debtor countries I therefore include two further variables: First, the

amount of per capita military grants allocated between 1989 and 1998 with data taken from

USAID (1999), divided by population (taken from World Bank, 2001). The other variable

tries to measure the similarity of policy positions. Signorino and Ritter (1999) have developed

a measure of policy similarity. This measure conceptualises two policy positions as falling

Page 17: Eric Neumayer Is good governance rewarded?: a cross ...eprints.lse.ac.uk/17883/1/Is good governance rewarded...debt forgiveness (for a brief exposition see, for example, Daseking and

16

within a policy space defined by all the possible policy positions. The measure falls in the

interval –1 to 1, where –1 means that two policy positions are as far apart in the policy space

as possible (complete dissimilarity) and 1 means that the two policy positions are identical

(complete similarity). Gartzke, Jo and Tucker (1999) use this measure to provide estimates of

the similarity of policy positions as revealed by the voting behaviour in the UN General

Assembly. Data for the similarity of policy positions of debtor countries with the United

States were available from 1989 to 1996.

Note that for all explanatory variables that are not constant the average value over the

period 1989 to 1998 or the latest available year was taken. We have debt forgiveness data for

136 developing countries and countries in transition (former East bloc countries). However,

the number of observations in the regressions reported below is somewhat lower, depending

on the availability of explanatory variables. The starting regressions in each table reported in

section 6, which only includes variables measuring the recipient countries’ need for debt

forgiveness, comprises 125 countries. The annex lists these countries.

5. STATISTICAL ISSUES

We will test the following three hypotheses. First, more debt forgiveness goes to countries

in need of debt forgiveness. Second, more debt forgiveness goes to countries for which

creditors have a political interest. Third, more debt forgiveness goes to countries with good

governance.

Some countries do not receive any debt forgiveness at all. There are basically two options for

dealing with the limitedness of the dependent variable. One is to follow the lead of the ODA

allocation literature and to distinguish between two stages in the process of debt forgiveness

allocation in employing the so-called two-stage or two-part model (see, for example,

Page 18: Eric Neumayer Is good governance rewarded?: a cross ...eprints.lse.ac.uk/17883/1/Is good governance rewarded...debt forgiveness (for a brief exposition see, for example, Daseking and

17

Cingranelli and Pasquarello, 1985; Carleton and Stohl, 1987). The first stage is the so-called

gate-keeping stage where it is determined which countries receive debt forgiveness. The

appropriate estimation technique for this kind of analysis is probit.9 The second stage is the

so-called level stage where it is determined how much of a country’s debt is forgiven, which

has been selected as a recipient of debt forgiveness in the first stage. Usually, OLS is used at

this stage. That this two-stage process might represent a realistic characterization is

tentatively supported by the fact that sometimes explicit prerequisites for the eligibility for

debt forgiveness are stated. For example, to qualify for debt forgiveness as part of the United

States Enterprise for the America Initiative, recipient countries ‘must have democratically

elected governments, must not have repeatedly provided support for international terrorism,

must not fail to cooperate on international drug control, and must not engage in consistent

patterns of gross violations of internationally recognized human rights’ (Sanford, 1995, p.

370, fn. 160). To qualify for the HIPC initiative of the World Bank and IMF, countries have

to fulfill certain criteria with respect to their debt-to-export or, in few cases, their debt-to-tax

ratios (Cohen, 2000).

The second method for dealing with the limitedness of the dependent variable uses an

estimation technique called tobit. Use of this technique does not necessitate breaking down

the process of aid allocation into two stages since, contrary to OLS techniques, tobit explicitly

takes into account that the dependent variable can be zero for a substantial part of the

population.

None of the two methods can be said to be superior since they are based on different

assumptions. The two-stage method implicitly assumes that creditors actually do make two-

stage decisions, i.e. that they first decide on whether or not a country is eligible for debt

forgiveness and then on how much debt should be forgiven. Furthermore, it is assumed that

the error terms from both stages are uncorrelated. The tobit method avoids the potentially

Page 19: Eric Neumayer Is good governance rewarded?: a cross ...eprints.lse.ac.uk/17883/1/Is good governance rewarded...debt forgiveness (for a brief exposition see, for example, Daseking and

18

artificial construct of a two-stage allocation process, but it suffers from restrictive underlying

assumptions as well. The two main ones are that, first, the same set of variables is assumed to

determine both whether the dependent variable is zero and, if positive, what size it has.

Second, the sign of those variables is constrained to be the same (Verbeek, 2000, p. 207). The

first assumption is not so problematic in the context of this article since I use the same

variables for both the gate-keeping stage and the level stage as well in the alternative method.

The second assumption is somewhat more restrictive. However, it does not seem

unreasonable to assume that if a variable has a positive influence on the probability of

receiving any debt forgiveness at all, then it will also have a positive influence on the amount

of debt forgiven.

Heckman’s (1979) two-step estimator can be interpreted as an extension of the tobit

method (Amemiya 1985), relaxing both assumptions of the tobit method already mentioned as

well as allowing the error terms from both steps to be correlated. However, the two-step

estimator requires an exclusionary variable that has a significant impact upon the first step

(selection step), but not upon the second step. Unfortunately, such an exclusionary variable is

typically very difficult to find and without it model identification rests on restrictive

distributional assumptions only. This dependence on distributional assumptions renders the

two-step estimator inferior to either the two-part model or the tobit method in many

circumstances (Puhani 2000), but not always (Leung and Yu 1996). Since no exclusionary

variable could be found for this article, the two-step estimation technique is not applied.

6. RESULTS

We start with the tobit estimation technique testing for the influence of recipient need on the

allocation of debt forgiveness (see regression I of table 1). Both income and the debt to GNP

Page 20: Eric Neumayer Is good governance rewarded?: a cross ...eprints.lse.ac.uk/17883/1/Is good governance rewarded...debt forgiveness (for a brief exposition see, for example, Daseking and

19

ratio are statistically significant and have the expected sign. Richer countries are forgiven less

debt and countries burdened by a higher debt to GNP ratio are forgiven more debt.

Surprisingly, the debt service to exports ratio has an unexpected coefficient, but tests highly

insignificant. Next, regression II enters our creditor interest variables. With the exception of

U.S. military grants, all of them are statistically insignificant.10 Entering each creditor interest

variable in isolation leads to the same result (not shown). Clearly, creditor interest seems to be

a determinant of the allocation of debt forgiveness only with respect to direct United States

military or security interests. Since governance is our major explanatory variable and the

other creditor interest variables remain highly insignificant when entered in combination with

the various governance variables, all of the following regressions were run with U.S. military

grants as the only creditor interest variable included.

< Insert Table 1 about here >

Regressions III to VIII enter each of our six different indicators of governance from the

World Bank indicator set in isolation. Of these, “voice and accountability” and “regulatory

burden” are statistically significant with the expected sign. The other four indicators test

highly statistically insignificant. Regression IX enters the average governance indicator. It has

the expected sign and tests statistically significant at the 90% level. In table 2 we undertake

tobit estimations with the governance variables from the Freedom House, Heritage

Foundation and the ICRG indicator set. It confirms the results from table 1 in that “political

rights and civil liberties” and “regulatory burden” test statistically significant, whereas

“bureaucratic quality”, “law and order” and “corruption” do not.

< Insert Table 2 about here >

Page 21: Eric Neumayer Is good governance rewarded?: a cross ...eprints.lse.ac.uk/17883/1/Is good governance rewarded...debt forgiveness (for a brief exposition see, for example, Daseking and

20

Next, we apply the two-stage method. Table 3 reports results for the first stage using the

probit estimation technique for the World Bank indicators. Note that the reported coefficients

are not probit coefficients. Instead, they are already transformed into changes in the

probability at the mean of a variable, with all other independent variables held at their mean

values as well.11 Regression I starts again with the recipient need variables. Only the debt to

GNP ratio is statistically significant. A one point increase in the debt to GNP ratio above its

mean value increases the likelihood of becoming eligible for debt forgiveness by 0.3% if the

other two independent variables are held at their mean value. Regression II enters the creditor

interest variables, which are all statistically insignificant. The same is true for all the

governance indicators in isolation as well as the average governance indicator with results

reported in regressions III to IX. Note that in one regression the income variable becomes

marginally significant as does the debt service to exports ratio in another regression, but with

an unexpected sign.

< Insert Table 3 about here >

Table 4 reports first-stage estimation results for the Freedom House, Heritage Foundation

and ICRG indicators. As before, the debt to GNP ratio is statistically significant throughout.

Income is significant in two regressions. Interestingly, contrary to the comparable World

Bank indicator, “political rights and civil liberties” tests significant with the expected sign.

None of the other governance indicators tests significantly. If the allocation of debt

forgiveness can be characterized by two-stage decision making then only the debt to GNP

ratio and perhaps a country’s poverty as well as its protection of political rights and civil

Page 22: Eric Neumayer Is good governance rewarded?: a cross ...eprints.lse.ac.uk/17883/1/Is good governance rewarded...debt forgiveness (for a brief exposition see, for example, Daseking and

21

liberties seem to be statistically significant determinants of the decision on which countries

are deemed eligible for debt forgiveness in stage one.

< Insert Table 4 about here >

Table 5 reports results for the second stage using OLS for the World Bank indicator set.

As before, regression I starts with the recipient need variables. Similar to the tobit estimation

results, both income and the debt to GNP ratio are statistically significant and have the

expected sign. Entering the creditor interest variables in regression II confirms their statistical

insignificance, with the exception of U.S. military grants, which tests significant throughout.

Looking at the governance indicators in isolation in regressions III to VIII suggests again

“voice and accountability” as well as “regulatory burden” as statistically significant

explanatory variables with the expected sign. The other four are again insignificant. The

average governance indicator tests statistically insignificant in regression IX. The coefficient

of the income variable is significant in six regressions.

< Insert Table 5 about here >

Table 6 reports second-stage OLS estimation results for the Freedom House, Heritage

Foundation and ICRG indicators. The debt to GNP ratio is statistically significant throughout

as before, but the income variable only in two regressions. Interestingly, while the

insignificance of “bureaucratic quality”, “law and order” and “corruption” confirms the

analysis in table 5, both “political rights and civil liberties” and “regulatory burden” test

insignificant as opposed to “voice and accountability” and the “regulatory burden” variable

from the World Bank indicator set.

Page 23: Eric Neumayer Is good governance rewarded?: a cross ...eprints.lse.ac.uk/17883/1/Is good governance rewarded...debt forgiveness (for a brief exposition see, for example, Daseking and

22

< Insert Table 6 about here >

All in all the results reported above provide a mixed picture of the role the quality of

governance plays in the allocation of debt forgiveness. Apart from “political rights and civil

liberties” none of our six governance indicators is a statistically significant determinant of

whether or not a country is deemed eligible for receiving any debt forgiveness. As concerns

the amount of debt forgiven most of our governance indicators remain statistically

insignificant independent of the estimation technique used. “Voice and accountability”,

“political rights and civil liberties” as well as the “regulatory burden” variable from both

indicator sets assume statistical significance in the tobit estimations. But only “voice and

accountability” as well as “regulatory burden” from the World Bank indicator set remain

statistically significant in the OLS estimations of the two-stage technique. Even then, the

effect of good governance on the allocation of debt forgiveness is somewhat modest. To see

this, refer to table 7, which compares the second stage OLS regressions III and VI from table

5 to the same model without the governance indicators, but provides standardized beta

coefficients instead and constrains the sample to be the same. The R2 rises from .4292 to

merely .4624 if “voice and accountability” is added as an explanatory variable and to .4627 if

“regulatory burden” is added instead. In other words, variations in our governance indicators

do not add much to an explanation of the variation in the dependent variable debt forgiveness.

Looking at the beta coefficients we see that the effect of “voice and accountability” is

estimated as .22 and that of “regulatory burden” as .20. In other words, a one standard

deviation increase in these aspects of governance leads to a .19 and .22 standard deviation

increase in debt forgiveness. In comparison, the effect on the dependent variable of a one

Page 24: Eric Neumayer Is good governance rewarded?: a cross ...eprints.lse.ac.uk/17883/1/Is good governance rewarded...debt forgiveness (for a brief exposition see, for example, Daseking and

23

standard deviation increase in the debt to GNP ratio, one of the variables measuring a

country’s need for debt forgiveness, is about three times higher.

< Insert Table 7 about here >

7. SENSITIVITY ANALYSIS12

What happens to the results for the governance indicators if we replace the dependent variable

debt forgiveness per GDP by debt forgiveness per capita? The answer is not much. The only

difference is that the average governance variable as well as the “regulatory burden” variable

from the Heritage Foundation in tobit estimation become statistically insignificant, whereas

“graft” assumes statistical significance. “Law and order” also assumes statistical significance,

but with an unexpected sign, both in the tobit as well as the second stage OLS estimations.

That is, countries with a lower “law and order” performance are estimated to receive higher

debt forgiveness per capita.

Are the major results driven by the presence of outliers? The answer is no. Belsley, Kuh

and Welsch (1980) suggest excluding observations as outliers that have both high residuals

and a high leverage. I applied their criterion together with their suggested cut-off point to the

model that includes all three debtor need variables plus the United States military grants

variable for the regressions for which debt forgiveness per GDP is the dependent variable.13

Doing so leads to the exclusion of Angola, Bolivia, Congo (Republic), Egypt, Guinea-Bissau,

Guyana, Nicaragua, Yemen and Zambia from the sample. As concerns the governance

variables, the only thing that changes is that the average governance indicator as well as

“political rights & civil liberties” and the “regulatory burden” variable from the Heritage

Foundation become statistically significant in the level stage estimations. Interestingly, the

Page 25: Eric Neumayer Is good governance rewarded?: a cross ...eprints.lse.ac.uk/17883/1/Is good governance rewarded...debt forgiveness (for a brief exposition see, for example, Daseking and

24

United States military grants variable loses significance in all tobit estimations, tests

significant with a negative sign in most first-stage regressions and remains significant with a

positive sign in most second-stage OLS regressions. In other words, once outliers are

excluded countries that receive more United States military grants per capita are less likely to

receive debt forgiveness, but once selected receive more debt forgiveness than others.

As concerns potential problems caused by simultaneity, these should only be marginally

relevant for our governance indicators. There is no reason to presume that the amount of debt

forgiveness will have had a substantial impact upon the quality of governance. While there

have sometimes been conditions imposed on the beneficiary countries with regard to, for

example, government spending, no such conditions with regard to governance were set up to

any great extent. As argued above, even if they were it would be doubtful whether recipient

countries would actually be willing to put the demands into reality. It seems equally doubtful

that they would change the quality of their governance on their own in response to debt

forgiveness.

Simultaneity is likely to be much more of a problem for the three indicators measuring

recipient country need. After all, it is the very aim of debt forgiveness to reduce the debt to

GNP ratio as well as the debt service to exports ratio and to increase, if indirectly, income

levels within the recipient country. To check for simultaneity bias in the estimations, I have

therefore instrumented these three variables using their respective average values in the five

year period 1984 to 1988 as instruments. Since these instruments are determined prior to the

period of debt forgiveness looked at here, simultaneity bias should no longer pose a problem.

With respect to United States military grants one might argue that they are not influenced

by the amount of debt a country is forgiven, since the grants fulfil specific United States

strategic policy interests. On the other hand, since both military grants and debt forgiveness

improve the net financial position of the recipient country the two could be regarded as

Page 26: Eric Neumayer Is good governance rewarded?: a cross ...eprints.lse.ac.uk/17883/1/Is good governance rewarded...debt forgiveness (for a brief exposition see, for example, Daseking and

25

substitutes both from the perspective of the United States and the recipient country. However,

this assumes that the resources freed up by debt forgiveness would be spent on the same

purposes that the military grants would have been spent on.

On the whole, there seemed to be strong arguments for instrumenting only with respect to

the debtor need variables.14 Of course, this comes at the price of a decrease in the precision of

estimation as well as loss of observations since often the instruments are not available for all

countries. It is interesting to note that even then “voice and accountablity” as well as

“regulatory burden” from the World Bank indicator set remain statistically significant with

the expected sign in both tobit and second-stage OLS estimations, whilst “political rights and

civil liberties” is significant in the first-stage probit estimations. In all other cases, none of the

governance variables assumes significance, apart from “law and order”, which is significant

with an unexpected sign in both tobit and first-stage probit estimations. As concerns the

debtor need as well as the United States military grants variable, there is practically no change

compared to the regressions without instrumentation.

8. CONCLUSION

The analysis in this paper has shown that the need for debt forgiveness is clearly a powerful

determinant of the allocation of debt forgiveness, thus confirming the first hypothesis. As

concerns the second hypothesis, the evidence supports the statistical significance of creditors’

political interest only for the United States military grants variable. As concerns the third

hypothesis, there is no clear answer. There is evidence that some aspects of governance have

an influence on the allocation of debt forgiveness, but other aspects and governance in general

were often found to be statistically insignificant. It is maybe not surprising that of all the

different governance aspects “voice and accountability”, “political rights and civil liberties”

Page 27: Eric Neumayer Is good governance rewarded?: a cross ...eprints.lse.ac.uk/17883/1/Is good governance rewarded...debt forgiveness (for a brief exposition see, for example, Daseking and

26

and “regulatory burden” should stand out as having some, if modest, influence on the

allocation of debt forgiveness. After all, the respect for the political and participatory rights of

citizens and the abstention from highly distortionary and burdensome economic policies have

long been a top priority on the demand list of aid donors and debt creditors. As mentioned

above, whilst respect for political and participatory rights of citizens is more consensually

accepted as one aspect of good governance, “regulatory burden” is more contestable as it

relates to a particular view on economic policy making.

Overall, it seems therefore fair to say that in the past debt forgiveness has not been used

much to reward countries with good governance. From a normative point of view, future debt

forgiveness should revert this. Allocating a greater share of debt forgiveness to countries with

good governance would set the right incentives for highly indebted countries and would most

likely lead to a more effective and productive use of the resources employed. This will be true

no matter what the total amount of debt forgiven for all countries, an issue, which this article

has not discussed.

By implication, a similar argument can be made for the allocation of new lending and,

indeed, for aid disbursement. Critics argue that the debt crisis is partly to blame on loose

lending to corrupt and unaccountable governments with poor and highly distortive economic

policies, that is, countries with bad governance (Hanlon, 2000; Roodman, 2001). To prevent

this from re-occurring lenders need to take better into account the quality of governance of

potential borrowers whilst at the same time trying to help those countries improving their

governance that are committed to reform.

In order to do so, creditors and lenders need to invest more into developing high-quality

indicators of governance and collecting the necessary data. At the moment, besides major

efforts at the World Bank, the construction of governance indicators is mainly left to private

companies that sell their information to international business. Their view on what constitutes

Page 28: Eric Neumayer Is good governance rewarded?: a cross ...eprints.lse.ac.uk/17883/1/Is good governance rewarded...debt forgiveness (for a brief exposition see, for example, Daseking and

27

good governance need not coincide with how creditors and lenders perceive good governance,

however. There is therefore still a long way to go to strengthen the importance of good

governance in international financial lending and aid allocation decisions.

Page 29: Eric Neumayer Is good governance rewarded?: a cross ...eprints.lse.ac.uk/17883/1/Is good governance rewarded...debt forgiveness (for a brief exposition see, for example, Daseking and

28

NOTES

1 Note that debt relief and debt forgiveness are often used interchangeably, while sometimes debt relief is also

used as a more general term encompassing forgiveness, rescheduling, buyback schemes etc. In section 4, we will

define the meaning of debt forgiveness used in this article.

2 Note that Alesina and Weder (2000) use the term ‘debt relief’ in a broader sense encompassing both debt

forgiveness and debt rescheduling.

3 Indeed, as Theobald (1997, p. 301) points out, at least for Africa and despite the rhetoric to the contrary,

conditionality has always focused on purely economic rather than political aspects. Bad governance is as much a

political as an economic problem, however.

4 Note that due to strong collinearity the six indicators of governance were not entered simultaneously.

5 From a theoretical perspective the debt to exports ratio could have been used in lieu of the debt to GNP ratio

(the two variables are highly correlated – correlation coefficient of .67 in our sample). However, the debt to GNP

ratio proved to be a much more potent explanatory variable and was therefore preferred here.

6 Alternatively, a dummy variable for colonial status could have been created. The results on the colony variable

reported below remain basically the same if the dummy variable is used instead.

7 If this data was not available for a particular country, the existing data from a geographically close country was

taken instead.

8 On United States influence in the World Bank, see, for example, Wade (2002).

9 Alternatively, logit estimation could have been undertaken. The two techniques provide very similar results in

standard situations (Verbeek, 2000).

10 Note that contrary to Alesina and Weder (2000) we find that creditors do not forgive more debt for their

former colonies. The results are not directly comparable, however, since Alesina and Weder (2000) look at debt

relief rather than debt forgiveness and employ a much smaller sample.

11 Note that the probabilities are contingent on specific values of the independent variables because the probit

model is nonlinear, and therefore nonadditive, in the probabilities.

12 In order to save space results of the sensitivity analysis are merely described, but not reported. All results can

be received from the author upon request.

13 The criterion is to exclude an observation if its so-called DFITS is greater than twice the square root of (k/n),

where k is the number of independent variables and n the number of observations. DFITS is defined as the

square root of (hi/(1-hi)), where hi is an observation’s leverage, multiplied by its studentized residual.

Page 30: Eric Neumayer Is good governance rewarded?: a cross ...eprints.lse.ac.uk/17883/1/Is good governance rewarded...debt forgiveness (for a brief exposition see, for example, Daseking and

29

14 There is practically no change if United States military grants are instrumented for as well in the same way as

the debtor need variables are.

Page 31: Eric Neumayer Is good governance rewarded?: a cross ...eprints.lse.ac.uk/17883/1/Is good governance rewarded...debt forgiveness (for a brief exposition see, for example, Daseking and

30

REFERENCES

Adams, P. (1991). Odious debts: Loose lending, corruption, and the third world’s

environmental legacy. London: Earthscan.

Alesina, A. and Weder, B. (2000). Do corrupt governments receive less foreign aid? Mimeo,

Harvard University and University of Basel.

Alesina, A. and Dollar, D. (2000). Who gives foreign aid to whom and why? Journal of

Economic Growth, 5(1) 33-63.

Allen, T. and Weinhold, D. (2000). Dropping the debt for the new millennium: is it such a

good idea? Journal of International Development, 12(6), 857-875.

Amemiya, T. (1985). Advanced econometrics. Cambridge (Mass.): Harvard University Press.

Bauer, P. (1991). The development frontier: Essays in applied economics. London: Harvester

Wheatsheaf.

Belsley, D.A., Kuh, E. and Welsch, R.E. (1980). Regression diagnostics. New York: John

Wiley and Sons.

Boone, P. (1996). Politics and the effectiveness of foreign aid. European Economic Review,

40(2), 289-329.

Bräutigam, D. (2000). Aid dependence and governance, Washington D.C.: American

University

Burnside, C. and Dollar, D. (1997). Aid, policies and growth. Policy Research Working Paper

1777. Washington D.C.: World Bank.

Burnside, C. and Fanizza, D. (2001). Hiccups for HIPCs. Mimeo. Washington D.C.: World

Bank and International Monetary Fund.

Carleton, D. and Stohl, M. (1987). The Role of Human Rights in U.S. Foreign Assistance

Policy: a Critique and Reappraisal. American Journal of Political Science, 31(4), 1002–

1018.

Page 32: Eric Neumayer Is good governance rewarded?: a cross ...eprints.lse.ac.uk/17883/1/Is good governance rewarded...debt forgiveness (for a brief exposition see, for example, Daseking and

31

Cingranelli, D.L. and Pasquarello. T.E. (1985). Human Rights Practices and the Distribution

of U.S. Foreign Aid to Latin American Countries. American Journal of Political Science,

29(3), 539–563.

Cline, W.R. (1995). International debt reexamined. Washington D.C.: Institute for

International Economics.

Cohen, D. (2000). The HIPC initiative: True and false promises. Technical Papers 166. Paris:

Organization of Economic Co-operation and Development.

Daseking, C. and Powell, R. (1999). From Toronto terms to the HIPC initiative: a brief

history of debt relief for low-income countries. Working paper 99/142. Washington

D.C.: International Monetary Fund.

Easterly, W. (2000). How did highly indebted poor countries become highly indebted?

Reviewing two decades of debt relief. Mimeo. Washington D.C.: World Bank.

Freedom House (2000). Annual Surveys of Freedom Country Ratings 1972-73 to 1999-00.

New York: Freedom House.

Gallup, J.I. and Sachs, J. (1999). Geography and economic development. Mimeo. Cambridge

(Mass.): Harvard University.

Gartzke, E., Jo, D.J. and Tucker, R. (1999). The similarity of UN policy positions, 1946-96,

Dataset. http://www.vanderbilt.edu/~rtucker/data/affinity/un/similar

Hanlon, J. (2000). How much debt must be canceled? Journal of International Development

12(6), 877-901.

Heckman, J. (1979). Sample selection bias as a specification error. Econometrica, 47(1), 153-

161.

Heritage Foundation (2002). The Index of Economic Freedom. Washington, D.C.: The

Heritage Foundation.

Page 33: Eric Neumayer Is good governance rewarded?: a cross ...eprints.lse.ac.uk/17883/1/Is good governance rewarded...debt forgiveness (for a brief exposition see, for example, Daseking and

32

Hermes, N. and Lensink, R. (2001). Changing the conditions for development aid: A new

paradigm? Journal of Development Studies, 37(6), 1-16.

Hernández, L. and Katada, S.N. (1996). Grants and debt forgiveness in Africa: a descriptive

analysis. Policy Research Working Paper 1653. Washington D.C.: World Bank.

ICRG (2002). The Rating System. http://icrgonline.com

Karatnycky, Adrian (ed.) (1999). Freedom in the World – The Annual Survey of Political

Rights and Civil Liberties 1998-1999. New York: Freedom House.

Kaufmann, D., Kraay, A. and Zoido-Lobatón, P. (1999a). Aggregating Governance

Indicators. Policy Research Working Paper 2195. Washington D.C.: World Bank.

Kaufmann, D., Kraay, A. and Zoido-Lobatón, P. (1999b). Governance Matters. Mimeo.

Washington D.C.: World Bank.

King, G. and Zeng, L. (2001). Improving Forecasts of State Failure. World Politics, 53(4),

623-658.

Knack, S. (2000). Aid Dependence and the quality of governance: a cross-country empirical

analysis. Mimeo. Washington D.C.: World Bank.

Mikkelsen, J.G. (1991). Deserved debt relief: A note. World Development, 19(8), 1117-1120.

Neumayer, E. (2001a). Is respect for human rights rewarded? An analysis of bilateral and

multilateral aid allocation before and after the end of the Cold War. Mimeo. London:

London School of Economics.

Neumayer, E. (2001b). What factors determine the allocation of aid by Arab countries and

multilateral agencies? Mimeo. London: London School of Economics.

Neumayer, E. (2001c). The determinants of aid allocation by regional multilateral

development banks and United Nations agencies. Mimeo. London: London School of

Economics.

Page 34: Eric Neumayer Is good governance rewarded?: a cross ...eprints.lse.ac.uk/17883/1/Is good governance rewarded...debt forgiveness (for a brief exposition see, for example, Daseking and

33

Neumayer, E. (2002). Do human rights matter in bilateral aid allocation? A quantitative

analysis of 21 donor countries. Social Science Quarterly (forthcoming).

Puhani, P. (2000). The Heckman correction for sample selection and its critique. Journal of

Economic Surveys, 14(1), 53-68.

Roodman, D.M. (2001). Still waiting for the Jubilee: Pragmatic solutions for the Third World

debt crisis. Worldwatch Paper 155. Washington D.C.: Worldwatch Institute.

Sanford, J.E. (1995). Foreign debts to the U.S. government: recent rescheduling and

forgiveness. George Washington Journal of International Law and Economics, 28(2),

345-400.

Signorino, C.S. and Ritter, J.M. (1999). Tau-b or Not Tau-b: Measuring the Similarity of

Foreign Policy Positions. International Studies Quarterly, 43(1), 115-144.

Svensson, J. (1999). Aid, growth and democracy. Economics and Politics, 11(3), 275-297.

Theobald, R. (1997). Can debt be used to combat political corruption in Africa? Crime, Law

and Social Change, 27(3/4), 299-314.

USAID (1999). U.S. Oversees Loans and Grants Online (Greenbook). http://qesdb.cdie.org

Verbeek, M. (2000). A Guide to Modern Econometrics. Chichester: John Wiley and Sons.

Wade, R. (2002). U.S. hegemony and the World Bank: the fight over people and ideas.

Review of International Political Economy, 9(1), (forthcoming).

World Bank (1998). Assessing aid: What works, what doesn’t, and why. New York: Oxford

University Press.

World Bank (2000a). Global Development Finance Indicators on CD-Rom. Washington D.C.:

World Bank.

World Bank (2000b). Global Development Finance. Washington D.C.: World Bank.

World Bank (2001). World Development Indicators on CD-Rom. Washington D.C.: World

Bank.

Page 35: Eric Neumayer Is good governance rewarded?: a cross ...eprints.lse.ac.uk/17883/1/Is good governance rewarded...debt forgiveness (for a brief exposition see, for example, Daseking and

34

Table 1. Tobit estimation for World Bank indicators

I II III IV V VI VII VIII IX Debt/GNP .34***

(7.52) .35*** (7.16)

.33*** (7.50)

.34*** (7.03)

.34*** (7.03)

.35*** (7.74)

.34*** (7.26)

.34*** (6.67)

.35*** (7.61)

Debt service/exports -.27 (.74)

-.50 (1.24)

-.21 (.58)

-.53 (1.26)

-.56 (1.33)

-.60 (1.58)

-.34 (.87)

-.43 (.99)

-.29 (.78)

ln(GDP p.c.) -16.06*** (3.30)

-13.08** (2.22)

-23.87*** (4.36)

-18.49** (3.04)

-22.98*** (3.87)

-23.38*** (4.27)

-17.65** (3.17)

-19.04** (3.07)

-21.47*** (3.78)

U.S. military grants p.c. 3.29* (1.94)

3.33** (2.75)

3.09* (1.92)

2.86* (1.86)

2.82* (1.86)

3.07* (1.96)

3.12* (1.92)

2.92* (1.89)

U.S. policy similarity -36.58 (1.32)

Colony .08 (.51)

ln(Distance) -1.60 (.18)

Arms imports -.81 (.66)

Voice and accountability 16.23** (2.87)

Political instability and violence -5.75 (.92)

Government effectiveness 7.14 (.86)

Regulatory burden (World Bank) 17.17** (2.74)

Rule of law -5.75 (.16)

Graft 21.27 (.62)

Average governance 13.98* (1.76)

N 125 115 118 102 103 112 112 102 118 of which uncensored 93 86 88 75 76 85 85 75 88 Pseudo R-squared .0725 .0796 .0844 .0833 .0832 .0851 .0776 .0828 .0794

Note: Dependent variable is debt forgiveness. Absolute t-values in parentheses. Coefficient on constant not reported.

* statistically significant at 90% level ** at 95% level *** at 99% level.

Page 36: Eric Neumayer Is good governance rewarded?: a cross ...eprints.lse.ac.uk/17883/1/Is good governance rewarded...debt forgiveness (for a brief exposition see, for example, Daseking and

35

Table 2. Tobit estimation for Freedom House, Heritage Foundation and ICRG indicators

I II III IV V Debt/GNP .34***

(7.76) .43*** (6.90)

.37*** (7.95)

.41*** (6.50)

.43*** (6.92)

Debt service/exports -.29 (.82)

-.29 (.66)

-.50 (1.26)

-.32 (.73)

-.30 (.67)

ln(GDP p.c.) -23.14*** (4.15)

-14.23** (2.08)

-23.21*** (3.92)

-12.80* (1.95)

-14.84** (2.26)

U.S. military grants p.c. 3.43** (2.27)

3.05* (1.89)

3.18** (2.09)

3.23** (2.02)

3.02* (1.87)

Political rights and civil liberties 3.23** (2.29)

Bureaucratic quality -1.61 (.31)

Regulatory burden (Heritage Foundation) 14.01* (1.90)

Law and order -7.70 (1.58)

Corruption -.20 (.04)

N 125 81 107 81 81 of which uncensored 93 63 80 63 63 Pseudo R-squared .0812 .0850 .0878 .0883 .0849

Note: Dependent variable is debt forgiveness. Absolute t-values in parentheses. Coefficient on constant not reported.

* statistically significant at 90% level ** at 95% level *** at 99% level.

Page 37: Eric Neumayer Is good governance rewarded?: a cross ...eprints.lse.ac.uk/17883/1/Is good governance rewarded...debt forgiveness (for a brief exposition see, for example, Daseking and

36

Table 3. Gate-keeping stage (probit estimation) for World Bank indicators

I II III IV V VI VII VIII IX Debt/GNP .003**

(3.06) .002*** (3.46)

.003*** (3.31)

.002** (3.06)

.002*** (3.21)

.002** (2.86)

.001** (3.08)

.002** (3.13)

.003*** (3.31)

Debt service/exports -.002 (.79)

-.002* (1.93)

-.001 (.84)

-.002 (1.34)

-.002 (1.35)

-.001 (1.57)

-.001 (1.27)

-.001 (1.15)

-.001 (.90)

ln(GDP p.c.) -.032 (1.18)

-.005 (.45)

-.035 (1.50)

-.020 (1.06)

-.033* (1.66)

-.015 (1.17)

-.010 (.86)

-.011 (.72)

-.033 (1.40)

U.S. military grants p.c. -.001 (.39)

.001 (.30)

-.000 (.03)

-.000 (.09)

-.000 (.16)

.000 (.17)

.000 (.23)

.000 (.08)

U.S. policy similarity -.069 (1.40)

Colony -.000 (.38)

ln(Distance) -.016 (1.29)

Arms imports -.001 (.27)

Voice and accountability .030 (1.45)

Political instability and violence -.004 (.25)

Government effectiveness .018 (.86)

Regulatory burden (World Bank) -.002 (.15)

Rule of law .133 (1.47)

Graft .166 (1.15)

Average governance .036 (1.20)

N 125 115 118 102 103 112 112 102 118 Pseudo R-squared .2782 .3692 .3450 .3455 .3537 .3540 .3782 .3624 .3410

Note: Dependent variable is dummy for debt forgiveness eligibility (1 = country receives debt forgiveness; 0 = country does not receive debt forgiveness). Absolute z-values in

parentheses. Heteroscedasticity-robust standard errors. Coefficient on constant not reported. * statistically significant at 90% level ** at 95% level *** at 99% level.

Page 38: Eric Neumayer Is good governance rewarded?: a cross ...eprints.lse.ac.uk/17883/1/Is good governance rewarded...debt forgiveness (for a brief exposition see, for example, Daseking and

37

Table 4. Gate-keeping stage (probit estimation) for Freedom House, Heritage Foundation and ICRG indicators

I II III IV V Debt/GNP .003**

(2.92) .001** (2.61)

.003** (2.26)

.001** (2.68)

.001** (2.71)

Debt service/exports -.001 (.52)

-.001 (.78)

-.002 (.94)

-.001 (1.03)

-.001 (.98)

ln(GDP p.c.) -.085** (2.18)

-.015 (1.16)

-.058* (1.65)

-.012 (1.09)

-.015 (1.12)

U.S. military grants p.c. .004 (.78)

.028 (.33)

.005 (1.32)

.029 (.39)

.022 (.24)

Political rights and civil liberties .019** (2.08)

Bureaucratic quality -.006 (.81)

Regulatory burden (Heritage Foundation) .026 (.76)

Law and order -.008 (1.17)

Corruption -.014 (1.61)

N 125 81 107 81 81 Pseudo R-squared .3091 .3244 .3226 .3334 .3415

Note: Dependent variable is dummy for debt forgiveness eligibility (1 = country receives debt forgiveness; 0 = country does not receive debt forgiveness). Absolute z-values in

parentheses. Heteroscedasticity-robust standard errors. Coefficient on constant not reported. * statistically significant at 90% level ** at 95% level *** at 99% level.

Page 39: Eric Neumayer Is good governance rewarded?: a cross ...eprints.lse.ac.uk/17883/1/Is good governance rewarded...debt forgiveness (for a brief exposition see, for example, Daseking and

38

Table 5. Level stage (OLS estimation) for World Bank indicators

I II III IV V VI VII VIII IX Debt/GNP .30***

(3.39) .30*** (3.54)

.29*** (3.36)

.31*** (3.33)

.31*** (3.32)

.32*** (3.59)

.30*** (3.29)

.30*** (3.27)

.30*** (3.42)

Debt service/exports -.35 (.80)

-.50 (.93)

-.29 (.62)

-.64 (1.09)

-.64 (1.21)

-.58 (1.18)

-.45 (.89)

-.57 (.98)

-.37 (.81)

ln(GDP p.c.) -11.22* (1.88)

-8.32 (1.12)

-17.94** (2.70)

-11.40 (1.66)

-15.49* (2.10)

-16.71** (2.45)

-13.71* (1.86)

-13.61 (1.56)

-14.67** (2.18)

U.S. military grants p.c. 2.95* (1.97)

2.92*** (5.67)

2.65*** (6.53)

2.47*** (5.09)

2.50*** (5.05)

2.53*** (5.50)

2.60*** (5.34)

2.59*** (5.58)

U.S. policy similarity -17.68 (.50)

Colony .04 (.18)

ln(Distance) 5.38 (.72)

Arms imports -.63 (.25)

Voice and accountability 13.69** (2.37)

Political instability and violence -6.93 (.80)

Government effectiveness 4.36 (.48)

Regulatory burden (World Bank) 15.09** (2.51)

Rule of law -43.62 (1.30)

Graft 4.40 (.10)

Average governance 8.40 (1.01)

N 93 86 88 75 76 85 85 75 88 R-squared .4152 .4364 .4590 .4589 .4519 .4627 .4385 .4510 .4337

Note: Dependent variable is debt forgiveness. Only countries with positive debt forgiveness included. Absolute t-values in parentheses. Heteroscedasticity-robust standard errors.

Coefficient on constant not reported. * statistically significant at 90% level ** at 95% level *** at 99% level.

Page 40: Eric Neumayer Is good governance rewarded?: a cross ...eprints.lse.ac.uk/17883/1/Is good governance rewarded...debt forgiveness (for a brief exposition see, for example, Daseking and

39

Table 6. Level stage (OLS estimation) for Freedom House, Heritage Foundation and ICRG indicators

I II III IV V Debt/GNP .30***

(3.36) .39*** (4.27)

.34*** (3.45)

.38*** (4.28)

.40*** (4.16)

Debt service/exports -.35 (.81)

-.25 (.43)

.34 (.48)

-.27 (.46)

-.32 (.54)

ln(GDP p.c.) -16.02** (2.39)

-9.97 (2.12)

-16.15* (2.12)

-7.96 (1.01)

-9.98 (1.30)

U.S. military grants p.c. 2.94*** (6.61)

2.52** (4.09)

2.72** (5.14)

2.70** (3.92)

2.55*** (4.57)

Political rights and civil liberties 1.95 (1.39)

Bureaucratic quality 1.19 (.28)

Regulatory burden (Heritage Foundation) 11.18 (1.46)

Law and order -5.24 (1.08)

Corruption 3.79 (.79)

N 93 63 80 63 63 R-squared .4451 .4858 .4791 .4945 .4908

Note: Dependent variable is debt forgiveness. Only countries with positive debt forgiveness included. Absolute t-values in parentheses. Heteroscedasticity-robust standard errors.

Coefficient on constant not reported. * statistically significant at 90% level ** at 95% level *** at 99% level.

Page 41: Eric Neumayer Is good governance rewarded?: a cross ...eprints.lse.ac.uk/17883/1/Is good governance rewarded...debt forgiveness (for a brief exposition see, for example, Daseking and

40

Table 7. Level stage (OLS estimation): Standardized beta-coefficients

I III VI Debt/GNP .58***

(3.35) .57*** (3.34)

.61*** (3.59)

Debt service/exports -.07 (.67)

-.06 (.58)

-.12 (1.18)

ln(GDP p.c.) -.18* (1.79)

-.29** (2.55)

-.27** (2.45)

U.S. military grants p.c. .14*** (6.71)

.16*** (5.57)

.13*** (5.05)

Voice and accountability .21** (2.41)

Regulatory burden

.21** (2.51)

N 85 85 85 R-squared .4292 .4624 .4627

Note: Dependent variable is debt forgiveness. Coefficients are standardized beta coefficients. Only countries with positive debt forgiveness included. Absolute t-values in

parentheses. Heteroscedasticity-robust standard errors. Coefficient on constant not reported. * statistically significant at 90% level ** at 95% level *** at 99% level.

Page 42: Eric Neumayer Is good governance rewarded?: a cross ...eprints.lse.ac.uk/17883/1/Is good governance rewarded...debt forgiveness (for a brief exposition see, for example, Daseking and

41

Appendix: List of countries in tables 1 and 3, regression I

Albania, Algeria, Angola, Argentina, Armenia, Azerbaijan, Bangladesh, Barbados, Belarus,

Belize, Benin, Bhutan, Bolivia, Botswana, Brazil, Bulgaria, Burkina Faso, Burundi,

Cambodia, Cameroon, Cape Verde, Central African Republic, Chad, Chile, China, Colombia,

Comoros, Congo (Democratic Republic), Congo (Republic), Costa Rica, Cote d'Ivoire,

Croatia, Czech Republic, Dominica, Dominican Republic, Ecuador, Egypt, El Salvador,

Equatorial-Guinea, Eritrea, Estonia, Ethiopia, Fiji, Gabon, Gambia, Georgia, Ghana, Grenada,

Guatemala, Guinea, Guinea-Bissau, Guyana, Haiti, Honduras, Hungary, India, Indonesia,

Iran, Jamaica, Jordan, Kazakhstan, Kenya, Korea (Republic), Kyrgyz Republic, Laos, Latvia,

Lebanon, Lesotho, Lithuania, Macedonia (FYR), Madagascar, Malawi, Malaysia, Maldives,

Mali, Mauritania, Mauritius, Mexico, Moldova, Mongolia, Morocco, Mozambique, Nepal,

Nicaragua, Niger, Nigeria, Pakistan, Panama, Papua New Guinea, Paraguay, Peru,

Philippines, Poland, Romania, Russian Federation, Rwanda, Samoa, Senegal, Sierra Leone,

Slovak Republic, Solomon Islands, South Africa, Sri Lanka, St. Kitts and Nevis, St. Lucia, St.

Vincent and the Grenadines, Swaziland, Syria, Tanzania, Thailand, Togo, Trinidad and

Tobago, Tunisia, Turkey, Turkmenistan, Uganda, Ukraine, Uruguay, Uzbekistan, Vanuatu,

Venezuela, Vietnam, Yemen, Zambia, Zimbabwe.