european parking u-turn, itdp

Upload: norman-oder

Post on 07-Apr-2018

228 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

  • 8/6/2019 European Parking U-Turn, ITDP

    1/84

    EuropesParking U-Turn:From Accommodation

    to Regulation

    By Michael Kodransky and Gabrielle Hermann

    Spring, 2011

  • 8/6/2019 European Parking U-Turn, ITDP

    2/84

    2 | Europes Parking U-Turn

    A tremendous and special thanks to Walter Hook for his invaluable guidance

    and critical review of this publication. Thanks to Diego Salzillo Arriaga for his

    assistance collecting data and developing the Munich case study. This report

    also could not have been produced without the support of a number of other

    people such as Heiner Monheim, Julien Allaire, Marius Navazo, Bram van

    Liupen, Carina Zell, Mandy Held, Jan Willing, Nicole Foletta, Felix Bode, Willy

    Staley, Ryan Whitney, Matthew Egan, and Holly LaDue.

    Michael Kodranksy is Global Research Manager for ITDP and Gabrielle Hermann

    is a consultant to ITDP.

  • 8/6/2019 European Parking U-Turn, ITDP

    3/84

    itdp.org | 3

    Table of Contents

    4 Executive Summary

    8 Introduction

    10 Part 1: Historical Context

    12 Part 2: Current State of Successful Parking Management

    StrategiesEconomic Mechanisms

    Regulatory Measures

    Physical Design

    Quality of Service Contracting

    22 Part 3: Case Studies

    Amsterdam, The Netherlands

    Antwerp, Belgium

    Barcelona, Spain

    Copenhagen, Denmark

    London, United Kingdom

    Munich, Germany

    Paris, France

    Stockholm, Sweden

    Strasbourg, France

    Zurich, Switzerland

    74 Conclusion

    76 Appendix A: Munich Minimum Parking Requirements

    77 Appendix B: Additional Resources

    78 Appendix C: Parking Management and Technology

    Vendors

    80 Appendix D: Pay-by-phone Vendors

    81 Appendix E: Reference List

  • 8/6/2019 European Parking U-Turn, ITDP

    4/84

    4 | Europes Parking U-Turn

    Executive Summary

    This paper is the second in a series o policy papers rom ITDP on parking. The

    rst paper, released in Spring 2010, ocused on successul parking practices in

    U.S. cities. This paper reviews successul parking practices in European cities.Parking management is a critical and oten overlooked tool or achieving a va-

    riety o social goals. For much o the 20th Century, cities in Europe, like cities in

    the rest o the world, used parking policy mainly to encourage the construction

    o additional o-street parking, hoping to ease a perceived shortage o parking.

    In the last ew decades a growing number o European cities have led the world in changing the direc-

    tion o parking policy. European citizens grew tired o having public spaces and ootpaths occupied by

    surace parking. Each parking space consumes rom 15 m2 to 30 m2, and the average motorist uses two

    to ve dierent parking spaces every day. In dense European cities, a growing number o citizens began

    to question whether dedicating scarce public space to car parking was wise social policy, and whether

    encouraging new buildings to build parking spaces was a good idea. No matter how many new parkinggarages and motorways they built, the trac congestion only grew worse, and as much as 50% o trac

    congestion was caused by drivers cruising around in search o a cheaper parking space.

    In the cities reviewed here, parking policy has been reoriented around alternative social goals. Some

    recent parking reorms are driven by the need to comply with EU ambient air quality or national

    greenhouse gas targets. Other new parking policies are part o broader mobility targets encouraging

    reductions in the use o private motor vehicles. While London, Stockholm, and a ew other European

    cities have managed to implement congestion charging to reduce motor vehicle use, more are turning

    to parking.

    Every car trip begins and ends in a parking space, so parking regulation is one o the best ways to

    regulate car use. Vehicles cruising or parking oten make up a signicant share o total trac. Otherreasons or changing parking policies were driven by the desire to revitalize city centers and repurpose

    scarce road space or bike lanes or bike parking.

    The amount o parking available in a city is heavily infuenced by public policy. On-street parking is

    governed by municipal or district policy, and o-street parking is generally controlled through zoning

    and building regulations. These are ultimately political questions: how much parking is built in new

    buildings, and how much public space should be dedicated to motor vehicle parking as opposed to

    other uses.

    The impacts o these new parking policies have been impressive: revitalized and thriving town centers;

    signicant reductions in private car trips; reductions in air pollution; and generally improved quality o

    lie.

    Progress in Europe on parking reorm should not be overstated. Most cities still impose minimum park-

    ing requirements on developers, and ew cities have imposed maximum parking requirements. While

    a growing number o cities have mandated charges or both on- and o-street parking, they generally

    charge rates that are too low. The most innovative European parking practices are discussed below as

    actionable measures that can be applied by any city government depending on their short- and long-

    term goals.1

  • 8/6/2019 European Parking U-Turn, ITDP

    5/84

    itdp.org | 5

    EFFEcTivE PARki MAAEMET STRATEiES

    Eonom Mehansms

    Pricing: Trafc experts know that having 15% o parking spaces unoccupied is optimal rom the per-

    spective o minimizing the time people spend cruising or parking. European cities are ahead o theirU.S. counterparts, with most o the cities reviewed in this report setting parking ees at levels which

    vary at dierent locations and dierent times o day to keep occupancy rates at 85%. Some European

    cities like Strasbourg are also ahead o US cities in coordinating on-street parking pricing and supply

    with o-street pricing and supply. These measures help ensure that more desirable parking spaces

    are used by those most willing to pay or the privilege.

    Emissions-Based Parking Charges: Some municipalities, such as Amsterdam and about a dozen bor-

    oughs in London, have started to vary parking charges based on the CO2

    emission levels o vehicles

    at the time o registration. The London boroughs base the price o residential parking permits on the

    CO2

    emission standards o the drivers vehicle. Cleaner vehicles pay a discount rate, while a higher

    rate applies to cars that pollute more.

    Workplace Levies: Nottingham, in the UK, recently decided to impose a tax o 250 per year oncompanies or each parking space they provide or employees. The levy, which goes into eect begin-

    ning 2012, only applies to companies with over 10 parking spaces. Municipalities across the UK are

    considering ollowing suit.2 I all the districts currently considering the levy decide to implement it,

    an estimated ten million drivers would be impacted, as employers would likely pass down the cost

    on to employees.3 Other cities like Hamburg are allowing companies to provide ewer parking spaces

    than required by zoning regulations i they provide a monthly transit pass to employees.

    Earmarking/Ring Fencing: Revenue generated rom parking ees goes to support sustainable trans-

    port goals. Barcelona, Strasbourg, and certain boroughs in London unnel revenue rom parking ees

    to transit projects rather than putting the money into a general und. Political buy-in can be earned

    with this type o initiative because the public sees how money rom parking charges is spent. In

    Barcelona, 100% o parking ees go to support Bicingthe citys bike sharing program.

    Regulatory Mehansms

    Parking Supply Caps: Both Zurich and Hamburg roze the existing parking supply in the city center.

    When a new space is built o-street, an on-street space has to be removed, so it can be repurposed

    or other needs like widened sidewalks or bikeways. This type o cap-and-trade was implemented in

    Hamburg in 1976 and in Zurich as part o its historic parking compromise in 1996. Zurich went even

    urther. Outside o the zone where the parking cap applies, the City o Zurich only allows developers

    to build new parking spaces i the surrounding roads can absorb additional trafc without conges-

    tion, and the air can handle additional pollution without violating ambient air quality norms. This

    policy has helped make Zurich one o the most livable cities in Europe.

    Parking Maximums: Historically, most cities required developers to build a minimum number onew parking spaces. Residential buildings had to include at least one, i not more, parking spaces per

    residential unit, and commercial developments had to build a minimum number o parking spaces

    per square meter depending on how the building would be used. European cities today are abolishing

    these parking minimums in town centers and placing new ceilings on the number o new parking

    spaces they can build. In the past, planners thought that requiring developers to build more parking

    would transer the cost o parking supply onto private developers. Unortunately, it also created a

    perverse incentive or developers to build more parking than the market required and stimulated car

  • 8/6/2019 European Parking U-Turn, ITDP

    6/84

    6 | Europes Parking U-Turn

    use. Paris a bolished parking minimums and several other cities established zone-based maximums.

    Dutch cities, ollowing the national A, B, C policy introduced in 1989, divided themselves into three

    types o zones: areas with excellent transit access and poor car access (designated with the letter

    A), areas with good transit access and good car access (B), and areas with good car access but poor

    transit access (C). Each zone had its own parking minimum and parking maximum. New develop-

    ments in zone A could only build a ew parking spaces. In zone B they had to build a moderate

    amount o parking within a specifed range, and in zone C they could build even more parking, but

    again within a specifed range. Many cities outside o the Netherlands, like Antwerp and Zurich, also

    reduced parking maximums and minimums in locations proximate to transit acilities.

    Regulating the Location of Parking: While most cities regulate where parking can occur during dier-

    ent times o the day, European cities have used this regulatory power more requently or the purpose

    o encouraging transit use and creating vibrant street lie. Many cities push parking to peripheral lo-

    cations, while giving transit passengers and cyclists more convenient access to popular destinations

    than private motorists.

    Physical Design

    Bollards: Some cities install this type o barrier to prevent cars rom parking in pedestrian paths and

    in public plazas. The saety hazards caused by vehicles encroaching on walkways and bike paths can

    be avoided by erecting physical obstructions. Since 2001, Paris has invested approximately 15 mil-

    lion to install nearly 335,000 bollards. Bollards are also ubiquitous on the narrow streets o Madrid toprevent cars rom blocking building entrances and sidewalks. These may be automated and retract

    into the ground to allow limited access to certain vehicles, such as delivery vans, at certain times.

    Striped Lines: Stockholm uses painted lines to mark reserved spaces or vehicles with disability privi-

    leges. Individual spaces were once marked or all vehicles, but now this is only done or special cases.

    Entire sections o curbside are demarcated with one large box sometimes taking up an entire street

    as the latest practice. One large box encourages smaller vehicles to squeeze into the limited space. In

    this way the city optimizes revenue rom its pricing program.

    Repurposing Public Spaces: Copenhagen has transormed its city center by creating high-quality

    pedestrian districts and high-quality bicycle paths by eliminating hundreds o parking spaces.

    Danes can be seen riding their bikes and lingering in public spaces on the coldest, snowiest days

    o the year. As the urban planner Jan Gehl has remarked, Copenhagen eliminated winter in just 40

    years. Removal o on-street parking rom historic districts and central shopping streets has become

    a signature eature o many European cities. This is oten a boon or business, too; shops within the

    pedestrian precincts generate more income than those outside. Treating street space as a valuable

    public asset, by reclaiming it rom cars, can lead to much better land uses. Reducing the number o

    on-street car parking can be a way to encourage the use o other transportation modes by transorm-

    ing ormer spaces to bicycle paths or wider walkways.

    Street Geometry: Strategically arranging existing parking spaces can help make other street users

    more comortable. In Zurich, alternating parking spaces on two sides o a narrow street act as a chi-

    cane that slows vehicle speeds. Amsterdam has zones called wooners that use parked cars to create

    a winding passage which orces vehicles to move at a pedestrians pace. Paris and Copenhagen have

    bike lanes that are protected by parked carsthese act as a barrier between the cyclists and movingtrafc. Copenhagen and Antwerp have play-streets that allow children to saely spend time on the

    street without the threat o getting hit by a cartrees, benches, and other physical obstructions cue

    vehicles that they are guests in the space.

    Quality of Service Contracting and Technologies

    Outsourcing aspects o a citys parking management to a private third party can be an efcient tool to

    improve parking management and increase revenue collected rom fnes and ees. In Stockholm, many

  • 8/6/2019 European Parking U-Turn, ITDP

    7/84

  • 8/6/2019 European Parking U-Turn, ITDP

    8/84

    The most innovative approaches to parking have

    improved the economic, social, and environmen-

    tal quality of city centers. Choosing the right

    policies depends on a citys goalwhether it is to

    reduce CO2

    emissions, to relieve trac jams, to

    remove vehicles because they are a nuisance, or

    any number o other reasonsand certain poli-

    cies t certain goals better than others. This paper

    illustrates which cities are meeting their goals

    with success.

    Vehicle parking consumes a lot o land, is blight-

    ing, and contributes to dispersed development,

    increasing travel distances. Every car trip begins

    and ends in a parking space. Each parking space

    takes up an area that ranges rom 15 to 30 m2. Car

    drivers need between two to ve dierent parking

    spaces every day. Most cities still require develop-

    ers to build a minimum amount o parking, but

    cities at the oreront o parking reorm are reduc-

    ing or removing minimum parking requirements

    and replacing them with maximums.

    The ample provision of parking, especially free

    parking, contributes to excess car use by mak-ing driving the most convenient and affordabletravel option.

    Cities aiming to reduce car use also remove or

    restrict on-street parking in central areas, and

    charge a high price or the remaining spaces.

    European cities are ahead o the rest o the world

    in charging rational prices or on-street parking

    that leave an optimal amount o spaces vacant

    or newcomers. This substantially reduces trac

    rom vehicles cruising or parking.

    Parking policy can be a powerul tool to encour-

    age people to take public transportation or to

    bike. Because walking trips are slower than other

    trips, i a person can walk to their car aster than

    they can walk to the bus stop and catch a bus,

    most people will choose to drive.1 Some European

    districts, like Vauban in Freiburg, Germany, place

    parking at the perimeter o the neighborhood,

    keeping the neighborhood core car ree but acces-

    sible by bike and transit.

    Some cities are even charging or parking based

    on vehicle emissions. For example, several bor-

    oughs in London have introduced CO2

    emission-

    based residential parking permit schemes. The

    vehicles that emit the most CO2

    pay the highest

    ees, while electric cars can park or ree. MoreEuropean cities are using parking management

    to encourage replacement o clunkers with low-

    emission or emission-ree vehicles in an eort

    to improve air quality and tackle climate change.

    In France, or example, parking is viewed as a

    tool that can infuence a 14% reduction o the

    greenhouse gas emissions emitted every year

    nationwide.2

    Introduction

    This report examines European parking management over the last hal cen-

    tury, through the prism o ten case studies. Parking management has been

    an eective policy tool to improve the quality o city centers and surrounding

    areas, saving time and money or shoppers, residents, commuters, and busi-

    ness owners alike. Parking can be managed through economic and regulatory

    mechanisms, the implementation o certain physical designs, as well as quality

    o service contracting. This report examines all our o these strategies.

    8 | Europes Parking U-Turn

  • 8/6/2019 European Parking U-Turn, ITDP

    9/84

    itdp.org | 9

    Starting in the 1950s and 1960s, many European

    cities ound their once vibrant public plazas and

    boulevards encroached upon by vehicular park-

    ing. While most cities tried to accommodate the

    growing tide o car use, Zurich and Copenhagen

    took the lead in reclaiming this space or pedes-

    trians and tightly restricting parking in their ur-

    ban core. These decisions paid o and these cities

    are now among the most attractive and competi-

    tive cities in Europe.

    ThiS REPoRT hAS bEEn DiviDED inToThREE PARTS:

    Part 1 o this report provides a historic back-

    ground rom which many o the current progres-

    sive parking policies in Europe stem. The recent

    reversal o 50-year-old parking policy practices in

    Europe is a revolt against the lowered quality o

    lie that cars bring with them to public spaces.

    Part 2 details the tools used to manage parking

    by restricting it through regulatory procedures,

    physical design elements, and economic mecha-

    nisms. The current range o strategies that ft into

    these categories are outlined and discussed, in

    addition to a discussion o technologies like pay-

    by-phone and smart meters that enable better

    perormance o these management measures.

    Part 3 illustrates the ways in which each city

    documented in the case studies has successully

    shited trips away rom car travel toward moresustainable modes o transport.

    The conclusions reached are based on a review

    o research texts and public policy documents as

    well as phone, email, and ace-to-ace interviews.

    Parking managers, academics, private sector pro-

    essionals, advocacy groups, and parking technol-

    ogy experts were consulted to understand the

    multi-layered parking practices in Europe.

    a seen-sy mnpl pkng fly ss lng pmnen nl n he ene f Hmbg, peennghe ses, lke gng peple ess he wefn.

    the enne ledng he Ple f Ls xiv n veslles,Fne s nnded wh sfe pkng.

    NotES to iNtroDuctioN

    1 ineew wh Hemnn Knhe, ags 2010.

    2 E Gnele nd chsphe Begn, (2008) the imp f cPkng Ples n Geenhse Gs Emssns, assn fEpen tnsp.

    3 Knphe, Hemnn (2009). the le f pkng gnz-n f enmy, sey nd ennmen. tehnl unesyf venn. inse f tnspn, reseh cene ftnsp Plnnng & tf Engneeng.

  • 8/6/2019 European Parking U-Turn, ITDP

    10/84

    10 | Europes Parking U-Turn

    Local European governments, at frst, allowed

    vehicles to park at no cost in public squares, on

    sidewalks and nearly anywhere a car could ft.1

    Ater decades o unettered accommodation to

    cars within the densest and most visited parts o

    the cityoten the historic districts, central busi-

    ness areas, and nearby residential zonesmanylocal administrations developed more stringent

    parking regulations. City governments began

    to realize that public lie had been allowed to

    degrade as a result o trafc congestion, air pol-

    lution, noise, diminished street saety, and cars

    encroaching on public gathering places.

    Parking infrastructure can diminish the qualityof streetscapes, interrupt walking paths, andincrease distances between destinations.

    Drivers desire or nearby parking spots was

    almost always appeased, but at the same time an

    opportunity was lost to develop the land or other

    potential uses such as housing, ofce space, or

    retailespecially where land is scare, in already

    built-out districts. Parking space may take up

    property that has a higher social, environmental,

    and even economic value i developed dierently.

    In the Dutch city o Breda, a canal had been

    drained to build a 200-space underground car

    parking acility with a road above it. Ofcials in

    Breda decided the underground parking acility

    did not sufciently justiy losing the waterront.

    The canal has since been restored in a widely

    successul project that has transormed the old

    waterront into a popular destination. On-streetspaces were also removed to create a pedestrian

    promenade.

    Once the on-street parking spaces in many

    European cities had been consumed, local au-

    thorities ound themselves lacking public unds

    to satiate an ever-growing demand or even more

    parking, so they oered private parking compa-

    nies concessionsoten or indefnite or very long

    periods o timeto build and manage o-street

    acilities.2 Building regulations were also changed,

    requiring new developments o all typescom-

    mercial, residential, educational and othersto

    accommodate what was viewed as the mobility

    paradigm o the uture: personal travel by private

    car. These two policy decisionsoreiting control

    o o-street parking inventory and creating count-

    less square meters o new parking spacescre-

    ated a system o parking supply that would later

    prove quite challenging to reverse.

    PART 1:

    Historial context

    Since the 1960s, there has been a gradual shit across Europe, mainly in city

    centers, away rom unregulated or minimally regulated car parking to more

    restrictive policies that better balance the competing demands or urban space.

    Following the Second World War, motor vehicle ownership and use started to

    climb in and around European cities as new neighborhoods were designed to

    enable easier car travel. Eastern Europe was an exception, where car ownership

    only started to climb most signifcantly ater the introduction o market econo-

    mies in the 1990s. New town developments that ormed outside o the city

    center oten mimicked the kind o building trends that, at the time, also domi-

    nated the U.S., Canada, and Australiaand in most cases still do. Residents

    rom the dense inner cities started parking close to their home, oten blockingpedestrian paths and carriageways allocated or moving trafc. Sidewalks were

    eaten away to eed the driving and parking demand renzy while roads were

    widened, giving more public space away or private vehicle use.

  • 8/6/2019 European Parking U-Turn, ITDP

    11/84

    itdp.org | 11

    In the 1960s and 70s, ater a ew decades o

    ullling the unending demand or car parking,certain Western European cities, like Copenhagen

    and Zurich, began to realize that excessive park-

    ing supply was part o a system-wide policy

    mismatch that contributed to trac congestion.

    Parking plans that responded to demand without

    controlling supply threatened the economic pros-

    perity, community vitality, and historic advan-

    tage o many central city locations.3 The demand

    or more parking spaces had long been viewed as

    an indicator o a thriving economy, except when

    trac conditions began to impact productivity,

    polluted the air, and led to other undesirableconditions. These negative externalities demon-

    strated a need to reassess transportation invest-

    ment priorities and pricing mechanisms, which

    can infuence travel behavior. 4

    Car ownership increased in nearly every

    European country throughout the 1990s and

    in the beginning o the 2000s. Emerging mar-

    ket economies in Eastern Europe, like Slovenia

    and the Czech Republic, have outpaced more

    car-oriented countries, like Greece and Ireland,

    when it comes to car ownership. (See Figure 1.)

    This growth infuenced numerous cities to shit

    away rom catering to increased parking demand

    toward an approach that addressed many o the

    unintended and adverse impacts resulting rom

    unregulated parking supply.

    Parking demands fuctuate based on location,

    time o day, and day o the week. Central rail

    stations are oten high demand areas or quick

    passenger drop-os and pick-ups. Employment

    districts have high parking demand during

    business hours on the weekday, and experience

    less demand over the weekends. Sports arenasonly experience an infux o cars during events.

    Meanwhile, residential areas may have long-term

    parking demands overnight on weekdays, but

    lower demand on the weekends, when house-

    holds may use the amily car or retreats to the

    countryside.

    Befe (p) ndfe (b) heNeuwe mk wsesed f dnd undegundpkng fly he gnlnl n Bed, theNehelnds. Sue:Wessel Keze

    Fgue 1:chnge n nube f pssenge s pe 1,000 esdens, 199020045

    Austria

    Belgium

    Denmark

    Finland

    France

    Germany

    Greece

    Ireland

    Italy

    Netherlands

    Portugal

    Spain

    Sweden

    UK

    Bulgaria

    Czech

    Estonia

    Hungary

    Latvia

    Lithuania

    Poland

    Slovakia

    Slovenia

    1990

    19972004

    NotES to Part i

    1 Jn Gehl nd Ls Geze (2006). New cy Lfe. the Dnshaheul Pess: cpenhgen.

    2 Kenneh J. Bun (2006). the pll eny f pknghges n s nd send- bes wlds. tnspn Ply.13 (6), 470478.

    3 Jn Gehl nd Ls Geze (2003). New cy Spes. the Dnshaheul Pess: cpenhgen. thd Edn

    4 coSt an 342 (2006). Pkng Ples nd he Effes nEny nd mbly. tehnl cee n tnsp.

    5 Eus (2003). ae we vng n he gh den,Eupen Envnen ageny. Ssl yebk n nd-de unes, ofe f ofl Publns.

  • 8/6/2019 European Parking U-Turn, ITDP

    12/84

    12 | Europes Parking U-Turn

    EcooMic MEchAiSMS

    on-Street Prng

    The rst parking meter in the world was installed

    in Oklahoma City in the United States in 1935,2

    while the rst version in Europe was introduced

    in the summer o 1958 on Grosvenor Square in

    London outside o the American Embassy in the

    Mayair district.3

    On-street parking ees are set to optimize the use

    o curb space, infuencing turnover and mini-

    mizing the number o vehicles slowing trac by

    searching or parking. Prices are calibrated based

    on demand sensitivities (i.e., vacancy and occu-

    pancy targets). Drivers will park as close to their

    destination as possible even i it means blocking

    the moving trac lane and pedestrian paths.5

    Market-based perormance pricing mechanisms

    can work to shit the behavior o those who

    choose to drive. Harmonizing o-street and on-

    street prices is essential to nudge drivers into o-

    street acilities. Municipal garages in Strasbourg

    slightly undercut on-street parking costs to

    encourage drivers to park out o sight.

    Drivers circulating to nd a ree or cheap on-

    street space slow overall trac fow, while thosealready parked monopolize underpriced curbside

    spacepreventing turnover that could bring more

    customers into area shops. Vehicles searching or

    parking make up one-third o trac in London.6

    Decreasing the number o available spaces while

    increasing the cost to park may have ve eects

    on the behavior o drivers with dierent impli-

    cations or commuters, short-term drivers, and

    residents7:

    No mees mees Pies quadupled

    PART 2:

    cuen Sae of Suessful Pakingmanageen Saegies

    The main strategies or parking management all into our categories: pricing

    mechanisms, regulatory measures, physical design elements, and quality o

    service contracting (and the advanced technologies that enable these our).

    These can be employed in dierent combinations to achieve dierent eects,

    so the best practices ultimately depend on the goals o the city implementing

    the policy.1

    Gosveno

    Squae, London.

    Soue: trL4

  • 8/6/2019 European Parking U-Turn, ITDP

    13/84

    itdp.org | 13

    Find an alternative parking location

    Start their journey at another time

    Shift to another mode of transport

    Change their destination

    Avoid making the trip altogether

    The introduction o parking ees in Vienna led to a

    two-thirds drop in the vehicle kilometers traveled

    (rom ten to three million) resulting rom searches

    or an available space. Figure 1 compares parking

    ees in 11 city centers. An increase in the price o

    parking in o-street municipal acilities led to a

    30% dip in occupancy. At the same time, public

    transit and bike commuting increased, with 25%

    o car users switching modes.8

    A UK-based study compared the eect o parking

    restrictions and improved public transit on car

    use. Doubling parking ees reduced car usage by

    20%, while an increase in public transit requency

    was predicted to only decrease car use by a mea-

    ger 1 or 2%. Cutting the parking supply in hal led

    to a 30% drop in car use.9

    The price o parking linked to the number o

    available spaces infuences travel behavior in

    areas that have a high demand or parking. These

    Cost(Euros)

    Parking fee Cost increase

    20

    0

    0.5

    1

    1.5

    2

    2.5

    3

    Time (minutes)

    30 60 90 120

    Fge 2:mdd ble zne pgesse pkng hges

    Fge 1:Fs h pkng psns

    15-Minute Short-Term Parking in versailles

    Special devices designed by the French company

    AMCO have been installed along major commercial

    corridors in Versailles at individual parking spaces to

    control short-term 15minute ree parking between

    8 a.m. and 8 p.m. These spaces are meant or driv-

    ers making quick errands. Other French cities controlshort-term on-street parking using this device as

    well and can adjust the time. A red LED light begins

    to blink uriously to alert drivers and enorcement

    wardens that a vehicle has exceeded the allowable

    stay time. When the vehicle leaves, the light turns

    o. A magnetic detection wire is implanted under the

    parking space and connected to the blinking device.

    It is unclear i the cost o installing and maintaining

    the hardware justies its purpose. The same unction

    can be programmed into a pay-and-display machine

    or pay-by-phone service, especially since time limita-

    tions are harder to enorce than pricing mechanisms.

    city

    ased

    Lndn

    Skhl

    cpenhgen

    Ps

    Beln

    anwep

    mnh

    Hbg

    Ssbg

    venn

    city cENtEr FirSt Hour coSt (Es)

    5.00

    4.00

    3.87

    3.86

    3.60

    2.85

    2.50

    2.50

    2.00

    1.60

    1.20

  • 8/6/2019 European Parking U-Turn, ITDP

    14/84

    14 | Europes Parking U-Turn

    Rihmond-Upon-Thames c2-basedResidential Parking Permits

    Richmond-Upon-Thames, a leay and afuent borough

    in the Southwest o London, was the rst to issue resi-

    dential parking permits based on vehicle CO2

    emission

    levels, in 2007. Since then, the percentage o permits

    issued or the most emission-intensive cars has allen

    rom 16% to 13% and the amount issued to the lowestemission vehicles has increased rom 25% to 32%.10

    Richmond is also the rst borough to go one step ur-

    ther and charge or on-street and o-street metered

    parking based on vehicle emissions. Payments can

    be made using pay-by-phone services or by purchas-

    ing a pre-paid RichmondCard, which is debited every

    time a driver parks in a metered space. Under this

    scheme, the standard parking ee was increased by

    25% and drivers with cleaner vehicles could qualiy or

    a discount.

    As a way to gain support rom local businesses or

    the emission-based parking measures, the borough

    council came up with a proposal called 20:20 that al-

    lows drivers to park or 20 minutes on-street or only

    20 pencethus encouraging visitors to make shorterrands to local shops. Lower emission vehicles pay 10

    pence or the same amount o time.11

    In 2010, the new conservative government that took

    oce immediately abolished the CO2-based measure

    in Richmond-upon-Thames. Other boroughs still have

    their policies intact.

    BLuE DiScS

    cLEaN vEHicLES

    motorcycLES

    car SHariNG cLuBS

    DiSaBLED ParKiNG

    te-led fee spes e fen egled enllns n es sng he ble dss, wdel egnzedss Epe. Des s dspl he ds behnd he swndsheld ndng e f l. Sgn pss dspl hwlng pkng s peed sng he ble dss. the ple ln s p 90 nes.

    Skhl nd cpenhgen llw len ehles pkf fee s w enge phse f ele ehles hse wh lw essns. the lng-ew f hs seg sn ssnble sne ee f len ehles n sll hendesble nseqenessh s he need f pkngnfse he expense f he lnd se pssbles.

    Ps, Skhl, cpenhgen, nd ased llw -les pk f fee. the esl hs been plfen fzed w-wheeles, seen nll s bee lene pe ehle se. the bgh f Wesnse n Lndnnsed pd le pkng fe he plfen fw-wheeles bee pble wh dded ngesn,nse, nd plln.

    cpnes n ased nd he bgh f Wesnsen Lndn h n shng lbs e gen led, feen-see spe.

    Dsbled bdges llw fee pkng f n nled e. theenl Lndn egn ws exlded f he nnl ds-bled bdge shee, nsed ssng s wn shee. thesebdges e ssed b ll hes nd 70% f he essed (e.g., sed b fl ebe). the bdges n gesld f 2,000 n he blk ke. Se bdge hldesneed g befe pnel deene h he e leg-el dsbled, whle hes e eqed ge sgnedfd f ll d.

    Limited Free Parking

    Several policies exist across Europe

    that allow ree parking within zones

    that otherwise require payment. This

    is part o a theory that short-term er-

    rands should be enabled and the time

    o allowable ree parking should be

    limited, encouraging turnover.

  • 8/6/2019 European Parking U-Turn, ITDP

    15/84

    itdp.org | 15

    demands vary based on whether the area has a

    concentration of commercial, residential, indus-

    trial or other uses. A Controlled Parking Zone

    (CPZ) is a designated section of the city that can

    be as small as a block, or as large as an entire

    neighborhood. CPZs allow each council in Londonto determine what fees and regulations are ap-

    propriate to the local context, like setting the cost

    in a popular shopping district, in order to prevent

    all-day commuters from parking, while favoring

    short-term visitors, and businesses. Zurich and

    Munich use a similar approach with a block-by-

    block pricing designation that varies in cost based

    on location and time of day.

    Progressive charges

    Zurich, Antwerp, Vienna, and Madrid have on-

    street pricing schemes that charge a marginalcost increase with successive time to capture the

    increased marginal burden of a cars presence.

    Visitors to Madrid are allowed to park for a maxi-

    mum of two hours and the fee increases a mar-

    ginal amount following each time interval. Figure

    2 (previous spread) illustrates how the parking fee

    increases at a progressive rate.

    Residential Permits

    Spillover from central business districts (CBDs)

    into residential areas prompts the need for resi-

    dential parking permits. It is also a way to better

    manage the particular demands of residents,

    which differ from short-term visitor and commut-

    er parking. Residents in the Camden and Islington

    boroughs of London pay for residential parkingpermits based on their vehicles CO

    2emission

    standards that are assessed at the time of regis-

    trationthe most noxious cars pay a higher price.

    Residential parking permits in Munich helped

    reduce the share of car trips from 44% to 32%.

    Nearly 27% of car commuters switched to another

    mode of transport.12 Meanwhile, public transit

    ridership increased from 40% to 47%.13

    Workplae Levies

    Companies can be taxed for spaces providedat work sites. Municipalities across the UK are

    ready to charge up to 250 per year, as has been

    proposed in Nottingham beginning in 2012, for

    a parking space at a work site.14 The plan, gain-

    ing traction in many UK cities in recent months,

    would impact an estimated ten million drivers,

    as employers would likely pass down the cost

    imposed by local governments to employees.15

    construton of a 400-spae underground parkng

    falty wth resdental unts above, n the islands

    Brygge neghborhood of copenhagen, Denmark.

  • 8/6/2019 European Parking U-Turn, ITDP

    16/84

    16 | Europes Parking U-Turn

    A study done in Paris ound that given a scenario

    in which no workplace parking existed, 20% o

    drivers would walk or cycle instead, 20% would

    take public transit, 15% would car pool, 40% would

    search or ree spaces urther out, and 5% would

    be willing to pay or a spot. An estimated 75% ocommuters to the city center in the 2001 study

    had a parking space provided by an employer.16

    Earmarking/Ring Fening

    Barcelona, Strasbourg, Munich, and certain bor-

    oughs in London earmark revenue rom parking

    unds to support sustainable transport. Public

    support or parking charges can be won when the

    surplus unds are used to improve public transit,

    walking, or cycling conditions. In the London bor-

    ough o Kensington and Chelsea, 12% o parking

    revenue is used to und Freedom Passa programthat gives ree transit tickets to the elderly (60+)

    and disabled. In Barcelona, 100% o parking ees

    are used to support Bicingthe citys bike sharing

    program arranged as a public-private partnership

    with ClearChannel.

    REULATRY MEASURES

    Parking Supply caps

    Hamburg, Zurich,17 and Budapest have insti-

    tuted caps on the total parking supply in the city

    center, reorming the building codes to reeze the

    existing inventory and ban any urther increases.

    The Hamburg supply cap was instituted in 1976,

    sealing the inventory at roughly 30,000 spaces.

    Zurich instituted a cap in 1996. While commuters

    are mostly dissuaded rom driving into the central

    business district, some fexibility still exists or

    other types o uses, like delivery trucks. For every

    o-street space created within the capped area,

    an equal number o spaces must be removed romthe on-street supply. This type o a parking-based

    cap-and-trade allows the supply to stay constant

    while repurposing the on-street uses.

    In Copenhagen, this type o arrangement was

    used as political leverage to remove 1,000 on-

    street spaces or repurposing as bike and pedes-

    trian paths in exchange or the creation o 3,000

    o-street spaces built by a private developer. Car

    ownership in the city, especially in the areas im-

    mediately outside the municipal boundaries, has

    been increasing in the last decade, as it has all

    across Europe.

    Parking Maximums

    Some cities in Europe have recognized the need

    to institute parking maximums, creating ceil-

    ings or the amount o parking included in new

    developments. Cities like Zurich, Amsterdam, and

    Strasbourg are leading the way in this initiative

    while most other cities are still ollowing regula-

    tions or minimums based on antiquated build-

    ing codes that have not been updated in decades.

    Switzerland, the United Kingdom, and Italy set

    maximums as national guidelines. The Milan met-

    ropolitan area tailors national standards to the

    local context.

    Publi Transit Employee eneft Program

    Companies in Hamburg are required to provide less parking than is mandated by the citysminimum parking requirements i a signicant number o employees have public transit

    passes. The transit-pass benet program requires opt-in rom employees, whose payment is

    deducted rom a pre-tax salary.

    Some portion o the pass is also subsidized by the company. The parking spaces oered to

    those who still wish to commute by car may be accommodated o-site at a certain distance

    rom the company building.18

  • 8/6/2019 European Parking U-Turn, ITDP

    17/84

    itdp.org | 17

    Local jurisdictions in the UK are required to

    set maximums as a way to promote sustain-

    able transport choices, reduce the land-take o

    development, enable schemes to ft into central

    urban sites, promote linked-trips and access to

    development or those without use o a car, and to

    tackle congestion.19 For non-residential devel-

    opments, the policy goes urther and says that

    the maximum requirements should be set basedon what is locally appropriate to reduce the car

    use, promote cycling and walking, reduce carbon

    emissions, attain air quality standards, reduce

    sprawl, and meet other objectives.20 Despite the

    strong language, however, the requirements are

    not legally binding.

    The idea o requiring parking minimums is that

    new developments will generate driving trips and

    demand or parking. Requiring a minimum provi-

    sion is thought to transer the burden o creating

    new parking onto private developers. Yet orecast-

    ing or parking demand is not based on any well-studied algorithm. Most parking managers cannot

    explain the origin or rationale to parking require-

    ments or buildings, which orce opportunity

    costs onto developers who may preer to use the

    square meters or other purposes. In older historic

    districts, the regulations do not have as much

    o an impact because there is limited change to

    the buildings. In parts o the city where many

    new construction projects exist, the eects o

    the policy are palpable. Zurich has demonstrated

    with such projects as SihlCity that it is possible to

    regulate demand or parking by requiring devel-

    opments to promote visits by transit, biking, and

    walking trips while capping how many allowable

    car trips can be made to the site.

    Figure 3 shows how parking minimums vary be-

    tween cities or residential accessory parking.

    Hamburg may be an outlier in this case because

    o the amount o unregulated on-street space

    that exists in many districts immediately outside

    the CBD. Developers can also pay a ee in lieu o

    providing parkingto reduce development costs

    and encourage shared parkingand in act must

    do so in the CBD as a result o the citys parking

    cap. The in-lieu ee amounts to $20,705 per park-

    ing space in the city center, and $11,300 in the

    surrounding neighborhoods.21

    Stockholm has the lowest mandated provision

    o any city analyzed or this report. Developers

    there can ulfll parking requirements by fnding

    available spaces in nearby parking acilities with

    the assistance o Stockholm Parkering, the local

    parking authority. In act, the city requires them

    to do a scan o available spaces beore complying

    with the building code on parking.

    a Bng son n Belon n he G ds.

    city

    ased

    anwep

    Belon

    copenhgen

    Hbg

    mdd

    mnh

    Sokhol

    Ssbog

    venn

    miNimum rESiDENtiaL StaNDarDS

    1 spo/hosng n + 0.2 dded fo gess

    1.1 spos/dwellng n; 2 ble spos/dwellng n

    1 spo/26 pens (dependng on e)

    1 spo/100 sq. ees

    0.2/lng n n cBD, 0.8/lng n osde cBD

    1 spo/n

    1 spo/n

    0.14 spos/oo

    0.5 spos/pen f whn 500 ees of Pt,

    1 spo/pen ohewse

    1 spo/dwellng

    Fge 3:a opson of pkng ns n dozen es.

  • 8/6/2019 European Parking U-Turn, ITDP

    18/84

    18 | Europes Parking U-Turn

    In Madrid, which has the highest share o

    residential parking acilities in Europe (120,000

    acilities), owners o spaces in these car garages

    can lend them temporarily to visitors by way o

    controlled reservations. In the London borough

    o Westminster, on-street residential bays have

    also been opened up to visitors. And in Paris, an

    experiment has been underway since 2009 al-

    lowing residential vehicles to park overnight in

    loading zones. These shared space arrangements

    decrease the orecasted need to build more park-

    ing inrastructure.

    Parking requirements can be urther limited de-

    pending on public transit accessibility as has been

    done in Antwerp, Paris, Amsterdam, and Zurich.

    The Dutch A, B, C policy modies non-residential

    parking standards based on distance to a transit

    stopdevelopments closest to transit (at A loca-

    tions) are required to build limited parking while

    those near no transit access (at C locations) are

    encouraged to build more parking. In Paris, build-

    ing parking at new developments is orbidden 500

    meters rom a transit stopnearly every part o

    the inner city is within this distance.

    Regulatng te Loaton of Parkng

    Vehicles may be limited or banned altogether in

    pedestrian priority districts, except or delivery o

    goods during specic times o the day. Cars have

    been restricted or banned in many historic cen-

    ters and popular retail corridors. Barcelona has a

    trac cell in the Gracia District called the Super

    Manzanas project, which orces trac to move

    along the periphery o the zone that has been

    reprioritized or pedestrians and cyclistsspecial

    permissions may be granted or vehicles to park

    inside or short periods, but otherwise parking

    inside the zone is orbidden.

    Certain categories o vehicles are banned rom

    city centers based on their emission levels. This

    type o strategy is used in Berlin, London, Milan,

    and dozens o other cities. While not a parking-

    based strategy per se, the eect is that those

    vehicles with high emissions are not permitted to

    park in the city due to the specic driving pro-

    scription.

    PhYSicAL DESiS

    ollards

    Paris and Madrid have bollards installed through-

    out the city to prevent vehicles rom blocking

    pedestrian paths and encroaching on public pla-

    zas. Since 2001, Paris has invested approximately

    15 million to install nearly 335,000 bollards.

    Sometimes retractable bollards, vehicle-height-

    limiting bars, and other types o barricades are

    used to restrict street access, while giving emer-

    gency vehicles and delivery vans the fexibility to

    enter and park, i needed.

    Strped Lnes

    Stockholm has painted white lines demarcat-

    ing where parking is allowed on a given street,

    serving as a sot visual cue that organizes park-

    ing rom other unctional spaces such as pedes-

    trian paths, bike lanes, and moving trac lanes.

    Painted markers can also include words that limit

    demarcated spaces to specic userssuch as car-

    sharing club vehicles. The success o this type o

    installation is dependent on strong compliance

    and enorcement o parking rules.

    Repurposng Publ Spae

    Copenhagen started removing parking spaces

    rom the city center in the 1960s, especially along

    Strget Streetthe main car-ree retail corridor

    in the city. The total number o parking spaces

    in the inner city was reduced by 400 spaces rom

    3,100 to 2,720 between 1995 and 2000, through

    Bollards on a street in a residential neighborhood in the city

    center of madrid.

  • 8/6/2019 European Parking U-Turn, ITDP

    19/84

    itdp.org | 19

    small reductions over time, while the network o

    pedestrian areas increased by 4,020 m2 in roughly

    the same period.22

    Other compelling reasons or removing parking

    spaces include: the improvement o sightlines

    at intersections; decreasing crossing times or

    pedestrians by installing bulb-outs (sidewalk ex-

    pansions at crosswalks); greening the streetscape

    with tree plantings; expanding the space available

    to caes on narrow streets; and the addition o

    benches to encourage lingering. All these alterna-

    tive uses slowly decrease the overall parking sup-

    ply on the street, while improving the streetscape

    or other uses.

    Retailers are sometimes the loudest critics o

    restrictive parking policies, because they believe

    that the economic vitality o a city is linked to ac-cessibility by car. A study conducted in Rotterdam,

    The Netherlands, ound that retailers on one o

    the busiest shopping streets grossly overesti-

    mated the percentage o customers who arrive by

    car.23 Shops in a pedestrian zone where parking

    spaces have been wholly removed generate more

    income than those outside.24 In the most promi-

    nent pedestrianized shopping district in Munich,

    only 16% o people come by car, while 72% come

    by public transit. The remainder walk or bike.25

    Street space has been reclaimed throughout

    Europe, and treated as a public asset that can be

    used or more highly valued purposes. In France,

    most rst- and second-tier cities have built costly

    underground parking acilities to revitalize public

    squares that were once overwhelmed by parked

    cars. Reducing the on-street supply can be a way

    to encourage the use o other transportation

    modes and improve the local environment.26 The

    enlargement o the tram network in Strasbourg,

    France, or example, resulted in the relocation

    o on-street space to o-street acilities beneath

    pedestrianized streets, the building o park-and-

    ride acilities at the ends o tram lines and the

    expansion o paid parking zones. These measures

    refect a general attitude that took hold in many

    European cities and has been decades in the

    makingone where unquestioned support or in-

    creased parking demand shited toward the strict

    control o supply, especially near transit.

    Street geometry

    Where on-street spaces have not been removed,

    they can be organized in a way to meet street

    saety goals. In Zurich, alternating parking spaces

    on two sides o a narrow street act as a chicane

    that slows vehicle speeds. Amsterdam has zones

    called wooners that use parked cars to create a

    winding passage that orces vehicles to move at

    a slower pace alongside cyclists and pedestrians.

    Paris and Copenhagen have bike lanes protected

    by parked cars that act as a barrier between the

    cyclists and moving trac. Copenhagen and

    Antwerp have play-streets that allow children

    to saely spend time on their street while limit-

    ing the threat o getting hit by a carhere trees,

    benches, and other physical obstructions cue

    vehicles that they are guests in the space.

    QUALiTY F SERvicE cnTRAcTingAnD TEchnLgiES

    In Stockholm, many traditional government unc-

    tions have been contracted out to private com-

    panies. Urban planning and health department

    tasks are now handled by outside consultants.

    This type o public-private arrangement is espe-

    cially relevant or cities acing budget constraints.

    Single designated parking space on a street inStockholm.

  • 8/6/2019 European Parking U-Turn, ITDP

    20/84

    20 | Europes Parking U-Turn

    Stockholm managed to decrease the number o

    in-house sta. Remaining employees overseeprivate contracts, review delivered products and

    services as well as make sure contract agreements

    are kept on track. Two private security companies,

    or instance, handle parking enorcementone

    responsible or the northern part o the city and

    the other the southern portion. Both companies

    must meet certain perormance targets and their

    payment allocations can fuctuate based on de-

    livery o service. Parking wardens are expected to

    monitor a set number o parking spots during a

    shit. The companies are also evaluated based on

    the percentage o vehicles within compliance o

    parking ruleswith the ultimate goal o reaching

    100% compliance.

    Technological advancements in the last decade

    have allowed cities to meet parking-related goals

    more eectively. Private companies can better

    ulll contract terms or services oered to cities,

    such as parking enorcement and revenue col-

    lection, through data-supported assistance and

    monitoring. The latest hardware and sotware is

    also meant to improve the customer experience

    or drivers. Four technologies that enable better

    parking management are described.

    Electronic Parking uidance Systems

    Drivers can spend nearly 25% o their travel time

    searching or parking. Real-time message boards

    placed at specic locations along the roadway di-

    rect drivers to available parking spaces in nearby

    garages. Every major city in Germany uses these

    advanced parking guidance systems. The next

    wave o guidance technology will include in-car

    inormation delivery.

    Smart Meters

    These types o meters have magnetic elds ca-

    pable o registering the metal mass o vehicles.

    They have a direct computer link to a police sta-

    tion and send a signal to parking wardens when

    a vehicle is parked beyond the allowable time.

    Drivers also receive an alert text message on their

    mobile phones. These meters have been installed

    throughout France with much success.

    Pay-by-phone

    While paying or parking is still possible in many

    places using pre-paid cards, coins, or credit

    cards, pay-by-phone is increasingly the preerred

    payment collection method because the han-

    dling o money is outsourced to a third-party

    vendor, thereby eliminating any chance o thet.

    The London borough o Westminster was losing

    200,000 per week to thet beore going cash-

    less. The pay-by-phone company Verrus handles

    parking transactions and receives 10% o the

    revenue as compensation. In Stockholm, custom-ers pay a subscription ee to EasyPark o3 per

    month and a transaction ee o0.50. EasyPark

    receives 3% o all revenue collected as compensa-

    tion. The competing companies in Amsterdam

    Parkmobile, Parkline, and SMS Parkingget 4 to

    5% o revenue as compensation or their services.

    Cities that have yet to implement pricing mecha-

    nisms or parking can bypass some o the prob-

    lems associated with thet and spillage o parking

    a street within the

    Super mnzns

    zone in the Grci

    district, Brcelon,

    Spin.

  • 8/6/2019 European Parking U-Turn, ITDP

    21/84

    itdp.org | 21

    fee collection by starting with a pay-by-phone

    program. Pay-by-phone is also a good way to get

    political buy-in for introducing performance pric-

    ing because it makes parking so much easier for

    drivers, who dont need to look for coins or rush

    back to a meter when running late.

    San cars

    Enforcement of parking has been revolutionized

    in Amsterdam, where a van with six cameras

    mounted on topthree on each sidemoving at

    40 km per hour, takes more than 160 photos per

    second. The scans capture license plate numbers

    using Automated Number Plate Recognition tech-

    nology, to assess whether a car is parked legally.

    The vans have a 98% accuracy rate. The remaining

    2% is due to unrecognizable vehicles from outsideThe Netherlands. Three wardens on scooters fol-

    low the van to issue penalty tickets. Some of the

    central London boroughs use CCTV for enforce-

    ment activities.

    NotES oN Part 2

    1 rbe Jd e l. (1996). a ql nd bn spe nge-en, the Sene f he tl Ennen, 189/190, 57-67.

    2 rhel Wenbege e l (2010). u.S. Pkng Ples: an oeewf mngeen Seges, inse f tnspn ndDeelpen Pl.

    3 Pken celebes he Glden annes f he Pkng mee.aessed nlne Jl 2010. [urL: hp://www.pken./de/Pess-relese/Pken-elebes-he-glden-nnes-f-he-pkng-ee.hl].

    4 trL (tnsp reseh Lb), uK.

    5 Sn andesn nd and de Pl (2004). the ens fpng pkng, Jnl f ubn Ens. unes f vgn.vle 55, isse 1.

    6 ineew wh Lndn cnls, Sepebe 2009.

    7 Bend P. Feene (1989). a eew f he p f pkngpl eses n el dend, tnspn Plnnng ndtehnlg, 13(4), pp. 229_/244.

    8 Bndesnse f vekeh, innn nd tehnlge(2007). vekeh n Zhlen-asgbe, pp. 64-70. aessed nlne Jl2010. [urL: hp://www.b.g./ekeh/gesekeh/ss-k/dwnlds/z07_kp4.pdf].

    9 m. Dsgp e l. (1994). the ip f tnsp Ples n Feces, tnsp reseh Lb.

    10 co2 Bsed chges. aessed nlne ags, 2010.[urL: hp://www.hnd.lbdes.g.k/news/002936/2_bsed_pkng_hges.hl].

    11 co2 Essns Bsed Pkng n rhnd pn thes [urL:hp://www.hnd.g.k/2_essns_bsed_pkng_lef-le.pdf].

    12 H H. tpp (1994). Z rlle des Pkens n devekehsbehgng, Senekehsehnk, pp. 375-379.

    13 t re e l. (2006). Expnsn f cnlled Pkng Zne(cPZ) nd s inene n mdl Spl: the cse f Ednbgh,tnspn Plnnng nd tehnlg, 29 (1) pp 75 89.

    14 Dl ml repe. Des fng 250--e x pk wk despe pledge end w n ss Dl ml onlne.

    aessed nlne ags 2010. [urL: hp://www.dll..k/news/le-1305362/Des-fng-250-x-pk-wk-despe-end-w-ss-pledge.hl#xzz0xbWxyk].

    15 Jes tpseld (2010). Wkple pkng lees be psedb nls. the independen: uK. aessed nlne ags 2010.[urL: hp://www.ndependen..k/news/k/pls/wkple-pkng-lees--be-psed-b-nls-2059468.hl].

    16 W. yng e l. (1991). a eew f bn pkng dels,tnsp reews: 11 (1), 6384.

    17 Zh Hs cpse Pkng cp. aessed nlne obe2010. [urL: www.sd-zeh.h/pkplzkpss].

    18 ineew wh c f Hbg, Sepebe 2009.

    19 annex D: mx Pkng Sndds (2001). Plnnng PlGdne 13: tnsp Depen f cnes nd LlGenen. aessed nlne Sepebe 2010. [urL: hp://www.shfd.g.k/pdf/PPG%2013%20annex%20D.pdf].

    20 Depen f cnes nd Ll Genens (2009).Plnnng f Pspes Enes, Ec10.2 aessed nlneags 2010. [urL: hp://www.nes.g.k/dens/plnnngndbldng/pdf/pps4sespnses.pdf].

    21 Dnld Shp (1999). in Le f reqe Pkng, Jnl fPlnnng Edn nd reseh. assn f cllege Shlsf Plnnng: 18:307-320.

    22 Jn Gehl e l. (2006). New c Lfe. the Dnsh ahelPess: cpenhgen.

    23 Gln mngd e l. (2009). N pkng, sll bsness,vekeesknde, N. 4.

    24 cen Hss-Kl (1993). ip f pedesnzn nd flng n elng: a eew f he edene f Gen nd he

    uK, tnsp Pl, 1 (1), pp 21-31.

    25 rlf mnhe (2001). the rle f Pedesn Pens nhe Eln f Gen c cenes f Shppng ubnEnenen cenes, Pesened asl: Wlkng he 21scen, Peh, Wesen asl.

    26 GtZ (2010). Pkng mngeen: a cnbn twds Lbleces, Ssnble tnsp: a Sebk f Plkesn Deelpng ces. mdle 2c Dsn f We, Eneg ndtnsp.

  • 8/6/2019 European Parking U-Turn, ITDP

    22/84

    22 | Europes Parking U-Turn

    Pricing MechanismsCurbside Charges

    Progressive Fee Structure

    Off-Street Price Harmonization

    Residential Permits

    Workplace Levies

    Ring Fencing

    Regulatory Measures

    Supply Caps

    Minimums

    Maximums

    Transit Based Min/Max Reductions

    Access Bans

    Emissions Reduction Goals

    Public-Private Partnership

    Physical Designs

    Bollards

    Striped Lines

    Repurposing Public Space

    Advanced Technologies

    Electronic Parking Guidance Systems

    Smart Meters

    Pay-by-Phone

    Scan Cars

    x

    x

    x

    x

    x

    x

    x

    x

    x

    x

    x

    x

    x

    x

    x

    x

    x

    x

    x

    x

    x

    x

    x

    x

    x

    x

    x

    x

    x

    x

    x

    x

    x

    x

    x

    x

    x

    x

    x

    x

    x

    x

    x

    x

    x

    x

    x

    x

    x

    x

    x

    x

    x

    x

    x

    x

    x

    x

    x

    x

    x

    x

    x

    x

    x

    x

    x

    x

    x

    x

    x

    x

    x

    x

    x

    x

    x

    x

    x

    x

    x

    x

    Amste

    rdam

    Antw

    erp

    Barc

    elona

    Copenh

    agen

    Lond

    on

    Mun

    ich

    Paris

    Stockh

    olm

    Strasb

    ourg

    Zurich

    Figure 1:

    Poliies applied in European ities

    PART 3:

    case Studies

    This section will examine ten different cities based on the variety of measuresthey use to decrease vehicle kilometres travelled (VKT) and shift travel from

    car trips to other modes of transport. Figure 1 outlines which policy instru-

    ments have been applied in each city.

  • 8/6/2019 European Parking U-Turn, ITDP

    23/84

    itdp.org | 23

    Each case study city can be viewed as a prime application o the ollowing specifc strategies:

    AmsterdamNearly all license plates are digitized, allowing or enorcement to be handled using scan cars

    that rapidly photograph and assess whether a vehicle is compliant with parking rules.

    AntwerpA public-private partnership allows or parking to be managed more efciently.

    arelonaAll the revenue generated by parking ees pay or operation and maintenance o a bike-sharing

    scheme.

    copenhagenThousands o meters o street space have been pedestrianized over several decades with

    hundreds o car spaces removed.

    London

    Emission standards are recorded at the time o a vehicles registration and this has allowed

    several boroughs to charge CO2-based parking ees.

    MunihOverall restrictive policies with a goal o shiting away rom car trips has proven successul.

    ParisStreet space has been repurposed or bike sharing and tramways.

    StokholmEnorcement is outsourced to a couple private companies that better survey parked vehicles.

    Strasbourg

    Parking provision is dependent on distance and access to transit.

    ZurihExisting supply in the city center has been capped and allowable car trips generated by new

    developments are also capped.

  • 8/6/2019 European Parking U-Turn, ITDP

    24/84

    24 | Europes Parking U-Turn

    cASE STUDY:

    aserd, the Neherlnds

    ciTY ovERviEW

    Population: 758,198

    Population Density: 4,459/km2 (11,548.8/sq mi)

    Parking Supply: 211,457 (on-street: 181,457; o-street: ~30,000)

    Curbside Fees: Range is rom 0.90/hour up to 5.00/hour

    Total City Budget: 5-6 billion (parking: 140 million/ year)

    Car Ownership: 57.2% o households own a car (Total: 215,600 cars)

    Policy Goals: Emissions Reduction, Congestion Mitigation, Alternative Mode Promotion

    Approximately 40% of air pollution in Amsterdam

    is caused by 10% of cars. Parking ees were

    introduced to counter decades o car-centric

    policies and expanded most recently to tackle air

    quality issues triggered by EU directives regard-

    ing NO2 and PM10 emissions. The Dutch govern-

    ment chose to ollow the most rigid o the EU

    interpretations. Paid parking can be ound nearly

    everywhere in the pre-1940s parts o the city, and

    is rapidly spreading to newer areas. The eect o

    paid parking has been a 20% decrease in car tra-

    fc in the inner city as well as a 20% reduction in

    trafc searching or a space to park.

    Beore 1993, vehicle exhaust was not registered

    in any way. Now car plate numbers are registered

    with emissions inormation. Yet Amsterdam

    has not linked parking ees to vehicle emissions

    Figure 1:mp of

    P&D zones,

    aserd.

    Soure: ciy

    of aserd

  • 8/6/2019 European Parking U-Turn, ITDP

    25/84

    itdp.org | 25

    directly as has already been done by several

    boroughs in London. A parking authority is being

    established with 100% ownership by the govern-

    ment to better manage parking, issue parking per-

    mits, and communicate about changes in policy.

    Parking policy is still made by the city council.

    Pay-and-display (P&D) Parking

    Pay-and-display machines are gradually being

    replaced with license plate input technology.

    Approximately 3,000 P&D machines are used to

    handle payments. The cost o on-street park-

    ing ranges rom 0.90 per hour all the way up to

    5.00 per hour in the historical city center, which

    is amongst most expensive street parking in the

    world. Most o the on-street parking within the

    A10 ring road has a ee as do some areas outside

    the ring. Figure 1 shows all the pay zones.

    One o the newest pay zones, originally 90-cents-

    per-hour, was implemented in an outer borough

    that has a high on-street parking occupancy rate

    near a large shopping center. The ee has risen to

    1.10 per hour, and will increase to 1.30 in 2012.

    Blue zones are areas where parking is ree.

    blue Zones

    Parking spaces that accept the European parking

    disk, which is a time-limited short-term parking

    management tool, are in this zone. Any parking

    fne incurred in a blue zone goes to the ederal

    government, not the city. The city only collects

    fnes in P&D spaces.

    10-cent Zones

    The lowest ee or on-street short-term parking in

    the city is 10 cents per hour, with a time limit o

    one hour. 10-cent zones exist on certain shopping

    streets in non-central areas and near cemeter-

    ies. Currently, the only way to restrict immediate

    re-parking in the same spot is i a driver pays by

    mobile phone. Drivers are known to renew pay-

    ment or parking immediately.

    The nominal ee is the smallest amount that P&D

    machines will accept. By charging this small ee,

    the city can retain jurisdiction over these parking

    spaces. Otherwise, the fnes rom illegal parking

    would go to the ederal government because they

    would be in deault blue zones.

    Cars with residential permits are not allowed in

    the 10-cent zones rom 9 a.m. to about 7 p.m., giv-

    ing short-term parking priority.

    Residential Parking Permits

    A driver in Amsterdam has three options i

    they want to park in the central city: apply or a

    permit; rent space in a garage; or buy a parking

    space (general cost: 40,000). Owners o a private

    parking space oreit the chance to get a residen-

    tial permit. Residential permits cost up to 150.00

    annually and are in such high demand that a sev-

    eral year wait is usually required. Once obtained,

    a residential permit is only valid near a vehicle

    owners home. Drivers must still pay the P&D rate

    P&D ustoer pying for prk-

    ing spe.vn Swindenstrt is 10-cent Zone fro mondy to Sturdy

    between 9 ..7 p.. all other ties residentil perits nd isitor

    P&D fees re in effet.

  • 8/6/2019 European Parking U-Turn, ITDP

    26/84

    26 | Europes Parking U-Turn

    outside o their own neighborhoods. As o 2009,

    residential parking permits can be oreited in

    exchange or a one-year transit pass. This has no

    impact on the parking supply since the permit is

    simply transerred to another driver and the spot

    remains.

    City ocials determine how many on-street

    permits to issue by subtracting 10% rom the totalparking supply. New developments, usually in

    outer boroughs, have garages included with each

    apartment. I a parking spot is not secured at the

    time o purchase, a resident is ineligible to get an

    on-street permit.

    Disabled persons and delivery trucks get special

    parking permits too. Doctors have signs or their

    own designated spaces. Midwives get ree spots as

    well. A dierent ordinance applies or each case.

    car-sharing

    Permits or on-street car-sharing parking spots

    are issued just like residential permits, except

    the car-sharing companies get dedicated parking

    spaces. A car-sharing company must have at least

    ten cars in its feet to be recognized as legitimate.

    The city has made contractual provisions so that

    the car-sharing company must use the parking

    place.

    P&r wynding signge is ment to help deese

    uising fo pking spe.

    Figue 2:

    aBc lotion sheme fo pking inlusion in developments

    A

    B

    C

    Excellent public transitfacilities, surroundingmain train stations

    Good public transit and

    also good accessibilityby car

    Mainly well accessibleby car

    1 parking space/250 m2

    1 parking space/125 m2

    Tailor made, no norms

    Geen Wheels is one of the mny lubs in

    amstedm offeing - shing sevies to membes.

  • 8/6/2019 European Parking U-Turn, ITDP

    27/84

    itdp.org | 27

    ff-Street Parking Regulations

    Parking norms or housing can be determined on

    a project-to-project basis by the boroughs. There

    is a regulation in Amsterdam that or every spot

    created o-street, an on-street spot should be

    removed.

    The norms used include these maximums:0.6 spaces per social (public) housing unit

    1.0 space per normal housing unit, with 0.2 per

    house added or visitors

    Commercial acilities are dealt with by the mu-

    nicipal Location Policy 2008, also known as the

    ABC system. For acilities, the norms vary with

    dierent types o location, mostly congruent with

    the A, B, and C locations (see Figure 2).

    Park-and-ride (P&R)

    P&R acilities are located on the outskirts o the

    city. Drivers pay 6 to park and can get a 24-hour

    public transit pass or up to fve people. The stay

    can be extended with the same transit pass deal

    or 48 and 72 hours. This sends a clear message:

    people are welcome in the city center, but cars

    are not. In 2011 this ee will increase to 8, with a

    maximum transit pass or up to two people.

    Wayfnding signage helps drivers locate P&R

    acilities. The next generation o signage uses an

    integrated dynamic parking (IDP) system, a type o

    advanced parking guidance system (APGS) that is

    meant to direct drivers to available parking spaces

    and curtail excess VKT rom cruising. There is

    also a park-and-bike program. In lieu o a transit

    ticket, P&R users can borrow a city-owned bike or

    the whole day.

    Pay-by-phone

    Pay-by-phone service was introduced in

    Amsterdam around 2006. The city keeps a record

    o user inormation and sends bills based on what

    they gather rom the pay-by-phone providers.

    There are three private companies that the city

    contracts to handle the mobile phone payments

    in Amsterdam:

    Parkmobile

    Parkline

    SMS Parking

    These companies collect the revenues and then

    transer them to the city. The city pays a ee at

    a rate o 45% o the revenue or the services.

    Residential parking permits are 90% digitized.

    a typil volkswgen cddy mxi prking enfore-

    ent sn n.Prking wrden on sooter.

  • 8/6/2019 European Parking U-Turn, ITDP

    28/84

    28 | Europes Parking U-Turn

    Drivers will soon be able to pay or parking mostly

    by phone or internet.

    There has been some discussion about introduc-

    ing a national pay-by-phone system that would

    help lower the overall ee, allowing smaller

    municipalities to take advantage o this service as

    well. Dutch cities are leading an eort, in conjunc-

    tion with a private company, to implement such a

    national scheme.

    Parking Enforcement

    At the moment, parking enorcement is mostly

    managed by wardens who patrol the streets. The

    next generation uses a scan car and wardens

    on scooters. Designed by Abstract Computing

    International B.V. using a Volkswagen Caddy

    Maxi van, the car has six camerasthree on each

    sideand automatic license plate number rec-

    ognition technology to recognize illegal parkers.

    Driven at 40 kilometers per hour up and down the

    street, the car takes scans o the surroundings at

    a rate o over 160 scans per second.

    A small group o wardens ollow the car on scoot-

    ers and issue tickets or violations. This system

    is twice as ecient as the old one. The scan car

    system has a 98% accuracy rate, although some

    parked cars, mostly oreign vehicles, must be

    checked manually.

    Parking Revenues

    Every borough in Amsterdam has a contract with

    Cition, a company owned by the municipality.

    Cition gets a ne i it does not collect P&D ees

    rom visitors. Parking revenues go back into inra-

    structure projects. These projects must be part o

    the citywide mobility scheme, not just within the

    borough where it happens to be collected. There

    is a parking und, but the money can be used in

    many fexible ways, even to nance kindergartens.

    The parking und comes rom P&D ees, penalty

    nes, and permit revenues. Every borough is re-

    quired to give about 30% o its parking revenue to

    the municipal government.

    The ne or a parking violation in a paid spot is

    always 50.90 plus the price o one-hour parking

    (max 5). This applies even i the car is parked or

    ten hours in one spot having only paid or one

    hour. The maximum parking ne, 150, is reserved

    or parking in a handicapped spot.

    Trucks and Freight

    All trucks over three-and-a-hal tons need to com-

    ply with stringent air quality norms. Most trucks

    older than seven or eight years will not be allowed

    into the city. Trucks can unload or a maximum o

    15 minutes in spots where they are not allowed to

    park. Loading and unloading must be done beore

    10 a.m. or 11 a.m., depending on the street, and

    then the trucks need to exit the city.

    a woonerf with perpendiculr prking rrnged to clm the

    street, giving priority to pedestrins nd bicyclists.a truck driver prks on nrrow rod nd quickly

    unlods goods on before 9:30 .m.

  • 8/6/2019 European Parking U-Turn, ITDP

    29/84

    itdp.org | 29

    Fuel-Efcent vehcle incentes

    There is a debate over whether to reduce the

    parking permit ees or electric cars, small and

    clean cars, or any environmentally upgraded vehi-

    cles. For this to be possible, national policies need

    to change to veriy uel efciency o vehicles by

    license plate number. Parking permits will only go

    to clean or electric cars. By 2012, nearly 200 elec-

    tric charge points across the city are expected to

    supply power by the renewable energy frm Nuon.

    I this happens, the city will need to simultane-

    ously reduce the number o other parking permits

    issued. Electric cars can help improve air quality,

    but not energy efciency or saety, and they still

    require parking spaces.

    Street Desgn

    Amsterdam has several streets that use park-

    ing orientation to create saer environments or

    bicycle users and pedestrians. A wooner in the

    borough o Westerpark includes perpendicular

    parking to create a quasi-chicane. Motorists must

    give priority to people on bikes and walking whenmoving through the space. Other streets use

    parallel parking to protect the bike lane, which is

    segregated rom the pedestrian space by a curb,

    and rom the parking lane with a curb on the

    other side. The curb closer to the parking lane acts

    as a buer, preventing collisions between cyclists

    and car doors opening into the bike lane.

    the pkng lne s desgned pe he bke lnef he ng f lne.

    SourcES For amStErDam

    abs cpng inennl B.v. aessed nlne Jly, 2009(urL: hp://www.bspng.nl/).

    cle chelle (2002). a beh f fesh F Shee.tnsp nd Ennen (t&E).

    clles inennl, Glbl cBD Pkng re Sey 2009.aessed nlne Jny, 2010 (urL: hp://www.lles./nen/glblllespkngesey2009.pdf).

    Dn Jnes (Feby 2010). ased bsnesses ge 3 fele .

    Pwe nd Enegy. GDS Pblshng Ld. aessed nlneDeebe 1, 2010. (urL: hp://www.ngpwee./news/sed-ele-s/).

    ineew wh mledefense, Fends f he Eh Nehelnds,Jly 2009.

    ineew wh cy Sellne See (Dens Sdsezh),Jly 2009.

    ineew wh cy f ased, Jly 2009.

    ineew wh Erys reseh nd cnslng, Jly 2009.

    Pkng Ply n ased (NL) F Shee, Pllnredn opns Newk (PNe). aessed nlne Deebe1, 2010. (urL: hp://www.wel.nw.de/wel/pdf/pne/fshees/13.pdf).

    vs pkng pl f ased ased.aessednlne Jly, 2009. (urL:hp://www.sed./en/sng/snfn/gengnd/pkng/pkngnsed).

    Wll Lse (Jne 2009). c Shng Sn n Pbl SeeSpe inellgen Enegy Epe. m Pje. c Shng Fshee N. 6. aessed nlne Jly 2009. (urL: hp://www.p.g/pdf/fshee6esnsnpblspe.pdf).

  • 8/6/2019 European Parking U-Turn, ITDP

    30/84

    30 | Europes Parking U-Turn

    cASE STUDY:

    antwerp, Belgiu

    ciTY vERviEWPopulation: 360,000

    Population Density: 2,308 inhabitants per km

    Parking Supply: 38,318 inner city on-street, 93,516 outer city on-street; 11,280 o-street

    Curbside Fees: Range is rom 0.50/hour up to 3.50/hour, depending on zone

    and duration

    Policy Goals: Optimal Curbside Visitor Turnover, Prioritized Residential Parking,

    Congestion Mitigation, Alternative Mode Promotion

    Antwerp, Belgium is using parking as a means

    of limiting car use in the city center. The citys

    goal is to create higher turnover at the curb

    for visitors, while accommodating residential

    parking needs. All parking is managed through

    a semi-private parking authority, Gemeentelijk

    Autonoom Parkeerbedrij AntwerpenMunicipal

    Autonomous Parking Antwerpor GAPA.

    Emphasis has been placed on pricing, enorce-

    ment, and the use o technology to reach the

    parking programs goals. In the summer o 2011,

    Antwerp is planning to launch a bike-sharing pro-

    gram, nancially modeled ater Barcelonas, using

    revenue collected rom the parking programs.

    Parking nes are currently invested into mobility

    projects in the city.

    Parkng Authorty as Publ Prate Partnershp

    The City Council ounded GAPA in 2001 in a pub-

    lic-private partnership (PPP), transerring all exist-

    ing parking-related contracts to GAPA and givingGAPA ull authority to manage, oversee, and

    control all on-street and publicly-owned o-street

    acilities. GAPA is allowed to build and manage

    new o-street lots. In return, GAPA is expected to

    cooperate with other o-street parking operators,

    enorce parking regulations, prepare parking poli-

    cies, and pay personnel and operational costs or

    enorcement. All revenues are collected through

    a special escrow account.

    There are many benets to running a parking

    authority through a PPP. The contract encour-

    ages and allows GAPA to be innovative by using

    technology or enorcement and data-collection

    needs. GAPA, unlike the city, is also more fex-

    ible in their ability to negotiate work agreements

    with employees. It is also in GAPAs best interest

    Figure 1:

    mp of three antwerp P&D zones. Source: GaPa

  • 8/6/2019 European Parking U-Turn, ITDP

    31/84

    itdp.org | 31

    to charge the highest easible price or parking,

    thereby regulating the number o cars in the cen-

    ter city, even i political pressures and city council

    approval o parking ees do nevertheless suppress

    parking prices slightly below market value.

    Pay-and-display Parking

    Antwerp is divided into three P&D zones (red,

    dark green, and light green) ranging rom most

    to least expensive respectively (Figure 1). Parking

    ees range rom 0.50 to 3.50 per hour, depend-

    ing on the zone and the duration o stay (Figure 4).

    The number o paid on-street parking spots has

    increased rom 9,500 in December 2003 to 14,460

    in March 2005. GAPA has doubled its number o

    P&D machines between 2003 and 2006 rom 500

    to 1,000.

    The fne or nonpayment or overstaying is 23.

    Enforcement and Parking Revenue

    GAPA has enjoyed a steady increase in revenue

    rom the P&D machines (Figure 2). To improve

    compliance, both auxiliary police and parking

    wardens o GAPA work on enorcement. Figure

    3 shows how compliance levels increased along

    with enorcement. Red represents income rom

    fnes and blue represents income rom the P&D

    machines.

    2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009

    0%

    10%

    20%

    30%

    40%

    60%

    50%

    80%

    90%

    100%

    70%

    Income Fines Income P&D Machines

    Figue 4:on-see pking su fee suue

    Ds

    vlid ties

    Line tiff

    Pgessie tiff

    D tike

    mx. PkingDuin

    ceil re

    Blue Zne

    rED ZoNE(cenl Sin & cBD)

    mn S

    9 .. 10 p..

    1.50/2.50/3.50 pe hu

    N pplible

    3 hus

    23/12hus

    N pplible

    GrEEN ZoNE(wihin single sei-ing d)

    mn S

    9 10 p..

    0.60/1.00/hu

    3.50/10hus (n n shppingsees when hee is n ff-see pking fili neb)

    10 hus

    23/12hus

    resied suppl

    yELLoW ZoNE(uside single sei-ing d)

    mn S

    9 10 p..

    0.50/hu

    0.50/hu

    2.50/10 hus (n n shpping sees when hee is n ff-see pking filineb)

    10 hus

    23/12hus

    Pssible

    Year

    Amount(inEuros)

    2001 2002 2003

    5 000 000

    4 500 000

    4 000 000

    3 500 000

    3 000 000

    2 500 000

    2 000 000

    1 500 000

    1 000 000

    500 000

    0

    1 2 3 4

    Figue 2:reenue f P&D hines (20012003)

    Figue 3:Pking ine bekdwn (%). Sue: GaPa

  • 8/6/2019 European Parking U-Turn, ITDP

    32/84

    32 | Europes Parking U-Turn

    P&D Technology and Payment ptions

    Customers can choose rom our dierent types

    o payment methods: coins, SMS, pay-by-phone

    and Smart Card. P&D machines only accept coins

    and do not accept bills. The frst ten minutes o

    SMS and pay-by-phone parking is ree; the frst 15

    minutes o Smart Card parking is ree.

    The company Mobile-or (www.4411.be) has been

    operating SMS parking in Antwerp since 2004.

    Customers who are registered online can send an

    SMS to a special number located on the side o a

    P&D machine with their vehicle plate number and

    a code. A confrmation SMS is then sent in return.

    Each SMS sent and received costs 0.15.

    Customers can view their parking history, billing,

    and settings online. Since the summer o 2009there has been a GAPA-owned o-street parking

    lot at the National Bank that allows SMS parking.

    Another payment option, oered by the company

    Park Line, allows customers to make a call rom

    their mobile phone to start and end a parking ses-

    sion. There is a one-time ee o10, and a monthly

    charge o1.75.

    Customers have the option o buying a personal

    electronic parking meter called a Smart Park. The

    device is hung in the rearview mirror and elimi-

    nates the need to go searching or the nearest

    P&D machine. Inserting a rechargeable card into

    the device activates the system. It is possible to

    preset the device so that it only runs during paid

    parking times. The frst ten minutes is always

    ree. A new starter kit costs 116.50 and reload-

    able cards cost 50. This technology is ideal or

    employees who must drive a lot and who do not

    want to pay out-o-pocket or parking.

    Residential Parking Permits

    Each household living in a paid or blue parkingzone is entitled to two ree residential park-

    ing permits. In partnership with the company

    Mobile-or, the distribution and control o resident

    permits are digitalized and issued through a new

    internet-based sotware application. This allows

    GAPA to better control how many residents have

    a permit, and it reduces paper use. In 2009, 32,510

    resident permits were issued; each is valid or two

    years. There were approximately 70,000 resident

    permits in circulation at the end o 2010. The

    parking zones overlap so that residents are notrequired to walk more than 200 meters between

    zones. Residents can select the zone where they

    want their parking permit to be valid.

    The digitized licensing system allows or efcient

    parking control. When a car has paid through

    SMS parking, the parking attendants can check

    through their hand-held computer terminals us-

    ing the license plate o the car. Resident permits

    are placed in the windshield and must be checked

    manually by the attendants.

    ff-Street Parking Regulations

    In order or GAPA to manage privately owned o-

    street parking acilities, quality standards have

    been developed. GAPA is able to enorce these

    standards by closing down non-complying ga-

    rages, or converting them to resident- or subscrip-

    tion-only garages.

    Figure 5 summarizes the building code or car and

    bicycle parking.

    By the end of 2007, 15% of ll prking trnsctionswere pid for by mobile phone. Source: GaPa

    Smrt Prkelectronic prkingmeter (with crdreder) for indi-vidul crs.Source: GaPa

  • 8/6/2019 European Parking U-Turn, ITDP

    33/84

    itdp.org | 33

    Shared Use of Private Parking Spots

    To improve the efcient use o parking spaces,

    GAPA is working on a scheme to bring privately

    owned parking lots into public use in the eve-

    nings, when privately owned lots, like those at su-

    permarkets and ofce parks, are typically unused.

    GAPA believes that they are in a better position

    than public companies to negotiate with private

    owners to allow or shared space o privately-

    owned parking lots because they are able to oer

    technical assistance and subsidies or technical

    modifcations.

    GAPA is oering the ollowing services to acili-

    tate shared parking spaces:

    Arranging or residents to get reduced rates Drating model contracts or owners and users Providing an online platorm where parking

    spaces can be rented or put up or rent

    Subsidizing a private car park or the subscrip-tion o residents on the condition that they give

    up their on-street resident parking permit

    Facilitating private initiatives or the building onearby parking lots

    Oering bicycle parking on private parking lotsthat can be used by the public

    car Sharing

    GAPA reserves parking spots or car sharing in

    parking zones where parking time is limited.

    Residents who live within 200 meters o a parked

    car and who are car-sharing members receive the

    equivalent o a residential permit so that they can

    park car-sharing vehicles near the house.

    The citys modal share or commutersa popula-tion that tends to park the whole dayshows a

    trend toward more public transit and non-motor-

    ized transport. In the time peri