exploiting new market opportunities in telecommunications...101 -privatization in tunisia, jamal...

36
CFS Discussion Paper Series, Number 110 Exploiting New Market Opportunities in Telecommunications Lessons fior Developing Coulntries Veronique Bishop Ashoka Mody Mark Schankerman Cofinancing and Financial Advisory Services (Project Financing Group) July 1995 21 The World Bank - Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized

Upload: others

Post on 02-Oct-2020

2 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Exploiting New Market Opportunities in Telecommunications...101 -Privatization in Tunisia, Jamal Saghir, 1993. 102 -Export Credits: Review and Prospects, Waman S. Tambe, Ning S. Zhu,

CFS Discussion Paper Series, Number 110

Exploiting New MarketOpportunities inTelecommunications

Lessons fior Developing Coulntries

Veronique BishopAshoka ModyMark Schankerman

Cofinancing and Financial Advisory Services (Project Financing Group)July 1995

21 The World Bank -

Pub

lic D

iscl

osur

e A

utho

rized

Pub

lic D

iscl

osur

e A

utho

rized

Pub

lic D

iscl

osur

e A

utho

rized

Pub

lic D

iscl

osur

e A

utho

rized

Pub

lic D

iscl

osur

e A

utho

rized

Pub

lic D

iscl

osur

e A

utho

rized

Pub

lic D

iscl

osur

e A

utho

rized

Pub

lic D

iscl

osur

e A

utho

rized

Page 2: Exploiting New Market Opportunities in Telecommunications...101 -Privatization in Tunisia, Jamal Saghir, 1993. 102 -Export Credits: Review and Prospects, Waman S. Tambe, Ning S. Zhu,

CFS DISCUSSION PAPERS

101 - Privatization in Tunisia, Jamal Saghir, 1993.

102 - Export Credits: Review and Prospects, Waman S. Tambe, Ning S. Zhu, 1993.

103 - Argentinas Privatization Program, Myrna Alexander, Carlos Corti, 1993.

104 - Eastern European Experience with Small-Scale Privatization: A Collaborative Study with the Central European Univer-sity Privatization Project, 1994.

105 - Japans Main Bank System and the Role of the Banking System in TSEs, Satoshi Sunumura, 1994.

106 - Selling State Companies to Strategic Investors: Trade Sale Privatizations in Poland, Hungary, the Czech Republic, and theSlovak Republic, Volumes I and 2, Susan L. Rutledge, 1995.

107 - Japanese National Railways Privatization Study II: Institutionalizing Major Policy Change and Examining EconomicImplications, Koichiro Fukui, Kiyoshi Nakamura, Tsutomu Ozaki, Hiroshi Sakmaki, Fumitoshi Mizutani, 1994.

108 - Management Contracts: A Review of International Experience, Hafeez Shaikh, Maziar Minovi, 1995.

109 - Commercial Real Estate Market Development in Russia, April L. Harding, 1995.

JOINT DISCUSSION PAPERS

Privatization in the Republics of the Former Soviet Union: Framework and Initial Results, Soo J. Im, Robert Jalali, JamalSaghir; PSD Group, Legal Department and PSD and Privatization Group, CFS - Joint Staff Discussion Paper, 1993.

MobilizingPrivate Capitalfor the Power Sector. Experience inAsia and LatinAmerica, David Baughman, Matthew Buresch;Joint World Bank-USAID Discussion Paper, 1994.

OTHER CFS PUBLICATIONS

Japanese National Railways Privatization Study, World Bank Discussion Paper, Number 172, 1992.

Nippon Telephone and Telegraph Privatization Study, World Bank Discussion Paper, Number 179, 1993.

Beyond Syndicated Loans, World Bank Technical Paper, Number 163, 1992.

CFS Link, Quarterly Newsletter.

Copyright( 1995The World Bank1818 H Street, N.W.Washington, D.C. 20433, U.S.A.

All rights reservedManufactured and printed in the United States of AmericaFirst printing, July 1995

The findings, interpretations, and conclusions expressed herein are entirely those of the authors and should notbe attributed in any manner to CFS, the World Bank, or to members of the Board of Executive Directors or the countriesthey represent. The World Bank does not guarantee the accuracy of the data included in this publication, and accepts noresponsibility whatsoever for any consequence of their use. The paper and any part thereof may not be cited or quotedwithout the author's expressed written consent.

Page 3: Exploiting New Market Opportunities in Telecommunications...101 -Privatization in Tunisia, Jamal Saghir, 1993. 102 -Export Credits: Review and Prospects, Waman S. Tambe, Ning S. Zhu,

CFS Discussion Paper Series, Number 1 10

Exploiting New Market Opportunitiesin

Telecommunications

Lessons for Developing Countries

Veronique BishopAshoka Mody

Mark Schankerman

For additional copies, please contact the CFS Information Office, tel: (202) 473-7594, fax: (202) 477-3045.

Page 4: Exploiting New Market Opportunities in Telecommunications...101 -Privatization in Tunisia, Jamal Saghir, 1993. 102 -Export Credits: Review and Prospects, Waman S. Tambe, Ning S. Zhu,
Page 5: Exploiting New Market Opportunities in Telecommunications...101 -Privatization in Tunisia, Jamal Saghir, 1993. 102 -Export Credits: Review and Prospects, Waman S. Tambe, Ning S. Zhu,

TABLE OF CONTENTS

List of Tables, Figures and Boxes iiiAcknowledgments iv

Foreword v

Exploiting New Market Opportunities in Telecommunications:Lessons for Developing Countries - Abstract 1

Overview 1

The Supply-Demand Gap 3Evidence of Suppressed Demand 3The Magnitude of Suppressed Demand 4The Transition from Old Ways to New 5Enterprise Restructuring 6Corporatization and Decentralization 6Privatization of the Government-Monopoly Operator 7Contracting Out: The Thai Example 8

Bringing in Competition 9Do Natural Monopolies Exist? 9Ways to Unbundle 9Competition: Possibilities and Implications 10Competition: An Assessment 13

Regulatory Reform 13Rate Rebalancing 13Consumer Pricing Rules 14Interconnection Pricing 15Making the Regulatory Transition 17

Political Economy of Reform 18Creating New Constituencies 19Labor Acceptance of Reform 19

Looking Ahead 20

References 21

EXPLOITING NEw MARKET OPPORTUNITIES IN TELECOMUNICATIONS

Page 6: Exploiting New Market Opportunities in Telecommunications...101 -Privatization in Tunisia, Jamal Saghir, 1993. 102 -Export Credits: Review and Prospects, Waman S. Tambe, Ning S. Zhu,

LIST OF TABLES, FIGURES AND BoxEs

Tables1. Annual Telecom Investment Requirements for Developing Countries ............. .............6

Figures1. Direction of Liberalization of the Telecommunications Sector .................... ..................22. GNP vs. Main Line per Capita, 1983 & 1992, Low to Middle Income Countries ....... 33. Waiting Lists as a Percentage of Main Lines ................................................ 4.........44. India and Chile: Wait Lists and Main Lines

Boxes1. China Introduces Competition ........................... 112. Long-Distance Competition in Mexico .......................... 123. Interconnection in Poland ................. , 1 64. Legal Test of Efficient Components Pricing ............... ........................... 175. Unbundling the Government's Role in Mexico and Malaysia ...................................... 18

LESSONS FOR DEVELOPING COUNTRIES iii

Page 7: Exploiting New Market Opportunities in Telecommunications...101 -Privatization in Tunisia, Jamal Saghir, 1993. 102 -Export Credits: Review and Prospects, Waman S. Tambe, Ning S. Zhu,

ACKNOWLEDGMENTS

The authors acknowledge with gratitude the help received from numerous public officials and experts on the telecommu-nications policy, including Henry Ergas, David Sappington, and in particular, Hugh Lantzke and Robert Bruce.

iv EXPLOrING NEW MARKET OPPORTUNITIES IN TELECOMUNICATIONS

Page 8: Exploiting New Market Opportunities in Telecommunications...101 -Privatization in Tunisia, Jamal Saghir, 1993. 102 -Export Credits: Review and Prospects, Waman S. Tambe, Ning S. Zhu,
Page 9: Exploiting New Market Opportunities in Telecommunications...101 -Privatization in Tunisia, Jamal Saghir, 1993. 102 -Export Credits: Review and Prospects, Waman S. Tambe, Ning S. Zhu,

FopuEwoRD

Developing countries are in transition from telecommunications monopolies to multiple providers that compete with andcomplement each other. The transition stems from a huge suppressed demand for telecommunications, a dissatisfactionwith traditional state-owned monopolies, and an unprecedented range of technological opportunities. The promise of apluralistic market structure is great and may represent the only realistic hope of more than doubling telecommunicationsinvestments in the developing world to over $60 billion a year, conservatively estimated to meet unfulfilled and growingdemands for conventional and new services.

However, for the promise of technological opportunities to be realized, interlocking measures will be needed to: (a)render incumbent providers more commercially oriented and subject to the same basic rules as other providers; (b) createa regulatory environment that provides incentives for efficient investment, protects consumers, and ensures fair competi-tion; and (c) sensitively manage conflicting interests during the period of transition, especially in addressing the concerns oftraditional telecommunications workers. Thus, the successful transition to a competitive structure follows not merely fromtechnological developments that have reduced the economic benefits of large-sized operations but it follows also, andmore importantly, from coordinated institutional reforms.

In most countries, telecommunications services have traditionally been delivered by a single, government-owned pro-vider. Such state-owned monopolies have only rarely mobilized significant amounts of capital for the telecom network, andeven in those instances have a poor record of responding to the evolving and varied needs of businesses and households. Asa consequence of their past failures and abetted by technological change, monopolies are giving way to a heterogeneousstructure where competition exists in numerous market segments. Countries undertaking reform show restructuring of thegovernment-owned monopoly operator and regulatory reform occurring in tandem.

Promoting competition requires liberal market entry rules. In particular, to encourage entry by providers who maywish to supply only specific services, traditional cross-subsidization across services needs to be eliminated, which in turnmay require sectoral unbundling. Such unbundling may occur through physical separation of assets and operations; often,however, an accounting separation, as between network and retail services, can go a long way in facilitating competition.The longer-term regulatory task is to implement pricing rules that protect customers and provide incentives to operators toreduce their costs. At the same time, a regulator in a pluralistic regime must establish rules and prices for the interconnec-tion of the multiple networks-and this practice is still evolving.

Although the benefits of reform are often evident, the pace of change can be slowed by incumbent interests andexperience shows that sectoral reform has to be led by forces outside the traditional sectoral establishment. For example,established interests often invoke, in a self-serving manner, the potential displacement of workers as a reason for holdingback. In practice, this tactic has been undermined by a variety of measures that have successfully mitigated the potentiallynegative effects on workers.

This paper is about policy reform in a complex sector, where not only the physical network elements but also theinstitutional aspects are interedependent on each other. In dealing with these interlocking elements, our coverage is neces-sarily broad rather than deep. The aim is to provide an account of links between different aspects of the reform process,entailing a sacrifice in the extent to which specific issues can be probed.

This paper was prepared as part of the CFS Discussion Paper Series. The purpose of the Discussion Paper Series is todisseminate current practices and the lessons learned in privatization and private sector related activities. As a Departmentthat covers all the World Bank's borrowing countries, Cofinancing and Financial Advisory Services (CFS) endeavors toshare with outside readers some of its cross-country experience in privatization. We are pleased to present this interna-tional review of telecommunications opportunities and hope it will contribute to the debate on the appropriate choice ofinstruments for privatization and public enterprise reform.

Ram Kumar Chopra Nina ShapiroDirector Manager

Cofinancing and Financial Advisory Services Project Finance Group(CFS) (CFSPS)

LESSONS FOR DEVELOPING COUNTRIES V

Page 10: Exploiting New Market Opportunities in Telecommunications...101 -Privatization in Tunisia, Jamal Saghir, 1993. 102 -Export Credits: Review and Prospects, Waman S. Tambe, Ning S. Zhu,

vi EXPLOITING NEW MARKET OPPORTUNITIES IN TELECOMUNICATIONS

Page 11: Exploiting New Market Opportunities in Telecommunications...101 -Privatization in Tunisia, Jamal Saghir, 1993. 102 -Export Credits: Review and Prospects, Waman S. Tambe, Ning S. Zhu,

EXPLOITING NEW MARKET

OPPORTUNITIES IN TELECOMMUNICATIONS

LESSONS FOR DEVELOPING COUNTRIES

OVERVIEW since prospective users do not register on waiting lists untilStemming from a huge suppressed demand for telecom- there is a realistic chance of receiving a phone connection.munications, a dissatisfaction with traditional state-owned Countries undertaking reform show restructuring of themonopolies, and unprecedented technological opportuni- government-owned monopoly operator and regulatory re-ties, an increasing number of developing countries are form occurring in tandem. Revitalizing the incumbent, typi-embarking upon a transition to a system of multiple tele- cally the government-owned monopoly, is undertaken forcommunications providers-competing with and social and commercial goals. Social objectives include thecomplementing each other. The promise of a pluralistic preservation of the government's financial assets and pro-market structure is great and may represent the only real- tection of the interests of workers in such enterprises.istic hope of more than doubling telecommunications in- However, to aid the process of sectoral reform, the incum-vestments in the developing world to over $60 billion a bent operator's incentives need to be reoriented towardsyear, conservatively required to meet existing, unfulfilled commercial goals through corporatization, decentralizationdemands as well as the growing demand for conventional of activities into profit centers, and, finally, privatization.and new services. However, for the promise to be real- Beyond restructuring lies competition. As a conse-ized, measures will be needed to: (a) render incumbent quence of their past failures and abetted by technologicalproviders more commercially oriented and subject to the change, monopolies are giving way to a heterogeneoussame basic rules as other providers; (b) create a regulatory structure where competition exists in numerous market seg-environment that provides incentives for efficient invest- ments (Figure 1). Today, competitive entry is possible inment, protects consumers, and ensures fair competition; all segments of the sector. While competition is best es-and (c) sensitively manage conflicting interests during the tablished in domestic long-distance services, the cartel lim-period of transition, dealing especially with the concerns iting competition in international services is being deci-of traditional telecommunications workers. sively broken, and the local loop providing the link from

Thus, the successful transition to a competitive struc- the ultimate user to the network-and the last bastion ofture follows not merely from technological developments monopoly-is also witnessing growing competition. Pro-that have reduced the economic benefits of large sized op- moting such competition requires liberal market entry rules.erations but it follows also, and more importantly, from In particular, to prevent cross-subsidization across services,institutional innovation. The good news is that institutional and hence promote entry by new providers who may wishchange is possible-as this paper documents based on ex- to supply only specific services, the sector needs to be un-amples of successful reform in select countries. Though bundled. Such unbundling may occur by requiring physi-much of the experience to date comes from industrialized cal separation of assets and operations; often, however, ancountries, several developing countries have undertaken accounting separation, as between network and retail ser-varying degrees of sector reform, addressing their own spe- vices, can go a long way in facilitating competition.cial problems but also adapting lessons learned in advanced The further task is to build new policy and regulatoryeconomies. Institutional innovations can spread across in- structures to ensure fair competition. First, a number ofternational borders with remarkable speed. transitional objectives must be achieved. Old rate struc-

In most countries, telecommunications services have tures that embed large cross-subsidies have to be phasedtraditionally been delivered by a single, government-owned out and replaced with new ones more conducive to com-provider. Such state-owned monopolies have rarely mobi- petition. During the transition, the incumbent operatorlized significant amounts of capital for the telecommuni- maintains a dominating position and thus can prevent faircations network, and even in those instances have a poor competition; however, the incumbent is also saddled withrecord of responding to the evolving and varied needs of service obligations that new entrants often do not have,businesses and households. Large waiting lists are evident, requiring transitional compensation. The longer-term regu-especially in low income countries. Moreover, a sizable latory task is to implement pricing rules that protect cus-latent demand lies concealed in most developing countries tomers and provide incentives to operators to reduce their

Page 12: Exploiting New Market Opportunities in Telecommunications...101 -Privatization in Tunisia, Jamal Saghir, 1993. 102 -Export Credits: Review and Prospects, Waman S. Tambe, Ning S. Zhu,

DIRECTION OF LIBERALIZATION OF THE TELECOMMUNICATIONS SECTOR

Competition

Structure Govt. Govt. Owned Liberalization Private Monopoly Except All SegmentsDepartment Corporation Of Services Local Loop

MOST COUNTRIES

1970 | Chile USAI Jamaica

Argentina MexicoChile

1975 JamaicaMexicoVenezuela

1980

1981

1982

1983 UK USA

1984 JapanI UK

1985

1986 Japan

1987 Malaysia ChileNew Zealand C

1988

1989 New Zealand

1990 Bangl ades

1 ~~~~~~Argentina 1991 Pakistan Malaysia

Germany Venezuela \

1992

1996

Mexico

Germany

INCREASING LIBERALIZATION 0

EXPLOMNG NEw MARKET OPPoRTUrNITtEs IN TELECOMMUNICATIONS

Page 13: Exploiting New Market Opportunities in Telecommunications...101 -Privatization in Tunisia, Jamal Saghir, 1993. 102 -Export Credits: Review and Prospects, Waman S. Tambe, Ning S. Zhu,

costs. At the same time, a regulator in a pluralistic regime with international transactions. Addressing this supply-must establish rules and prices for the interconnection of demand gap will require substantial new investments, pos-the multiple networks-and this practice is still evolving. sibly of the order of $60 billion a year.

Although the benefits of reform are often evident, thepace of change can be slowed by incumbent interests; Evidence of Suppressed Demandhence, experience shows that sectoral reform has to be led Figure 2 shows a familiar relationship: the availability ofby forces outside the traditional sectoral establishment. For phones per capita increases with income per capita. Moreexample, established interests often invoke, in a self-serv- importantly, a comparison of the regression lines for 1981ing manner, the potential displacement of workers as a rea- and 1991 reveals that this gap in telephone use betweenson for holding back. In practice, this tactic has been un- the high-income and low-income countries has increaseddermined by a variety of measures that have successfully over the last decade. Such a gap could suggest that themitigated the potentially negative effects on workers. No telephone is a luxury indulged in by the rich-indeed, Presi-doubt, the diffusion of reform has been accelerated by user dent Charles de Gaulle of France scorned it as a gadget-demand for technological advances. But it has taken the or that telecommunications are more productive in thecommitment of senior leadership to realign interests in fa- more information-intensive, rich countries. We find per-vor of consumers and away from the old telecommunica- suasive evidence, however, that the gap arises in large parttions establishment. from severe underinvestment in telecommunications ser-

In what follows, we deal successively with the large vices in developing countries.gap between supply and demand, restructuring the incum- Today, no one can seriously assert that telecommuni-bent to face the market test, the new opportunities for com- cations is a luxury. For firms competing in internationalpetition, creating a new regulatory regime, and the politi- markets, the demand is particularly acute. Empirical stud-cal economy of change. ies have shown that both the quantity (lines per popula-

tion) and the quality of telecommunications are extremelyTHE SUPPLY-DEMAND GAP important for generating exports and for attracting foreignThe large unfulfilled demand for telecommunications in investment (see Boatman 1991, Mody and Yilmaz 1994,developing countries-seen in long waiting lists and poor Wheeler and Mody 1992). In some respects, developingservice quality-impose a severe cost on the operations of countries are even more dependent on telecommunicationsfirms and households. In addition to "plain old telephone infrastructure than are developed countries. Exports ofservice," applications tailored to customer needs are being products that are characterized by rapidly-evolving demandpioneered in developed countries, but their relevance is as (such as apparel) are particularly sensitive to the availabil-great for developing country enterprises, especially those ity of a telecommunications network. In addition, the ex-

Figure 2 - GNP vs. Main Line per Capita, 1983 & 1992, Low to Middle Income Countries

45u 1992

. 40 - 1983

.2 35-

0 30 - 1:

25- 1/

0 20-

a.e CL

0

0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10

GNP per Capita, 1992 US$1,000

LEssoNs FOR DEVELOPING COUNTRIES 3

Page 14: Exploiting New Market Opportunities in Telecommunications...101 -Privatization in Tunisia, Jamal Saghir, 1993. 102 -Export Credits: Review and Prospects, Waman S. Tambe, Ning S. Zhu,

port of intermediate products (such as auto parts) requiresclose contact with customers who need to minimize their _inventory levels. In the newly industrializing economies ofEast Asia, advanced applcations of telecommunications Waiting lists are a serious problem in the lower income countries:

for the movement of documents and goods are being de- - 40%

veloped to bolster their competitive advantage in traditional - 35%

exports such as garments, footwear, auto parts, and elec- - 30%

tronics goods (Mody and Reinfeld 1994). This implies an - 25%

accelerating increase in demand for telecommunications - 20%

services.- 15%

Telecommunications investments in developing coun- - 10% . .tries have shown high economic rates of return. For World

- 5%Bank projects, they were estimated at 27 percent on aver- - oo/.age, which is substantially higher than the average on the Low Lower Upper High

Income Middle middle IncomeBank's portfolio (World Bank 1991, p. 4). These estimatesmake conservative assessments of the consumer surplus Income Category

from telecommunications investments and do not accountfor spillover benefits. month in developed countries. Low call-completion rates

Failure to keep pace with growing demand has been for domestic and international services increase costs forespecially evident in low-income developing countries, users and depress revenues for the provider. According towhere suppressed demand is highest. According to ITU an estimate for Ghana in 1992, call completion rates were(1994), registered waiting lists for new telephone service less than 50 percent; the average number of lines not work-represent 27 percent of the installed base in developing ing at any time was 20 percent and the average duration ofcountries. The situation is most acute in Sub-Saharan Af- faults was 30 days, though for rural connections repair timesrica, where the average waiting list is 60 percent of the could be over a year (Anderson Management Internationalnumber of installed lines. In many cases, waiting times ex- 1993). In addition to the high demand for "plain old tele-ceed ten years. In contrast, the upper half of middle-in- phone service", there is a growing demand for many spe-come countries have waiting lists of 19 percent (Figure 3). cialized and "intelligent" services.'

NEW LINES. Pent-up demand in developing countries can The Magnitude of Suppressed Demandbe conservatively estimated at 45 million lines, the total of The estimated $60 billion annual investment required toregistered waiting lists (ITU 1994, p. A9). This is conser- meet the demand for telecommunications services repre-vative in that: (a) not all countries report waiting lists, and sents 1.36 percent of the annual GDP of these countries(b) discouraged "waiters" are not reported. The existence (Table 1). Clearly, this amount signifies a much larger com-of discouraged waiters is illustrated by the increase in wait- mitment than most governments are willing to make. Thoseing lists that typically occurs as more phones are provided countries achieving the most rapid network growth, suchand the prospect of receiving a phone improves (ITU 1994, as Korea in the mid-1980s, spent in peak years about 2p. 73). This phenomenon is strikingly illustrated in Figure percent of GDP on telecommunications investment.4a for India, where, even though at least one quarter of The International Telecommunication Union (ITU)waiters have been served each year for the past decade, has projected developing country investment in basic tele-the waiting list has continued to grow. In Chile, the num- communications networks at $32.1 billion per year (ITUber of lines increased by more than the size of the waiting 1994, p. A60). This estimate, however, is based on pastlist between 1989 and 1990, yet the waiting list remained supply trends, an inaccurate guide for the future, and ex-(Figure 4b). Similarly, according to one report, for everynew telephone installed in China, two new applicants jointhe queue for telephones (Communications International, Many businesses urgently need packet-switching facilities,July 1994, p. 8). X.400 messaging services, electronic data interchange, and paging

and mobile services. To overcome these shortages, dedicatedSERVICE QUALITY AND ENHANCED SERVICES. bypass networks have been, or are being, created to enableUnderinvestment and poor maintenance has also resulted companies with local and international needs to transfer data. Inin poor service quality. Fault rates of 20 per month for India, these include networks belonging to the Indian Railways,

the Steel Authority, the State Bank, Reliance Corporation, andevery 100 lines are not uncommon in developing coun- others. In Ghana, Barclays Bank has dedicated lines for its datatries, compared to fault rates of 2 per 100 telephones per transfer between branches.

4 EXPLOITING NEW MARKET OPPORTUNITIES IN TELECOMMUNICATIONS

Page 15: Exploiting New Market Opportunities in Telecommunications...101 -Privatization in Tunisia, Jamal Saghir, 1993. 102 -Export Credits: Review and Prospects, Waman S. Tambe, Ning S. Zhu,

Figure 4 - India and Chile: Wait Lists and Main Lines

As phone availability increases, so do waiting lists:

Figure 4a - India: 7,000 Figure 4b - ChileWait Lists and Main Lines Wait Lists and Main Lines 1,400(in u-and.) 6f -o(in tho-snd.)

6,000- 1,200-

4,000- Wait Ust 800 -

3,000- 600 -

2,000- 400-

Main Lines Main Lines

1,000 200-

82 83 84 85 86 87 88 89 90 91 92 82 83 84 85 86 87 88 89 90 91 92

cludes, moreover, investment required to meet the de- fold as domestic and international capital markets play a

mands of waiters.2 Supplying the 45 million waiting for a more important role in financing infrastructure. Joint ven-

telephone, and not even counting those waiting in the tures add another bank of opportunities, with leading in-wings, would cost an additional $67.5 billion (assuming ternational companies allowing transfer of expertise. For

the conservative ITU cost of $1500 per line), implying an such capital and expertise to be efficiently deployed, ser-investment of $11 billion per year if the existing waiting vices must be oriented towards the needs of consumers,

lists are to be eliminated by the year 2000. with an emphasis on greater pluralism in the network.

Although no accurate measures of investment require- Given the growth of needed investment in the sector

ments exist for quality improvements and enhanced ser- over the past decade, state-monopoly telecommunicationsvices, it is estimated that high-income countries invested provision has diminished to make way for more open, com-some $81 billion in these areas in 1992, or $200 per in- petitive structures. As Figure 1 demonstrates, there is a

stalled line.3 Given the lower sophistication of developing marked trend towards liberalization: in a dozen countries,

country networks, we could assume that their investments the sector has evolved from the government monopolyin quality improvements and enhanced services were only model prevalent in the 1970s to one in which a broadening

half the high-income country levels, or $100 per installed array of services is being "unbundled" from the predomi-line, creating a further appetite for $17 billion per annum. nant operator. During the mid- 1980s, many of these enti-

ties were reorganized so that telecommunications were

The Transition from Old Ways to New separated from posts, operators were corporatized, and in

Today, the challenge is to provide the large scale of requirednetwork investment without imposing a burden on gov-

ernment resources.4 At the same time, opportunities un-7 million in 1975 to 25 million in 1985 (Ergas, 1992, p. 2).Turkey's PTT similarly trebled its network, but in an even fastersix years. And Korea's network has grown by 1 million lines per

2 ITU's calculations are based on the assumption that invest- year since the early 1980s (Kim, Kim and Yoon, 1992).ment to the year 2000 will continue at the rate experienced in Even state-owned monopolies that have mobilized funds forprevious years (at a cost of $1500 perline): "Projection (is) based network investment have had a poor record of product innovationon average annual growth rate in main lines and population over and introduction, due largely to their relative inflexibility. Francelast 8 years" (ITU, 1994, p. 3). Telecom's inability to successfully introduce new products (inI ITU estimates total investment in high-income countries at $99 contrast to its success in network development) has been attrib-billion in 1992, during which year 12.6 million new lines were uted to rigid attitudes in the state sector such as a managementinstalled. Using the nTU benchmark of $1500 per line, the new bias towards high-technology solutions (Ergas, 1992). Similarly,lines would have cost $17.4 to install.. The balance, $82 billion, Kim, Kim, and Yoon have conduded that Korea's state-ownedspread over 406 million installed lines, implies an average invest- public common carriers (PCCs) "lack sufficient incentives toment in quality and service enhancement of $200 per line. innovate technologically and improve quality. The PCCs, limited4A handful of government-owned monopolies have successfully by their monopolistic nature and a shortage of personnel andenlarged the network. France transformed one of the smallest and financial resources, could not effectively respond to the newmost backward networks in Europe into one of the most modem opportunities" to provide specialized communication servicesin the world, trebling the number of main lines in a decade from (Kim, et al. 1992).

LEssONS FOR DEVELOPING COUNTRIES 5

Page 16: Exploiting New Market Opportunities in Telecommunications...101 -Privatization in Tunisia, Jamal Saghir, 1993. 102 -Export Credits: Review and Prospects, Waman S. Tambe, Ning S. Zhu,

some cases, these government-owned corporations were arm's length from the government, corporatization permitsprivatized. Meanwhile, certain services were opened to telecommunications operators to respond directly to thecompetition, but generally only those outside of basic net- market. Checks on the operator may be instituted at thiswork services. This limited unbundling typically occurred stage through licensing conditions that stipulate the con-in the following order: equipment, value-added services, ditions of operation. The goal, often not realized, is thatdata transmission, and cellular and private circuits. In the all requirements placed on the corporation by governmentlate 1980s and 1990s, competition was finally opened in be explicit, thus eliminating the need to respond ad hoc tonetwork services as well-primarily domestic long-distance, government prerogatives.but in a few instances local services as well. Following corporatization, one strategy for improving

efficiency is to decentralize operations. This practice al-Enterprise Restructuring lows greater responsiveness to customers and increasesThe restructuring of the incumbent operator is critical for managerial accountability. Regionally based profit cen-both economic and political reasons. Increased au- ters or separation into lines of business have beentonomy-with incentives for commercial orientation-can mechanisms for decentralization in New Zealand, Indo-greatly improve total performance. Typically, such au- nesia, and Mexico.tonomy is achieved through corporatization, but often thefurther step of privatization is needed to minimize govern- NEW ZEALAND. To create Telecommunications Corpora-mental interference in operations. Privatization is-in prac- tion of New Zealand Ltd. (TCNZ), the government passedtice-used to achieve goals beyond enterprise performance, the State Owned Enterprise Act in December 1986, andincluding the development of capital markets. Successful the Telecommunications Act in July 1987. Under theseprivatization requires sensitivity to maintaining national laws, TCNZ became a corporation fully owned by the gov-ownership and continued adherence to social goals. Where emient. Following corporatization, TCNZ decentralizedconstraints to privatization exist, contracting out-through decisionmaking responsibility into subsidiaries so that man-build-operate-transfer (BOT) schemes and their variants- agers closest to the customer would be accountable for theircan draw new investment and improve efficiency needs and for unit profitability. Four new Regional Oper-

An important premise of enterprise restructuring is that ating Companies were created to provide local telephonethe regulatory functions must be separated from network service, and one subsidiary was created to provide domes-operations from the start to create a level playing field for tic and international long distance service. There were alsoall operators. It is often argued that a regulatory frame- nine small, entrepreneurial "NewVenture" companies, eachwork must precede privatization, or even corporatization; focusing on a specialized market segment. New managershowever, in practice, the two tasks proceed side-by-side. with commercial business experience were recruited and(We deal with regulatory reform later in the paper.) appointed to the boards of the newly created subsidiaries.

Corporatization and Decentralization INDONESIA. In 1991, the legal status of PT. TELKOM wasCorporatization is often a prelude to privatization. The changed from a government enterprise to a limited liabil-major objective of corporatization is to convert the tele- ity company. The new company's shares are still held wholycommunications department into an autonomous organi- by the Government, but this structure allows future trans-zation that is owned by the government, but runs on a com- fer of shares, perhaps in tranches, to private entities.mercial basis. By placing the telephone company at an TELKOM is in the process of decentralizing its organiza-

I0 -I - 0 - -T-_ . -r- 0 i I AP M 0 a

;; 000:DeveIop>:g Countrynup 0 i, ..b~~~~~~~~Lw .' Lower-M^Idle Upper-Middl All; Wi,'

NewLineITZU~simstei ; ;0 0$ ; 3 11 iS0i 10; 20t2o 11 tt0;0 New Une,- t . uppIy.current wplt lIU b ar00 e. ;2 ; : 5 i 4 :i;:0E;i; 101

Quaity liproveeSntand* enhancdivoe 2ig 6. 9 -170;

TOTAL . 15 21 24 60

PsrcentageotaDP(%) 1.52 1.82 1.10 1.36 |...................................... EXLOTNG NW _ .PPORTuNITIEs IN TELECOMMUNICATIONS

6 EXPLOITING NEwV MAR)KET OPPORTUNITIES IN TELECOMMUNICATIONS

Page 17: Exploiting New Market Opportunities in Telecommunications...101 -Privatization in Tunisia, Jamal Saghir, 1993. 102 -Export Credits: Review and Prospects, Waman S. Tambe, Ning S. Zhu,

tion with the ultimate goal of creating several regional sub- proportion of pre-privatization sales were 12 percent insidiaries, plus a long-distance and a cellular operator un- the United Kingdom, they were much higher at 50 inder a holding company. The subsidiary companies will, in Mexico and 155 percent in Chile (Galal, Jones, Tandon,turn, form joint ventures with experienced telephone op- and Vogelsang 1994).erators. Another company is likely to be established to To provide quick consumer access to new lines,manage the PALAPA satellite system. privatizations are often accompanied by a requirement to

The restructuring dovetails with the goals of invest- undertake certain minimum investments. These so-calledment mobilization and stimulation of competition. The "roll-out" obligations are exemplified by the service condi-new structure is likely to encourage competition in two re- tions imposed on Telmex, the privatized Mexican telecom-spects. First, decentralization will create "benchmark com- munications provider. Network development targets builtpetition" among the regional subsidiaries. The managers into the concession required Telmex to achieve a line growthof each subsidiary will be responsible for the relative prof- rate of at least 12 percent a year-twice the growth rateitability of their subsidiaries. Second, a new wireless com- achieved during the late 1980s. In addition to line growthpany will provide long-distance and local cellular service in requirements, the concession also required improvementscompetition with TELKOM. in service quality. Telmex more than met the targets. Similar

roll-out conditions were used in Argentina and VenezuelaMExco. In 1987, to prepare for privatization, Telmex's where also the privatized utilities outperformed obligations.corporate structure was decentralized and separated from For example, privatized in December 1991, CANTV inministerial control. Functions were also restructured into Venezuela expanded its network by 50 percent in the fol-geographic or service-related profit centers. Managers at lowing two years and virtually all targets for service im-the regional level could make decisions without relying on provements were met. Since the levels of service provi-central approval and were more accountable for regional sion are now so low in developing countries and the incen-profitability "This change accelerates decision-making, tives to expand so enormous, roll-out requirements mayclarifies responsibility, helps to allocate capital, serving the be unnecessary. Moreover, when roll-outs are used to se-needs of Telmex's different customer groups" (Casasus, cure the provision of services on uneconomic terms to par-1994, p. 10). ticular areas or consumers, they can distort pricing.

Meanwhile, administrative control of Telmex was Of interest, however, is the great sensitivity to politi-transferred from the Communications Ministry to the cal and social concerns in the privatizations witnessed thusFinance Ministry, which was managing the privatization far. The message clearly is that while efficiency gains areprogram. The Finance Ministry allowed greater au- likely to be achieved through privatization, concerns re-tonomy in operations and Telmex gained more finan- garding local ownership, redistribution of ownership andcially autonomy through the large price increases of rents to employees and other socio-economic groups, and1988 and 1990. Telmex could then self-finance a larger availability of service to weak consumers are of central in-proportion of its investment. Through innovative new terest to policymakers. Also, externalities-such as the de-securitization transactions, Telmex gained access to in- velopment of capital markets-are a major objective international capital markets and raised over $900m in privatizing utilities. These lessons are illustrated by thethree years. privatization operations in Mexico and New Zealand.

TELMEX CAPITAL RESTRUCTURING FOR PRIVATIZATION.

Privatization of the Government-Monopoly Operator The privatization process in Mexico was designed with sev-The objectives of efficient operation can, in principle, be eral objectives in mind: (i) transfer part of the ownershipmet through corporatization, and restructuring the organi- to Telmex employees, (ii) attract equity interest from ex-zation into profit centers. But the further step of perienced foreign operators, but retain Mexican control ofprivatization has increasingly been taken. Transfer of own- Telmex, and (iii) develop the ability to raise capital usingership to the private sector is justified for a variety of rea- new international financial instruments.sons, including additional insulation of operations from First, the government sold 4.4 percent of its A sharespolitical whims, greater efficiency of operations, and cre- to the company's employees, of which 1.6 percent wereation of a level playing field for other private operators. sold to its managers (Dougan and Bruno 1991, p.6 ). These

The evidence is that post-privatization efficiency im- were paid for through an eight-year credit provided by theprovements benefit shareholders and labor; while consum- government's development bank, on favorable terms.ers gain from rapid network expansion, but often pay higher Second, a controlling block of shares was sold to aprices for services that were heavily subsidized. A study of private Mexican-led consortium on December 20, 1990 fortotal welfare gains (sum of monetary gains to sharehold- $1.76 billion. Foreign operating companies were allowed toers, employees, and consumers) found that the gains as a participate as minority partners (in keeping with the for-

LESSONS FOR DEVELOPING COUNTRIES 7

Page 18: Exploiting New Market Opportunities in Telecommunications...101 -Privatization in Tunisia, Jamal Saghir, 1993. 102 -Export Credits: Review and Prospects, Waman S. Tambe, Ning S. Zhu,

eign investment law). The winning group included Grupo Contracting Out: The Thai ExampleCarso, a diversified Mexican group in association with the Where political or other constraints to full privatizationminority investors Southwestern Bell and France Telecom- exist, yet another method for increasing network size andmunications. Though the group acquired a 20.5 percent improving efficiency is contracting out, which brings inownership of Telmex, its voting rights were 51 percent. private initiative under the existing government operator's

Third, to further attract foreign capital but retain Mexi- umbrella. Such contracting out has been undertaken incan control, new shares with limited voting rights were is- Thailand to provide local telecommunications servicessued in an international public stock offering to investors (Augenblick, Stern, and Sullivan 1994, and Financial Times,in the U.S., Europe, and Asia for $2.2 billion in May 1991. April 6, 1994).This was a landmark deal, representing the largest global To help meet the growing demand for telecommuni-stock offering by any Latin American company. It was also cations services, the Telephone Organization of Thailandthe first time a privatization was carried out through a public (TOT) has granted two Build-Transfer-and-Operate (BTO)offering of shares in Latin America, and the first time that concessions to private operators to provide three millionmore than 85 percent of the shares being offered were new telephone lines by 1996 at an estimated cost of US$ 5placed outside the home country. Mexico's government, billion. The first concession, granted in 1991, provided fornow a minority Telmex holder, sold a 14 percent stake in the installation of two million lines in the Bangkok area.the company. The offering placed the single largest injec- The winner of the concession was a Thai-owned multina-tion of foreign money to date into Mexico's government tional (Charoen Pokphand group, an agro-industrial cor-coffers (Dougan and Bruno 1991, p. 6). poration), which subsequently formed TelecomAsia, in

Finally, in May 1992, the Mexican government sold partnership with NYNEX, an American regional operatoran additional 4.7 percent of the company in an interna- (which took a 15 percent equity position). NYNEX ap-tional and domestic offering, and now retains about a 4.8 points the chief operating officer and other key executives.percent holding. Overall, the government received some Unde the BTO scheme, TelecomAsia is installing theUS$ 5 billion from the Telmex privatization (Casasus, 1994, new lines, will transfer ownership to the Government, andp. 15; Tandon, 1992, Ch. 16, p.16). then operate the system for 25 years under a revenue-shar-

ing agreement. This agreement specifies that TelecomAsiaTHE "Kiwi" SHEARE IN NEW ZEAIAND. In privatizing TCNZ, will pass 16 percent of total service revenues to the Tele-the Government of New Zealand sought to limit foreign phone Organization of Thailand (TOT). The system willownership to 49.9 percent, to ensure coverage of local ser- consist of an overlay network that interconnects with bothvice areas, and, through a "kiwi" share, to maintain leader- the 1.2 million-line TOT network and Communicationsship in policymaking. Authority of Thailand's international gateway. TOT has

In September 1990, the government took a dramatic agreed not to compete with TelecomAsia before 1997.step: 100 percent of TCNZ shares were sold through open A second BTO was awarded in 1992 to Thai Telephonebidding to a consortium led by two New Zealand manag- and Telecommunication Co. (TT&T), an affiliate of theers (with 0.5 percent ownership) and owned by two Ameri- Loxley group withJapan's Nippon Telegraph and Telephonecan regional operating companies (Ameritech Corporation holding a 20 percent interest, to install and operate oneand Bell Atlantic). To ensure that the government's objec- million new lines in the rural northern provinces or "uptives would be met, it attached several conditions to this country," centered on Chiang Mai. In the 25-year conces-sale. The agreement stipulated that the owners would: (1) sion agreement, TT&T will take 56.9 percent of revenuessell back 10 percent of the stock to a New Zealand corpo- collected; TOT will take the rest. The larger revenue-shareration, and (2) reduce ownership below 49.9 percent by for TOT, compared to the 16 percent for TelecomAsia, isspring 1994 through public subscription. justified on the grounds that provincial lines generate more

A special share-the "kiwi share"-issued to the revenue through long-distance calls.Crown gave the finance minister specific rights to control The Thai BTO schemes prove the potential for attract-overseas ownership and other key articles of incorporation. ing private financing to telecommunications projects, evenThe articles require that half of the directors be New for local networks. The projects have been financed withZealand nationals. The government instituted service ob- a combination of supplier credits, loans, and project cashligations in the "Telecommunications Pledge," including generation. The two BTO companies have since raisedcontinued free local residential calling, residential line rental funds through public offerings on the Thai capital marketprice increases limited to the consumer price index, equal and form-along with other telecommunications listings-pricing for rural and urban customers, continued universal 16 percent of the Stock Exchange of Thailand. Similaraccess, and the requirement to publish quality-of-service schemes are now being attempted in other developing coun-records (New Zealand Ministry of Commerce 1992). tries, notably Indonesia.

8 EXPLOITING NEW MARKET OPPORTUNITIES IN TELECOMMUNICATIONS

Page 19: Exploiting New Market Opportunities in Telecommunications...101 -Privatization in Tunisia, Jamal Saghir, 1993. 102 -Export Credits: Review and Prospects, Waman S. Tambe, Ning S. Zhu,

BRINGING IN COMPETITION tem in the United States came to very different conclu-Until only a decade ago, in most countries the telecommu- sions on this question, although subsequent evidence hasnications sector was dominated by a single organization tended to favor the view that while scope economies dothat provided a variety of goods and services with very dif- exist, they are relatively limited (see Evans and Heckmanferent economic characteristics. Scale economies (the ad- 1984, Charnes, Cooper, and Sueyoshi 1988, Banker,vantages of large size) and scope economies (the savings Chang, and Majumdar 1992). The physical evidence alsorealized from the joint production of services) justified the undermines economies of scope. Common standards em-single provider. But economies of scale and scope have bodied, for example, in switching software (such as Opengenerally declined with technical progress of the last de- Network Architecture) seamlessly interconnect networkscade and, even where they exist, such economies may no and services offered by numerous suppliers and permit thelonger justify government-mandated monopolies. There charges from these suppliers to be itemized on a singleis compelling evidence that competition is possible for com- bill. Such software allows use of common facilities bypetitive possibilities in virtually all segments of telecom- multiple providers.munications. With economies of scale and scope declining, the ques-

tion is: how much competition can the telecommunica-Do Natural Monopolies Exist? tions sector sustain? Although telecommunications mar-When one provider can serve the market at a lower cost kets with numerous suppliers are still rare, competitionthan two or more providers could, a natural monopoly is among a few rival providers can lower costs and prices.said to exist. Such cases occur when the costs of produc- The theory of contestable markets says that even whereing and delivering a service decline with increasing output economies of scale and scope favor a single provider, po-(often referred to as economies of scale). It is also com- tential rival suppliers that contest the market limit the risksmon for these providers to supply a number of services, of monopoly abuse. Thus, all new entrants should be al-only some of which benefit from economies of scale. A lowed to provide services, letting the market decide hownatural monopoly in one service, however, may allow the many providers can operate profitably. Potential competi-provider to gain an advantage in another service that could tion is most effective where new entrants have limited sunkbe competitively provided. This occurs when it is cheaper costs of market entry-that is, when entrants can recoverfor a single provider to produce and deliver two or more their investments by selling assets if they decide to pull outservices jointly than for separate entities to provide the ser- of the business. By permitting easier redeployment of as-vices individually (economies of scope). The telecommu- sets-through developments in switching, VSAT, cellular,nications sector was long considered to exhibit both scale and software systems-technological change is undermin-and scope economies because of the "lumpiness" of the ing monopoly provision of telecommunications services.required investment and the adaptability of the physicalinfrastructure to multiple uses. Ways to Unbundle

Evidence now shows declining economies of scale in Competition is facilitated by unbundling the sector, eitherthe provision of telecommunications services. In switch- physically or in its accounting. Separation along businessing or routing of calls, increased modularity means that line allows prospective entrants to compete in those seg-being small has less disadvantage in cost. After being ments open to multiple providers. Moreover, unbundlingswitched, calls are traditionally transmitted over under- allows for the market to test economies of scale and scope,ground copper cables, but wireless technologies reduce the rather than allowing regulators to predetermine which seg-minimum efficient size of investment for long-distance ments should remain bundled.communications. Very small aperture terminals (VSAT), Vertical unbundling occurs when two activities-onefor example, are a low-cost, satellite-based alternative for of which is an input for the provision of the other-arelong-distance communication. Radio-based, cellular tech- institutionally separated. For example, since long-distancenologies that provide service to a small customer base in a operators need local networks to reach their customers,local area are available at increasingly competitive prices. the separation of local and long-distance services is verti-Optical fibers do not conform to this trend-once laid in cal unbundling. Separation can also occur between provi-the ground their very large capacities render parallel in- sion of network services (an intermediate input) and retailvestments wasteful. However, even with fiber optics, soft- services (a final output).ware make it possible for competitors to "share" the fiber Horizontal unbundling separates activities by markets-in transparent and fair ways. either geographically or by service category. Telecommu-

The evidence on economies of scope in the telecom- nications also lends itself to this form of unbundling. Themunications sector is weak at best. Economists attempt- operation of rapidly growing radio-based cellular servicesing to measure scope economies for the former Bell sys- is typically separated from the provision of traditional tele-

LESSONS FOR DEVELOPING COUNTRIES 9

Page 20: Exploiting New Market Opportunities in Telecommunications...101 -Privatization in Tunisia, Jamal Saghir, 1993. 102 -Export Credits: Review and Prospects, Waman S. Tambe, Ning S. Zhu,

phone services. In some cases, horizontal unbundling or LONG-DISTANCE COMPETITION. Unbundling-either in-divestiture into a number of producers allows direct com- duced by the market or mandated by the regulator-be-petition; in other cases, as when divestiture leads to re- gins with long-distance service because this segment hasgional monopolies, it allows for better performance com- high profit margins, which are typically used to subsidizeparisons and thus more efficient regulatory monitoring. local services. The recent history of competition in tele-

But the distinction between vertical and horizontal communications begins with MCI's challenge to the ven-unbundling is not always sharp. Specialized providers sell erable AT&T with the aid of microwave technology forinformation services using communication links owned by transmitting long-distance communications signals.traditional network operators-thus vertical unbundling Long-distance services are also an important arena ofbetween the provision of networks and the supply of infor- competition in developing countries.5 Two significant de-mation services is needed to allow fair competition between velopments are occurring in China, which has recently hi-horizontally separated service operators. censed a second operator (Box 1), and in Mexico, where

Constraints to unbundling are technical and economic. competition for long-distance services will commence onAttempting to force activities that are closely interdepen- January 1, 1997 (Box 2).dent into distinct boxes can impose high transaction costs Chile, also having begun with long-distance competi-because coordination, once achieved smoothly within a tion, has introduced full-fledged competition. In Chile,single firm, becomes more difficult and less effective when two companies have dominated the market. Compania dehandled between firms. And having separate, vertically Telefonos de Chile (CTC) provides local telecommunica-linked monopolies, each charging a markup over costs, may tions service to over 90 percent of the population, and asresult in higher charges than with a single, vertically inte- such is the main interface with the customer. Additionally,grated firm. CTC provides a limited amount of long-distance service,

But even where the technology accommodates unbun- operates cellular networks in the two major metropolisesdling, the legacy of institutions often limits the possibili- (Santiago and Valparaiso) and offers a variety of other ser-ties. In Hungary, a telecommunications law enacted in 1992 vices. Empresa Nacional de Telecommunications (Entel)separated long-distance (including international) services is the primary long-distance phone company in Chile,and local telephone services, which are under the jurisdic- though its share of the market has fallen to 70 percent astion of municipal authorities (Bruce, Harrell, and Kovacs new entrants have been allowed to provide long-distance1993). Under the law, private concessions for local ser- service in the past few years. A third company, Telex-Chile,vices were to be granted on a competitive basis. But prac- controls about 25 percent of the long-distance traffictical problems intervened. As in other countries, local rates through its subsidiary Chilesat.are very low, attracting few investors to that part of the From this unbundled, yet monopolistic position, Chilenetwork. And investors in the long-distance service faced is moving to a multi-carrier, and potentially highly com-the prospect of bargaining with group after group of local petitive, structure. In mid-1994, new legislation permit-government officials on terms of interconnection to local ted CTC to extend and therefore compete in long-distancenetworks. A compromise awarded a single franchise for services (through its subsidiary Chile-MUNDO), while al-long-distance services and 60 percent of the local network. lowing Entel to provide local telephone connections. OtherCompetition for the rest of the local network was opened existing and potential providers will have similar rights toto companies having demonstrable financial strength and provide integrated services. For the Chilean customer, thissound business plans. implies a choice of telephone companies, both on a call-

by-call basis by dialing an access code and through pre-Competition: Possibilities and Implications subscription to a specific company. Initially, primary com-A telecommunications market appropriately unbundled petition is likely to occur between CTC and Entel; how-opens up competition in virtually every segment. Compe- ever, Chilesat was successful in signing customers for inte-tition in any one segment lowers tariffs in that segment, grated service even in anticipation of the changed policy,which changes the prospects for other segments. For ex- serving notice of significant competitive possibilities. An-ample, competition in domestic long-distance telephonyand international telephony has often substantially loweredthe traditionally large margins in these services so that they 5 India is an exception. While maintaining a monopoly of long-can no longer subsidize local services. The consequent rise distance, Indian decision makers have chosen to divide the

in loaaesihdeeomntnwreestchooy country into 18 regions, in each of which a second operator wilin local rates, with developments in wireless technology evnulyb'loe ocmeewt h nubn.Frsc) ~~~~~~~~~~~~eventually be aDlowed to compete with the incumbent. For suchand the entry of cable network operators, is gradually, but competition to be realistic and meaningful, local rateswould needdefinitely, making local services amenable to competition. to be substantially revised upwards.

10 ExPLOITING NEW MARKET OPPORTUNITIES IN TELECOMMUNICATIONS

Page 21: Exploiting New Market Opportunities in Telecommunications...101 -Privatization in Tunisia, Jamal Saghir, 1993. 102 -Export Credits: Review and Prospects, Waman S. Tambe, Ning S. Zhu,

other major company likely to join the fray is Bell South, Box 1 - China Introduces Competitionone of the major U.S. regional operating companies.6

Prospects for long-distance competition continue to China has announced an historically unprecedentedimprove with developments in satellite technology. Long- expansion of its network from about 30 million lines todistance transmission of voice and data via satellite is used 120 million lines by the year 2000. Investment by thein Indonesia, but still principally under the umbrella of the monopoly operator, the Ministry of Posts and Telecom-government-owned provider-although, as in other coun- tnunications (MPT), is expected to be about $8 billion intries, the use of satellite transmission for private, dedicated 1994-aggregate telecommunications investment innetworks (using VSAT technology) is increasing. Recently, China could rise to $15 billion a year if the ambitiousMalaysia announced the acquisition of a satellite explicitly targets are to be met,in the context of entry by a second telecommunications To mobilize such large investments, the State Coun-company (Journal of Commerce, May 18, 1994). In the cil has abolished MPT's monopoly, licensing a new pro-Philippines, Philippine Global Communications Inc. is vider, China United Telecommunications (Unicom), toexpected to set up a domestic satellite network in the near operate a nationwide network, including both long-dis-future (Journal of Commerce, June 30, 1994). tance and local connections. Unicom is a partnership of

three Chinese mninistries-raiways, electric power, andINTERNATIONAL COMMUNICATIONS. The growing competi- electronics. The expectation is that the networks alreadytion in international services does not stem, as yet, from operated by the railways and power ninistries would formany major technological breakthroughs and would not be the nucleus of the new enterprise. The Ministry of Elec-worth remarking upon if it were not for the devastating tronics brings its expertise in modern communicationsimpact international competition will have on the tradi- technologies to the venture.tional rate structures. Until recently, international services Other steps towards opening the telecommunicationswere a carefully managed cartel of national telecommuni- market include: permission to the Ministry of Electron-cations authorities. By restricting other channels of inter- ics in January 1994 to compete with MPT in data ser-national communications flows, national authorities had vices; allowing the People's Liberation Army to use itsdevised a system of high international service rates, which radio network for cornmercial ends; and the separationthey then shared ("settled") according to arcane account- of regulatory and operation functions within MPT to en-ing rules. The huge profits from international services sub- sure that the incumbent and domninant operator does notsidized domestic, especially local, phone services. enjoy undue advantage over new entrants.

The pressures on the cartel have been many. The settle- Though joint venture partnerships with foreign com-ment arrangements between national telecommunications panies for the provision of services are currently not per-authorities led to large anomalies in pricing. The anoma- mitted, the indications are that such partnerships will soonlies are being exploited with the creative use of technology. be allowed. NYNEX, a regional operator in the UnitedFor example, in the deregulated U.S. market, which offers States, has established an advisory relationship withamong the lowest international rates, over a hundred "call- Unicorn. Cable and Wireless of the United Kingdom,back" bureaus have mushroomed. The overseas caller dis- through its subsidiary Hong Kong Telecom, has beenconnects after the first ring. The intelligent switch in the nominated a 'preferred partner" by MPT. Expectationsbureau automatically calls back with a dial tone, permit- are that these partnerships will be formalized and usedting the user to place a call as if from the United States to construct and operateregional and functional networks,(Financial Times, August 15, 1994). possibly on a "build-operate-and transfer" (BOT) basis.

In addition, powerful pressures from firms operating Source: Financial Times, July 21, June 23, May 27, May 20, and Apri

20, 1994.

6 Competition will be maintained through continued regulatory a band judicial oversight. The Chilean Supreme Court confirmed a i a global marketplace have forced most major telecom-recent antitrust ruling requiring Telefonica Internacional (a sub- munications companies to form both formal and informalsidiary of Telefonica de Espana) to sell one or the other of its alliances, leading further to the crumbling of national bar-holdings in the two leading Chilean phone companies, CTC or riers. With growing competition among the different alli-Entel. Telefonica has since sold a 15 percent stake of the 20 ances for the business of multinational companies, old ratepercent it held in Entel, while maintaining its 44 percent interest . .rin CTC. Also, in the transition to full competition, rates charged structures are receivig further blows (Financial flmes,Juneby the different companies, especially CTC, will be capped by the 16, 1994).regulator. Also, increased international transmission capacity has

LESSONS FOR DEVELOPING COUNTRIES 1I

Page 22: Exploiting New Market Opportunities in Telecommunications...101 -Privatization in Tunisia, Jamal Saghir, 1993. 102 -Export Credits: Review and Prospects, Waman S. Tambe, Ning S. Zhu,

further frayed the cartel. International services have tradi- existing local networks, and in many countries with onetionally been carried by publicly owned satellites, princi- another. By 1993, Sri Lanka had licensed three cellularpally Intelsat.7 Availability of alternative transmission ser- operators (soon to be four), which has decreased its tariffsvices, via satellite and undersea fiber optic cables, has fa- to among the lowest in the world-connection costs of $100cilitated bypassing the channels controlled by national au- and operating costs of 16 cents a minute. This can be com-thorities. Satellite-based services are growing at a rapid pared with the more typical costs charged by a monopolypace (O'Brien 1994). In addition to a number of regional provider in El Salvador-$ 1,000 and 35 cents a minute.initiatives in Europe and Asia, Panamsat, Intelsat's chief Cellular telephony, which uses radio waves for com-global competitor, launched the first of three satellites in munications, is largely used for mobile communications,July 1994. The three new satellites will give Panamsat be- but it can also be used for "fixed" telephones. Accordingtween six and seven times its current capacity. Competi- to one commentator, the imminent development of fixedtion in satellite-services will be greatly reinforced if the radio networks for local communications is a "revolutionexotic low-earth satellite ventures, such as Iridium, were waiting to happen" (Adonis 1994). In the coming years, itto materialize. is expected that the cost of fixed radio connections for the

Growing competition in international services has trig- local loop will plummet, making them competitive withgered new public policy concerns. For organizations like traditional, wireline networks. In the U.K., lonica, an as-Intelsat and Inmarsat to perform effectively in the new com- piring competitor to British Telecommunications and Mer-petitive environment, they may need to be privatized (Wall cury, plans to build local loops throughout the country us-Street Journal, July 29, 1994). More importantly, in place ing such radio technology (Financial Times, August 19,of maintaining a cartel for provision of international ser- 1994). In Indonesia, Ratelindo, a joint venture betweenvices, greater resources are being devoted-in service ne- the state-owned operator and a private company, has beengotiations under the General Agreement on Tariffs and licensed to provide 280,000 fixed radio connections, prin-Trade-to seek enhanced access in foreign markets cipallyinJakarta.(Broadman and Balassa 1993). Although radio-based mobile telephony already pro-

vides a measure of competition in local telephony, the tra-LocAL COMPETITION. The advent of radio-based cellular ditional wire networks for providing the final connectiontelephone networks has introduced a major competitive to the customer continue to appear immune to significantelement, especially in developing countries. These net- competition. However, increased competition is evidentworks have relatively low capital costs which make them even in this segment. Two types of competition to con-readily contestable. Radio-based telephones compete with sider are benchmark competition and direct competition.

In benchmark competition a country is split into regions,each of which has a monopoly local operator. For example,Argentina has two regional operators (Telecommunications

Intelsat is mainly owned by government-owned monopoly Argentina in the north and Telefonica de Argentina in thetelecommunications providers, though U.S. interests are repre- south) and the US has seven (called the Regional Bell Op-sented by Comsat, a private company. erating Companies). This type of competition allows regu-

In Mexico, Telefonos de Mexico (Te Tex)e l ierigtt provide lniun at unt9January 1, 1997Wand local service through the year 2026. i anticpation othe ;peof h logstance n rkt, thegovernment is preparing to sell concessions to new -oprors. At the trt, 60 of Me s mast nptaznt cities willenefi?t from cometitive provision of long-distance setvices, twing toover 200 cities by%the yeat 2000.

Some ;00 0prinnt international operators, BellAtlantic, ', andMCI Co rc iciOnnS ar3 said tO be negotiatingjoint ventures with Mexican partners to bid'for these concessions& TeX` ' diet me,ani is gearing up provi'deminteronnection to the new operators. While details of tie iih ionnertonptiga* o ii they ae expected to

reflect th costs tof providing interconnection linkages nd to follow tenatioal nor oftansparency and non-discimintionbetwen perators.

Br lcensing cellular operator in? 1989, Me;xico hiaid a the bis Cellular providers thatarenot:subsidiries) of Telrnex have formed an asso a-ion, whici has soght to etablish precedents on interconnection

ssttaitprwes.~ ~~~~~soato, i $iitt it:y (. ;\i..n ;2ction:;:; stanidards, and prices.

Sorce:Reuter , july 1, 1994.

12 EXPLOITING NEW MARKET OPPORTUNrTIES IN TELECOMMUNICATIONS

Page 23: Exploiting New Market Opportunities in Telecommunications...101 -Privatization in Tunisia, Jamal Saghir, 1993. 102 -Export Credits: Review and Prospects, Waman S. Tambe, Ning S. Zhu,

lators to check that one operator's prices are not signifi- In the developing world, the experience of compe-cantly out of line, without having to address the complex tition is still limited. Competition exists primarily inissues surrounding interconnection and natural monopoly. cellular telephony. There, the evidence from Sri LankaBut since there is no competition within the local market, already cited is most striking. And not only are the ser-benchmark competition does not create direct incentives vice costs low, but the cost of a cellular phone declinedfor businesses to cut costs and improve efficiency from $2500 to $250 over the past year (due in part to a

Direct competition is rapidly approaching. The Brit- decline in import duty). The number of subscribers isish government decided to permit new entrants to the lo- reported to be growing at 8 to 10 percent a monthcal market in 1991, prompting cableITVoperators and re- (Reuters, September 11, 1994).gional electricity to plan expansion of network services,using their existing infrastructure which already supplies REGULATORY REFORMindividual customers. Over 100 companies have been li- At the same time as enterprise restructuring takes placecensed to provide local services though British Telecom- and competition is introduced, three regulatory tasks aremunications still dominates with a 90 percent market share. typically undertaken to induce efficient investment, pro-In the United States, several states have passed legislation tect consumers, and maintain fair competition. Traditionalto permit local competition (Baumol and Sidak 1994). As cross-subsidies are gradually eliminated through rate rebal-noted, Chile also allows local competition, though CTC at ancing, to ensure that new entrants do not "cherry pick",present controls over 90 percent of the local telephone lines. leaving the incumbent saddled with least profitable ser-

vices; but the goal also is to raise local rates with a view toCompetition: An Assessment promoting investment in that most underserved section ofWhere economies of scale exist, it can be socially wasteful the network. Consumer interests are protected through afor competing providers to lay duplicate networks-this is regime that places a cap on price increases-such a regimethe traditional argument in favor of restricting provision to also induces the operator to improve operating efficiencya single operator. However, even where a natural monopoly Finally, the successful operation of an unbundled networkexists, competition may be desirable since it increases in- requires rules for fair pricing of interconnection betweencentives for efficiency and consumer choice. The judg- network segments. Ideally, rate rebalancing should be com-ment is increasingly being made that the benefits of com- pleted early; failure or inability to do so constrains, as wepetition outweigh losses on account of natural monopoly will see, the effectiveness of other tasks.characteristics that persist in the telecommunications net-work (see Cave 1991). Rate Rebalancing

The contemporary experience with direct competition The structure of telephone tariffs influences the segmentsis only a decade old, but both the early experiments with of the telecommunications market to which investors arecompetition and recent results validate its benefits. Data attracted. In the past, long-distance telephone calls werefor the United States during the early decades of this cen- priced high enough to allow monopoly suppliers of tele-tury show that "competition stimulated growth, extended communications services to earn reasonable profits whileservice to unserved or underserved areas, and created pres- keeping down the price of access to the network and ofsures which improved both the deveiopment and the ap- local calls. When telecommunications markets have beenplication of telephone technology" (Mueller 1991). Fol- opened up, new investment has typically flooded to long-lowing the divestiture of AT&T in 1984, several-new en- distance service-where tariffs are significantly abovetrants invested in network capacity in the United States costs-rather than to network services where investment(Crandall 1989, pp. 58-59). After the introduction of a needs are more urgent, but tariffs are below costs. In Ja-number of major deregulatory initiatives over the past two pan, for example, several new investors entered the profit-decades, greater competition has led to lower prices or able long distance market, while none wanted to competebetter services for consumers-while efficiency gains, new with NTT's loss-making local service.technologies, and business practices led to sustained prof- Alternative approaches exist to deal with the relateditability (Winston 1993). Outside the United States, fall- issues of rate rebalancing and fostering new entry. Rebal-ing prices, better quality, and greater responsiveness to ancing can be achieved directly by raising local rates andcustomers appeared inJapan, New Zealand, and the United all countries seeking to introduce competition have to goKingdom (Takano 1992, Oniki, Oum, and Stevenson 1990, through this process. However, it may be unfeasible toWilliamson 1993, Bell and Cave 1991). In each of these raise rates in one shot-though substantial increases havecountries, however, gains from competition cannot be eas- been achieved over the short-run in Latin America. Forily separated from efficiency improvements following the example, when Mexico's Telmex was awarded a six-yearprivatization of the state-owned monopoly. monopoly under a concession agreement in 1990, rates for

LESSONS FOR DEVELOPING COUNTIuES 13

Page 24: Exploiting New Market Opportunities in Telecommunications...101 -Privatization in Tunisia, Jamal Saghir, 1993. 102 -Export Credits: Review and Prospects, Waman S. Tambe, Ning S. Zhu,

local services were raised three or four times over original or the productivity offset. The X-factor is the differencelevels. In light of impending long-distance competition, between the rate of growth in total factor productivityTelmex further rebalanced rates during the period of the (TFP) in the selected service or group of services and theconcession: long-distance rates have fallen while rates for aggregate economy The purpose of the X-factor is to re-local services have risen steadily flect the whole range of diverse factors that cause changes

In contrast, the Philippines chose to encourage new in the unit costs of service delivery, apart from the inputentry immediately, although the rate structures will change prices-these include technological advances and shifts inonly gradually. New operators are prevented from serving demand that influence costs through economies of scale,only the lucrative international services market, and are scope, and density.8further required to provide 300 of the less profitable local First applied in the United Kingdom, the price capexchange lines for each connection they make to the inter- system has been adopted around the world because of itsnational gateway expected benefits in encouraging efficiency improvements

Another transitional approach is to embed the cross- while allowing the operator to better predict its revenues.subsidy in the access price. For example, when a new en- Empirical investigations of these benefits have been fewtrant is providing the more lucrative long-distance service, because price caps are recent and adequate benchmarksthe incumbent who has access to the final consumer can for comparison are not available. One study based on in-charge an access price that reflects some of the costs of terstate differences in regulatory regimes in the U.S. showedmaintaining the local network (see discussion below on that the presence of a price-cap regime has a significantaccess pricing). This does not solve the problem of en- effect in lowering service prices (Mathios and Rogers 1989).couraging new entry in the local network but does facili- Many states in the U.S. instituting price caps have alsotate competition in long-distance services without putting simultaneously required operators to increase deploymentthe incumbent at a disadvantage on account of its local of digital infrastructure (Greenstein, McMaster, and Spillerservice obligations. 1994). However, as may be expected, price caps do not

have any influence on price in a competitive situation, whichConsumer Pricing Rules prevails in cellular telephony (Shew 1994).Competition provides incentives for suppliers to charge the Improvisation has been an obligatory feature of pricelowest profitable price. So if barriers to entry were elimi- cap implementation, not only across countries to allow fornated, in theory, there would be no need to control prices. varying conditions, but also within countries. IntroducedIn reality, however, competition in the telecommunications in 1984 for governing prices charged by British Telecom-sector is imperfect, so price regulation is generally required munications in the U.K., the X-factor was set at 3 percentin some segments. As noted above, Chile has maintained and applied to one basket of services comprising line rent-a price-cap regime for the dominant providers despite sub- als and tariffs for local and national calls (OFTEL 1992).stantially liberalizing entry. The first review in 1989 raised the X-factor to 4.5 percent,

Traditionally, utilities have operated under "rate-of- followed by an interim review in 1991, which brought thereturn" regulation-as was the case for the U.S. telephone highly profitable international services within the basketcompany, AT&T, until 1989 (Braeutigam and Panzar 1993). and raised the X-factor to 6.25 percent. Finally, in 1993,Such regulation, also referred to as "embedded cost regu- the X-factor was placed at 7.5 percent and should remainlation" or "cost-plus" pricing, was used to cover operational at that level till 1997. In parallel, a specific cap (or a subcosts and permit an agreed return on investment. The cap) was placed on line rentals (the X-factor was negative,agreement sought to protect consumers from excessive implying that real prices increased). Also, private circuits,prices while ensuring adequate investor returns. This regu- which had no price control because they were believed tolatory device not only creates no incentives to limit costs, it be competitive were covered under a new basket in 1989perversely encourages higher investments and cost infla- with an X-factor of zero.tion to increase total returns.

As such, a move has occurred to so-called "incentive To prevent strategic behavior aimed at influencing the produc-regulations", which focus on fostering efficiency and tech- tivityoffset, the value of the offset must be based on industrywidenical progress in the network while at the same time pro- indicators and not be tied to the operational and investmentviding high quality service to customers (Sappington in this decisions of individual firms. Moreover, the productivity offsetvolume). An important application of incentive regulation should be based on long run movements in (continued) produc-has been "price-cap" regulation, which sets the maximum tivitygrowth. Measurementof"bestpractice" productivitygrowthaBowable rate of price increase. The.allowed.rate.of .n- must be based on recent historical data, rather than forecasts

allowable rate of price increase. The allowed rate of in- (since, in competitive markets, price changes follow unit costcrease is the general rate of inflation in the economy, mea- reduction rather than anticipating them and also because fore-sured by the retail price index (RPI), minus an "X-factor", casting is impractical).

14 EXPLOITING NEw MARKET OPPORTUNITIES IN TELECOMMUNICATIONS

Page 25: Exploiting New Market Opportunities in Telecommunications...101 -Privatization in Tunisia, Jamal Saghir, 1993. 102 -Export Credits: Review and Prospects, Waman S. Tambe, Ning S. Zhu,

Telmex in Mexico became subject to price cap regula- that, mandatory interconnection with non-discriminatorytion in January 1992, a year after privatization. A single and fair pricing is needed.price cap is applied to the overall weighted average priceof Telmex's services. The X-factor is zero, implying that Interconnection Pricingprices on average can keep pace with inflation. The much Interconnection pricing is in its infancy, particularly in de-lower X-factor than in the U.K. arises because the X-factor veloping countries (Box 3). In practice, rough and readyreflects not just productivity differentials, as it should in norms for revenue-sharing between different componentstheory, but also seeks to compensate for historically low of the network are adopted. However, as the number ofprices of certain services. As noted above, Telmex can de- providers increases and as networks become more com-cide how to rebalance its rates, keeping in mind that it will plex, the basis for interconnection pricing will be tied morebe subject to competition in long distance services in 1996. to the costs of interconnection.

In the U.S., the price cap plan for AT&T has three The lessons learned from interconnection regulationbaskets-to discourage cross-subsidy between the baskets in developed countries are only just beginning to emerge.but permit flexibility within a basket. The average price of A primary social objective of the interconnection pricingservices in each basket has to be lowered by 3 percent. regime is to facilitate efficient new entry. The incumbentOver time, as particular services become more competi- operator has an incentive to limit competition by restrict-tive, they are freed from regulation. For example, services ing physical interconnection and/or charging a price so highhave been steadily removed from basket three, which con- that new entrants cannot operate profitably merely by con-tains business services such as private line ne tworks and necting a set of new customers to the existing network.data transmission. Although lower interconnection costs make new entry prof-

No clear practice has emerged on pricing new and in- itable and induce greater competition, it is a mixed bless-novative services. Though it may generally be expected ing. When interconnection costs are low, the new entrantthat such services are subject to competition, this is not has less incentive to build its own network-to lay its ownalways the case (e.g., call waiting and forwarding for resi- cables, establish new wireless links, or install new switches-dential customers remains largely under the domain of the since it has cheap access to an existing network. This maydominant local provider). However, placing price caps on be appropriate where the existing network is already well-new services runs the risk of reducing incentives to inno- developed since duplication is considered undesirable. Invate. Appropriate treatment of new services is related to that case, new entry is primarily a means for fostering greaterthe partitioning of services into baskets. One approach efficiency. Low interconnection prices in Japan, set at themay be to cover all services-new and old-under one level of highly subsidized local call rates, have resulted inbasket, as in Mexico. Provided average price commitments only limited network expansion. Where networks areare met, application of the price cap to a single basket of sparse, as in many developing countries, the objective ofservices allows the alleged monopolist pricing flexibility new entry is not only to create a more competitive envi-across services. However, this raises the danger of ineffi- ronment but also to expand the basic network. Thus, ancient cross-subsidies, leading to an argument for a larger interconnection price should at least cover the incremen-number of baskets. Fewer baskets are preferred since they tal costs (fixed and traffic-sensitive costs).reduce the administrative burden of negotiating and moni- A distinction is made between directly attributable coststoring a proliferating set of productivity offsets, as has (or the incremental costs of conveying a call) and the op-happened in certain U.S. states (Schankerman 1994). portunity costs along the interconnection link (or the prof-

As with any regulatory regime, price capping is not its foregone from renting the interconnection link to a com-perfect. The operator retains monopoly profits when cost petitor). Directly attributable costs are not precisely mea-reduction is greater than the expected productivity offset. surable since the facilities are typically used in conjunctionThere are also practical problems in implementation. In- with other parts of the network when providing multipleevitably, renegotiations of the productivity offset occur, services. Thus, cost allocations between services-an ar-leading to reexamination of the fairness of rates and hence bitrary exercise in practice-and conventions of more ora reversion to the rate-of-return type calculations which less accuracy are used to overcome this problem.9

the system sought to avoid. Thus, though the productivityoffset legitimately needs to be updated to ensure thatchanges in productivity growth are reflected in the price The directly lattributable costs of interconnection have twocap, the offset should be left in place for several years- components: fixed and variable. Fixed costs are the costs ofcap, eenyast miti heicnie eeiso providing the physical access and refer to the hardware instaDledfive to seven years-to maintain the incentive benefits of for creating access for other carriers as well as software (includingthe price cap mechanism. Ultimately, the goal must be to the relevant databases on subscribers). Variable costs, or the costsphase out price regulation, as competition develops. For of actually conveying the call, depend upon the volume of traffic

LEssONS FOR DEVELOPING COUNTRIES 15

Page 26: Exploiting New Market Opportunities in Telecommunications...101 -Privatization in Tunisia, Jamal Saghir, 1993. 102 -Export Credits: Review and Prospects, Waman S. Tambe, Ning S. Zhu,

The greater controversy lies in the appropriate defini-

tion and measurement of opportunity costs. There are twodistinct problems here. The first is a transitional issue, The intrconnecion issue is acquiringincreasingirrm-related to the historical structure of tariffs. As discussed portance in developng countries, and especia in East-above, prices for services have been unbalanced, i.e., local em Europe ere multiple operators have been licensed.services have typically been unprofitable, requiring recov- In Poland, for example, a 1990 telecommunications lawery of costs from long-distance (and especially international) allowMe independlent perators the right to develop net-services. This legacy has a direct impact on interconnec- works 7 in regions not served by the government-ownedtion charges. A new entrant has the greatest incentive to telecommunications prvider Telkomunikacja (TPSA).provide long-distance service where prices are above costs, ree large independ operators, in addition to almnostwhere they can "skim the cream." If the incumbent charges 60 smaller providers, have been licensed to prvide localonly for the conveyance costs, then profits in the long-dis- servi es to customers.tance business will erode, while losses in local telephony in ercon ectionbetweenFP;Aandtheinlependentremain. This requires that interconnection charges include operators imvolves establishing a means of providing ac-some of the foregone profits in long-distance. In the United cess to each company's network and sharing revenuesKingdom, such charges are referred to as access deficit fromtthis access. To date there is no one stadard inter-charges; similarly, in Australia, new entrants are required cnnection agreement between TPSA and the indepen-to contribute to a fund for providing universal services. dents. Th etelecommunications law states that each in-The U.K. regulator, OFTEL, has often chosen, however, dependent compaln must negotiate its own separateto discount or even waive these access deficit charges to agreement with TPA. This lac of standard agreementstimulate new entry (Armstrong and Doyle 1994). has prevented hemajotof the iependents from fur-

Opportunity costs remain even after rates are rebal- iher pursuing the development of thir local networ.

anced to reflect their hidden cost and there no longer exist Without interconnection, outside investors are hesitantsignificant deficits in the provision of particular services. to commit any resourcest uniti a strong and fair contractThe efficient components pricing rule is an economically ef- is estalished.ficient way of pricing interconnection, under certain con- Revenue-sharing ibetween operators is likely to beditions. The rule specifies that the price of interconnec- the most practical solution sincereiable measures of cost

tion equal the opportunity cost to the provider on the par- do notexist. t Underdsuh a systemr, revenue is sharedticular route, where opportunity cost is measured as the between the local operator originating the call, the long-revenue the provider would obtain from final consumers distance operator, and the local operator completing theof telecommunications services minus any cost savings call.iThe share reeive d by each of the three parties is aachieved if new entrant itself incurred some of the opera- matterdof negotiation. However, the expectation is thattional expenses in establishing that link. rthe log-distance torwl receive somewhat less than

This pricing scheme compensates the incumbent not atofte revenue, withtheremaining revenuesharedonly for direct costs incurred but also for profits lost when equally beeen the local operators. Such sharing is pre-the entrant takes away the incumbent's customers. The sumed torteflctcosts incurredbthe different parties.rule also provides some competitive discipline, since only

Source: Personal communication nrom Dan Craun-Selka and Normanthose competitors able to undertake operations at a lowercost than the incumbent will enter (Baumol and Sidak _____________i __i:_i__a___E____E___:_C_X____:___

1994). Moreover, if followed strictly, the rule is simpleand the information required for implementation (the price grounds that opportunity costs include monopoly profitscharged by the incumbent and incremental costs along that of the incumbent provider, and is relevant only when com-route incurred by the entrant) relatively easy to acquire, petitive conditions prevail or when the final price chargedand specific problems associated with determining and al- to the consumer is regulated (Box 4). Application of thelocating costs to the incumbent are eliminated. rule is further complicated by practical considerations. For

In practice, the rule has not been easy to implement. example, customers gained by the new entrant are not nec-In New Zealand the rule has been challenged on the essarily customers lost by the incumbent. By identifying

new customers and catering to their special requirements,the entrant can expand the size of the customer base, while

and, in practice, are determined by the level of traffic during the enhancing the value of the incumbent's network. In suchbusy hours when congestion in the network is likely to be thegreatest. Ultimately, the fixed costs should be transferred tosubscribers, as part of their rental charges, as has gradually needs to be scaled down to reflect the contribution madeoccurred in the United States. by the entrant in attracting new business.

16 ExPLOITING NEW MARKET OPPORTUNITIES IN TELECOMMUNICATIONS

Page 27: Exploiting New Market Opportunities in Telecommunications...101 -Privatization in Tunisia, Jamal Saghir, 1993. 102 -Export Credits: Review and Prospects, Waman S. Tambe, Ning S. Zhu,

Alternative approaches have been suggested to over- Box 4 - Legal Test of Efficient Componentscome the difficulties associated with a dominant operator. PricingOne is to mandate the break-up of the dominant operator.For New Zealand, Mueller (1993) has suggested that In New Zealand, the "efficient components pricingTCNZ be split into several companies. In this proposal, rule" is under dispute. Telecommunications Corporationeach company would have a regional base but would com- of New Zealand (TCNZ), the incumbent, has proposedpete for all services with other companies. The limnitations this rule which requires the new entrant, Clear Telecom-of such an approach are: i) the break-up will be arbitrary munications (Clear), to pay the direct incremental coststo a degree, ii) the cost efficiencies from the broader scope to TCNZ of providing the interconnection as well as theof activities enjoyed by large companies will be dissipated, opportunity cost of that interconnection (which is theand iii) no barriers exists to prevent the reemergence of profits forgone by TCNZ when it allows Clear to use itsone or more dominating operators. communication lines). Applied to the local loop (the link

A different approach to this problem with great rel- from the customer to the nearest phone exchange}, inevance to a modern interconnection regime is emerging. effect this requires that Clear's customers payTCNZ theIn this model, no attempt is made to break-up the opera- same line rental charge as do TCNZ's own customerstor regionally or to isolate local and long-distance provi- (TCNZ would also receive payment for incremental costssion (as in the United States). Rather, separation occurs of linking to Clear's network less costs saved due tobetween network and retail services. In Rochester, N.Y, Clear's investments in the local loop).for example, the local phone company has voluntarily Although considered a fair pricing rule by the Highagreed to separate its business into one that provides the Court of New Zealand, it was found later by the Court ofnetwork infrastructure, which will be used by the new ser- Appeal to violate section 36 of the Commerce Act sincevices company on the same terms as other entrants. The the price included monopoly profits. The Court of Ap-United Kingdom is moving in the same direction. OFTEL peal agreed with the principle that the incumbent shouldhas proposed an accounting separation between the net- be compensated for lost profits, provided these were prof-work and service operations of BT its earned in a competitive set up and not in a monopoly

Ultimately, as with price capping, the expectation situation, Alternatively, if the final price to the consumerwould be that mandatory intercornection with regulated were regulated at approximately the level prevailing in aprices would no longer be required. This would happen competitive market, then it would once again be appro-when, within narrowly specified geographic areas, alterna- priate to charge for profits foregone.tive carriers are available to provide the interconnection to The Privy Council determnined that the judgment ofthe customer, thus breaking the monopoly on interconnec- the High Court had been appropriate. It reasoned thattion services. Dispensation with interconnection regula- charging an interconnection price that included monopolytion could occur even when there are only two providers profits did not violate the Commerce Act since a "levelof interconnection services (Schankerman 1994). playing field' existed and TCNZ effectively charged it-

self the same price for interconnection as it charged corn-Making the Regulatory Transition petitors. The matter of controlling monopoly profits wasEmpowering independent bodies with policymaking and a separate one and needed to be addressed independentlyregulatory capabilities, and ensuring their separation from In arriving at this judgment the Privy Council noted thatthe dominant operator, checks the power of the operator. it had not resolved the interconnection dispute but hadPolicymaking sets the broad agenda based on the needs of only concluded that TCNZ's position was consistent withusers, whereas regulation enforces the goals set by the objectives of the Commerce Act.policymakers. Thus, the first task is to unbundle the vari-ous roles of the government. Box 5 describes, for Mexicoand Malaysia, the range of actions required and process rights and responsibilities of operators. Examples of suchfollowed in this unbundling process. provisions include the "kiwi share" in New Zealand or a

The regulatory objective, in turn, can be undertaken similar "golden share" in Malaysia through which the gov-in alternative ways. An independent regulator implements ernment ensures social obligations of the dominant pro-policies with respect to new entry, handles various aspects vider. Also, as in Mexico and Argentina, the roll-out obli-of pricing, acts as a source of information to both sides in gations of the provider are embodied in the concessionthe transaction, and arbitrates contracts and disputes be- agreement between the provider and the government.tween parties. However, in practice, regulatory provisions Where limited regulatory capacity exists or relevant legis-are also incorporated into the charters of operating com- lation limits the scope of action, such contracts take onpanies and other company-specific contracts, laying out the additional importance.

LESSONS FOR DEVELOPING COUNTRIES 17

Page 28: Exploiting New Market Opportunities in Telecommunications...101 -Privatization in Tunisia, Jamal Saghir, 1993. 102 -Export Credits: Review and Prospects, Waman S. Tambe, Ning S. Zhu,

Developing regulatory capacity requires an ongoing Experience in industrial countries shows that as regu-commitment to provide resources for regulatory skill de- lators become stronger, "regulating the regulators" may bevelopment as well as ensuring the independence and au- desirable. In the United Kingdom, for example, the Na-thority of the regulator, as the Argentinean example shows. tional Audit Office audits regulators under a larger man-Charged with regulatory responsibilities in November 1990, date to determine "value for money" in public service, andthe Comisi6n Nacional de Telecomunicaciones (CNT) in the Monopolies and Mergers Commission hears appealsArgentina did little until the end of 1991 (Hill and Abdala of decisions by sectoral regulators.1993). CNT's failure to formulate standards and processesfor issuing licenses retarded the development of new tele- POLITICAL ECONOMY OF REFORMcommunications services. Meanwhile, a number of radio As most policy reformers know, not all efficient solutionsoperators and telephone cooperatives, faced with a delay are adopted and achieving change depends upon dealingin receiving licenses and little or no policing of their opera- with relevant interest groups. The greatest threat is posedtions, started operations without licenses. Consumers also by those who merely derive rents from the existing short-suffered from CNT's inability to effectively address ser- ages. Successful implementation of reform requires thatvice complaints. Efforts to reform CNT have, however, these non-productive parties-those who dispense phonesimproved its performance. A team of outside consultants in short supply-be phased out through creating a stron-working with CNT from early 1992 to May 1993 made ger consumer constituency Then there are those whoseprogress in developing strategies and procedures. CNT's skills could be rendered obsolete by the changes initiated-top staff, previously political appointees, have since Octo- labor being the key group under this threat. Mechanismsber 1993 been chosen through a competitive selection pro- for increased labor ownership are needed to ensure thatcess. The Philippines has also undertaken measures to all productive players share in the long-term gains, evenmake the regulatory process more autonomous and ac- though some may endure short-term losses. Little is knowncountable. A draft bill in the lower house of Congress de- about the most vulnerable group who cannot adapt to thefines the role of the National Telecommunications Com- new conditions; however, the rapid telecommunicationsmission, increases the number of commissioners, assigns a growth in the post-reform phase and training initiatives havefixed tenure, and increases access to operational funds. diminished the size of this group.

1:~~~~~~~~~~~~ M:~~~~~~~~0 : 4 1 X - : ; : f ; V f 7 S S - S - 0S - * :V S U

Beforet reform, Mexico's Ministry Of C i ations was responsie for polcmaking, reglation, and some

aspects of operation of telecommuniationsserces.0 ThisperietheMisy toinunTl es lopeatand

I finnial decisions. When the Governent privatized Tlmex anditroduced cpeti the policy-making, rla-tory, anFd operating functions needed4to Ibesearated.

Thei 0 government's efforts to stieainii andreiWftegulatofmeworklhad three majorFirst, teregulator relinquished direct participaion kinthe construions of newvorks and piaized tele cations services

tsly been provide d ircty,such ast federlmicrowave netwr.Se:cond the rulesunder wch Telrnex operated were reformed. ric capreulatio ttsforntwokeansin quatereapiewta comniitmgot to gradually opei up ct itag all telecommucatonssrces. Telex was alsogranted aconcessiontoop reeaerate a cellulr is.f t ions:re n

was passed to complement the Geneal icatoas Law Theseaid outthe tso t th govern-mrinet and thleconditions for competition inthesector s

n 0 ;Malaysia, the legal frameworks for the regulation and corporatization of telecommunications were establshedgsitnu,ltaneoly through three legal acts, The 1985 am nt heTleomuiatinsAct of10rfrmuaed theTelEeommunications Department of 6Malia as the sole regltory afuthoitd edefinedt its funcions and power"Qw iinthe sector. The Ministry of Eneg Psts, andTelecomiuications'retained therihtto lenseoerators.. T1985 amendment to fthe PensionsA 8(madea ialpwIsoto peservhei e neflotmembers. The Teleconmunications Servie (Suessor Cimpany)Ac of 1985transerd the telco ationsoperatingbuswiness and associated assets 4and liabiltes from the former Tlecommunications Department to a new oper-aung company. In addition to these legal acthgovemment used adminiiv means to enale the new orating

compay to uncton as. a. Viable cocen

ource: Cassus 1994 .(Mexico) and Daudb

18 EXPLOITING NEW MARKET OPPORTUNITIES IN TELECOMMUNICATIONS

Page 29: Exploiting New Market Opportunities in Telecommunications...101 -Privatization in Tunisia, Jamal Saghir, 1993. 102 -Export Credits: Review and Prospects, Waman S. Tambe, Ning S. Zhu,

Creating New Constituencies fied, especially since many monopoly operators are highlyIt is to be expected that the threat of dismantling a large inefficient. Staff levels of 70 staff per 1000 lines are nottelecommunications monopoly will generate considerable uncommon in developing countries, compared with 5 or 6resistance to change, often at the highest administrative staff per 1000 lines for efficient, developed country opera-levels. The loss of unofficial perquisites and diminished tors. For example, India's telecommunications operatorpower can motivate considerable opposition. Usually, there employs nearly half a million workers (or about 56 staffare few people outside of the government operator with per 1000 lines). The staffing ratio of Tanzania's state tele-adequate knowledge of the workings of the sector and thus communications operator is over 70 per 1000 lines, andthe operator can use its knowledge and experience to ad- the ratio has been increasing over the past several years."1vantage to raise issues and concerns designed to block or Obtaining labor buy-in for the reform process first re-delay the reform momentum. quires involving labor representatives in the analysis of

In those countries where reforms have been success- policy options (inviting labor "inside the tent") and pre-ful, telecommunications has been approached from the user serving some of their major benefits (especially pensions).perspective. This approach forces reform initiatives to shift But reforms also provide an opportunity for radical rethink-out of the traditional telecommunications ministries or de- ing of labor-management relationships, especially by giv-partments. Where major changes have been implemented, ing labor a greater stake in the restructured operation (own-ministries representing user interests have been in the fore- ership stake or potential participation in increased profit-front of change. Finance ministries, for example, were ability). To be effective, the more radical approach requiresprominent both in New Zealand and Mexico. programs to increase the skills and flexibility of the

Australia created an independent regulatory body workforce by offering: (i) training and re-training, so that(Austel) and then wedged a "reformist bureaucracy" be- the full range of workers keeps up with the demands oftween Austel and the Government. Austel was an arm's new technologies, (ii) job placement programs to allow flex-length authority that created an appeal mechanism for me- ible redeployment of staff, and (iii) incentives to increasediation of conflicts between the government and market skills using methods like "productivity clauses" that offerplayers. The reformist bureaucracy took a proactive ap- merit-based pay raises.proach by creating communications between various in- In many cases, labor has been persuaded to acceptterested parties. Australia also developed two other inter- liberalization. In Mexico, a number of measures were takenesting consensus-building mechanisms: (i) a parliamen- to protect labor, and as a result, "the telephone workers'tary "Caucus committee" and subcommittees including union (STRM) supported the idea [of privatization] almostthose Members of Parliament who had worked in the sec- unanimously" (Galal, Jones, Tandon, and Vogelsang, 1994).tor, and (ii) a "ministerial advisory committee," acting as These protective measures were as follows:an extra-parliamentary mechanism to bring all interestgroups-operators, potential operators, and labor-"inside * A government commitment not to reduce staffing,the tent" to sound out ideas and generate consensus. made clear from the start;

Users have also directly pressed for reform. The Aus- .Worker participation in the capital of Telmex wheretralian Telephone User Group (ATUG) lobbied govern- 4.4 percent of the company's shares were sold to thement continuously to erode the power of the telecommu- union;nications monopoly and to seek improved conditions for Renegotiation of union contracts, reducing thebusiness. ATUG then took an active role in providing a number of contracts from 56 to a single one to beuser perspective dunng the reform implementation phase. negotiated once a yearIn Argentina in 1987, 17 banks had joined together to push negoti e nce a oyear;for new network facilities in Buenos Aires, preferably by a Re duce. ingjthetnum er tofocrateoriesrmo 5itonew operator (Cowhey 1993). Potential foreign investors 41 bseafunin jo tierefrom one function to another;and multinational development agencies have alerted thegovernment to the international community's interest in * Increased spending on worker retraining and skillsbecoming involved in improving India's telecommunica- development;tions services. * "Productivity clauses" to reward workers for high

performance.

Labor Acceptance of ReformOrganized labor can block reform or privatization of a state-owned telecommunications operator. Telecommunications 0The World Bank, Staff Appraisal Report The United Republicworkers everywhere fear that restructuring might mean lay- of Tanzania, Third Telecommunications Project; April 2, 1993, p.offs or harsher working conditions. This concern is justi- 16.

LESSONS FOR DEVELOPING COUNTRIES 19

Page 30: Exploiting New Market Opportunities in Telecommunications...101 -Privatization in Tunisia, Jamal Saghir, 1993. 102 -Export Credits: Review and Prospects, Waman S. Tambe, Ning S. Zhu,

In the end, the total number of workers declined only others, 1994, p. 528). Employees saw share bonuses andmarginally, and Telmex's real labor productivity, after stag- large wage increases in return for changes in working prac-nating from 1981 to 1988, rose sharply from 1989 through tices that allowed the company greater flexibility in labor1991. This balance was reached by growing the network allocation decisions.at least 12 percent per annum, introducing new labor-sav-ing technology, retraining workers to operate the new equip- LOOKING AHEADment, and implementing a union agreement that permit- In the world of telecommunications it is easy to be capti-ted re-assignment of workers. Labor gained significantly vated by the ingenuity of technical advances, of which therefrom the privatization process as well. One study found is an unending stream. Both the technology and econom-that the aggregate welfare change as a result of the privatiza- ics point to increasingly competitive provision of telecom-tion was worth 50.7 percent of sales; of this, Telmex work- munications services, and there can be little doubt that theers received 15.9 percent-just less than a third of the to- world is being relentlessly driven in that direction.tal gain through salary increases, profit sharing, and stock The stream of technical advances will be best exploitedappreciation (Galal and others 1994, Figure 23-1, p. 528). when regulatory restrictions on new entry and operations

In Malaysia, one goal of the overall privatization pro- are minimized. In the past, governments have oftencess was to prune the civil service, and telecommunica- thought it fit to prepare the ground by first restructuringtions workers saw this as a threat. But Telkom Malaysia and privatizing the existing operator before allowing com-was restructured without layoffs-99.9 percent of Telkom's petition. But especially where telephone penetration ratesgovernment employees accepted the package offered by are low, the early appearance of new players, operating onthe new corporation. The package was attractive because level terms with the incumbent, can provide much neededof Telkom's commitment to "no retrenchment for five phones, spur better performance from the incumbent, andyears" and to "terms no worse than pre-privatization" in reduce-though not eliminate-the burden of regulation.terms of pay, benefits, and pensions. In fact, both skilled The irony is that reform often proves most difficultand unskilled workers are better paid in the privatized just where phones are most scarce and where the creationTelkom than they were prior to privatization. of a new telecommunications regime might seem easiest

In the United Kingdom, labor relations prior to because of the small installed base. The message of thisprivatization were difficult not only within British Telecom- survey is that change requires institutional savvy, whichmunications but all around the country. British Telecom- balances many conflicting goals and interests. Though cer-munications has been reducing its labor force since 1981, tain practical measures to defuse these conflicts were de-when management unilaterally announced a plan to reduce scribed, a heavy burden is placed on policymakers and regu-the work force by 15,000 over a five-year period. Bargain- lators who will continue to face ever-emerging challenges.ing between the company and the unions continues to be This requires access to the best information, developmenthard, with at least one industrial action in 1987, Labor of new skills, and, most importantly, the institutional flex-still gained marginally from the privatization (Galal and ibility to evolve with the new conditions.

20 EXPLOITING NEw MARKET OPPORTUNITIES IN TELECOMMUNICATIONS

Page 31: Exploiting New Market Opportunities in Telecommunications...101 -Privatization in Tunisia, Jamal Saghir, 1993. 102 -Export Credits: Review and Prospects, Waman S. Tambe, Ning S. Zhu,

REFERENCES

Adonis, Andrew. 1994. "Indonesia's Fixed Cellular Revolution." Financial Times, August 15, 1994, p. 9.

Andersen Management International. 1993. The Future Development of the Telecommunication Sector in Ghana.

Armstrong, Mark and Chris Doyle. 1994. "Social Obligations and Access Pricing: Telecommunications and Railways inthe UK." Department of Economics, University of Southampton and Department of Economics, University ofCambridge.

Augenblick, Mark, Jill Abehouse Stem, and Jane Sullivan. 1994. "Strategies for Financing Telecommunications Infra-structure Development in the Pacific Rim." 16th Annual Pacific Telecommunications Conference, January 16-20,1994.

Banker, Rajiv D., Hsi-hui Chang, and Sumit Majumdar. 1992. "Returns to Scale in Telecommunications: Evidence andRamifications for the U.S. Local Exchange Sector." Mimeo., University of Michigan.

Baumol, William J. and J. Gregory Sidak. 1994. "The Pricing of Inputs Sold to Competitors." Yale Journal of Regulation11(1): 172-202, Winter.

Bell, Alan and Martin Cave. 1991. "Lessons from the UK Duopoly Review." Paper for CPR 1991 Conference in Nether-lands, 23-25 October.

Bin Ishhak, Daud. 1989. "Meeting the Challenges of Privatization in Malaysia." In Bjorn Wellenius and others, ed.Restructuring and Managing the Telecommunications Sector. Washington D.C.: The World Bank.

Boatman, Kara T. 1991. Telecommunications and Export Performance: An Empirical Investigation of Developing Countries.Ph.D Dissertation: University of Maryland, College Park.

Braeutigam, Ronald and John Panzar. 1993. "Effects of the Change from Rate-of-Return to Price-Cap Regulation."American Economic Review Papers and Proceedings, May: 191-198.

Broadman, Harry G. and Carol Balassa. 1993. "Liberalizing International Trade in Telecommunications Services." Co-lumbia Journal of World Business, Winter, pp. 31-37.

Bruce, Robert and Michael Harrell, and Zsuzsa Kovacs. 1993. "Who Will Win the Battle for Hungary's Telecoms Com-pany?" International Financial Law Review 7 (5): 25-27.

Casasus, Carlos. 1994. "Privatization of Telecommunications: the case of Mexico." In Bjom Wellenius and Peter Stern,eds. Implementing Reforms in the Telecommunications Sector: lessonsfrom expetience. Washington D.C.: The WorldBank.

Cave, Martin. 1991. "Regulating Competitin in Telecommunications: British Experience and its Lessons." EconomicAnalysis and Policy 21(2): 129-143.

LESSONS FOR DEVELOPING COUNTRIUES 21

Page 32: Exploiting New Market Opportunities in Telecommunications...101 -Privatization in Tunisia, Jamal Saghir, 1993. 102 -Export Credits: Review and Prospects, Waman S. Tambe, Ning S. Zhu,

Charnes, A., WW. Cooper, and T Sueyoshi. 1988. "A Goal Programming/Constrained Regression Review of the BellSystem Break-up." Management Science 34 (1): 1-26.

Cowhey, Peter. 1993. "Domestic Institutions and the Credibility of International Commitments: Japan and UnitedStates." International Organization 47 (2): 299-326.

Crandall, Robert W 1989. "Fragmentation of the Telephone Network." In Paula R. Newburg ed., "New Directions inTelecommunications Policy." Durham, N.C.: Duke University Press.

Dougan, Diana Lady and Susan Bruno, eds. 1991. "Trade, Telecom, and Mexico: the new bilateral menu." WashingtonD.C.: CSIS International Communications Studies Program.

Ergas, Henry. 1992. "France Telecom: Has the model worked?" Workshop on International Experiences in Telecommu-nications Reform and its relevance to India, November 21 and 22, New Delhi: Industrial Credit and InvestmentCorporation of India, Ltd.

Evans, David and James Heckman. 1984. 'A Test for the Subadditivity of the Cost Function with an Application to theBell System." American Economic Review 74 (4): 615-23.

Galal, Ahmed, Leroy Jones, Pankaj Tandon, and Ingo Vogelsang. 1994. Welfare Consequences of Selling Public Enterprises.New York: Oxford University Press.

Greenstein, Shane, Susan McMaster, and Pablo T. Spiller. "The Effect of Incentive Regulation on Local ExchangeCompanies' Deployment of Digital Infrastructure." AEI Telecommunications Summit. Washington D.C.: AmericanEnterprise Institute.

Hill, Alice and Manuel Angel Abdala. 1993. "Regulation, Institutions, and Commitment: Privatization and Regulation inthe Argentine Telecommunications Sector." Policy Research Working Paper 1216. Washington D.C.: World Bank.

Huber, Peter. W 1993. "Telecommunications Regulation: The Beginning of the End," Issues in Science and Technology,Fall.

International Telecommunications Union (ITU). 1994. World Telecommunications Development Report.

Kim, Cae-one, Young Kon Kim, and Chang-bun Yoon, 1992. " Korean Telecommunications Development: Achievmentsand cautionary lessons." World Development 20 (2): 1829-1841.

Mathios, Alan and Robert Rogers. 1989. "The Impact of Alternative Forms of State Regulation of AT&T onDirect-Dial,Long-Distance Telephone Rates." Rand Journal of Economics 20: 437-53.

Mody, Ashoka and Carl Dahlman. 1992. "Performance and Potential of Information Technology: An InternationalPerspective." World Development 20 (12): 1703-1719.

Mody, Ashoka and William Reinfeld. 1994. 'Advanced Infrastructure for Time Management: The Competitive Edge inEast Asia." CFS Discussion Papers, forthcoming, Washington D.C.: The World Bank.

Mody, Ashoka and Kamil Yilmaz. 1994. "Is There Persistence in Manufactured Goods Exports?" Policy Research WorkingPaper 1276, Washington D.C.: The World Bank, Policy Research Department.

Mueller, Milton. 1991. "Telecommunications Development Models and Telephone History: A response to the WorldBank." ICTMNews 2(2). International CenterforTelecommunications Management, University of Nebraska, Omaha.

22 EXPLOITING NEw MARKET OPPORTUNITIES IN TELECOMMUNICATIONS

Page 33: Exploiting New Market Opportunities in Telecommunications...101 -Privatization in Tunisia, Jamal Saghir, 1993. 102 -Export Credits: Review and Prospects, Waman S. Tambe, Ning S. Zhu,

Mueller, Milton. 1993. "On the Frontier of Deregulation: New Zealand Telecommunications and the Problem of Inter-connecting Competing Networks." Los Angeles: The Reason Foundation.

New Zealand Ministry of Commerce. 1992. "Telecommunications Information Leaflet No. 1." Wellington: Ministry ofCommerce.

O'Brien, Ross. 1994. "When Pride Holds the Purse Strings." Communications International, May 1994, pp. 54-57.

Office of Telecommunications (Oftel). 1992. "The Regulation of BT's Price." A Consultative Document, issued by theDirector General of Telecommunications, Office of Telecommunications, London.

Office of Telecommunications (Oftel). 1993. "Interconnection and Accounting Separation." A Consultative Document,issued by the Director General of Telecommunications, Office of Telecommunications, London.

Oniki, Hajime, Tae H. Oum, and Rodney Stevenson. 1990. "NTT's Productivity Performance". Wisconsin Working Paper1-90-2.

Schankerman, Mark. 1993. "Competition Through Regulatory Synmmetry: regulatory reform for local exchange carriers."London School of Economics.

Shew, William. 1994. "Regulation, Competition, and Prices in Cellular Telephony." Working Paper, AEI Studies in Tele-communications Deregulation. American Enterprise Institute, Washington D.C.

Sidak, Gregory. 1993. "Telecommunications in Jericho." California Law Review 81 (5): 1209-1239, October.

Takano, Yoshiro. 1992. "Nippon Telegraph and Telephone Privatization Study: Experience of Japan and Lessons for Devel-oping Countries." World Bank Discussion Papers 179, Washington D.C.: The World Bank.

Wellenius, Bjorn. 1991. "Telecommunications: World Bank Experience and Strategy." World Bank Discussion Paper 192,Washington D.C.: The World Bank.

Wheeler, David and Ashoka Mody. 1992. "International Investment Location Decisions: the case of U.S. Firms". Journalof International Economics 33 (1/2): 57-76.

Williamson, Maurice. 1993. "Telecommunications Reform in New Zealand."

Winston, Clifford. 1993. "Economic Deregulation: Days of Reckoning for Microeconomists." Journal of Economic Litera-ture 31 (September): 1263-1289.

World Bank. 1991. "Issues in Telecommunications Development: Policy Responses and Sector Strategy for Sub-SaharanAfrica". Industry and Energy Division Note No. 6, Africa Technical Department, Washington D.C.: The World Bank.

LESSONS FOR DEVELOPING COUNTRIES 23

Page 34: Exploiting New Market Opportunities in Telecommunications...101 -Privatization in Tunisia, Jamal Saghir, 1993. 102 -Export Credits: Review and Prospects, Waman S. Tambe, Ning S. Zhu,
Page 35: Exploiting New Market Opportunities in Telecommunications...101 -Privatization in Tunisia, Jamal Saghir, 1993. 102 -Export Credits: Review and Prospects, Waman S. Tambe, Ning S. Zhu,

II1,

Page 36: Exploiting New Market Opportunities in Telecommunications...101 -Privatization in Tunisia, Jamal Saghir, 1993. 102 -Export Credits: Review and Prospects, Waman S. Tambe, Ning S. Zhu,

The World Bank

HleadquLartcrs1818 H Street, N.W.\ashiil-ton. D.C_ '04. ., .SI CIlIplnne: (202) 477 1234Lax: (202) 477-639'1Iclcx: M\C(Il 64145 NVO()DI.A)IiNK

MCI 248423 \WORLD)BANK( 'ablc Addi-css: INIBAFRAl)

WVASI I I N'F ()N 1N(

European Office66, avcIe L 'IC lla

751 I 1 Par-is, Francclelcp lollc : ( 1) 40.69.30.00Facsimile: ( 1) 40.69.30.66I'cIc\: 640651

Tokyo OfficeKokUksai llfildJinm1-1. MarlLI]IOLICIbi 3-Chonie-l

ChiVojia-lUl, T0kVo 100, JapainI clclplollc: (3)) 3214-5001Facsimilc: (3) 32 14-3657'Felex: 26838