geog 3890 r23

Upload: alicechan28

Post on 08-Apr-2018

242 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

  • 8/7/2019 GEOG 3890 R23

    1/25

    Housing Inequality in Urban China: Guangzhou 1996 and 2005

    By

    Si-ming Li

    Department of Geography

    And

    Centre for China Urban and Regional Studies

    Hong Kong Baptist University

    October 2009

    Acknowledgements: The author would like to thank Miss Becky Pang who assisted in

    data analysis. This research is funded in part by Hong Kong Research Grants Council,

    Grant No. HKBU242907.

  • 8/7/2019 GEOG 3890 R23

    2/25

    Abstract

    Based on household surveys conducted in the City of Guangzhou in 1996 and 2005, this

    paper examines the changes in the extent and nature of urban housing inequality upon the

    cessation of the welfare allocation of housing in the southern gateway to China. The

    result shows that the overall level of housing inequality has remained quite stable. Both

    continuities and changes are revealed for the factors behind the differences in housing

    consumption. In particular, household income has assumed much greater importance.

    However, variables characterizing social and housing stratification in the former socialist

    planned economy, such as membership in the CCP and hukou status, continue to affect

    access to housing resource.

    Keywords: Housing inequality, Guangzhou, welfare allocation of housing, determinants

    of housing consumption

    Introduction

    China is undergoing unprecedented urban transformation. Official statistics put

    the total urban population at the end of 2006 at 577.06 million and an urbanization rate of

    43.9 percent. The corresponding figures for 1980, when the reform was about to begin,

    were 191.40 million and 19.39 percent. In other words, some 386 million people were

    added to Chinas urban areas over a period of 26 years. While the early reform years saw

    the revival of market towns and rapid growth of small cities in association with rapid

    development of rural or township and village enterprises, in more recent times especially

    since the mid 1990s growth has been concentrated in the countrys largest metropolitan

    2

  • 8/7/2019 GEOG 3890 R23

    3/25

    centres (Li, 2008; Gu et al, 2008). Between 2000 and 2004, the average population

    growth rate of super-large cities (cities with non-agricultural population1 exceeding 2

    million) reached 10.77 percent per annum. On the other hand, the population of small

    cities (cities with non-agricultural population less than 200,000) actually decreased by an

    average of 2.59 percent (Li, 2008, p. 362).

    Yet, despite the immense population pressure, the housing conditions for the

    average urban dweller in China have registered remarkable improvements over the past

    two decades. According to the Statistical Yearbook of China, the per capita housing space

    consumed in urban areas increased steadily from 3.6m

    2

    in 1978 to 10.0 m

    2

    in 1985, 16.3

    m2 in 1995, 20.8 m2 in 2001 and 26.1 m2 in 2005 (Li and Li, 2008, p. 384). Admittedly

    the official statistics refer to the situation of people with the properhukou, and it is well

    documented that migrants housing conditions are generally much worse (Wang et al,

    forthcoming). Nonetheless, the progress made is still immense. Census data also show

    that other aspects of housing conditions such as availability of separate toilet and kitchen

    inside the dwelling unit as well as home furnishing also manifest substantial gains.

    Moreover, the urban homeownership rate jumped from 24 percent in 1990 to 72 percent

    in 2000 and further to 82 percent in 2005 (Li and Li, 2008, p. 386). Underlying the huge

    increase in per capita housing space amidst phenomenal population growth are massive

    investments in housing construction. The 2000 Population Census shows that 47.6

    percent of the urban housing stock was less than 10 years old. In Shanghai, the largest

    city of the country, the figure was 51.3 percent (Li and Li, 2008, p. 387). The pace of

    1 Chinas hukou or household registration system comprises a dual classification, firstly the differentiation

    the population into agricultural and non-agricultural, and secondly into local and non-local (see, for

    example, Chan, 2009). With the massive increase in migration and the encroachment of urban areas into

    surrounding farmlands, many holding the agricultural status are no longer peasants. Yet, officially they are

    still considered agricultural by virtual of their hukou status.

    3

  • 8/7/2019 GEOG 3890 R23

    4/25

    housing construction accelerated even further in the new millennium. New housing starts

    by real estate developers increased from 188.0 million m2 in 1999 to 551.6 m2 in 2005,

    and the total number of commodity housing completions between 1999 and 2005 reached

    19.88 million units (Li and Li, 2008, p. 399).

    Surely, the improvements are unlikely to be evenly felt among all segments of the

    population. Some would have benefited more while others much less. For certain groups

    the housing conditions could be even worse than before. While there existed housing and

    other inequalities under the former socialist redistributive economy, the nature of housing

    inequality in China today is much more complicated, with market forces playing an

    increasingly influential role. The gradualist and incremental nature of Chinas reform

    (Zhu, 1999), particularly the continuing domination of the Chinese Communist Party

    (CCP or Party) and the state over economy and society, however, implies that the nature

    of housing inequality in China is unlikely to be the same as that in Western countries.

    In China under Mao the major social cleavage was the rural-urban divide, which

    was underpinned by both the hukou or household registration system and a price system

    variously known as scissors difference, which favoured urban-industrial goods over

    primary commodities (Chan, 1992). Only people with non-agricultural hukou would be

    provided with grain rations and assigned to a danwei or work unit (Lu and Perry, 1992).

    The latter, which could be a state or Party organ or a state enterprise, was much more

    than an employer. It also acted as the single most important institution performing

    redistribution functions as well as exercising social and political control. The great

    majority of urban dwellers were danwei members, and lived in danwei-provided housing

    within the respective danwei compounds.

    4

  • 8/7/2019 GEOG 3890 R23

    5/25

    While most danwei dwellings were of similar size and quality, the lopsided

    emphasis on production over consumption resulted in perennial severe housing shortage

    (Chan, 1992). Not every danwei member would be able to secure a danwei flat. Priority

    in the allocation ofdanwei housing was based on job rank, seniority, Party affiliation and

    rank in the Party, and recognized contribution to the state. Also, not every danwei was

    equally endowed with resources. Enterprises not in industries top on the development

    agenda were deprived of resources. Housing conditions in such danwei tended to be

    much worse than those that were emphasized. But it was those people without danwei

    housing who had to stay in dilapidated housing inherited from pre-1949 times, the great

    majority of which came under the control of the municipal housing bureau upon the

    socialist transformation of the 1950s, endured the worst housing conditions (Li and Li,

    2008; Bian and Logan, 1996).

    Accompanying the economic reform was reform in urban housing provision.

    Initially the reform focussed on the supply side, with the establishment of real estate

    companies to replace individual danwei as the main developers of new housing. Yet most

    commodity housing units built by the real estate companies was bought by the danwei for

    subsequent allocation as a welfare item to their workers. With the promulgation of the

    Views on Nationwide Implementation of Urban Housing Reform in 1991 and the

    Decision on Deepening Urban Housing Reform in 1994, the emphasis of the reform

    gradually shifted to the demand side, with homeownership promotion being a major

    objective. Danwei were encouraged to sell their housing stock to sitting tenants at highly

    discounted price and provide substantial assistance those currently without danwei

    housing to purchase in the open market. Housing thus sold is termed reform housing.

    5

  • 8/7/2019 GEOG 3890 R23

    6/25

    Established criteria such as job rank and seniority in the workplace were important

    considerations in prioritizing the sale of reform housing and the price charged (Wang and

    Murie, 1999; Li and Li, 2008).

    In 1998 the State Council called for the ending of the welfare allocation of

    housing. That is to say, danwei would cease to provide subsidized housing to their

    workers. From then onwards, most households have to satisfy their housing needs

    through buying or renting in the market. Under such circumstances, wealth and income,

    which have become increasingly polarized under the reform, are likely to become the

    most important determinants of housing consumption. Although municipal governments

    have continued and even expanded the comfortable housing scheme under which

    selected housing development projects would be put on sale to low and middle income

    households at prices some 30 percent below prevailing market levels, such housing

    remained quite expensive and beyond the reach of the target population. The last two

    years of the twentieth century saw workers in state-owned enterprises and state and Party

    organizations stampeding to buy reform housing, a phenomenon variously known as

    catching the last train (Li and Yi, 2007). Of course, there were those retirees and low

    income workers, as well as those who were forced to be permanently off duty or

    xiagangbecause of plant closures or firm restructuring in conjunction with the enterprise

    reform of the mid and late 1990s. Expectedly, these people could not afford to buy even

    with the big discounts.

    In the early 2000s, one city after another, reform housing was given full property

    right and allowed to enter the market. With the huge difference between the market and

    subsidized price, this is tantamount to the conferment of windfall profits to the former

    6

  • 8/7/2019 GEOG 3890 R23

    7/25

    purchasers of reform housing, who are now able to trade their reform housing unit for

    spacious commodity housing in a well landscaped and well maintained gated housing

    estate. This, together with phenomenal increases in housing price, has many times

    magnified wealth inequality in urban China, which now increasingly manifests in terms

    of housing tenure and the value of the dwelling the individual owns (Li, 2007). It may be

    argued that people who did well in the former socialist planned economy are doing even

    much better in the present socialist market economy. Those who were left behind in the

    latest round of housing reform have to live with their dilapidating dwellings or wait for

    resettlement to remote suburbs upon redevelopment of their existing premises.

    The discussion so far has been concerned with people with the properhukou. The

    reform has brought hundreds of millions of migrants from the countrys vast rural

    hinterlands to the major metropolitan centres. A two-class society comprising those with

    and without the properhukou today characterizes all major cities in China (Chan, 2009)

    The great majority of the migrant population suffer from discrimination in both the job

    and housing markets. In particular, subsidized housing is largely out of reach to the

    migrant population. And, given the high price, formal market housing is unaffordable to a

    large proportion of migrants. Many have to be contented with substandard housing with

    dubious legal status in the urban villages on the former urban-rural fringe (Jie and

    Taubmann, 2002).

    The highly complicated and varied housing consumption scene resulting from the

    different phases of economic and housing reform described above points towards not

    only heightened housing inequality but also both continuities and changes in the nature of

    housing inequality. Based on data derived from household surveys conducted

    7

  • 8/7/2019 GEOG 3890 R23

    8/25

    Guangzhou in 1996 and 2005, the present paper attempts to provide quantitative

    indicators measuring the extent of such changes. It may be noted that in the earlier survey

    year most commodity housing built was first sold to individual danwei, which then rented

    or sold the housing to their workers. In the latter year the market dominated both the

    supply and demand sides. Thus, comparisons based on the two surveys provide allow us

    to gauge the difference in the extent and nature of housing inequality between a system

    which is primarily market based and one in whichdanwei and other socialist

    redistributive institutions still dominated the housing provision scene. The following

    section details how the two surveys were conducted and discusses the comparability of

    the two datasets. The empirical analysis is divided into two parts, first on the overall

    pattern of housing inequality in the two survey years, and second on the changes in the

    nature of housing inequality between the two years.

    Data

    Both the 1996 and 2005 Guangzhou surveys were conducted through household

    interviews with the assistance of the Centre of Urban and Regional Studies at Sun Yat-sen

    University, which had substantial experience in doing household interviews

    established connections with government departments at the municipal, district and

    street-committee levels of the city. Such connections were essential for obtaining the

    requisite data for the construction of a reliable sampling frame as well as for obtaining

    the permission to undertake the household interviews.

    Strictly speaking, the two surveys were targeting at two different types of housing

    and hence populations. More specifically, the 1996 survey only covered n

    8

  • 8/7/2019 GEOG 3890 R23

    9/25

    constructed commodity housing, that is, housing put up by developers for sale at market

    price. But the 1996 survey was carried out prior to the ending of the welfare allocation of

    housing. While some work units continued to build housing for their workers, in

    Guangzhou supply-side commodification was well under way. The bulk of new housing

    supply was provided by real estate developers, although the main buyers remained the

    individual danwei. In the sample only about 25 percent of the households purchased or

    rented directly in the open market (Li, 2000). The rest remained within the subsidized

    housing sector. In this sense, the 1996 sample still provided a snapshot of the general

    housing situation of Guangzhou at the time of survey, despite its specificity. Surely,

    caution has to be exercised in interpreting the findings based on the survey. By definition,

    all respondents interviewed were recent movers. Moreover, they were either those who

    were privileged enough to be assigned by the given danwei or municipal housing bureau

    new apartments, or those who were able to purchase or rent in the open market. All these

    suggest a built-in bias towards the better-to-do groups. As such, the degree of housing

    inequality revealed by the sample is likely to be an underestimate of the true extent.

    However, by introducing statistical controls in a multivariate setting, it is still possible to

    provide reasonable estimates of the effects of individual factors on housing consumption.

    The sampling frame was constructed by reference to the list of presale commodity

    housing projects issued by the Municipal Land and Housing Administration Bureau over

    the period January 1992 - August 1994. The target sample size was 1000 housing units

    (and hence 1000 households). A multi-level probability proportional to size (PPS)

    sampling strategy was adopted. In particular, the sample was designed so that the number

    of housing units surveyed in each of the eight urban districts of Guangzhou at that time

    9

  • 8/7/2019 GEOG 3890 R23

    10/25

    was proportional to the total number of presale housing units in the given district. Within

    each urban district, a number of urban streets (or sub-districts) were selected as sampling

    spatial clusters on a randomized basis, according to the size distribution of the sub-

    districts in respect to the number of housing units. Finally, each cluster contained 25

    sampled housing units, again selected on a randomized basis. This geographically based

    sampling strategy ensured adequate representation of different types of residential areas

    in different parts of the city. Included in the questionnaire were a wide range of questions

    on various aspects of housing consumption as well as on the socio-demographic attributes

    and employment characteristics of each member of the household. It took on average 45-

    50 minutes to complete an interview.

    In comparison, the 2005 survey was a more general survey, with the target

    population being all households in Guangzhou. Again, a multi-level PPS sampling

    strategy was adopted. Street- or Sub-district-level tabulations provided by the Public

    Security Bureau on the size distribution of households (including those without the local

    hukou or household registration status) over the former eight urban districts plus the

    newly incorporated districts of Panyu were used to construct the sampling frame. The

    target sample size was 1200, to be distributed according to the PPS principle over the

    nine urban districts surveyed. Again, for a given urban district a number of spatial

    clusters or urban streets were selected and then for each selected cluster 25 households

    were sampled following the PPS principle on a randomized basis. Comparison with data

    given by the 2005 One Percent Sample Census shows reasonably closed correspondence

    (Li, forthcoming). However, although the Guangzhou survey under-sampled migrants

    without properhukou in the city; this is largely because only households residing in

    10

  • 8/7/2019 GEOG 3890 R23

    11/25

    permanent housing were interviewed. It may be argued that the 2005 Guangzhou survey

    provides a reasonably good snapshot of the housing consumption pattern in the city at the

    time of survey. The questionnaire employed was constructed with reference to the one

    used in the 1996 survey, although the 2005 questionnaire tried to elicit detailed

    information also on residential and employment history.

    Overall Housing Inequality

    Housing is a multi-dimensional good. Size of dwelling, type of structure in which

    the dwelling is located, internal design, decoration and furnishing, dwelling age and state

    of maintenance, estate and neighbourhood amenities, accessibility to employment and

    shopping facilities, etc. are all important dimensions affecting how much and what kind

    of housing service a dwelling provides. While it is not absolutely essential, the

    construction of a composite measure would facilitate the comparison of the state of

    housing well being between individuals and households, and hence the assessment of

    housing inequality.

    Commonly employed in the analysis of housing demand is the price or rent

    (annualized price) of the dwelling unit. Hedonic theory argues that the price of a

    dwelling, which is the outcome of the interplay between a myriad of supply and demand

    factors, can be seen as the summation of the values attached to individual housing

    attributes (Olsen, 1987; Straszheim, 1973). Thus, price or value is commonly used as a

    measure of the composite good, housing service. However, the use of the price variable

    presumes the presence of a more or less competitive market, which is clearly not the case

    in China where the state continues to exert substantial influence on the land and housing

    11

  • 8/7/2019 GEOG 3890 R23

    12/25

    market and where collusion between real estate developers and local government is

    prevalent. The price variable was particularly problematic in 1996 when the great

    majority of housing was sold by danwei and the municipal housing bureau to sitting

    tenants at heavily discounted prices.

    In this study dwelling floor area (in m2) is used to gauge the amount of housing

    service consumed. Admittedly this is not a perfect measure. But this is a variable that is

    more readily susceptible to inter-temporal comparison. The fact that the 1996 survey

    included only newly completed housing whereas the 2005 survey tried to proportionately

    include all types of housing could render the comparison somewhat problematic.

    However, Guangzhou, along with other major cities in the country, has experienced a

    housing construction boom unseen elsewhere in the world. The housing stock is very

    new, mostly built in the 1990s and beyond. The massive scale of housing construction in

    recent years has introduced a degree of standardization in the floor space measure for the

    two surveys.

    Between the two survey years the Chinese economy and society had undergone

    tremendous changes. Almost incessant double-digit over the period growth not only

    resulted in a general increase in income, but it also brought about much greater

    concentration of wealth towards business proprietors, managers of major state-owned

    enterprises, and people with access to valuable business and state information and with

    close connections to government at different levels. Further, the enterprise reform of the

    1990s and the growth of the foreign-funded enterprises, which tended to reward the top

    managers and sought-after professionals remuneration packages mimicking those in their

    home countries, led to much enlarged income spread. On the housing front, the 1998

    12

  • 8/7/2019 GEOG 3890 R23

    13/25

    reform ended the welfare allocation of housing. Since then, wealth and income have

    probably become the single most important factors underlying housing consumption. All

    these argue for a substantial increase in housing inequality.

    Figures 1a and 1b plot the distribution of dwelling floor space in the two samples.

    The mean floor space consumed increased slightly from 58.9 m2 for the 1996 sample to

    62.3 m2 for the 2005 sample. But this rather small increase has to be judged against the

    fact that the 1996 data were only concerned with newly completed commodity housing

    units, which were of better quality and generally larger than the pre-1949 old dwellings as

    well as danwei apartments built in earlier times. Also, the data and probably pertain to the

    better-to-do groups. It may be safe to conclude that the overall improvement in housing

    consumption is substantially larger than the difference in the mean value between the two

    samples. The corresponding standard deviations were 22.93 m2 and 25.81 m2,

    respectively. Thus, while in both years there existed quite substantial variations in the

    level of housing consumption, the difference between the haves and have-nots appeared

    not to be too extreme.

    Figures. 1a and 1b: The distribution of dwelling floor space in 1996 and 2005

    13

  • 8/7/2019 GEOG 3890 R23

    14/25

    The coefficient of variation (CV), defined as standard deviation divided by the

    mean value, is a commonly employed measure of inequality. The CV increased slightly

    from 0.39 for the 1996 sample to 0.41 for the 2005 sample. The slight increase in the CV,

    again, has to be judged against the difference in the target populations of the two surveys.

    Above it was argued that the 1996 sample would probably bias the inequality estimate

    downward. If this is indeed the case, then it is safe to conclude that the increase in

    housing inequality was likely to be even smaller than what the difference in CV suggests.

    Another commonly employed measure of inequality is the Gini coefficient, which ranges

    from 0 (absolute equality) to 1.0 (absolute inequality). Both samples yield a Gini

    coefficient of 0.21, again indicating stable and relatively mild housing inequality levels,

    irrespective of the massive changes that had taken place both in the housing and job

    markets between the two survey years.

    This is a rather surprising finding. In both samples migrants were unde

    represented. The degree of housing inequality revealed would be substantially higher if

    the sampling bias was corrected. But this would not materially affect the conclusion that

    the degree of housing inequality in Guangzhou remained more or less the same between

    1996 and 2005. Perhaps it may be noted that neither the CV nor the Gini coefficient

    computed takes into consideration spatial variations and hence accessibility to jobs,

    schools, medical services, shopping and neighbourhood amenities. In Guangzhou and

    other cities of the country, almost all good schools and hospitals as well as up-market

    shopping facilities and entertainment centres, in addition to the bulk of high status

    administrative and managerial jobs, are located within or close to the inner core (Li and

    Li, forthcoming). Previous studies reveal strong residential preference for centra

    14

  • 8/7/2019 GEOG 3890 R23

    15/25

    locations in the city, which implies steep rent gradients (Wang and Li, 2006). Dwellings

    with the same floor space in central locations and those in distance suburbs yield quite

    different levels of utility to the household. To the extent that better-off households are

    able to reside in highly priced commodity housing in redeveloped inne

    neighbourhoods while large numbers ofxiagangworkers and retirees have been forced to

    relocate to far-flung suburbs lacking amenities, the actual degree of housing equality in

    more recent years could be a lot more severe than was indicated by the CV or Gini

    coefficient reported above. Moreover, market-led redevelopment has turned many inner-

    city neighbourhoods and former work-unit compounds to homogeneous housing estates,

    both in terms of socioeconomic composition and dwelling size. As a result, the

    geographical distance between the better-to-does and the less-well-offs has probably

    increased by a wide margin. This increase in residential differentiation could greatly

    heighten the sense of injustice especially among the deprived.

    Changes in the Nature of Inequality

    The same level of housing inequality could arise from different underlying

    factors. This section reports the result of multiple regression analysis, which analyses the

    determinants of housing consumption in the two survey years. Previous works on housing

    demand suggest that demographic characteristics such as household size, age of the

    household head, and stage in the family life cycle are fundamental in determining

    housing needs and preferences and hence the amount of housing consumed (Clark and

    Dieleman, 1996). Of course, in a market setting, income is of paramount importance.

    Studies conducted in the United States show that the income elasticity of the demand for

    15

  • 8/7/2019 GEOG 3890 R23

    16/25

    housing service is in the region of 0.7, that is, an 1 percent increase in income will result

    in 0.7 percent increase in housing consumption, other things being constant (Olsen,

    1987). Education attainment, as a measure of human capital, is a major determinant of

    income; in addition, education also structures residential preferences and the ability to

    make appropriate housing decisions under fast-changing market conditions. Occupational

    status is another constituent component in assessing socioeconomic status. Multinational

    firms generally offer subsidized housing to expatriate workers and high ra

    managerial and professional staff.

    In a socialist redistributive economy, rank in the work unit and the CCP largely

    determines the ability to command redistributive powers (Szelenyi, 1983; Bian and

    Logan, 1996). Advancement along the job ladder is closely tied to formal education

    credentials when the ability to generate profit is not a major concern. In the case of

    China, studies using data of the 1980s and 1990s have found all three variables, namely,

    education, occupational rank and CCP membership, to be major determinants of urban

    housing consumption (Bian and Logan, 1996; Huang and Clark, 2003; Li, 2000; Li and

    Li, 2006). Another variable which is of importance in structuring access to resource under

    state socialism is the nature of the work unit to which an individual is affiliated. Priority

    sectors are better endowed with resources. Also, national-level state enterprises are much

    better resourced than provincial-level ones, which, in turn, are much better resourced than

    enterprises established by city and county authorities. Collective enterprises,

    enterprises set up by street committees in urban areas and township authorities in rural

    areas, are the least resourced (Bian and Logan, 2003; Li and Li, 2008). Of course, there is

    hukou status, which assumes particular importance with hundreds of millions of migrants

    16

  • 8/7/2019 GEOG 3890 R23

    17/25

    of rural origin flocking to the countrys largest metropolitan centres.

    In the regression models the dependent variable is log (dwelling floor space)

    (m2).2 The independent variables include: (1) age, household size, family type (0 = family

    with children, 1 = otherwise); (2) log (household income per annum) (RMB 10000); (3)

    education (0 = tertiary, 1 = primary or lower, 2 = junior secondary, 3 = senior secondary);

    (4) occupational rank (0 = cadre or managerial, 1 = unskilled worker 2 = skilled worker, 3

    = professional, 4 = others); (5) danwei type (0 = non-state, 1 = state); (6) source of

    housing provision (0 = danwei, 1 = market, 2 = municipal housing bureau, 3 = others);

    and (7) membership in the CCP (0 = non-member, 1 = member), and (8) hukou (0 = non-

    local, 1 = local). The results are given in Table 1. The estimated equations for both years

    are highly significant. While the R2 obtained are not very high, 0.33 for 1996 and 0.31

    for 2005, they are quite acceptable for regressions employing micro-level

    Nonetheless, the exclusion of location variables in the model probably reduces the

    goodness of fit.

    Table 1.Linear regression analysis in 1996 and 2005

    1996 2005

    Independent variable: log dwelling floor space

    (square meters)

    R square = 0.327 R square = 0.305

    B B

    Age of head 0.003** 0.000

    Household size 0.051*** 0.060***

    Family type: married with children -0.048 0.014

    Log (Household income per annum) (RMB 10000) 0.136*** 0.187***

    Education

    Primary or lower N.A. 0.036

    Junior secondary -0.099** -0.064

    2 The logarithmic scale gives better fit than the linear scale. Also with income also expressed in logarithmic

    scale the associated parameter gives the income elasticity estimate. The parameters of other variables give

    the percentage change in floor space resulting from one unit change of the respective variable, which is

    more easily to be subject to inter-temporal comparison.

    17

  • 8/7/2019 GEOG 3890 R23

    18/25

    Senior secondary -0.145*** -0.003

    Occupation rank

    Unskilled worker -0.098** -0.048

    Skilled worker -0.155*** -0.038

    Professional -0.022 0.022

    Others -0.095* -0.110

    Danwei type: state 0.007 -0.010

    Source of housing provision

    Market -0.040* 0.140***

    Municipal Housing Bureau -0.342 -0.271***

    Others -0.065 0.138***

    Membership in the CCP 0.106*** 0.113***

    Hukou: local -0.266*** 0.119***

    CONSTANT 3.892*** 1.713***

    *significant level at 0.05; ** significant level at 0.01; ***significant level at 0.001

    Let us first consider the demographic attributes. Age, which correlated closely

    with seniority in the workplace especially under low or non-existent job mobility in the

    former centrally planned economy, is highly significant and positive for the 1996

    equation. Numerically, every 10 years increase in age was associated with 4 percent

    increase in housing space. However, age is not significant in the 2005 equation and the

    coefficient estimate is close to zero. Probably this is because danwei provision of housing

    was no longer common in the latter year. Household size is significant in both equations.

    In terms of magnitude, in 1996 one extra person was associated with 5.6 percent more

    floor space; in 2006 the corresponding figure was 3.4 percent. With respect to family

    type, in both years no significant difference was found between families with and without

    children. However, individuals who were single or widowed consumed slightly more

    housing space in 1996 but substantially less housing space (19.7 percent less in

    comparison with families with children) in 2005. The latter finding is more akin to the

    situation in most market economies.

    18

  • 8/7/2019 GEOG 3890 R23

    19/25

    Next, we examine household income. While the variable is significant and

    positive in both equations, the magnitude of influence differs tremendously. In 1996, the

    parameter estimate, which gives the income elasticity of demand for housing, was 0.14,

    whereas in 2005 it increased to 0.18. As the income measured employed refers to current

    income rather than permanent income, the true income elasticity in Guangzhou in both

    years would be somewhat higher than these estimates. As expected, income has become

    increasingly important in determining housing consumption in China, although the 2005

    estimate, if allowed for under-estimation, is still somewhat below those obtained in

    Western economies.

    Education attainment was a highly significant variable in 1996. People with

    tertiary education had much higher level of housing consumption than did people

    without. But in 2005, all education dummies were insignificant. Education probably

    continued to play a significant role in determining a persons occupation and income and

    through this on housing consumption; however, its direct effect was no longer obvious

    with the deepening of the market-oriented reform.

    The occupational status dummies generally yield the expected sign. In both years

    managerial and professional workers enjoyed significantly more housing space than

    either non-skilled or skilled workers. The differences, after controlling for income and

    other variables, are larger in the 1996 equation than in the 2005 equation. This suggests

    the diminishing effects of pure job ranking on housing consumption, a finding which is

    not too dissimilar with the finding on education attainment reported above.

    None of the danwei dummies in either equation is significant. In Guangzhou, even

    back in 1996, nature ofdanwei (whether being a state work unit or not) did not have any

    19

  • 8/7/2019 GEOG 3890 R23

    20/25

    significant influence on how much housing an individual consumed. Source of housing

    provision, however, was a major determinant of housing consumption in both years.

    More specifically, housing provided by the municipal housing bureau (accounting for 7.8

    percent of the 1996 sample and 7.7 percent of the 2005 sample), was smaller than

    housing provided by individual danwei by 33.9 percent in 1996 and 26.4 percent of the

    sample in 2005. Housing obtained in the market (accounting for 42.9 percent of the 1996

    sample and 60.8 percent of the 2005 sample), which did not differ too much in size from

    housing from danwei in 1996, was 14.1 percent larger in 2005. In other words, people

    who were able to move from municipal and danwei housing to market housing, including

    those who trade their reform housing unit for better dwellings in the market, were those

    who gained most in terms of floor space consumed.

    Previous works established the importance of CCP membership in access to

    housing resource. In both regression equations, CCP membership (which accounts for

    23.1 percent of the 1996 sample and 15.1 percent of the 2005 sample) is significant at the

    0.001 level. Also the magnitude of influence is about the same: 10.0 percent for the 1996

    equation and 11.9 percent for the 2005 equation. Considering that membership in the

    CCP probably also affects promotion prospects, the total effect of CCP membership on

    housing consumption in Guangzhou is quite substantial, despite the drive towards

    marketization and the neoliberal rhetoric in conjunction with globalization.

    Finally, there is hukou status. Surprisingly, the coefficient estimate for the 1996

    equation is negative and significant at the 0.001 level, although the one for the 2005

    equation is positive and of marginal significance. Of course, the rather surprising finding

    for 1996 may indicate that while migrants at the time were discriminated in the job

    20

  • 8/7/2019 GEOG 3890 R23

    21/25

    market, and because of this, lived in relatively poor housing, housing discrimination per

    se was not apparent. However, this was probably due to the fact that the 1996 sample

    only contained recently built commodity housing, and the migrants included in the

    sample were the better off groups. Similar but smaller selectivity bias was likely to be

    present in the 2005 sample. Migrants who did not have permanent residence were

    excluded from the survey. Nonetheless, the findings do suggest that for those migrants

    who are able to establish themselves in the city and move up the job ladder, their housing

    lots probably are not too different from those holding the properhukou.

    Concluding Remarks

    The results of the statistical analysis using the 1996 and 2005 survey data reveal

    both quite surprising findings and those in line with expectation. Regarding the overall

    level of housing inequality, the two surveys yield similar CVs and almost identical Gini

    coefficients. Both measures indicate relative mild levels of inequality in the two years. At

    least in the case of Guangzhou, which was relatively advanced in its transition to a

    housing regime based primarily on market provision back in 1996, the newest phase of

    the reform which called for the cessation of the welfare allocation apparently has not

    worsened significantly housing inequality. Most people have been able to benefit from

    the improvement in housing space brought about by the massive housing construction

    boom in recent years. Of course, in cities where the state sectors had a total dominance

    over the economy and society, and where the danwei provision of housing was much

    more entrenched, the enterprise reform and the latest marketization move in the housing

    realm could bring about vastly different effects on housing distribution.

    21

  • 8/7/2019 GEOG 3890 R23

    22/25

    With respect to the individual factors affecting housing consumption, life-cycle

    effects have remained relatively weak, although singles (including widowed) in the latter

    year consumed much less housing space than family households. Income has assumed

    greater importance, but the income elasticity of demand in 2005 was still quite low, even

    if the income measure employed refers to current rather than permanent income.

    Education per se in the latter year no longer yielded significant effect on dwelling floor

    space. Occupational rank remained to be effective, however, the magnitude of influence

    also declined. All these point towards greater market influence on housing consumption

    than in 1996. But, CCP member remained a major factor affecting housing space

    consumed, and the magnitude of influence in 2005 was even slightly larger than in the

    1996. On the whole, it may be concluded that the nature of housing inequality in

    Guangzhou differed very little between the two years.

    22

  • 8/7/2019 GEOG 3890 R23

    23/25

    References:

    Bian, Yanjie, and John R. Logan. 1996. Market Transition and Income Inequality in

    Urban China. American Sociological Review 61:759-78.

    Chan, Kam Wing, 1992, Economic growth strategy and urbanization policy in China,

    1949-82, International Journal of Urban and Regional Research, 16 (2): 275-305.

    Chan, Kam Wing, 2009, The Chinese hukou system at 50, Eurasian Geography and

    Economics, 50 (2): 197-221

    Chan, Kam Wing and Will Buckingham, 2008, Is China abolishing the hukou system?

    The China Quarterly, 195: 582-606.

    Clark, William A V and Frans M Dieleman, 1996, Households and Housing: Choice and

    Outcomes in the Housing Market. New Brunswick, New Jersey: Rutgers.

    Gu, Chaolin, Taofang Yu and Wangming Li, 2008, Zhongguo Chengshihua: Geju,

    Guocheng, Jili (Chinas Urbanization: Patterns, Processes and Mechanisms).

    (Bejing: Keshuchubanshe)

    Huang, Youqin and William A V Clark, 2003, Housing tenure choice in transitional

    China: a multilevel analysis, Urban Studies, 18 (1): 103-106

    Jie, Fan and Wolfgang Taubmann, 2002, Migrant enclaves in large Chinese cities. In: The

    New Chinese City: Globalization and Market Reform. Ed. John R Logan.

    (Oxford, England: Blackwell), pp. 137-152.

    Li, Limei and Si-ming Li, forthcoming, The impact of variations in urban registration

    within cities. In: Martin K Whyte, ed. One Country, Two Societies? Rural-Urban

    Inequality in Contemporary China. (Cambridge, Mass: Harvard University Press)

    23

  • 8/7/2019 GEOG 3890 R23

    24/25

    Li, Si-ming, 2000, The housing market and tenure decision in Chinese Cities: A

    multivariate analysis of the case of Guangzhou, Housing Studies. 15 (2): 213-

    236.

    Li, Si-ming, 2007, Transition to homeownership: implications for wealth redistribution.

    In: Fulong Wu, ed., Chinas Emerging Cities: The Making of New Urbanism.

    London and New York: Routledge, pp. 143-160.

    Li, Si-ming, 2008, Zhongguo de chengshihua yu chengshi fazhan (Urbanization and

    urban development in China), in: Chixu yu Bianqian: Dandai Zhongguo de

    Zhengjing, Shehui yu Kongjian Fazhan(Continuity and Change: Political-

    Economic, Social and Spatial Development in Contemporary China). Eds. Si-

    ming Li, Feng Chen and Yat-ming Siu. (Hong Kong: Hong Kong Educational

    Publishers), pp. 348-382.

    Li, Si-ming, forthcoming 2010, Evolving residential and employment locations and

    patterns of commute under hyper growth: the case of Guangzhou, China, Urban

    Studies.

    Li, Si-ming and Limei Li, 2006, Life course and housing tenure change in urban China: a

    case study of Guangzhou, Housing Studies A, 21 (5): 653-670.

    Li, Limei and Si-ming Li, 2008, Zhongguo chengzhen zhufang zhidu gaige: huigu yu

    pingjia (Chinas urban housing reform: retrospect and evaluation), in: Chixu yu

    Bianqian: Dandai Zhongguo de Zhengjing, Shehui yu Kongjian Fazh

    (Continuity and Change: Political-Economic, Social and Spatial Development in

    Contemporary China). Eds. Si-ming Li, Feng Chen and Yat-ming Siu. (Hong

    24

  • 8/7/2019 GEOG 3890 R23

    25/25

    Kong: Hong Kong Educational Publishers), pp. 348-382.

    Lu, Xiaobo and Elizabeth J Perry, 1997, Danwei: the Changing Chinese Workplace in

    Historical and Comparative Perspective. Armonk, New York: M E Sharp.

    Olsen, Edgar O, 1987, The demand and supply of housing service: a critical survey of the

    empirical literature. Handbook of Regional and Urban Economics. Ed. E S Mills.

    (Amsterdam and New York: Elsvier Science Publishers BV), pp. 988- 1022.

    Straszheim, Mahlon, 1973, Estimation of the demand for urban housing services from

    household interview data. Review of Economics and Statistics, 55: 1-8.

    Szelenyim Ivan, 1983, Urban Inequality under State Socialism. Oxford, England: Oxford

    University Press.

    Wang, Donggen and Si-ming Li, 2006, Housing reform, socio-economic differentials, and

    stated housing preferences in Guangzhou, China. Habitat International, 30: 305-

    326.

    Wang, Ya Ping, Yanglin Wang and Jianshen Wu, forthcoming, Housing migrant workers

    in rapidly urbanising regions: a case study of Shenzhen City, China. Housing

    Studies, 25 (1).

    Zhu, Jieming, 1999, Local growth coalition: the context and implications of Chinas

    gradualist land reforms, International Journal of Urban and Regional Research,

    23 (3): 534-548.