getting by with a little help from my friends: does ...alexander settles rutgers university 1...

46
Getting by with a Little Help from My Friends: The Relevance of Political Affinity for the Bidding Strategy in Cross-Border Acquisitions Olivier Bertrand SKEMA Business School Rue Dostoïevksi, BP085, 06902 Sophia Antipolis Cedex, France [email protected] Marie-Ann Betschinger (corresponding author) National Research University Higher School of Economics 33/5 Kirpchnaya ul. 105679 Moscow, Russia [email protected] Alexander Settles Rutgers University 1 Washington Park Newark, New Jersey, USA 07102 [email protected] Running Head: Political Affinity and Bidding Strategy Key Words: international relations, cross-border mergers and acquisitions, bidding strategy. Notes: Olivier Bertrand and Marie-Ann Betschinger contributed equally to this work and should be considered as co-first authors. We thank Egor Krivosheya for excellent research assistance. We thank Christian Julliard, Carsten Sprenger, Giovanna Nicodano, Sergey Gelman, and the participants at the Academy of International Business Meeting, the Strategic Management Society Annual Conference, and the Second International Moscow Finance Conference in 2012 for valuable comments on previous versions of this paper. We gratefully acknowledge the support of the International Laboratory of Financial Economics and the Basic Research Program of the National Research University Higher School of Economics.

Upload: others

Post on 22-Sep-2020

2 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Getting by with a Little Help from My Friends: Does ...Alexander Settles Rutgers University 1 Washington Park Newark, New Jersey, USA 07102 ... We thank Christian Julliard, Carsten

Getting by with a Little Help from My Friends: The Relevance of Political Affinity for the

Bidding Strategy in Cross-Border Acquisitions

Olivier Bertrand

SKEMA Business School

Rue Dostoïevksi, BP085, 06902

Sophia Antipolis Cedex, France

[email protected]

Marie-Ann Betschinger (corresponding author)

National Research University Higher School of Economics

33/5 Kirpchnaya ul.

105679 Moscow, Russia

[email protected]

Alexander Settles

Rutgers University

1 Washington Park

Newark, New Jersey, USA 07102

[email protected]

Running Head: Political Affinity and Bidding Strategy

Key Words: international relations, cross-border mergers and acquisitions, bidding strategy.

Notes: Olivier Bertrand and Marie-Ann Betschinger contributed equally to this work and should

be considered as co-first authors. We thank Egor Krivosheya for excellent research assistance.

We thank Christian Julliard, Carsten Sprenger, Giovanna Nicodano, Sergey Gelman, and the

participants at the Academy of International Business Meeting, the Strategic Management

Society Annual Conference, and the Second International Moscow Finance Conference in 2012

for valuable comments on previous versions of this paper. We gratefully acknowledge the

support of the International Laboratory of Financial Economics and the Basic Research Program

of the National Research University Higher School of Economics.

Page 2: Getting by with a Little Help from My Friends: Does ...Alexander Settles Rutgers University 1 Washington Park Newark, New Jersey, USA 07102 ... We thank Christian Julliard, Carsten

2

Getting by with a Little Help from My Friends: The Relevance of Political Affinity for the

Bidding Strategy in Cross-Border Acquisitions

ABSTRACT

We investigate the relevance of political affinity between countries for a firm’s bidding strategy

in cross-border acquisitions. We argue that it affects the bargaining position that foreign

acquirers anticipate to have in the negotiations with domestic target firms because it reduces the

extent of political help from the domestic government a target firm can expect to rely on during

the acquisition process. We find strong evidence that political affinity, as revealed by UN voting

patterns, leads to lower initial acquisition premiums and influences other bidding choices.

Supplementary analyses identify political contingency factors and show that shareholder

expectations are also positively related to political affinity. This research contributes to the small,

but growing literature on the implications of international relations for corporate business

transactions.

Page 3: Getting by with a Little Help from My Friends: Does ...Alexander Settles Rutgers University 1 Washington Park Newark, New Jersey, USA 07102 ... We thank Christian Julliard, Carsten

3

INTRODUCTION

Wikileak cables have recently revealed to the public how business and politics are intertwined all

around the world (Lipton, Clark, and Lehren, 2011). These cables in particular suggest that

favorable bilateral political relations can be critical for the success of international business

transactions. For instance, diplomats regularly speculated on the implications of the special

relationship between the former Prime Minister of Italy Berlusconi with Russia’s president Putin

for business outcomes or on the privileges of Chinese firms in African countries with which the

Chinese government had excellent political relations (Copson, Dumbaugh, and Lau, 2005; Shane

and Lehren, 2010).

In spite of numerous anecdotes in the media on the importance of this phenomenon and

its potential impact on international deals, we still know very little about the mechanisms at play

and the channels through which bilateral political relations are incorporated in business decision-

making. The relevance of bilateral country relations and foreign policy for firms remains an

under-investigated topic. In this paper we focus on political affinity, an underlying driver of

“special relationships” between governments. We explore the role of political affinity in the

context of cross-border acquisition-making. We analyze its impact on the acquiring firm’s

strategic bidding behavior, in particular the initial bid (or acquisition) premium. Studying the

strategic bidding behavior permits us to capture the expectation of foreign acquirers concerning

the implications that political affinity has on their bargaining power with the target firm. We

argue that a forward-looking foreign acquirer anticipates a lower bargaining power of the target

firm with a higher level of political affinity between the home and host countries, because higher

political affinity reduces the likelihood of government intervention in favor of the domestic

target firm and, in general, the extent of political discrimination the foreign firm is likely to face

Page 4: Getting by with a Little Help from My Friends: Does ...Alexander Settles Rutgers University 1 Washington Park Newark, New Jersey, USA 07102 ... We thank Christian Julliard, Carsten

4

in the host country. Overall, foreign acquirers are usually exposed to substantial challenges in the

host country, not only with regard to the economic or cultural environment, but also to the

political context (Boddewyn and Brewer, 1994). The existence of protectionism or political

intervention by the host government against foreign firms – also called economic nationalism –

has been illustrated in numerous anecdotes (e.g., Bertrand et al., 2012; Clifton and Diaz-Fuentes,

2011) and has been subject to a few empirical studies in the context of the European Union (EU)

(Aktas, De Bodt, and Roll, 2004; 2007; Dinc and Erel, forthcoming). These studies, however,

have not distinguished among foreign acquirers. But the nationality of the acquirer can play a

critical role in the decisions made by the host government since the quality of political relations

may substantially vary across country dyads.

Previous studies that have linked interstate relations with business activities have mainly

explored the relevance of military conflicts or political agreements between countries, such as

military alliances or international trade and investment agreements, for patterns of international

business (Buthe and Milner, 2008; Egger and Merlo, 2007; Li and Sacko, 2002; Li and

Vashchilko, 2010; Nebus and Rufin, 2010; Ramamurti, 2001; Rangan and Sengul, 2009).

Multilateral international organizations or bilateral international agreements have been viewed

mainly as platforms to increase country interactions, norm diffusion, and trust (Rangan and

Sengul, 2009), or as mechanisms to generate credible commitments towards foreigners (Hafner-

Burton, von Stein, and Gartzke, 2008).

This paper focuses on political affinity, defined as the similarity of national preferences in

global affairs (Gartzke, 1998). We investigate a higher order process through which the

willingness of countries to pursue a cooperative or conflictual relationship with a partner country

not only explains its actions in the political, but also in the international business arena. While

Page 5: Getting by with a Little Help from My Friends: Does ...Alexander Settles Rutgers University 1 Washington Park Newark, New Jersey, USA 07102 ... We thank Christian Julliard, Carsten

5

the implications of political affinity for decisions in the political domain have been part of the

debate in the international relations literature already for many years (Gartzke, 1998), its impact

on cross-border business transactions has been largely neglected in contrast to the vast literature

that has analyzed the effects of cultural or institutional distances (Ahern, Daminelli and Fracassi,

forthcoming; Dikova, Rao Sahib, and van Witteloostuijn, 2010; Dinc and Erel, forthcoming;

Kogut and Singh, 1988; Kostova and Zaheer, 1999). Political affinity has only very recently been

considered as an explanatory variable by Johan, Knill, and Mauck (2013) and Knill, Lee and

Mauck (2012) in the context of sovereign wealth fund (SWF) activities. While these authors

relate political affinity with the political goals of investment funds governed by states, our focus

is different. We shift the theoretical and empirical discussion of the implications of political

affinity for foreign investments to those conducted by non-institutional investors without direct

state involvement, hereafter simply referred to as private non-financial firms or strategic

acquirers. Through investments abroad the firms we examine are willing to gain strategic control

over the management of the target firm with a primarily long-term profit-maximization goal that

is a priori free of political motives.

To gain insights into the channels through which international relations are at play in

business decision-making, we focus on the importance of political affinity for the bidding

strategy of foreign acquirers in international M&A (Merger and Acquisition) deals, contrary to,

for instance, Johan et al. (2013) and Knill et al. (2012). We argue that political affinity affects

firm strategy and international transactions by changing the expectations of foreign acquirers

concerning the bargaining power of the target firm during the pre-acquisition process. In M&As

such an effect should be best captured in the behavior of firms in the pre-announcement period or

bidding phase.

Page 6: Getting by with a Little Help from My Friends: Does ...Alexander Settles Rutgers University 1 Washington Park Newark, New Jersey, USA 07102 ... We thank Christian Julliard, Carsten

6

The size of the initial acquisition premium is considered as the most important decision

that has to be taken in a firm’s bidding strategy (Eckbo, 2009) and has been used as the main

variable of interest in this context (Aktas, de Bodt, and Roll, 2010). The initial bid premium

signals the confidence of acquirers in their ability to win the bid (Haleblian, et al., 2009;

Hayward and Hambrick, 1997). Albeit largely overlooked by the literature in management,

“[a]cquisition premiums are an interesting and important area […] because there is so much

variation in premiums, and large premiums can be disastrous” (Haunschild, 1994: 393). Gaining

a better understanding of the initial bid premium is important since paying too much has been

very often suggested as one major reason for the widely observed underperformance of M&As

(Agrawal and Jaffe, 2000; Haunschild, 1994; Hayward and Hambrick, 1997; Sirower, 1994).

Overpayment increases the uncertainty about the M&A success and may, eventually, jeopardize

the performance of the acquirer by diverting too many financial resources from other necessary

investments or obliging the acquiring firm to take cost-reduction decisions harmful in the long

run (Krishnan, Hitt, and Park, 2007). Other major strategic decisions in the bidding phase that we

study in this paper relate to the “pre-bid ownership stake (toehold) in the target, and selecting an

optimal payment method (mix of cash and securities)” (Eckbo, 2009: 150).

In this context, we argue that forward-looking foreign acquirers incorporate the political

dimension into their decision-making process during the bidding phase. They expect that higher

political affinity between the home and host country will make it less likely that the host

government will shield the target firm by supporting other potential domestic bidders or by

helping target management in blocking the acquisition. As a result, with increasing political

affinity, foreign acquirers anticipate target firms to be in a less favorable negotiation position and

Page 7: Getting by with a Little Help from My Friends: Does ...Alexander Settles Rutgers University 1 Washington Park Newark, New Jersey, USA 07102 ... We thank Christian Julliard, Carsten

7

reduce their initial offer price. We expect that firms that find themselves in this favorable

position will also adapt their toehold strategy and payment method.

We empirically test the relationship between political affinity and the acquisition

premium on a sample of 715 cross-border acquisitions from 1990-2008. This sample is limited to

listed target firms and, hence, includes large targets and acquirers. Large cross-border M&As are

economic events that are visible and well-advertised; foreign bidders can anticipate that such

deals are likely to attract the attention, efforts, and resources of governments (Clougherty, 2003;

Saner, Yiu, and Sondergaard, 2000). The sample excludes deals where state actors were involved

(including SWFs) or associated with financial or institutional investment firms to keep our focus

on strategic acquirers. We measure political affinity “based on the similarity of nations' roll-call

voting in the United Nations General Assembly” (Gartzke, 1998: 12).

We find robust evidence that the initial premium proposed to the target firm in cross-

border deals is, ceteris paribus, negatively related to political affinity. Controlling for economic,

cultural, and other institutional distances, we show that the political affinity effect is both

statistically and economically highly significant. In addition, political affinity consistently affects

strategic choices in terms of payment method and toehold. Moreover, in supplementary analyses,

we empirically identify political contingency factors of the political affinity effect on the M&A

premium: It is moderated by the host country political environment (namely by government

weakness and the extent of nationalism) and domestic political connections of the target firms.

We finally show that not only managerial expectations towards the deal, as revealed in their

bidding strategy, are influenced by political affinity, but also the expectations of the stock

market. These results are important given the dominant role of cross-border acquisitions in FDI

flows and their impact on host economies (UNCTAD, 2000). The findings highlight not only an

Page 8: Getting by with a Little Help from My Friends: Does ...Alexander Settles Rutgers University 1 Washington Park Newark, New Jersey, USA 07102 ... We thank Christian Julliard, Carsten

8

important mechanism at play at the intersection of international relations and cross-border

business activities, political affinity, but also, with the bidding strategy, help to identify a channel

through which international relations shape firm strategic behavior and hence business success.

Our study contributes to the literature by linking international relations with international

strategy and finance. Political affinity enables us to highlight a characteristic of the bilateral

relationship between countries which can alter the nature and intensity of political interference in

the host market. The emphasis on political affinity allows for moving the attention from the role

of cultural or institutional distance that has been abundantly discussed in the International

Business (IB) literature to the importance of political friendship. Compared to most previous

research on international relations in IB that has been done at a macroeconomic level, we extend

the analysis to firm-level strategic decisions in international deals. We primarily focus on the

bidding strategy of the firm and, in particular, the initial acquisition premium. The role of the

host country political environment and of firm-level domestic political connections or, more

broadly, political corporate strategy, has been extensively discussed through different lenses in

strategy (e.g., Delios and Henisz, 2003; Hillman, Keim, and Schuler, 2004; Holburn and Zelner,

2010) or in finance (e.g., Faccio, 2006; Faccio, Masulis, and McConnell, 2006; Fisman, 2001).

Only a few studies have investigated government intervention in business transactions (Aktas et

al., 2004, 2007; Dinc and Erel, forthcoming). This research stream, however, overlooks

international relations and, thus, the heterogeneity of bilateral political relations. In this paper we

take into account the quality of interstate relations, focusing on political affinity. To our

knowledge only, Knill et al. (2012) and Johan et al. (2013) have very recently studied the role of

interstate relations and, in particular, political affinity. Our work is complementary. While they

focus on SWFs, we examine the strategic behavior of private non-financial firms and argue that

Page 9: Getting by with a Little Help from My Friends: Does ...Alexander Settles Rutgers University 1 Washington Park Newark, New Jersey, USA 07102 ... We thank Christian Julliard, Carsten

9

political affinity matters for cross-border acquisitions made by these firms driven primarily by

strategic and long-term profit-maximization goals. Interestingly, Knill et al. (2012) find that

political affinity deters investments from SWFs. They interpret this result as evidence that state-

players use SWFs as an instrument to fulfill political goals. We arrive at opposite conclusions

and findings for private non-financial firms. Both acquirer management and the stock market

positively value political affinity in these strategic international acquisitions. We also go beyond

their studies by exploring political contingency factors. Overall, our empirical set-up and

theoretical focus differ from the cited research works.

The remainder of the paper is structured as follows. We start by developing our

hypotheses on the implications of political affinity for the bidding behavior of the foreign

acquirer. We then describe our data and methods before reporting our empirical results for the

bidding strategy. In a supplementary analysis section we proceed to further empirical

investigations, analyzing the political drivers of affinity outcomes and the effect of political

affinity on shareholder reactions to international deals. Finally, we discuss our findings and

indicate the contributions and limitations of the study.

THEORY AND HYPOTHESIS

Political affinity in international business

The importance of the bilateral political relationship between countries for firms operating in

international markets has been analyzed in the IB field primarily in a two-tier negotiation

framework (Frynas, Mellahi, and Pigman, 2006; Nebus and Rufin, 2010; Ramamurti, 2001). In

this framework, Tier 1 examines home and host country government negotiations that concern

Page 10: Getting by with a Little Help from My Friends: Does ...Alexander Settles Rutgers University 1 Washington Park Newark, New Jersey, USA 07102 ... We thank Christian Julliard, Carsten

10

business matters.1 Tier 2 relates to the bargaining that occurs directly between multinational

enterprises (MNEs) and the host country government. Tier 1 negotiations can shape the political

framework within which firms bargain on the micro-level in Tier 2 or, more generally, even

without any MNEs-host government interactions, the level of political discrimination foreign

firms are confronted with in the host country.

A government may choose to support or oppose the activities of foreign firms in their

economy (Hymer, 1976; Stopford and Strange, 1992). Due to informational asymmetries or

stereotypes (Kostova and Zaheer, 1999; Zaheer, 1995), foreign firms, however, suffer from a

liability of foreignness, making them more likely than domestic firms to fail in their political

behavior and to experience political discrimination in general and unfavorable government

intervention in particular (Boddewyn and Brewer, 1994; Eden, Lenway, and Schuler, 2005;

Hillman and Wan, 2005). Government intervention can take different facets; it can be direct

(e.g., via regulatory measures; see Dinc and Erel, forthcoming), or indirect through its vast

political and business network (Colignon and Usui, 2001; Kadushin, 1995; Kim, Pantzalis, and

Park, 2012).

We, however, still know very little about what drives political discrimination in the host

market and how the nature of the political relationship between countries may affect decisions

taken by the host government. We argue that the similarity in preferences in global affairs of the

host and home country shapes host government behavior and the extent of political

discrimination foreign firms eventually experience in the host market. In the international

relations literature the character of bilateral political relationships has been associated with the

1 Previous research on this issue has mostly explored formal bilateral or multilateral agreements and linked them to

their role as platforms to increase interstate exchange, economic liberalization, norm diffusion, and trust (e.g.,

Ramamurti, 2001; Rangan and Sengul, 2009) or as mechanisms to increase the credibility of government policies

towards foreigners (e.g., Buthe and Milner, 2008; Hafner-Burton et al., 2008).

Page 11: Getting by with a Little Help from My Friends: Does ...Alexander Settles Rutgers University 1 Washington Park Newark, New Jersey, USA 07102 ... We thank Christian Julliard, Carsten

11

‘‘willingness’’ (Gartzke, 1998: 6) of governments, usually the most influential actors in affecting

foreign policy outcomes in a country (Moe and Howell, 1999), to engage either in conflictual or

cooperative actions in relation to each other. This willingness is shaped by a country’s

“objectives in global relations” (Gartzke, 1998: 7). When “global objectives coincide” (Gartzke,

1998:12) and countries share “world views” (Gartzke, 1998: 7), political affinity is positive or

high. Similar interests make conflicts less probable (Gartzke, 1998; Kinsella and Russett, 2002).

Governments are more likely to take cooperative actions and act as a friend.

Just as political affinity is argued to affect government behavior in the political arena, we

posit in this paper that it can influence the intensity and nature of political intervention in the

host country in cross-border business deals. The relevance of the quality of political relations for

cross-border business deals has been illustrated numerous times in the media and, although much

less frequently, in academic research (Frynas et al., 2006). While positive political affinity opens

the door for economic cooperation, transactions of firms from less friendly countries are

rendered more difficult. The notion of political affinity is thus distinct from that of cultural

distance or institutional distance that has been extensively studied (Ahern et al., forthcoming;

Dikova et al., 2010; Dinc and Erel, forthcoming; Kogut and Singh, 1988; Kostova and Zaheer,

1999). In particular, distance in cultures relates to the degree of divergence in the “personality”

of the “human collectivity” found within the boundaries of one country (Hofstede, 1980: 21).

Differently, political affinity refers to the extent of preference alignment between nation-states,

where these preferences concern issues relevant in global affairs. Differences in institutions are

associated with the differences in the rules that structure human interactions (North, 1994) in the

two countries. In contrast, political affinity focuses on the degree of similarity of national

interests in the international arena. These interests are shaped by a variety of factors including

Page 12: Getting by with a Little Help from My Friends: Does ...Alexander Settles Rutgers University 1 Washington Park Newark, New Jersey, USA 07102 ... We thank Christian Julliard, Carsten

12

“governing structures or political cultures” (Gartzke, 1998: 7), but also “national wealth,

geography, culture, ethnic identity, and idiosyncratic political agendas” (Gartzke, 1998: 12).

Political affinity provides a dynamic construct on world views and gives a different texture

explanation of the contact between foreigners and local agents.

In the two-tier framework, political affinity can shape the host environment that the

foreign firm is confronted with during a cross-border deal by altering the negotiations taking

place in Tier 1, such as those concerning formal treaties or other diplomacy outcomes, and those

at the micro-level in Tier 2. The home government may leverage the good relation between

governments and more easily intervene in favor of the economic interests of its firms. Even

without any negotiations taking place on Tier 1 or 2, political affinity should matter; it affects the

willingness of the host government to act in favor of or against a foreign firm and contributes to

determining the level of political discrimination the foreign firm is confronted with during a

cross-border business deal. In such a context, we assert that forward-looking foreign firms are

aware of international political issues and take into account the level of political affinity between

their home and host countries in their decision-making.

Political affinity and the acquiring firm’s bidding strategy

In this paper, we examine the relationship between political affinity and the acquirer’s bidding

strategy in international acquisition deals. We posit that political affinity modifies the bargaining

power that the foreign acquirer anticipates to have vis-à-vis the target firm during the pre-

announcement period or bidding phase.

During this phase, the level of the initial bid premium – which refers to the difference

between the price proposed for a target firm and the pre-acquisition market value – has been

Page 13: Getting by with a Little Help from My Friends: Does ...Alexander Settles Rutgers University 1 Washington Park Newark, New Jersey, USA 07102 ... We thank Christian Julliard, Carsten

13

recognized as a major strategic decision taken by the acquiring firm (Aktas et al., 2010;

Haleblian et al., 2009; Officer, 2003) and has even been identified as the most important bidding

parameter (Eckbo, 2009). When setting the initial offer price, the acquiring firm wishes to pay as

little as possible for the target firm in order to minimize the overall cost of the acquisition

(Haunschild, 1994; Haunschild and Beckman, 2002; Reichheld and Henske, 1991). The acquirer,

however, can only win the bid if target shareholders agree to a sale. These shareholders will only

accept the deal if the offer price is above the expected post-acquisition value (Grossman and Hart,

1980) or the value of the firm in case that the transaction does not take place, namely, in case

that the target stays independent or is acquired by a third-party (Betton, Eckbo, and Thorburn,

2008; Schwert, 1996). For instance, in August 2010, the initial bid of the Australian firm BHP

for the Canadian Potash Corporation, the world’s largest fertilizer producer, was perceived to be

set so low, that target management felt “insulted” and chose to reveal the Australian bidder to the

public and pursue other strategies to raise the standalone value of the firm (McNish, Bouw, and

Reguly, 2010). Forward-looking acquirers need to incorporate these constraints into their initial

bid, i.e., proposing a price that is low enough to be profitable, but high enough to convince target

shareholder to sell. An acquirer also has to consider the first-mover advantage that initiating a

bid might offer, like pre-empting competition (Fishman, 1988). Acquirers, therefore, have to set

the initial premium such that it discourages the target firm from opposing the bid, taking

resistance strategies to increase the target’s standalone value, or accepting a competing offer.

Due to their liability of foreignness, foreign acquirers are particularly exposed to

uncertainties and challenges during the acquisition price negotiations with the local target firm

(Dikova et al., 2010). Empirical evidence suggests that they, on average, pay a higher premium

than domestic bidders (Rossi and Volpin, 2004). Therefore, when deciding on the initial offer

Page 14: Getting by with a Little Help from My Friends: Does ...Alexander Settles Rutgers University 1 Washington Park Newark, New Jersey, USA 07102 ... We thank Christian Julliard, Carsten

14

price, foreign acquirers need to investigate the cross-border context in which the deal takes place

and, in doing so, consider the level of political affinity between countries. If the host government

acts in favor of local target firms, it raises the bargaining power of the latter and the acquisition

price they are able to claim. Target firms can proactively ask for help of the government in the

bargaining phase. Consultants from the legal consulting group Davies Ward Phillips & Vineberg

LLP (Thomson, Bodrug, and Damiani, 2010) even advise target firms to utilize government

protectionism to defend themselves: “[…] the target is often best placed to identify hot button

[regulatory] issues and advance them quickly and effectively” (Thomson, Bodrug, and Damiani,

2010: 47). But even if target firms remain passive, governments may interfere in their favor in

the pre-acquisition phase, as the case of the bid of Mittal Steel for Arcelor in 2006 illustrates.

“French intelligence services have been used to monitor potential bids. Reportedly, intelligence

services alerted Arcelor on November 17 of Mittal Steel's bidding intentions, two months before

the bid became public” (Wikileaks, 2006). Overall, the intervention of the host government could

affect the strength of target firms to oppose foreign acquisitions by reducing information

asymmetries, influencing their standalone value, or the threat of alternative acquirers. Recent

research has confirmed that foreign acquirers are more likely to experience unfavorable

government intervention (Aktas et al., 2007; Dinc and Erel, forthcoming) than domestic ones.2

Nevertheless, we argue that the actual degree of political discrimination faced by

foreigner acquirers depends on their nationality and the political relations between the home and

2 In line with political affinity considerations, the host government can interfere in the acquisition process through

various channels. For instance, through persuasion or regulatory measures the government can exercise direct

pressure on target firms to accept or refuse the deal. A government can also leverage its power as a major customer

or use its influence on the local community to reduce or increase resistance to the transaction. Moreover, a

government can often exert impact on banks and thus affect the target firm’s access to loans or other forms of

finance; similarly, it can affect labor unions and employee-employer negotiation outcomes during the deal process.

In general, a government is able to de- or increase the stand-alone value of the local target firm by, for instance,

(not) granting subsidies or giving regulatory advantages. Through political-business networks, a government can

also function as an intermediary that allows, for instance, a foreign acquirer to be introduced to the target firm or the

target firm to find alternative domestic partners to counter the foreign acquirer’s initiative.

Page 15: Getting by with a Little Help from My Friends: Does ...Alexander Settles Rutgers University 1 Washington Park Newark, New Jersey, USA 07102 ... We thank Christian Julliard, Carsten

15

host countries as captured by political affinity. The higher the political affinity, the less likely the

host government will act against the foreign acquirer at the benefit of the local target firm.

Hence, foreign acquirers can expect a higher political affinity to decrease the ability of target

firms to leverage the host government, consequently reducing the target firms’ bargaining power

during price negotiations. With a higher level of political affinity, acquirers will then propose a

lower initial acquisition premium, anticipating such an offer to be sufficient to buy a target firm.

In setting the initial price, it is the expectation towards political discrimination that matters, not

the actual level that is then experienced. Indeed, if correctly set, government intervention might

not take place at all. Target firms will be willing to sell immediately since the offer surpasses or

equals the minimum price they require. They could even be willing to help foreign acquirers to

overcome government resistance as, for instance, experts suggested in the case of the

unsuccessful bid of BHP for Potash Corporation. “A senior Canadian investment banker said the

low offer failed to whet the appetite of Canada's biggest and most powerful investors - the

pension funds. If those funds and other big-name investors couldn't resist the offer, he said, they

would have put enormous political pressure on Premier Wall and top federal politicians to

approve the deal. […] If BHP had made a real bid, there would have been a cacophony of large

shareholders telling the governments to butt out” (McNish, Bouw, and Reguly, 2010).3

In sum, a higher political affinity should reduce the premium that a foreign acquirer has

to pay. This is important since the premium paid determines the cost of the acquisition and may

therefore affect the performance of the deal and the future success of the company. Hence, we

state:

3 In such circumstances bidding high is advised by legal consultants: “[For bidders] it may be well advised to open

with a relatively higher bid price to minimize the prospects for an aggressive regulatory defence strategy by the

target” (Thomson, Bodrug, and Damiani, 2010: 47)

Page 16: Getting by with a Little Help from My Friends: Does ...Alexander Settles Rutgers University 1 Washington Park Newark, New Jersey, USA 07102 ... We thank Christian Julliard, Carsten

16

Hypothesis 1: There is a negative relationship between the initial acquisition premium

for cross-border acquisitions and the level of political affinity between acquirer and target

countries.

Following the same line of reasoning, we predict that political affinity also influences

other strategic bidding elements. In a bidding strategy, “[i]n addition to the initial offer premium

and subsequent bid revisions, strategic choices include acquiring a pre-bid ownership stake

(toehold) in the target, and selecting an optimal payment method (mix of cash and securities)”

(Eckbo, 2009: 150). Accordingly, we focus on the impact of political affinity on these two

strategic parameters.

A toehold reduces the risk and the costs of an acquisition since only a lower stake needs

to be acquired at a premium in the control acquisition (e.g., Chowdry and Jegadeesh, 1994;

Hirshleifer and Titman, 1990). Nevertheless, only a small number of companies actually use

toeholds as a platform for further acquisitions (Betton, Eckbo, and Thorburn, 2009; Choi, 1991).

This paradox has been explained by the hostility of target management to acquisition offers

associated with toeholds. The establishment of a toehold is perceived as an aggressive move

which raises target management resistance to the bid (Betton et al., 2009) and hence the costs of

the acquirer in overcoming this resistance. Also, in case that an acquisition fails, the pre-bid

target shares of the acquirer can lose in value as target management resistance to the deal may

lead to value reducing defensive measures or signal strong management entrenchment in general

(Goldman and Qian, 2005). A toehold can, therefore, reveal the acquirer’s perception of the

degree of target resistance it will face in the control transaction: An acquiring firm opts for a

toehold-based acquisition only if it expects that the target management will not be able to defend

Page 17: Getting by with a Little Help from My Friends: Does ...Alexander Settles Rutgers University 1 Washington Park Newark, New Jersey, USA 07102 ... We thank Christian Julliard, Carsten

17

itself successfully. In our context, we argue that political affinity reduces the chances that a

target firm can rely on political or regulatory mechanisms to improve its bargaining position

during a bid. Therefore, establishing a toehold should become less risky with a higher level of

political affinity for forward looking acquirers as target management is less likely to leverage

political power to block the acquisition. We propose:

Hypothesis 2: There is a positive relationship between the likelihood of a foreign

acquirer to use a toehold strategy in a cross-border acquisition and the level of political

affinity between acquirer and target countries.

Also, the choice of the offered payment method depends on the anticipated relative

bargaining power of the acquirer and target. For the acquirer a cash payment is less desirable in

an acquisition since it requires a higher cash outlay and is riskier than a payment via shares. In

case of a stock payment the value of the offer is contingent upon the future performance of the

acquiring firm (Sudarsanam, 1995). The target firm thus shares the risks of the acquisition failure

and, more generally, of a possible negative revaluation after the bid's completion (Martynova and

Renneboog, 2009). For the same reason, target shareholders usually prefer a cash offer. It is

simple to evaluate and provides a safe return. A stock offer from the acquirer’s side could even

suggest that the acquirer’s stocks are overvalued (Peterson and Peterson, 1991). In sum, equity

payments are less likely to convince target shareholders to sell and to decrease any deal-related

resistance (Sudarsanam, 1995). In the opposite, cash payments tend to signal the high valuation

of the target firm by the acquirer. Several research works have thus shown that a cash offer tends

to deter competitive offers for the target firm (Fishman, 1989; Giammarino and Heinkel; 1986;

Hirshleifer and Png, 1989; Peterson and Peterson, 1991). In our context we argue that a higher

Page 18: Getting by with a Little Help from My Friends: Does ...Alexander Settles Rutgers University 1 Washington Park Newark, New Jersey, USA 07102 ... We thank Christian Julliard, Carsten

18

level of political affinity reduces the risk of host government intervention in favor of the target

firm for the foreign acquirer. As a result, the foreign acquirer can provide lower incentives to

target shareholders to sell. The acquirer can more easily switch from a cash to a stock payment in

order to reduce the risk and the costs related with the acquisition deal. Hence, we state:

Hypothesis 3: There is a negative relationship between the likelihood of a foreign

acquirer to make a cash offer in a cross-border acquisition and the level of political

affinity between acquirer and target countries.

METHODOLOGY

Data and sample

The sample is obtained from the Thomson ONE (former SDC) database. We selected deals that

were either completed or withdrawn within the period 1990-2008 and had premium and financial

statement information (namely total assets, EBITDA, and firm debt) available for the acquiring

and target firms. We excluded divestitures of assets, leveraged buy outs, and joint ventures and

only kept deals where the acquirer purchased more than 50 percent of the equity of the target

firm and hence gained majority control. Moreover, we removed transactions where states were

involved either as acquirers or targets (including SWFs) or were associated with financial or

institutional investment firms. Such deals are likely to be driven by other considerations (Karolyi

and Liao, 2013). The sample is further limited due to the availability of our other explanatory

variables.

The final sample consists of 715 cross-border deals from 31 (26) acquirer (target) nations

(see the appendix for further details on our acquisition sample). These acquisitions took place in

a variety of industries going from primary to services industries (excluding financial services).

Page 19: Getting by with a Little Help from My Friends: Does ...Alexander Settles Rutgers University 1 Washington Park Newark, New Jersey, USA 07102 ... We thank Christian Julliard, Carsten

19

Manufacturing and service industries contained the majority of acquisitions (respectively 46%

and 22%), followed by the primary industry (with 14%).

Dependent variable

Our main dependent variable is the value of the initial premium of the offer price to the

target closing stock price four weeks prior to the original announcement date as reported by the

Thomson One database. Based on the analysis of SDC premiums by Officer (2003) and

following Hope, Wayne, and Vyas (2011) we trim the premium data to eliminate outliers by

dropping the largest and smallest 2 percent of initial bids. In our sample, the four-week initial bid

premium has an average value of 44.67 (percent) and a standard deviation of 37.08.

The two other bidding parameters are cash payment and a toehold strategy indicator. The

cash variable is equal to one if the bid is offered only in cash, and zero otherwise (Aktas et al.,

2004). 65% of the transactions in our sample are cash bids.4 The toehold variable takes the value

one when the acquirer has committed to a toehold strategy, and zero otherwise. Following Betton

et al. (2009), we assign the value one if the acquirer has a minimum ownership position of 10%

in the target prior to the control acquisition.5 11% of our sample acquirers pursue a toehold-based

control acquisition.

Empirical model

The acquirer’s initial bid premium can be modeled as follows: ( )

where is the initial bid premium at which the acquiring firm i announces to take over the

4 In a robustness check we also include hybrid offers that involve both cash and stock payment in the cash indicator

variable as a one. Results are similar and available on request. 5 Betton et al. (2009) argue that due to the specific cost-benefit structure of toehold strategies there is a minimum

toehold, or prior stockholding threshold, that is needed for an acquirer to gain, which they estimate at 9%. Our

estimation results are similar when taking the exact 9% cut-off.

Page 20: Getting by with a Little Help from My Friends: Does ...Alexander Settles Rutgers University 1 Washington Park Newark, New Jersey, USA 07102 ... We thank Christian Julliard, Carsten

20

firm j at time t. The vector represents the country-level variables that are related to acquirer i

and target j. The vector indicates firm-level attributes of acquirer i or target j, while are

characteristics particular to the focal deal. We add a vector of year dummies and industry

dummies to account, respectively, for time specific effects and unobserved industry

heterogeneity. We use the same model for explaining the acquisition payment method and the

toehold strategy.

Independent variable

The vector of country-level characteristics includes our focal variable, the political affinity

of countries, which we measure using the voting patterns in the United Nations (UN) General

Assembly (Source: Gartzke, 1998).6 Previous research in political science has demonstrated the

value of utilizing UN voting patterns as a means to account for the alignment of national

preferences and thereby political affinity between countries (e.g., Gartzke, 1998; Stone, 2004). In

the UN General Assembly, as opposed to the UN Security Council, the public stance on a large

number of issues is revealed and countries are relatively free to express sincere preferences since

the cost that they incur for showing them are small (Gartzke, 1998). For the case of African

countries, for instance, Stone (2004) highlights that “patrons are not concerned about how

African countries vote in the UN General Assembly but, rather, that these votes are unimportant

enough to serve as a sincere measure of countries' foreign policy preferences” (Stone, 2004:

580). UN General Assembly voting thus captures more than just military or security interests

(Voeten, 2000). Those countries that vote together are expected to be friends and those with

6 Political affinity is based on Spearman rank-order correlations of roll-call voting patterns in the UN General

Assembly with values ranging between -1 and 1. Dyads which have the same voting pattern obtain the value 1,

while those with a complete opposite voting pattern are assigned the value -1.

Page 21: Getting by with a Little Help from My Friends: Does ...Alexander Settles Rutgers University 1 Washington Park Newark, New Jersey, USA 07102 ... We thank Christian Julliard, Carsten

21

“negative affinity scores are, ceteris paribus, more likely to be considered as “enemies” […]”

(Gartzke, 1998:15). UN General Assembly voting gives a fine-grained measure of country

preferences that varies over time. UN voting covers almost the total universe of countries and is

available over a long period of time.7

Political affinity is biased towards positive values: The majority of observations in our

sample are above zero (83%). But, with its mean of 0.31 and standard deviation of 0.37, this bias

is less pronounced than in the universe of country dyads included in the original database

(comprising a total of 189 countries), where political affinity exhibits a mean of 0.67 and a

standard deviation of 0.29 over the same period 1990-2008.

Control variables

To account for other variables that possibly explain a firm’s bidding strategy we include a

number of control variables. All our monetary data are expressed in US dollars and are deflated

using the GDP deflator (Source: World Bank).

First, we control for other country dyadic factors reflecting the degree to which the

country of acquirer i differs from the country of target j. We account for institutional differences

between the two countries. We first consider the cultural distance between countries, using the

Kogut and Singh (1988) index based on Hofstede’s (1980) data (see, e.g., Hope et al., 2011).

Also, we include differences in the political system and shareholder governance. We use the

PolityIV score (Source: Center for Systemic Peace) to capture the political regime (e.g., Munck

7 Such political subtleties have been only partly captured by previous research. International formal institutional

arrangements do not fully reflect the nuances by which bilateral political relations are made up and which shape

foreign policy outcomes (Boehmer, Gartzke, & Nordstrom, 2004). Membership varies little over time as countries

very rarely withdraw from ratified agreements or leave international organizations once admitted (Gartzke, 1998).

Multilateral organizations in themselves also include a variety of national preferences of constituent countries

(Boehmer et al., 2004). Similarly, bilateral agreements may imperfectly reveal the similarity of preference of

countries as agreements could reflect competitive economic pressures to gain access to capital (Elkins, Guzman, &

Simmons, 2006), regional security needs, or the effects of a third party (Werner, 1997).

Page 22: Getting by with a Little Help from My Friends: Does ...Alexander Settles Rutgers University 1 Washington Park Newark, New Jersey, USA 07102 ... We thank Christian Julliard, Carsten

22

and Verkuilen, 2002). For shareholder governance, we resort to a time-invariant measure for

shareholder protection that is computed using the updated version of the anti-director rights

index from La Porta, Lopez-de-Silanes, and Shleifer (2008). This index is multiplied with the

rule of law, following the methodology of Wurgler (2000). Political affinity could be in

particular co-determined or the result of political regime or cultural similarities. Nevertheless,

there exists strong heterogeneity of national preferences even within similar regime types or

cultures (Gartzke, 1998; Gartzke and Gleditsch, 2006).8 At the country dyadic level, like Rossi

and Volpin (2004) or Bris and Cabolis (2008) we, furthermore, consider the GDP per capita

differences to capture cross-country economic development disparities (Source: World Bank). It

is calculated as the difference of the natural logarithm transformed values of acquirer country i

and target country j.

In our estimations we include several firm-specific control variables ( ). We account

for the difference of the size of target and acquiring firms (taking the natural logarithm

transformed value of their total assets) and control for the profitability of target and acquirer

firms (using the ratio of EBITDA over total assets). We also include their debt ratios (i.e., the

ratio of total debt over total assets) and the M&A experience of the acquirer i (as computed by

the number of completed acquisitions prior to the focal acquisition).

For deal specific variables we include variables that indicate if the deal is

completed, if there are competing bids, if the bid is a tender offer, and if it is hostile. We also

account for the industry relatedness of firms. Acquisitions are defined as horizontal when both

business partners are within the same 2-digit SIC industry. Finally, we account for the percentage

8 Our data supports this. We find that the correlation between political regime similarity, or cultural distance, and

political affinity is low.

Page 23: Getting by with a Little Help from My Friends: Does ...Alexander Settles Rutgers University 1 Washington Park Newark, New Jersey, USA 07102 ... We thank Christian Julliard, Carsten

23

sought in the target firm and if the deal is paid in cash when we estimate the bid premium

separately. We obtain all our firm- and deal-level variables from the Thomson ONE database.

Econometric method

We proceed in two steps. First, we examine the initial acquisition premium, our main dependent

variable of interest. We apply pooled least squares regressions like in previous research (e.g.,

Haunschild, 1994; Hope et al., 2011; Laamanen, 2007). Second, we investigate the acquisition

payment method and the toehold choice. Given the dichotomous nature of these variables, we

use a probit model in both cases. In addition, following some previous studies (e.g., Rao and

Drazi, 2002; Reuer, Tong, Tyler, and Ariño, 2013; Zellner, 1962), we evaluate the three

dependent variables acquisition premium, cash, and toehold simultaneously using the seemingly

unrelated regression (SUR) technique. The SUR model allows for correlated errors between

equations.

In all specifications, we cluster errors at the country pair level. Descriptive statistics and

cross-correlations of the variables included in the base model are provided in Table 1. There is

no sign for multicollinearity.

*** Insert Table 1 about here ***

RESULTS

To begin with, we perform several statistical tests to examine the relationship between political

affinity and the initial acquisition (or bid) premium. First, we observe that the simple correlation

between political affinity and the initial acquisition premium is negative (-0.13) and statistically

significant (p < 0.01). Second, we distinguish relatively friendly versus unfriendly country pairs

Page 24: Getting by with a Little Help from My Friends: Does ...Alexander Settles Rutgers University 1 Washington Park Newark, New Jersey, USA 07102 ... We thank Christian Julliard, Carsten

24

by separating country-dyads into two groups depending on the median value of political affinity.

Cross-border deals involving relatively friendly countries exhibit, on average, a lower acquisition

premium (M = 40.35; SD = 36.72) than deals between relatively unfriendly countries (M =

48.86; SD = 36.99). A t-test on the equality of the means of the acquisition premium for the two

groups shows that the difference is statistically significant (p < 0.01). These results are confirmed

by non-parametric tests. The Wilcoxon rank-sum test indicates a statistically significant

difference in the distributions at the 1% level. The non-parametric test for equality of the median

also reveals a significant difference (p < 0.01). Third, we explore to what degree changes in

political affinity over time also lead to variation in acquisition premiums within a given country

pair. We find that the negative relationship between political affinity and the initial acquisition

premium is supported longitudinally. The correlation between political affinity and the initial

acquisition premium within country pairs is again statistically significant (p < 0.01). Taking the

sample of country pairs that experience a relative increase in political affinity between 1990-

1999 and 2000-2008, we also observe that the initial acquisition premium is significantly lower

(p < 0.05) in the latter period than in the former one.

We then investigate the relationship between political affinity and the initial acquisition

premium more rigorously in a multivariate regression setting. In Table 2, we, in Model 1, first

show the regression outcome comprising control variables only. The R-squared, albeit low at

11.6 percent, is similar to what can be found in the literature (Hope et al., 2011; Laamanen,

2007). We then augment this baseline model in Model 2 of Table 2 by adding the variable

Political Affinity. As predicted in hypothesis 1, controlling for economic, cultural, political, and

shareholder protection differences between the countries of the acquirer and the target firm, the

variable Political Affinity is negative and significant (p < 0.01). Ceteris paribus, a higher level of

Page 25: Getting by with a Little Help from My Friends: Does ...Alexander Settles Rutgers University 1 Washington Park Newark, New Jersey, USA 07102 ... We thank Christian Julliard, Carsten

25

political affinity decreases the acquisition premium. Political affinity matters strongly also in

terms of economic significance. A one standard deviation change in political affinity leads to a

5.1 percentage point reduction in the bid premium. This is important since the premium paid

determines the cost of the acquisition and may in turn affect the performance of the deal and the

success of the company.

*** Insert Table 2 about here ***

In the same Table 2, to confirm the robustness of our findings, we do several sensitivity

checks in Models 3 to 10. First, to further check that our results are not driven by outliers, we

trim political affinity by dropping observations corresponding to the largest and smallest 2 per

cent of political affinity in Model 3. Results are robust. Then, we replace our dependent variable,

the initial bid premium, by the final bid premium in Model 4. The final bid premium reflects the

outcome of the bargaining process started by the initial offer. It is also significantly and

negatively affected by political affinity. In addition, following prior research (see e.g., Benner

and Tushman, 2002; Phelps, 2010; Zelner, Henisz and Holburn, 2009) we also lag political

affinity by one year in Model 5 to control for possible reverse causality issues. Results are again

robust.9 In Model 6, 7 and 8 we add further control variables that could possibly explain the

acquisition premium. In Model 6 we include two country-dyad level indicator variables that,

respectively, take on the value one if the host and home countries have ratified a bilateral

investment treaty (Source: UNCTAD) and are members to a common regional trade agreement

(Source: De Sousa, 2012). We also add the difference of the natural logarithm transformed GDP

between the home and host country to take into account power imbalance between countries

(Source: WDI). “The best single indicator of a state’s power may be its total GDP, which

9 When lagging political affinity by two years, the result still holds.

Page 26: Getting by with a Little Help from My Friends: Does ...Alexander Settles Rutgers University 1 Washington Park Newark, New Jersey, USA 07102 ... We thank Christian Julliard, Carsten

26

combines overall size, technological level, and wealth” (Goldstein and Pevehouse, 2006: 57). In

Model 7, similar to Rossi and Volpin (2004), we add three variables that could also account for

the extent of proximity between countries, namely a common language, contiguity, and the

intensity of bilateral trade. The variable common language and contiguity take on the value one

if countries share the same official language and have a common border respectively and zero

otherwise (source: CEPII). The intensity of bilateral trade is computed as the sum of export and

import flows divided by the sum of GDP of the involved countries for each country pair (Source:

Correlates of War Project Trade Data Set).10

All variables added in Models 6 and 7 are

insignificant and do not change the political affinity outcome. In Model 8, we replace the

country-level dyadic variables that capture the differences in the political system, shareholder

governance, and economic development level with their respective host and home country values

separately. Political affinity continues to reduce the initial bid premium. Finally, we focus on

potential selection problems. Deals between country dyads with a low political affinity score

might be deterred due to these bad relations. We follow Capron and Guillen (2009) and estimate

the determinants of the number of acquisitions between two countries using a negative binomial

regression model (results not shown, but available on request). This allows us to obtain the

predicted number of acquisitions between country dyads. When including this predicted number

of acquisitions as an additional regressor in Model 9, the variable is insignificant and political

affinity still strongly affects the acquisition premium. Also, when focusing on cross-border deals,

we do not consider the domestic alternative a target has when agreeing on being bought by a

foreigner. Following Bris and Cabolis (2008) we, therefore, first match cross-border deals with

similar domestic ones based on target firm and industry characteristics. We then take the

10

Note that due to the high correlation between cultural distance and the common language indicator we need to

exclude the former from this model.

Page 27: Getting by with a Little Help from My Friends: Does ...Alexander Settles Rutgers University 1 Washington Park Newark, New Jersey, USA 07102 ... We thank Christian Julliard, Carsten

27

difference between the premiums offered in these two deals as the dependent variable in Model

10.11

We find that a higher level of political affinity reduces the initial acquisition premium in

cross-border relative to domestic deals, thus confirming our previous results.

*** Insert Table 3 about here ***

In Table 3, we report the findings for the seemingly unrelated regressions for the

acquisition premium in Model 1, the toehold choice in Model 2, and the payment mode in Model

3 as the dependent variables. In all three models political affinity follows the predictions. A

higher political affinity score decreases the premium offered and the likelihood that an acquirer

will pay in cash, while it increases the propensity of using a toehold strategy. We check for the

robustness of the results in Models 4 to 9. In Models 4 to 6 we winsorize the political affinity

variable at 2 per cent and 98 per cent to control for possible outliers. In Models 7 to 9 we replace

political affinity with its one period lagged value for considering possible reverse causality

issues. The results remain robust in all models. Hypotheses 1 to 3 are supported. Political affinity

significantly influences the bidding strategy of private non-financial firms in cross-border

transactions.

11

Similar to Bris and Cabolis (2008) we match deals using the following criteria: The deals are announced in the

same year; the target firm belongs to the same industry (2-digit SIC code) and country; and the target firm in the

domestic deal is the closest in terms of total assets to the target firm in the cross-border deal. We exclude deals

where the matched transaction partners differ strongly in size.

Page 28: Getting by with a Little Help from My Friends: Does ...Alexander Settles Rutgers University 1 Washington Park Newark, New Jersey, USA 07102 ... We thank Christian Julliard, Carsten

28

SUPPLEMENTARY ANALYSES

Moderating role of the political context in the relationship between the acquisition

premium and political affinity

In our supplementary analyses, our first objective is to understand more in depth the mechanisms

through which political affinity affects cross-border acquisition deal-making. We focus on the

moderating role of the political context in the target country on the relationship between political

affinity and the acquisition premium, as the acquisition premium is the most important bidding

parameter and features a large variation in outcomes. We present the results for the models when

adding these moderators individually (Models 1 to 4) and when including them jointly (Model

5).We explore two different, but complementary dimensions of the political context, namely the

host government environment and the domestic political connections of the target firm.

*** Insert Table 4 about here ***

Concerning the first dimension we analyze the relevance of government weakness and

the extent of nationalism in a host country for political affinity effectiveness. Both have been

found to influence government interventions against foreign acquisitions in general (Dinc and

Erel, forthcoming). The political decisions that may influence a cross-border acquisition result

from a trade-off for the host government between foreign policy and domestic interests (Putnam,

1988). While the host government desires to realize its foreign policy interests, it also has to take

into account domestic arrangements. If political decision-making procedures limit governments

in their ability to set policy outcomes, foreign policy objectives are more difficult to implement

(Morgan and Campbell, 1991; Rogowski, 1999). In this regard, it has been argued that coalition

governments are weaker (Dinc and Erel, forthcoming), since they face larger difficulties to find

Page 29: Getting by with a Little Help from My Friends: Does ...Alexander Settles Rutgers University 1 Washington Park Newark, New Jersey, USA 07102 ... We thank Christian Julliard, Carsten

29

consensus within the government for a coherent action agenda (Martin and Vanberg, 2003). A

forward-looking acquirer is likely to consider the constraints the host government faces in

exerting power in the domestic context and its ability to push through foreign policy interests.

Therefore, the relationship between the initial acquisition premium and political affinity could be

moderated by government weakness. We use government fractionalization (Source: Database of

Political Institutions (DPI)) as a measure (Dinc and Erel, forthcoming). We find support in

Model 1 and 5 in table 4 that it positively moderates the effect of political affinity.

Also, nationalist tendencies in a country should reduce the ability of a host government to

provide help to foreign political friends. We measure nationalism with the share of votes of

nationalist parties in a country’s parliament (Source: DPI). We find that, indeed, when the

country is more nationalistic, foreign policy objectives weigh in lower. The effect of political

affinity is reduced; foreign firms have to pay a relatively higher premium for a given level of

political affinity (see the Models 2 and 5 in Table 4). Interestingly, we observe in the Models 3

and 5 that the moderating effect is reversed and becomes negative with a larger share of

nationalists in a country’s government (Source: DPI). Once nationalists have a larger share of

government control, foreign acquirers expect them to more closely consider political affinity

when taking political decisions.

At a different level, foreign acquirers should expect host governments to be more likely

to interfere in M&A transactions according to political affinity considerations when the target

firm is politically connected. There is large evidence that firms can leverage political connections

at their benefit (e.g., Faccio, 2006; Faccio, Masulis, and McConnell, 2006; Fisman, 2001). But,

at the same time, politicians can also use these connections for advancing their political interests

(Lenway and Murtha, 1994). Communication to the target firm might be easier and power

Page 30: Getting by with a Little Help from My Friends: Does ...Alexander Settles Rutgers University 1 Washington Park Newark, New Jersey, USA 07102 ... We thank Christian Julliard, Carsten

30

towards the target firm could be larger. The negative effect of political affinity on the premium

could therefore be strengthened when political connections exist. To investigate this issue we use

the data on politically connected firms collected by Faccio (2006) and available on the website of

the American Economic Association, which identifies a firm as politically connected when a

member of parliament, a minister, or someone closely related to a top politician or party is one of

the large owners or a top officer of this firm.

We find evidence in Models 4 and 5 in Table 4 that political connections of the target

firm reinforce the negative effect of political affinity. Our measure assumes that political

connections remain persistent over time; firms that have a connection in 1997-2001 (the period

used by Faccio (2006) for identifying political connected firms) are more likely to have some

connection before and are also more likely to continue having one or get a new direct political

connection later. Such an assumption is reasonable since the connections captured by Faccio

(2006: 369) are described as relatively “durable”. Albeit a dramatic reduction in our sample size,

the interaction term between the variables political connection and political affinity remains

significantly negative if we use a shorter period of time (1994-2004) or the strict period 1997-

2001. Results are available on request.

Political affinity and stock market reaction to the deal

The question also arises to what degree political affinity influences shareholder expectations

towards the acquisition. To answer it, we apply the standard event study methodology. We

calculate cumulative abnormal returns for each acquiring firm i for the three-day (-1,1) and five-

day (-2,2) window around acquisition announcements. Assuming market efficiency, the

abnormal returns provide an evaluation by the (stock) market of the value that is anticipated to be

Page 31: Getting by with a Little Help from My Friends: Does ...Alexander Settles Rutgers University 1 Washington Park Newark, New Jersey, USA 07102 ... We thank Christian Julliard, Carsten

31

created by the acquisition for the acquiring firm (Fama, 1970). The abnormal return for firm

security i at day t, cumulated over the event window, is the differential between the returns for

security i at day t and the normal returns for firm i at the same day t. Normal returns are obtained

using the market model. We use a 250 trading day estimation window (-292, -43) following the

existing literature. As market indices we use the local market indices as provided by Thomson

Datastream. We then regress these abnormal returns on the list of explanatory variables,

including political affinity. In Models 6 (three-day window) and 7 (five-day window) of Table 4,

political affinity significantly increases the abnormal returns to the acquirer. Hence, the market

perceives political affinity to be valuable for the acquiring firms, supporting our previous

findings.

In sum, both managers, as observed in the bidding strategy, and shareholders of the

acquiring firm, as revealed by their immediate reaction to the announcement of the deal, expect

that a higher level of political affinity will be favorable to acquisitions in foreign markets.

DISCUSSION AND CONCLUSION

In this paper we examine the role of political affinity between countries in cross-border M&A

deal-making. We find that the initial bid premium – the major strategic bidding component –

decreases with a higher level of political affinity, controlling for a large set of variables,

including cultural and other institutional differences between countries. We also observe that

political affinity impacts the two other strategic bidding choices, i.e., the acquisition payment

method and the establishment of a toehold. In a supplementary analysis we identify political

contingency factors at the target and host government level. We also find that shareholders

expect the foreign acquirer to gain from a higher level of political affinity, underlining the

Page 32: Getting by with a Little Help from My Friends: Does ...Alexander Settles Rutgers University 1 Washington Park Newark, New Jersey, USA 07102 ... We thank Christian Julliard, Carsten

32

empirical robustness of the result that political affinity has an impact on cross-border

transactions. These findings point at the importance of international relations for cross-border

deals.

We contribute to a small, but growing literature on international relations and foreign

acquisitions in the following way. An abundant literature has explored the role of institutions in

general and of the host country political environment in particular for business transactions

(Boddewyn and Brewer, 1994; Delios and Henisz, 2003). In this research area a few studies have

focused on protectionism and host government interventions against foreigners (Aktas et al.

2004; 2007; Dinc and Erel, forthcoming). Also, researchers have explained how firms can

leverage their domestic political connections to modify to their advantage their local business

environment (Faccio, 2006; Oliver and Holzinger, 2008). But, at a different level of analysis,

little has been said about country-level bilateral political relations and how they can interfere

with international business. Hence, while the distinction between domestic and foreign acquirers

has been made to explain, for instance, government intervention (e.g., Dinc and Erel,

forthcoming), the literature has only to a limited degree taken into account the heterogeneity of

interstate relations for explaining the variation in political discrimination experienced by firms of

different nationalities and its eventual impact on their business transactions.

This paper helps to fill this gap. We stretch the boundaries of previous macro-level work

which found that international relations are important for country-level aggregated FDI (Li and

Sacko, 2002; Li and Vashchilko, 2010) to decisions made by private non-financial companies in

international deals. In this context we add to previous research on the bearing of multilateral or

bilateral international agreements on international business (e.g., Ramamurti, 2001; Rangan and

Sengul, 2009) by referring to political affinity. Political affinity captures the similarity in

Page 33: Getting by with a Little Help from My Friends: Does ...Alexander Settles Rutgers University 1 Washington Park Newark, New Jersey, USA 07102 ... We thank Christian Julliard, Carsten

33

preferences in global affairs of the host and home country and is a finer-grained and higher-order

process that focuses on the willingness of governments to carry out cooperative or conflictual

foreign policy actions. In the international relations literature the concept of political affinity was

first developed by Gartzke (1998) as a construct to analyze the role of preferences of countries in

militarized international disputes. We apply it to the international business setting and argue that,

just as similarity in political preferences shape international political outcomes, it also affects

government behavior in economic matters and is therefore likely to translate into a differing

extent of political discrimination that foreign firms experience in the host market based on their

nationality. While positive political affinity opens the door for economic cooperation,

transactions of firms from less friendly countries are rendered more difficult.

Our research work complements very recent empirical studies by Knill et al. (2012) and

Johan et al. (2013) which focus on SWFs and highlight that political affinity influences their

foreign investments according to the state funds’ political motivations. We examine the strategic

behavior of private non-financial firms and, contrary to these two studies, argue that political

affinity can favorably affect the profit-maximization decisions of strategic acquirers. Strategic

acquirers view a favorable political relation as creating strategic advantages. On top of that, we

empirically identify moderators of the political affinity effect. We find that the effect of country-

level bilateral political relations can be moderated by the domestic political connections of the

target firm and the political context in which the host government is embedded. Political

friendship is particularly important when a country’s environment is receptive to foreign policy

issues.

Both our theoretical focus and empirical set-up differ from the papers that have been

previously cited. In addition to highlighting political affinity as an underlying driver of “special

Page 34: Getting by with a Little Help from My Friends: Does ...Alexander Settles Rutgers University 1 Washington Park Newark, New Jersey, USA 07102 ... We thank Christian Julliard, Carsten

34

relationships” between countries, we examine strategic decisions that have been seldom analyzed

in the field of IB. As a firm-level decision we decided to focus on the bidding behavior of the

foreign firm. The bidding strategy of the acquirer reveals the bargaining position the acquirer

anticipates to have during deal negotiations. Since Jemison and Sitkin (1986)’s seminal work,

there has been a call for considering the acquisition process in more detail. But only a few

studies have studied it (see, e.g., Finkelstein and Haleblian, 2002; Muehlfeld, Rao Sahib, and

Van Witteloostuijn, 2012), especially in the cross-border context (see, e.g., Dikova et al., 2010).

Also, within strategic bidding choices, we put a strong emphasis on the initial bid premium since

“[t]he most important of these offer parameters is the initial bid premium” (Eckbo, 2009: 150).

In addition, acquisition premiums feature a large variation in outcomes and large acquisition

premiums can have a disastrous impact on the acquisition performance (Haunschild, 1994). By

showing that political affinity matters, we extend the small, but growing literature on premium

antecedents in finance (Bris and Cabolis, 2008; Rossi and Volpin, 2004) and in strategy in

general (Beckman and Haunschild, 2002; Hope et al., 2011; Kim, Haleblian, and Finkelstein,

2011).

An important managerial implication from our results is that MNEs are not without

grounding in global markets as firms retain a home nationality (Pauly and Reich, 1997). The

world market is spiky and political friction can contribute to these spikes. Consequently, firms

seeking to expand abroad should closely examine the bilateral political aspect of the international

deal. They should incorporate not only the political situation in the target country, but also the

dyadic relationship between the home and host countries.

As in other studies there are limitations to our paper, offering avenues for future research.

For instance, our sample consists of listed targets and thereby of large target and acquiring firms.

Page 35: Getting by with a Little Help from My Friends: Does ...Alexander Settles Rutgers University 1 Washington Park Newark, New Jersey, USA 07102 ... We thank Christian Julliard, Carsten

35

The sample selection of deals with publicly listed firms certainly helps in reducing the possibility

of a spurious relationship between political affinity and strategic bidding choices since these

firms are highly visible and deals are likely to be well advertised. Consequently, these

acquisitions have a higher probability to attract the attention of governments. On the other hand,

this sample selection limits generalizability as we do not include small transactions. Also, in our

analysis, due to data constraints, we neglect the role of diplomacy. When relations are friendlier,

diplomatic representations could operate more smoothly (Neumayer, 2008) as diplomats’ phone

calls are more likely to be returned and access to political and business networks is wider and

faster. Publicly available data, however, on diplomatic representation (Bayer, 2006) only

accounts for the presence of general diplomatic ties, but do not capture the nature and intensity

of diplomatic exchanges. Moreover, during the period we study, all our sample countries already

have some diplomatic representation in the partner country.

Page 36: Getting by with a Little Help from My Friends: Does ...Alexander Settles Rutgers University 1 Washington Park Newark, New Jersey, USA 07102 ... We thank Christian Julliard, Carsten

36

REFERENCES

Agrawal A, Jaffe JE. 2000. The post-merger performance puzzle. In Advances in Mergers &

Acquisitions, Volume 1, Finkelstein S, Cooper C. (eds). Emerald Group Publishing

Limited: London; 7-41.

Ahern K, Daminelli D, Fracassi C. Lost in translation? The effect of cultural values on mergers

around the world. Journal of Financial Economics, forthcoming.

Aktas N, de Bodt E, Roll, R. 2004. Market response to European regulation of business

combinations. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 39(4): 731-757.

Aktas N, de Bodt E, Roll, R. 2007. Is European M&A regulation protectionist? Economic

Journal 117(522): 1096-1121.

Aktas N, de Bodt E, Roll R. 2010. Negotiations under the Threat of an Auction. Journal of

Financial Economics 98(2): 241-255.

Bayer R. 2006. Diplomatic Exchange Data set, v2006.1. http://correlatesofwar.org. [15 August

2012].

Beckman CM, Haunschild PR. 2002. Network Learning: The Effects of Partners' Heterogeneity

of Experience on Corporate Acquisitions. Administrative Science Quarterly 47(1): 92-

124.

Benner MJ, Tushman M. 2002. Process management and technological innovation: a

longitudinal study of the photography and paint industries. Administrative Science

Quarterly 47: 676-708.

Bertrand O, Hakkala K, Norbäck PJ, Persson L. 2012. Should Countries Block Foreign

Takeovers of R&D Champions and Promote Greenfield Entry? Canadian Journal of

Economics 45(3): 1083-1124.

Betton S, Eckbo BE, Thorburn KS. 2008. Markup pricing revisited. Working paper, Tuck School

of Business at Dartmouth.

Betton S, Eckbo BE, Thorburn K. S. 2009. Merger negotiations and the toehold puzzle. Journal

of Financial Economics 91: 158-178.

Boddewyn JJ, Brewer TL. 1994. International-Business Political Behavior: New Theoretical

Directions. Academy of Management Review 19(1): 119-143.

Boehmer C, Gartzke E, Nordstrom T. 2004. Do intergovernmental organizations promote peace?

World Politics 57(1): 1-38.

Bris A, Cabolis C. 2008. The Value of Investor Protection: Firm Evidence from Cross-Border

Mergers. Review of Financial Studies 21(2): 605-648.

Buthe T, Milner HV. 2008. The politics of foreign direct investment into developing countries:

Increasing FDI through international trade agreements? American Journal of Political

Science 52(4): 741-762.

Capron L, Guillen MF. 2009. National Corporate Governance Institutions and Post-Acquisition

Target Reorganization. Strategic Management Journal 30(8): 803-833.

Choi D. 1991. Toehold acquisitions, shareholder wealth, and the market for corporate control.

Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 26: 391-407.

Chowdry B, Jegadeesh N, 1994. Pre-tender offer share acquisition strategy in takeovers. Journal

of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 29: 117-129.

Clifton J, Díaz-Fuentes D. 2011. The European Union, Southern Multinationals and the question

of the Strategic Industries. In L. Brennan (ed.), The Emergence of Southern

Multinationals: Their Impact on Europe: 230-245. London: Palgrave Macmillan.

Page 37: Getting by with a Little Help from My Friends: Does ...Alexander Settles Rutgers University 1 Washington Park Newark, New Jersey, USA 07102 ... We thank Christian Julliard, Carsten

37

Clougherty JA. 2003. Non-Market Strategy for Merger Reviews: The Roles of Institutional

Independence & International Competitive Effects. Business & Society 42(1): 115-143.

Colignon R, Usui, C. 2001. The resilience of Japan's iron triangle - Amakudari. Asian Survey

41(5): 865-895.

Copson RW, Dumbaugh K, Lau M. 2005. Congressional Research Service. Report RL33055.

China and Sub-Saharan Africa. August 29, 2005.

http://wlstorage.net/file/crs/RL33055.pdf [20 November 2013].

Delios A, Henisz WJ. 2003. Policy Uncertainty and the Sequence of Entry by Japanese Firms,

1980-1998. Journal of International Business Studies 34(3): 227-241.

De Sousa J. 2012. The currency union effect on trade is decreasing over time. Economics Letters

117(3): 917-920.

Dikova D, Rao Sahib P, van Witteloostuijn A. 2010. Cross-border acquisition abandonment and

completion: The effect of institutional differences and organizational learning in the

international business service industry, 1981-2001. Journal of International Business

Studies 41(2): 223-245.

Dinc S, Erel I. Economic Nationalism in Mergers and Acquisitions. Journal of Finance

forthcoming.

Eckbo EB, 2009. Bidding strategies and takeover premiums: A review. Journal of Corporate

Finance 15: 149-178.

Eden L, Lenway S, Schuler D. 2005. From the obsolescing bargain to the political bargaining

model. In International business–government relations in the 21st century, Grosse R.

(ed). Cambridge University Press: Cambridge, UK; 251-272.

Egger P, Merlo V. 2007. The impact of bilateral investment treaties on FDI dynamics. World

Economy 30(10): 1536-1549.

Elkins Z, Guzman AT, Simmons BA. 2006. Competing for capital: The diffusion of bilateral

investment treaties, 1960-2000. International Organization 60(4): 811-846.

Faccio M. 2006. Politically connected firms. American Economic Review 96(1): 369-386.

Faccio M, McConnell JJ, Masulis RW. 2006. Political connections and corporate bailouts.

Journal of Finance 61(6): 2597-2635.

Fama E. 1970. Efficient capital markets: a review of theory and empirical work. Journal of

Finance 25(2): 383-417.

Finkelstein S, Haleblian J. 2002. Understanding acquisition performance: The role of transfer

effects. Organization Science 13(1): 36-47.

Fishman MJ. 1988. A theory of preemptive takeover bidding. RAND Journal of Economics 19:

88-101.

Fishman MJ. 1989. Preemptive Bidding and the Role of the Medium of Exchange in

Acquisitions. The Journal of Finance 44(1): 41-57.

Fisman RJ. 2001. Estimating the Value of Political Connections. American Economic Review

91(4): 1095-1102.

Frynas JJG, Mellahi K, Pigman GA. 2006. First mover advantages in international business and

firm-specific political resources. Strategic Management Journal 27(4): 321-345.

Gartzke E. 1998. Kant we all just get along? Opportunity, willingness, and the origins of the

democratic peace. American Journal of Political Science 42(1): 1-27.

Gartzke E, Gleditsch KS. 2006. Identity and conflict: Ties that bind and differences that divide.

European Journal of International Relations 12(1): 53-87.

Page 38: Getting by with a Little Help from My Friends: Does ...Alexander Settles Rutgers University 1 Washington Park Newark, New Jersey, USA 07102 ... We thank Christian Julliard, Carsten

38

Giammarino RM, Heinkel RL. 1986. A model of dynamic takeover behavior. Journal of Finance

41: 465-480.

Goldman E, Qian J. 2005. Optimal toeholds in takeover contests. Journal of Financial

Economics 77: 321-346.

Goldstein JS, Pevehouse JC. 2006. International Relations: 2006- 2007 Edition. Pearson

Longman: New York.

Grossman S, Hart O. 1980. Takeover bids, the free rider problem, and the theory of the

corporation. Bell Journal of Economics 11(1): 42-69.

Hafner-Burton EM, von Stein J, Gartzke E. 2008. International organizations count. Journal of

Conflict Resolution 52(2): 175-188.

Haleblian JC, Devers E, McNamara G, Carpenter MA, Davison, R. B. 2009. Taking Stock of

What We Know About Mergers and Acquisitions: A Review and Research Agenda.

Journal of Management 35(3): 469-502.

Haunschild PR. 1994. How much is that company worth: Interorganizational relationships,

uncertainty and acquisition premiums. Administrative Science Quarterly 39(3): 392-411.

Haunschild PR, Beckman CM. 1998. When do interlocks matter? Alternate sources of

information and interlock influence. Administrative Science Quarterly 43(4): 815-844.

Hayward MLA, Hambrick DC. 1997. Explaining the premiums paid for large acquisitions:

Evidence of CEO hubris. Administrative Science Quarterly 42(1): 103-127.

Hillman AJ, Keim GD, Schuler D. 2004. Corporate political activity: A review and research

agenda. Journal of Management 30(6): 837-857.

Hillman AJ, Wan W. 2005. The Determinants of MNE subsidiaries’ political strategies: evidence

of institutional duality. Journal of International Business Studies 36(3): 322-340.

Hirshleifer D, Png IPL. 1989. Facilitation of competing bids and the price of a takeover target.

Review of Financial Studies 2: 587-606.

Hirshleifer D, Titman S. 1990. Share tendering strategies and the success of hostile takeover bids.

Journal of Political Economy 98: 295-324.

Holburn GLF, Zelner BA. 2010. Political Capabilities, Policy Risk and International Investment

Strategy: Evidence from the Global Electric Power Industry. Strategic Management

Journal 31(12): 1290-1315.

Hofstede G. 1980. Culture's Consequences: International Differences in Work Related Values.

Sage: Beverly Hills, CA.

Hope O, Wayne T, Vyas D. 2011. The cost of pride: Why do firms from developing countries

bid higher? Journal of International Business Studies 42: 128-151.

Hymer S. 1976 .The International Operations of National Firms: A Study of Direct Foreign

Investment. MIT Press: Cambridge, MA.

Jemison DB, Sitkin SB. 1986. Corporate Acquisitions: A Process Perspective. Academy of

Management Review 11(1): 145-163.

Johan S, Knill A. Mauck N. 2013. Determinants of sovereign wealth fund investment in private

equity vs public equity. Journal of International Business Studies 44: 155-172.

Kadushin C. 1995. Friendship among the French financial elite. American Sociological Review

60(2): 202-221.

Karolyi GA, Liao RC. 2013. State Capitalism’s Global Reach: Evidence from Foreign

Acquisitions by State-owned Companies, Working paper.

Page 39: Getting by with a Little Help from My Friends: Does ...Alexander Settles Rutgers University 1 Washington Park Newark, New Jersey, USA 07102 ... We thank Christian Julliard, Carsten

39

Kim JY, Haleblian J, Finkelstein S. 2011. When Firms Are Desperate to Grow via Acquisition:

The Effect of Growth Patterns and Acquisition Experience on Acquisition Premiums.

Administrative Science Quarterly 56(1): 26-60.

Kim CF, Pantzalis C, Park JC. 2012. Political Geography and Stock Returns: The Value and

Risk Implications of Proximity to Political Power. Journal of Financial Economics 106:

196-228.

Kinsella D, Russett B. 2002. Conflict emergence and escalation in interactive international

dyads. Journal of Politics 64(4): 1045-1068.

Knill A, Lee B-S, Mauck N. 2012. Bilateral Political Relations and Sovereign Wealth Fund

Investment. Journal of Corporate Finance 18(1): 108-123.

Kogut B, Singh H. 1988. The effect of national culture on the choice of entry mode. Journal of

International Business Studies 19(3): 411-432.

Kostova T, Zaheer S. 1999. Organizational legitimacy under conditions of complexity: The case

of the multinational enterprise. Academy of Management Review 24(1): 64-81.

Krishnan HA, Hitt MA., Park D. 2007. Acquisition premiums, subsequent workforce reductions

and post-acquisition performance. Journal of Management Studies 44(5): 709-732.

La Porta R, Lopez-de-Silanes F, Shleifer A. 2008. The economic consequences of legal origins.

Journal of Economic Literature 46(2): 285-332.

Laamanen T. 2007. On the role of acquisition premium in acquisition research. Strategic

Management Journal 28(13): 1359-1369.

Lenway SA, Murtha TP. 1994. The state as strategist in international business research. Journal

of International Business Studies 25: 513-535.

Li Q, Sacko D. 2002. The (ir)relevance of militarized interstate disputes for international trade.

International Studies Quarterly 46(1): 11-43.

Li Q, Vashchilko T. 2010. Dyadic military conflict, security alliances, and bilateral FDI flows.

Journal of International Business Studies 41(5): 765-782.

Lipton E, Clark N, Lehren AW. 2011. Diplomats Help Push Sales of Jetliners on the Global

Market, The New York Times January 2: A(1).

Martin LW, Vanberg G. 2003. Wasting time? The impact of ideology and size on delay in

coalition formation. British Journal of Political Science 33(2): 323-332.

Martynova M, Renneboog L. 2009. What determines the financing decision in corporate

takeovers: Cost of capital, agency problems, or the means of payment? Journal of

Corporate Finance 15(3): 290-315.

McNish J, Bouw B, Reguly E. 2010. Potash: The deal that didn't have to die. The Globe and

Mail November 05: http://www.theglobeandmail.com/globe-investor/potash-the-deal-

that-didnt-have-to-die/article565916/?page=all [Aug 23 2012].

Moe TM, Howell WG. 1999. The presidential power of unilateral action. Journal of Law

Economics & Organization 15(1): 132-179.

Morgan TC, Campbell SH. 1991. Domestic structure, decisional constraints, and war: So why

Kant democracies fight. Journal of Conflict Resolution 35(2): 187-211.

Muehlfeld K, Rao Sahib P, Van Witteloostuijn A. 2012. A contextual theory of organizational

learning from failures and successes: A study of acquisition completion in the global

newspaper industry, 1981–2008. Strategic Management Journal 33(8): 938-964.

Munck GL, Verkuilen J. 2002. Conceptualizing and measuring democracy. Comparative

Political Studies 35(1): 5-34.

Page 40: Getting by with a Little Help from My Friends: Does ...Alexander Settles Rutgers University 1 Washington Park Newark, New Jersey, USA 07102 ... We thank Christian Julliard, Carsten

40

Nebus J, Rufin C. 2010. Extending the bargaining power model: Explaining bargaining

outcomes among nations, MNEs, and NGOs. Journal of International Business Studies

41(6): 996-1015.

Neumayer E. 2008. Distance, power and ideology: diplomatic representation in a world of

nation-states. Area 40(2): 228–236.

North D. 1994. Economic Performance through Time. American Economic Review 84(3): 359-

368.

Officer MS. 2003. Termination fees in mergers and acquisitions. Journal of Financial

Economics 69(3): 431-467.

Oliver C, Holzinger I. 2008. The effectiveness of strategic political management: A dynamic

capabilities framework. Academy of Management Review 33(2): 496-520.

Pauly LW, Reich S. 1997. National structures and multinational corporate behavior: Enduring

differences in the age of globalization. International Organization 51(1): 1-30.

Peterson D, Peterson P. 1991. The medium of exchange in mergers and Acquisitions. Journal of

Banking and Finance 15: 383-405.

Phelps C. 2010. A longitudinal study of the influence of alliance network structure and

composition on firm exploratory innovation. Academy of Management Journal 53(4):

890-913.

Putnam RD. 1988. Diplomacy and Domestic Politics: The Logic of Two-Level Games.

International Organization 42(3): 427-460.

Ramamurti R. 2001. The obsolescing 'bargaining model'? MNC-host developing country

relations revisited. Journal of International Business Studies 32(1):23-39.

Rangan S, Sengul M. 2009. The Influence of Macro Structure on the Foreign Market

Performance of Transnational Firms: The Value of IGO Connections, Export

Dependence, and Immigration Links. Administrative Science Quarterly 54(2): 229-267.

Rao H, Drazin R. 2002. Overcoming resource constraints on product innovation by recruiting

talent from rivals: a study of the mutual fund industry, 1986–1994. Academy of

Management Journal 45: 491-508.

Reichheld FF, Henske B. 1991. The only sure method of recouping merger premiums. Journal of

Retail Banking 8(2): 9-17.

Reuer J, Tong TW, Tyler BB, Ariño A. 2013. Executive preferences for governance modes and

exchange partners: An information economics perspective. Strategic Management

Journal 34(9): 1104-1122.

Rogowski R. 1999. Institutions as Constraints on Strategic Choice. In Strategic Choice, Lake

DA, Powell R. (eds). Princeton University Press: Princeton, NJ; 115-136.

Rossi S, Volpin P. 2004. Cross-Country Determinants of Mergers and Acquisitions. Journal of

Financial Economics 74: 277-304.

Saner R, Yiu L, Sondergaard M. 2000. Business diplomacy management: A core competency for

global companies. Academy of Management Executive 14(1): 80-92.

Schwert GW. 1996. Markup pricing in mergers and acquisitions. Journal of Financial

Economics 41, 153-192.

Shane and Lehren, 2010. Leaked Cables Offer Raw Look at U.S. Diplomacy, The New York

Times November 29: A(1).

Sirower ML. 1994. Acquisition Behavior, Strategic Resource Commitments and the Acquisition

Game: A New Perspective on Performance and Risk in Acquiring Firms. Columbia

University Press: New York.

Page 41: Getting by with a Little Help from My Friends: Does ...Alexander Settles Rutgers University 1 Washington Park Newark, New Jersey, USA 07102 ... We thank Christian Julliard, Carsten

41

Stone RW. 2004. The political economy of IMF lending in Africa. American Political Science

Review 98(4): 577-591.

Stopford J, Strange S. 1991. Rival states and rival firms: competition for world market shares.

Cambridge University Press: Cambridge, UK.

Sudarasanam S. 1995. The role of defensive strategies and ownership structure of target firms:

evidence from UK hostile takeover bids. European Financial Management 1: 223-40.

Thomson K, Bodrug J, Damiani L. 2011. Protectionism: Implications for Hostile and Friendly

Change of Control Transactions. Lexpert July: 43-48.

http://www.dwpv.com/~/media/Files/PDF/Article_Protectionism_Implications_for_Hosti

le_and_Friendly_Change_of_Control_Transactions.ashx [20 November 2013].

UNCTAD 2000. World Investment Report: Cross-Border Mergers and Acquisitions and

Development. United Nations: New York and Geneva.

Voeten E, 2000. Clashes in the Assembly. International Organization 54(2): 185-215.

Werner S. 1997. In search of security: Relative gains and losses in dyadic relations. Journal of

Peace Research 34(3): 289-302.

Wikileaks 2006. France and foreign investment: job protectionism trumps open capital markets.

http://www.wikileaks.org/plusd/cables/06PARIS1823_a.html [20 November 2013].

Wurgler J. 2000. Financial markets and the allocation of capital. Journal of Financial Economics

58(1-2):187-214.

Zaheer S. 1995.Overcoming the liability of foreignness. Academy of Management Journal 38(2):

341-363.

Zelner BA, Henisz WJ, Holburn GLF. 2009. Contentious Implementation and Retrenchment in

Neoliberal Policy Reform: The Global Electricity Power Industry 1989-2001.

Administrative Science Quarterly 54: 379-412.

Zellner A. 1962. An efficient method for estimating seemingly unrelated regressions and test of

aggregation bias. American Statistical Association Journal 57: 500-509.

Page 42: Getting by with a Little Help from My Friends: Does ...Alexander Settles Rutgers University 1 Washington Park Newark, New Jersey, USA 07102 ... We thank Christian Julliard, Carsten

42

Table 1: Summary statistics and correlations

VARIABLES Mean S.D. 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 21 22 23 24

1 Initial Acquisition Premium 44.67 37.076 1

2 Political Affinity 0.312 0.37 -0.1255 1

3 Difference in Political Systems between Countries 0.397 1.545 0.0292 -0.0408 1

4 Cultural Distance 1.714 1.155 0.0053 0.1085 0.3449 1

5 Difference in Shareholder Protection between Countries -0.156 0.999 -0.0191 -0.064 -0.018 -0.0696 1

6 Difference in GDP per Capita between Countries -0.168 0.637 0.0138 0.1998 -0.0938 -0.1909 0.039 1

7 Difference in Size between Acquiror and Target 2.355 1.788 0.0489 -0.0776 0.0121 -0.0442 -0.0794 0.0289 1

8 Acquiror ROA 0.121 0.108 -0.0039 -0.0773 0.0234 -0.0032 0.0351 -0.0392 0.1313 1

9 Target ROA 0.025 0.081 0.0024 0.0481 0.0065 0.025 0.0619 0.0163 -0.3492 0.2083 1

10 Acquiror Debt Ratio 0.524 0.199 -0.0818 0.1232 -0.0549 0.1149 -0.0337 0.0327 0.0994 0.0201 0.0559 1

11 Target Debt Ratio 0.491 0.272 0.0051 0.1046 0.0161 0.0416 0.0017 0.0174 -0.0878 0.0197 0.0608 0.3311 1

12 Acquisition Experience 2.917 4.498 -0.0094 -0.0477 -0.0225 -0.031 -0.068 0.0865 0.3833 0.1053 -0.065 0.1269 -0.0405 1

13 Stake Sought 95.631 11.552 0.1394 -0.1918 -0.1565 -0.1493 -0.0407 -0.0948 -0.0302 -0.0018 0.0132 -0.0723 -0.0719 -0.0369 1

14 Completed Deal 0.929 0.258 0.042 -0.0491 -0.0343 0.0284 0.0845 -0.0683 0.048 -0.0362 -0.0632 0.0305 0.0046 -0.0136 -0.0217 1

15 Multiple Bidders 0.11 0.314 0.095 0.037 0.0018 -0.0769 -0.1702 0.0064 -0.0159 0.0511 0.1026 -0.0028 0.0147 0.0561 0.0415 -0.4397 1

16 Tender Offer 0.618 0.486 0.1118 0.2057 -0.0141 0.101 -0.1266 0.0709 0.0782 0.0993 -0.0137 0.1402 0.073 -0.0196 -0.0447 0.0618 0.0658 1

17 Cash Payment 0.648 0.478 0.061 -0.0988 0.004 0.091 0.0459 -0.1139 0.2754 0.1862 -0.0104 0.1466 0.0379 0.1011 -0.1316 0.0117 0.0359 0.2638 1

18 Toehold 0.112 0.315 -0.0952 0.154 0.0753 0.078 0.0293 0.0693 0.0308 0.0285 0.006 0.0593 0.0358 0.0875 -0.7278 0.0294 -0.026 0.142 0.0854 1

19 Horizontal Acquisition 0.359 0.48 -0.0327 0.0268 0.0659 -0.0619 0.0204 -0.0343 -0.1792 -0.0032 0.0972 -0.0837 0.0172 -0.0498 0.0605 -0.0302 -0.013 -0.0472 -0.1734 -0.0347 1

20 Hostile Acquisition 0.062 0.24 0.0075 0.0696 -0.047 -0.0354 -0.0912 0.0831 -0.0799 0.056 0.0671 0.0338 0.0191 0.0138 -0.0211 -0.2456 0.1511 0.1533 0.0915 0.0937 -0.0341 1

21 Nationalist Party Parliament Vote Share 1.378 5.347 -0.0106 -0.005 -0.0178 -0.1285 -0.1005 0.1723 0.0251 0.0015 0.0404 0.0067 -0.0548 0.012 0.0136 0.0199 -0.0193 -0.0521 -0.0389 0.0091 0.0132 -0.0236 1

22 Nationalist Party Government Vote Share 0.151 1.85 0.0152 0.109 0.0525 0.005 0.1219 0.0649 -0.0465 0.0185 0.0549 0.0073 -0.0287 0.0213 -0.0448 -0.0236 0.0085 0.0156 -0.0041 0.0582 0.0029 -0.0209 0.3276 1

23 Government Fractionalization 0.097 0.199 -0.0411 0.4001 -0.0292 0.1817 0.0933 0.0991 -0.032 0.0348 -0.0024 -0.0706 -0.0212 0.0262 -0.1937 -0.0184 0.0516 0.1204 -0.039 0.1724 0.0011 -0.002 0.0129 0.2333 1

24 Target Political Connection 0.017 0.129 -0.0143 0.1261 -0.0125 0.0446 -0.0774 0.0338 -0.0816 -0.0048 0.076 0.0486 0.0895 0.0072 0.0095 -0.0907 0.0581 -0.0094 -0.0631 0.0227 -0.0071 0.1025 0.0057 -0.0106 -0.0635 1

Page 43: Getting by with a Little Help from My Friends: Does ...Alexander Settles Rutgers University 1 Washington Park Newark, New Jersey, USA 07102 ... We thank Christian Julliard, Carsten

43

Table 2: The effect of political affinity on the acquisition premium

Model 1 Model 2 Model 3 Model 4 Model 5 Model 6 Model 7 Model 8 Model 9 Model 10

Control

variables only

Baseline

model

Trimmed

value

Final bid

premium

Lagged

variable

Few more

controls

Few more

controls

Non-daydic

controls

Selection bias

procedure

Matching

procedure

Difference in Political Systems between Countries 1.060 0.862 0.839 -0.219 0.919 1.009 0.913 0.812 0.295

(0.969) (0.924) (1.388) (0.571) (0.926) (0.929) (0.898) (0.930) (0.977)

Cultural Distance -0.251 0.428 1.121 0.670 0.294 0.549 0.680 0.331 0.768

(1.263) (1.205) (1.365) (1.200) (1.258) (1.213) (1.304) (1.413) (1.954)

Difference in Shareholder Protection between Countries -1.022 -0.988 -1.081 -0.342 -0.963 -0.728 -1.048 -1.028 -2.103

(1.433) (1.364) (1.365) (1.327) (1.354) (1.439) (1.387) (1.406) (1.747)

Difference in GDP per Capita between Countries 2.669 4.093* 2.802 4.541* 3.751 3.651 4.120* 4.180* 5.973**

(2.377) (2.347) (2.292) (2.300) (2.356) (2.696) (2.215) (2.416) (2.470)

Difference in Size between Acquiror and Target 1.110 1.149 0.277 0.910 1.180 1.210 1.074 1.139 1.300 -1.044

(1.355) (1.353) (1.390) (1.409) (1.357) (1.348) (1.351) (1.360) (1.399) (1.202)

Acquiror ROA -4.729 -10.00 -0.689 -4.308 -8.925 -9.462 -9.415 -8.989 -9.147 -17.60

(26.86) (25.10) (24.76) (25.01) (25.44) (25.05) (25.23) (25.40) (25.91) (13.38)

Target ROA 16.04 19.11 13.96 19.54 18.66 19.36 18.56 18.98 21.49 -21.69

(37.63) (38.13) (36.74) (41.56) (38.16) (37.98) (38.20) (38.25) (38.44) (21.29)

Acquiror Debt Ratio -26.35** -24.20** -22.17** -22.37** -23.41** -24.04** -24.58** -24.95** -24.88** -2.228

(10.22) (10.50) (10.08) (10.89) (10.62) (10.49) (10.56) (10.46) (10.52) (12.24)

Target Debt Ratio 5.084 5.873 7.974 8.614 5.740 5.854 5.061 5.775 5.795 9.212

(6.262) (6.137) (6.245) (6.812) (6.161) (6.152) (6.189) (6.162) (6.164) (9.131)

Acquisition Experience -0.0531 -0.0637 0.0989 0.191 -0.0668 -0.0452 -0.0312 -0.0515 -0.148 0.247

(0.296) (0.285) (0.310) (0.310) (0.292) (0.286) (0.290) (0.275) (0.308) (0.477)

Stake Sought 0.467*** 0.410*** 0.427*** 0.353*** 0.418*** 0.409*** 0.401*** 0.378*** 0.412*** 0.190

(0.104) (0.108) (0.111) (0.106) (0.108) (0.108) (0.113) (0.104) (0.109) (0.140)

Completed Deal 14.10*** 13.38*** 11.47** 11.97** 13.35*** 13.50*** 14.01*** 13.68*** 11.67** 13.94

(4.670) (4.748) (5.224) (5.394) (4.729) (4.733) (4.770) (4.765) (4.689) (8.598)

Multiple Bidders 17.51*** 17.44*** 11.12*** 19.17*** 17.49*** 17.52*** 18.20*** 17.57*** 16.03*** 18.72***

(4.430) (4.470) (4.165) (5.207) (4.503) (4.610) (4.639) (4.497) (4.526) (6.918)

Tender Offer 6.289* 7.597** 8.923** 10.17*** 7.244** 7.598** 7.620** 7.739** 7.624** 5.007

(3.415) (3.477) (4.041) (3.273) (3.396) (3.555) (3.502) (3.503) (3.465) (4.963)

Cash Payment 4.752 4.246 4.922 1.590 4.231 4.537 4.426 4.241 4.282 -2.076

(3.936) (3.939) (4.046) (4.151) (3.950) (3.891) (3.756) (3.915) (4.163) (6.360)

Hostile Acquisition -2.431 -1.255 -2.325 -1.993 -1.036 -1.469 -1.619 -1.499 -2.562 -6.481

(4.402) (4.232) (4.423) (4.348) (4.242) (4.277) (4.195) (4.227) (4.478) (8.287)

Horizontal Acquisition -0.102 -0.162 0.246 -0.552 -0.314 -0.212 0.102 0.0949 0.158 3.368

(3.331) (3.383) (3.841) (3.310) (3.387) (3.417) (3.502) (3.395) (3.336) (4.706)

Political Affinity -13.77*** -14.11*** -15.32*** -13.95*** -13.77*** -13.84*** -12.38**

(4.200) (4.189) (4.049) (4.268) (4.809) (4.094) (5.965)

Political Affinity (Trimmed value - 2 %) -15.33**

(6.157)

Political Affinity (t-1) -12.60***

(4.068)

Power Imbalance 0.277

(0.697)

BIT Effectiveness -6.308

(11.58)

Regional Trade Agreement 2.827

(2.355)

Common Language -2.643

(3.046)

Contiguity -0.705

(8.115)

Bilateral Trade Intensity 147.3

(272.6)

Home Country Political System -1.065

(0.756)

Host Country Political System -0.448

(1.579)

Home Country Shareholder Protection -0.428

(2.348)

Host Country Shareholder Protection 2.369

(2.295)

Home Country GDP per Capita 5.140*

(2.707)

Host Country GDP per Capita 0.355

(5.590)

Predicted Number of M&A -0.00812

(0.203)

Constant -31.76 -11.17 -17.14 -3.913 -13.97 -11.16 -9.499 -51.56 -7.602 44.02

(23.46) (23.14) (19.74) (20.19) (20.08) (23.93) (18.99) (60.38) (20.69) (31.25)

Observations 726 715 616 712 707 715 707 715 692 532

R-squared 0.116 0.127 0.124 0.118 0.120 0.129 0.128 0.129 0.121 0.090

*** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1

Sector and year fixed effects are included in each regression.

We cluster errors at the country pair level.

Page 44: Getting by with a Little Help from My Friends: Does ...Alexander Settles Rutgers University 1 Washington Park Newark, New Jersey, USA 07102 ... We thank Christian Julliard, Carsten

44

Table 3: The effect of political affinity on the toehold choice and payment mode

Model 1 Model 2 Model 3 Model 4 Model 5 Model 6 Model 7 Model 8 Model 9

Premium Toehold Cash Premium Toehold Cash Premium Toehold Cash

Trimmed value Trimmed value Trimmed value Lagged variable Lagged variable Lagged variable

Difference in Political Systems between Countries 0.393 0.0904*** -0.00702 0.205 0.0906** 0.0125 0.431 0.0938*** -0.00694

(0.940) (0.0291) (0.0425) (1.392) (0.0453) (0.0485) (0.942) (0.0292) (0.0425)

Cultural Distance 0.0435 0.0223 -0.0164 0.677 -0.00210 -0.00481 -0.0585 0.0150 -0.0186

(1.185) (0.0662) (0.0562) (1.340) (0.0737) (0.0640) (1.248) (0.0659) (0.0575)

Difference in Shareholder Protection between Countries -1.102 0.0509 0.122* -1.311 0.0606 0.128* -1.082 0.0494 0.127**

(1.461) (0.0848) (0.0641) (1.481) (0.0871) (0.0677) (1.441) (0.0845) (0.0643)

Difference in GDP per Capita between Countries 3.069 0.0298 -0.332*** 1.006 0.104 -0.380*** 2.711 0.0328 -0.337***

(2.480) (0.105) (0.0691) (2.511) (0.143) (0.0996) (2.491) (0.106) (0.0696)

Difference in Size between Acquiror and Target 1.341 -0.0256 0.116*** 0.519 -0.0431 0.126*** 1.372 -0.0253 0.118***

(1.276) (0.0351) (0.0310) (1.319) (0.0322) (0.0300) (1.283) (0.0358) (0.0314)

Acquiror ROA -8.290 0.458 0.738** 1.002 0.180 0.915*** -7.367 0.559 0.737**

(23.83) (0.483) (0.325) (23.76) (0.485) (0.317) (24.11) (0.475) (0.327)

Target ROA 21.85 0.0335 0.354 17.43 -0.00169 0.444 21.33 -0.0127 0.469

(36.93) (0.407) (0.541) (35.32) (0.386) (0.563) (37.00) (0.432) (0.530)

Acquiror Debt Ratio -23.69** -0.0250 0.434** -21.87** 0.113 0.483** -22.84** -0.0908 0.432**

(10.64) (0.278) (0.194) (10.34) (0.295) (0.208) (10.75) (0.294) (0.196)

Target Debt Ratio 5.220 -0.0677 -0.0967 7.207 -0.0534 -0.0269 5.065 -0.0608 -0.128

(6.075) (0.195) (0.149) (6.106) (0.177) (0.164) (6.095) (0.198) (0.149)

Acquisition Experience -0.129 0.0365*** -0.0170* 0.0265 0.0397*** -0.0262** -0.136 0.0372*** -0.0175*

(0.283) (0.0126) (0.00903) (0.305) (0.0133) (0.0107) (0.290) (0.0128) (0.00902)

Completed Deal 12.62*** 0.205 0.589*** 10.27** 0.252 0.643*** 12.60*** 0.211 0.578***

(4.640) (0.199) (0.147) (5.236) (0.205) (0.151) (4.622) (0.198) (0.147)

Multiple Bidders 17.95*** -0.265 0.316* 11.35*** -0.195 0.344* 18.05*** -0.277 0.306*

(4.303) (0.181) (0.175) (4.048) (0.186) (0.188) (4.341) (0.179) (0.176)

Tender Offer 8.830*** 0.620*** 1.043*** 10.45*** 0.621*** 1.017*** 8.385** 0.641*** 1.058***

(3.309) (0.123) (0.171) (3.845) (0.130) (0.191) (3.269) (0.123) (0.170)

Hostile Acquisition -0.912 0.332* 0.722*** -1.961 0.355* 0.792*** -0.662 0.325* 0.717***

(4.087) (0.186) (0.247) (4.105) (0.185) (0.256) (4.073) (0.186) (0.247)

Horizontal Acquisition 0.110 -0.190 -0.124 0.488 -0.178 -0.182* -0.0383 -0.181 -0.122

(3.447) (0.122) (0.0868) (3.985) (0.118) (0.0954) (3.450) (0.122) (0.0873)

Political Affinity -16.52*** 0.420*** -0.467***

(3.913) (0.158) (0.133)

Political Affinity (Trimmed value - 2 %) -18.74*** 0.626*** -0.570***

(5.802) (0.195) (0.163)

Political Affinity (t-1) -15.47*** 0.474*** -0.466***

(3.849) (0.159) (0.136)

Constant 36.37* -0.774 0.493 26.72* -0.771 0.566 27.70* -0.782 0.478

(18.99) (0.728) (0.924) (14.95) (0.738) (0.974) (16.67) (0.726) (0.926)

Observations 715 1123 1164 616 979 1020 707 1111 1152

*** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1

Sector and year fixed effects are included in each regression.

We cluster errors at the country pair level.

Page 45: Getting by with a Little Help from My Friends: Does ...Alexander Settles Rutgers University 1 Washington Park Newark, New Jersey, USA 07102 ... We thank Christian Julliard, Carsten

45

Table 4: Supplementary analyses: Political contingency factors; Stock market reaction

Model 1 Model 2 Model 3 Model 4 Model 5 Model 6 Model 7

Moderators Moderators Moderators Moderators Moderators CAAR (1,1) CAAR(2,2)

Difference in Political Systems between Countries 0.825 0.782 0.833 0.838 0.771 -0.00262 -0.00298

(0.923) (0.921) (0.927) (0.926) (0.932) (0.00159) (0.00180)

Cultural Distance 0.754 0.380 0.422 0.586 0.800 0.00233 -0.000633

(1.292) (1.235) (1.207) (1.227) (1.358) (0.00208) (0.00222)

Difference in Shareholder Protection between Countries -1.548 -1.379 -1.195 -1.032 -2.055 0.000508 0.00137

(1.478) (1.563) (1.412) (1.393) (1.774) (0.00215) (0.00228)

Difference in GDP per Capita between Countries 4.841** 4.361* 3.968* 4.023* 5.139** -0.00396 -0.00127

(2.301) (2.532) (2.381) (2.366) (2.558) (0.00357) (0.00376)

Difference in Size between Acquiror and Target 1.122 1.245 1.185 1.067 1.141 0.000181 -0.000499

(1.347) (1.367) (1.355) (1.367) (1.381) (0.00207) (0.00185)

Acquiror ROA -10.45 -10.21 -9.968 -9.983 -10.19 0.0495 0.0221

(25.02) (25.24) (25.13) (25.00) (25.17) (0.0325) (0.0446)

Target ROA 20.48 19.53 18.12 19.18 20.07 0.0511 0.0663*

(37.90) (38.70) (37.96) (38.09) (38.40) (0.0388) (0.0380)

Acquiror Debt Ratio -24.89** -24.12** -23.96** -23.85** -23.88** -0.0158 -0.0154

(10.66) (10.34) (10.53) (10.60) (10.68) (0.0134) (0.0153)

Target Debt Ratio 6.045 5.805 6.066 5.284 5.320 0.0192 0.0200

(6.155) (6.194) (6.159) (6.303) (6.409) (0.0143) (0.0177)

Acquisition Experience -0.00181 -0.109 -0.0812 -0.0549 -0.0475 -0.000363 -0.000107

(0.285) (0.289) (0.287) (0.284) (0.289) (0.000326) (0.000446)

Stake Sought 0.431*** 0.415*** 0.414*** 0.411*** 0.441*** -4.58e-05 -0.000291

(0.109) (0.107) (0.108) (0.108) (0.109) (0.000265) (0.000331)

Completed Deal 13.08*** 13.39*** 13.37*** 12.66*** 12.28** -0.00475 0.00133

(4.863) (4.763) (4.751) (4.646) (4.843) (0.00715) (0.00786)

Multiple Bidders 17.36*** 17.04*** 17.40*** 16.82*** 16.43*** 0.00499 0.00302

(4.532) (4.314) (4.463) (4.523) (4.390) (0.0108) (0.00974)

Tender Offer 8.161** 8.041** 7.512** 7.134** 8.270** 0.000406 -0.00179

(3.570) (3.589) (3.479) (3.491) (3.766) (0.00586) (0.00657)

Cash Payment 4.138 4.335 4.277 4.456 4.494 0.0282*** 0.0261***

(3.968) (4.014) (3.957) (3.948) (4.068) (0.00766) (0.00853)

Horizontal Acquisition -0.0963 -0.0292 -0.0287 0.113 0.443 -0.00608 -0.00280

(3.412) (3.399) (3.405) (3.372) (3.436) (0.00601) (0.00689)

Hostile Acquisition -1.199 -1.021 -1.141 -1.098 -0.980 -0.0279*** -0.0276**

(4.238) (4.240) (4.228) (4.140) (4.191) (0.00988) (0.0108)

Political Affinity -19.40*** -15.55*** -13.92*** -13.11*** -20.63*** 0.0199*** 0.0195***

(5.223) (4.526) (4.261) (4.281) (5.893) (0.00641) (0.00696)

Government Fractionalization -17.82* -19.06**

(9.064) (9.294)

Political Affinity * Government Fractionalization 35.30*** 36.92**

(13.39) (14.18)

Nationalist Party Parliament Vote Share -0.359* -0.430**

(0.201) (0.217)

Political Affinity * Nationalist Party Parliament Vote Share 1.297*** 1.502***

(0.454) (0.495)

Nationalist Party Government Vote Share 6.667* 8.454***

(3.513) (3.093)

Political Affinity * Nationalist Party Government Vote Share -7.620* -11.00***

(4.098) (3.580)

Target Political Connection 37.55*** 34.38***

(12.50) (12.40)

Political Affinity * Target Political Connection -60.51*** -53.86***

(17.74) (17.29)

Constant -7.785 -9.731 -11.89 -10.91 -6.899 -0.0983 -0.0491

(22.69) (22.94) (23.13) (23.43) (22.90) (0.0630) (0.0622)

Observations 715 715 715 715 715 662 662

R-squared 0.132 0.131 0.129 0.130 0.139 0.137 0.109

*** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1

Sector and year fixed effects are included in each regression.

We cluster errors at the country pair level.

Page 46: Getting by with a Little Help from My Friends: Does ...Alexander Settles Rutgers University 1 Washington Park Newark, New Jersey, USA 07102 ... We thank Christian Julliard, Carsten

46

APPENDIX

Country Number of International Number of International Year Number of International M&As

Acquirers Targets

Argentina 3 1 1990 6

Australia 19 54 1991 5

Austria 3 0 1992 1

Belgium 13 5 1993 1

Brazil 2 0 1994 9

Chile 0 3 1995 15

Canada 78 87 1996 10

Denmark 9 3 1997 39

Finland 15 4 1998 55

France 59 12 1999 80

Germany 51 5 2000 97

Greece 1 1 2001 49

India 6 0 2002 30

Indonesia 1 0 2003 38

Israel 11 6 2004 43

Italy 16 1 2005 51

Japan 18 3 2006 68

Korea 1 1 2007 67

Malaysia 2 1 2008 51

Mexico 6 0

Netherlands 48 21

New Zealand 4 6

Norway 4 17

Peru 1 1

Philippines 1 0

Singapore 5 7

South Africa 12 2

Spain 17 4

Sweden 23 22

Switzerland 16 7

United Kingdom 93 128

United States of America 177 313