global capital markets: integration, crisis and growth...prof. alan taylor (northwestem...

61
" " GETULIO VARGAS EPGE Escola de Pós-Graduação em Economia - - SE\II'\ \RIOS DF >l \ " rCU,\()\lJC \ "Global Capital Markets: Integration, Crisis and Growth" Prof. Alan Taylor (Northwestem University/NBER) (co-autoria com Maurice Obstfeld) LOCAL Fundação Getulio Vargas Praia de Botafogo, 190 - 10° andar - Auditório DATA 12/11/98 (53 feira) HORÁRIO 16:00h Coordenação: Prof. Pedro Cavalcanti Gomes Ferreira Email: [email protected](021) 536-9250

Upload: others

Post on 22-Oct-2020

3 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

  • " ~FUNDAÇÃO " GETULIO VARGAS

    EPGE Escola de Pós-Graduação em Economia

    - -

    SE\II'\ \RIOS DF PF~( >l J~ \

    " rCU,\()\lJC \

    "Global Capital Markets: Integration,

    Crisis and Growth"

    Prof. Alan Taylor (Northwestem University/NBER) (co-autoria com Maurice Obstfeld)

    LOCAL Fundação Getulio Vargas

    Praia de Botafogo, 190 - 10° andar - Auditório

    DATA 12/11/98 (53 feira)

    HORÁRIO 16:00h

    Coordenação: Prof. Pedro Cavalcanti Gomes Ferreira Email: [email protected] • (021) 536-9250

  • fH3c1Jd C'it){2-- 5 BIBLIOTECA

    '. MARIO HENR'QlJE SIMONSEN FUNJAÇAO G::OU; VARGAS

    '( < ;.': ; J ( __ \ \

    r _ . - I ) U ')

  • Global Capital Markets

    Integration, Crisis, and Growth

    This book presents an economic history of intemational capital mobility since the late nineteenth century. The book begins with a preamble that introduces the major issues and examines developments in the eighteeneth century and before, important historical preconditions that set the stage for a global market in the nineteenth century. We then discuss the theory and empirical evidence surrounding the falI and rise of integration in the global market. A discussion of institutional developments focuses on the use of capital controls and the pursuit of macroeconomic policy objectives in the context of changing monetary regimes. A fundamental macroeconomic policy trilemma has forced policymakers to trade off beteween conflicting goals, with natural implications for capital mobility. Understood this way, the present era of globalization can be seen, in part, as merely the resumption of a liberal world order that had previously been established in the years from 1880 to 1914. Marking a reaction against that order, the Great Depression emerges as the key tuming point in the recent history of intemational capital markets, and offers important insights for contemporary policy debates.

    MAURICE OBSTFELD is Class of 1958 Professor of Economics at the University of Califomia at Berkeley and a Research Associate of the National Bureau of Economic Research.

    ALAN M. TAYLOR is Assistant Professor ofEconomics at Northwestem University and a Faculty Research Fellow of the National Bureau of Economic Research .

    NWOTECA IlARIO HENRIQUE __ qlNDAclO GETOUD 'AlUI

  • Global Capital Markets

    Integration, Crisis, and Growth

    MAURICE OBSTFELD

    ALA'; ;"1. TAYLOR

    6C~BRIDGE >, UI'

  • Contents

    Foreword

    Acknowledgements

    Part one: Preamble

    Global Capital Markets: Overview and Origins

    1.1 Theoretical Benefits

    1.1.1 Intemational Risk Sharing

    1.1.2 Intertemporal Trade

    1.1.3 Discipline

    page Xl

    X 111

    4

    5

    5

    8

    9

    1.2 Problems of Supranational Capital Markets in Practice 10

    1.2.1 Enforcement of Contracts and Informational Problems 10

    1.2.2 Loss of Policy Autonomy II

    1.2.3 Intemational Aspects of Capital-Market Crises 12

    1.3 The Emergence of World Capital Markets 14

    1.3.1 Early Modem FinanciaI Development 15

    1.3.2 Technological and Institutional Changes 17

    1.3.3 The Rise of Global Finance 21

    IA Stylized Facts for the Twentieth Century 23

    1.5 Trilemma: Capital Mobility, the Exchange Rate, and

    Monetary Policy

    1.6 Summary

    26 28

    Vil

  • Vll1 Contents

    Part two: Global Capital in Modero HistoricaI Perspective 31

    2 Globalization in Capital Markets: The Long-Run Evidence 34

    2.1 Introduction 34 .., .., Overview 36 2.3 Quantity Cri teria 41

    2.3.1 The Stocks of Foreign Capital 41

    2.3.2 The Size ofFlows 52

    2.3.3 The Saving-Investment Relationship 59

    2.3.4 Caveats: Quantity Cri teria 68

    2.4 Price Criteria 71

    2.4.1 Covered Interest Parity 72

    2.4.2 Real Interest Parity 76

    2.4.3 Purchasing Power Parity 79

    2.4.4 Caveats: Price Cri teria 85

    2.5 Summary 86

    3 Globalization in Capital Markets: A Long-Run Narrative 88

    3.1 Capital Without Constraints: The Gold Standard, 1870-1931 88

    3.1.1 The Classical Gold Standard Era 88

    3.1.2 Rebuilding the Gold Standard 91

    3.2 Crisis and Compromise: Depression and War, 1931-46 97

    3.2.1 Capital Markets and the Great Depression 97

    3.2.2 Policy Response: A Consensus on Capital Mobility 103

    3.2.3 World War II and its Aftermath 107

    3.3 Containment Then Collapse: Bretton Woods, 1946-71 113 3.3.1 Stability Without Integration? 113

    3.3.2 Leakage, then Deluge 119

    3.4 Crisis and Compromise II: The Floating Era, 1971-99 121

    3 A.1 Integration Without Stability? 121

    3A.2 The New Global Capital Market 123

  • Contents IX

    Part three: Lessons for Today 125

    4 Open Capital Markets: Worth the Risk? 127

    4.1 Introduction 127

    4.1.1 Open Capital Markets in Historical Perspective 127 4.1.2 Open Capital Markets Today 127

    4.2 Evidence on Benefits versus Costs 127

    4.2.1 Convergence 127

    4.2.2 Growth 128

    4.2.3 Portfolio diversification 128 4.2.4 Consumption smoothing 4.2.5 Output volatility

    128

    128 4.2.6 Corrleation versus Causation 128

    4.3 Implications for Today's Global Economy 128 4.3.1 The Menu of Policy Choices 128

    4.3.2 The Perpetuai Choice: Intervention versus Markets 128

    Appendix: An InternatÍona{ Macroeconomic Database 129

    References 130

    lndex 140

  • 2

    Globalization in Capital Markets: The Long-Run Evidence

    2.1 Introduction

    In theory and practice, the extent of intemational capital mobility can have

    profound implications for the operation of individual and global economies.

    With respect to theory, the applicability of various classes of macroeconomic

    models rests on many assumptions, and not the least important of these are

    axioms linked to the closure of the model in the capital market. The predictions

    of a theory and its usefulness for policy debates can revolve critically on this

    part of the structure.

    The importance of these issues for policy is not surprising at

  • 2.1 /ntroduction 35

    hardly describe them as being integrated in a single market, as the equality of

    prices was merely a chance event. Or consider looking at the size of ftows

    between two markets as a gauge of mobility; this is an equally ftawed criterion,

    for suppose we now destroyed the barrier between the two economies just

    mentioned. and reduced transaction costs to zero; we would then truly have

    a single integrated market, but, since on either side of the barrier prices were

    identical in autarky, there would be no incentive for any good or factor to move

    after the barrier disappeared. Thus, convergence of prices and movements of

    goods are not unambiguous indicators of market integration. One could run

    through any number of other putative criteria for market integration. examining

    perhaps the leveIs or correlations of prices or quantities, and discover essentially

    the same kind of weakness: alI such tests may be able to evaluate market

    integration. but only as a joint hypothesis test where some other maintained

    assumptions are needed to make the test meaningful.

    Given this impasse, an historical study such as the present chapter is poten-

    tially valuable in two respects. First, we can use a very large array of data

    sources covering different aspects of international capital mobility over the last

    one hundred years or more. Without being wedded to a single criterion, we can

    attempt to make inferences about the path of global capital mobility with a bat-

    tery of tests. using both quantity and price cri teria of various kinds. As long as

    important caveats are kept in mind about each method, especially the auxiliary

    assumptions required for meaningful inference, we can essay a broad-based

    approach to the evidence. Should the different methods all lead to a similar

    conclusion we would be in a stronger position than if we simply relied on a

    single test.

    Historical work offers a second benefit in that it provides a natural set of

    benchmarks for our understanding of today's situation. In addition to the many

    competing tests for capital mobility, we also face the problem that almost every

    test is usually a matter of degree. of interpreting a parameter or a measure of

    dispersion or some other variable or coefficient. We face the typical empirical

    conundrums (how big is big:' or how fast is fast?) in placing an absolute

    meamng on these measures. An historical perspective allows a more nuanced

    view, and places all such inferences in a relative context: when we say that a

    parameter for capital mobility is big, this is easier to interpret if we can say that

    by this we mean bigger than a decade or a century ago. The historical focus

    of this chapter will be directed at addressing just such concerns. I We examine

    BUI nOle lha!. agJ..ln. auxiliary assumprions will be necessary. and lhe caveals will be considered along lhe", ay: for example. whal if neighboring eco no mies became exogenously more or less Idenllcal o\er time. but no more or less integrated in terms of transactlon costs O

  • 36 Globalization in Capital Markets: The Long-Run Evidenee

    the broadest range of data over the last one-hundred-plus years to see what has happened to the degree of capital mobility in a cross section of countries. 2

    The empirical work begins by looking at the extent of international capital

    movements over a century or more, employing data on both stocks and fiows of foreign capital. We then develop more refined quantity criteria by looking

    at the correlations of saving and investment in individual economies over the long run. In principie, more open economies should be better able to de-link

    saving and investment decisions via externai finance. An important discussion

    of caveats ends this section. The next empirical section focuses on price-based criteria for capital market

    integration, and looks at three parity relations: covered interest parity (CIP), real interest parity (RIP), and purchasing power parity (PPP). In principie, ali three

    relations should come c10ser to equality the more integrated markets are. An

    examination of long-run price and interest rate series since the late nineteenth century affords a test ofthese relations. Once again, an important section details

    the caveats with this approach.

    The conclusion conjectures some reasons why international capital mobility might have varied from time to time in the international economy over the last

    century or so. Important constraints on policy makers included a fundamental tradeoff between monetary policy choice, policies as regards capital mobility,

    and the desire for activist domestic monetary policy. We have termed this the

    maeroeeanomie palie)' trilemma 3 Consideratio!'! ofthe trilemma illustrates the

    tensions facing policymakers during the interwar period, a major turning point in the evolution of markets in the twentieth century, and helps us understand

    the changing commitments of governments to monetary regimes, their attempts

    at sterilization, and their confiict over adherence to the previously sacrosanct "rules of the game" under the orthodoxy of the gold standard. In this political

    economy context, the empirical evidence appears consistent with the stylized facts of twentieth-century social, political, and economic history.

    2.2 Overview

    The broad trends and cycles in the world capital market that we will document refiect changing responses to the fundamental trilemma. Before 1914, each of

    ~ Given the limitations of the data. we will frequently be restricted to looking at between a dozen and twenty countries for which long-run macroeconomic statistics are available. and this sample will be dominated by today's developed countries. including most of the OECD countries. However, we a1so have long data series for some developing countries such as Argentina. Brazil. and Mexico: and in some criteria. such as our opening look at the evolution of the stock of foreign investments, we can examine a much broader sample.

    3. See section 1.5.

  • 2.2 Overview 37

    the world's major economies pegged its currency's price in terrns of gold, and

    thus. implicitly, maintained a fixed rate of exchange against every other major

    country's currency. Financiai interests ruled the world of the classical gold

    standard and financiai orthodoxy saw no alternative mode of sound finance. 4

    Latin American interludes of floating exchange rates were viewed from the

    main financiai centers with "fascinated disgust," to use the words of Bacha and

    Dlaz Alejandro (1982). Thus the gold standard system met the trilemma by

    opting for fixed exchange rates and capital mobility, sometimes at the expense

    of domestic macroeconomic health. Between 1891 and 1897, for example, the

    United States Treasury put the country through a harsh deflation in the face

    of persistent speculation on the dollar's departure from gold. These policies

    were hotly debated; the Populist movement agitated forcefully against gold, but

    lost. The balance of political power began to change only with the First World

    War, which brought a sea-change in the social contract underlying the industrial

    democracies. Organized labor emerged as a political power, a counterweight

    to the interests of capital 5

    Although Britain's return to gold in 1925 led the way to a restored interna-

    tional gold standard and a limited resurgence of international finance, the system

    helped propagate a worldwide depression after the 1929 New York stock mar-

    ket crash. Following (and in some cases anticipating) Britain's example, many

    countnes abandoned the gold standard in the early 1930s and depreciated their

    currencies: many also resorted to trade and capital controls in order to manage

    independently their exchange rates and domestic policies. Those countries in

    the "gold bloc," which stubbornly clung to gold through the mid-1930s, showed

    the steepest output and price-Ievel declines. But eventually in the 1930s, ali

    countries jettisoned rigid exchange-rate targets and or open capital markets in

    favor of domes ti c macroeconomic goals. 6

    Thcse decisions reflected the shift in political power solidified by the First

    World \Var. They also signaled the beginnings of a new consensus on the role of

    economic policy that would endure through the inflationary 1970s. As an im-

    mediate consequence. howevcr. the Great Depression discredited gold-standard

    orthodoxy and brought Keynesian ideas about macroeconomic management to

    the fore. It also made financiai markets and financiai practitioners unpopular.

    Their supposcd ex cesses and attachment to gold became identified in the public

    mind as causes of the economic calamity. In the United States. the New Deal

    brought a Jacksonian hostility toward eastern (read: New York) high finance

    back to Washington. Financiai products and markets were banned or more

    .1 See Bordo and Schwartz (198.1): Eichengreen (1996). ~. See Temm ( 1989) 6 See Temm ( 1989): Eichengreen (1992)

  • 38 Globalization in Capital Markets: The Long-Run Evidence

    closely regulated, and the Federal Reserve was brought under heavier Treasury influence. Similar reactions occurred in other countries.

    Changed attitudes toward financiai activities and economic management un-derlay the new postwar economic order negotiated at Bretton Woods, New

    Hampshire, in July 1944. Forty-four allied countries set up a system based on fixed, but adjustable, exchange parities, in the belief that floating exchange

    rates would exhibit instability and damage international trade. At the center

    of the system was the International Monetary Fund (IMF). The IMF's prime

    function was as a source of hard-currency loans to governments that might oth-erwise have to put their economies into recession to maintain a fixed exchange

    rate. Countries experiencing pennanent balance-of-payments problems had the option of realigning their currencies, subject to IMF approval. 7

    Importantly, the IMF's founders viewed its lending capability as primarily a substitute for, not a complement to, private capital inflows. Interwar experience had given the latter a reputation as unreliable at best and, at worst, a dangerous

    source of disturbances. Encompassing controls over private capital movement,

    perfected in wartime, were expected to continue. The IMF's Articles of Agree-

    ment explicitly empowered countries to impose new capital controls. Article VIII of the IMF agreement did demand that countries' currencies eventually be

    made convertible - in effect. freely saleable to the issuing central bank, at the of-

    ncial exchange parity, for dollars or gold. But this privilege was to be extended

    only to ;;:nresidents (not a country's own citizens), and only if the country's

    currency had been earned either through merchandise sales or as à return on

    past lending. Convertibility on capital account, as opposed to current-account convertibility, was not viewed as mandatory or desirable.

    Unfortunately, a wide extent even of current-account convertibility took many

    years to achieve. In the interim, countries resorted to bilateral trade deals

    that required balanced or nearly balanced trade between every pair of trading

    partners. IfFrance had an export surplus with Britain, and Britain a surplus with

    Germany, Britain could not use its excess marks to obtain dollars with which

    to pay France. Germany had very few dollars and guarded them jealously for

    criticai imports from the Americas. Instead, each country would try to divert

    import demand toward countries with high demand for its goods, and to direct its exports toward countries whose goods were favored domestically.

    Convertibility gridlock in Europe and its dependencies was ended through

    a regional multilateral clearing scheme, the European Payments Union (EPU).

    The clearing scheme was set up in 1950 and some countries reached de facto

    7. On lhe Brelton Woods syslem. see Bordo and Eichengreen (1993).

  • 2.2 Overv/ew 39

    convertibility by mid-decade. But it was not until December 27, 1958 that

    Europe officially embraced convertibility and ended the EPU.

    Although most European countries still chose to retain extensive capital con-

    trols (Germany being the main exception), the retum to convertibility, important

    as it was in promoting multilateral trade growth, also increased the opportuni-

    ties for disguised capital movements. These might take the form, for example,

    of misinvoicing and accelerated or delayed merchandise payments. Buoyant

    growth encouraged some countries in further financialliberalization, although

    the U.s.. worried about its gold losses, raised progressively higher barriers

    to capital outftow over the 1960s. Eventually, the Bretton Woods system 's

    very successes hastened its collapse by resurrecting the "inconsistent trinity"

    or tr/lemma.

    Key countries in the system, notably the U.S. (fearful of slower growth) and

    Germany (fearful of higher inftation), proved unwilling to accept the domestic

    policy implications of maintaining fixed rates. Even the limited capital mobility

    of the early 1970s proved sufficient to allow furious speculative attacks on the

    major currencies, and after vain attempts to restore fixed dollar exchange rates,

    the industrial countries retreated to ftoating rates early in 1973. Although

    viewed at the time as a temporary emergency measure, the ftoating-dollar-rate

    regime is still with us a quarter-century on.

    Floating exchange rates have allowed the explosion in intemational financiai

    markets experienced over that same quarter-century. Freed from one element

    of the trilemma - fixed exchange rates - countries have been able to open their

    capital markets while still retaining the ftexibility to deploy monetary policy in

    pursuit of national objectives.8

    There are several valid reasons for countries to fix their exchange rates -

    for example. to keep a better lid on inflation or to counter exchange-rate insta-

    bility due to financial-market shocks. However, few countries that have tried

    have succeeded for long; eventually, exchange-rate stability tends to come into

    conflict with other policy objectives. the capital markets catch on to the gov-

    ernment's predicament. and a crisis adds enough economic pain to make the

    authorities give in. In recent years only a very few major countries have ob-

    served the discipline of fixed exchange rates for at least five years, and most

    of those were rather special cases.9 One puzzling case, Thailand, has dropped

    off the list - with a resounding crash. Even Hong Kong, which operates as a

    8. Aksma. Grilli. and ~ilesi-Ferreni (1994) and Grilli and Milesi-Ferreni (1995) report on panel studles of the incidence of capital controls (for 20 industrial countries over the years 1950 to 1989. and for 61 industrial and developing countries over the years 1966 to 1989). They find that more tlexible exchange rate regimes and greater central bank independence lower the probability of capnal controls.

    9 See Obstfeld and Rogoff (1995).

  • ,

    40 Globalization in Capital Markets: The Long-Run Evidenee

    currency board supposedly subordinated to maintaining the Hong Kong-U.S.

    dollar peg, suffered repeated speculative attacks in 1997. Another currency-

    board country, Argentina, has now held to its 1: 1 dollar exchange rate since

    April 1991, and so joins the exclusive five-year club. To accomplish this feat,

    the country has relied on IMF credit and has suffered unemployment higher

    than many countries could tolerate. The European Union members that have

    maintained mutually fixed rates have been aided by market confidence in their

    own planned solution to the trilemma, a full currency merger due to be con-

    summated in J anuary 1999. The trend toward greater financiai openness has

    been accompanied - inevitably, we would argue - by a declining reliance on

    pegged exchange rates in favor of greater exchange rate flexibility.

    In short, the limitations that open capital markets place on exchange rates

    and monetary policy are summed up by the idea of the "inconsistent trinity" or,

    as we term it, the maeroeeonomie poliey trilemma: a country cannot simultane-ously maintain fixed exchange rates and an open capital market while pursuing

    a monetary policy oriented toward domestic goals. Governments may choose

    only two of the above. If, monetary policy is geared toward domestic consid-

    erations, capital mobility or the exchange-rate target must go. If instead, fixed

    exchange rates and integration into the global capital market are the primary

    desiderata, monetary policy must be entirely subjugated to those ends.

    The details of this argument form the core of this book, based on empirical

    evidence and the historical r~cord, but we can already pinpoint lhe ke:' turning

    points (see Table 2.1). The Great Depression stands as the watershed here,

    in that it was caused by an ill-advised subordination of monetary policy to an

    exchange-rate constraint (the gold standard), which led to a chaotic time of

    troubles in which countries experimented, typically noncooperatively, with al-

    ternative modes of addressing the fundamental trilemma. Interwar experience,

    in turn, discredited the gold standard and led to a new and fairly universal policy

    consensus. The new consensus shaped the more cooperative postwar interna-

    tional economic order fashioned by Harry Dexter White and John Maynard

    Keynes. but also implanted within that order the seeds of its own eventual de-

    struction a quarter-century bter. The global financiai nexus that evolved since

    is based on a solution to the basic open-economy trilemma quite different than

    that envisioned by Keynes or White - one that allows considerable freedom

    for capital movements, gives the major currency areas freedom to pursue in-

    ternai goals, but largely leaves their mutual exchange rates as the equilibrating

    residual.

  • 2.3 QlIantiry Criteria 41

    Table 2.1. The Trilemma and Major Phases of Capital Mobility

    Resolutlon of tnlemma -Countries choose to sacrifice:

    Activist Capital Fixed

    Era Eolicies mobilitv exchange rate Notes

    Gold standard Most R are Rare Broad consensus. (crises)

    lnterv.·ar Rare Several Most Capital controls esp. in (when off goldl C. Europe. La!. America.

    Bretton Woods None(O) Most R are Broad consensus. (crisies)

    Float Rare Gening Gening Some consensus; except to be rare to be common currency boards. others.

    2.3 Quantity Criteria

    This section employs data on the stocks and ftows of capital between coun-

    tries. that is. quantity data. to examine how the extent of capital mobility has

    changcd o\'cr the last hundred or so years. We begin by looking at long-term

    capital mobility. and we first discuss the size of foreign investment stocks and

    flows. Ceteris pariblls. a greater degree of capital mobility should lead to larger

    tlows ando with cumulation over time, larger stocks of foreign investment. We

    then relate the size of ftows to saving and investment pattems, to see to what

    extent the externaI ftows mattered in terms of the overalI composition of saving

    and in\cstment. \Ve next consider the saving-investment correlation. an oft-

    employed test that asks whether saving and investment activities lean toward

    being dc-Ilnked. as in a theoretically open economy, or tend in the direction of

    equallty. as in a closed economy.

    2.3.1 The Stocks of Foreign Capital

    In this section we examine the extant data on foreign capital stocks to get some

    sense of the evolution of the global market. AIthough the concept is simple, the

    measurement is not. Perhaps the simplest measure of the activity in the global

    capital market is obtained by looking at the total stock of overseas investment at

    a point In time. Suppose that the total asset stock in country or region i, owned

    by country or region j, at time tis Aij/' lncluded in here is the domestically-

    , '.

  • 42 Globali:.atioll in Capital Markets: The Long-Rull Evidence

    owned capital stock Aiit. Of interest are two concepts: what share of lhe total

    assets of country j are held overseas? and what share ofthe Iiabilities of country i are held overseas? Essentially, we are interested in the measures

    ForeignAssetsShareit = LAjir!LAjit; (2.1 ) j#1 j

    Foreign Liabilities Shareit LAijr!LAijt. (2.2) j#i j

    Note that here we are concerned with net wealth and asset measures, since

    we want to identify the extent to which the net wealth of a country is held in its

    own versus others' portfolios. There is, then, a complication to our measures,

    since, over the long-run timescales we are dealing with, there has been a vast

    multiplication in the ratio oftotal assets to net weath and total assets to GDP. This

    is because financiai development, and the increasing sophistication of national

    capital markets, has allowed the capital stock of each economy to be packaged

    and repackaged in various asset bundles, which may be held by a chain of

    assets and Iiabilities in various financiai intennediaries between the physical

    asset itself and the ultimate net wealth owner. At the international levei, we

    also need to keep the net wealth question in perspective, but the problem is

    somewhat simpler in the sense that ali net foreign claims are true net c1aims on

    a natIonal economy: should ali creditors show up demanding paymenl, lhen,

    even after a country Iiquidates its own foreign holdings, it will still need to hand

    over an amount of its own net wealth equal to the net c1aim. In that sense, net

    foreign Iiabilities represent a claim on an economy's net wealth. Thus, in ali

    that follows we must be careful to keep this distinction in mind. 10

    A relatively easy hurdle to surmount concerns nonnalization of the data;

    foreign investment stocks are commonly measured at a point in time in current

    nominal terms, in most cases U.S. dollars. Obviously, both the growth of the

    national and international economies might be associated with an increase in

    such a nominal quantity, as would any long run inflation. These trends would

    have nothing to do with market integration per se. To overcome this problem,

    we elected to normalize foreign capital at each point in time by some measure

    of the size of the world economy, dividing through by a nominal size indexo

    The ideal denominator. given that the numerator is the stock of foreign-

    owned capital, would probably be the total stock of capital. However, construct-

    ing long-run time-series for national capital stocks is fraught with difficulty. 11

    10. For cross-country evidence on the evolution of financia! assets as a fraction of output see Gold-smith (1985).

    II Only a few countries have reliable data from which to estimate capita! stocks. Most of these

  • 2.3 Quantity Criteria 43

    Given these problems we chose a simpler and more readily available measure

    of the size of an economy, namely the levei of output Y measured in current prices in a common currency unit. 12 Over short horizons, unless the capital-

    output ratio were to move dramatically, the ratio of foreign capital to output

    should be adequate as a proxy measure of the penetration of foreign capital in

    any economy. Over the long run, difficulties might arise if the capital-output

    ratio has changed significantly over time - but we have little firm evidence to

    suggest that it has. 13 Thus. our analysis focuses on capital-to-GDP ratios of

    the form

    Foreign Assets-to-GDP Rati0it

    Foreign Liabilities-to-GDP Rati0it

    L Ajir/Yit ; Ui

    L Aijr/Yi!. Ui

    (2.3)

    (2.4)

    A still irksome empirical problem, however, arises for the numerator. It is

    in fact very difficult to discover the extent of foreign capital in an economy

    using both contemporary and historical data. For example, the IMF has always

    reported balance-of-payments ftow transactions in its lnternationai Financiai Statistics. It is straightforward for most of the recent postwar period to discover

    the annual flows of equity, debt, or other forms of capital account transactions

    fram these accounts. Conversely, it was only in 1997 that the IMF began reporting the corresponding stock data, namely, the international investment position of each country. This data is also more sparse, beginning in 1980 for less than a dozen countries. and expanding to about 30 countries by the mid-

    estlmates are accurate only at benchmark censuses. and in between census dates they rely on comblnations of interpolation and estimation based on investment fiow data and depreciation assumpttons. Most ofthese esttmares are calculared in real (constanr price) rather than nominal (current pnce) rerrns. which makes them incommensurate with the nominally measured foreign caflital data. At the end of the day. we would be unlikely to find more than a handful of countries for whlch thls technique would be feasible for the entire twentierh century. and certainly nothing lik.: global coverage would be posslble even for recent years.

    12 For the GDP data we rely on Maddison's (1995) constant price 1990 U.S. dollar estimares of output for the period from 1820. These figures are then "reflared" using a U.S. price deflator to obtaln estimates of nominal USo dollar "World" GDP at each benchmark date. This approach is crude. stnce. in particular. it relies on a PPP assumption. Ideally we would want historical series on nominal GDP and exchange rates. to estimate a common (U.Sdollar) GDP figure at various hlstoncal dates. This is possible for a small sample of countries. notably the main creditor nattons In the disrant pasr; it is also possible for the last few decades for almost alI countries. \Ve follow this route when applying our method to a smaller sample group of countries.

    13 But for exactly the reasons just mentioned. since we have no capital stock data for many countries. it is hard to forrn a sample of capital-output ratios to see how these differ across time and space. What IS typlcally the case. and the working assumptton for most studies. is that the capital-output ranges from 3 to 4 for most countries. both developed and developing. [Literature on capltal-output ratios.]

  • 44 Globalization in Capital Markets: The Long-Run Evidence

    1990s. The paucity of data is understandable, since the collection burden for

    this data is much more significant: knowing the size of a bond issue in a single

    year reveals the tlow transaction size; knowing the implications for future stocks

    requires, for example, tracking each debt and equity item, and its tluctuating

    market value over time, and maintaining an aggregate of these data. The stock

    data is not simply a temporal aggregate of fiows: the stock value depends on

    past tlows, capital gains and losses, and any retirements ofprincipal or buybacks

    of equity, and a host of other factors. Not surprisingly this kind of data is hard

    to collect and rarely seen. Just as the IMF has had difficulty assembling this

    data, so toa have economic historians. Looking back over the nineteenth and

    twentieth centuries an exhaustive search across many different sources yields

    only a handful of benchmark years in which estimates have been made, an

    effort that draws on the work of dozens of scholars in official institutions and

    numerous other individual efforts. 14 It is based on these efforts that we can put

    together a fragmentary, but still potentially illuminating, historical description

    in Table 2.2 and Figure 2. I. Displayed here are nominal foreign investment

    and output data for major countries and regions, grouped according to assets

    and Iiabilities. Many cells are empty because data is unavailable, but where

    possible summary data have been derived to illustrate the ratio of foreign capital

    to output, and the share of various countries in foreign investment activity.

    What do the data show? On the asset side it is immediately apparent that

    for alI of the nineteenth century, and until the intcrwar period, the British werc

    rightly terrned the'bankers to the worId"; at its peak, the British share of total

    glob::d foreign investment was almost 80 perccnt. This is far above the current

    U.S. share of global foreign assets, a mere 24 percent in 1995, and still higher

    than the maximum U.S. share of 50 percent circa 1960. The only rivais to the

    British in the early nineteenth century were the Dutch, who according to these

    figures held perhaps 30 percent of global assets in 1825. This comes as no

    surprise given what we know of Amsterdam's early preeminence as the first

    global financiai center before London 's rise to dominance in the eighteenth and

    nineteenth centuries. IS By the late nineteenth century both Paris and Berlin had

    also emerged as major financiaI centers, and, as their own economies grew and

    industrialized. French and German holdings offoreign capital rose significantly,

    each ecIipsing the Dutch position. In this era the United States was a debtor

    rather than a creditor nation, and was only starting to emerge as a major lender

    and foreign asset holder after 1900. European borrowing from the United States

    in WorId War One then suddenly made the United States a big creditor. This

    14. See. for example. Paish (19xx), Staley (19xx), Woodruff (19xx), and Twomey (19xx). 15. Indeed, the Amsterdam market was an important source of externai finance for Britain during

    the Industrial Revolution. See chapter I.

  • 2.3 Quantity Criteria 45

    Table 2.2. Foreign Capital Stocks

    1825 1855 1870 1900 1914 1930 1938 1945

    Assers

    Umted Kingdom 0.5a 0.7a 4.9a 12.la 19.5a 18.23 22.ge 14.23

    Franee O.la 2.5a 5.2a 8.6a 3.5a 3.ge

    Germany 4.8a 6.7a l.la 0.7e

    Netherlands 0.3a 0.2a O.3a l.la l.2a 2.3a 4.8e 3.7a

    United States O.Oa O.Oa O.Oa O.5a 2.5a 14.7a 11.5e 15.3a Canada O.la 0.2a 1.3 a l.ge

    Japan l.2e

    Other Europe 4.6c

    Other 6.0c 2.0a Ali 0.9a 0.9a 7.7a 23.8a 38.7a 4 1.1 a 52.8e 35.13

    World GDP Illb 128b 221b 491b 491b 722b Sample GDP 43f 76f 149f 182f 273f Sample slze 7f 7f 7f 7f 7f

    Assets/Sample GDP 0.55 0.51 0.28 0.26 0.12 Assets/World GDP 0.07 0.19 0.18 0.08 0.11 0.05

    UKJAII 0.56 0.78 0.64 0.51 0.50 0.44 0.43 0.40 CS/AII 0.00 000 0.00 0.02 0.06 0.36 0.22 0.43 Lwbilules

    Europe 5.4a 12.0a 10.3a North Amenca 2.6a I !.la 13.7a Oceanla l.6a 2.3a 4.5a LatIn Amen~a 2.9g 8.9g l1.3g ASla lexd. Japan) 2.4g 6.8g 10.6g Afn.:a 3.0g 4.lg 4.0g Developlng Countries 6.0g 13.0g 25.9g Ali 17.9a 45.5a 55.0a

    World GDP Illb 128b 221b 491b 491b 722b Sampk GDP

    Sampk slze

    LiabIlIlles/Sample GDP

    LiabIlltIes/World GDP 0.14 0.21 0.11

    Developlng Counuies/AII 0.34 0.29 0.47

    --.-':"--:~.-, ... --

  • 46 Globalization in Capital Markets: The Long-Run Evidence

    Table 2.2. (Continued)

    1960 1971 1980 1985 1990 1995

    AsseIS

    United Kingdom 26.4a 551d 857d l.757d 2 .. ~89d

    Franee 736d 1.105d

    Germany 1.2a 257d 342d 1.I00d 1.672d

    N etherlands 27.6a 178d 418d

    United States 63.6a 775d 1.296d 2.178d 3,353d , Canada 129d 227d 302d

    Japan 160d 437d 1.858d 2.725d

    Other Europe

    Other 5.9a

    All 124.7a 1.963d 4.025d 10.321d 14.25ld

    World GDP 1.942b 4.733b 11.118e 12.455e 21.141e 25.llOe

    SampleGDP 67lf 5.922d 8.873d 17.584d 21.479d

    Sample size 7f 10d 19d 28d 29d

    AssetslSample GDP 0.18 0.29 0.37 0.47 0.54

    Assets!World GDP 0.06 0.18 0.32 0.49 0.57

    UKlAIl 0.21 0.28 0.21 0.17 0.17

    US/AIl 0.51 0.39 0.32 0.21 0.24

    Liabilitles

    Europe 7.6a

    N orth Ameriea 12.5a

    Oeeania 2.2a

    Latin Ameriea 9.2a 5~G '", 250g 505g 768g

    Asia lexel. Japan) 2.7a 29g 129g 524g 960g Afriea 2.23 199 124g 306g 353g Developing Countries 14.la 107g 506g 1.338g 2.086g

    All 39.9a 1.569d 3.685d 10.311d 1".735d

    World GDP 1.942b 4.733b 11.118e 12.455e 21.141e 25.11Oe

    Sample GDP 5.922d 8.873d 17.584d 21.479d

    Sample size 10d 19d 28d 29d

    Liabilities/Sample GDP 0.26 0.42 0.59 0.69

    Liabilities/World GDP 0.02 0.14 0.30 0.49 0.59

    Developing Countries/All 0.35 0.32 013 0.14

    Notes and Sources:

    VOlts for foreign investment and GDP are billions of eurrent U.S. dollars.

    a = from Woodruff(1967. 150-159). b = from t\laddlson (1995): sample of 199 eountries: 1990 US dollars converted to eurrent dollars using US GDP deflator: some interpolation.

    e = from Lewis (1945. 292-97). d = from lFS (9/97). Maximum 40 eountry sample 1980-1997. Sample size varies. e = from World Bank (1994). f = excludes "Other Europe" and "Other": GDP data from appendix. g = from Twomey (1998: unEublished worksheets).

    ". .,-,

  • 2.3 Quantity Criteria

    1.0

    0.9

    0.8 ~

    0.7 ~

    0.6 -

    0.5 ~

    0.4 ~

    0.3 -

    0.2 -

    0.1

    / /

    '" / , / , /

    --- AsselS/Sample GDP • AsselS/World GDP

    - - - - UK share of ali asseIS - - - - - - US share of ali assets

    0.0 -------~~=--=--:=-----------------

    1820

    1.0

    0.9 ~

    0.8

    0./

    06

    0.5

    OA

    0:1

    02

    0.1

    00

    IS20

    1840 1860

    18.\0 1860

    1880 1900 1920 1940 1960 1980 2000

    ---Liabilities/Sample GDP • Liabilities/World GDP

    - - - - LDC share of allliabilities

    1880

    "'-/ "-

    / "-...... / '-

    ...... /

    1900 1920 1940 1960

    Fig. 2.1. Foreign capital stocks

    \....-

    1980 2000

    47

    :;

    , ." -,.,'

  • 48 Globa/ization in Capital Markets: The Long-Run Evidence

    carne at a time when she was ready, if not altogether willing, to assume the

    mantle of "banker to the world," following Britain 's abdication of this position

    under the burden of war and recovery in the 1910s and 1920s.16 But the dislocations of the interwar years were to postpone the United States' nse as a foreign creditor, and New York's pivotal role as a financiai center. After

    1945, however, the United States decisively surpassed Britain as the major

    international asset holder, a position that has never been challenged. 17

    How big were nineteenth century holdings of foreign assets? In 1870 we estimate that foreign assets were just 7 percent of World GDP; but this figure

    rose quickly, to just under 20 percent in the years 1900-14 at the zenith of the classical gold standard. During the interwar penod, the collapse was swift,

    and foreign assets were only 8 percent of world output by 1930, 11 percent in 1938, and just 5 percent in 1945. Since this low point, the ratio has climbed,

    to 6 percent in 1960, 18 percent in 1980, and then climbing drarnatically to

    57 percent in 1995. Thus, the 1900-14 ratio of foreign investment to output in the world economy was not equaled again until 1980, but has now been

    approximately doubled. 18

    An alternative measure recognizes the incompleteness of the data sources:

    for many countries we have no information on foreign investments at ali, so

    a zero has been placed in the numerator, although that country 's output has

    been included in the denominator as part of the World GDP estimate. This is an unfortunate aspect of our estirr.:!t;:::;) procedure, and makcs ~he above

    ratio a likely an underestimate, or lower bound, for the true ratio of foreign

    assets to output. One way to correct this is to only include in the denominator

    the countries for which we actually have data on foreign investment in the numerator. 19 This procedure yields an estimate we term the ratio of foreign

    16. This Anglo-American transfer of hegemonic power is discussed by Kindleberger (1986). 17. or course. lhis is lhe gross foreign inveslmenl position. nOllhe nel position. The Uniled Slales

    is also now lhe world's number one debtor nalion. in bOI h gross and net lerms. She holds more liabililies lhan any olher country. ando since the early 19805, has been. on neto a debtor country.

    18. However. even lhen we cannOl necessarily infer lhallhere has been an increase in foreign asseI ownership relalive 10 10lal asseIS. since lhe asseI 10 GDP ralio has risen across lhe twentielh century wilh financial developmenl (see Goldsmilh 1985). This is nOl a problem if we view ali foreign asseIs as "outside" - bUl allhough lhat mighl be reasonable for lhe nineleenth century. il mighl nOl be 50 reasonable now. In lhe pasl. mOSl assel-liabilily posilions were one way aI lhe national levei (examp!e: Brilain circa 1900). bUlloday lhe nel ftows are much less lhan lhe gross ftows (example: mOSl OECD countries loday). Hence. nOl ali foreign asseIs may be "outside" and 50 the multiplicalion of asseIs can be an issue lhal introduces biases even aI lhis levei - as when. say, a domeslic asseI is held overseas by an instilution lhal is in lum held by domestic investors. Given lhe macroeconomic aggregale dala we are dealing with here. however. lhe resolulion of lhis kind of dala problem seems impractical.

    19. Thal sample of countries is much less lhan lhe entire world. as we have nOled. Unlil 1960. il inc1udes only lhe seven major credilor countries nOled in Table 2.2; after 1980. we rely on lhe IMF sample from which we can identify 10. rising to 30. countries wilh foreign investment and GDP dala.

  • 2.3 Quantity Criteria 49

    assets to sample GDP. This is likely an overestimate, or upper bound, for the

    true ratio, largely because in historical data, if not in contemporary sources,

    attention in the collection of foreign investment data has usually focused on

    the principal players, that is, the countries which have significant foreign asset

    holdings. 20 Given ali these concerns, does the ratio to sample GDP evolve in a

    very different way? No. It is, as expected, higher at most points, except 1985.

    The two ratios are very dose after 1980. But before 1945 they are quite far apart:

    from 1870 to 1914, the sample of seven countries has a foreign asset to GDP

    ratio of over 50 percent, far above the world figure of7 to 20 percent. Clearly,

    these seven major creditors were exceptionally internationally diversified in

    the late nineteenth century in a way that no group of countries is today. By

    this reckoning, in countries like today's United States, we still have yet to see

    a return to the extremely high degree of international portfolio diversification

    seen in, sal'. Britain in the 1900-14 period, a historical finding that sheds light

    on the ongoing international diversification puzzle. 21

    Is the picture similar for liabilities as well as assets? Essentially, yes. The

    data is much more fragmentary here, with none in the nineteenth century, when

    the inforrnation for the key creditor nations was simpler to collect than data

    for a multitude of debtors, perhaps. Even so, we have some estimates running

    from 1900 to the present at a few key dates. The ratio of liabilities to World

    GDP follows a path very much like that of the asset ratio, which is reassuring:

    thel' are each approximations built from different data sources at certain time

    points. though, in principie, they should be equal. Again, the ratio reaches a

    local maximum in 1914 of 21 percent, collapsing in the interwar period to 11

    percent in 1938, andjust 2 percent in 1960. By 1980 the ratio had risen to 14

    percent. and by 1985 it had exceeded the 1914 levei and stood at 30 percent.

    By 1995, the ratio was 59 percent.

    Finally, what about the distinction between net and gross stocks? A cursory

    glancc at the data reveals that this problem is very serious in recent decades,

    but relatively unimportant in the pre-1914 era of globalization. The reason is

    simple: in the late nineteenth century the principal ftows were long-terrn in-

    vestment capital, and virtually unidirectional at that. The key creditor nations,

    20 Th~t 15. we are probably restricted in these samples to eountries with individually high ratios of forelgn assets to GOP. For example. in the rest ofEurope eirea 1914. we would be unlikely to find countries with portfolios as diversified intemationally as the British. French. Germans. and Outch. If we included those other eountries it would probably bring our estimated ratio down. Howc'er. In the 19805 and 1990s IMF data the problem is much less severe sinee we observe m~ny more countries. and both large and small asset holders. Sample selection might not be as biased in thls data set: for example. one of the biggest foreign investors in 1990 is France. but French data IS unavailable for most of lhe 1980s. This is interesting because it is only at the 1985 benchmark that this ratio to sample GOP is below the ratio to "World GOP."

    21 On the intemational dlversification puzzle see K. K. Lewis (1996)

  • 50 Globali:ation in Capital Markets: The Long-Run Evidence

    principally Britain, but also France and Gennany, engaged in the financing of

    other countries' capital accumulation, and in doing so, developed enonnous

    one-way positions in their portfolios. For example, circa 1914 the scale of Ar-

    gentine assets in Britain 's portfolio was very large, but the converse holding of

    British assets by Argentine 's was trivial by comparsion. Thus, the nineteenth

    century was an era of one-way asset shifts, leading to great portfolio diversifi-

    cation by the principal creditor/outftow nations like Britain, but relatively little

    diversification by the debtor/inftow nations. To a first approximation, the gross

    asset and liability positions were very c10se to net in that distant era. The 1980s

    and 1990s are obviously very different: for example, the United States became

    in this period the world's largest net debtor nation. But whilst accounting for

    the biggest national stock of gross foreign liabilities, the United States also held the largest stock of gross foreign assets.

    Thus, our discussion of the stock data, and our inferences conceming the

    recovery of foreign asset and liabilities in the world economy after 1980 needs

    considerable modification to take into account this problem. And, indeed, it is

    a significant problem for ali of the countries concemed: the rank of countries

    by foreign assets in the IMF sample, is very highly correlated with the rank by

    foreign liabilites. Countries such as Britain, Japan, Canada, Germany, and the

    Netherlands are ali big holders of both foreign assets and liabilities. Strikingly,

    when we net out the data. the result is that, since 1980, there has been virtually

    /lO change in the net foreign asset position (or liability) position in the wcdd

    economy, as inàicatcd by Figure 2.2. Thus, for ali the suggestion that we have

    retumed to the pre-1914 type of global capital market, here is one major qualita-

    tive difference between then and now. Today's foreign asset distribution is much

    more about asset swapping by countries, than about the accumulation of large

    one-way positions. It is therefore more about hedging, portfolio diversifcation,

    and risk sharing than it is about long-term finance and the mediation of saving

    supply and investment demand between countries. In the latter sense, we have

    never come c10se to recapturing the heady times of the pre-1914 era, when a

    creditor like Britain could persist for years in satisfying half of its accumulation

    of assets with foreign capital, or a debtor like Argentina could simlarly go on

    for years generating liabilities of which one half were taken up by foreigners.

    Instead. still to a very great extent today, a country's net wealth will depend, for

    accumulation, on the pravision of financing from domestic rather than foreign

    sources. and issue we will shortly take up again in the discussion of long-run

    trends in capital ftows. An interesting, and c10sely related, insight also follows fram looking at the

    share of less-developed countries (LDCs) in global liabilities. This is now at

    an ali time low. In 1900. LDCs in Asia. Latin America, and Africa accounted

  • 2.3 Quantity Criteria

    08~-------------------------------------------------------

    ~ Assets/Sample GDP 07; ---o- LiabilitieslSample GDP

    I _ Assets/World GDP ___ LiabilitiesIWorld GDP _ Net Assets/World GDP

    06; ___ Net Liabilities/World GDP

    05 .

    o' .

    o:. '

    02 j

    OI • .... .. -- • • • • • • • • • ~ I 00-------------------------------------------------------

    IQ!l5 1900 109\

    Fig. 2.2. Foreign capital stocks

    51

    for 34 percent of global Iiabilities. The global capital market of the nineteenth

    century centered on Europe, especially London, extended relatively more credit

    to LDCs than does today's global capital market. Is this surprising? There are

    various interpretations for this observation. One is that capital markets are

    biased now, or were biased in the past; for example, did Britain, as an imperial

    power. favor LDCs within her orbit with finance? or, today, does the global

    capital market fail in the sense that there are insufficient capital flows to LDCs,

    and an excess of flows among developed countries (DCs)? These are hard

    c1aims to prove, as market failure could be a cause, as could a host of other

    factors including institutions and policies affecting the marginal product of

    capital in different 10cations.22 Of course, this resultjust follows from the fact

    that many of the top asset holders also figure in the top Iiability holders, and

    most of them are developed OECD countries. A rival explanation for the recent

    fali in the LDC share of liabilities, and the rise of DC Iiabilities, could be just

    a move toward greater - c10ser to optima!? - global portfolio diversification,

    22. See Lucas ( 1990).

  • 52 Globalization in Capital Markets: The Long-Run Evidence

    and we might see this as an efficient rebalancing given the large weight that DC

    capital has in the global capital stock.

    Figuring whether toa much or toa little diversification existed at any point

    must remain conjecturai, and conclusions would hinge on a calibrated and

    estimated portfolio model applied historically. This is certainly an object for

    future research. However, unless the global economy has dramatically changed

    in terms of the risk-return profile of assets and their global distribution, we have

    no prior reason to expect the efficient degree of diversification to have changed.

    For the present we can just say that, unless a massive such change did occur in

    the 1914-45 period, and unless ir was then promptly reversed in the 1945-90 period, we cannot explain the time path of foreign capital stocks seen in Table

    2.2 and Figures 2.1 and 2.2 except as a result of a dramatic decline in capital

    mobility in the interwar period, and a very slow recovery of capital mobility

    thereafter.

    2.3.2 The Size of Flows

    In contrast to the previous discussion of stocks, this section now attempts an

    analogous historical survey of global foreign investment ftows since the late

    nineteenth century. 23 The stock data suggested a amrked diminution of foreign

    investment activity in the middle of the twentieth century, with recovery to the

    1900--14 leveis only seen as recently as the 1980s and 1980s. Can the fiow data

    detect a similar historical evolution?

    Some basic definitions and notation will now prove useful. To simplify, we

    may define gross domestic product Q as the sum of goods produced, which, with imports M, may be allocated to private consumption C, public consumption G, investment 1, or export X, so that Q + M = C + 1 + G + X. Rearranging, GDP is given by

    GDP == Q = C + I + G + NX, (2.5)

    \vhere N X = X - M is net exports. If the country's net credit (debt) position vis-a-vis the rest of the world is B (-B), and these claims (debts) earn (pay)

    interest at a world interest rate r, then gross national product is GDP plus (minus) this net factor income from (to) the rest of the world,

    GNP == Y = Q + rB = C + I + G + NX + rB. (2.6)

    It is then simple to show that the net balance on the current account is

    C A == N X + r B = (Y - C - G) - 1 = S - 1, (2.7) 23. The next!Wo sections draw heavily on A. M. Taylor (1998).

  • 2.3 Quantity Criteria 53

    where 5 == Y - C - G is gross national saving. Finally, the dynamic structure of the current account and the credit position is given by the equality of the

    current account surplus (C A) and the capital account deficit (- K A), so that

    t::,.BI = BI - BI_I == CAI = -K AI' (2.8)

    This section, and some that follow, will focus on the patterns of saving (5),

    investment (I), and the current account (C A) as defined above. The basic

    identity (2.7), C A = 5 - I, is central to the analysis. In terrns of historical data collection, it proves essential to utilize the identity to measure saving

    residually, as 5 = 1 + C A. because no national accounts before the 1940s supply independent saving estimates; rather, we have access only to investrnent

    and current-account data.

    A sense of the changing patterns of international financiai ftows can be

    gleaned by examining their trends and cycles. However, a norrnalization is

    again needed. Measurement traditionally focuses on the size of the current

    account balance C A, equal to net foreign investment, as a fraction of national

    income Y. Thus (C A / n/I becomes the variable of interest, for country i in

    period t. a convention we follow here. Table 2.3 and Figure 2.3 present some

    basic trends in foreign capital ftows. We measures the extent of capital ftows

    with the mean absolute value I'lICA/Yi.I' The average size of capital ftows in

    this sample was often as high as 4 to 5 percent of national income before World

    \Var I. At its first peak it reached 5.1 percent in the overseas investment boom

    of the late 1880s. This fell to around 3 percent in the depression of the 1890s.

    The figure approached 4 percent again in 1905-14, and wartime lending pushed

    the figure over 6 percent in 1915-19. Flows diminished in size in the 1920s,

    however. and international capital ftows were less than 2 percent of national

    in come in the late 1930s. Again. wartime loans raised the figure in the 1940s,

    but in the 19505 and 1960s, the sizc of international capital ftows in this sample

    declincd to an ali time low. around 1.3 percent of national income. Only in the

    late 19705 and 1980s have ftows increased. though not to leveis comparable to

    those of a century ag0 24

    Indl\idual country data supply some detail to fill in this general picture. Some

    countries were clearly very dependent on foreign capital inftows before 1914,

    including the well-known cases of the settler economies, Argentina, Australia,

    and Canada. ~lany of these countries had typical capital inftows in excess of

    5 percent of GDP, and in some years in excess of 10 percent. The Argentine

    figure beforc 1890 is inaccurate and surely an overstatement, as it derives from

    24 The open c"eles in Figure 2.3 (and later figures) denote gaps in data coverage due to the two world wars. The cireles' positlons are determined by the incomplete sample of countJies for whlch data are available.

  • 54 Globalization in Capital Markets: The Long-Run Evidence

    Table 2.3. Si::.e of Capital Flows: Average Absolute Value of CA/Y, By

    Country, Selected Periods, Annual Data

    ARe AOS i:AN IJ1'lK t:11'l t:RA IJEO IrA 1870-1889 .187 .097 .072 .018 .062 .029 .019 .012 1890-1913 .062 .063 .076 .027 .059 .023 .014 .019 1914-1918 .027 .076 .035 .054 .142 .031 .117 1919-1926 .049 .088 .023 .012 .039 .117 .022 .043 1927-1931 .037 .128 .036 .007 .029 .037 .018 .015 1932-1939 .016 .037 .016 .008 .029 .025 .004 .007 1940-1946 .048 .071 .065 .024 .069 .018 .034 1947-1959 .031 .034 .023 .014 .014 .015 .020 .014 1960-1973 .010 .023 .012 .019 .017 .006 .010 .021 1974-1989 .019 .036 .017 .032 .024 .008 .021 .013 1989-1996 .020 .045 .040 .018 .051 .007 .027 .016

    lPN NLD NOR ESP SWE GBR USA AlI 1870-1889 .005 .060 .016 .010 .031 .045 .015 .040 1890-1913 .022 .053 .041 .014 .023 .045 .008 .037 1914-1918 .066 .043 .033 .063 .029 .035 .058 1919-1926 .021 .069 .027 .020 .029 .017 .039 1927-1931 .006 .004 .019 .018 .016 .020 .008 .027 1932-1939 .011 .018 .013 .012 .015 .011 .006 .015 1940-1946 .010 .049 .013 .019 .073 .010 .039 1947-1959 .013 .038 .031 .023 .011 .012 .006 .020 1960-1973 .010 .013 .024 .012 .007 .008 .005 .013 1974-1989 .018 .026 .052 .020 .015 .015 .014 .022 1989-1996 .021 .030 .029 .032 .020 .026 .012 .026

    the rather poor quality data from this era. Even so it reveals the extent to which

    foreign finance was willing to fuel an investment boom before the Baring crash

    in 1890. AIso. note that. unlike the settler economies, the U.S. economy had

    matured by the tum of the century, and was on the verge of becoming a capital

    exporter. with saving and investment almost in balance.

    The major capital exporter was obviously Britain. with between 5 percent and

    10 percent of GDP devoted to overseas investment in a typical year before 1914.

    This coincided with the years of so-called "Edwardian failure" at home, and

    the increasingly promising ventures for capital within and beyond the empire. 25

    This extraordinary net ftow of capital as a share of output has never been matched

    since by any overseas investing country. AlI countries shared in the collapse of

    capital ftows in the interwar period, and few have recovered the pre-1914 leveI

    of ftows as a share of output. 26

    25. See Edelstein (1982) and HaIl (1968) for more on this phenomenon ofBritish capital outlfow. 26. That is. excepting brief upsurges during and after the wanime periods when credits. especiaIly

  • 2.3 QlIarztity Criteria

    .07 -

    06 -

    05 -

    .Oo! .

    .02 -

    .0 I -

    00

    1860 1880 1900

    o " I I I' I ,

    I

    1920

    9, I

    19o!O 1960 1980 2000

    Fig. 2.3. Slze af capital ftaws: average absolute value of CNY, 15 cauntries. quinquennia. annual data

    55

    Gi\en that the size of flows is still smaller then a century ago, we would

    have to take this data as indicative of an incomplete recovery of global capital

    markets relative to their levei of integration in 1914. There still cou1d be other

    explanations for this path of capital flows over time, but. as in the caveats for

    the stock data, we would have to posit some large shock that made countries

    more alike. reducing the incipient flows after 1914. This is potentially plau-

    sibk \\ithin the group of most developed OECD countries where productivity

    convergence has taken place: but it stillleaves out the potential flows betweerz core to periphery that. given the still large development gap between rich and

    poor countries today.

    In order to confront that questiono Figure 2.4 examines the same kind of flow

    data on the time series of C A / Y for the postwar period, but expanding the samplc to encompass developed and developing countries. 27 We here divide

    the world into two samples. and look at the size of flows in each as a share of

    from the l:nited States to Europe. inftated the size of intemational transactions. For clarity . .... anlme qumquennia (1914-18 and 19o!~6) are shown as open circles in the chart: note that in these penods the averages are based on incomplete samp1es.

    2~ We dra .... on data from the lr"vrFs InrernarlOIlQ1 Financiai Srarisrics here and in Figure 2.6. Note that because of errors and omissions it seems tha! planet earth is usually running a current account Imbalance.

    "

    " ....... , .. ~

  • 56 Globalization in Capital Markets: The Long-Run Evidence

    .w'I--------------------------------------------{)-- Industrialized Countries CNGDP

    I - Developing Countries CNGDP .03 1

    I

    .02 ~

    -.02 ~ I I

    -.03 J i

    -.04 -'---------------------------' 1940 1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000

    Fig. 2.4. Size of capital ftows, postwar: CA/Y, developed and developing country samples. annual data

    each region 's output. It is apparent that there has been a surge in capital flows to

    devclopir.g countries in the 1930s and 1990s, far exceeding any previous flows

    in the preceding fifty years. At peak times this flow has amounted to about 3

    to -+ percent of dcvloping country GDP. and a very much smaller fraction of developed country GDP. However,judged next to the size offlows see in the late

    nineteenth century, one is struck by two features of this postwar data: first. how

    small even the large flows in the 1990s are as a fraction of the receiving region 's

    output. as compared to similar receiving region in the 1890s and 19OOs; second,

    one is struck by the fact that this surge in inflows was not witnessed sooner

    in the postwar period. taking about thirty to forty years to overcome whatever

    impediments to capital movement there were between core and periphery. Thus,

    even expanding to a global sample, we argue that, most likely, the U-shape in

    the long-run flow data reflect the considerable shifts in the transactions costs

    for capital arising from policy environments which became more inimical to

    capital movements after 1914, and especially so after 1929. This phase of

    relative capital immobility has perhaps only just disappeared in the last decade

    or so.

    In order to further contrast the situation now and a hundred years ago it is

    worth spending a few moments examining how important capital flows are now,

    and were then. relative not just to GDP, but relative to total capital formation.

  • 2.3 Quantity Cri te ria

    .60

    .50 -

    40 ~

    .30 ~

    :0 .

    10 ~

    00

    - 10

    (a) Ratio of capital inflows to investment for periphery economies

    1 78

    ARG FIN AUS CAN NOR SWE

    01870-1889

    1111890-1913

    DNK ESP

    (b) Ratio of capital outflows to saving for core economies

    40 -----------------------------

    .30 ~

    10 -

    00

    - 10 -

    01870-1889

    1111890-1913

    -20------------------------------GBR NLD FRA DEU USA lPN

    57

    Fig.2.5. CapItal flows in relation to saving and investment, 1870--1913: 15 countries, quinquennia, annual data

    Some natural questions to ask are: how important are the inftows as a fraction of

    total capital forrnation in recipient countries? and how important were outftows

    as a fraction of total saving for source countries?

    Let us look first at the data for the late nineteenth century. Figure 2.5 displays

    the ratio of average capital inftows to average investment for periphery countries

    in our l5-country sample, and the ratio of capital outftows to saving for core

    countries. looking at subperiods 1870-89 and 1890-1913. Once again, the

    Argenune figure pre-1890 must be taken with a pinch of salt, but in several cases,

    especially the settler economies, we see the remarkable importance of capital

    inftows for capital formation. In several economies foreign capital supplied up to half of investment demando This squares with well-known data on the

    stocks of foreign capital in some of the settler economies: by 1914 about 50

    percent of the Argentine capital stock was in the hands offoreigners: for Canada

    , . - '

  • 58 Globa/i;:ation in Capital Markets: The Long-Run Evidence

    .15 -,--------------------,----------

    .10

    .05

    -.05

    -.10 ,

    --o-- Industrialized Countries CNS _ Developing Countries -CM

    -.15 -'-I----------------------~ 1940 1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000

    Fig. 2.6. Capital flows in relation to saving and investment, postwar: developed and developing country samples, annual data

    and Australia the figure was in the range 20 percent to 30 percent. 28 Clearly

    these large ftows cumulated over time into a vcry strong foreign (read, mostly

    British) interest in the total capital stock of many nations before 1914. On the

    sending side. the British dominance is readily apparent in the figure: about one

    third of total British saving was devoted to overseas investment in the 1870-

    1914 period; moreover, it is acknowledged that in some periods, for example

    1900-13, this fraction crept as high as one half. 29 In contrast, few other capital

    exporters in the core could register anything like so high a fraction of foreign

    investment relative to total savings, with France, Germany, and the Netherlands

    each registering less than 10 percent of domestic savings as destined for foreign

    countries in the 1890-1913 era.

    Next. we again make a comparison to the contemporary era with this type

    of measure. Using our long run database we would find postwar ftows much

    lower relative to saving and investment as compared to the pre-1914 era, just as

    we did relative to output. But clearly we cannot satisfactorily use our existing

    long-run database for this question, or we open ourselves to the criticism that in

    focusing on our long-run fifteen-country sample we are missing the heart of the

    action in today's global capital market. Instead we should tum our attention to

    28. See A. M. Taylor (1992) for more discussion of these comparative data and sources. 29 On British foreign investment in this era see Edelstein (1982).

  • 2.3 Qlwfltiry Criteria 59

    the importance of capital ftows in relation to saving and investment in today's

    core and periphery. We can use the postwar data to look at how important

    developed countries outftows were as a share of their total saving, and how

    important developing country inftows were as a share of their total investment.

    These measures would then accord with the pre-1914 data in Figure 2.5.

    For the postwar period Figure 2.6 supplies the details. As with the discussion

    of ftows as a share of output in Figure 2.4, one is forced to note the relatively

    small impact offtows until the 1980s and 1990s: inftows have never amounted to

    more than about lOto 15 percent of developing country investment, and outftows

    neve r more than about 5 percent of developed country saving. This contrasts

    with nineteenth century experience, where a country like Britain exported as

    much as half her annual savings. and where countries such as Australia, Canada,

    and Argentina, imported up to half their savings supply. And even now, the

    ftows for the core group are still small compared to the total size of the core

    capital market as measured by aggregate saving. lndeed, in many years, both

    periphery and core countries appear to have sizeable inftows, due to the usual

    data problems. But corrections to the data could probably not affect the two key

    qualitative messages of this chart. 30 First, ftows have grown large in the last

    ten years, for the first time in the postwar era, but they have not yet surpassed

    their importance in the pre-1914 era relative to receiving and sending region

    capital markets. Second. and as in the pre-1914 era, because the capital market

    in the core is so much bigger than the periphery, these ftows weigh as a much

    larger share of periphery investment than they do as a share of core saving.

    ar course, mere ftow data, as a quantity criterion, serve only as weak evi-dence of changing market integration. However, these basic descriptive tables

    and f1gures do illustrate the record of capital ftows, and offer prima facie ev-

    idence that the globalization of the capital market has been subject to major

    dislocations. most notably in the inter-war period, with a dramatic contraction

    of tlows seen in the Depression of the 1930s. Moreover, this low levei in the

    volume of ftows persisted long into the postwar era, and possibly even to to-

    day. We now turn to more formal tests to see whether this description, and the

    conventional historography of world markets that points to the Depression as

    an era of dlsintegration, has broader support.

    2.3.3 The Saving-Investment Relationslzip

    Feldstein and Horioka (1980) proposed cross-country saving-investment corre-

    lations as a measure of international capital mobility. They reasoned that, in a

    10 The concluslon holds éVen if we were to shift the focus to the key capital importers and exporters. we suspcct

  • 60 Globalization in Capital Markets: The Long-Run Evidence

    world of perfectly mobile capital, domestic savings would seek out the highest

    retums in the world capital market independent of local investment demand,

    and by the same token the world capital market would cater to domestic invest-

    ment needs independent of domestic savings supply. Thus, they expected to

    find low correlations of domestic saving and investment rates among developed

    countries given the conventional wisdom that intemational capital markets were

    well integrated by the 1960s and 1970s. In a surprising and provocative result,

    they discovered a high and significant investment rate-saving rate correlation

    with coefficients typically close to unity for a cross section of OECD countries

    with five-year period averaging. It appeared that changes in domestic saving

    passed through almost fully into domestic investment, suggesting imperfect

    intemational capital mobility.31

    A substantialliterature has evolved following Feldstein and Horioka (FH) to

    assess whether incrementai savings were retained in the home country or else

    entered the global capital market seeking out the highest retum. But as is well

    known, the same literature has criticized the FH methodology on both theoret-

    ical and empirical grounds. This section develops and extends the historical

    application of saving-investment analysis, and seeks to extend its theoretical

    and empirical scope in several ways.32 Methodologically, we apply not only

    the traditional FH tests, but offer an altemative time-series approach based on

    a more explicit mode!. A major criticism of the FH method is that one might

    expect saving and investment te be ~~ghly corre!ated once time-~""ragirg is

    performed in CI oss-section, simply because ali countries must abide by a long-

    run version of current account balance in order to satisfy their intertemporal

    budget constraint. This idea leads to a very different modelling approach, and

    to a hypothesis that saving and investment may have trends or unit roots, but

    that the current account will be stationary - that is, investment and saving will

    be cointegrated - and an error-correction model (ECM) emerges as a natural theoretical framework.

    The standard technique employed for estimating long-run capital mobility is

    the generic FH regression of average invcstment rates on a constant and average

    31 Their finding of a large and significant coefticient has been replicated many times for various cross-section and time-series samples using post-World War Two and historical data. so much so as to be now considered a robust result - a stylized fac!. as it were (Dombusch 1991; Feldstein and Bacchetta 1991; Frankel 1991; Obstfeld 1991; Tesar 1991; Sinn 1992).

    32. Our statistical tests have enhanced power compared to other historical studies. since we have increased the sample size: we use annual data for the full period 1850 to the present, and we increase the cross-section size from the usual nine or ten up to fifteen, by adding various countires missing from earlier studies. Some applications of the Feldstein-Horioka approach in economic history, the natural antecedents of this chapter, include Bayoumi (1989), Zevin (1992), and Eichengreen (1990)

  • 2.3 Quantiry Criteria 61

    saving rates. The regression is perfonned on a cross section of countries indexed

    by i. where we use a "short" averaging penod T (say, five or ten years):

    -- FH FH--(l/n,=a +b (S/ni+Ui, (2.9)

    -- IT --- IT where (l/ni = T LI (f/nit, (s/ni = T LI (S/nit. The cross-section slope coefficient bFH has the conventional interpretation of a long-run savings-

    retention coefficient for the sample of countries.33 The results are shown in

    Figure 2.7. The figure displays the coefficient bFH for both 5-year and ten-year

    averaging patterns with two-standard-error intervals above and below indicated

    by vertical bars. Before FH-type coefficients can be interpreted we require a

    benchmark for what constitutes a "high" or a "Iow" bFH . Put another way,

    bFH comes equipped with no intrinsic absolute yardstick: we need to find

    a period we consider one of undisputed capital mobility and then compare

    other bFH observations to this benchmark.34 Alternatively, we might search for

    movements in bFH as indicators of whether saving-investment interdependence

    was relatively high or low for a given penod. There is certainly variance in

    the coefficient. The estimated coefficient is significant in most periods, and

    usually positive. It occasionally exceeds unity. The results reveal considerable

    tluctuation in the magnitude of bFH over the long run.

    What do the results show? First. international capital market integration, as

    measured by bFH for this admittedly small sample, has shown no marked trend

    over the last hundred or so years: we can say that, in this narrow sense, saving-

    investment association has been no weaker in the last decade for these countries

    than it was circa 1900. Second, the coefficient bFH has not evolved unifonnly

    or monotonically over time: saving-investment association was relatively low

    during the 1880s, when financiaI markets were engaged in a frenzy of foreign

    investment. The crash of the early 1890s brought this phase to a halt (higher

    !JFH). Gradually. closer to \Vorld War One, saving-investment association again

    decreased (falling bFH ) in the last great foreign investment boom during the

    age 01' high imperialismo The Great Depression ushered in a time of increased corre lations ior several decades (rising bFH). The saving-investment association

    began to decline in the late 1970s and 1980s. albeit to a limited degree. 35 We

    :n In 3 s~n\~. bFH is measuring the extent to which the sample of countries deviates. on average over the sample penod. from the closed-economy property whereby saving rates equal investment r3tes by identitl'. Smce period averaging is employed the procedure anempts to abstract from buslness cl'cle fluctuations that simultaneously affect both saving and investment. The averaging :Dsa Implies that this procedure has nothing to sal' abou! l'ear-to-year (short-run) capital mobility: the ability of countries to temporanly run current-account surpluses or deficits in response to shocks a! hlgh frequencies (meaning approximately annual frequencies. or higher) .

    . '4 See Obstfeld (1986: 1994) ,5 For comparslOns on the size of the recent postwar coefficient see Feldstein and Bacchetta 1991:

    Obstfeld 1994: and A. M. Taylor 1994a.

  • 62

    Globali-:.ation in Capital Markets: The Long-Run Evidence

    2.0 ~----------------------

    1.5

    1.0 , .0 I'. ce . ... 0, ~.OC.O

    • U-' , Cit' ~~ cJP cJk)~ 00 ° °

    ° 0.5 l

    °

    i 1 I

    1 I

    00 +-' -----------------------+

    , 0 - , -) T

    I

    -1.0~' -----------------------'-

    1860 1880 1900 1920 1940 1960 1980 2000

    2.0~i ~~~1

    1.5~

    O ~~i~ 1.0 -05 +

    , ~~~

  • 2.3 Quantity Criteria 63

    may note the remarkable relationship between the results of the FH test and

    the stylized facts concerning institutional change, monetary experiments, and

    policy regimes. Still, we might ask, what does the FH coefficient mean and how do we

    measure it accurately? The criterion. despite the attention it has commanded

    and ItS widespread use, is handicapped by two distinct sets of problems: First,

    do the regressions of investment on saving measure true and unbiased "savings

    retention"'l Second. even if estimated accurately. what does the coefficient say

    about international capital mobility?36

    An alternative to the Feldstein-Horioka approach of estimating the savings-

    retention coefficient is to employ time-series analysis for an individual country.

    However. for technical reasons. there is no reason to expect cross-section and

    time-series coefficients to bear any relation to each other since the time-series

    and cross-section properties of the estimators differ dramatically.37 The time-

    series estimation ofthe coefficient also raises additional concems, as it embodies

    an assumption of stationarity in the series (1/ Y)it and (S/ Y)it. Such an as-sumption may indeed be valido especially for short time frames. However,over

    longer horizons, several studies have cast doubt on the assumption that saving

    and investment rates are truly stationary.38

    Ali the same. the above ideas would be entirely familiar to anyone applying

    the standard small-open-economy macroeconomic model, or an open-economy

    growth model, to the problem at hand: for a poor (capital scarce) country.

    accumulation-Ied growth would begin at low income leveis using borrowed

    funds for investment; at the same time, permanent consumption leveis would

    be attained by borrowing against future output. Saving would start low and

    end high. to repay these debts; investment would start high and end low, as

    36 Th~s~ concems hinge of the samc typ~s of caveats already mentioned: what auxiliary assump-tlons we thlnk are relevant for the structural modeling of saving and investment in the long run. and how we think the structure may have changes so as to possibly account for the parameters secn. Sce Obstfeld (1986: 1994)

    3 7 :-'lor~o\~r. the natural interpretation ofthe two coeffjcients differs substantially - typically bCS is consld~red an Indlcator of long-run Intemational capital mobility in a sample group of countries.

    w hereas b T 5 is seen as a measure of short-run. year-to-year intemational capital mobility in a slnglé country (Obstfcld 1986: 1994).

    38 Thls problem will come as no surprise to economic historians: the notion of saving and in-vestment shlfts as important features of growth and structural transformation in the long run is embodled in many national histories. includlng the famous "grand traverse" described by the Lnlted States economy in the nineteenth century (Abramovitz and David 1973: David 1977). A similar upward shift In the investment rate has been documented in nineteenth century Britain (Crafts 1985. chapter 4. for examplel. The stationarity of some settler-economy saving and Investment rate series could also be called into question based upon an examlnation of long-run trends in the Australian and Canadian data since 1870 (McLean 1994 illustrates the pattems). W A Lewis (1954.155) considered such shifts in saving and investment the essential problem of economic developmenL

  • 64 Globalization in Capital Markets: The Long-Run Evidence

    steady-state leveIs were reached. The long-run intertemporal budget constraint

    would be met, and the current account would tend toward a stable, steady-state

    leveI, implying stationarity. We used routine stationarity tests to check on the stationarity of the series

    (5/nit, (Ilnit, and (CA/nit in our long-run sample of annual data for 15 countries. The current-account ratio is stationary in ali cases, encouraging

    the view that it may be subject to equilibrium tendencies as theory suggests. However, the saving and investment series were not stationary. 39 Thus, the new

    strand of cointegration research into the properties of saving and investrnent cor-relations may have a particular resonance in long-run historical applications.40

    An important implication is that there exists an error-correction representation

    of the relationship. The simplest such representation, commonly adopted in

    the Iiterature, is the first-order error-correction model (ECM), which may be

    written

    = a ECM + bECM .6.(51 nt + c

    ECM((5 I nt-I - (I I nt-I) +

    dECM (51 nt-I + Ut· (2.10) This equation states that instantaneous changes in investrnent may be driven by

    a pass-thorugh from instantaneous changes in saving, as in a c10sed economy, or through an error-correction term, which tends to drive investment and saving

    back towards some long-run equilibrium relationship in levels.41

    In the ECM equation, each of the terms has implications not only for the

    dynamics. but for our interpretation of the system as decribing capital mobility. The coefficient bECM has the natural interpretation: even given a long-run

    equilibrium relationship between saving and investment, bECM measures to

    what extent a temporary annual shock to domestic saving .6. (5 I nt passes through (ful1y? partially? not at ali?) into domestic investment .6.(1 I nt.

    39. Standard Dickey-Fuller test were used. On these econometric maners see A. M. Taylor (1997). 40. The cOlntegration approach 10 the saving-investment relationship has been much discussed in

    th~ Inerature. and the details need not be repeated at length here (see Miller 1988; Leachman 1991; Vikoren 1991; Jansen and Schulze 1996; A. M. Taylor 1997).

    41 This approach follows Jansen and Schulze (1996). A. M. Taylor (1997) applied (2.10) as a con-venient estimating equation for implementing a well-specified test of the saving-investment correlation. It is immediately obvious that (2.10) embodies a long-run equilibrium rela-tionship between saving and investment prescribed by theory. In the steady-state equilib-rium 1':,.( I / Y)/ = /':;(5/ Y)/ = O. The implied equilibrium relationship in leveis is given by (JECM + ~CM«5/Y) - (l/n) + d ECM (5/Y) = O. Parameter restrictions may be used 10 test various natural hypotheses conceming the nature of this long-run equilibrium. If

    dECM = O then the relevant error-correction terrn is just the current account (C A/ n/; here. «(l/n/. (5/ nrl have a cointegrating veClOr that is (1. -I); and the long-run equilibrium cur-rent account is equal 10 a constant. C A' = (5/ Y)' - (l/ n' = _aECM / ~CM; moreover. if a ECM = d ECM = O, then this constant is zero.

  • 2.3 QI/antit)" Criteria 65

    .70 -

    • Pass Through (b) O Adjustment Speed (c)

    .60 .

    I .50 " f 40 " ! í .30 " f .20 "

    .10 "

    00

    1880--1913 191+-1945 1946-1971 1972-1992

    Fig. 2.8. The Saving"Investment Error"Correction Model: Pooled Coefficients with plus or minus 2 s.e. bars

    It is thus a "short-run" adjustment parameter, with a meaning not unlike that of a conventional FH coefficient. The coefficient cECM also has a natural mterpretation: it measures the speed of convergence of the system toward equilibrium Converted into a "half-life" measure, this provides an indication of the sustainability of saving-investment inequality for each country in the sample period under study. It is thus a kind of "long-run" measur