global production planning under exchange-rate uncertainty

24
Purdue University Purdue e-Pubs Purdue CIBER Working Papers Krannert Graduate School of Management 1-1-2000 Global Production Planning under Exchange-Rate Uncertainty Maqbool Dada Purdue University Herbert Moskowitz Purdue University Burak Kazaz University of Miami Follow this and additional works at: hp://docs.lib.purdue.edu/ciberwp is document has been made available through Purdue e-Pubs, a service of the Purdue University Libraries. Please contact [email protected] for additional information. Dada, Maqbool; Moskowitz, Herbert; and Kazaz, Burak, "Global Production Planning under Exchange-Rate Uncertainty " (2000). Purdue CIBER Working Papers. Paper 9. hp://docs.lib.purdue.edu/ciberwp/9

Upload: others

Post on 07-Dec-2021

4 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Global Production Planning under Exchange-Rate Uncertainty

Purdue UniversityPurdue e-Pubs

Purdue CIBER Working Papers Krannert Graduate School of Management

1-1-2000

Global Production Planning under Exchange-RateUncertaintyMaqbool DadaPurdue University

Herbert MoskowitzPurdue University

Burak KazazUniversity of Miami

Follow this and additional works at: http://docs.lib.purdue.edu/ciberwp

This document has been made available through Purdue e-Pubs, a service of the Purdue University Libraries. Please contact [email protected] foradditional information.

Dada, Maqbool; Moskowitz, Herbert; and Kazaz, Burak, "Global Production Planning under Exchange-Rate Uncertainty " (2000).Purdue CIBER Working Papers. Paper 9.http://docs.lib.purdue.edu/ciberwp/9

Page 2: Global Production Planning under Exchange-Rate Uncertainty

Center for Intefnational Business-Education and Research

Global Production Planning under Exchange-Rate Uncertainty

iVIaqbooi· Dada· Purdue University

Herbert Moskowitz Purdue University

. BurakKazaz . University of !vfiami.

2000-009

. Knmnert Graduate School of Management Purdue Uiriversity · 1310 Knmnert Building West Lafayette, IN 47907-1310 (765) 494-4463 . Fax (765) 494-%58

Page 3: Global Production Planning under Exchange-Rate Uncertainty

Global Production Planning under Exchange-Rate Uncertainty

Burak Ka:zaz1& 2 Maqbool Dada3 Herbert Moskowitz3

1 School of Business, University of Miami, 414 Jenkins Building, Coral Gables, FL 33124 USA

2 IBM T. J. Watson Research Center, Yorktown Heights, NY 10538, USA

3 Krannert Graduate School of Management, Purdue University, W. Lafayette, IN 47907, USA

Draft: October 11, 2001

Abstract

Motivated by a production planning problem in an actual global manufacturing network, we examine

the impact of exchange-rate uncertainty ... namely the volatility in an& correlations among exchange rates

... on the choice of various optimal production policies and the conditions which lead to them. A two-stage

stochastic program with recourse is developed that provides opportunities to hedge financial risk by allowing

for some production planning decisions to be deferred until exchange rates are realized. The proposed model

and analysis yield the following results: (1) Under significan~ exchange-rate uncertainty it may be optimal

to hedge production by producing less than total demand, (2) production hedging is more likely an optimal

policy when either the profit margin is small and/or the exchange rates are highly volatile, (3) the probability

of following a production hedging policy decrea,ses as the correlations between exchange rates monotonically

increaSe in a positive direction, (4) after exchange rates are realized it may be optimal to hedge allocation

by not allocating all production to some of the markets, and (5) given production and/or allocation hedging,

our model identifies the value of financial hedging for each firm rather than a single option price for all firms.

This guarantees that all markets are served and that each firm gets an option price that is commensurate

with its exchange-rate risk. These findings and implications are illustrated with examples adapted from data

provided by IBM.

1

Page 4: Global Production Planning under Exchange-Rate Uncertainty
Page 5: Global Production Planning under Exchange-Rate Uncertainty

1 Introduction

This study is motivated by a production-planning problem regularly faced by a global electronics manufacturer,

and common to many global companies. The component manufacturing division of the company periodically

receives projected demand from the company's personal computer (PC) division as well as other original equip­

ment manufacturers (OEM). These projections are crucial to determining the quarterly aggregate plan that

allocates how much to manufacture of each product in each of its plants in order to maximize expected profit.

Along with setting the production plan, the company allocates budgets and sets transfer prices for sales to all

countries. Consequently, the revenue of the manufacturing division is subject to financial risk from currency

conversion since exchange rates fluctuate over time.

The standard approach as detailed in Flaherty's [1996] case, Applichem (A), is to replace those parameters

that are influenced by fluctuations -in-exchange rates by thejr expect_ed values. She then proceeds to solve

an aggregate production-planning problem in much the same way as when the problem setting is dom~stic.

Since all production and allocation decisions are made before the realization of exchange rates, this approach

has the limitation that it does not take into account that in practice some decisions, for example the allocation

decision, may be deferred until exchange rates are realized. Consequently, using_this approach foregoes significant

opportunities to hedge financial risk from exchange-rate fluctuations by allowing additional information prior

to determining an allocation policy.

This motivates us to focus on developing a modeling approach that provides opportunities to mitigate

financial risk by explicitly allowing for some decisions to be deferred until the exchange rates are realized. It

leads naturally to the formulation of a stochastic program with recourse whose objective is to maximize expected

profit. In the first stage of the problem, given projected demands in each country and costs for an aggregate

product, the production plan is determined. A hedge is introduced by allowing planned production to be less

than the total demand. Mter the first stage decisions are made, the realized exchange rates are observed.

Given the realized exchange rates, in the second or recourse stage of the problem, production is allocated to

meet demand. A second hedge iS introduced here by providing the opportunity to discard production if some

exchange-rate realizations are deemed to be economically unfavorable.

Our model differs considerably from related models in the literature because it advocates two forms of

operational hedging to mitigate exchange-rate risk. In one form, it can be optimal to produce less than the

total demand (stage 1). We coin this as production hedging. The optimality of production hedging holds true

notwithstanding the assumption that all foreign markets are ex-ante profitable (i.e. expected revenue is greater

than the total of manufacturing and transportation costs), making it a powerful result. In the other form, it

can be optimal to discard some production if the realized exchange rates are so unfavorable that revenues do

not justify transportation expenses. We call this allocation hedging (stage 2 or recourse stage). One might

2

Page 6: Global Production Planning under Exchange-Rate Uncertainty

intuit that allocation hedging leads to production hedging. Although allocation hedging helps to contribute to

this ~trategy, production hedging can be optimal without the presence of allocation hedging. This observation

further enhances the value of production hedging. Therefore, an optimal solution can have none, one, or both of

these two hedging features. We also quantify the magnitude of the financial risk faced by a manufacturer who

is compelled to meet all of the demand in its aggregate plan. This is determined by appropriately comparing

the optimal solution of our program with that of suitably related model variants. This analysis allows us to

compute reservation prices for any financial instrument (i.e. the maximum amount of money that one should

be willing to pay for such instruments) that may be purchased to hedge risk. Finally, our analysis also shows

how the financial risk can be appropriately shared among different functional entities within the company.

Section 2 provides a review of the operational hedging literature. We begin our analysis in Section 3 with the

most general form of our model. Then, considering several simpler variants enables us to present virtually all

the structural results pertinent to this model, characterize the optimal policy structure, and develop managerial

iusights. Exchange-rate uncertainty arises in our model from the following two sources: (a) the natural volatility

in each real (not nominal) exchange rate relative to the numeraire currency; and (b) the correlation among

the exchange rates when revenues arise from two or more foreign markets where the revenue from each is

denominated in its own local currency. In section 4, we apply our model to the global manufacturing network

of IBM, described in our motivating example. Concluding remarks are discussed in Section 5. Finally, proofs

are presented in an addendum available from the authors.

2 Literature Review

To put our two uses of operational hedges in perspective, consider the 1?-atural sequence of decisions in managing

a manufacturing network: 1) invest -in capacity, 2) manufacture, and 3) after manufacturing occurs, allocate

production to meet demand. Exchange rates are known either after steps 1, 2 or 3. This leads naturally to

thinking of the problem as a stochastic program with recourse. Figure 1 shows a framework to classify modeling

approaches for these conditions. For the global electronics manufacturer who motivated this study, the exchange

rates are realized after step 2 so that only the allocation decisions are made in the recourse stage of the problem.

We will refer to this problem as the recourse-after-production problem. Obviously, if exchange rates are known

prior to ali three manufacturing steps, then we can obtain the value of perfect information as a benchmark case.

Finally, in the traditional domestic analogue of our problem, exchange rates are realized after step 3. Thus,

there is no opportunity for recourse, and random exchange rates can be replaced by their expected values. As

a general rule, the more decisions that are deferred till exchange rates are realized, the higher the resulting

expected contribution. While the modeling approach developed in this paper is sufficiently general to apply to

all four situations outlined above, we focus on the case when exchange rates are realized between steps 2 and 3

3

Page 7: Global Production Planning under Exchange-Rate Uncertainty

in order to highlight the motivating application.

Figure l: Natural sequence of operational decisions and models that have different timing of exchange-rate

realizations

Earlier models of operational hedging have focused on the long-term, more strategic issues of capacity

investment and production switching. Huchzermeier and Cohen [1996] viewed an operational hedge as flexibility

to utilize a number of supply contract and production location options in a global supply chain. They employed

a recourse-after-capacity model (viz, exchange rates are observed after capacity decisions are made) in selecting

the design of the supply chain. Although their study does not provide structural results on the nature of the

optimal policy, it presents numerical examples that show that operational hedging can reduce the downside risk

of exchange rates in the longer term. The authors suggest that financial hedging be used to reduce the variability

of the firm's cash flows in the short term. Using the same modeling approach, Huchzermeier [1998] evaluated

the option value of operational flexibility in Applichem's network. Aspects of Huchzermeier and Cohen's [1996]

research may be seen as extending Kogut and Kulatilaka's [1994] uncapacitated model of costly switching of

production from one supplier to another in response to changing macroeconomic data. This switching strategy

can also be interpreted as an operational hedge. Using a sirullar approach, Dasu and Li [1997] deterrulned

production sv.ritchover among plants when costs were influenced by exchange rates. In a more recent paper,

Kouvelis et al. [2001] prescribed the choice of ownership structure (e.g. exporting, joint venture, and wholly­

owned subsidiary) for a set of production facilities under the presence of switchover costs. Rosenfield [1996]

provided a complementary approach to that proposed by Huchzermeier and Cohen [1996]. HiS production

and capacity decisions were based on minimizing costs influenced by exchange-rate fluctuations. In another

study, Kouvelis and Gutierrez [1997] deterrulned optimal production quantities and transfer prices within two

markets where demand of each occurred in non-overlapping time periods. Exchange-rate uncertainty was also

investigated in the context of supplier relationships where order quantities and contra.ct terms were determined

based on such fluctuations (e.g. Kouvelis [1999], Scheller-Wolf and Tayur [1999]).

The above models complement earlier work on incorporating exchange-rate uncertainty into the strategic

4

Page 8: Global Production Planning under Exchange-Rate Uncertainty

decision of capacity investment. Jucker and Carlson [1976) were the first to incorporate exchange-rate uncer­

tainty within the context of an uncapacitated plant location problem. They considered a model in which there

is demand and price uncertainty. Uncertainty in exchange rates was embedded in the uncertainty in prices since

exchange rates were assumed to influence prices in local markets. In a series of papers using a notion of an

exchange-rate mean-variance trade-off, this model was extended by Hodder and Jucker [1985a, 1985b). The ex­

tension of this approach to include limited capacity was considered by Hodder and Dincer [1986). Hodder [1984)

simplified the solution technique with a model that introduced a capital market (CAPM) approach with an

exchange-rate mean-covariance objective function. These studies permitted other sources of uncert'ainties such

as fluctuations in financial markets to reflect the definition of uncertainty. Below, as a summary, we tabulate

our survey of papers under recourse-after-capacity and recourse-after-production models_.

T bl 1 Cl iii a e : ass f 'h cahon o papers Wit t d r h respect o mo e mg apvroac es

Recourse-after-capacity models Recourse-after-production models

Cohen and Huchzermeier [1999) Dasu and Li [1997)

Hodder [1984) Kouvelis [1999)

Hodder and Jucker [1985a,b) Kouvelis and Gutierrez [1997)

Hodder and Dincer [1986)

Huchzermeier [1998)

Huchzermeier and Cohen [1996)

Kogut and Kulatilaka [1994)

Rosenfield [1996)

Scheller-Wolf and Tayur [1999[

Kouvelis et al. [2001)

3 The Model and Structural Results

This section presents a two-stage stochastic programming model for the aggregateproductiori planning problem

of a multinational company. We first introduce the most general form of the model, then use simpler variants

of the model in order to highlight key properties affecting operating decisions. The multinational company

obtains its revenues in the currency of the country of sale and converts it to the home country currency by

using exchange rates. Since exchange rates fluctuate, these cash flows are subject to risk. One optimal solution

suggests that under certain circumstances it is better to produce less than the total projected demand. This

can be viewed as a signal to inform managers that foreign prices are not properly aligned to compensate for

the exchange-rate risk, albeit, it may not be possible for the manager to increase priCes for competitive reasons.

5

Page 9: Global Production Planning under Exchange-Rate Uncertainty

When this is the case, we determine the value of deploying financial hedging. We also consider the impact of

correlated exchange rates and the timing of exchange rate realization on aggregate production planning.

3.1 The General Model

The first stage can be viewed as a contract to produce a certain output. The company commits to production

quantities at each plant, and headquarters transfers the associated amount of working capital to plants ( coun­

tries) for manufacturing purposes. Therefore, the mann!acturing costs are paid in advance and can be defined

in terms of the home country currency. Based on the output in stage 1 and the realized exchange rates, in stage

2 this output is allocated to markets in order to maximize expected profit (revenue less transportation costs).

The definition of stages are as follows:

Stage 1: Determine the production quantity.

Stage 2: Allocate produced units to markets after observing the exchange rates.

Using the above sequence, the resulting formulation ·is a stochastic program with recourse. Recourse refers

to carrying the optimal second stage decisions to the first stage in order to calculate the expected profit. We

use the following notation to introduce the mathematical model:

Parameters:

i: index representing country of production facility, i = 1, ... ,I

j: index representing country of sale (or markets), y" = 1, ... , J

r i: unit revenue from a sale in market y" (in terms of the currency of country y")

c;: unit cost of manufacturing in country i plant (in terms of domestic currency)

cij: unit transportation cost between countries i andy" (in terms of domestic currency); to simplify exposure,

we assume that Cii = 0 in the analysis

ei: a random variable representing the exchange rate that converts foreign currency y" to home country currency

(ej 2: 0)

( e1, ... , e;, ... , eJ ): a set of random variables representing the realization of exchange rates e1 through eJ

dj: the projected demand in country (market) j

Stage 1 Decision Variable:

X,: the amount of production in the plant of country i

6

Page 10: Global Production Planning under Exchange-Rate Uncertainty

Stage 2 Decision Variables:

X;;: the amount produced in country i and shipped for sale in country (market) j

To rule out trivial cases we impose the following:

{A.1) r;e; > c; + c;;, Vi= 1, ... ,I, Vj = 1, ... , J (expected unit revenue from selling in market j is greater than

the sum of unit manufacturing cost in country i and unit transportation cost from country i to country j)

where e; is the mean value of the exchange-rate random variable for country j. Assumption (A.1) makes all

markets to be ex-ante profitable. This assumptions is innocuous because the firm would probably not consider

doing business in these markets if it was not to hold. Using this notation, our problem is formulated as a

mathematical programming model which maximizes expected profit subject to transportation and demand

constraints. The first stage problem can be written as:

{P1) MAX(x,, ... ,x,, ... ,x,J E[P (X,, ... , X;, ... , Xr )] = I

- ~c;X;+E[PA((X,, ... ,X;, ... ,Xr) I (e,, ... ,e;, ... ,eJ))] {1) i=l

s.t.

xi 2: o,'v'i = I, ... J,'rlj = 1, ... ,J (2)

where E[PA ((X1, ... , X;, ... ,Xr) I {e1 , ... , e;, ... , eJ))] is the expected revenue obtained from producing the quan-

tities of {X1 , ... , X;, ... , Xr) in the first stage and P A ((X,, ... , X;, ... , XI) I (e., ... , e;, ... , eJ)) is the second stage

optimal solution value for given {X1 , ... ,X;, ... ,XI) units of production in each country {from stage 1) and

realized exchange rates of ( e1, ... , ej, ... , eJ) . E[ · J is the expectation operator over f ( e1, .. :, ej, ... , eJ), the joint

probability density function (pdf).

rhe second stage problem, allocation of production to markets, can be Written as:

J I

PA((X,, ... ,X;, ... ,XI) I (e,, ... ,e;, ... ,eJ)) = MAX(xu, ... ,x,,, ... ,Xu) ~~(r;ej -c;;)X;; (3) j=l i=l

s.t.

J

~X;; < Xi, 'Vi= 1, ... ,J {4) j=l

I

~X;; < dj,'Vj = l, ... ,J (5) i=l

Xij > O,'Vi = l, ... ,I,'Vj = l, ... ,J {6)

7

Page 11: Global Production Planning under Exchange-Rate Uncertainty

Compared to traditional aggregate production planning models, this formulation provides two forms of

increased flexibility. The first one enables production to be less than the total demand in stage 1, therefore a

constraint set such as I J

LX;= Ld;,'lj = l, ... ,J (7) i=l J=l

is not enforced. The second flexibility allows some of the production to be discarded in the second stage. This

is accomplished by not enforcing a constraint set that all produced units ate allocated to markets:

I J I

LX,= LLX;;,'Ii = l, ... ,I. (8) i=l j=l i=l

The latter is beneficial only when the realized exchange rate is sufficiently low enough that the transporta­

tion costs cannot be justified by sales revenue from a foreign market. The following remarks are useful in

understanding the value that such flexibility adds to aggregate production planning:

Remark 1 The value of (Pl) with constraint sets (7) and (8) enforced is less than or equal to that of (Pl) with

constraint set (7) enforced.

Remark 2 The value of (Pl} with constraint sets (7) and {8) enforced is less than or equal to that of (Pl) with

constraint set (8) enforced.

Remark 3 The value of (Pl} is greater than or equal to that of (Pl) with constraint set (7) enforced.

Remark 4 The value of {Pl} is greater than or equal to that of (Pl) with constraint set {8) enforced.

Remark 5 The value of {Pl} is greater than or equal to that of (Pl) with constraint sets (7) and (8) enforced.

Consequently, the optimal policy for problem (Pl) is different. One optimal solution suggests that producing

less than the total projected demand can be more beneficial. This means that equation (7) is not satisfied in the

optimal solution, and production hedging is the prescribed optimal policy. Even if the optimal solution suggests

to produce the total demand, there is no guarantee that equation (8) will be satisfied in the optimal policy. This

occurs when the realized exchange rate is low enough that transportation cost is not justified by revenue times

~xchange rate. Therefore, the foreign market is not served, and equation {8) is not satisfied. We refer to this

as allocation hedging. As a~resnlt, the flexibility by not enforcing the equations (7) and (8), which are typically

enforced in traditional modeling approaches, can provide optimal policies that employ production or allocation

hedging alone, or both simultaneously. Furthermore, the set of potentially optimal solutions for the two-stage

stochastic program consists of sums of some projected demand values. Since the number Of solutions grows

super-exponentially, it is unlikely to that a tractable computational scheme can be developed. Nevertheless,

substantial understanding of the problem structure can be obtained from the analysis of special cases.

8

Page 12: Global Production Planning under Exchange-Rate Uncertainty

3.2 Impact of Exchange-Rate Uncertainty on Production Hedging

Here, we analyze the impact of exchange-rate uncertainty in a network that consists of one plant and two markets

(one domestic and one foreign). Revenue in the foreign market is collected in foreign currency. Therefore, there

is a single exchange-rate varia~le, denoted by e2. Decision variable X 1 represents the production quantity in the

plant in the first stage, and X 11 and X 1z are the second stage allocation quantities from the plant to these two

markets. Parameters d1 and d2 are projected demand values in the domestic and foreign countries, respectively.

To characterize the optimal solution, first observe that P A (X1 I ez) is the value of the optimal solution

to a linear program for a given production quantity of Xr (from stage 1) and the realized value of e2 • It is

piecewise-linear and concave in X 1 with break points located at X1 = min(d1,d2 ), X 1 = max(d1,d2 ), and

X1 = dr + d2 . Since these hold true for all realizations of ez, the first stage objective function, E[P (X1)], is

also concave and piec~wise-linear in X1_. Hence, the optimal value of X 1 ·occurs at a break point. These break

points areXr =0, X, =min(dr,dz),Xr =ma.x(dr,dz), andXr =dr+dz. Xr =OandX, =min(dr,dz) can

be eliminated by assumption (A.l). This leads to the following theorem:

Theorem 1 The optimal production quantity in stage 1 is either the maximum of (dr, dz) or dr + d2 •

The managerial implications of this theorem are counter-intuitive. Despite the assumption (A.l) that each

market is ex-ante profitable, total production in an optimal solution may be less than the total demand. In

other words, a production hedge can be optimal. Furthermore, it can b~ optimal to discard some production

due to unfavorable exchange-rate realizations. This is termed as allocation hedging, and can be observed with

or without production hedging. To develop some insight regarding allocation hedging, consider the time that

the exchange rate is realized. If it is favorable enough that per unit profit (net of shipping) from the foreign

market in stage 2 exceeds that of its domestic counterpart, as much output as possible is shipped to the foreign

market. The remaining (if any) products are sold in the domestic market. If the exchange rate is unfavorable,

however, as much output as possible is sold in the domestic market. The remaining products (if any) are shipped

to the foreign market only if the revenue converted to the _home country currency exceeds transportation costs;

otherWise, they are discarded. Therefore, the domestic market acts as a backup tha~ mitigates some of the risk

from exchange-rate fluctuations.

Production hedging becomes optimal when there is significant exchange-rate volatility andfor when the

expected profit margin is low. This is shown in the following remark:

Remark 6 The following condition, 0, determines whether producing dr + dz is preferable to producing the

maximum of (dr, dz):

(9)

9

Page 13: Global Production Planning under Exchange-Rate Uncertainty

and the value of B increases with increasing values of Tt and r2 and _decreasing values of c 1 and c 12 . Therefore,

a).i&>O ar, b).i&>O ar, c).i&<O ac, d 1 .lt!L < 0. 'I 8c12

We already know from Theorem 1 that the firm must produce at least the maximum of (d1 ,d2). Because of

linearity, e can be interpreted as a derivative that represents the value of producing one more unit beyond the

maximum of (d1 , d2 ). The cost of producing one more unit is c1• The two integral terms in (9) represent the

expected second stage return from a unit increase in production. Each term has the returns from the less desired

market as a result of this marginal perspective. Accounting for··an contingencies, the first integral represents

the incremental revenue which results from using this unit to serve the foreign market. If the exchange rate

is unfavorable (when e2 - c,2/r2 < 0) this incremental nnit is not used. This is more likely to occur with a

higher value of c12 , the unit transportation cost, relative to the unit revenue in the foreign market. The same

conclusion is made when the exchange rate distribution is volatile and has a higher mass between the values of

0 and C!2/r2. The second integral term has a constant return, rr; for all realizations of e2. This term represents

the concurrent incremental revenue from being able to sell one more unit in the domestic market. As a result,

if the total incremental revenue exceeds the unit production cost, cb (I is non-negative, and it is beneficial to

produce one more unit. Then, it follows from linearity that it is best to increase production to the total deniand.

Otherwise, it is optimal to produce the maximum of ( d,, d:l); in other words, follow a production hedging policy.

As can be summarized from Remark 6, whenever the expected profit margin is low or there is higher volatility

in exchange rates, the more likely it is that B will be negative; consequently the more likely it is that production

hedging will be optimal.

Suppose that (9) is not satisfied and it is optimal to follow a production hedging policy; in other words

produce less than the total demand. When this is the case managers may be uncomfortable with deliberately

underserving markets. (} offers insight as to how a firm can remedy this. From an operations perspective, the

firm conid lower the unit manufacturing cost c1 and/or the unit transportation cost c12 making e larger. Such

action is solely within the domain of the finn and has the added effect of raising the profit margins for all.

customers. From a management perspective, the firm could attempt to raise the price in one or both markets to

make e larger. The latter would be considerably more difficult to carry out because of internal transfer pricing

policies and external price competition.

Even if management can satisfy (9) so that it is optimal to produce the total demand, there is no guarantee

that both markets will be served. This is due to the fact that under allocation hedging production will be

discarded when exchange rates are urifavorable. An obvious mechanism to overcome this adverse action is to

buy a call option to limit downside risk. We next calculate the value of purchasing such financial instruments

10

Page 14: Global Production Planning under Exchange-Rate Uncertainty

in the context of this problem. This economic value enables managers to make interactive decisions between

financial and operational hedging.

3.3 Economic Values of Financial and Operational Hedging and Their Interaction

We now determine how much value financial hedging would add to the global production planning problem.

Because our model has the flexibility of not satisfying equations (7) and (8), the decision maker has to consider

the interaction between financial and operational hedging. The value calculated here corresponds to the man­

ager's reservation price to employ a financial instrument such as a call option under various operational hedging

schemes. The reservation price is the maximum that the decision maker would be willing to pay for such an

instrument. To simplify the exposition, we assume that both markets have identical demand d. The incremental

value of utilizing financial hedging is shown for both of the potentially optimal policies, production hedging, and

producing the total demand. First, consider the case where the optimal solution is a production hedge which

suggests manufacturing only d. However, the firm is interested in making certain that total production is 2d

and that both markets will be fully served- namely, neither production nor allocation hedging will be exercised.

Clearly this solution is sub-optimal and riskier to the firm. Notice that this risk derives from converting the

revenue of r2e2 into the numeraire currency. An obvious way to mitigate this risk is to purchase a call option

to convert r2d units of the foreign currency at the ·numeraire amount of r2e2d (strike price of e2). The premium

paid to purchase this option is ignored for the time being in order to identify ex-post returns. However, it is

used to compare the value-added to the system at the end, and the decision to purchase the option depends on

this comparison.

This simple call option, as shown in the Appendix, has a positive value if the strike price is greater than

or equal to the ratio of the sum of unit manufacturing and transportation costs to the unit revenue from the

foreign market, e2 2: ~. Its val~e to the firm is greater than r1 - c1 if the foreign customer is more profitable

ex-ante ( r 1 < r2e2 - c12). Its_ value is between zero and r1 - c1 if the foreign customer is less profitable ex-ante

(r1 2: r2e2- c12). The incremental value of utilizing such an option, denoted as V(e2), when producing and

satisfying all requirements can be written as follows:

V(e~) =

d [r, - c, + J~r, +c,)jr, (r2e~ - i:12 - r1) f (e2) de2 + J(~: +c,)jr, r2 (e~- e2) f (e2) de2 J if TI < T2e2 - C12

d [r, - c1 + J;; (roe~ - Cl2 - r,) f (e2) de2 + J,~' +c,)jr, (r2e2 - c12 - r,) f (e2) de2 J

if T1 2: r2e2 - Ci2

(10)

Notice that each expression for V(e2) is similar to that of 0; however, in the region of allocation hedging,

0::; e2 ::; c12/r2, V(e~) is always positive. Notice that it is 0 in the same region in 0. Hence, we can conclude

11

Page 15: Global Production Planning under Exchange-Rate Uncertainty

that if a call option to convert r2d units of the foreign currency at the strike price of e~ can be purchased for

a premium of up to V(eD, then it is optimal to increase pro.duction to the total demand and fully serve both

customers. A similar approach can be used to show that if the optimal policy were to produce the total demand,

and a call option were to be purchased to hedge against the exchange-rate risk, it too would have a positive

value. Since a call ~ption with a strike price, e2, greater than or equal to c12/r2 prevents allocation hedging,

the incremental value can be written as:

(11)

Similarly, if a call option can be purchased for a premium up to this value, then it is optimal to purchase the

financial option and guarantee serving both markets. Otherwise, it is still optimal to produce the total demand,

however, the possibility of allocation hedging is not eliminated.

We have outlined how the presence of exchange-rate uncertainty necessitates a cross-functional approach to

overcoming its adverse effects when engaging in production planning for a global manufacturing network. The

structural results described above are quite robust, in the sense that they hold for any exchange-rate distribution.

The model used in this section considered one foreign market and explored ouly the effect of exchange rate

volatility. It can be shown that the policy implications of our model are valid in the presence of correlated

exchange rates among foreign markets and provides additional insight regarding their impact on choices.

3.4 Impact of Correlated Exchange Rates

It is not necessary for a domestic market to be present in order for a production hedge to be effective: We now

examine how the policy structure changes when there is one plant and two foreign markets whose exchange

rates are correlated. Define r2 and r3 as the unit revenues from selling in countries 2 and 3, respectively. X1

(first stage decision variable) is the amount of production in the plant, and X12 and X 1a (second stage decision

variables) are the quantities shipped to the second and third markets, respectively. To simplify the exposition,

we assume that the demand in each country is equal to d. Since both markets are foreign, two exchange rates

must be considered. e2 and e3 denote the two random variables that represent these exchange rates. These two

random variables have a joint pdf j(e2, ea); the correlation coefficient is p ( -1 :S p::; +1). In this case, p plays

a crucial role in determining how much to produce. Production hedging is apt to occur when p is sufficiently

small. We begin the analysis with the following:

Theorem 2 The optimal production quantity in stage 1 is either d or 2d.

While Theorem 2 is useful in characterizing the structure of the optimal policy, it is also of interest to

examine the sensitivity of the optimal solution to p, the correlation between two exchange rates. We begin by

12

Page 16: Global Production Planning under Exchange-Rate Uncertainty

defining the function 8 (p) as the difference between the expected profits of producing 2d and d for a given p.

8 (p) = EP[X1 = 2d I p[- EP[X1 =dIp] (12)

It follows that when 8 (p) is negative, the optimal production quantity is d, so that the optimal solution

can be interpreted as a production hedging policy. Conversely, when 8 (p) is positive, the optimal production

quantity is 2d. To make the optimal production decision, it is sufficient to evaluate the sign of 8 (p). Although,

in general, the evaluation of 8 (p) depends on specifying a joint density for e2 and es, there are important

exceptions. It should be noted here that the line rzez - ctz = raea - era divides the exchange rate space

diagonally into two sections. Considering that the vertical axis represents ez values, a realization of exchange

rate below this line makes the second stage return of raea - era higher than rzez - Ctz· Therefore revenue from

foreign market 3 is preferred over that of foreign market 2. It can be shown that 8 (p) is always positive if the

density is positive only above the choice line of rzez - crz = raea - era or only below rzez - c1z = raea - Cta·

When this is the case, the optimal policy is to produce 2d.

In general, however, the joint density will be positive on both sides of the choice line, rzez - c1z = Taea- eta,

thus additional analysis of 8 (p) is warranted. Intuition suggests that if the production hedging policy X1 = d is

optimal (8 (p) < 0) it is more apt to occur when pis close to -1. This is due to the fact that a favorable value

of e2 is balanced by an unfavorable value of e3 • As p increases this balance would tilt towards full production

(8 (p) > 0). In order to further examine the behavior of 8(p), some restrictions need to be imposed on the density.

Adequate tractability is achieved, while providing a rich modeling framework, by restricting the density to the

following sub-family of the family of densities developed in Van Mieghem [1995]:

,, = l 1 if (-=Er -2 (-=E)(-=E)+(-=Er <1-p2 l n.Jl-p2 2112 P Zcr2 Za-3 2cra

0 otherwise

for -1 <p<+1

j(e2, es

= l _1_ if (~)=-(~) and -1::; ( c1:;~) :S +1 and -1 < (e.,->1) < +1 l 2-/2 - 2cra -

0 otherwise

for p= -1

l _1_ if(-=E)=(=) and -1 < ( ez-F.) < +1 and -1 <(eo-eo)< +1 l '"' 2-/2 2cr2 2cra - 2d2 - - 2tra -

0 otherwise

for p=+1

=

Notice that in (13) the density is non-negative and uniform on an ellipse when -1 < p < + 1, and on a

line-segment when p = -1 or p = +1. Next, we show that 8(p) is monotonically increasing with increasing

values of p. Using a common practice of setting prices to make both markets equally attractive ex-ante, or

r2e2 - c12 = r3e3 - C13, we can prove the following:

13

Page 17: Global Production Planning under Exchange-Rate Uncertainty

Theorem 3 lfr2e2- c12 = raea- c13 and j(e2,eal p) is given by {13}, then o(p) is monotonically increasing

urith the increasing values of p.

The implication of Theorem 3 is that there exists at most one solution to o(p) = 0. We denote the correlation

coefficient that satisfies o(p) = 0 as p*. The value of this critical correlation coefficient can be found in the

following theorem.

Theorem 4 lfr2e2- c12 = raea- c13 and j(e2, ea I p) is given by {13}, then the critical correlation coefficient,

p*, that satisfies o(p) = 0 is equal to:

p* =! (r2o-2) +! (rao-a) _ 9rr2

(r2il2- c12- c,) (raea- c13- c,)

2 racrs 2 rza2 32 rzuz raua (14)

when -l < 1 (1:2.£2.) +! (=) _ 9'lf2

Cr2e2"-c12-cd (rse"3-c1s-cd < + 1. 2 raua 2 r2u2 32 r2u2 raua

When the .correlation coefficient among two exchange rates is below p*, then production hedging is the

optimal solution; otherwise, it is more profitable to produce the total demand. The critical correlation coefficient

can also be seen as the point where the company switches its policy from production hedging to satisfying the

total demand. In order for the company to satisfy the total demand, it has to have either a sufficiently high

profit margin or a relatively low volatility in exchange rates. It is useful to observe that the first 2 terms of (14)

balance reciprocally the relative risk from the two markets, while the last term adjusts for the joint risk from

the two markets.

Remark 7 The critical correlation coefficient, p*, of {14) decreases with

a) increasing values of expected second stage contributions, i.e. rzez - cr2

b) decreasing values of standard deviation of exchange rates, o-2 and as

Knowing that managers would like to satisfy total demand, it seems that it would be in their best interest to

increase locaL prices. Although this may not be possible due to competition, assuming that it can be increased

up to infinity provides a threshold value for the optimal solution. In the limit when r2 and r3 go to infinity,

production hedging is still optimal When the correlation coefficient among two exchange rates is below this

threshold value. We use ~ ( C'L72 = ~) and cv3 ( cv3 = *) to denote the coefficient of variation for exchange

rates of e2 and e3 1 respectively.

Theorem 5 When r2e2- C!2 = r3e3- c13 and j(e2,ea·l p) is given by {13}, production hedging is always

optimal for correlation coefficient values that are smaller than or equal to:

1 (0"2) . 1 (0"3) 97r2

1 2 0"3 + 2 0"2 - 32 CV2CV3

(15)

when -1 < 1 (~) +! (£>)- 911"

2-

1- < +1. 2 0"3 2 0"2 32 CV2CV3

When o-2 = o-3 is assumed1 the above threshold simplifies to 1 - 93~22

~. Therefore, under this assumption, cv,

production hedging is always optimal when cv2 2: 4~.

14

Page 18: Global Production Planning under Exchange-Rate Uncertainty

3.5 Effect of Exchange Rate Realization Timing

We now consider the timing effect of exchange-rate realization on the optimal production and allocation poli­

cies. As discussed in Section 1, the recourse problem is sensitive to the timing of exchange-rate realizations.

Interestingly, not only is expected profit monotone in the timing of information, but as we show for the one

plant, one domestic and one foreign market case, so is the optimal policy. As a general rule, the later exchange

rates are realized, the lower is the expected profit and the higher is the investment in capacity. We begin

with a comparison of the recourse-after-production model with the recourse-after-capacity model. The only

difference between these two models is that the exchange rate is observed after capacity commitment but be­

fore production commitment occurs in the recourse-after-capacity model; it is observed after production in the

recourse-after-production mod,el. In the recourse-after-production model, c1 is the unit cost of manufacturing

and capacity investment in the plant. If G! is decomposed into two terms as the unit cost of manufacturing,

defined as em, and the unit cost of capacity investment, defined as cc, where c1 = em + cc, these two models

become directly comparable. Capacity investment occurs prior to production in both models. The unit cost

of manufacturing, however, occurs in the second stage in the recourse-after-capacity model whereas it occurs

in the first stage in the recourse-after-production model. Thus for the same capacity investment, the expected

profit is never lower in the recourse-after-capacity model. However, when the capacity is less than the minimum

requirement of the two markets, the expected profit for each of these models is identical and increases with the

same slope. When capacity increases beyond this minimum, the unit contribution to expected profit is higher

in the recourse-after-capacity model as illustrated in Figure 2.

Expected Profits

---

Recourse-after-

--

Figure 2: A sample of expected profit vs. production quantity graphs for a recourse-after-capacity and a

recourse-after-production model

15

Page 19: Global Production Planning under Exchange-Rate Uncertainty

Because the exchange rate is observed prior to the production and allocation decisions, the recourse-after·

capacity model has neither allocation nor production hedging. Instead it has a capacity hedge because the

capacity decision can be less than the total demand. It can also experience an unfavorable recourse of capacity

because production can be less than capacity. These insights are formalized as:

Theorem 6 Expected profit from the optimal production policy in the recourse-after-capacity model is always

greater than or equal to that of the recourse-after-production model.

The single-period version of the model of Huchzermeier and Cohen [1996] is a form of the recourse-after­

capacity model. In their multi-period model they commit to capacity before the start of each period, and

after observing the exchange rate they decide on production and allocation decisions. Since their capacity

commitment is in lumpy quantities it is unlikely that structural results like those in our model can be obtained.

They conclude that the firm would engage in higher capacity investment under exchange-rate uncertainty. This

can.be seen as a capacity hedging policy that mitigates the downside risk of exchange-rate uncertainty.

The following theorem allows us to compare the results of the recourse-after-capacity model with the recourse­

after-production model. This theorem states that the single-period version of the recourse-after-capacity model

has structural results similar to the recourse-after-production model. Furthermore, in the single-period version,

the optimal capacity investment does not exceed the total demand. We conjecture that the recommendation of

Huchzermeier and Cohen [1996], i.e. investing in higher capacity to compensate for exchange-rate uncertainty,

is a consequence of the fact that their capacity choices are discrete.

Theorem 7 a) If the optimal production in the recourse-after-production model is the total demand, d1 + d2,

then in the recourse-after-capacity model the optimal capacitY investment is also equal to the total demand,

d, + dz; b) If the recourse-after-capacity model results in a capacity hedging policy (investing in less capacity

than the total demand), then the "recourse-after-production model also prescribes production hedging in optimal

solutions.

This theorem does not imply that the two models always provide the same results, but that X, in the recourse­

after-capacity model is never less than the corresponding value in the recourse-after-production model. Indeed,

there might be cases where the recourse-after-capacity model yields a capacity investment equal to the total

demand whereas the recourse-after-production model calls for a production hedging policy. This result is due to

the timing of exchange-rate realization. The optimal policy for these models may recommend completely different

sets of capacity investment, production quantity, and allocation to market decisions. Therefore, we conclude

that the timing of exchange-rate realization influences all operational decisions; namely capacity investment,

production planning, and allocation of production to markets.

In both models a hedge can occur in two ways: (a) the first is the case where the profit margin is small

andfor the exchange rate distribution is volatile, and (b) the second is where there is a significant amount of

16

Page 20: Global Production Planning under Exchange-Rate Uncertainty

allocation hedging. It should be noted that allocation hedging is a consequence of high transportation cost

relative to the price. Analogous results can be obtained by a pairwise comparison of the perfect information

model to the recourse-after-capacity model; and to the recourse-after-production model with the no-information

model.

4 An Empirical Study of a Global Manufacturing Network

This section demonstrates how our model may be employed to make aggregate planning decisions in an actual

empirical setting. The data is adapted from a global manufacturing network of IBM. Our objective is not to

assess network performance, but rather to illustrate the application of our model and the potential benefits

that could result from using it. Although the actual network is quite complex, for illustrative purposes we can

consider it to consist of three regions: North America, Europe, and Asia/Pacific. Each of these three markets has

a projected demand and only two of these three markets have a production plant. We employ a sample of daily

real exchange-rate quotations from September 1996 to February 1997, as recorded in International Financial

Statistics. The data set has 115 observations and the following statistical properties: Ji.DM = 0.640917; Jl.y =

0.008724; <7DM = 0.025190; oy = 0.000338; p = 0.96119. Here Ji.DM and Jl.y are the mean, and <7DM and o-y

are the standard deviations of the Deutsche Mark and the Japanese Yen, respectively. The price in Europe is

expressed in Deutsche Marks (DM), for Asia/Pacific the Japanese Yen, and for North America the US Dollar.

It is important to note that in this specific period of time which the data set represents, exchange rates of these

currencies did not exhibit great volatility.

One approach to solving this problem is to fit a joint distribution to the underlying exchange rates and then

attempt to directly solve the resulting stochastic program. Alternatively, as done here, we can characterize

admissible extreme points (there are 23). If we think of each of these solutions as a scenario that is feasible in

the first stage, when the expected value of the second stage program is known, these 23 scenarios could then be

compared to determine the optimal solution. Rather than compute the expectation, we generate an estimate

of it by solving the second-stage linear programs for each of the 115 exchange rate observations. The mean of

each of these 115 solutions net of production costs yields an unbiased estimate of the expected profit for that

scenario. The scenario yielding the highest expected profit is then selected as the optimal solution.

Our numerical experiment reveals that the optimal solution for this product is to produce the total demand.

Moreover, exchange rates aie sufficiently stable so that allocation hedging is never exercised; consequently all

three markets are fully served. The same analysis is replicated with prices that are 3.6% lower in each market.

(The earlier assumptions on ex-ante profitability are not violated with the reduction in prices.) In contrast

to the case with original prices, the optimal solution is a production hedging policy that calls for producing

just 50% of the total demand; once again allocation hedging is not exercised. It is interesting to note that the

17

Page 21: Global Production Planning under Exchange-Rate Uncertainty

expected profit under this optimal production hedging policy is 137% higher than under the best plan that

produces the total demand. This result highlights the importance of exchange rate volatility on production

planning. The benefits of using production hedging under significant volatility are likely to be even greater.

Since the expected profit under the production hedge is significantly higher, and, a strategic decision is made

to serve all markets, the ensuing financial risk can be mitigated by buying call options with the Deutsche Mark

· and Yen as discussed in Section 3.3. The strike prices of each of these options are equal to its mean value. Recall

that when such options are utilized, the optimal solution is to produce the total demand and satisfy all markets.

In order to simplify the comparison, we rescale expected profits by taking the best solution of producing the total

demand with no financial options as the basis ($1.00). With this scale, the optimal production hedging solution

has an expected profit of $2.37. The optimal expected profit using financial options is $2. 70, 170% higher than

the base case plan when the premium for these options are excluded. This expected profit is also 13.77% higher

than in the optimal production hedging policy. From an operations manager's perspective, this difference of

$0.33 corresponds to the value of using such options. Alternatively, it determines her/his reservation price. If

the premium of the options costs less than that $0.33, then it is beneficial to buy the options, produce the

total demand, and satisfy all markets. Suppose that the premium is higher than $0.33 but less than $1. 70. In

contrast, if the corporate policy is to fully serve all markets as part of their strategic plans, then the reservation

price from a corporate perspective is $1. 70. Hence, we can conclude that up to $0.33 of the premium should

be charged to the operations manager, and the remaiuing premium should be absorbed at the corporate level.

This "realistic'' example not only shows that the value of using financial instruments can be substantial, it

also provides insight on how to share the expenses of such an action among production divisions and corporate

headquarters.

5 Conclusions and Managerial Insights

We have investigated the impact of exchange-rate uncertainty on production planning decisions in a global

manufacturing network. A two-stage stochastic program is developed in which the firm is given the choice of

serving less than the market demand. This is accomplished ex-ante by a "production hedge'' under which total

production is less than total demand. It is exercised ex-post by not allocating all production to markets when

the exchange rates are too unfavorable. The latter option is termed "allocation hedging."

We began our analysis by identifying the set of potentially optimal production policies and the conditions

which enforce them. When the production hedging policy is optimal, we calculate the reservation price for a

manager who wants to utilize a financial instrument, e.g. an option, in order to mitigate the downside risk of

exchange-rate fluctuations and of satisfying demand in all markets. It is important to note that no assumptions

were made with regard to exchange-rate distributions, thus these structural results are robust. By using a

18

Page 22: Global Production Planning under Exchange-Rate Uncertainty

special family of distributions (Van Mieghem [1995]), we are able to show that similar structural results hold

when there are multiple exchange rates that are correlated. Finally, our analytical results are illustrated with

actual data from a global manufacturing network of IBM that reveals the substantial benefits of production and

financial hedging.

The analysis presented yields three main results. First, notwithstanding the assmnption that each market

is ex-ante profitable we show that under significant exchange-rate risk it can be optimal to produce less than

the total demand. We refer to this as the "production hedging" policy. Several examples of this policy can be

observed in industrial practice. For example, an article in the Wall Street Journal ("Weak Yen Stymies U.S.

Strategies for Asia," June 15, 1998, pp. A2) states that the Chrysler Corp. recognizes that there is unmet

demand for its U.S. made cars in Japan, but, the company is not quite sure whether to explore this market

due to the downside risk of the Japanese Yen: "In December, when a dollar sold for around 130 yen, Chrysler

Corp. chief economist M. Van Bussman warned that if the U.S. currency rose to 140 yen, 'it would scare the

pants off us.' On Friday, a dollar bought 144.33 yen in New York." The article concludes, "That puts quite a

chill on Chrysler's efforts to sell cars in Japan.'' Despite the demand in Japan, Chrysler chooses not to serve

the Japanese market due to the fall of the yen.

The second result shows that production hedging is more likely to be optimal when the profit margin is

small and/ or the exchange rate is highly volatile. In order to provide further insight on this, we analyze

the case of correlated multiple exchange rates using a sub-family of the family of densities developed by Van

Mieghem [1995]. This yields a third result that the probability of following a production hedging policy as an

the optimal solution decreases as the correlation coefficient between exchange rates monotonically increases from

being perfectly negatively correlated to being perfectly positively correlated. We then find a critical correlation

coefficient that determines when to switch from a policy of production hedging to producing the total demand.

The value of this "critical" correlation coefficient is impacted by th~ profit margin and the exchange rate

coefficient of variation. These results provide managerial insight and guidance by incorporating the two main

factors that influence risk in exchange-rate markets: volatility of each exchange rate and their correlation.

Our model also suggests that when exchange rates exhibit high volatility and the optimal solution calls for

a production hedge, we show ·how the plan can be modified to fully serve all markets. This is achieved by

developing an integrated solution that requires collaborative decision making among three different functional

areas (marketing, operations, and finance.) From a marketing perspective, the possibility of increasing prices

can be explored (however, this may not be easily accomplished due to external price competition or internal

transfer pricing policy); or, reducing manufacturing costs can be considered by the operations ~ction. Finally,

the feasibility of utilizirig a financial instrument to mitigate the downside risk can be investigated. Indeed, such

approaches are used in practice. For example, in another article in the Wall Street Journal ( "UTC Battles

Asian Slmnp with Cutback," August 19, 1998, pp. Al, A6), it was reported that the United Technologies Corp.

19

Page 23: Global Production Planning under Exchange-Rate Uncertainty

(UTC - producer of heating/air conditioning instruments and elevators) chose to make all efforts in reducing

manufacturing costs as it could not increase prices due to competition. The article also stated that UTC was

decreasing its capacity investment in Asia due to fluctuations in exchange rates. This decision was made despite

the fact that Asia was the fastest growing market for its products. This corresponds to a form of production

hedging.

Finally, we propose three extensions for future research. The first is to develop models that consider inventory

holding decisions in a multi-period context. We conjecture that policies such as production hedging are likely

to be optimal in this setting as well. The second extension is to examine the combined impact of exchange rate

and demand uncertainty on production and capacity planning decisions. In view of the above studies, the third

extension would consider more strategic decisions such as the number and location of facilities.

Acknowledgments

We would like to thank Dr. Robert Baseman and Mr. William Grey of the IBM T. J. Watson Research

Center, Yorktown Heights, NY for the insight they provided during numerous enlightening conversations. We

are also grateful for their generous contribution of data for sample IBM products.

References

[1] Christopher, M., "Logistics and Supply Chain Management," IRWIN Professional Publishing, New York,

1994.

[2] Cohen, M., Huchzermeier, A., "Global Supply Chain Management: A Survey of Research and Applications,"

pp. 669-702, edited by S. Tayur et a!., Kluwer Academic Publishers, Massachusetts, 1999.

[3] Dasu, S., Li, L., "Optimal Operating Policies in the Presence of Exchange Rate Variability,'' Management

Science, Vol. 43, No. 5, pp. 705-722, 1997.

[4] Flaherty, T., "Global Operations Management," McGraw Hill, New York, 1996.

[5] Hodder, J., uFinancial Mark~t Approaches to Facility Location under Uncertaintyt Operations Research,

Vol. 32, pp. 1374-1380, 1984.

[6] Hodder, J., Jucker, J., "Illternational Plant Location under Price and Exchange Rate Uncertainty,'' Engi­

neering Costs and Production Economics, Vol. 9,·pp. 225-229, 1985a.

[7] Hodder, J., Jucker, J., "A Simple Plant Location Model for Quantity-Setting Firms Subject to Price

Uncertainty," European Journal of Operations Research, Vol. 21, pp. 39-46, 1985b.

[8] Hodder, J., Dincer, C., "A Multifactor Model for International Plant Location and Financing under Un­

certainty," Computers and Operations Research, Vol. 13, No. 5, pp. 601-609, 1986.

20

Page 24: Global Production Planning under Exchange-Rate Uncertainty

[9] Huchzermeier, A., "Evaluating the Benefit of Operational Flexibility and the Real Option Value of Manage­

rial Flexibility in Global Supply Chain Networks," Production and Operations Management (forthcoming),

1998.

[10] Huchzermeier, A., Cohen, M., "Valuing Operational Flexibility Under Exchange Rate rusk," Operations

Research, Vol. 44, pp. 100-113, 1996.

[11] Jucker, J., Carlson, R., "The Simple Plant-Location Problem under Uncertainty/' Operations Research,

Vol. 24, pp. 1045-1055, 1976.

[12] Kogut, B., Kulatilaks, N., "Operating Flexibility, Global Manufacturing, and the Option Value of a Multi­

national Network," Management Science, Vol. 40, No. 1, pp. 123-139, 1994.

[13] Kouvelis, P., "Global Sourcing Strategies under Exchange Rate Uncertainty, " pp. 625-667, edited by S.

Tayur et a!., Kluwer Academic Publishers, Massachusetts, 1999.

[14] Kouvelis, P., Axarloglou, K., Sinha, V., "Exchange Rates and the Choice of Ownership Structure of Pro­

duction Facilities," Management Science, Vol. 47, No. 8, pp. 1063-1080, 2001.

[15] Kouvelis, P., Gutierrez, G., "The Newsvendor Problem in a Global Market: Optimal Centralized and

Decentralized Control Policies for a Two-Market Stochastic Inventory System,'' Management Science, Vol.

43, No. 5, pp. 571-585, 1997.

[16] Petruzzi, N., Dada, M., "Information and Inventory Recourse for a Two-Market, Price-Setting Retailer,"

Working Paper, 2000.

[17] Rosenfield, D. B., "Global and Variable Cost Manufacturing Systems," European Journal of Operations

Research , Vol. 95, pp. 325-343, 1996.

[18] Scheller-Wolf, A., Tayur, S., "Managing Supply Chains in Emerging Markets," pp. 703-735, edited by S.

Taynr et al., Kluwer Academic Publishers, Massachusetts, 1999.

[19] Van Mieghem, J. A., "Multi-Resource Investment Strategies under Uncertainty," Unpublished Doctoral

Dissertation, Graduate School of Business, Stanford University, 1-89, May 1995.

21