household credit and the monetary transmission mechanism · household credit and the monetary...

32
WORKING PAPER SERIES Household Credit and the Monetary Transmission Mechanism Victor E. Li Working Paper 1998-019A http://research.stlouisfed.org/wp/1998/1998-019.pdf FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS Research Division 411 Locust Street St. Louis, MO 63102 ______________________________________________________________________________________ The views expressed are those of the individual authors and do not necessarily reflect official positions of the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis, the Federal Reserve System, or the Board of Governors. Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Working Papers are preliminary materials circulated to stimulate discussion and critical comment. References in publications to Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Working Papers (other than an acknowledgment that the writer has had access to unpublished material) should be cleared with the author or authors. Photo courtesy of The Gateway Arch, St. Louis, MO. www.gatewayarch.com

Upload: truongmien

Post on 04-May-2018

221 views

Category:

Documents


2 download

TRANSCRIPT

WORKING PAPER SERIES

Household Credit and the Monetary

Transmission Mechanism

Victor E. Li

Working Paper 1998-019A

http://research.stlouisfed.org/wp/1998/1998-019.pdf

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUISResearch Division

411 Locust Street

St. Louis, MO 63102

______________________________________________________________________________________

The views expressed are those of the individual authors and do not necessarily reflect official positions of

the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis, the Federal Reserve System, or the Board of Governors.

Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Working Papers are preliminary materials circulated to stimulate

discussion and critical comment. References in publications to Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Working

Papers (other than an acknowledgment that the writer has had access to unpublished material) should be

cleared with the author or authors.

Photo courtesy of The Gateway Arch, St. Louis, MO. www.gatewayarch.com

HOUSEHOLD CREDIT AND THE MONETARYTRANSMISSION MECHANISM

September 1998

Abstract

This paper evaluates the importance of household credit in the transmission of monetary policy

and in explaining the positive correlation between money and credit services over the business

cycle. It does so in the context of a general equilibrium framework of cash and household credit

with two distinguishing features. There is an explicit financial sector with firms specializing in

the production of credit services. Second, the financial sector also contains financial

intermediaries who provide interest bearing accounts for households and loanable funds to credit

producers. It is shown that monetary injections in this set-up can generate a liquidity effect

which positively influences the availability of household credit services and real activity.

Furthermore, the model predicts that monetary injections actually lower the real cost of

consumption, thus resolving a difficulty with recent liquidity effect models. The potential

quantitative importance of this monetary transmission mechanism is analyzed.

JEL Classification: E5 1, E43

Keywords: Money and credit, financial intermediation liquidity effect

I am grateful to Roberto Chang, Barry Ickes, Loretta Mester, Leonard Nakamura, Ping Wang,Steve Williamson, and workshop participants at the 1996 ASSA Meetings, the Federal ReserveBank of Atlanta, and the 1996 Summer Meetings of the Econometric Society for helpfulcomments.

I. Introduction

Themonetary transmission mechanism has received muchrecent theoretical and empirical

attention in the macroeconomic literature. While many empirical studies find that (i) there is a

negative contemporaneous correlation between monetary shocks and nominal interest rates and

(ii) money and financial services tend to be positively correlated over the business cycle,’

capturing both of these features in a general equilibrium framework has eluded conventional

business cycle approaches.2 This observation has spurred a growing literature advocating the

credit market as an important mechanism for the transmission of monetary policy [see Bernanke

(1992)J. In particular, the recent liquidity effect approaches of Lucas (1990) and Fuerst (1992)

represents a promising class of models embodying this credit view. Liquidity effect models

highlight the role of financial intermediaries in receiving cash injections from the monetary

authority and channeling loans from households to firms. Fuerst (1992) demonstrates that in such

a model with portfolio rigidities positive monetary innovations can generate a liquidity effect and

increase real activity through increasing the availability of loanable funds to business firms.

This paper evaluates the role of household credit markets in the transmission ofmonetary

policy. By doing so, it seeks to address two important deficiencies in the liquidity effect

literature. First, as noted by Christiano (1991) and Fuerst (1993), the basic liquidity effect model

‘Examples include King and Plosser (1984), Bernanke and Blinder (1992), and Christiano and

Eichenbaum (1992).

2 For example, cash-in-advance models [Stockman (1981) and Cooley and Hansen (1989)] predict

that positive shocks to the money growth rate generates a pure inflation tax effect which raisesnominal rates and depresses real output. Introducing credit goods in these models [as in Lucas andStokey (1987)] explains the money-credit correlation through this inflation tax effect. The “reverse-causation” real business cycle approach of King and Plosser (1984) captures the relationship betweeninside money and credit but provides no role for policy generated monetary shocks.

1

has counterfactual quantitative implications. In particular, the liquidity effect may be too small

to dominate the anticipated inflation effect of a serially correlated monetary shock. Secondly,

even when it dominates, consumption falls in the period ofthe shock.3 A link between monetary

policy and the availability of household credit services provides a natural mechanism by which

monetary shocks reduce the real cost of consumption. As a result, without imposing additional

restrictions on the timing of household decisions, observations (i) and (ii) can be reconciled with

a positive contemporaneous correlation between monetary shocks and consumption.

Second, this paperprovides some theoretical support to recent empirical studies suggesting

that consumer credit is an important link between monetary policy and real activity. While most

of the literature on the credit channel has focused on business borrowing, there is also

considerable evidence indicating that monetary policy has important effects on household

financing of consumption and investment goods as well. For example, Boldin (1995) uncovers

a positive correlation between mortgage financing costs and the federal funds rate; Wilcox (1989)

determines that nominal interest rates are equally important in explaining both durable and

nondurable consumption; and Duca (1995) finds a significant positive relationship between the

availability of consumer installment loans by banks and various indicators of monetary policy. ~

Intuitively, this feature stems from the assumption that consumption is a pure cash good andresponds negatively to the inflation tax effect of a monetary injection. Christiano and Eichenbaum(1995) assumes that investment decisions cannot change in the period ofthe shock to correct thisproblem. See Fuerst (1993) for a survey of the recent “liquidity effect” literature.

4Some authors have argued that an exception to these observations is the credit card market whereinterest rates tend to be sticky and above competitive rates [Ausubel (1991) and Mester (1994)]. Thismarket may not be representative of the overall household loan market. First, the high degree ofheterogeneity among borrowers creates an adverse selection problem for credit card providers.Secondly, credit card debt consists of less than ten percent of the total liabilities of the householdsector [see Park (1993), Duca (1995)].

2

The paper constructs a general equilibrium framework ofcash and household credit with

two central features. First, similar to Aiyagari and Eckstein (1994), the model incorporates an

explicit financial sector with firms which specializes in the production and selling of credit

services to households. Purchasing these credit services permits households to finance part of

their current purchases ofconsumption or capital goods with current income (instead ofrequiring

“cash-in-advance”). One of the advantages of this approach is that it does not require an a priori

distinction between “cash goods” and “credit goods” in household preferences -- this distinction

is made in the transactions technology.

Second, the banking sector consists of both a financial intermediary and producers of

credit services. The financial intermediary provides interest bearing accounts where households

deposit a portion of their cash holdings at the beginning of the period. Producers of credit

services must borrow these deposits to finance household credit purchases within the period.

Adopting the modeling strategy of Lucas (1990) and Fuerst (1992), monetary injections occur

asymmetrically through the financial sector and credit producing firms. This realistic feature of

the model is obtained by assuming that household saving decisions must be made prior to the

current realization of the monetary shock.

The results of the paper may be summarized by the following. A monetary shock that

exhibits positive serial correlation has two opposing equilibrium effects. The anticipated inflation

effect leads households to substitute out ofcash and into credit transactions, hence increasing the

demand for credit services. This increases the nominal interest rate and the relative price of

credit services to goods. As a result, overall work effort falls while there is a reallocation of

labor towards the financial sector. These results are consistent with empirical findings which

3

show that the relative size ofthe banking sector expands during hyperinflations and shrinks after

monetary stabilization.5 Because cash injections are received by credit producers, monetary

injections also create a liquidity effect which drive down nominal interest rates. In response, the

relative price of credit services to goods falls and credit producers spend the extra cash on

expanding credit services to households. Employment in both sectors respond positively to the

liquidity effect, the fraction of goods purchased with cash falls while total consumption rises.

Finally, the quantitative experiments find that there does exist plausible parameterizations ofthe

model where this liquidity effect can dominate the anticipated inflation effect.

The paper proceeds as follows. Section II will set-up the general model and characterize

the efficiency and equilibrium conditions. To analyze the liquidity and anticipated inflation

effects in this model, Section III analytically solves a special case of our general framework

where capital is inelastically supplied. Section IV then investigates some qualitative and

quantitative predictions of the general model. Finally, Section V concludes with a brief

summary.

~ See Aiyagari and Eckstein (1994) for documentation of this observations.

4

IL A Model of Household Credit

The economy is populated with infinitely lived identical households with preferences over

consumption c~and leisure. The expected lifetime utility ofthe representative household is given

by

E0E 13t{u(c~) + V(1—n~)}, (1)

where n, is work effort at time t, c, is consumption purchases at time t, 0 < < 1 is the time

discount factor, and u and v, the utility obtained from consumption and leisure, respectively, are

given by u(c) = ln(c) and V(1-n) = A(1-n) with A> Ø•6 Households purchase both consumption

and investment goods I~in the commodity market and has the option ofusing cash or credit when

purchasing either good. Similar to the definition given by Lucas and Stokey (1987), a cash

transaction must be financed with cash-in-advance while a credit transaction may be financed

with end-of-current-period income. Let g,, and g2~denote household purchases ofcash and credit

goods, respectively. The household’s total purchases of goods must thus satisfy the following

resource constraint:

g1~+ g2~ c~+ I~= + k~+1 — (1 —o)k~, (2)

where k~is the household’s stock of capital and ~ ~ (0,1) is the capital depreciation rate.

In addition to households, the economy is also populated by many producers oftwo types.

Firms in the goods producing sector (Sector 1) employ labor n,~and k,~to produce output Y~

6 The logarithmic form of preferences with separable leisure is standard in the

business cycle literature. However, it should be clear that the qualitative effects are notsensitive to more general “balanced growth” preferences of the type suggested by King,Plosser, and Rebelo (1987).

5

according to a Cobb-Douglas production technology Y, = F(k,~,n,,)= ~ where a E (0,1).

Credit producers in the financial sector (Sector 2) employ labor n2~and capital k2~to produce a

flow of credit services qt according to technology q~ Q(k2,,n2J = ~ where 4 > 0 and

y E (0,1). Since it is likely that employment is more intensive and variable than physical capital

in the provision of credit services over the business cycle, capital is supplied inelastically to the

financial sector so that k2, = k2. The purchase of a unit of credit services permits households to

finance a unit of a good with credit: g2, = q,. Finally, the financial sector also consists of

financial intermediaries who accept cash deposits from households, receives monetary injections

from the central bank, and provides loans to credit producers. These credit producers use the

borrowed funds to finance household credit purchases within the period. The money supply

process is given by

M~1= M~s+ X~= (1 +x~)Mts, (3)

where M~’is the beginning-of-period t nominal money supply per household, X~is the monetary

injection, and x~is the money growth rate between periods t and t+1.

To keep the flow of funds tractable in this model we adopt the “family” methodology of

Lucas (1990) and Fuerst (1992). That is, each representative family consists ofa worker/shopper

pair, a goods producing firm, a credit producing firm, and a financial intermediary. By lumping

all sectors ofthe economy together, monetary injections which occur through the financial sector

will be asymmetric within the family. However, since at the end of the period the family

reunites and pools their cash receipts, these monetary injections will be symmetric across

families. Given this structure, the timing ofevents within period t will proceed as follows. The

family begins the period with capital stock k~and nominal cash holdings M~and deposits D~

6

dollars into the financial intermediary. The family then separates. The state of nature s, E S is

revealed in the form of a monetary injection to the financial intermediary, X,, where S is the

compact continuous support ofthe stochastic money growth rate. The financial intermediary now

has available D~+ X~dollars to loan out. The nominal interest rate financial intermediaries

charge for loans and pay on deposits is given by R~.The worker travels to the labor market and

supplies a total of n~hours of work effort in the goods and financial sector and receives a

nominal wage payment W~.Goods and credit services are then produced with n,~,k,,, k2, and n2~.

The shopper first travels to the financial sector to rent out the capital stock k~to goods

and credit producers at a rental price of r~and to purchase a given amount of credit services q~

at price ~qt’ It is assumed that households may finance these credit services with end-of-period

income. The shopper then travels to the goods market to buy consumption and capital goods at

price ~gt where g~is financed with cash and g2~= q~with credit services. Credit producers are

obligated to finance household purchases of g2~in the goods market and a fraction ~ < 1 ofthat

quantity must be in the form of cash, To obtain that cash, credit producers borrow an amount

B~from the financial intermediary. This leads to the following cash-in-advance constraints for

shoppers and credit producers, respectively:

P~g1~ M~— (4)

aPgtQ(k~,n2t) (5)

At the end of the period the family reunites to enjoy the consumption of goods. All credit loans

(between households, credit producers, goods producers, and the financial intermediary) are

repaid and households receive rental income generated by the capital stock. The family pools

its cash receipts and enters period t+ 1. Figure 1 of the paper provides a flow diagram of the

7

activities within and at the end of the period. The end-of-period t cash holdings of the family

must thus satisfy the following budget constraint:

M~+1 = [M~+ D~R~+ r~P8/c~+ — ‘~(~c1~+ q1) — Pq~q~]+ X~(1+ R~)(6)

+{PgrF(kit~~1~)— — rtPg~kitI + [PqtQ(k2~fl2t)— W~n2~— r~P~~k2— BR~I.

The first term in brackets represents the cash receipts of the worker/shopper, the second is the

cash holdings of the financial intermediary, the third is the profits of the goods producing firm,

and fourth is the profits of the credit producer, net of loan repayments to the financial

intermediary. The family’s optimization problem thus consists of choosing a sequence {g,~,q~,

n~,k~,,D~,n,,, n2~,k1,, B,} maximizing (1) subject to (2), (4), (5), and (6).

In a stationary equilibrium all nominal variables will be growing at the same rate as the

nominal money supply. Thus, it will be convenient to introduce a stationary transformation by

scaling all nominal variables by the beginning-of-period money supply Mis. Denote m = M/MtS,

d~= D~/M~t,b, = B/MtS, w~= W/MtS, Pgt = PgtIMtS, and Pqt = Pqt/MtS. Let the transition density for

the state variable be expressed as cI(s~,ds~+,)= Prob(s~+, s~I s~= s~)for all 5i,5j E S. Denoting

primes (‘) as next period’s variables, the household’s dynamic programming problem can be

expressed as

J(m,k,s) = maxf max {u(c) + V(1—n) + ~J(m ~‘,k‘,s “)} 1 (s,ds ~‘) (7)d g

1,q,k’,n,b,n

1,n

2,k

1

subject to

g1 + 4q = c + — (1—o)k, (8)

p8g1 m —d, (9)

8

OPgQ(k2~fl2) b, (10)

/ = m+dR+rpgk+wn~~pg(g,+q) ~~pqq+x(1 +R) +p8F(k,,n,) -wn, —rp8k1 +PqQ(k2~fl2)—wn2 - rp8k2 -bR (11)1 +x

The market-clearing conditions for goods, credit services, labor, capital, financial intermediary

loans, and money are given by g, + q = F(k,,n,), q = Q(k2,n2), n = n, + n2, k = k, + k2, b = d

+ x, and m = m’ = 1. Letting 2~, and ~2 denote the Lagrange multipliers associated with cash

constraints (9) and (10), the household’s first order conditions for g,, q, k’, d, n, b, n,, n2, k,

evaluated at the market-clearing conditions, is given by

u ‘[c(k~/)] = p~(s~’)P ~ + ~~(k~ /)}~ (12)I 1+x(s~)

u ‘[c(k~’)] = p Jm(k’~~ ~gk~’) + Pq(k~’)], (13)1 +x(s I’)

u”[c(k,s,s’)] = PJk(k’,s’) (14)

fPR(k /)Jm(k ~(s,ds~ = fA1(k~’)~(s,ds’), (15)1 +x(s ~‘)

Pg(k~~ (k~~ P jm(k ~ = V’[l -n(k~’)], (16)1 +x(s ~j

J (k’,.Y)m R(k,s,s “) = X2(k,s,s”), (17)1 +x(s ~

F~(k1,n1)= o(k,s,s’) (18)

J (kcY) (19){PqQ’~~S‘)Q~(k2,n2)- ~ (k,s,s “)Pg(k~S~S~)} ~3 / = pg(k,s~/) X2(k,s,s /) aQ~(k2,n2),

1 +x(s)

9

Fk(kl,nl) = r(k,s,s”). (20)

where w(s,s’) w(s,s’)/p~(s,s’)is the real wage rate. The envelope conditions are given by

J (ky) 21= I ip in + ?~1(k,s,s “) .

J ~ 1+x(s”)

Jk(k~)= f~u‘[c(k~~](1-ô) + r(k~‘)p (k~~p ~ (s,d~~ (22)J I 1+x(s’)

Equations (21) and (12) give

= fu’~(k,~s’)}~(s,ds~. (23)j Pg(1~Y)

Equation (23) states that the marginal value of cash to the family is simply the marginal value

of next period’s consumption it will generate. The intuition behind these first order conditions

are straightforward. For example, (13) equates the marginal benefits of an additional unit of

credit services, which is the additional utility from the consumption of credit goods, with the

marginal costs of purchasing both credit services and the goods that it will buy. Equation (19)

equates the marginal value of cash obtained from employing an additional unit of labor in the

credit producing sector to the marginal cost of financing a portion c~of the additional credit

services provided to households with cash borrowed from financial intermediaries.

The crucial feature ofthe model which will produce a liquidity effect component to the

nominal interest rate is contained in (15) and (17). Substituting (17) into (15) yields J7c, ~T~(s,ds’)

= f?~2 1(s,ds’). This implies that the family equates the expected or average marginal value of

cash across the goods and credit markets. However, as in Fuerst (1992), unexpected changes in

10

the economy’s state of nature may cause cash to be more valuable in one market and the nominal

rate will be non-Fisherian. For example, if asymmetric monetary injections cause the marginal

value of cash in the goods market to be high relative to the financial market, then holding the

anticipated inflation effect constant, an unexpected monetary shock will lower R and create a

liquidity effect.

The conditions defining an equilibrium in this economy can be simplified by collapsing

the system of equations to be strictly functions ofk, n,, and d. Substitute (17) into (19) and use

(18) to obtain

= F~(k1,n~)+ oR (24)

p8 Q~(k~,n2)

All else being equal, a high relative price of credit services to goods causes a reallocation of

labor demand away from the industrial sector and towards credit producing firms. Also, quite

naturally, there will be a positive relationship between nominal rates and the relative price of

credit services. We will return to the precise nature ofthis relationship below. Also, from (13)

= u’(c)/{pg+pq}. Substituting this into (16) gives an expression for the relative

price of credit services:

Pq = u’(c)F~(k1,n1) — 1 (25)p8 A

Substituting (25) into (24) gives us an expression for the nominal interest rate:

R = u ‘(c)F~(k1,n1)- 1 - F~(k1,n1) (26)a A Q~(k2,n2)

11

Substituting (22) into (14) and using P.11~(k’,5’)~’(1~)= A!PgFn from (16) gives us an efficiency

condition for k’(k,s,s’),

p IIF(k1,n1)A

u “(c) = ~3I u ‘(c ‘)( 1 — ô) + k ~ (s ‘c~s”), (27)F~(k~,n~)

(12) and (15) obtains an efficiency condition for the choice of d(k,s):

f[1 +R} A cI’(s,ds~’)= (u ~‘(c)I(s,d~’), (28)J P/nQti,?ui) ,j Pg

and equations (23) and (16) provides an efficiency condition for n(k,s,s’):

____ = A (29)1+xj ~‘ p8F~(k1,n1)

From (9) and (10) Pg = (1-d)/g, = (d+x)/o~Q(k2,n2). Using the goods market-clearing condition,

substitute out g, and simplify to get

Q(k2,n2) {o(1 ~~+d+X}~1’fh~ (30)

Notice that equation (30) expresses the quantity of credit goods purchased g2 as a share of total

output. All else being equal, this share is increasing in x and d. It also implicitly defines n2 as

a function ofk, n~,and d. From the goods market-clearing condition, (8), and (9), g1 = F(k,,n,)

- g2, Pg = (1-d)/g1, and c = F(k,,n,) - k’ + (1-~)kare functions of k, n,, and d as well. With

these and (26), a stationary competitive equilibrium can be defined as policy functions for

{k’(k,s,s’),n, (k,s,s’),d(k,s)} satisfying (27), (28), and (29).

This also derives an “average” relationship between the price of a credit good relative to

12

the price of a cash good. The price ofpurchasing one unit of a good on credit is given by Pg +

Pq’ since one unit of credit services can purchase one credit good, and thus the relative price of

a credit good is 1 + Pq”Pg = u’(c)F~(k,,n1)/Aby (25). However, notice that on average, or if d

is chosen after observing s’, (28) implies that 1+R = u”(c)F~(k,,n,)/A. Therefore, the steady

state relative price of credit to cash goods is simply the gross nominal interest rate 1 +R.

Intuitively, this is simply saying that the household, at the optimum, equalizes the marginal cost

of using cash and credit services in transactions. However, as shall be seen below, unanticipated

shocks could cause the relative price of credit goods to deviate from the nominal rate.

Before analyzing the stochastic properties of this general model, it will be useful to first

consider a simplified version of the model where the capital stock is exogenously fixed. This

will permit us to analytically separate out the anticipated inflation and liquidity effect from a

monetary injection and analyze the channel by which it influences the household credit market

and real activity in each sector.

III. The Model with Fixed Capital Stock

In order to analytically analyze the anticipated inflation and liquidity effects from

monetary growth this section simplifies the general model above by assuming an inelastically

fixed level of aggregate capital k,~= k2~= 1 and setting ö = 0. Thus, g, and g2 = q now denotes

the consumption of cash and credit goods, respectively, and c = g1 + q; The relevant first-order

conditions for this problem are (12) - (13) and (15) - (19).

A. Some Steady State Properties

The effects of steady anticipated money growth can be clearly seen by analyzing the

13

steady state of the model. Given that s = s’ and using the efficiency conditions from the

previous section, the steady state nominal interest rate and employment in the goods and credit

sectors is given by

1+~i=1+R=1~ ~3(1—a)Pg p ‘ 1 A(1+x)

= - - a)

A - (1÷oR)n13

With these expressions the following steady state properties are immediate:

Proposition 1:

(i) ER/ax> 0, ôn,/&x < 0, 0n2/~x>0, and anlox < 0.

(ii) aq/ox> 0, a(g,+g2)/ax < 0, ag2/ax> 0.

(iii) As a —~ 1, n2,q, and g2 —* 0. A necessary condition for existence of a steady state

equilibrium with credit transactions is a < 1.

Proposition 1 (i) and (ii) captures the inflation tax effect of money growth. Similar to

standard cash-in-advance models, the inflation tax causes individuals to substitute away from

activities involving cash and into credit transactions. This increase in the demand for credit

services drives up the nominal rate and the relative price of credit services. Thus, there is a

reallocation of labor away from goods production to the production of credit services and the

total fraction of goods purchased with credit rises. Since leisure can be viewed as a costless

credit good as well, there is a reduction in the overall equilibrium work effort. As a result,

consumption and the production of goods will be strictly decreasing in the money growth rate.

14

Proposition 1 (iii) says that in the limiting case where credit producers must finance all

of the household’s credit purchases with cash (a = 1), the model degenerates to a pure cash in

advance economy where all household transactions involve cash and the credit producing sector

vanishes. Intuitively, a can be viewed as a technological or institutional parameter which

measures how more efficiently credit producers can carry out transactions relative to households.

Since the cost of borrowing to credit producers is directly proportional to this parameter, their

profit maximizing choice ofemployment decreases with a. Also, since the steady state relative

price of credit services is exactly the nominal interest rate, it will never be optimal to hire labor

and supply credit services if credit producers are equally cash constrained as households in the

goods market. We will discuss further intuition behind a in an institutional context in the

quantitative exercises of Section IV.

B. Some Properties of the Stochastic Equilibrium

To analytically extract the liquidity effect of monetary shocks from the anticipated

inflation effects, let the stochastic process governing the money growth rate be i.i.d. Thus, the

transition density may be written as 1’(s,ds’) = D(ds’). The cash-constraints in (9) and (10)

gives p6[g1 + ~q] = {d(1-a) + a + x}/a. Substituting this into (23) gives

J (s) = a ~ (dy’) = j. (31)in JId(1—a) + ~ +xJ in

Notice that since d E (0,1) is chosen before the current state s’ is realized, it can be treated as

a constant in the decision rules ofthe other variables within the period. Equation (31) states that

this feature, combined with the i.i.d. nature of the monetary shock, implies that the marginal

value of an extra dollar for the family entering the current period will be constant. This result

15

will prove extremely useful in establishing the following proposition regarding the effect of an

unanticipated monetary shock.

Proposition 2. A positive innovation to the money growth rate

(i) increases the fraction of total household consumption purchased with credit,

(ii) increases employment and output in the goods producing and credit services sectors,

(iii) decreases the relative price of credit services to consumption goods.

Proof. From equation (10) p,, = (d+x)/aQ(n2). Substituting this and (18) into equation (16) and

rearranging gives

fd + Xl.j - AoQ(n2)+ xf in - F~(n1)

Substituting (30) into the above expression yields one equation which can be solved for n, as a

function of d, ~m’and x:

= ,~, a~3fa+ x + d(1-a)~ (32)tmAo~ 1+x J

Since a + d(1-a) < 1, it is immediate that employment and output in the goods producing sector

will be strictly increasing in the monetary shock. With this, the stochastic behavior ofn2 can be

easily characterized by substituting (32) into (30) and solving for Q(n2):

~ - d + x ~ aP(o + x + d(1-o)~ (33)2 o+x+d(1—o) [~~AOI~, 1 + x

Thus, employment and output in the credit producing sector increases with the size of the

monetary shock as well. These results imply that aggregate consumption and household work

effort will respond positively to the monetary innovation. Equation (26) implies that this leads

16

to a negative relationship between a positive money shock and the relative price of credit

services. ~

The intuition behind these results can be given by the following observations. Since the

household saving decision (d) must be made prior the realization ofthe current monetary shock,

monetary injections ofcash enter the economy asymmetrically through the financial sector and

credit producing firms. This creates a liquidity premium for producers of credit services who

must finance a portion of household purchases of credit goods with cash. As a result, credit

producing firms increase their demand for labor and expand the supply of credit services to

households. This drives the relative price of credit services as well as the nominal interest rate

down. Credit services are valuable to households because it permits them to circumvent the

inflation tax effects ofholding cash between periods (given a positive steady state money growth

rate). Households respond to this increased availability of credit services by increasing work

effort, the fraction of consumption financed with credit, and total consumption. As a result,

employment and output in both sectors respond positively to the current monetary injection.

IV. Quantitative Properties of the General Model

The previous section separated out both the pure anticipated inflation and liquidity effect

of a monetary injection in the household credit model. Since money growth rates consistent with

U.S. time series exhibit positive serial correlation both of these effects will be present. This

section investigates the cyclical properties of our general model and evaluates at some

quantitative level the importance of household credit markets in generating a dominant liquidity

effect. The model is solved using a linear-quadratic (L-Q) approximation technique that involves

17

linearizing Euler equations (27), (28), and (29) with a Taylor-series approximation about the

steady state. A method of undetermined coefficients is then used to solve for decision rules

which are linear in the model’s state variables. The money growth rate in the model will be

assumed to follow a stationary AR(1) process:

= (1 — p)x* + px~+ ~, (34)

where x~is the steady state value for x,, p < 1, and ~ is a white noise disturbance with zero

mean and constant variance.

Consistent with previous real business cycle studies [e.g., Cooley and Hansen (1989)] we

set a = 0.36, ~ = 0.99, and S = 0.025. The value of A = 2.55 is chosen to give a steady state

hours worked of 1/3. Aiyagari and Eckstein (1994) uses estimates ofthe production function for

credit services which finds y = 0.35. The money supply process parameters are set as x* = 0.016

and p = 0.32 based on Christiano (1991).~However, it is not immediately obvious how to select

an appropriate values for a. Recall that a measures the fraction of household credit purchases

that credit producers must finance with cash. Since in equilibrium a = (d+x)/p6g2, one possible

empirical counterpart to this is the ratio ofthe quantity ofcash deposited into the financial sector

to bank loans. Thus, a rough estimate for a may be inferred by looking at the ratio of total

reserves to demand deposits. This gives us a benchmark value of a = 0.15 and a starting point

7This figure, used as the benchmark parameters for Christiano (1990) and Fuerst (1993), is based

upon estimated money growth models for the post-1970 sub-sample

18

about which to conduct our sensitivity analysis.8 Finally ~ and k2 are set to 41.6 and 0.12,

respectively, so that the steady state value of pqQ/(pgY+pqQ) is 0.89%, the approximate value

added share of the U.S. household banking sector.9

Impulse response plots to a one time, one percent positive monetary shock for the cash-in-

advance (CIA) case, where d is chosen after x~is observed, as well as our household credit (HC)

model are presented in Figures 2A through 21. The shock occurs in period 10 and the vertical

axis for real variables measures percent deviations from steady state. Figure 2B shows that

employment in the credit producing sector increases for both models. This is since the

anticipated inflation effect increases household credit demand while the liquidity effect works to

increase the availability ofhousehold credit. Hence, the equilibrium quantity of credit services

in Figure 2D increases for both models.

However, the models have exactly the opposite predictions for the cyclical behavior of

employment in the goods producing sector, aggregate employment, consumption, investment, and

the nominal interest rate. Although money and credit services are positively related in CIA they

are also countercyclical. The anticipated inflation effect in CIA depresses employment and real

activity in the goods producing sector and raises the nominal interest rate. To the contrary, the

benchmark HC model displays a dominant liquidity effect where the nominal interest rate in

Figure 2G falls in the period ofthe shock. The expansion ofhousehold credit services increases

8 Source: Federal Reserve Bulletin, 1995. Alternative measures include the ratio of reserves to

consumer loans and reserves to transactions deposits (10 percent and 7.5 percent in 1996, respectively).Thus, a = 0.15 seems like a reasonable and “conservative” choice.

9The value added share of the banking sector [excluding insurance agents and services] is 2.7% ofGDP [see Diaz-Gimenez et.al. (1992)]. Actual household financial activity accounts for roughly 1/3 ofthis measure.

19

hours worked in both sectors as well as aggregate employment and investment and this leads to

a short-term boom in the industrial sector (Figures 2A, 2B, 2C, and 2F). Furthermore,

consumption in Figure 2E now rises in the period of the shock as well. Unlike the typical

liquidity effect model, the monetary injection is actually able to mitigate the inflation tax effect

by lowering the real cost of consumption through the availability of credit services.

Finally, Figures 2H and 21 compare the responses of the nominal rate (Ri) and relative

price of credit services (PR,) across CIA and HC models. Since the monetary shock is

anticipated when portfolio decisions are made, CIA predicts that both coincide and rise in the

period of the shock. Interestingly enough, while both falls in HC, the volatility of the nominal

rate exceeds that of the relative price of credit services. Intuitively, the monetary shock

unexpectedly increases the marginal value of cash in the goods market relative to the financial

market, making the opportunity cost of using cash, or the nominal rate, lower than that ofusing

credit services at the margin. This feature ofthe model may also help to explain the observation,

by some, that the cost of consumer borrowing tends to be “sticky” and less volatile than the

nominal interest rate.

To test the sensitivity ofthe size ofthe liquidity effect in the HC model to changes in the

fraction ofhousehold credit purchases which credit producers must finance with cash, alternative

values of a are considered. In addition to the our benchmark value, we consider higher values

of a = 0.25 and 0.30. Corresponding to each value of a we also choose an alternate value for

4’ so that the model’s steady state remains consistent with a 0.89 percent value added share ofthe

household credit sector. Figures 3A through 3G compares the impulse responses from these

cases to that of the benchmark model. These plots clearly show that the size of the liquidity

20

effect is strictly decreasing in the size of a. Otherwise, the behavior of hours worked,

consumption, investment, and credit services look similar to the patterns in Figure 2.

To understand the reasoning behind this result, consider the cash constraint on credit

producers given by (10). In equilibrium this constraint becomes pgq = (d+x)/a. Intuitively, 1/a

can be interpreted as a measure of how efficiently credit producers carry out transactions for

households. At a = 1 credit producers and households are equally cash constrained and hence

credit producers will have no incentive to supply credit services. Such a model degenerates to

a basic cash-in-advance model where all household transactions will involve cash. All else being

equal, (1/a) > 1 generates a “multiplier effect” by which a monetary injection expands the

availability of nominal credit services to households and hence the size of the liquidity effect.

Thus, as a falls the liquidity effect will begin to dominate the anticipated inflation effect. Notice

that this intuition also makes sense given our institutional interpretation of a. If we view it as

the total fraction of required and excess reserves in the banking system, it is reasonable to think

that the quantity of credit available in response to a monetary injection would be decreasing in

this ratio (with no credit services available in the extreme case of a = 100%).

V. Concluding Remarks

This paper has explored the role ofhousehold credit markets in explaining the observed

positive and procyclical relationship between money and credit services over the business cycle.

Monetary injections through financial intermediaries and credit producers were shown to generate

a liquidity effect by which real activity is influenced through an expansion of household credit

services. Our quantitative results also suggests that there does exist reasonable parameter values

21

where this effect may dominate the anticipated inflation effects of monetary growth.

Furthermore, the model is able to resolve one important difficulty with the basic Lucas-Fuerst

liquidity effect model. Because monetary injections increase the availability ofhousehold credit

services it is actually able to circumvent the inflation tax effect on consumption. Thus,

consumption responds positively to the monetary shock as well.

These results also provide a nice complement to recent liquidity effect models

emphasizing business credit as an important element in explaining the procyclical behavior of

money and the business cycle. However, similar to these models, our set-up also lacks a

persistent liquidity effect which is evident in U.S. time series. There are two possibilities to

pursue with this issue. First, one could add rigidities which prevent the immediate adjustment

ofhousehold funds in the periods following an unexpected monetary shock. Second, and perhaps

more interesting, is to explicitly analyze the behavior of consumer durable spending in this

model. This may not only contribute to the persistence issue but also help explain another

important empirical regularity. Over a typical business cycle household investment is procyclical

and leads the cycle while business investment lags the cycle. From causal observation, a

majority of consumer durables and residential investment is financed with credit as opposed to

cash. Thus, our household credit framework may be able to provide a monetary explanation of

this phenomena.

22

References

Aiyagari, S. Rao and Zvi Eckstein (1994). “Interpreting Monetary Stabilization in a Growth

Model with Credit Goods Production.” Working Paper 525, Federal Reserve Bank of

Minneapolis.

Ausubel, Lawrence (1991). “The Failure of Competition in the Credit Card Market.” American

Economic Review 81: 50-81.

Bernanke, Benjamin (1992). “Credit in the Macroeconomy.” Federal Reserve Bank ofNew York

Quarterly Review, Spring.

Bernanke, Benjamin and Alan Blinder (1992). “The Federal Funds Rate and the Channels of

Monetary Transmission.” American Economic Review 82: 901-21.

Boldin, Michael (1994). “Econometric Analysis of the Recent Downturn in Housing: Was it a

Credit Crunch?,” mimeo, Federal Reserve Bank ofNew York.

Christiano, Lawrence J. (1991). “Modeling the Liquidity Effect of a Money Shock.” Federal

Reserve Bank ofMinneapolis Quarterly Review, Winter.

Christiano, Lawrence J. and Martin Eichenbaum (1992). “Liquidity Effects and the Monetary

Transmission Mechanism.” American Economic Review 82: 346-53.

Christiano, Lawrence J. and Martin Eichenbaum (1995). “Liquidity Effects, Monetary Policy,

and the Business Cycle.” Forthcoming in Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking.

Cooley, Thomas F. and Gary D. Hansen (1989). “The Inflation Tax in a Real Business Cycle

Model.” American Economic Review 79: 733-48.

Cooley, Thomas F. and Gary D. Hansen (1991). “The Welfare Cost of Moderate Inflations.”

Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking 23: 483-503.

Diaz-Gimenez, Javier, Edward Prescott, Terry Fitzgerald, and Fernando Alvarez (1992).

“Banking in Computable General Equilibrium Economies.” Journal of Economic

Dynamics and Control 16: 533-559.

Duca, John (1995). “Credit Availability, Bank Consumer Lending, and Consumer Durables.”

Working Paper 95-14, Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas.

Fuerst, Timothy S. (1992). “Liquidity, Loadable Funds, and Real Activity.” Journal of

Monetary Economics 29: 3-24.

23

Fuerst, Timothy 5. (1993). “Liquidity Effect Models and their Implications for Monetary

Policy.” Working Paper, Northwestern University.

King, Robert G. and Charles Plosser (1984). “Money, Credit, and Prices in a Real Business

Cycle Model.” American Economic Review 74: 363-380.

King, Robert G., Charles Plosser, and Sergio Rebelo (1987). “Production, Growth, and Cycles:

Technical Appendix.” Manuscript, University of Rochester.

Lucas, Robert E. Jr. and Nancy L. Stokey (1987). “Money and Interest in a Cash-in-Advance

Economy.” Econometrica 55: 491-513.

Lucas, Robert E. Jr. (1990). “Liquidity and Interest Rates.” Journal of Economic Theory 50:

237-264.

Mester, Loretta J. (1994). “Why are Credit Card Rates Sticky?” Economic Theory 4: 505-530.

Park, Sangkyun (1993). “The Determinants ofConsumer Installment Credit.” Economic Review,

The Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis (November): 23-38.

Stockman, Alan C. (1981). “Anticipated Inflation and the Capital Stock in a Cash-in-Advance

Economy.” Journal of Monetary Economics 8 (November): 387-93.

Wilcox, James (1990). “Nominal Interest Rate Effects on Real Consumer Expenditure.”

Business Economics (October): 31-37.

24

Figure 2A: Employment in Goods Producing Sector0.0084

0.0072

0.0060

0.0048

0.0036

0.0024

0.0012

0.0000

-0.00 1210

Figure 2B: Employment in Credit Producing Sector0.0320

0.0280

0.0240

0.0200

0.0 160

0.0120

0.0080

0.0040

0.0000

-0.0040

0.0084

0.0072

0.0060

0.0048

0.0036

0.0024

0.0012

0.0000

-0.00 12

0.0200

0.0175

0.0150

0.012S

0.0100

0.007S

0.0OS0

0.002S

0.0000

-0.0026

Figure 2C: Aggregate Employment

Figure 2D: Credit Services

3 17 24 3 10 17 24

3 10 17 24 3 10 17 24

.~LiR~ I

(I) ~

Ftr~ANc~AL

t~re~c~,-1E~oI4R~(~‘2~ +~

—3

(.1) E~ -c~- ~

~JA~ttAL~ t-~L_~] < —i-- tt~rE~He~rAw~(

ftc~oL~uEc J

Icr2e-~tr I

~fRL~

I

~ft ~ ~7-+

NA4 —

I—l

(.~

Figure 2E: Consumption Figure 2G: Nominal Interest Rate0.00030

0.00026

0.00020

0.000 15

0.000 10

0.00006

0.00000

-0.00005

0.0270

0.0240

0.0210

0.0 180

0.0160

0.0 120

0.0090

0.0060

0.00303 10 17 24

Figure 2F: Investment

2 9 16 23

0.0200

0.0175

0.0 150

0.0 126

0.0100

0.0076

0.0050

0.0026

0.0000

-0.00263 10 17 24

Figure 2H:0.02660

0.02646

0.02640

0.02636

0.02630

0.02626

Nominal Rate and Relative Price of Credit - CIA

Figure 21:0.0270

0.0240

0.0210

0.0180

0.0 150

0.0120

0.0090

0.0060

0.0030

3 10 17 24

Nominal Rate and Relative Price of Credit - HC

2 9 16 23

sigma ~0.1S

sigma ~O.2S

sigma ~O.3S

0.0200

0.0176

0.0 150

0.0 125

0.0100

0.0076

0.0060

0.0026

0.0000

-0.0025

Employment in Goods Producing Sector

it

‘II I1kt

0.0084

0.0072

0.0060

0.0048

0.0036

0.0024

0.00 12

0.0000

-0.00 12

Figure 3C: Aggregate Employment

sigma 0.15

sigma ~O.2S

sigma ~O.35

I~’I

‘Iv

I’

Figure 3A:0.0084

0.0072

0.0060-

0.0048

0.0036

0.0024

0.0012 -

0.0000 *

-0.0012

Figure 3B:0.0320

0.0280

0.0240

0.0200-

0.0160-

0.0 120

0.0080

0.0040

0.0000

-0.0040 -

— I III II I Ill II Ill II

3 10 17 24 3 10 17 24

Employment in Credit Producing Sector

sigma~O.1S —

sigma 0.25 — —

~II’“I

I! I

‘I

sigma 0.35 — —

-- ~-

Figure 3D: Credit Services

sigma 0.15

sigma 0.25

sigma 0.36

I’

Ii’~‘I~

I! ~I

3 10 17 24 3 10 17 24

Figure 3E: Consumption0.0270

0.0240

0.0210

0.0180

0.0 150

0.0 120

0.0090

0.0060

0.0030

Figure 3G: Nominal Interest Rate

0.0200

0.0175

0.0150

0.0125

0.0 100

0.0075

0.0050

0.0025

0.0000

-0.0026

Figure 3F: Investment

sigma 0.16

sigma 0.26

sigma 0.3S

I’

I~II, \%

I’

0.000300

0.000260

0.000200

0.000 150

0.000100

0.000060

0.000000

-0.0000503 11 19 27 2 9 16 23

3 10 17 24