human capital, its implication en informal trading

41
Human Capital: its implication in informal trading Isabel Pereira Pizani

Upload: cedice-libertad-ac

Post on 01-Apr-2016

218 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

DESCRIPTION

Isabel Pereira Cedice Libertad

TRANSCRIPT

Human Capital: its implication in informal trading

Isabel Pereira Pizani

1

Abstract

The men and women who occupy public places earning a living in street trading are victims of a double exclusion: on the first front, as a consequence of the statist- rentier-distributive nature of the Venezuelan State and of the attempt to impose a collectivist model in the place of the market and private property -both with strong anti-job-generating traits reflected in the game rules governing the incorporation of Venezuelans into the labor market-, a situation that has resulted in informal work becoming a structural feature of the Venezuelan labor market; and on the second, this differentiating exclusion occurs as a result of the nonparticipation of informals in the building of the knowledge society, a key factor for generating wealth, for innovation, and for adding value as the fruit of the transforming power of human capital. Key words: Statism, distributive society, human capital, knowledge society, informal workers, contributions and benefits

2

Introduction Since Adam Smith postulated labor as the source generating all wealth in 1776, little

progress has been made, in relative terms, in managing to convert it into the axis of

mankind’s progress. “The annual labour of every nation is the fund which originally

supplies it with all the necessaries and conveniences of life which it annually consumes,

and which consist always either in the immediate produce of that labour, or in what is

purchased with that produce from other nations. (…) It is the great multiplication of the

productions of all the different arts, in consequence of the division of labour, which

occasions, in a well-governed society, that universal opulence which extends itself to the

lowest ranks of the people.”1

It is not too farfetched to say that much more has been invested in finding ways to

supplant labor than in expanding and consolidating spheres of freedom that would permit

the creativity of the worker to become the guide and mainstay of the creation of wealth. It

was not until half way through the 20th century that some researchers, among them Gary

Becker and Amartya Sen, began more definitive research into the importance of the

relationship between productivity, labor and the possibility of achieving better standards of

living for mankind. This change in direction in thinking was the starting point of an

unceasing search for the link between labor, wealth and standard of living.

This short paper responds to this need to understand what participating in the labor

market as informals means for workers and the opportunities this offers them. By

“informals” we mean workers whose work is based on game rules that are different from

and often diametrically opposed to those of the rest of society, i.e. the formal sector that is

accounted for and legally constituted.

In the specific case of Venezuela, it is important to note that informality occurs at

the heart of a society whose defining trait is that it is a rentier-oil country: “The State is the

owner of the revenues it charges and collects from the world market independently of the

domestic economy or, what comes to the same thing, of the economic life of the society

under its aegis,”2 a circumstance that sets limits on the labor market and puts informal

workers in a situation of dual exclusion: exclusion derived from this rentier state having to

do with the scant generation of job opportunities and, secondly, the intrinsic separation

that engaging in a productive activity on the informal side of the tracks confers. The

combination of both factors results in an informal sector that carries most weight within the

1 Smith (1776), u, pages 27 and 41.

2 Baptista (2004) b, page 33.

3

labor market, numerically speaking, but offers its members scant possibilities of rising

above that situation or consolidating those aspects of their line of work that could become

viable.

This paper takes a look at the possibilities of expanding human capital as a result

of combining real job opportunities in the formal sector and options for development and

consolidation derived from engaging in informal economic activity, this being the main

occupation of the majority of Venezuelan workers.

The first part of the paper presents the basic concepts relating to rentierism, as a

basis for understanding the general economic dynamic as a determining factor in the labor

market structure and an effective cause of informality. It suggests the importance of the

absence of links between of the processes of salarization, productivity and salary as

essential elements of the labor dynamic. The second part, based on a field study

conducted on the streets of Caracas by CEDICE LIBERTAD’s Public Policy Analysis Unit

and a comparative analysis of the findings, puts forward the following hypotheses: a)

Informal economic activity is not one engaged in by choice; and b) the level of education of

the population in the economically active age group has little impact on their incorporation

into the labor market. Both hypotheses clearly show us how decisively general economic

conditions affect the possible options open to the informal worker.

Finally, a number of conclusions are presented as a point of departure for further

research together with proposed general guidelines for defining public policies and other

measures that local and central government could adopt immediately.

1. Basic Concepts

The labor market can be defined as an area of human relations that clearly

expresses the way in which a society is made up: the type of prevailing economic

development, game rules, current social conventions, the rates of productivity derived from

efforts in the field of knowledge-technology, and the level of education of the working

population, to name just a few of an infinite number of variables.

We live in salaried work societies that hinge on two principles, relative security for

all those taking part in the economic process derived from game rules adopted by common

accord, and the calculability of costs, expectations and risks over the long term. Salaried

work is, moreover, the base of the Welfare State and Social Security. Only when societies

4

achieve near full employment can the economically active generations finance the older

ones.

Salaried work is also a guarantee of democracy. A worker is a citizen whose

existence depends on his participation in a market with pre-established game rules and

who, in his daily life, actively ensures that those rules are improved. This worker-citizen is,

therefore, the bearer of a given order of things, of a project that is translated into his own

biography.

The special feature of this research paper on human capital and informality stems

from its own proposal; it has to do with determining the limits and restrictions on expansion

for those individuals who have salaried status, but in a sense that runs counter to the given

order of things and the rules that this society establishes as constituent elements, i.e.

established game rules that are formally recognized by society (labor laws, property laws,

among others).

An informal worker is defined as being someone who forms part of an income

generation process not regulated by society’s institutions in the same way as other similar

activities are regulated socially and legally.3

This research paper extrapolates the Richard Barret’s idea regarding efficient

organizations to the concept of human capital, understood not merely as a seeking of

efficiency and productivity, but as those individuals who, because of their training and

personal qualities, are capable of forming part of “visionary organizations that find a

dynamic equilibrium between the needs of survival and growth, the meeting of their

personal needs, economic sustainability, and being socially and environmentally

responsible with their community and society in general”.4

Now then, the Venezuelan labor market, like any other, is in fact a variable that

depends on the general development option adopted by this society. In capitalism, labor

markets clearly express the margins allowed for and restrictions on the economic freedom

to invest and, in doing so, to drive the development of the productivity and salarization of

the population or, put another way, of opportunities for incorporating workers into

relationships of formal wage dependency and prospects of salaries understood as “current

schemes of remuneration, benefit or advantage, whatever their denomination or method of

3 Portes, Castells and Benton (1989), q, page 34.

4 Barret (2001), d, page 33.

5

calculation, provided they can be given a cash value and are due to the worker for the

provision of his service.”5

In market economies, salarization, productivity and the salary are elements bound

together in a close relationship, where a variation in one triggers immediate reactions in

the others. In societies of a socialist-statist bent, the existence of labor markets is

debatable. They will always be the result of the discretionary expressions of those who

direct or plan the economy. The incorporation of men into the labor market or salarization,

the level of productivity, innovation, technological development and salary levels will be

variables that are independent of one another, responding, fundamentally, to the political

decisions of those who control the State apparatus and set the objectives of central

government planning.

However, in the specific case of Venezuela, taken as a country of a capitalist

persuasion, we see that the labor market responds to a socialist-type model, given the

superimposition of the weight of the State, endowed with a nature that is intrinsically that of

a proprietor, possessor of the ownership and control of the main sources of production of

wealth and whose main revenues come from the sale of oil on the international market.

This series of factors determines the specific nature of the Venezuelan labor

market, where the weight of the State has the capacity to generate, destroy or simply not

create jobs, replacing them with any other means of subsidizing of or transference to

sectors of the population of job age in this market.

The Venezuelan labor market, rather than expressing healthy competition between

individuals and reflecting our levels of productivity, is a sphere where the effects of the

redistribution policies decided upon or adopted by the proprietor-State at any given

moment or in a specific set of circumstances materialize.

Addressing the issue of the possibilities for and restrictions on the development of

human capital involves, first of all, a comprehensive empirical view of how the labor market

has been formed in its relationship of dependence on the general economic model

prevailing in this society. A second approximation reveals informality as one of the forms of

specific participation in the labor market, as opposed to the formal sector, that is the sector

covered or governed by the framework legally established by society.

Determining the possibilities of and restrictions on the human capital of the informal

worker remits us, then, in the first place to the significance of the proprietor-rentier model

of the economy in the Venezuelan labor market.

5 Ley Orgánica del Trabajo (1997), p, page 34.

6

2. The rentier, proprietor, redistributive State

The economic theses put forward as a proposal for Venezuela during the second

half of the 20th century emerged in a context where there was a need to shake off any

remnants of the dictatorships and militarism that had existed for nearly 60 years and the

autocratic way of managing and understanding the economy and politics. Up until then, the

main beneficiaries of setting up the oil industry in Venezuela had been the military

dictators and their cronies. The need to break with that atavism reinforced the proposal of

the new ideologues regarding the necessity of putting all the economic power in the hands

of the State. “Not a single oil concession for private individuals”6 was the manifesto and

objective of the new leaders, who, in their understandable settling of scores with the old

tyrannies, scorning half measures, lumped together all private individuals with the former

beneficiaries of the military dictatorships. Thus Venezuelans were stripped of any

possibility of making a comeback, this time as the creators of wealth, and a first

expropriation was perpetrated, that of participating in the industry that generates practically

all the country’s wealth, the oil industry, a circumstance that we will call here “the

confiscation of comparative advantages.” 7

As a result of this circumstance, investment in Venezuela in highly profitable

sectors or sectors where there are static and dynamic comparative advantages is

restricted by the presence of institutions that give precedence to public investment over

private investment. This includes the energy sector in general (hydrocarbons, electricity,

etc.), mining and tourism, all examples of areas of economic activity where the decisions

to invest and redirect resources and productive factors are restricted by a supply of

property rights controlled by the State on the basis of formal rules that it shapes to suit the

political interests of the day.

The supply of property rights relating to investment in sectors with the biggest

competitive advantages is the outcome of a legal scheme of things that is based on the

coercive capacity of the political power held by the State. This institutional dynamic,

consolidated ideologically, imposes transaction costs that make private investment in

those sectors prohibitive. In this way, the productivity potential and the country’s potential

6 Betancourt (1978 ), g, page 33.

7 Pereira y Zanoni (2004), o, page 33.

7

are affected, because of the existence of “institutionalized” state monopolies that restrict

competition, lessen the possibilities of adding value to our economy and, basically, turn the

majority of workers into passive individuals in dealings with the State.

The political consensuses reached in each government express these limitations

on investing, which are only made more flexible, in practice, in response to the need to

generate fiscal revenues. The State “grants quotas” or it cedes limited property rights to

investors only to the point where it gains in terms of power thanks to increased fiscal

revenues, which it can distribute. Workers and their families lose the opportunity of having

decent jobs and achieving better standards of living as a result of their merits and efforts.

The proprietor-State is not interested in generating value but in obtaining fiscal

revenues that will guarantee political power. In the case of the Venezuelan economy, this

characteristic, which is frequently got around, defines the structure of the real sector of the

economy and determines macroeconomic options for achieving growth and well-being. An

economy whose productive apparatus is dichotomized into profitable economic activities

(appropriated by the State) and economic activities having scant capacity for generating

value engaged in by the rest of society can only generate a labor market with profound

restrictions.

In contrast, the perennial proposal to grow based on the development of the private

non-oil economy, to diversify building on the growth of sectors where transaction costs are

very high and profitability doubtful has turned attempts to industrialize Venezuela into a

kind of bottomless pit that swallows up vast sums of fiscal resources. And it could hardly

be otherwise, when the State reserves to itself the economic activities having comparative

advantages, redistributes fiscal revenues to sectors with low profitability and inhibits

competition in a scheme of inward growth. This situation explains the problem that is

restricting the country’s possibilities of growth: on the one hand, the infinite and

insurmountable transaction costs involved in establishing private investments in profitable

sectors and, on the other, a very high “Venezuela Cost”8 for achieving growth in sectors

with scant comparative advantages.

This is the distorted situation facing Venezuela’s economic growth and social

development: the impossibility of achieving growth in the sectors with the biggest

advantages, on the one hand, and, on the other, the use of the resources generated by the

profitable state-owned companies to “subsidize” sectors with scant or zero profitability.

8 Penfold (2002), m, page 33.

8

2.1. Political Expropriation

This insistence on doing away with the participation of private individuals in the oil

business, a kind of anti-caudillo backlash, could have been a passing phenomenon while

the aftermath of years of dictatorship dissipated. Unfortunately for us, however, it served

as the basis for another and perhaps worse transformation. Although the production of

wealth was no longer in the hands of private individuals, it was now in the hands of the

State, converted, inexorably, into the recipient and owner of undreamed-of revenues and

wealth. The creation of mechanisms of mediation between this omnipotent public

machinery and the citizenry became a necessity, particularly given the aspirations of

founding a democracy that was inspiring the leaders emerging in the country at that time.

In 1945, the proposal was for a society that disowned the economic citizen, but

established the party man as the interlocutor of the State, a newly created monster. Since

then, people’s standing as citizens has been linked to their membership of mass

organizations. The political and cultural consequences of this belligerence on the part of

the political parties are very profound, given that the transfer of responsibility is an attribute

of the political organization. In point of fact, this organization is now more responsible than

the individual. Henceforth, the sense of individual responsibility was to be conceived of as

being directly tied to obedience to the party and, indirectly, as responding to the inexorable

and transcendent course of history as a social process. So it is that the party has become

the principal interlocutor of the State in the place of citizen participation.

This mediation by the political parties between the citizen and society

consummated the second and, perhaps, most terrible confiscation, that of a person’s

status as a citizen. The pacts between the parties were to be the fundamental point of

political consensus in the relations between the State and society and in the social plurality

required by democratic regimes. Henceforth, citizens would not be distinguished on the

grounds of merit or civic ethics, but for their loyalty and responsibility to the party. Party

membership was to become the most valuable means of identification that would establish

the difference between one Venezuelan and the next. The strength of governments would

be associated with the consistency and allegiances derived from agreements expressing a

new form of tutelage or control, this time plural, clearly replacing the possibility of building

a society of citizens. This particular trait assumed by the Democratic State in its early days

is what the researcher Luís J. Oropeza describes in the Gendarme Innecesario as being a

9

system’s source of legitimacy where control, order and possibilities are still not in the

hands of the citizens.

These two major expropriations are at the base of the State that has been built in

Venezuela since 1958. These expropriations are defined as a combination of the

confiscation of the citizenry by political parties, the establishment of pacts that were to

guarantee plural tutelage, and the alienation of economic freedoms and, with them, the

possibility of developing our comparative advantages as a country. Both confiscations, the

political and the economic, were to become the foundations of the Proprietor-Redistributive

State, the political mainstay of the democratic trials of the second part of the 20th century

and the attempts to establish a completely socialist regime in the 21st.

2.2. The impact of the “confiscation of comparative advantages”

The process of expropriation of comparative advantages, endorsed by powerful

pacts among the political parties, is the platform that bestows on Venezuela the nature of

rentier society or economy. The main revenue of the country’s economy depends on the

price of oil imposed by the world market; it is “income not created by the country,” that is to

say income for which there is no entry of labor and capital on the other side of the balance

sheet. In this sense, it is income without a balancing entry in terms of production… “The

State is the owner of revenues it charges and collects from the world market outside the

domestic economy, or put another way, apart from the economic life of the society under

its aegis.” 9

The appropriation of the oil industry by the State, which gives rise to the

expropriation of comparative advantages as a means of sustaining the rentier economy, is

a determining factor in Venezuela’s economic and social future, given its direct effects on

the basic structure of the labor market and because of its social repercussions in terms of

the depreciation of human capital as the engine of economic development.

The structure of the Venezuelan economy and, in particular, its labor market, is an

expression of the ideological-political visions that have prevailed in the management of the

country, a situation that is reflected in the different degrees of fragmentation that

characterize the labor market as an overall structure. By fragmentation of the labor market

we mean the coexistence within it of segments differentiated on the basis of specific

economic logics.

9 Baptista (2004), b, page 33.

10

This nature of the structure of employment in Venezuela is apparent when we

observe the overwhelming presence of informal workers, both in terms of physical space

and over time, as a category that is more numerous than public and private sector

employment combined. This means that the majority of Venezuelan workers are not

protected by the legal and regulatory framework that covers the formal worker, and which

gives rise to a series of basic contributions and benefits aimed at ensuring their welfare as

individuals and as a group. The most obvious conclusion is that two logics of workers’

material reproduction coexist in the labor market, with the informal strategy

predominating.

Understanding this fragmented nature of the labor market allows us to appreciate

more fully the behavior and reactions of variables such as the level of employment,

unemployment, informality, the types and quality of jobs, wages and income and, most

important, it allows us to approach poverty as a phenomenon that results from the dynamic

interrelating of these variables. On this point, it is worth formulating some preliminary

considerations to be used as a working hypothesis, which are derived from the premise of

revenue being used as a mechanism of distribution and not as capital for generating new

wealth and opportunities; in other words, taking into account not the usufruct of the

revenue but the fact that this revenue does not imply any major domestic productive effort.

a. The fragmentation of the labor market is a phenomenon generated autonomously.

It has no preconceived form. It is the product of the interrelating of the economic,

political and legal game rules under which it falls and which constitute its quasi-

material means of support.

b. If we accept this premise, the second has to do with identifying the game rules that

determine the Venezuelan economy and, therefore, the labor market: public

ownership of the profitable sectors of the economy, political-legal restrictions on the

participation or intervention of private investment in the development of these

sectors, and the proprietor-rentier nature of the State. This public control of the

lion’s share of the economy supports the imposition of a state agent with a political

rationality that seeks power, crushing and squeezing out the economic rationality

that should prevail in the wealth generation process and, with it, the creation of

productive jobs as the substratum for incorporating Venezuelans into opportunities

for human, physical and material development.

c. Based on the foregoing, it is possible to reach an approximation to a preliminary

conclusion: the goals and objectives of the Venezuelan economy are not geared

11

primarily to the creation of wealth. Given the prevalence of the political interest over

the economic, the purposes of the economy are tied to the generation of fiscal

revenues in order to sustain the political power structure. This explains the

historical difficulties Venezuela faces when it comes to adopting an appropriate

path for developing the economy other than the one deriving from the distribution of

revenues.

d. Control of the economy by the public sector based on ownership of the industries

that are most profitable, extremely capital intensive and generate few jobs, added

to the scant political interest in developing or opening up areas of investment

downstream in these industries that would permit the involvement of sectors other

than public capital, limits or restricts the capacity for generating jobs in the

domestic economy. If the dominant rationality is not the creation of wealth and, if

the basic economic activity is a poor job-generator, then the formal labor market in

Venezuela will be very restricted insofar as its capacity for expanding employment

is concerned, as it has always been.

e. Domestic private investors are relegated to sectors with low profitability compared

to the economic potential of the country. As this is the only way of sustaining these

private activities, the State maintains a structure that subsidizes private economic

activity either directly or indirectly. The private sector emerges in the shadow of the

State. This is the closing move in a perverse game played out within Venezuela’s

institutional framework: the political-legal framework turns the State into the

economy’s employer, denies the rest of society the right to invest where it can

obtain a return, but, at the same time and out of the need to maintain itself in

power, shares these resources out among the population and subsidizes

unprofitable activities that reduce the impact of unemployment and poverty. This

process explains the confiscation of the comparative advantages as a basic

malaise of the Venezuelan economy, a confiscation that explains the Venezuelan

economy’s scant capacity for generating jobs and the high cost of producing them

for sectors with low profitability. The paradox is that, when the majority of these

private incursions into the economy produce poor results, the private sector is

blamed for its low level of profitability and for wasting public funds.

f. The demand for productive jobs is not a priority, and the growth of employment is

discretionary depending on the volume of revenues obtained by the State. When

there is an abundance of resources, owing to rising international oil prices, the

12

State, as a form of indirect subsidy, permits itself to finance more jobs in the public

sector with no regard for their productivity and transfers resources to private

undertakings with small chance of success. When oil prices fall, the margin the

State has for implementing these mechanisms for generating employment shrinks

or disappears. The notion of labor is not strictly associated with the generation of

added value, and a considerable number of surplus unproductive jobs are

generated within the public sector. This is what causes the deep crises and

Venezuelans’ scant ability to weather the storms resulting from a reduction in

public funds.

g. The qualification of the labor force is not a determining factor for its entry into the

labor market, except in the modern, highly technified sectors. This manifest

incapacity of the Venezuelan productive apparatus, added to the high cost of doing

business for the private sector, forces the majority of Venezuelans to develop

strategies for generating income outside the formal economy, engaging in activities

that do not contribute, on a large scale, to the gross domestic product. This is a

situation that does not worry the governments, as long as the revenues from the

state-owned companies are sufficient to meet their fiscal requirements. In point of

fact, the informal economy is left practically undisturbed by the authorities, even

when it becomes a nuisance, takes over public places and contributes to their

deterioration or poses a threat to public health.

h. The absence of productive activity is financed by the State through social spending

(missions or social programs, subsidies, handouts), which, in turn, is fed by oil

revenues. There is a trade-off between salaries and social spending to ensure

peace in the country. Rather than use fiscal revenues to protect the highly

vulnerable sectors, they are allocated to disguise the structural lack of jobs and

salaries facing the population in the economically active age group.

i. Rentierism and the expropriation of comparative advantages produce a separation

between fundamental categories at the very base of the labor market: salarization

is not driven by the dynamics of the economy or the need to ensure greater yield

on investments. To the same extent, the growth of salaries does not operate as a

process that is closely linked to increases in productivity. This relation between

salarization, productivity and salaries in the Venezuelan rentier economy is not,

therefore, a determining factor in the size, composition and structure of the labor

market.

13

j. The extension of salary relations is extremely limited, a situation that is translated

directly into informality as a consequence of the tremendous difficulty of obtaining

access to a real income that is the product of work, of being cut off from the formal

economy, and of poor access to systems of contributions and benefits that back up

the worker’s well-being and social stability.

k. This structural differentiation in the labor market –its fragmentation in other words-

stems from this perverse dynamic that ruptures the intimate relationship between

salary, productivity and salarization.

l. This situation has given rise to the splitting off and formation of economic, cultural

and political sectors, each with their own particular game rules, dissimilar and

contradictory goals and objectives, and values that are an expression of the deep

splits and differences that exist in Venezuelan society.

3. The extension of salary relations

The extension of salary relations and the defragmentation of the labor market have

been pre-requisites for capitalist expansion and ensuring the domestic social peace of

countries. In this regard, it is unquestionable that the well-being in rich countries is closely

related to the unequivocal approach adopted by their ruling classes in the search for better

conditions for incorporating the huge masses of people occupying wretched jobs into the

capitalist labor market.

It was into this dilemma-ridden scenario that the Welfare States emerged at the end

of the 19th century as the element providing most solid support for capitalist development in

Europe and the United States and as guarantors of the process of homogenization of the

salary relation or salarization, by permitting the incorporation of workers into the labor

market with lower social costs. The great objective was to consolidate growing,

homogenous societies within which it was possible to share risks, societies in which the

immense majority of the population would be able to have a stable job.

The great historical role played by the Welfare States was that of establishing a

form of conciliation that would get past the “hand-to-hand” combat that was occurring in

each factory to obtain better wages. The public sector’s social efforts were focused on this

objective: agreeing game rules by setting up a system of risk sharing that would permit

capitalist expansion and, at the same time, favor workers. To achieve these objectives, the

states, making full use of their fiscal policies, built up social security systems, granted their

14

economic agents full freedom, and strengthened the legal bases guaranteeing legal

certainty for the expansion of capital. It is worth pointing out here that, in these cases,

intervention in the economy by the State was restricted to setting and managing the fiscal

policy.

Through the different welfare systems, based on universal systems of contributions

by workers and employers, the governments of these countries took on tasks that before

had fallen within the private domain of the family or were reserved to the more powerful

sectors. Amidst tremendous conflicts, strikes, negotiations and agreements, they

implemented measures and took action aimed at backing this profound social migration to

new forms of economic participation (extension of salary relations; defragmentation of the

labor market), while at the same time setting up systems of social contributions and

benefits unheard of until then. In less than a century, they managed to extend access to

education and make it compulsory, democratize the entry into universities and training

centers, while getting legislation passed that would provide the worker with protection from

the complexities of his working life.

The priority for welfare regimes, established as a result of the extension of salary

relations, meant, in a more general sense, increasing the value of the human potential of all

non-owners so that they would acquire, via that route, autonomy as political citizens and

economic entities, a circumstance that guaranteed them the enjoyment of their social

citizenship and freedom to sell their labor and their know-how and accumulated skill

potential without restrictions, so turning this into the key to individual and collective well-

being.

Another decisive player joined this process of increasing the value of the salary,

underpinned by the different types of Welfare States and welfare systems: the large trade

unions, defenders of the financial power of the wage, which were to undergo an intense

process of organization and internal democratization throughout this entire period, a basic

requirement for ensuring the workers’ representation in dealings with the State and capital.

As can be seen in Table No. 1, the prevailing trend in the United Kingdom, France

and the United States has been the extension of salary relations and, with it, of formal

employment. By the 90s, more than 80% of the economically active population in each of

these countries were wage-earners, a trend that runs counter to what has happened in

Venezuela, where growth of the salarized population tends to be dominated increasingly by

the informal sector (see Tables Nos. 2 and 3).

15

Table No. 1

Salaried Status: International Experience 1688-1993

(Salaried population as a percentage of the economically active population)

United

Kingdom

% France % USA %

1688 35.8

1801 43.2 1900 69.8

1911 87.2 1866 57.7 1940 75.7

1951 92.8 1926 65.1 1970 89.8

1991 87.9 1982 83.6 1992 91.2

Source: Baptista, Asdrúbal. 2004. “Teoría Económica del capitalismo Rentístico”. Caracas

Ediciones IESA 1999.

Table No. 2

Venezuela

Salaried population as a percentage of the economically active population

(1936- 1995)

Salarization

Year %

1936 37.4

1953 63.6

1961 70.7

1971 78.7

1995 83.8

Source: Baptista, Asdrúbal. 2004. “Teoría Económica del capitalismo Rentístico”.

Caracas Ediciones IESA 1999.

16

0

20

40

60

80

196919721975197819811984198719901993199619992002

Formal

Informal

Table No. 3

Venezuela

Population Working in the Formal and Informal Sectors

Source. Encuestas de Hogares por muestreo. 1969-2003. Instituto

Nacional de Estadísticas

Regardless of the ways in which Welfare States operate or the specific details of

their social security systems or welfare regimes, it is undeniable that their participation was

decisive in the creation of risk-sharing societies that were guarantors of capitalist

expansion, the defragmentation of the labor market in an environment or relative social

peace and, above all, in benefiting workers without creating disincentives to business

investment.

By way of conclusion, it can be said that the combination of the extension of salary

relations and the free development of business within the general framework of the

Welfare States, the organization of trade union movements, and the expansion of

educational-health services permitted the leaders of these countries to incorporate large

masses of the population into wealth-generating economic activity, create the conditions

for expanding their possibilities of developing human capital and so overcome poverty as a

structural problem.

Although these countries may experience periods when the salary loses value or

the capacity for employment contracts, neither of these situations constitutes phenomena

of poverty as we know them in our country.

In Venezuela, the construction of a risk-sharing society based on defragmentation

of the labor market, extension of salary relations, and generation of formal jobs has not

occurred. Depending on how the economy is behaving at any given time, informal workers

account for just over or just under half the economically active population. Added to this is

17

the magnitude of unproductive public sector employment, whose dimensions stem from

the rentier nature of our economy.

18

Graph No. 1

Structure of the Venezuelan Labor Market

2004

Source: Instituto Nacional de Estadísticas. 2004

The vast majority of informal workers are either poor or potentially poor, lack

savings capacity, do not have ties with the financial system or any possibility of taking part

in the contribution systems that would provide them with the protection of social benefits in

the event of being unable to work or a family emergency. In Venezuela, only 30% of

workers contribute to the social security system. This means that it is impossible to

generate possibilities for human development and to deal with poverty without making

direct reference to this instability and fragmentation of our labor market.

The extension of salary relations in the formal sector, or salarization, as an

alternative to poverty implies, then, generating jobs as a response to the demand for

economic development and salary relations that are valid insofar as they contribute to the

expansion of physical and human capital and to the generation of goods that consumers

need and find desirable at home and abroad.

4. Productivity in a rentier society

The oil revenue that the Venezuelan State receives is income that has no

counterpart in terms of productive effort. This initial circumstance indicates that the

Some features:

Salarization shows negative

fragmentation; majority of non-

taxpayers

Predominance of non-salary

relations and of sectors providing scant

added value (jobs in informal + public

sectors)

Private-sector formal market is a

comparatively small employer in

international terms

Poor remuneration

Productivity with zero strategic

value in terms of the participation of the

sectors

Impossibility of universal social

security owing to the low level of

distribution

Informal Sector

52%

Public Sector

24%

Private Sector

34%

19

salaries set within the domestic economy have little to do with productivity -unlike what

happens in capitalist societies where salaries closely follow increases generated in

productivity-, a trend that accentuates the lack of linkage between productivity, salary and

salarization -fundamental variables in the growth of employment and the extension of

salary relations- in the Venezuelan rentier economy and restricts workers’ potential for

human development.

Although it can be said that increased productivity is not sufficient to definitely

ensure improvements in the social conditions of the worker, it is unquestionable that, in

order to guarantee social rights, it is necessary that society’s productivity levels be

increased to the point where resources are available from which to distribute any surplus.

This is not a situation that prevails in oil rentier societies, where the State’s

fundamental income is not linked to increases in endogenous productivity. In these cases,

redistribution or sharing out automatically becomes a discretionary function of the sectors

or institutions that control the flow of income and, ultimately, it is a product of the game

rules agreed upon by a given society for distributing that fiscal revenue.

When the revenue is channeled to encouraging a domestic productive structure

where this income is used as seed capital, a kind of original sum to finance new economic

activities that will generate new income, the linkage between productivity, salary and

salarization is formed immediately. The rate of benefits that this type of investment

produces for society will be directly related to the productivity of labor and the

competitiveness of the products generated by this activity. In this situation it can be

expected that the salarization process, understood as the generation of opportunities for

incorporating workers into dependent, formal salaried relations, will be reinforced.

Establishing the link between productivity, salary and salarization is a pre-requisite

not only for achieving improvements in people’s standard of living, but also for achieving a

true strengthening of democracy. If this link exists as a fundamental of economic fact, the

fate of the working population will not depend on chance external circumstances, as in our

case, where the variations in the price of oil on the world market, the volume of oil sold

and, above all, the political decision and political interests are the factors that prevail when

it comes to directing the redistribution process. If the link between salary, salarization and

productivity does exist, a healthy competition can be established between the State,

business and workers to determine growing salary levels that are sustainable over time.

The trade unions can make sure that the level of wages are representative of workers’

efforts and that achievements in productivity are translated into salary improvements;

20

similarly, the extension of the salaried population would occur as a result of the expansion

in economic activity, and not as a result of a decision to increase jobs in the public sector

or in any other unproductive activity.

As can be seen in Table no. 4, in the main developed countries, salaries, while very

near productivity levels, always remain below them.

Table No. 4

Productivity and Real Salaries, Various Countries

Germany France Italy United

Kingdom

Europe USA

1965- 1981

Productivity 4.0 4.1 4.4 3.3 3.9 1.4

Salaries 3.8 3.4 4.6 2.9 3.6 1.1

1981 -1997

Productivity 1.9 2.3 2.3 1.8 2.1 0.7

Salaries 0.7 1.1 0.8 1.5 1.0 0.5

Source: Baptista Asdrúbal. 2004. “Teoría Económica del capitalismo Rentístico”. Caracas

Ediciones IESA 1999.

In the case of Venezuela, this relationship does not exist and may be the opposite;

the growth or decline in salaries is not a direct consequence of variations in productivity

(see Table No. 5).

Given the economic power of the State, its capacity to generate employment at its

discretion based on its policies for redistributing revenue, and the considerable subsidizing

and protection of domestic industry, a margin or degree of independence between the

worker wage and productivity variables is created. “…the rates showing the behavior of

both indicators since 1958 permit the observation that, while per capita GDP is at 1962

levels, the productivity of the employed work force in the country is only 70% of what it was

in 1958. In other words, today, each worker produces 30% less than his counterpart might

have generated in 1958. Current academic discussion links productivity and long-term

growth to the effort of developing human and social capital, the quality of institutions, the

strength and flexibility of labor markets and, in general, to conditions that might promote

and favor investment in all areas having positive consequences for the human

development of all a country’s citizens. It is for this reason that verifying this continuous

21

deterioration in the contribution made by production is a crucial element for the future and

prosperity of Venezuela. Low productivity also implies declining real remuneration, which

means that better conditions can hardly be expected for workers and for the population in

general.”10

10 Curiel (2005), i, page 33.

22

Table No. 5

Productivity and Real Salaries, Venezuela

(1953 -1980)

Source: Baptista Asdrúbal. 2004. “Teoría Económica del capitalismo

Rentístico”. Caracas Ediciones IESA 1999.

The lack of linkage between salaries and productivity affects all Venezuelan

workers, except those who work in the private sector, where benefits depend on the

profitability of the business. In the case of the informal workers, income depends not so

much on the productivity of their work but on the existence of game rules that will allow

them to obtain additional benefits, such as not existing as far as the tax authorities are

concerned, which means they do not pay either taxes or municipal business licenses,

evading the labor costs implicit in the labor law, and evading fixed costs, such as paying

for electricity, renting premises, etc.

5. Devaluation of education in the rentier economy

The absence of linkage between salary and productivity, typical of the rentier

society, has as one of its correlates the devaluation of the credentials of human capital as

an irreplaceable requirement for the generation of income. Despite the huge amounts of

resources obtained by the State from oil revenues, Venezuelan statistics show that the

number of people without specific job qualifications in the Venezuelan labor market is

extremely high, a situation that affects more than three quarters of people in the

economically active age group. These same statistics also show, however, that the

number of people with higher education qualifications is twice the average of that in

developed countries. This paradoxical situation is due to the peculiarities of the

Venezuelan education system, which offers university education as an alternative to

Period Productivity Salaries

1953-1961 5.6 6.8

1961-1970 4.8 4.1

1971-1978 -1.4 2.5

1978-1995 0.3 -5.2

23

Nivel Educativo de la Fuerza Laboral Ocupada

2004

5% 1%

54%

21%

19%

0%

Analfabetas

Sin Nivel

Básica

Media Diversificada y Profesional

Superior

No Declarado

Nivel Educativo Buhoneros de Caracas

1%

51%

38%

10%

Sin Nivel

Básica

Media Diversificada y Profesional

Superior

joining the labor market, for the privileged, but lacks opportunities for acquiring mid-level

qualifications that would allow the mass of the population to obtain the qualifications they

need, pressed, as they are, to start working at an early age. This contradictory situation of

a large mass of people without qualifications and a sector with university qualifications that

is larger than the averages in more developed countries shows the lack of linkage between

education and the country’s development requirements. There are no opportunities for the

majority to obtain qualifications. The structure of the levels of education within the informal

population reflects averages similar to those prevailing in the formal sector, with 81% also

lacking any professional qualification.

Contrary to all expectations, the research done by CEDICE managed to

demonstrate that there are no significant differences between the educational

characteristics of informal workers and those of workers in the formal sector: more than

38% of informal street workers are high school graduates or mid-level technicians and

10% have higher education, while the predominant level of education for both sectors,

formal and informal, is primary education, which covers more than 50% of the workers in

both cases.

Graph No. 2 Graph No. 3

Source: Instituto Nacional de Estadísticas 2004

This devaluation of education is significant when revenue distribution alternatives

are generated based on large-scale education-type programs of an inferior quality through

which the population is offered mass qualifications without meeting the requirements that

would lead to the training of human capital capable of playing a competitive role in the

economy, a situation that takes on greater significance when it is understood that joining

the informal sector is not a completely autonomous or voluntary decision, as our research

shows.

A first conclusion that can be drawn from the analysis of these data is that it is not

the level of education that prevents informal workers from joining the labor market, as fairly

Source: UAPPEI, CEDICE LIBERTAD

24

Lo Que Sabe Hacer Mejor es...

40%

60%

Comercio / Buhonerismo

Otro

Experiencia en Otras Ocupaciones

(Distintas al Buhonerismo)

79%

21%

Si

No

Tiempo Transcurrido desde Última

Ocuapción

(Distinta al Buhonerismo)

9%

18%

34%

19%

20%

Menos de 1 Año

De 1 a 2 Años

De 2 a 4 Años

De 4 a 6 Años

Más de 6 Años

similar levels of education predominate in the two sectors. Now then, what can be

postulated as a deduction is that it is not the levels of education that generate

opportunities for joining the formal labor market but the specific characteristics of the

general rentier economy model.

6. Is informal work an option chosen voluntarily?

Despite knowing the limitations facing anyone in the economically active age group

when attempting to enter the labor market, it is important to understand to what extent

informal work can be considered an option chosen voluntarily by the people in this sector,

according to the findings of the study conducted by CEDICE. The following graphs show

that 60% of street vendors stated that what they know best is an occupation other than

commerce/street vending, which is in line with the 80% who have experience in other lines

of work.

Graph No. 3 Graph No. 4

Source: UAPPEI, CEDICE LIBERTAD Source: UAPPEI, CEDICE LIBERTAD

Moreover, it can be seen that 62% of all informals interviewed had worked in

occupations other than street vending for periods of more than two years and a third had

worked for brief periods in other occupations.

Graph No. 5

25

Años en Última Ocupación

(Distinta al Buhonerismo)

11%

19%

10%

33%

27%

Menos de 1 Año

De 1 a 2 Años

De 2 a 4 Años

De 4 a 6 Años

Más de 6 Años

Horas de Trabajo Diarias

78%

15%

7%

Entre 5 y 8 Horas

Entre 9 y 12 Horas

Entre 13 y 16 Horas

Días a la Semana que Trabaja

2%

18%

78%

2%3 Días o Menos

4 Días

5 Días

6 Días

7 Días

Años de Experiencia Como Buhonero

7%

18%

43%

18%

14%

Menos de 1 Año

De 1 a 2 Años

De 2 a 4 Años

De 4 a 6 Años

Más de 6 Años

Source: UAPPEI, CEDICE LIBERTAD

Graph No. 6 Graph No. 7

Source: UAPPEI, CEDICE LIBERTAD Source: UAPPEI,

CEDICE LIBERTAD

However, even though the occupation they know best is different from street

vending, 64% have remained in this line of work for periods of more than six years. Given

these facts, it is worth asking, if a street vendor gives another occupation as what he

knows best and has ample experience in other types of job, why does he continue in street

vending? One possible hypothesis would be that his continuing in this line of work does

not depend on training or experience, but on the lack of jobs in the fields or areas in which

he has skills and experience. It also permits us to infer that the possibility of mobility into

the formal sector grows less the longer a person remains on the street.

But if, besides that, we add the hours a typical street vendor works, the question

that then arises is what is the attraction or what are the motives that induce these people

to work between 9 and 12 hours a day, seven days a week, which are normal working

hours according to 78% of Caracas street vendors?

Graph No. 8 Graph No. 9

Source: UAPPEI, CEDICE LIBERTAD Source: UAPPEI, CEDICE

LIBERTAD

26

The hypothesis that joining the informal workforce is not a matter of free choice

seems to be confirmed by the study’s findings regarding the perceptions of informal

workers, where almost all the answers have to do with the possibility of joining the formal

sector. Most aspire to having their own business, formally owned by them, provided the

change in their job status does not mean a loss of real benefits enjoyed at present.

27

Percepciones

99%

88%

77%

64%

26%

0%

10%

20%

30%

40%

50%

60%

70%

80%

90%

100%

Tener Comercio Propio Buhonerismo Acabará

Prox. 5 años

Tomaría Trabajo Formal Aceptaría ese Trabajo

Ganando Igual

Se Formalizaría si con

eso Ganara Igual

Aspiraciones

84% 86%80%77%

97%

0%

10%

20%

30%

40%

50%

60%

70%

80%

90%

100%

Cambiar a otra

Actividad Formal en

la que Ganase Igual

Contar con Seguro

Social

Cubrir los Costos

de SS a sus

Empleados y/o

Famlia

Pagar Impuestos

Sobre la Renta

Pagar Impuestos

Municipales

Graph No. 10 Perceptions of Informal Workers

Caracas Metropolitan Area

Source: UAPPEI, CEDICE LIBERTAD

As for their aspirations, there are clear references to formalizing their situation, the

majority would like the backing of a social security system that protects their families, to

pay municipal taxes, and to change over to a formal line of work.

Graph No. 11 Aspirations of Informal Workers

Caracas Metropolitan Area

Source: UAPPEI, CEDICE LIBERTAD

28

Deseo de Formalizarse

95%

5%

No

This verification of the informal worker’s working conditions and the desire of 95%

of informal workers to formalize their situation give rise to definite doubts as to whether

joining the informal market can be a matter of preference or free choice.

Graph No. 12

Aspirations of Informal Workers to join the Formal Economy Caracas Metropolitan Area

Source: UAPPEI, CEDICE LIBERTAD

7. Learning “the other game rules”

Besides the outdoor working conditions that the informal workers have to face in

order to guarantee a living, they have to adopt or abide by game rules that are different to

those prevailing in the formal sector. Factors such as “having someone to take care of the

stand,” indicative of the precarious nature of rules governing this line of work or of the

absence of formal ownership, and having to depend on direct dealings with persons of

influence in order to survive -with the police, for example, for getting round legal

procedures and requirements that restrict informality- are part of the cultural environment

of the game rules they must learn and master if they are to be reasonably successful in

street trading.

Mastering the extra-legal game rules allows these workers to cope with the factors

associated with informality, such as the insecurity and instability that makes physical

control of the stand from which they work enormously important, a variable expressed in

the relevance of “never leaving the stand” because of the fear of maybe losing the

29

business or being evicted. Another requirement is being “sharp or on the ball,” which is

translated into the capacity to respond immediately to rules that aim to regulate their line of

work or any changes in the game rules governing the business. These factors are as

relevant as the conventional factors in any commercial relationship, such as treating the

customer well, being a responsible person or the level of formal education.

30

Índice de Factores de Redes Sociales en el Éxito de la

Buhonería

0,16 0,150,11

0,16

0,220,19

0

0,05

0,1

0,15

0,2

0,25

0,3

Conocer lider de

la cuadra

Conocer

policias

Conocer

maladros

Conocer

personas

influyentes

Tener panas en

la zona

Tener alguien

para cuidar el

puesto cuando

te vas

Índice de Factores de Aptitudes / Actitudes en el Éxito

de la Buhonería

0,15

0,05 0,05

0,16 0,15 0,13 0,150,15

0

0,05

0,1

0,15

0,2

0,25

0,3

Ser

viv

o/p

ilas

Ser

vio

lento

Esta

r

arm

ado

Buen t

rato

con e

l

públic

o

Ser

una

pers

ona

responsable

Ser

respeta

do

Ser

Bachill

er

Nunca f

altar

al puesto

Graph No. 13

Source: UAPPEI, CEDICE LIBERTAD

Graph No. 14

Source: UAPPEI, CEDICE LIBERTAD

Those who work in the informal sector on a daily basis are exposed to the ups and

downs of the contradictions between formal and informal rules, so much so that 10% of

informal traders consider that the laws regulating public places -and therefore their

business activities- are well defined, while 71% consider that they are either poorly defined

(34%) or not applicable (37%).

31

Graph No. 15

Source: UAPPEI, CEDICE LIBERTAD

This contradiction is reflected in the perception these workers have of their formal

rights as regards the legal situation of their line of business, with 67% of those surveyed

recognizing that the Constitution does not grant them the right to occupy the streets, but

almost a third pointing out that Article 87 of the Constitution clearly states that they have

the right to work as non-dependent workers.

Graph No. 16

Source: UAPPEI, CEDICE LIBERTAD

These working conditions that prevail in the informal economy, added to the social

friction that adopting game rules that are opposed to those of the formal sector, allow us to

infer that remaining in a situation of informality or the difficulty in formalizing their situation

is tightly linked to the specific model of work socialization centered on the learning of

Las leyes que regulan el espacio publico están:

10%

34% 37%

19%

Bien definidas Mal definidas

No son aplicables No sabe/ no responde

¿Existe un derecho Constitucional para trabajar

en la calle?

No sabe/ no responde 3%

Si da un derecho 30%

No da derecho a Trabajar en

la calle

32

values contrary to those that govern formal society, owing to the scant opportunities for

entering the labor market in an economy founded on the distribution of revenue and not on

the generation of productive investment opportunities. This is a situation that denies

opportunities for creating formal jobs and casts a shadow over or reduces the role of the

factors that have been considered key factors for closing the gap that separates us from

more advanced countries: investment in education, opening up to new technologies, and

encouraging research and development in the private sector.

While the annual per capita income in the region doubled from US$3,000 to

US$6,200 between 1950 and 2000, in developed countries, it tripled from US$7,300 to

US$23,000. The number of poor people in Latin America and the Caribbean today comes

to nearly 169 million. This phenomenon of lagging behind in the growth of income is due to

a productivity gap, which, in turn, stems from Latin America’s and the Caribbean’s inability

to keep abreast with adopting new technologies in their productive processes and the slow

updating of skills.

To close this gap, it is not enough to simply import the latest technology, it is

necessary to bring the level of education and skills of the population up to the level

required in order to exploit its full productive potential, because technology and skills

closely complement one another.”11

8. Decline in the number of jobs since 1999

In 1999, the clear trend of informal work becoming the predominant activity within

the Venezuelan labor market began to emerge. The expansion of informal work, in our

view, is going to be closely linked to the new approach adopted by the Venezuelan

government, focused on the following elements:

a. Return to centralization and the concentration of power

This approach adopted by the Venezuelan government broke with the boost that had

been given to redistributing the economic and political power within the country during

the decade 1980-1990. This objective, pursued during this period, became evident in

the Law on the Direct Election of Governors (1989) and the Decentralization Law

(1989), which transferred the management and control of public services to the

municipal and state governments. This process of gradually reversing the process of

decentralization has meant a return to the concentration of power in the rentier State.

11 World Bank (2003), a, page 33

33

In terms of employment, it has had the effect of discouraging the growth of economic

fabrics with their bases in local communities and municipalities and inhibiting the

democratic redistribution of regional economic activities.

b. Reducing the participation of private enterprise in the country’s economic

development. Replacing private activity with public.

The escalation of the penning-in of private companies through laws and decrees that

severely restrict economic freedoms, the majority of which contradict the present

Constitution, has caused, among other problems, a major shift in economic activity

from the private to the public sector. It is worth noting here how the ratio of Total Fiscal

Spending to Gross Domestic Product grew from 21.2% between 1990 and 1999 to

24.4% between 2000 and 2004, the latter being the highest rate of growth since

statistical records have been kept in Venezuela. This same ratio in the 60s did not

exceed 16% according to figures produced by the Central Bank of Venezuela.

This re-orientation of the economy marked the starting point for a gradual

escalation of measures, decrees and regulations, conveniently accompanied by threats

of expropriations, invasions of private property, and rigidity in the rules for operating

private companies, the most obvious result of which is the absence of private

investment, both domestic and foreign.

Graph No. 17

Foreign Investment in Venezuela 1996 - 2004

Source: www. venamcham.org

34

With the defining and application of these approaches, the generation of private

sector jobs in the labor market began to decline. The number of manufacturing industries

contracted by nearly half between 2000 and 2004, from 13,000 establishments to nearly

7,000 in 2004. Industry has declined and with it the number of employed workers in the

private sector. What is clear, however, is that, while the decline in the private industrial

sector is a negative result in economic-social terms, it is one of the political objectives

pursued by the new regime, which aims to cover this vacuum in the generation of

employment by slowly and gradually imposing economic establishments based on

collective forms of economic organization and ownership.

With this objective in mind, the new law on the functioning of cooperatives was

passed, in which cooperatives are conceived of as unions of associated producers with

considerable restrictions on incorporating salaried labor, so managing to substitute this

type of property ownership for all private sources of generation of employment. These are

cooperatives with a strong anti-employment bias, as they are only allowed to incorporate

salaried workers as an exception with temporary jobs lasting for up to six months, at the

end of which time the worker has the right to demand that he be allowed to become a

member on the same terms as the founder members. In situations where the incorporation

of new salaried workers is indispensable, because the cooperatives are not in a position to

be able to do the work themselves, the law orders that these workers be hired through

other cooperatives, companies in the social, participative economy or even enterprises

having other forms of legal incorporation. Sanctions, including suspension of certification

as a cooperative and fines, are established for cases where salaried workers are hired on

a permanent basis.

The regulatory framework for these cooperatives reflects the anti-capitalist bias that

prevails in the law, which is aimed at eliminating salaried work or reducing to its minimum

expression. These cooperatives, which are being promoted by the government as the

great alternative to poverty, will be a source of major social conflicts, as, inevitably and

because of internal inertia, they will block the entry of new members as a mechanism for

preserving a larger slice of the earnings for each of their members, to the detriment of the

poor jobless sectors, who will pressure for new opportunities to join.

9. Conclusions

35

In modern, competitive market economies, human development is a priority. In

rentier economies, whose main revenue does not come from domestic productive efforts

and where salaried labor is not the fundamental linking factor between individuals but

rather a determining feature of the separation and differentiation of expectations, human

development is not a priority. The absence of this priority as a fundamental in the

socialization experience in salaried labor is, moreover, the cause of the proliferation of

violent behaviors, insecurity and the destruction of society’s collective assets.

The education and training of the individual lose their strategic importance as a

requirement for achieving better standards of living.

The division between the population in the formal sector and the population in the

informal sector generates a weakness in terms of contributions that makes it impossible for

societies to build up universal assistance and security systems to help individuals cope

with life’s ups and downs: illness, old age, losses in the family, and so on.

These conditions, which pose restrictions on the human development of men and

women engaged in street trading in public places, make them victims of exclusion twice

over, so making them more vulnerable and reducing their possibilities of opting for an

alternative that would improve their economic and social circumstances. This double

exclusion manifests itself on two fronts:

The first has to do with the specific conditions of the economic-political regime that

characterizes Venezuelan society insofar as it is a) a statist-rentier distributive society and

b) a society where attempts are being made to impose a collectivist production model in

the place of the market and private property. Both features of this sociopolitical model

have a characteristic in common: their strong anti-job-generation trait expressed in all the

public policies, laws and game rules that govern the incorporation of Venezuelans into the

labor market. This anti-employment trait has become the efficient cause of the presence of

informal work as a structural feature of the Venezuelan labor market.

On the second front, the differentiating exclusion of informal traders occurs as a

result of their non-participation or distancing as a social group from the possibilities of

human development implicit in the building of a knowledge society and a key factor for

generating wealth, innovation and added value as a product of the individual’s subjective

transforming power. In street trading, what prevails is the kingdom of “other knowledge” or

learning and continuous improvisation of game rules for the survival of these growing

social sectors.

36

The two types of exclusion have features in common. Both in the distributive,

collectivist societies and in the social groups outside the knowledge society, human capital

becomes a passive, dependent factor and not a crucial element for generating wealth.

Education and investment in human capital is not the highest priority; education is not

conceived of as the intangible with the highest power of transformation, with the result that

belonging to the knowledge society loses its strategic value. The problem becomes more

complex given the evidence that any attempt at urban regulation and at re-launching the

market economy includes the incorporation of the vast majority of these street vendors into

economic activities where the level of training, socialization and work culture are key

factors for their effective inclusion.

The existence of these two worlds –the one formal, modern, centered on

knowledge and innovation as they key for generating wealth, and the other, on the other

side of the tracks and based on the ability and skill for negotiating informal game rules,

where shrewdness and the capacity to deal with whoever happens to be in authority takes

the place of education- gives rise to an irreconcilable split within society, a situation in

which both sides end up losers, inhabitants of the same world and occupying the same

geographical space but who view life from totally different perspectives.

The significance of this double exclusion of informal vendors is linked to the fact

that, increasingly, in the Venezuelan distributive society, now tending towards collectivism,

informal economic activity is becoming predominant owing to the effects of the model

itself. A side effect of this expansion in informality is the decline in the importance of

education, investment in the individual and the growth of human capital, for the simple

reason that the survival of the majorities does not depend on their intrinsic membership of

the knowledge society but, rather, on how they manage to get around these formal rules,

which do not take them into account.

The alternatives or solutions to this crucial problem must address both of its

manifestations: the transformation of the general model, which necessarily has to be re-

oriented to turning the distributive society into a society based on a system of contributions

and benefits, as it only has the individual, the power of human capital as its center, and the

revaluation of education and continuous learning as the key factor of change and social

well-being.

10. Challenges involved in developing informal human capital in Venezuela

37

Creating opportunities for human development for informal workers involves, first of

all, a) a change in society’s understanding and perception of informality as an economic

and socio-cultural phenomenon; and b) the generation of expectations of integration or

self-betterment within these groups.

If the game rules prevent large segments of the population from gaining access to

formal work that generates wealth and viable life projects, society must take steps to

engage in self-criticism that gives rise to changes and modifications in those game rules. If

the country’s economic strategy prevents the growth of opportunities for business or the

salaried population with decent wages and access to social security from expanding, the

economy or its pattern of development needs to be re-oriented so that opportunities are

made available to all. If the legal framework excludes the informal population, the law as a

sphere for intersubjective creation must be rethought so that it gradually opens up to bring

the informal population under the rule of law.

10.1. Surmounting the rentier model

It will only be possible to solve the social division implicit in the separation between formal

and informal society by surmounting the rentier mode, a task that necessarily involves

adopting the following approaches and taking the following measures:

Restoring to Venezuelans investment opportunities in sectors with comparative

advantages.

Extending salary relations by establishing the link between salary and productivity

Increasing the value of and strengthen the capacity for generating value adding

activities of the informal sectors.

Giving priority to education as part of a new paradigm that will convert human capital

into the foundation of the generation of wealth in our society.

All these reforms are linked to the transformation of the proprietor-State into a manager of

democracy and to restoring to citizens the possibility of investing in the sectors having

comparative advantages.

10.2. Mass human development program and capitalizing the informal

sectors

This program would imply:

38

Consolidating the business initiatives of productive units with a low application of

capital and scant technological and management development.

Reeducating or retraining informal workers whose line of work is unviable.

Amending the education law and reforming the national education system by

establishing professional accreditations for sectors that join the labor market at an

early age.

Contributing to the creation of a legal-regulatory framework that counteracts the

undercapitalization of companies in low-income sectors.

Promoting economic organizations of informal workers through corporate structures

that facilitate trade (e.g. trading companies)

Transferring to organizations of low-income groups methods for negotiating the

elimination of useless permits that hinder the exercising of economic freedom and

make it more expensive.

Promoting access to financing and technological support opportunities offered by the

private sector for informal businessmen

Creating new opportunities for the Venezuelan business sector to negotiate social

responsibilities.

Transferring methodologies to the municipal governments that will enable them to

effectively negotiate property ownership with the low-income sectors.

39

BIBLIOGRAPHIC REFERENCES

a. World Bank (2003). Informe: Cerrando la brecha en educación, tecnología y productividad. Washington

b. Baptista Asdrúbal (2004). El relevo del capitalismo rentístico. Caracas. Fundación

Polar.

c. Baptista Asdrúbal (1999). Teoría Económica del capitalismo Rentístico. Caracas Ediciones IESA

d. e. Barret, Richard (2001). Liberando el alma de la empresa. Buenos Aires. SMS

editores.

f. Beck, Ulrico (2002). Libertad o Capitalismo. Barcelona. Editorial Paidós.

g. Becker, Gary (1964). Human Capital: a theoretical and empirical analysis. New York. Columbia University Press.

h. Betancourt, Rómulo (1978). Venezuela, Política y Petróleo. Barcelona Editorial

Seix Barral.

i. Castro Leiva, Luís (1988). El dilema octubrista 1945-1987. Caracas. Cuadernos

Lagoven.

j. Curiel Claudia (2005). Análisis de la estrategia utilizada para restringir la actividad productiva. Caracas. CONINDUSTTRIA.

k. García Muller, Alberto (2002). Acerca de la reforma de la Ley de Cooperativas. Mérida. Universidad de los Andes.

l. Lechner, Norberto (1999). Desafíos al Desarrollo Humano. Individualización y Capital Social. Washington. Inter-American Development Bank.

40

m. Oropeza, Luís José (1998). El Gendarme Innecesario. Caracas. Editorial Panapo.

n. Penfold Michael (2002). Costo Venezuela. Opciones de Política para Mejorar la Competitividad CONAPRI-Corporación Andina de Fomento.

o. Pereira Isabel (2004). La extensión de relaciones salariales. Caracas. Fundación

Principia.

p. Pereira, Isabel y Zanoni, Wladimir (2004). Por la Paz y el Empleo. Caracas. Fundación Principia.

q. r. Poder Legislativo de Venezuela (1997). Ley Orgánica del Trabajo. Caracas.

Gaceta Oficial Nº 5.152 Extraordinario.

s. Portes, Castells and Benton (1989). The informal economy. New York. The Johns Hopkins University Press

t. Samaniego, Norma (2002). Los principales desafíos que enfrenta el mercado de

trabajo en Méjico. Méjico. Siglo XXI.

u. Schultz, Theodore (1992). Restablecimiento del equilibrio económico. Los recursos

humanos en una economía en proceso de modernización. Méjico. Editorial Gedisa.

v. Sen, Amartya (2000). Desarrollo y Libertad. Barcelona. Editorial Planeta.

w. Smith, Adam (1776). La Riqueza de las Naciones. 2002. Madrid. Alianza Editorial