implications of a new puhca for...director columbus, ohio august 14, 1992 acknowledgements the...

96
IMPLICATIONS OF A NEW PUHCA FOR THE ELECTRIC INDUSTRY AND REGULATORS Kenneth W. Costello Associate Director Edward H. Jennings Professor of Finance The Ohio State University Timothy W. Viezer Graduate Research Associate THE NATIONAL REGULATORY RESEARCH INSTITUTE The Ohio State University 1080 Carmack Road Columbus, Ohio 43210-1002 (614) 292-9404 August 1992 NRRI92-13 This report was prepared by The National Regulatory Research Institute (NRRI) with funding provided by participating member commissions of the National Association of Regulatory Utility Commissioners (NARUC). The views and opinions of the authors do not necessarily state or reflect the views, opinions, or policies of the NRRI, the NARUC, or their contributors.

Upload: others

Post on 02-Oct-2020

0 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: IMPLICATIONS OF A NEW PUHCA FOR...Director Columbus, Ohio August 14, 1992 ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS The authors gratefully acknowledge the comments of Dr. Douglas N. Jones, Mr. Robert E. Burns,

IMPLICATIONS OF A NEW PUHCA FOR THE ELECTRIC INDUSTRY AND REGULATORS

Kenneth W. Costello Associate Director

Edward H. Jennings Professor of Finance

The Ohio State University

Timothy W. Viezer Graduate Research Associate

THE NATIONAL REGULATORY RESEARCH INSTITUTE The Ohio State University

1080 Carmack Road Columbus, Ohio 43210-1002

( 614) 292-9404

August 1992

NRRI92-13

This report was prepared by The National Regulatory Research Institute (NRRI) with funding provided by participating member commissions of the National Association of Regulatory Utility Commissioners (NARUC). The views and opinions of the authors do not necessarily state or reflect the views, opinions, or policies of the NRRI, the NARUC, or their contributors.

Page 2: IMPLICATIONS OF A NEW PUHCA FOR...Director Columbus, Ohio August 14, 1992 ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS The authors gratefully acknowledge the comments of Dr. Douglas N. Jones, Mr. Robert E. Burns,
Page 3: IMPLICATIONS OF A NEW PUHCA FOR...Director Columbus, Ohio August 14, 1992 ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS The authors gratefully acknowledge the comments of Dr. Douglas N. Jones, Mr. Robert E. Burns,

EXECUTIVE SUMMARY

Later in 1992, the electric industry is likely to see the passage of legislation

facilitating the entry of new generators in the wholesale power markets. An amended

Public Utility Holding Company Act (PUHCA) could be enacted into law giving a new

group of power producers the opportunity to become important players in the future

electric industry. A new PUHCA would lift key entry restrictions into wholesale power

production. Specifically, it would provide nonutility companies an expanded opportunity

to participate as power producers and allow utilities opportunities to produce power

outside of their retail service areas.

As of mid-summer, it remains uncertain what effect a new PUHCA would have

on the electric industry. Assuming it would stimulate the growth of the independent

power industry, the electric industry would likely undergo fundamental changes with

important implications for both retail electricity consumers and state public utility

commissions.

One conceivable outcome is a radical change in the structure of the electric

industry that could see it become less vertically integrated. More power generation

could come from independent producers employing the most economical technologies to

serve wholesale power markets. While the optimal industry structure is unknown, it is

intended that a new PUHCA will steer the industry toward a more economical structure

allowing market forces to discover the most efficient producers. Although independent

power producers ultimately may not playa major role as power generators, a new

PUHCA will give them a chance to compete more equally with alternate sources of new

resources (both supply side and demand side). As a policy matter, independent power

production should thrive only if it can offer the nation an economical source of new

power supply.

A new PUHCA would result in traditional regulated utilities increasingly

searching for new markets in which to sell the power they produce and to buy the power

111

Page 4: IMPLICATIONS OF A NEW PUHCA FOR...Director Columbus, Ohio August 14, 1992 ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS The authors gratefully acknowledge the comments of Dr. Douglas N. Jones, Mr. Robert E. Burns,

they need to serve their retail customers. These activities should advance competition in

the wholesale power markets, leading over time to the vertical disintegration of utilities.

State public utility commissions will playa pivotal part in affecting independent

power production and its effect on increasing competition in the wholesale power

markets. Through their actions and policies, they will provide the bedrock for

determining how utilities can and will pursue new supply sources needed to meet the

demand of their retail customers. Incentives and opportunities for power purchases by

utilities will depend largely on the environment created by state regulators. Regulators

may have to reduce regulatory impediments to elicit more economical purchases of firm

wholesale power by utilities.

State regulators will have particular concern over utilities forming wholesale

power production subsidiaries. Possible anticompetitive activities by operating utilities

and utility holding companies with wholesale power subsidiaries imply that state

regulators will have to stand guard more intensively against potential abuses that can

harm retail customers. A new PUHCA would likely give state commissions more certain

authority to protect retail customers from these abuses. While some state regulators may

believe they could cope with possible abuses under their current procedures, others may

decide to take more dramatic actions such as increasing staff resources and even

adopting a different regulatory mechanism. In either case, state regulators would have to

reaffirm their ability to prevent abuses by utilities and their wholesale power affiliates.

The gains of a new PUHCA to retail customers will depend on several factors.

The extent to which new independent power producers can generate electricity at low

cost with the economic gains spread to the retail market will determine the benefits to

end-use electricity consumers. These benefits, in turn, will hinge largely on the practices

and policies of regulators--namely, the Federal Energy Regulatory Commission in

affecting wholesale power pricing and transmission access and the state commissions in

affecting incentives and opportunities for utilities to purchase firm wholesale power.

Benefits will also depend on the long-term operating performance of independent power

facilities and on increases in competitive forces induced by the easier entry of new

wholesale power producers.

IV

Page 5: IMPLICATIONS OF A NEW PUHCA FOR...Director Columbus, Ohio August 14, 1992 ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS The authors gratefully acknowledge the comments of Dr. Douglas N. Jones, Mr. Robert E. Burns,

TABLE OF CONTENTS

Page

LIST OF FIGURES ............. 0 0 •••••••••••••••••• 0 • • • • • • • • • Vll

LIST OF TABLES 0 •••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••• 0 • • • • • • • • • • Vlll

FOREWORD .................................... 0 • • • • • • • • • • IX

ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS ..................................... Xl

Chapter

1 Introduction 1

2 Historical Overview of PUHCA ............................ . 5

The Early Days ......................................... 5 The Era of Utility Holding Companies ........ 0 • • • • • • • • • • • • • • • 9 Later Events ........................................... 14

3 Power Generators in the Electric Industry .................... . 17

Recent Changes . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 17 Different Power Generators .......................... 0 • • • • • 19 How a New PUHCA Would Affect Different

Power Generators .............. 0 • • • • • • • • • • • • • • • • • • • • • • • 24

4 The Implications of a New PUHCA for Retail Consumers ..................................... . 29

5 The Major Components of a New PUHCA 35

6 Remaining Obstacles for Independent Power Production ..................................... . 47

Transmission Access ..................................... 47 Self-Dealing . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 49 Demand-Side Initiatives . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 50 Regulatory Incentives . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 51

v

Page 6: IMPLICATIONS OF A NEW PUHCA FOR...Director Columbus, Ohio August 14, 1992 ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS The authors gratefully acknowledge the comments of Dr. Douglas N. Jones, Mr. Robert E. Burns,

TABLE OF CONTENTS--Continued

Page

7 New Challenges for Regulators ............................. . 53

8 Conclusions ........................................... . 61

Appendix

The Financial Leverage Issue . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 63

Introduction . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 63 The Naive Capital Structure . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 64 The Modigliani and Miller Capital Structure ................... 67 Perfect Capital Markets . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 69 Tax Modifications to the M & M Capital Structure .............. 71 Other Adjustments to the M & M Capital Structure . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 74 The Real World Cost of Capital ............................ 75 The Cost of Capital Advantage for the NUG .... . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 76 Summary and Conclusions ................................. 82

VI

Page 7: IMPLICATIONS OF A NEW PUHCA FOR...Director Columbus, Ohio August 14, 1992 ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS The authors gratefully acknowledge the comments of Dr. Douglas N. Jones, Mr. Robert E. Burns,

LIST OF FIGURES

Page

A-I Graphical Representation of the Cost of Capital 66

A-2 Graphical Representation of the Cost of Capital Under M & M Conditions . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 70

A-3 Graphical Representation of the Cost of Capital Under M & M Conditions Including Corporate Taxes 73

A-4 Consensus Cost of Capital Reflecting Real World Conditions .............................. 77

A-5 Hypothetical Electric Utility Cost of Capital Curve. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 79

Vll

Page 8: IMPLICATIONS OF A NEW PUHCA FOR...Director Columbus, Ohio August 14, 1992 ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS The authors gratefully acknowledge the comments of Dr. Douglas N. Jones, Mr. Robert E. Burns,

LIST OF TABLES

Table Page

1-1 Major Arguments Advanced during PUHCA Debate ............. 2

2-1 SEC Jurisdiction Over Utility Holding Companies ............... 12

3-1 Different Categories of Power Generators ..................... 20

3-2 Characteristics of Different Power Generators 21

3-3 PUHCA Restrictions on Forming Wholesale Power Facilities. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 25

4-1 Factors of Benefits to Retail Consumers . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 33

5-1 Features of New PUHCA in Senate Energy Bill. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 37

5-2 PUHCA Issues for Joint House-Senate Conference .............. 41

7-1 Implications of New PUHCA for State Regulators .. . . . . . . . . . . . . . 54

A-1 Hypothetical Income Statement ... . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 65

A-2 Alternative Investment Strategies . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 68

A-3 Hypothetical Income Statement Including Corporate Income Taxes ..................................... 72

A-4 Alternative Investment Strategies with Corporate Income Taxes .... ~ . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 72

VIll

Page 9: IMPLICATIONS OF A NEW PUHCA FOR...Director Columbus, Ohio August 14, 1992 ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS The authors gratefully acknowledge the comments of Dr. Douglas N. Jones, Mr. Robert E. Burns,

FOREWORD

The U.S. Congress is currently debating whether the Public Utility Company Holding Act of 1935 (PUHCA) should be amended to facilitate the entry of a new class of power generators into the electric industry. The odds are good that some federal legislation will be passed this year advancing this goal. New legislation could have consequential effects on both the future structure of the electric industry and on state public utility regulation.

The major objective of this report is to assist state commissions in better understanding what effects a new PUHCA could have on both the electric industry and state regulation. It is to this end that we believe the report will be valuable to our clientele.

IX

Douglas N. Jones Director Columbus, Ohio August 14, 1992

Page 10: IMPLICATIONS OF A NEW PUHCA FOR...Director Columbus, Ohio August 14, 1992 ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS The authors gratefully acknowledge the comments of Dr. Douglas N. Jones, Mr. Robert E. Burns,
Page 11: IMPLICATIONS OF A NEW PUHCA FOR...Director Columbus, Ohio August 14, 1992 ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS The authors gratefully acknowledge the comments of Dr. Douglas N. Jones, Mr. Robert E. Burns,

ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS

The authors gratefully acknowledge the comments of Dr. Douglas N. Jones, Mr. Robert E. Burns, and Mr. John Borrows of the NRRI, and Mr. Russell Profozich of the U.S. Department of Energy. The authors also appreciate the editing of Mr. David Wagman and the typing and patience of Ms. Marilyn Reiss.

Xl

Page 12: IMPLICATIONS OF A NEW PUHCA FOR...Director Columbus, Ohio August 14, 1992 ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS The authors gratefully acknowledge the comments of Dr. Douglas N. Jones, Mr. Robert E. Burns,
Page 13: IMPLICATIONS OF A NEW PUHCA FOR...Director Columbus, Ohio August 14, 1992 ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS The authors gratefully acknowledge the comments of Dr. Douglas N. Jones, Mr. Robert E. Burns,

CHAPTER 1

INTRODUCTION

The time has come for state public utility commissions (PUCs) to begin preparing

for the day when the Public Utility Holding Company Act (PUHCA) will no longer

severely constrain electric utilities from participating in interstate, nonintegrated power

generation activities. While the debate over the status of PUHCA continues, it is now

likely that major amendments to PUHCA could be enacted into law before the end of

1992. After several years of exhaustive and sometimes bitter debate in Congress, l the

battle over whether PUHCA should be amended is coming to an end with proponents of

change apparently being the victor (see Table 1-1 for a summary of the arguments

presented by participants of the PUHCA debate).2

A new PUHCA would change the structure of the electric industry. Specifically, it

would accelerate the industry's movement away from vertical integration and toward

more competition among power generators. According to proponents of change, a new

1 Major interest groups participating in the PUHCA debate include the electric utility industry (split between "retailers" and "wholesalers"), nonutility generators, state public utility commissions, consumer groups, and the natural gas industry.

2 A list of the benefits and costs of a new PUHCA is contained in U.S. Department of Energy, Analysis of Options to Amend the Public Utility Holding Company Act of 1935, Technical Annex 1 (Washington, D.C.: U.S. Department of Energy, 1991); U.S. General Accounting Office, Electric Supply: Potential Effects of Amending the Public Utility Holding Company Act, GAO/RCED 92-52 (Washington, D.C.: U.S. General Accounting Office, January 1992); Scott Hempling, "Confusing 'Competitors' with 'Competition,'" Public Utilities Fortnightly (March 15, 1991): 30-32; Richard L. Gordon, "The Public Utility Holding Company Act: The Easy Step in Electric Utility Regulatory Reform," Regulation (Winter 1992): 58-65; and Philip R. O'Connor, Wayne P. Olson, and Gerald M. Keenan, PUHCA Reform: Exploding the Myth of Deregulation (Chicago, IL: Palmer Bellevue Corporation, September 1991). The U.S. DOE study estimated a new PUHCA, at the minimum, would reduce the expected capital cost for new generating capacity between $300 million and $1.8 billion per annum by the year 2000.

1

Page 14: IMPLICATIONS OF A NEW PUHCA FOR...Director Columbus, Ohio August 14, 1992 ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS The authors gratefully acknowledge the comments of Dr. Douglas N. Jones, Mr. Robert E. Burns,

TABLE 1 .. 1

MAJOR ARGUMENTS ADVANCED DURING PUHCA DEBATE

Arguments for Amendment:

Increase number of wholesale power producers

Shift power generation to lower-cost sources

Advance competition in electric industry

Move electric industry toward more optimal structure

Shift risk away from retail consumers

Lower entry cost of new producers

Stimulate pressure for more open transmission access

Create more equal competition among wholesale power producers

Source: Authors' construct.

Arguments Against Amendment:

Erode state authority

Diminish coordination (scope) economies

Jeopardize reliability of electric power systems

Enhance self-dealing abuses

Enhance cross-subsidization

PUHCA would facilitate the economical entry of power entrepreneurs, called

"independent power producers," into an industry long dominated by vertically integrated

utilities. New legislation also would allow the access of electric utilities to geographically

dispersed markets. Although as of now the degree of enhanced competition stimulated

2

Page 15: IMPLICATIONS OF A NEW PUHCA FOR...Director Columbus, Ohio August 14, 1992 ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS The authors gratefully acknowledge the comments of Dr. Douglas N. Jones, Mr. Robert E. Burns,

by the entry of new power producers lacks certainty, it is indisputable that the electric

industry ultimately would undergo dramatic changes in part because of a new PUHCA?

The mission of this report is two-fold. First, it will identify those features of new

PUHCA legislation that will most affect the electric industry and regulators. Although at

the time of this writing no legislation has been signed into law, the direction of the

debate along with actual bills passed by the Senate and the House manifests the likely

components of finallegislation.4 A joint House-Senate Conference will reconcile

differences in the two bills.5

Second, and more importantly, this report will examine the implications of a new

PUHCA for regulation. Both the Federal Energy Regulatory Commission (FERC) and

state commissions will face new demands in assuring that the growth in independent

power production will benefit electricity consumers. Identifying these demands as well as

the options available to regulators to deal with them will be this report's major objective.

3 The experiences with independent power production so far suggest that this source of new power is reliable. This should come as no surprise since independents have access to the same technologies and expertise as utilities in constructing and operating power plants. See, for example, U.S. General Accounting Office Electricity Supply: Potential Effects of Amending the Public Utility Holding Company Act; and P. J. Adam, "Reliability of Non-Utility Generation," presented at Electric Utility Business Environment Conference, Denver, Colorado, March 18, 1992.

4 These bills are the U.S. Senate "National Energy Security Act of 1992," S. 2166, 102d Congress, 2d Session (February 19, 1992): and U.S. House of Representatives, "Comprehensive National Energy Policy Act," H.R. 776, l02d Congress, 2d Session (May 27, 1992).

5 At this writing, it is expected that the conference will send out a bill to be signed by the President by early fall of this year.

3

Page 16: IMPLICATIONS OF A NEW PUHCA FOR...Director Columbus, Ohio August 14, 1992 ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS The authors gratefully acknowledge the comments of Dr. Douglas N. Jones, Mr. Robert E. Burns,
Page 17: IMPLICATIONS OF A NEW PUHCA FOR...Director Columbus, Ohio August 14, 1992 ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS The authors gratefully acknowledge the comments of Dr. Douglas N. Jones, Mr. Robert E. Burns,

CHAPTER 2

HISTORICAL OVERVIEW OF PUHCA

The Public Utility Holding Company Act of 1935 was a legislative response to the

consolidation of privately owned electric utilities that rapidly spread during the early

decades of the industry'S existence. Understanding the rationale for PUHCA requires a

knowledge of the events both within and outside the electric industry that took place

prior to its passage. The following provides a brief historical overview of the electric

industry up to 1935.

The Early Days

The late 19th century was a time of innovation, falling energy prices, and high

economic growth. Investors sought the promise of huge profits by financing many of the

inventors who competed to develop practical electrical equipment. Competition came

from all sides within the industry, but the dominant gas companies appeared to be the

new technology's biggest threat. According to Thomas Edison, the gas companies "were

our bitter enemies, keenly watching our every move and ready to pounce upon us at the

slightest failure. ,,1

To combat the infant electric industry, New York's contentious gas firms merged

into Consolidated Gas Company and lowered their prices. Although natural gas would

remain less expensive for almost thirty years, electricity's convenience eventually won it

prominence in the lighting market.

Electrical innovations in late 19th century America sparked not only a

technological transformation but a business revolution as well. For example, the average

incandescent bulb which lasted only 400 hours in 1883 would triple its durability only two

1 Richard Munson, The Power Makers (Emmaus, P A: Rodale Press, 1985), 48.

5

Page 18: IMPLICATIONS OF A NEW PUHCA FOR...Director Columbus, Ohio August 14, 1992 ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS The authors gratefully acknowledge the comments of Dr. Douglas N. Jones, Mr. Robert E. Burns,

years later. 2 Its success created the inducement for numerous entrepreneurs to

manufacture the lamps and generators needed to power them. Within a decade of their

introduction, incandescent lamps lit more than 1.3 million homes and offices throughout

the United States.3

Such innovations created chaos as well as opportunity. Totally unique electrical

arrangements overlapped each other. In Philadelphia alone, more than twenty electric

power systems operated based on different patents by Edison, Sawyer, Maxim,

Westinghouse, Brush, among others.4 Twenty-nine franchises were granted in Chicago,

three of which were citywide.s Some direct current (DC) companies offered electricity

at 100, 110, 220, and 600 volts; alternating current (AC) firms supplied frequencies of 40,

60, 66, 125, and 133 cycles.6 It was said that a customer moving across the street would

often find that none of his electrical appliances worked in the new home.

In an attempt to protect themselves from "ruinous competition," electric utility

executives initially tried to fix prices and production levels. These secret efforts were

eventually denounced by the public and rendered illegal by the Sherman Antitrust Act of

1890.

A more practical step was to merge or consolidate. George Westinghouse built

his electric company by acquiring other people's patents rather than developing his own

inventions. After purchasing the United States Electric Lighting Company (which owned

the then important Maxim and Sawyer lamp patents), Westinghouse even contemplated

cooperation with Edison. But Edison would have no part of sharing his business with a

rival.

2 Ibid., 52.

3 Ibid.

4 Ibid.

S Leonard S. Hyman, America's Electric Utilities: Past, Present, and Future (Arlington, VA: Public Utilities Reports, Inc., 1988), 64.

6 Munson, The Power Makers, 52.

6

Page 19: IMPLICATIONS OF A NEW PUHCA FOR...Director Columbus, Ohio August 14, 1992 ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS The authors gratefully acknowledge the comments of Dr. Douglas N. Jones, Mr. Robert E. Burns,

It was J. P. Morgan who envisioned the largest merger. Having gained effective

control of the Edison General Electric Company, Morgan met with Charles Coffin,

president of the Thompson-Houston Electric company. Coffin, like Westinghouse, had

purchased patent rights and named his company after the Philadelphia professors who

developed them. Coffin expanded Thompson-Houston's business and increased its value

beyond that of Edison General Electric by offering easy credit and by accepting the

securities of local electric companies. The merger of these two companies made both

financial and technological sense because they possessed complementary patent holdings:

Edison General Electric dominated urban DC stations, DC power transmission and

street railways, while Thompson-Houston's forte lay in arc lighting and alternating

currents.7

Despite the bounding engineering advances and optimistic predictions, producing

and delivering electricity remained an infant struggling industry at the turn of the

century. Electric motors powered only one factory in thirteen while incandescent bulbs

illuminated one lamp in twenty. 8

Prospects for growth remained uncertain. Factory owners were reluctant to

displace their steam-powered, belt-driven systems with still-unreliable electric motors.

Most consumers initially favored the less expensive light supplied by gas lamps. Even

electric company executives believed electricity would remain a luxury good without a

mass market. Quickly adding new customers required construction of expensive

distribution systems, which for a time increased the cost of power and decreased the

power company's profits. The favored strategy in the early days was to grow slowly by

encouraging a small number of customers to buy more power at progressively lower

rates.

At that time, "smart" money favored isolated plants over central power stations.

Coaxed by J. P. Morgan and other financiers, the new General Electric Company

7 Ibid., 53.

8 Ibid., 55.

7

Page 20: IMPLICATIONS OF A NEW PUHCA FOR...Director Columbus, Ohio August 14, 1992 ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS The authors gratefully acknowledge the comments of Dr. Douglas N. Jones, Mr. Robert E. Burns,

promoted small-scale systems. These systems could be mass-produced and sold at a

substantial profit to factories and office buildings. At the same time, General Electric

charged inflated prices for its central station equipment to combat competition from

emerging electric companies for its small systems market. As a result, when Edison's

former personal secretary, Samuel Insull, left to manage the Chicago Edison Company in

1892, small-scale systems were the dominant suppliers in the United States. On-site

generators such as streetcar companies, commercial building managers, and industrialists

supplied almost two-thirds of the nation's electricity.9

In addition to competing with isolated electric plants, belt-driven motors, and gas

lamps, electric companies vied with each other. Unlike today's electric utilities,

generating firms did not possess monopoly control over a specific region. For example,

the Denver Common Council granted franchises "to all comers" as long as the companies

did not block public streets.10 Forty-seven generating companies competed in Chicago

alone. 11

Although these electric empires were logical outgrowths of emerging technologies,

they provoked public mistrust and anger. Exclusive control of a given territory remained

Insull's ultimate goal, but he understood the public's mistrust of monopolies. He

suggested a bargain: an exclusive franchise in exchange for public regulation. To avoid

public takeovers and political headaches, Insull promulgated a plan to establish state

regulatory commissions. These commissions were to be staffed with professionals and

operated independent of local politics. Not all of his electric company colleagues agreed

with this idea, however. Nonetheless, in 1907 progressive governors such as Robert M.

La Follette of Wisconsin and Charles Evans Hughes of New York established

9 Ibid., 55.

10 Ibid., 56.

11 Ibid.

8

Page 21: IMPLICATIONS OF A NEW PUHCA FOR...Director Columbus, Ohio August 14, 1992 ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS The authors gratefully acknowledge the comments of Dr. Douglas N. Jones, Mr. Robert E. Burns,

independent regulatory commissions to oversee electric firms. By the end of World War I,

twenty-six states had followed their lead.12

These state commissions transformed competitive electricity suppliers into

regulated public utilities. To eliminate the clutter and expense of duplicative

transmission wires, they gave the new utilities monopoly control of electricity distribution

in defined service territories and offered them the ability to obtain economies of scale

offered by large power plants. By extending previous Supreme Court decisions affecting

railroads, regulators helped to assure electric companies a "fair return" on their

investments.

The Era of Utility Holdin2 Companies

The 1920s represented a roller coaster period for the electric industry. New

technologies made further expansion possible. Larger and more efficient generators

were built and long-distance transmission lines sent power over greater distances.

Expansion was also a deliberate attempt to lower costs through economies of scale.

Indeed, the cost of a kilowatthour from a central power station dropped from 22 cents in

1892 to 7 cents three decades later.13

The industry also saw the massive merging of small operating utilities into a few

large holding companies. Some analysts attributed this restructuring to the potential

scale and coordination economies that could be realized by the formation of large

electric power systems under the umbrella of a single corporate entity. Studies

conducted in the early 1920s showed that significant scale economies could result from

further interconnections of existing electric power systems.14

12 Ibid., 62.

13 Ibid., 56.

14 It was widely recognized in the 1920s and 1930s that large integrated networks were the most economical form of utility structure. Many of the mergers during the 1920s involved the integration of several small operating companies into large holding companies. See William J. Hausman and John L. Neufeld, "Public Policy and the Structure of the Electric Power Industry: Lessons from the Past," presented at the 23rd Annual Conference of the Institute of Public Utilities, Michigan State University, Williamsburg, Virginia, December 10, 1991.

9

Page 22: IMPLICATIONS OF A NEW PUHCA FOR...Director Columbus, Ohio August 14, 1992 ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS The authors gratefully acknowledge the comments of Dr. Douglas N. Jones, Mr. Robert E. Burns,

The 1920s was a period of dramatic growth in demand for electricity. As the

industry looked for ways to attract new capital, it increasingly looked to a holding­

company structure. One author calculated that electric utilities spent more money during

the 1920s than the transcontinental railroads during the era of their most rapid

expansion. 15 By 1932 about half of the privately owned electric industry was controlled

by three "super" holding companies.16 By 1938 when PUHCA was first enforced, there

were 214 registered holding companies.17

Holding companies were successful in acquiring new capital and achieving

integration economies, but they engaged in various abuses. At the request of Congress,

the Federal Trade Commission (FTC) conducted a large-scale study on the "complex and

shadowy" accounting and financial practices of utility holding companies. In a report

issued in 1935, the FTC documented holding-company abuses starting in the 1920s.18

The most noteworthy alleged abuses included "pyramiding" of corporate structure

that allowed large amounts of operating company assets to be controlled by those with

small investments; issuing securities affecting subsidiaries without state approval; abusive

self-dealing in which subsidiaries pay inflated prices for services, materials, and

equipment; shifting costs among subsidiaries located in different states; and excessive

leveraging of debt. The FTC report did concede that "under holding companies [ electric]

service was improved and extended, consumption increased, and costs of production were

reduced."19

15 Thomas Hughes, Networks of Power (Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press, 1983).

16 Douglas W. Hawes, Utility Holding Companies (New York: Clark Boardman Company, 1987), 2-5.

17 Ibid., 2-18.

18 Federal Trade COffiI11ission, Utility Corporations, S. Doc. 92, 70th Congo (1928-1935).

19 Quoted in Munson, The Power Makers, 64.

10

Page 23: IMPLICATIONS OF A NEW PUHCA FOR...Director Columbus, Ohio August 14, 1992 ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS The authors gratefully acknowledge the comments of Dr. Douglas N. Jones, Mr. Robert E. Burns,

Even before the FTC report was completed, however, the utility holding

companies' house of cards had folded. Successful "customer ownership drives" of Insull

had helped the holding companies attract the money needed to acquire other utility

properties. Security prices soared but the good times came to a quick halt. On "Black

Friday," October 29, 1929, stock prices plummeted. Despite the economy's subsequent

collapse, utility stock prices and earnings initially fared better than the rest of the

economy. Part of this was attributable to increasing residential demand for electricity,

but another part to fraud. The Depression did dry up financial capital needed for

capacity expansion, however, forcing holding companies to dramatically extend their

borrowings from banks and to juggle funds among their numerous operating companies.

As the financial crises of the early 1930s intensified, utility holding companies ultimately

failed and the price of their stocks plummeted.

The reported abuses in the 1935 FTC study and large investor losses led to new

federal legislation, providing the political ammunition for drastic changes in the

structuring of the electric industry. The early 1930's debate over PUHCA occurred at a

time when the Roosevelt Administration was pursuing general regulatory reform. For

electric utilities change began when Roosevelt signed into law the Rural Electrification

Act, which provided low-cost loans to public cooperatives that built their own power

lines and generated their own electricity. The "New Dealers" created the Securities and

Exchange Commission (SEC) to protect investors against deceptive practices and a series

of banking acts to prohibit commercial banks from having investment banking affiliates.

Legislation such as the Federal Power Act, the Natural Gas Act, and the Federal

Communications Act all were enacted during the 1930s. These acts, similar to PUHCA,

helped to close jurisdictional gaps in regulation. During the 1930s legislation also

strengthened the position of pUblic-power entities (for example, the Tennessee Valley

Authority and the Bonneville Power Administration), and rural electric cooperatives.

The general belief was that privately owned utilities could not be relied upon to ensure

the wide distribution of low-priced power, especially to rural areas.

Enacted in 1935 (although not enforced until 1938) PUHCA ushered in two

significant changes in the electric industry (see Table 2-1 for the broad SEC regulations

11

Page 24: IMPLICATIONS OF A NEW PUHCA FOR...Director Columbus, Ohio August 14, 1992 ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS The authors gratefully acknowledge the comments of Dr. Douglas N. Jones, Mr. Robert E. Burns,

TABLE 2ml

SEC JURISDICTION OVER UTILITY HOLDING COMPANIES

Producer

Registered utility holding companies

Exempt utility holding companies

Source: Authors' construct.

Regulations

approval of utility acquisition and vertically nonutility acquisitions

approval of service, sales, and construction contracts and other activities between holding company and affiliates

• restriction of acquisitions to utility-related businesses (mostly to facilities integrated with existing utility system)

approval of corporate and financial structures

approval of securities sales

approval of acquisition of 5 percent or more of another utility'S securities

monitoring of activities by reviewing annual SEC filings and industry publications

following PUHCA). First, it gave state public utility commissions the de facto ability to

regulate electric utilities as prescribed by state statutes. Prior to the passage of

PUHCA, although state commissions may have had jurisdiction over operating electric

companies, no regulatory entity oversaw the activities of highly complex holding

companies that controlled and often exploited their operating companies. By simplifying

holding companies' corporate and financial structures and by restricting their utility

12

Page 25: IMPLICATIONS OF A NEW PUHCA FOR...Director Columbus, Ohio August 14, 1992 ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS The authors gratefully acknowledge the comments of Dr. Douglas N. Jones, Mr. Robert E. Burns,

operations to a single geographical area, PUHCA allowed state commissions to regulate

more effectively.

Second, PUHCA achieved its objective of restructuring the electric industry.

Under its so-called "death clause," the Act eliminated all holding companies that did not

operate as an integrated electric power system. As proof, in 1938 there were 214

registered holding companies; by 1955, when the Securities and Exchange Commission

had largely completed its job of dissolving and reorganizing the registered holding

companies, there were twenty-five registered systems with 171 utility subsidiaries and 137

nonutility subsidiaries; today, the number of registered holding companies is nine.20

During the first twenty years after the passage of PUHCA, registered holding

companies divested themselves of 839 subsidiaries with assets of nearly $13 billion.21

Only those holding companies that demonstrated efficient operation of a single,

integrated multistate electric power system were left intact.

In SUfi, PUHCA reorganized the electric industry in a way that allowed regulators

to perform their designated task more effectively. The industry today for the most part

consists of intrastate utilities owning and controlling functionally and geographically

integrated power systems. PUHCA may have constrained the electric industry from

structuring more efficiently. In the absence of PUHCA, the electric industry today

probably would be less vertically integrated and be less subject to state regulation.

20 These are: Allegheny Power System, American Electric Power Company, Central and South West Corporation, Eastern Utilities Associates, Entergy Corporation, General Public Utilities Corporation, New England Electric System, Northeast Utilities, and the Southern Company. Registered holding companies account for about 25 percent of the electricity generated in the United States.

As of 1991, there were 110 exempt electric utility holding companies. They account for over 50 percent of the electricity generated in the United States. See U.S. General Accounting Office, Electricity Supply: Regulating Utility Holding Companies in a Changing Electric Industry (Washington, D.C.: U.S. General Accounting Office, April 1992).

21 Hawes, Utility Holding Companies, 2-18.

13

Page 26: IMPLICATIONS OF A NEW PUHCA FOR...Director Columbus, Ohio August 14, 1992 ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS The authors gratefully acknowledge the comments of Dr. Douglas N. Jones, Mr. Robert E. Burns,

Later Events

The current debate on PUHCA can trace its origins to 1978 and the Public

Utilities Regulatory Policies Act (PURP A), which was in part a response to the unstable

energy conditions of the 1970s.22 The electric utility enjoyed a "golden age" in the two

decades following World War II, but by the end of the 1970s, events had evidenced an

erosion in the electric industry's ability to provided energy efficiently.

First came the Northeast Blackout of 1965, followed by Consolidated Edison's

omission of its common stock dividend in April 1974, the accident at Three Mile Island

in March 1979, as well as the construction cost overruns, prudence reviews, and

abandonments of nuclear plants in the 1980s. The problems raised by the inflation of

the 1970s and later the increasingly costly safety changes required in the wake of TMI

created a quandary for legislators and regulators. One response was to mandate

incentives for cogeneration and small power production.

As nonutility power producers began to increase in number and compete with

(not merely supplement) established integrated electric utilities, transmission access grew

as an important issue. Congress first considered provisions for expanding transmission

access in the debate over PURP A and again when it passed the Electric Consumers

Protection Act in 1986. But these provisions were never included in the legislation.

Power "shortages" during the summer of 1988 refocused attention on the need for

additional generation in some parts of the country. The debate in Congress over how to

"fix" the industry and whether amending PUHCA was part of that solution dragged on

over the next four years. Recent events, however, galvanized Congress' determination to

produce some sort of comprehensive energy legislation which included amending

PUHCA. The United States' involvement in the 1990-91 Gulf War appeared to some

critics to be triggered by a national energy strategy of "import oil." Fearing that an anti-

22 As a factual observation, the SEC in the early 1980s urged the repeal of PUHCA on grounds that the Act had achieved its purpose and was no longer necessary.

14

Page 27: IMPLICATIONS OF A NEW PUHCA FOR...Director Columbus, Ohio August 14, 1992 ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS The authors gratefully acknowledge the comments of Dr. Douglas N. Jones, Mr. Robert E. Burns,

incumbent whiplash would result from a perceived failure to enact some sort of

comprehensive legislation, Congressional leaders pushed the PUHCA debate on through

1992. When the electric utility industry began to split over the status of PUHCA, the

prospects for amendment grew significantly.

15

Page 28: IMPLICATIONS OF A NEW PUHCA FOR...Director Columbus, Ohio August 14, 1992 ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS The authors gratefully acknowledge the comments of Dr. Douglas N. Jones, Mr. Robert E. Burns,
Page 29: IMPLICATIONS OF A NEW PUHCA FOR...Director Columbus, Ohio August 14, 1992 ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS The authors gratefully acknowledge the comments of Dr. Douglas N. Jones, Mr. Robert E. Burns,

CHAPTER 3

POWER GENERATORS IN THE ELECTRIC INDUSTRY

Recent Changes

Passage of the Public Utility Regulatory Policies Act of 1978 (PURPA) initiated a

series of events that reshaped the structure of the electric industry. A changing

perception induced in part by PURP A's success was that smaller-scale generating

facilities owned and operated by nonutilities could provide the nation with an economical

source of new capacity.1

During the past decade PURP A-qualifying facilities have produced over 31,000

megawatts of generating capacity, or about 25 percent of new capacity.2 The U.S.

Department of Energy and others predict that the country will require an additional

100,000 to 150,000 megawatts of new generating capacity by the year 2000.3 Assuming a

new PUHCA and the elimination of other major barriers to independent power

generation, as much as 50 percent of this new capacity may come from nonutilities.4

1 See, for example, Paul L. Joskow, "Expanding Competitive Opportunities in Electricity Generation," Regulation (Winter 1992): 25-37; and Council of Economic Advisors, Economic Report of the President (Washington, D.C.: U.S. Government Printing Office, February 1992), 178-80.

2 "Consensus Reached Among Diverse Group of Electric Power Suppliers and Consumers for PUHCA Amendment," NARUC No. 40-1990, (Washington, D.C.: National Association of Regulatory Utility Commissioners, October 1, 1990), 20.

3 Ibid.

4 See, for example, Jerry L. Pfeffer, '''Megatrends' in the Electric Power Industry: Toward the Year 2000," presented at Electric Utility Business Environment Conference, Denver, Colorado, March 18, 1992; and "EEl Sees No Shortages, Increasing Reliance on DSM Programs and NUGs," Electric Utility Week (December 9, 1991): 7-8.

One example of a major barrier is obstructions to widespread transmission access. Other barriers are discussed in Chapter 6.

17

Page 30: IMPLICATIONS OF A NEW PUHCA FOR...Director Columbus, Ohio August 14, 1992 ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS The authors gratefully acknowledge the comments of Dr. Douglas N. Jones, Mr. Robert E. Burns,

Electricity markets increasingly gravitate toward smaller generating facilities, in

part because of lower load growth and the increasing uncertainties over future electricity

demand and construction costs for large generating facilities. By allowing producers

more flexibility, small facilities diminish the risks of unexpected events. Smaller-scale

generating facilities also have benefitted from recent technological advancements. Until

recently, technological advances in the electric industry have disproportionally benefitted

large-scale facilities.5

The trend in the electric industry toward smaller and less capital-intensive

generating facilities with shorter construction lead times reflects a rational response to

economic realities. The dismal record of electric utilities building new nuclear power

plants during the 1970s and 1980s points to the risks associated with power plants large

in scale but apparently immature in technology.6 Further, it illustrates the increased

incentive for participants to restructure the electric industry so smaller-scale facilities can

compete more equally with other generating facilities. The recent popularity of state­

approved power procurement and least-cost energy planning mechanisms partially

exemplifies the state regulators' perception of the potentially high risks associated with

large-scale generating facilities.?

Other factors have also contributed to the current push toward restructuring the

electric industry. Charles Stalon and Reinier Lock point to the changed macroeconomic

and energy-market conditions (for example, high interest and inflation rates, stagnant

5 See Paul L. 10skow and Richard Schmalensee, Markets for Power: An Analysis of Electric Utility Deregulation (Cambridge, MA: The MIT Press, 1983).

6 See Martin B. Zimmerman, "Learning Effects and the Commercialization of New Energy Technologies: the Case of Nuclear Power," The Bell Journal of Economics 13 no. 2 (Autumn 1982): 297-310. Zimmerman blames the lack of understanding of the basic nuclear-power technology as a major reason for the problems experienced by the utility industry during the 1970s.

? The popularity of power procurement mechanisms is demonstrated in Kenneth Rose, Robert E. Burns, and Mark Eifert, Implementing a Competitive Bidding Program for Electric Power Supply (Columbus, OR: The National Regulatory Research Institute, 1991).

18

Page 31: IMPLICATIONS OF A NEW PUHCA FOR...Director Columbus, Ohio August 14, 1992 ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS The authors gratefully acknowledge the comments of Dr. Douglas N. Jones, Mr. Robert E. Burns,

technological advancements, and volatile fuel prices) beginning during the 1970s which

rate-of-return regulation poorly addressed.8 When utility costs started to rise sharply

and quickly, regulators were faced with either allowing utilities to fully recover their

increased costs at the disdain of ratepayers or not allowing full recovery, which would

jeopardize a utility's financial position. While regulators searched hard to balance the

interests of ratepayers and utility shareholders, they faced a "Catch-22" situation over

which they had little control. The fallout that resulted caused ratepayers and utilities

alike to be skeptical of the prevailing order. The general public through their political

representatives increasingly began to believe that more competition could help control

electricity prices while utilities questioned whether there was an easier way to make

profits (for example, by repositioning their assets to serve markets subject to less

stringent regulation). Both groups started to accept the idea that restructuring of the

electric industry would be a potentially acceptable alternative to the status quo.9

Different Power Generators

Table 3-1 lists the commonly identified categories of power generators currently

operating in the electric industry. (See Table 3-2 for attributes of each major class of

8 Charles G. Stalon and Reinier H. J. H. Lock, "State-Federal Relations in the Economic Regulation of Energy," Yale Journal on Regulation 7 no. 2 (Summer 1990): 427-97.

9 Another way of expressing this thought, according to the economic theory of regulation, is that restructuring will occur whenever changes either in political power or market conditions dissipate much of the benefits of the status quo to market participants. See Sam Peltzman, "The Economic Theory of Regulation after a Decade of Deregulation," Martin Neil Baily and Clifford Winston, eds., Brookings Papers on Economic Activity: Microeconomics 1989 (Washington, D.C.: The Brookings Institution, 1989), 1-59.

19

Page 32: IMPLICATIONS OF A NEW PUHCA FOR...Director Columbus, Ohio August 14, 1992 ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS The authors gratefully acknowledge the comments of Dr. Douglas N. Jones, Mr. Robert E. Burns,

TABLE 3-1

DIFFERENT CATEGORIES OF POWER GENERATORS

where

where

and

Total Generators (TG) = Nonutility Generator (NU Gs) + Rate Based Generators (REGs)

NUGs = Qualifying Facilities (QFs) + Nonqualifying Facilities (NQFs)

QFs = Cogenerators (CGs) + Small Power Producers (SPPs)

NQFs = True Independent Generators (TIGs) + Utility Affiliated Generators (UAGs)

Source: Authors' construct.

20

Page 33: IMPLICATIONS OF A NEW PUHCA FOR...Director Columbus, Ohio August 14, 1992 ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS The authors gratefully acknowledge the comments of Dr. Douglas N. Jones, Mr. Robert E. Burns,

N ~

TABLE 3-2

CHARACTERISTICS OF DIFFERENT POWER GENERATORS

Power Generator

ill PURP A Qualifying Facilities (QFs)

.. True Independent Generators (TIGs)

• Utility_Affiliated Generators (UAUs)

• Rate Based Generators

SOllrCe: Authors' construct.

Pricing (jurisdictional regulator)

• Avoided cost (PU Cs )

ill Competitive bidding price (PUCs)

• Market based (FERC)

III Cost of service (FERC)

III Market based (FERC)

• Cost of service (PU Cs)

• Cost of service (FERC)

Comments

• ExemRt from PUHCA (not greater than "'30 megawatts)

4& Guaranteed market and price

1& 50 percent utility ownership limit

ill rovver r.redotp.inantly for local sale or Interna , on-sIte use

1& Nonexempt from PUHCA

• Cornp,etes with other wholesale suppIiers

1& No limit on utility ownership

• Little chance of market power

• Nonexempt from PUHCA

• COIDp,etes with other wholesale suppIiers

• No limit on utility ownership

• Potential problem of market power

III Spinoffs nonexempt from PUHCA

• Subject to traditional regulation

• Exclusively utility owners

• Po"ver primarily sold to retail customers under traditional ratemaking

Page 34: IMPLICATIONS OF A NEW PUHCA FOR...Director Columbus, Ohio August 14, 1992 ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS The authors gratefully acknowledge the comments of Dr. Douglas N. Jones, Mr. Robert E. Burns,

power generator).l0 Generators consist of two general types, ratebased generators and

nonutility generators. Ratebased generators (RBGs) produce most of their power for

wholesale requirements and retail consumers.l1 They are subject to either state or

federal regulation and their costs generally are recoverable from customers by cost-of­

service ratemaking.12

Nonutility generators include PURPA-qualifying facilities (QFs) and nonqualifying

facilities (NQFs). Power produced from PURPA-qualifying facilities, namely

cogenerators (CGs) and small power producers (SPPs), is typically priced on the basis of

the local utility's avoided cost. All available power produced by QFs must be purchased

by the local utility.

Nonqualifying facilities, in contrast, have no guaranteed market; they must sell

their power at a price competitive with other options accessible to a utility and other

buyers. The price received by NQFs is based either on market conditions or the

producer's cost of service.13

Nonqualifying facilities include true independent generators (TIGs) and utility

affiliated generators (UAFs). The essential difference between the two generators lies in

10 A similar breakdown of power generators is presented in Bernard W. Tenenbaum and J. Stephen Henderson, "Market-Based Pricing of Wholesale Electric Services," The Electricity Journal 4 no. 10 (December 1991), 42.

11 Wholesale requirements buyers usually are utilities that own little or no generating capacity. They most frequently are either municipalities or rural electric cooperatives located within the control area of the selling utility.

12 A portion of many ratebased facilities is used to sell coordination power in wholesale markets. A utility selling such power has temporary surplus capacity that can be used to generate power for other than native-load customers. In most circumstances, FERC allows the transactors of coordination power to negotiate a mutually agreed price and other terms and conditions (assuming that market power is not a problem). A commonly used pricing practice for transactions is the "split-the-savings" approach (that is, price is set halfway between the seller's incremental cost and the buyer's avoided cost).

13 As discussed later, the pricing method allowed by FERC depends on the degree of market power that is assumed to be held by a producer.

22

Page 35: IMPLICATIONS OF A NEW PUHCA FOR...Director Columbus, Ohio August 14, 1992 ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS The authors gratefully acknowledge the comments of Dr. Douglas N. Jones, Mr. Robert E. Burns,

their potential to exercise market power. True independents by definition have no retail

franchises, no affiliation with vertically integrated utilities, and no transmission facilities.

Their profits and survival potential depend on their ability to provide wholesale markets

with competitively priced, highly reliable power.14 Power production from nonqualifying

facilities currently is small. For example, only five such facilities were operating in

1991.15

Mfiliated generators represent less of an opportunity to foster competition,

contingent upon their ability and incentive to self-deal with a parent company that

controls transmission lines and serves core retail ratepayers. The category "nonqualifying

facilities" (assuming that they sell only to wholesale consumers) is identical to the

meaning of "exempt wholesale generators" (EWGs) in the recently passed Senate energy

legislation.16 Currently, most of the power produced from nonutility generators comes

from PURP A-qualifying facilities. An expected and supposedly desirable outcome of

14 With the emergence of nondiscriminatory transmission access, independent power producers may not require long-term power contracts to enter the marketplace. Open transmission access may create an environment for a highly developed spot market for power while at the same time it may increase the costs to both producers and buyers of limiting themselves to long-term contracts.

It is questionable how purchased power contracts over the next few years will allocate risks between independent power producers and utility buyers. Passing all of the risk onto the producers, while protecting utility ratepayers, may jeopardize the financial viability of the independent power industry in the long run. At the other end, state regulators and bond rating agencies have expressed some concern that independent producers and lenders have successfully transferred risks back to utilities and their ratepayers. For example, many existing long-term purchased power contracts between a nonutility generator and a utility contain "minimum take" provisions and fuel price indexation clauses that pass most fuel-price risk to the utility. See Edward P. Kahn, "Risks in Independent Power Contracts: An Empirical Survey," The Electricity Journal 4 no. 9 (November 1991): 30-45.

15 U.S. General Accounting Office, Electricity Supply: Regulating Utility Holding Companies in a Changing Electric Industry (Washington, D.C.: U.S. General Accounting Office, April 1992), 5.

16 In the House bill these generators are called "independent power producers," who operate facilities that generate power exclusively for wholesale markets as well.

23

Page 36: IMPLICATIONS OF A NEW PUHCA FOR...Director Columbus, Ohio August 14, 1992 ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS The authors gratefully acknowledge the comments of Dr. Douglas N. Jones, Mr. Robert E. Burns,

PUHCA amendments would be a shifting of nonutility power production from PURP A­

qualifying facilities to nonqualifying facilities. Federal regulations exempt most PURPA­

qualifying facilities from PUHCA.17

How a New PUHCA Would Affect Different Power Generators

PUHCA has discouraged the formation of wholesale power facilities that do not

qualify under PURP A. Wholesale power facilities are defined as "electric utilities" under

PUHCA and generally are financed under a holding company structure.18 Both utilities

and nonutilities wanting an interest in such facilities, consequently, are restricted by

PUHCA (see Table 3_3).19

PUHCA generally has precluded both registered and exempt holding companies

from having an interest (ownership or operation) in wholesale power facilities located in

states outside their franchised service area. As a general rule, the SEC would only

approve acquisitions of those facilities integrated with existing utility operations and

confined to a single area. Exempt holding companies would retain their status only

when they acquire a wholesale facility that integrates with their existing intrastate utility

operation or when the utility business functionally relates to the nonutility business and

represents a small part of the holding company's income.2o The SEC also may approve

17 FERC has exercised its authority under section 210( e) of the Public Utility Regulatory Act of 1978 (PURP A) to exempt cogenerators and small power producers of 30 megawatts or less as well as producers of 80 megawatts or less using biomass as the primary fuel (45 Federal Register 12214, 12232-12233 (February 25, 1980».

18 By forming a separate subsidiary, rather than a separate division, the owner avoids liability for its existing businesses. As utilities they also would favor forming a subsidiary to prevent regulators from transferring profits to ratepayers in the form of lower rates.

19 Any legal entity becomes a utility holding company when it gains control of 10 percent or more of an electric or gas utility (Public Utility Holding Company Act, section 2(a)(3).)

20 See, for example, Public Utility Holding Company Act, section 3(a)(3) (the "only incidentally holding companies" exemption).

24

Page 37: IMPLICATIONS OF A NEW PUHCA FOR...Director Columbus, Ohio August 14, 1992 ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS The authors gratefully acknowledge the comments of Dr. Douglas N. Jones, Mr. Robert E. Burns,

TABLE 3-3

PUHCA RESTRICTIONS ON FORMING WHOLESALE POWER FACILITIES

Entity

Registered Holding Companies:

Exempt Holding Companies:

Operating Utilities:

Nonutility Firms:

PURPA Qualifying Facilities:

Source: Authors' construct.

Current Restriction

Mainly prohibited, unless wholesale power subsidiary integrated with existing utility system*

Limited to geographical area of affiliated operating utilities or else either luay lose exemption status or be prohibited

Status of utilities changed to utility holding company (exempt or registered) subject to SEC regulations

Controlling interests defined as utility holding companies (exempt or registered) subject to SEC regulations

None (for QFs not greater than 30 megawatts)

* This assumes that the holding company gains control of 10 percent or more of the voting securities.

an acquisition when the holding company is predominantly a utility whose operations are

wholly within one state or in contiguous states.21

21 Public Utility Holding Company Act, section 3(a)(1) (the "predominantly intrastate" exemption). The vast majority of the 110 exempt utility holding companies qualify under this section of the Act.

25

Page 38: IMPLICATIONS OF A NEW PUHCA FOR...Director Columbus, Ohio August 14, 1992 ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS The authors gratefully acknowledge the comments of Dr. Douglas N. Jones, Mr. Robert E. Burns,

An operating utility that falls outside a holding-company structure also confronts

restrictions in having interest in a wholesale power facility. It would be subject to SEC

regulations as a newly formed utility holding company, thereby restricted from forming

wholesale facilities in different areas unless integrated as a single utility operation.

Nonutility firms such as engineering firms and construction companies would

become utility holding companies any time they have an interest in a wholesale power

facility. This would limit both their development of wholesale facilities to one area and

their diversification into other nonutility businesses. In the case where they would not

receive exempt holding company status from the SEC, they would be required to divest

nonutility activities.22

Most PURPA-qualifying facilities are exempt from PUHCA. Utilities (including

utility holding companies), however, generally are limited to 50 percent ownership

interest in such facilities.23 PURPA explicitly says that an entity (for example, an

electric utility or its affiliates) cannot own a qualifying facility that is "primarily engaged"

in the sale or generation of electricity. In rules adopted in 1980, FERC interpreted the

term "owned" to mean having more than a 50 percent equity interest in a qualifying

facility. FERC has broadly interpreted "primarily engaged" as "any person ... which sells

electric energy [other than electric energy from QFs]." This person would be considered

an "electric utility" under PURP A and therefore limited to 50 percent ownership of a

qualifying facility. FERC, however, has allowed exceptions to this rule where an entity

received an exemption from PUH CA as being "not primarily engaged in electric power

generation or sales."

The new PUHCA would eliminate SEC oversight of both utilities and nonutility

firms acquiring wholesale power facilities. It would end the advantage currently given to

most PURP A qualifying facilities because of their exemption from PUHCA. For

22 The SEC has required that a nonutility in seeking an exemption under section 3(a)(3) of PUHCA must not only show that it is primarily engaged in nonutility business (for example, it receives less than 10 percent of its revenues from utility operations) but also that the utility business is "functionally related" to the nonutility business.

23 example, FERC has on occasion allowed exceptions to the 50 percent rule when an entity previously obtained an exemption from the SEC as being "not primarily engaged in electric power generation or sales."

26

Page 39: IMPLICATIONS OF A NEW PUHCA FOR...Director Columbus, Ohio August 14, 1992 ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS The authors gratefully acknowledge the comments of Dr. Douglas N. Jones, Mr. Robert E. Burns,

example, utility holding companies and operating utilities can have an interest in PURPA

qualifying facilities without regard to their geographical location. The substantial capital

and entrepreneurial efforts that have gone into cogeneration may have otherwise been

diverted to other, more efficient, generation facilities if all wholesale operations were

considered equal in the eyes of PUHCA. On the other hand, it can be argued that the

50 percent utility ownership limitation applied to PURP A qualifying facilities has likely

discouraged some development of these facilities. It seems that with a new PUHCA,

nonqualifying facilities will have an advantage because of the ownership restrictions on

qualifying facilities, assuming other things are equal. Other things often are not equal,

however; for example, PURPA bestows favors on qualifying facilities unavailable to

other facilities--most importantly, it assures a market for qualifying facilities. Other

wholesale power facilities do not have such a luxury; they must participate with other

producers in a marketplace that has become more competitive.

A new PUHCA also may allow utilities to spin off ratebased facilities as exempt

wholesale facilities.24 Utilities may see more future profits coming from existing

facilities that are subject to FERC regulation than state regulation. Especially if the

spun-off facility receives FERC approval for charging market-based prices, utilities may

find it more lucrative to dedicate some of their existing facilities to wholesale markets.

This would especially be true for depreciated facilities earning the utility small

returns.25 In such a situation, where the book cost of a facility lies below the market

24 As noted later, the House bill would prohibit such activities by excluding existing ratebased facilities from eligibility as exempt facilities.

25 Dedicating existing facilities to wholesale markets would mean that these facilities would no longer be ratebased and subject to state regulation. A utility would favor such action when it expects to earn a higher profit (adjusted for risk) from selling in the more competitive wholesale markets than from selling directly to retail customers under cost­of-service regulation. Although the price for power generated by dedicated wholesale facilities would be regulated by FERC, none of the seller's profits would be distributed to retail customers. This is because these customers are no longer paying any of the costs associated with the dedicated facilities. From a social perspective dedication may be attractive since the seller would have a strong incentive to sell power anytime it receives a price greater than its marginal cost as well as to minimize its cost of operation. The second incentive assumes that the price is divorced from the seller's cost of service (for example, FERC allows market-based prices).

27

Page 40: IMPLICATIONS OF A NEW PUHCA FOR...Director Columbus, Ohio August 14, 1992 ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS The authors gratefully acknowledge the comments of Dr. Douglas N. Jones, Mr. Robert E. Burns,

value, a utility would have the incentive to transfer the facility to a market-priced regime.

The problem for retail customers is that they would lose the benefits of low-cost

electricity which they in effect previously paid for during the earlier years of the facility's

life.

28

Page 41: IMPLICATIONS OF A NEW PUHCA FOR...Director Columbus, Ohio August 14, 1992 ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS The authors gratefully acknowledge the comments of Dr. Douglas N. Jones, Mr. Robert E. Burns,

CHAPTER 4

THE IMPLICATIONS OF A NEW PUHCA FOR RETAIL CONSUMERS

A more lenient PUHCA would ease the entry of new generators into the electric

industry. Nonutility and utility entities alike would have the freedom to own interests in

wholesale power facilities in different parts of the country without the restrictions of

PUHCA. Wholesale power producers, including utility affiliates, currently could avoid

all SEC regulations under PUHCA, for example, by shifting their roles from a general

partner during financing and construction to a limited partner when plant operations

begin. One problem with this approach revolves around choosing a general partner who

is competent and trustworthy. Another option is for no partner to have more than a 10

percent voting interest in a facility.l

Assuming that the current PUHCA has discouraged the entry of wholesale power

producers, utilities would have more options from which to choose to satisfy their future

demand needs. New supply sources, by and of themselves, should give utilities the

opportunity to lower their future costs. As a matter of practice, however, the possibility

for anticompetitive actions by utilities makes it less than certain that a new PUHCA

would benefit retail consumers.2

Both FERC and state public utility commissions would play important roles in

affecting the benefits to retail consumers. FERC would face more requests from

wholesale producers to approve market-based rates. The ability of FERC to allow such

1 Options to avoid becoming a holding company are discussed in Kenneth Rose, Robert E. Burns, and Mark Eifert, Implementing a Competitive Bidding Program for Electric Power Supply (Columbus, OH: The National Regulatory Research Institute, 1991), 86-88. The authors distinguish these options from those that allow a holding company to qualify as an exempt holding company.

2 As discussed later, these actions include self-dealing abuses, cross-subsidization, and collusive arrangements among utilities.

29

Page 42: IMPLICATIONS OF A NEW PUHCA FOR...Director Columbus, Ohio August 14, 1992 ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS The authors gratefully acknowledge the comments of Dr. Douglas N. Jones, Mr. Robert E. Burns,

rates only for those transactions consummated under workably competitive conditions

will influence the benefits to retail consumers.3

At the state level, commissions would have to determine with greater frequency

whether long-term wholesale purchases by jurisdictional utilities represent least-cost

resource options. Utilities should have available more resource options from which to

choose. They, as well as their regulators, must decide whether these new available

resources represent least-cost options. Faced with the prospect of increased requests for

self-dealing transactions, commissions would have to devote greater time and effort to

assuring that such transactions do not entail an abusive arrangement.4 Greater numbers

of utilities also would likely request approval to form subsidiaries and spin off existing

generating facilities as exempt wholesale generators. Under the Senate bill, spinoffs of

facilities by utility holding companies and operating utilities will require approval from

state commissions, or, for existing affiliates of registered holding companies, from the

SEC. Commissions, in response, must examine the effects these actions will have on

retail consumers. For example, allowing the formation of subsidiaries may impose risks

that would increase the utility's cost of capital and improperly shift costs to the utility's

operating company.5 The entry of new wholesale producers enhances the economic

3 FERC is likely to adopt generic rules during the next several months on eligibility for market-based pricing by wholesale power producers. Past criteria used by FERC on a case-by-case basis for the acceptability of market-based pricing are discussed in Bernard W. Tenenbaum and J. Stephen Henderson, "Market-Based Pricing of Wholesale Electric Services," The Electricity Journal 4 no. 10 (December 1991): 30-45. It is expected that the rules will follow closely the criteria applied by FERC in recent decisions.

4 This assumes that the states have the authority and are willing to allow self-dealing transactions involving exempt wholesale power producers.

5 These risks are discussed in detail in Robert E. Burns et aI., Regulating Electric Utilities with Subsidiaries (Columbus, OH: The National Regulatory Research Institute, 1986). Although the study showed that the vast majority of states have procedures in place directed at mitigating these risks, their ability to do so remains doubtful. For example, the study concluded that:

A particularly difficult common cost allocation problem faced by commissions is to distinguish an operating utility's cost of capital from that of its subsidiaries. When an electric utility has subsidiaries or is itself owned by a parent company, its capital is likely to be intermingled with the capital of the other entities (p. v).

30

Page 43: IMPLICATIONS OF A NEW PUHCA FOR...Director Columbus, Ohio August 14, 1992 ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS The authors gratefully acknowledge the comments of Dr. Douglas N. Jones, Mr. Robert E. Burns,

performance of the electric industry only when these producers can generate electricity at

a lower cost. This means producers are able to outperform other producers such as

vertically integrated utilities and PURP A qualifying facilities. Reasons for this include

lower construction and fuel costs, the adoption of more economical technologies, and

plants operating at higher technical efficiencies.6 By producing at lower cost, new

entrants can pressure other producers to act more efficiently. Wholesale buyers

therefore would have access to lower-cost power, which presumably would flow through

to retail consumers in the form of lower rates.

The potential for retail consumers to benefit from the entry of new producers

does not necessarily imply this will happen. The outcome will depend in part on the

success of regulators in protecting consumers from the possibility of abusive dealings and

other actions between exempt wholesale generators and affiliated utilities. Potential

abuses resulting from self-dealing, cross-subsidization, and spinning off existing low-cost

facilities loom as real risks that could undermine the benefits of a new PUHCA for retail

consumers. Whether commissions would be able to protect retail consumers against

these practices represents a major challenge.7

6 See, for example, Roger F. Naill and William C. Dudley, "IPP Leveraged Financing: Unfair Advantage?" Public Utilities Fortnightly (January 15, 1992): 15-18. The authors present persuasive reasons for why independent power producers would be expected to perform better than tightly regulated utilities. They argue that independents need to control their costs to win contracts and make profits. As an illustration, independents have an incentive to achieve higher plant availability since their profits would increase; for regulated utilities, higher plant availability usually means lower rates but not higher profits.

7 See, for example, Burns et aI., Regulating Electric Utilities with Subsidiaries; and U.S. General Accounting Office, Electric Supply: Potential Effects of Amending the Public Utility Holding Company Act. The GAO study concluded that states have considerable experience in monitoring and regulating utilities' wholesale power transactions. For example, most states have procedures to prevent utility holding companies from allocating improper expenses to a utility subsidiary. Most states have, in addition, the authority to regulate power-plant spinoffs to a nonutilty subsidiary.

31

Page 44: IMPLICATIONS OF A NEW PUHCA FOR...Director Columbus, Ohio August 14, 1992 ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS The authors gratefully acknowledge the comments of Dr. Douglas N. Jones, Mr. Robert E. Burns,

A new PUHCA likely would increase the pressure for open transmission access to

wholesale power producers.8 New producers, whether independent or utility affiliated,

would seek to broaden the markets for their power. They would request transmission

system owners to transport their power to those buyers willing to give the most favorable

terms. In sum, independents would be expected to make unilateral petitions for gaining

transmission access.

Utility affiliates would also benefit from open transmission access; in exchange for

this right, their parent companies may reciprocate by providing more liberalized

transmission access to other utilities and affiliates.9 ~AJthough there is some question of

whether retail consumers would benefit immediately from increased wholesale

transmission, it is likely that in the long term they would.lO With utility buyers having

more choices over sources of firm power in addition to the expected increase in

competition in wholesale markets, their revenue requirements should fall below what

they otherwise would be.

Benefits of a new PUHCA to retail consumers would depend both on the

performance of additional wholesale power producers drawn into the marketplace and

on the actions of FERC and state commissions (see Table 4-1). A world in which

8 There seems to be a growing consensus that open transmission access will become a reality by the end of this decade through a combination of voluntary utility actions, FERC initiatives and incentives, antitrust lawsuits, and new legislation. See Jerry L. Pfeffer, '''Megatrends' in the Electric Power Industry: Toward the Year 2000" presented at Electric Utility Business Environment Conference, Denver, Colorado, March 18, 1992.

9 In a similar vein, some utilities have "bargained" with FERC for the opportunity to sell wholesale power at market-based prices in return for more open access to their transmission systems. For example, Public Service of Indiana recently received approval from FERC to price 450 megawatts of wholesale power at market prices in return for granting both utility and independent suppliers greater access to its transmission system.

10 Retail consumers may suffer in the near term. For example, giving wheeling priority to third parties over economy purchases may harm native-load customers. This would happen when the lost savings from foregone economy purchases exceed the transmission revenues paid by third parties that are returned to native-load customers.

32

Page 45: IMPLICATIONS OF A NEW PUHCA FOR...Director Columbus, Ohio August 14, 1992 ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS The authors gratefully acknowledge the comments of Dr. Douglas N. Jones, Mr. Robert E. Burns,

TABLE 4-1

FACTORS OF BENEFITS TO RETAIL CONSUMERS

1. The entry of low-cost wholesale power producers

2. Competitiveness of wholesale power with other resource options available to utility buyers

3. Ability of FERC to approve "just and reasonable" wholesale rates

4. Ability of commissions to approve least-cost wholesale power purchases

5. Enhanced pressure to liberalize transmission access sales for wholesale producers

Source: Authors' construct.

regulators are successful in preventing anticompetitive actions and new independent

power producers are highly efficient would likely produce large benefits to retail

consumers. On the other hand, the converse of these conditions would produce minimal

benefits or, more unlikely, impose a cost on retail consumers.

33

Page 46: IMPLICATIONS OF A NEW PUHCA FOR...Director Columbus, Ohio August 14, 1992 ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS The authors gratefully acknowledge the comments of Dr. Douglas N. Jones, Mr. Robert E. Burns,
Page 47: IMPLICATIONS OF A NEW PUHCA FOR...Director Columbus, Ohio August 14, 1992 ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS The authors gratefully acknowledge the comments of Dr. Douglas N. Jones, Mr. Robert E. Burns,

CHAPTER 5

THE MAJOR COMPONENTS OF A NEW PUHCA

Major changes to PUHCA would facilitate the entry of power producers in

wholesale markets. PUHCA restrictions have deterred and severely limited, in the case

of some holding companies, the formation of wholesale power subsidiaries.1 Nonutility

and utility affiliated firms currently are constrained by PUHCA to locate new facilities in

geographically dispersed areas. For example, in owning a wholesale power facility, a

nonutility entity such as an industrial firm would be classified as a utility under PUHCA

and thereby become subject to SEC regulations. If the entity fails to receive an exempt

status, it would be required to divest its nonutility assets.2

Although no final bill has yet been enacted into law, certain components at this

time appear likely. They include:

1. formation of a new generator class to be exempt from PUHCA;

2. continued SEC authority over existing affiliates of registered holding

companies;

3. continued SEC authority over financing and other activities between registered

holding companies and affiliates;

1 While the current PUHCA undoubtedly has inhibited the development of independent power production, it is uncertain how much. One view is that independents are waiting for more favorable pricing practices by FERC and easier transmission access before embarking in the wholesale power business. If this is true, the stifling effect of PUHCA per se may not be as significant as many people believe.

2 Recall, the SEC has required nonutilities seeking exemption status under PUHCA to show that they are primarily involved in nonutility businesses and that the utility business is "functionally related" to the nonutility businesses. Even after gaining exemption, nonutilities would be constrained from owning wholesale power facilities in different geographical areas and in diversifying into nonutility businesses. See u.S. General Accounting Office, Electricity Supply: Regulating Utility Holding Companies in a Changing Electric Industry (Washington, D.C.: U.S. General Accounting Office, April 1992), 23.

35

Page 48: IMPLICATIONS OF A NEW PUHCA FOR...Director Columbus, Ohio August 14, 1992 ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS The authors gratefully acknowledge the comments of Dr. Douglas N. Jones, Mr. Robert E. Burns,

4. plenary SEC authority over power transactions between affiliates of registered

holding companies, excluding purchases by affiliates from exempt generators;

5. PUC authority over status of existing ratebased facilities subject to state

regulation;

6. codification of the Pike County Doctrine (the authority of PUCs to disallow

wholesale power costs in the retail costs of the buying utility when lower-cost

comparable sources of power were available );3

7. prohibition of PUC authority over determining the reasonableness of the

selling utility's wholesale power rates approved by FERC; and

8. PUC access to books and records of exempt wholesale generators (EWGs) and

affiliated utilities needed to exercise adequately affected commission's

authority.

Table 5-1 lists the major components of the Senate bill amending PUHCA.

Compared with the PUHCA provisions in the House bill, the Senate version as a whole

may be more favorable to state interests.4 The bill designates a class of power

generation, called "exempt wholesale generators (EWGs)," to be exempt from PUHCA.

An EWG is defined as an entity in the business of selling electricity exclusively for the

wholesale markets. Ownership of EWG is unrestricted meaning utility holding

companies, operating utilities, and nonutilities all are able to gain exempt status.

The Senate bill would retain the SEC's broad authority over registered holding

companies. For example, the SEC would continue to regulate preexisting affiliates of

registered holding companies.

3 For a discussion of the Pike County Doctrine, see William W. Lindsay and Jerry L. Pfeffer, The Narragansett Doctrine: A 1986 Update (Columbus, OH: The National Regulatory Research Institute, 1986).

4 The most important reason is that the Senate bill would codify the Pike County Doctrine while the House bill would not. The Senate bill also places fewer constraints on state commissions, particularly in allowing states more discretion in making decisions on such matters as self-dealing transactions and spinoffs of existing facilities.

36

Page 49: IMPLICATIONS OF A NEW PUHCA FOR...Director Columbus, Ohio August 14, 1992 ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS The authors gratefully acknowledge the comments of Dr. Douglas N. Jones, Mr. Robert E. Burns,

TABLE 5-1

FEATURES OF NEW PUHCA IN SENATE ENERGY BILL

1. Exemption of new wholesale facilities ("exempt wholesale generators" [EWGs]), including those owned by registered holding companies

2. Continued SEC authority over existing affiliates of registered holding company

3. PUC authority over existing facilities subject to state regulation

4. SEC authority over financing and contracts between registered holding company and affiliated EWGs

5. Utility ownership restriction for PURPA-qualifying facilities not affected by ownership in EWGs

6. FERC prohibition of rate approval for sales by EWGs resulting in PUC action disallowing recovery of capital expenses by buying utility for generating facilities under construction or currently receiving a rate of return

7. FERC prohibition of rate approval for EWGs selling directly to either retail customer, nonutility reseller, or any purchaser not using its own transmission or distribution facilities

8. Denial of affiliated transactions involving EWG, unless consented to by all commissions having authority over utility buyer

9. FERC prohibition of rate approval for abusive transactions between EWG and affiliated buyer

10. Prohibition of collusive arrangements among unaffiliated companies

11. Codification of Pike County Doctrine (authority of commissions to disallow wholesale power costs in retail rates)

12. Prohibition of PUC authority over reasonableness of wholesale power rates approved by FERC (Narragansett Doctrine)

13. Preapproval determination by PUC, at request of utility, of wholesale power costs associated with purchases from EWG; PUC approval binding in absence of new information

37

Page 50: IMPLICATIONS OF A NEW PUHCA FOR...Director Columbus, Ohio August 14, 1992 ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS The authors gratefully acknowledge the comments of Dr. Douglas N. Jones, Mr. Robert E. Burns,

TABLE Sal .. ·Continued

14. Plenary FERC authority over power transactions among affiliates of registered holding company (Mississippi Doctrine), excluding purchases by affiliates from EWG

15. PUC consideration of long-term wholesale power purchases on utility buyer's cost of capital, retail rates, and reliability; requirement of commission hearing on whether EWGs with less than 35 percent equity have unfair market advantage over self-generation utility

16. PUC access to books and records of EWG and affiliated utility relevant to exercise of affected commission's authority

The Senate bill would place some restrictions on FERC in approving rates. Rate

approval would be disallowed in cases where an EWG transaction would result in a state

commission disallowing the recovery of capital costs by the buying utility. The FERC

also could not approve rates for affiliated transactions that give an EWG an unfair

advantage.

The bill would give state commissions explicit authorities as well as imposes

certain restrictions. State commissions would have authority to approve of plant spinoffs

to an EWG status,S to disallow wholesale power costs in retail rates, and to gain access

to the books and records of EWGs and their affiliate utilities. On the other hand, state

commissions would be prohibited, as they are now, from rejecting FERC-approved

wholesale power rates. States also would be required, in the spirit of Title I of PURP A,

to consider the effects of wholesale power purchases on the jurisdictional-utility buyer's

cost of capital, retail rates, and reliability. Hearings would be required to determine

S The SEC would continue to have authority over plant spinoffs by existing affiliates of registered holding companies.

38

Page 51: IMPLICATIONS OF A NEW PUHCA FOR...Director Columbus, Ohio August 14, 1992 ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS The authors gratefully acknowledge the comments of Dr. Douglas N. Jones, Mr. Robert E. Burns,

whether EWGs with less than 35 percent equity have an unfair advantage over a self­

generation utility in meeting the utility's capacity needs.6 Based on the acquired

information, the state would have to determine the appropriateness of adopting capital

structure standards within one year after enactment of the bill. Further, at the request

of a utility states would have to make a pre approval decision on a proposed transaction

with an EWG seller. Cost recovery for approved transactions would be binding on a

state commission except when there is "new information which the state commission

believes is relevant and material to such cost recovery."? Preapproval is a controversial

issue that in important ways violates the basic tenets of rate-of-return regulation.8

The Senate bill would give the states the right to approve self-deal transactions

involving an EWG and an affiliated utility. Finally, the bill would prohibit collusive

activities between unaffiliated utilities or their affiliates. Such activities can include

6 The two major arguments in support of this provision were: highly leveraged EWGs pose risk to the buying utility and its customers and they have an unfair financial advantage over utilities who must finance their assets more with higher-cost equity. For a critique of these arguments, see Roger F. Naill and William C. Dudley, "IPP Leveraged Financing: Unfair Advantage?" Public Utilities Fortnightly (January 15, 1992): 15-18. See also Laura J. Rittenhouse, "Perceptual Survey of the S&P Purchased Power Credit Risk Policy," The Electricity Journal 5 no. 3 (April 1992): 42-52. Some respondents to the survey correctly pointed out that it is not necessarily more risky for utilities to purchase power from third parties than to build new generating facilities. The outcome depends on such factors as the terms of the purchased power contract, the track record of the seller, and its credit status. Importantly, investors of EWGs would pressure operators to fulfill their contractual obligations with utility buyers. Even in the event of a financial failure it is unlikely that power would be unavailable, as owners would want a power plant to continue operating and selling power.

? U.S. Senate, "National Energy Security Act of 1992," section 15106, 553.

8 See, for example, Kenneth Rose et aI., Public Utility Commission Implementation of the Clean Air Act's Allowance Trading Program (Columbus, OR: The National Regulatory Research Institute, 1992); and Russell J. Profozich et aI., Commission Preapproval of Utility Investments (Columbus, OR: The National Regulatory Research Institute, 1981).

39

Page 52: IMPLICATIONS OF A NEW PUHCA FOR...Director Columbus, Ohio August 14, 1992 ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS The authors gratefully acknowledge the comments of Dr. Douglas N. Jones, Mr. Robert E. Burns,

a secret agreement where each colluding entity would purchase the other's power at an

excessive price.9

Table 5-2 lists the major unresolved PUHCA issues that will be discussed and

debated at the joint House-Senate Conference. The House and Senate bills amending

PUHCA contain some major differences. For example, the Senate bill would provide

eligible EWGs with a permanent exemption from PUHCA, while under the House bill

they would have to receive on a case-by-case basis an exemption from FERC.10 The

House bill would disallow any current ratebased generating facility from receiving an

exemption. It also would prohibit all self-dealing transactions involving an exempt

wholesale facility.l1

9 Such reciprocal dealings, when successfully concealed, can be damaging to retail customers and, of course, profitable to the colluding parties. Even without prohibitive legislation, reciprocal dealings may be risky to utilities and, perhaps in some cases, not difficult to detect. A state commission, for example, could determine the reasonableness of prices for individual contracts by comparing them with other prices offered to a utility under a competitive power procurement mechanism, including those rejected by the utility. Commissions could establish other procedures to determine whether certain offers (including those from affiliates) were given preferential treatment. Finally, deterrence would exist because the possibility of a utility "getting caught" may earn the condemnation of its state commission as well as the courts for violating antitrust laws. One problem revolves around the fact that detecting collusive behavior is made difficult by the presence of nonprice contractual provisions. A utility, for example, could argue that although price of power from one source may appear high, the contract allows it more flexibility or provides more highly reliable service. An example of a "daisy chaining" arrangement was the elaborate market allocation schemes, uncovered in 1960, involving electrical equipment manufacturers. See Richard A. Smith, "The Incredible Electrical Conspiracy," Fortune Magazine (April 1961): 132-224.

10 There is some indication that if the House version is passed, FERC would establish a process by which it would grant an exemption and approve market-based prices for EWGs simultaneously. See "FERC Waiting for Final Energy Bill before Issuing Market Pricing Rule," Electric Utility Week (June 15, 1992), 5.

11 Apparently the House considers the risks associated with self-dealing to be significant enough to prohibit all such transactions involving a PUHCA-exempt facility. As a practical matter, the benefits from self-dealing would likely be small: the typical utility should have a number of demand-side and supply side options from which to choose, implying that one less choice would probably have little effect on its costs.

40

Page 53: IMPLICATIONS OF A NEW PUHCA FOR...Director Columbus, Ohio August 14, 1992 ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS The authors gratefully acknowledge the comments of Dr. Douglas N. Jones, Mr. Robert E. Burns,

TABLE 5-2

PUHCA ISSUES FOR JOINT HOUSE-SENATE CONFERENCE

.. Exemption process for wholesale power generators

@ Exemption of existing ratebased facilities

• Self-dealing transactions

• Restrictions on FERC approval of rates for exempt generators

• Commission preapproval of purchased power costs

• Commission consideration of effects of long-term power purchases on utility buyer's cost of capital, rates, and reliability

• Codification of Pike County Doctrine

A highly important matter for the states is the codification of the Pike County

Doctrine; the House bill contains no codification.12 The Senate bill would require a

conditional preapproval determination by state commissions of wholesale power

12 The feeling in the House seems to be that states currently have the right to disapprove the costs associated with wholesale power purchases. Consequently, there is no need to legislate a right that already exists.

41

Page 54: IMPLICATIONS OF A NEW PUHCA FOR...Director Columbus, Ohio August 14, 1992 ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS The authors gratefully acknowledge the comments of Dr. Douglas N. Jones, Mr. Robert E. Burns,

transactions between an exempt generator and a jurisdictional utility.13 Unlike the

House bill, the Senate bill also would require states to consider the effects of power

purchases on a jurisdictional utility's cost of capital, retail rates, and reliability. State

commissions, in addition, would be required to hold a hearing on whether an exempt

wholesale generator with less than 35 percent equity financing has an unfair advantage

over a self-generation utility.

It is difficult to see the wisdom of this provision in the Senate bill. The fact that

a EWG may have less equity financing should in no way imply that its reallevelized cost

of financing new plant would be lower. The capital markets require EWGs to retain a

cash reserve fund and amortize their debt balance over a shorter period than utilities.14

On a more basic note, it is incorrect to argue that a firm with a higher debt-equity ratio

would necessarily have a lower cost of capital. This argues for utilities to be more highly

leveraged; but since debt increases the volatility of equity, a utility with a higher debt­

equity ratio would experience an increase in its cost of equity capital. Consequently,

there is no theoretical basis for believing that a firm's cost of capital would be lower with

a higher debt-equity ratio. (See the appendix for a more detailed discussion of the

financial leverage issue.)

Finally, the Senate bill would prohibit FERC from approving rates when an

exempt generator receives an unfair advantage from an affiliate, as well as when a state

commission disallows cost recovery for existing generating facilities of the utility buyer

because of power purchases from an exempt generator. How FERC would enforce these

provisions is difficult to foresee.

Two major points should be made about the likely outcomes of a new PUHCA.

First, it would give states wide-ranging authority to protect retail customers from abuses

by jurisdictional electric utilities. Past fears of state commissions centered on several

13 "Conditional" refers to the fact that a utility would first have to request preapproval and preapproved costs may be nullified by "new information which the state commission believes is relevant and material to such cost recovery."

14 See Naill and Dudley, "IPP Leveraged Financing: Unfair Advantage?".

42

Page 55: IMPLICATIONS OF A NEW PUHCA FOR...Director Columbus, Ohio August 14, 1992 ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS The authors gratefully acknowledge the comments of Dr. Douglas N. Jones, Mr. Robert E. Burns,

concerns: losing the authority to conduct prudence reviews of power purchases and

competitive power procurement mechanisms; lacking access to the books and records of

utility holding companies and their affiliates; lacking authority to oversee the spinoffs of

existing facilities as exempt wholesale generators; and lacking the right to form a

regional regulatory structure to regulate registered holding companies. IS

The new PUHCA largely would likely placate those state commissions that most

opposed any PUHCA changes. For example, the new PUHCA, at least if the provision

in the Senate bill passes through conference, would codify the Pike County Doctrine,

giving states guaranteed authority to assess the prudence of a utility buying power from

individual producers. Further, nothing in the new legislation would restrict the states

from establishing power procurement mechanisms.16 As an additional protection for

the states, the House energy bill would require FERC to establish "safe harbor" rules for

approving power sales by exempt generators.

The new PUHCA also would give states wide access to the books and records of

jurisdictional utilities, their affiliates, and exempt generators selling to those utilities.

The House bill gives states the broader authority by allowing them to examine books and

IS See National Association of Regulatory Utility Commissioners, "Resolution Endorsing Legislation to Amend the Federal Power Act to Reform State/Federal Jurisdiction," NARUC No. 9-1991 (March 4, 1991). One major concern of state commissions is that unrestricted utility ownership of wholesale power facilities would create opportunities for utilities to cross-subsidize these facilities through their retail distribution rates. This would especially be true when utilities own and operate wholesale power facilities that sell power to affiliated distribution companies.

16 Up to now FERC has demonstrated a willingness to defer to the states the outcomes of PUC-approved competitive power procurement programs when the winners are PURP A-qualifying facilities or "true" independent power producers. See Kenneth Rose, Robert E. Burns, and Mark Eifert, Implementing a Competitive Bidding Program for Electric Power Supply, (Columbus, OH: The National Regulatory Research Institute, 1991), 98.

43

Page 56: IMPLICATIONS OF A NEW PUHCA FOR...Director Columbus, Ohio August 14, 1992 ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS The authors gratefully acknowledge the comments of Dr. Douglas N. Jones, Mr. Robert E. Burns,

records as long as it is "required for the effective discharge of State commission's

regulatory responsibilities affecting the provision of electric service.,,17

Regarding spinoffs of existing facilities as an exempt wholesale generator, the

final bill either would prohibit the activity (the House bill version) or require state

approval (the Senate bill version). A utility generally would want to spin off a plant if it

expected to increase profits by repositioning its assets in response to changed market

forces.18 Commissions would have to deal with the thorny problem of allocating the

economic value of an existing plant between retail customers and the utility.

One important omission in the new PUHCA is a failure to overturn the

contentious Mississippi Power and Light decision.19 That decision upheld a FERC

ruling that prohibits state commissions from regulating the costs allocated to different

operating utilities by a multistate holding company. The decision, in effect, disallows

states from conducting a prudence review of FERC-approved cost-allocation decisions

made by registered holding companies for their utility subsidiaries. States have

responded indignantly, and rightly so, to the Mississippi Doctrine, appalled by the fact

that they have no control over the costs associated with planning decisions made by a

multistate holding company nor over planning decisions made by nonjurisdictional

affiliates. There is obviously a regulatory gap for registered holding companies, namely,

17 U.S. House of Representatives, "Comprehensive National Energy Policy Act," section 713, 434. The House bill goes as far as giving the United States district court the authority to issue an injunction requiring compliance with a PUC order.

18 See Philip R. O'Connor, "IPPs, Devolution and Competition in the Electric Industry," paper presented at Conference on Independent Power Ventures, Public Utilities Report, Washington, D.C., October 24, 1988; and Philip R. O'Connor et ai., "The Transition to Competition in the Electric Utility Industry," Journal of Energy Law and Policy, 8 no. 2 (1988): 222-54.

19 Mississippi Power and Light Company v. Moore, 108 S. Ct. 2428 (1988).

44

Page 57: IMPLICATIONS OF A NEW PUHCA FOR...Director Columbus, Ohio August 14, 1992 ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS The authors gratefully acknowledge the comments of Dr. Douglas N. Jones, Mr. Robert E. Burns,

FERC has no authority to approve or reject their generation planning decisions, while

states have no authority to regulate the rates of their operating companies.20

Two happenings would help to close this regulatory gap. One marginal response

would be passage of the provision in the Senate bill giving states authority to assess the

prudence of power purchases by an operating utility from an affiliated exempt wholesale

generator, both of which fall under the control of a registered holding company. The

second, and more significant response, involves giving states the explicit right to form

regional compacts with the authority to regulate the planning decisions of registered

holding companies. In April 1992 Senator Bennett Johnston introduced S. 2607 that

would give states such authority for integrated resource planning.21

The second major point to be made is that a new PUHCA would allow the SEC

to retain much of its authority over registered holding companies and exempt holding

companies. For example, the SEC would continue to regulate registered holding

companies regarding their financial and corporate structures, issuance of securities for

acquiring wholesale power facilities and other assets, and their service contracts with

wholesale power facilities. The SEC also would continue to have the authority to

approve mergers and acquisitions by exempt and registered holding companies of other

utilities (excluding exempt wholesale generators).

20 See, for example, Charles G. Stalon and Reinier H. J. H. Lock, "State-Federal Relations in the Economic Regulation of Energy," Yale Journal on Regulation 7 no. 2 (Summer 1990), 454-57. A discussion of different approaches to close this regulatory gap will be presented in a forthcoming NRRI report on regional regulation.

21 Senate bill 2607 is the legislative version of the so-called "Arkansas Plan," crafted jointly by a regulated holding company, a city, and a state PUC. The bill would authorize regional integrated resource planning by registered holding companies and the state pues regulating their operating companies. See "Johnston Offers Utility Regional­Planning Bill; May Hearing Likely," Inside F.E.R.C. (April 20, 1992): 2-3.

45

Page 58: IMPLICATIONS OF A NEW PUHCA FOR...Director Columbus, Ohio August 14, 1992 ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS The authors gratefully acknowledge the comments of Dr. Douglas N. Jones, Mr. Robert E. Burns,
Page 59: IMPLICATIONS OF A NEW PUHCA FOR...Director Columbus, Ohio August 14, 1992 ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS The authors gratefully acknowledge the comments of Dr. Douglas N. Jones, Mr. Robert E. Burns,

CHAPTER 6

REMAINING OBSTACLES FOR INDEPENDENT POWER PRODUCTION

Independent power producers still will face several obstacles after a new PUHCA

is enacted. It seems uncertain whether the industry over the next few years will

experience high growth. The PUHCA impediment represents only one of many that

independent power producers currently face. The latent market for independent power

may continue because of four factors: the lack of easy access to the regional translllission

system, the possibility of self-dealing abuses, the active pursuit of utility demand-side

initiatives, and the lack of strong incentives for wholesale purchases by utility buyers.l

Transmission Access

There is a growing consensus that active and workably competitive wholesale

power markets require that potential sellers have access to the market.2 Competitive

forces are nurtured any time more buyers are available to a seller and when more sellers

are available to a buyer. For true competition to exist in the wholesale power markets,

1 For example, as discussed later, traditional cost-of-service regulation restricts the incentive of a utility to purchase power from an independent power facility. Most states allow utilities to recover on a dollar-far-dollar basis the prudent costs expended for purchased power. With most utilities currently receiving no profits from buying wholesale power, they may opt for other new resources that are more profitable to them without regard to actual economic costs.

2 See, for example, Federal Energy Regulatory Commission, Electricity Transmission: Realities, Theory, and Policy Alternatives (Washington, D.C.: The Transmission Task Force's Report to the Commission, October 1989); Douglas A. Houston, "Toward Resolving the Access Issue: User-Ownership of Electric Transmission Grids," Policy Insight No. 129 (Santa Monica, CA: The Reason Foundation, August 1991); and Congress of the United States, Office of Technology Assessment, Electric Power Wheeling and Dealing (Washington, D.C.: Office of Technology Assessment, May 1989).

47

Page 60: IMPLICATIONS OF A NEW PUHCA FOR...Director Columbus, Ohio August 14, 1992 ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS The authors gratefully acknowledge the comments of Dr. Douglas N. Jones, Mr. Robert E. Burns,

it is now widely held that transmission access should be provided on a nondiscriminatory

basis to independent power producers and other wholesale producers.

The current debate over whether market-based prices or equal-access rules are

preferable for making transmission services more accessible should accentuate the

interdependency of the two options. More appropriately, the two options should be

viewed as complementary. For example, giving owners of transmission systems greater

profit opportunities from selling transmission services should increase access; in addition,

equal-access rules would enhance competitive pressures that, in turn, would drive prices

for transmission services (as well as other wholesale services) toward market-based

levels. Together, market-driven pricing and equal-access rules can represent the optimal

strategy for stimulating wholesale power markets.

Even if no transmission legislation is enacted, utilities will face increased

pressures to open their transmission systems.3 A new PUHCA would intensify these

pressures as more potential players will want access to wholesale markets so they can

market their power; they will push harder for either a political or legal solution to the

problem of inadequate transmission access. The "pushers" likely will include some

vertically integrated utilities that, for no other than economic reasons, may be more

responsive to opening their transmission systems as a quid pro quo for easier

transmission access and FERC-approved market-based prices for affiliates located

outside their control areas. As transmission access becomes widespread, utilities and

perhaps other power buyers in the longer term will have access to more independent

power producers. At that time the benefit of a new PUHCA should reach its highest

level.

So it seems likely that a new PUHCA would affect indirectly transmission access

by stimulating competition and pressures for change. While change in most likelihood

would have occurred otherwise, a new PUHCA should secure it earlier in time.

3 It is likely (as of mid-summer) that some legislation will be passed this year that would give FERC more authority to facilitate wholesale transmission access. See "Battle Over Transmission Policy Heats Up As a Showdown in Congress Nears," Electric Utility Week (June 8, 1992): 1, 16-17.

48

Page 61: IMPLICATIONS OF A NEW PUHCA FOR...Director Columbus, Ohio August 14, 1992 ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS The authors gratefully acknowledge the comments of Dr. Douglas N. Jones, Mr. Robert E. Burns,

Self-Dealinl:

Self-dealing transactions may hinder the growth of independent power production.

When utilities show partiality toward their affiliates, true independent power producers

stand to suffer. Utilities certainly have an incentive to buy power from affiliates as long

as they can pass through the costs to retail customers. Even with a least-cost planning

process in place and the ability to disallow imprudent costs, regulators under traditional

regulation still will have to monitor self-dealing transactions closely.4

Allegations of self-dealing abuse emerged during the recent Southern California

Edison-San Diego Gas and Electric merger proceedings before FERC and the California

Commission.5 Opponents to the merger argued that Southern California Edison was

engaging in improper self-dealing with one of its affiliates, Mission Energy. The Public

Utilities Commission staff accused Edison of favoritism toward negotiating and enforcing

purchased power contracts from cogeneration and enhanced oil recovery plants partially

owned by Mission Energy. As a condition for merger, Edison reached an agreement

with the U.S. Department of Justice that the proposed merged utility would not enter

into purchased power contracts with affiliates unless prior approval was obtained from

the California Commission.6

4 For example, regulators would have to carefully review both the price and nonprice provisions of a contract with an affiliate. Further, regulators would need to determine whether the utility restricted transmission access to competitors. By doing so the utility could argue for a higher avoided cost, thereby making affiliate transactions both more defensible and lucrative.

5 See Dan Seligman, "Self-Dealing Raised in Edison Merger," The Electricity Journal' 3 no. 6 (July 1990): 8-10.

6 The agreement was not included in the record of the FERC investigation on whether to approve the proposed merger. The proposal was ultimately rejected by FERC and withdrawn by the parties.

49

Page 62: IMPLICATIONS OF A NEW PUHCA FOR...Director Columbus, Ohio August 14, 1992 ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS The authors gratefully acknowledge the comments of Dr. Douglas N. Jones, Mr. Robert E. Burns,

Demand-Side Initiatives

Many electric utilities recently have undertaken aggressive actions to stimulate

demand-side initiatives.7 Over the next several years, these actions may constitute a

major impediment to the development of the independent power industry. Several state

public utility commissions have given utilities strong incentives to invest in demand-side

assets. For example, some have allowed utilities to offset their sales losses from energy

conservation initiatives by adjusting their rates upward outside of a rate-case proceeding;

others have allowed higher rates of return for demand-side investments and sharing of

benefits from demand-side initiatives.8

In the current environment, many utilities have a greater opportunity to earn

profits from demand-side investment than from building new generating facilities or from

purchasing power in wholesale markets. Until this changes, it seems likely that many

utilities will find purchased power as an inferior alternative to more profitable ones such

as demand-side investments.

7 See National Economic Research Associates, "Key Issues in Least-Cost Planning," NERA Working Paper No. 10 (August 1991); and Alfred E. Kahn, "An Economically Rational Approach to Least-Cost Planning," The Electricity Journal 4 no. 5 (June 1991): 11-20.

8 See Edison Electric Institute, Demand-Side Management Incentive Regulation (Washington, D.C.: Edison Electric Institute, March 1991); and National Association of Regulatory Utility Commissioners, Incentives for Demand-Side Management (Washington, D.C.: National Association of Regulatory Utility Commissioners, January 1992).

50

Page 63: IMPLICATIONS OF A NEW PUHCA FOR...Director Columbus, Ohio August 14, 1992 ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS The authors gratefully acknowledge the comments of Dr. Douglas N. Jones, Mr. Robert E. Burns,

Regulatory Incentives

As another obstacle to independent power production, traditional cost-of-service

regulation restricts a utility's incentive to purchase power in wholesale markets.9 Most

states allow utilities to recover on a dollar-for-dollar basis the prudent costs associated

with firm power purchases.1o A key question currently before state regulators, not

excluding those having in place a formalized least-cost energy process, is whether utilities

have an incentive to select the least-cost mix of new resources.

Simply "forcing" a utility, for example, to sign contracts with wholesale power

producers for long-term firm power rather than building a new generating facility may

not be good policy if the utility stands to gain little if anything by purchasing power. The

utility may consider purchasing power as too risky given no opportunity to profit. For

example, a dollar-for-dollar passthrough of purchased power costs, in view of possible

disallowances, provides the utility with little or no incentive to search actively for third-

9 See Paul L. Joskow, "Expanding Competitive Opportunities in Electricity Generation," Regulation (Winter 1991): 25-37; Lewis 1. Perl and Mark D. Luftig, "Financial Implications of Third Party Power Purchases," The Electricity Journal 3 no. 9 (November 1990): 24-31; and Laura 1. Rittenhouse, "Perceptual Survey of the S&P Purchased Power Credit Risk Policy," The Electricity Journal (April 1992): 42-52. The last article, which examines survey results conducted for Standard and Poor, showed why many utility executives are not enthusiastic about purchasing firm power from third parties: purchased power financially weakens a utility since it does not allow rate base growth; and power purchases pose an uncompensated risk to a utility--that is, state commissions can disallow costs, which means power purchases create risks that are not offset by an equity return on purchases.

10 See survey results in Robert E. Burns, Mark Eifert, and Peter A. Nagler, Current PGA and FA C Practices: Implications for Ratemaking in Competitive Markets (Columbus, OH: The National Regulatory Research Institute, November 1991).

51

Page 64: IMPLICATIONS OF A NEW PUHCA FOR...Director Columbus, Ohio August 14, 1992 ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS The authors gratefully acknowledge the comments of Dr. Douglas N. Jones, Mr. Robert E. Burns,

party power.ll Under rate-of-return regulation, a utility receives profits only by

investing in assets that are included in rate base. The recent interest by utilities in

purchasing firm power may stem more from the risks associated with building new

generating facilities than from the abundance of low-priced purchased power.

11 As another risk, rating agencies recently have treated purchased power contracts as a debt equivalent. Standard and Poor, for example, has downgraded some utilities with large nonutility power purchases. See Rittenhouse, "Perceptual Survey of the S&P Purchased Power Credit Risk Policy."

52

Page 65: IMPLICATIONS OF A NEW PUHCA FOR...Director Columbus, Ohio August 14, 1992 ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS The authors gratefully acknowledge the comments of Dr. Douglas N. Jones, Mr. Robert E. Burns,

CHAPTER 7

NEW CHALLENGES FOR REGULATORS

A new PUHCA would bring new challenges to federal and state regulators alike.

FERC would face increased requests for approval of wholesale power sales as well as

transmission services. State commissions would see increased requests from

jurisdictional utilities for approval of wholesale power contracts, some of which may

involve (if allowed) affiliated transactions. States may also encounter more frequent

requests from utilities for approval to spinoff ratebased generating facilities as exempt

wholesale subsidiaries (assuming it is allowed under the enacted law). (Table 7-1 lists the

major responsibilities of, and authority given to, state regulators that may come out of

new PUHCA legislation.)

How both FERC and the state commissions would respond to these challenges

will have important consequences for retail customers. Support for a new PUHCA

presumes that exempt wholesale generators would not exercise market power because of

effective regulation by both FERC (in setting prices) and state regulators (in approving

least-cost power purchases). While this may ultimately be true, getting there may entail

a difficult transitional period for regulators.

A current topic under discussion at FERC centers on the conditions needed for

allowing market-based wholesale power rates. Such rates depend on the buyer's

willingness to pay for firm power purchases. During the period of 1988 to 1991, FERC

approved twenty-eight of forty requests for market-based pricing.1 Until recently, firm

wholesale power transactions were priced almost always on the basis of cost-of-service

rules, similar to the way most retail transactions are currently priced.2

1 Bernard W. Tenenbaum and J. Stephen Henderson, "Market-Based Pricing of Wholesale Electric Services," The Electricity Journal 4 no. 10 (December 1991),30.

2 See, for example, Paul L. J oskow, "Regulatory Failure, Regulatory Reform, and Structural Changes in the Electrical Power Industry," Martin Neil Baily and Clifford Winston, eds. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity: Microeconomics 1989 (Washington, D.C.: The Brookings Institution, 1989), 125-208; and Jan Paul Acton and Stanley M. Besen, Regulation, Efficiency, and Competition in the Exchange of Electricity: First-Year Results from the FERC Bulk Power Market Experiments, Rand Report R-3301-DOE (Santa Monica, CA: The Rand Corporation, October 1985).

53

Page 66: IMPLICATIONS OF A NEW PUHCA FOR...Director Columbus, Ohio August 14, 1992 ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS The authors gratefully acknowledge the comments of Dr. Douglas N. Jones, Mr. Robert E. Burns,

TABLE 7 .. 1

IMPLICATIONS OF NEW PUHCA FOR STATE REGULATORS

Review of more wholesale transactions, as part of least-cost utility planning or competitive power procurement programs

Review of plant spinoffs by exempt holding companies and operating utilities

Scrutiny of potentially more anticompetitive activities such as cross-subsidization and self-dealing abuses

• Authority over prudence of wholesale power purchases

Preapproval of wholesale power purchases involving EWGs

Determination of effects of wholesale power purchases on cost of capital and reliability

Wide access to books and records for overseeing affiliate transactions

Review of utility restructuring proposals

The general position of FERC is that market-based pricing would be acceptable

for unaffiliated transactions where the seller can show lack of market power. For

example, in the case of an Illinois utility selling wholesale power through a subsidiary to

an unaffiliated buyer located in (say) Arizona, FERC would look favorably upon

allowing the two parties to negotiate a market-based price.

In situations where either the transaction involves affiliated parties or the seller

controls transmission facilities that can affect the buyer's supply choices, FERC has acted

54

Page 67: IMPLICATIONS OF A NEW PUHCA FOR...Director Columbus, Ohio August 14, 1992 ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS The authors gratefully acknowledge the comments of Dr. Douglas N. Jones, Mr. Robert E. Burns,

more cautiously.3 FERC considers a utility's potential for abusing its control of

transmission facilities as a major obstacle to market-based pricing. FERC is expected to

approve rules sometime next year defining the conditions under which market-based

pricing would be acceptable. The rules are expected to provide a "safe harbor" for

traditional utilities and affiliated power producers who agree to offer transmission

services on a nondiscriminatory basis.4 Since these rules will spell out FERC's policy on

wholesale power pricing in the years ahead, state commissions may find it in their

interest to participate actively in the rulemaking process.

Under a new PUHCA state rerulators would have authoritv over the orudence of ~ J A

power purchases, excepting those involving registered holding companies and their

operating subsidiaries. Codification of the Pike County Doctrine would give states

explicit authority to disallow wholesale power costs in retail rates.5 States, for example,

could determine whether a particular power purchase is compatible with least-cost

planning or the stated goals of a competitive power procurement mechanism. Although

3 In a speech before the American Bar Association on August 13, 1991 in Atlanta Georgia, Chairman Martin L. Allday remarked that:

We've three major concerns in looking at market power: (1) whether the seller can dominate the buyer's generation supply choices; (2) whether the seller controls transmission, so that other competitors can be shut out of the market; and (3) potential abuses of affiliate relationships (p. 3) ... 0 The biggest hurdle in getting quick FERC approval is and will continue to be market power in transmission. That's because control of transmission lets sellers shut out competitors and prevents buyers from getting to the lowest cost supply source (p.5).

4 Chairman Allday, in his American Bar Association speech, commented that "as long as APPs [affiliated power producers] and traditional utilities have on file with us [FERC] an acceptable open access transmission tariff for their entire system, or for those lines that the buyer could use to reach competing suppliers, we should presume that market power has been mitigated (p. 6)."

5 FERC will continue to have preemptive authority over the reasonableness of wholesale power rates.

55

Page 68: IMPLICATIONS OF A NEW PUHCA FOR...Director Columbus, Ohio August 14, 1992 ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS The authors gratefully acknowledge the comments of Dr. Douglas N. Jones, Mr. Robert E. Burns,

most states believe they now have that authority, codification in new energy legislation

would avoid any uncertainty over possible litigation.6

Notwithstanding this authority, states would have the task of closely monitoring

wholesale purchases. Particularly whenever self-dealing occurs, state commissions face

the difficult task of assuring ratepayers that utilities are pursuing least-cost activities.7

Whatever else may be true, utilities would have an incentive to favor power purchases

from affiliates, assuming other things are the same. Self-dealing abuses could lead to

higher retail rates and the unfair advantage of utility affiliates over other producers,

some of whom may have lower costs.

The informational problem, a constant nemesis for rate-of-return regulation,

would be accentuated if regulators were confronted by a rash of self-dealing requests.

For example, regulators would have to scrutinize both the price and nonprice provisions

of a proposed contract with an affiliate. Further, they would need to determine whether

the buying utility gave its unfair market advantages by restricting transmission access to

competitors. That is, even when the utility has the availability of power from a large

6 Even without codification it is unlikely that state commissions would face a challenge from utilities in exercising the authority to disallow wholesale power purchases. In a 1991 survey conducted by the U.S. General Accounting Office (see U.S. General Accounting Office, Electricity Supply: Potential Effects of Amending the Public Utility Holding Company Act, GAO-RCED 92-52 [Washington, D.C.: U.S. General Accounting Office, January 1992]), forty commissions (out of forty-eight that responded) indicated that "they have the authority to disallow utilities from passing on, through retail rates, a portion of the cost of a wholesale power purchase approved by FERC (p. 32)."

7 Some states have acted to minimize self-dealing abuses (U.S. General Accounting Office, Electricity Supply: Potential Effects of Amending the Public Utility Holding Company Act, 33). The Virginia State Corporation Commission, for example, prohibits self-dealing transactions consummated by means of a competitive power procurement mechanism. Several states, on the other hand, allow interaffiliate transactions, many of which require prior regulatory approval. For a detailed exposition of the problems associated with self­dealing transactions, see Robert E. Burns et aI., Regulating Electric Utilities with Subsidiaries (Columbus, OH: The National Regulatory Research Institute, 1986).

56

Page 69: IMPLICATIONS OF A NEW PUHCA FOR...Director Columbus, Ohio August 14, 1992 ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS The authors gratefully acknowledge the comments of Dr. Douglas N. Jones, Mr. Robert E. Burns,

denying transmission access) in its service area.8 By doing so the utility could argue for

a higher avoided cost, thereby making affiliate transactions more defensible.9

A new PUHCA would create more opportunities for utilities to form subsidiaries.

Any time a utility diversifies, there exists the problem of cross-subsidization. As noted

below, cross-subsidization can arise either from improper cost shifting between different

lines of business or from predatory pricing (namely, setting price below cost in the more

competitive market). In either case, a utility may attempt to impute more of the

common costs to the regulated side of its business where ratepayers have limited options.

being charged a profit-maximizing price. It is assumed, of course, that regulation was

previously effective in controlling the prices and profits of the utility below the

unregulated-monopoly levels. The utility, for example, may raise retail rates to help fund

its wholesale power subsidiary or other nonutility businesses.

The strongest incentive for cross-subsidization generally lies with the ability of a

regulated utility to increase its revenues in markets where it has monopoly power by

reallocating costs from markets where it faces more competition. Cross-subsidization,

while always raising rates in monopoly retail markets, may not always result in lower

wholesale power rates. lO When cross-subsidization results in what is called predatory

8 As PERC is given more authority to require transmission access such discriminatory actions are less likely to happen. This implies that opportunities for self­dealing abuses should diminish (although not be eliminated) as a problem for both PERC and state commissions.

9 The utility also may have an incentive to deter least-cost actions such as demand­side initiatives to inflate its avoided costs. The utility could then purchase power from an affiliate under inflated avoided cost rates, retaining all of the profits through its affiliates. If this happens, self-dealing would hamper rather than promote least-cost planning objectives.

10 See, for example, Lorenzo Brown, "Modelling Diversified Utilities and Cross­Subsidization," Resources and Energy 10 (December 1988): 213-24.

57

Page 70: IMPLICATIONS OF A NEW PUHCA FOR...Director Columbus, Ohio August 14, 1992 ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS The authors gratefully acknowledge the comments of Dr. Douglas N. Jones, Mr. Robert E. Burns,

pricing (pricing below cost) inefficiencies arise both because of higher prices in retail

markets and the displacement of efficient producers in wholesale markets.ll

Cross-subsidization can be avoided if regulators are able to segment costs

perfectly by customer class or service. Since they cannot, largely because of the presence

of common costs, utilities have the opportunity for shifting costs to markets in which

consumers have few choices. For example, a utility might impute more of the common

costs associated with management functions to retail customers, who have fewer options

than wholesale buyers.12 In any event, to the extent a new PUHCA would increase

utility diversification, state regulators will have to pay closer attention to the possibility of

cross-subsidization.

State regulators can act to mitigate some potential problems associated with self­

dealing, cross-subsidization, and other anticompetitive activities (for example, collusive

arrangements among utilities). First, they can more vigilantly monitor the cost of a

utility and its affiliates.13 The new PUHCA would allow state regulators wide access to

the books and records of exempt wholesale generators and their affiliated utilities.

Besides requiring additional commission staff resources, monitoring may produce

11 The possibility of predatory pricing is severely diminished anytime a utility affiliate has to compete with other suppliers, namely, PURP A-qualifying facilities, independent power producers, and outside utilities, in addition to demand-side initiatives. It seems highly unlikely that the utility affiliate could permanently drive out these competing sources by temporarily setting prices below cost. Further, funding a losing business with higher rates to some consumers for an extended period (which may be necessary to drive out competitors) may ultimately harm the parent company. This is because some of its subsidizing consumers could end up finding new electricity suppliers and the company could be threatened with antitrust or civil suits from its competitors.

12 Different ways in which wholesale power producers can engage in cross­subsidization are discussed in Tenenbaum and Henderson, "Market-Based Pricing of Wholesale Electric Services."

13 While this would require additional staff resources, less staff resources may be expended on such activities as reviewing the construction costs of new utility power plants and assessing how these costs should be incorporated into rates. Consequently, on net, the requirements on staff resources for many state commissions may not increase.

58

Page 71: IMPLICATIONS OF A NEW PUHCA FOR...Director Columbus, Ohio August 14, 1992 ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS The authors gratefully acknowledge the comments of Dr. Douglas N. Jones, Mr. Robert E. Burns,

uncertain outcomes because of the problem of distinguishing "legitimate" costs from

"illegitimate" costs incurred by the utility and its affiliates. As discussed earlier,

regulators, even with their best efforts, may lack the necessary information to prevent all

possible abuses.14

A second option for regulators (presented here more as a theoretical construct) is

to link retail rates with the profits earned by wholesale power affiliates.1s For example,

since cross-subsidization and self-dealing abuses would result in higher profits to

affiliates, regulators can "give back" part of these profits to retail customers in the form

of lower rates. This option would diminish the need for regulators to monitor possible

abuses, since the utility would have little incentive to engage in such activities; ideally,

every dollar of profit earned by abuses would be returned to retail customers. Although "

theoretically appealing, this option would be difficult to enforce as regulators would have

to account for the profits of an affiliate that are related to other factors in addition to

cross-subsidization and self-dealing abuses. Further, it would invite legal wrangling

resulting in high litigation costs.

Third, and perhaps the most attractive long-term option, regulators can enforce an

incentive-based mechanism by which prices to retail customers would deviate from a

utility's actual costs. By breaking the linkage between price and cost, a utility'S incentive

to inflate prices for self-dealing transactions or to shift costs to retail services would

14 The fundamental problem of allocating common costs between different services is discussed in William J. Baumol, Michael F. Koehn, and Robert D. Willig, "How Arbitrary Is Arbitrary?--or, Toward the Deserved Demise of Full Cost Allocation," Public Utilities Fortnightly (September 3, 1987): 16-21.

IS The idea of linking regulated prices with profits earned in unregulated or lightly regulated activities are discussed in Tracy R. Lewis and David E. M. Sappington, "An Informational Effect When Regulated Firms Enter Unregulated Markets," Journal of Regulatory Economics 1 (March 1989): 35-46.

59

Page 72: IMPLICATIONS OF A NEW PUHCA FOR...Director Columbus, Ohio August 14, 1992 ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS The authors gratefully acknowledge the comments of Dr. Douglas N. Jones, Mr. Robert E. Burns,

diminish. 16 As an example of one such mechanism--price-cap regulation--state

regulators could establish maximum allowable retail prices in core markets based on

indices divorced from the cost changes for any individual utility. Assuming a textbook

application of price-cap regulation, when a utility incurs higher costs, for example, by

paying an affiliate an excessive price for purchased power or by shifting costs to its retail

business, it gains little if anything. The inability of the utility under idealized price-cap

regulation to pass through higher reported costs to retail customers diminishes the

possibilities for self-dealing abuse, cross-subsidization, and collusive agreements.

P...s an additional benefit, price-cap regulation when properly applied would help

assure that different wholesale power producers will compete on an equal basis. Self­

dealing abuses and cross-subsidization, both of which place utility unaffiliated power

producers at a market disadvantage, would lessen over time.17

16 See, for example, Mark Newton Lowry, "The Case for Indexed Price Caps for U.S. Electric Utilities," The Electricity Journal 4 no. 8 (October 1991): 30-37. Under price-cap regulation, a utility may decide to sell surplus generating capacity at market-based prices without the need to form a subsidiary. As argued, price-cap regulation would provide a utility with the incentive to minimize costs in its regulated markets. Support for price­cap regulation in mitigating cost shifting is also discussed in Ronald R. Braeutigam, "Regulatory Reform for Diversified Public Utilities: For Better or for Worse?" Resources and Energy 14 nos. 1/2 (April 1992): 103-22.

17 While it is argued here that price-cap regulation can help to mitigate anticompetitive effects, it may have disadvantages over rate-of-return regulation in achieving other regulatory objectives. Further, the theoretical benefits of price-cap regulation may not transpire because of several factors induding political pressures. See, for example, Kenneth W. Costello and Sung-Bong Cho, A Review of FERC's Technical Reports on Incentive Regulation (Columbus, OH: The National Regulatory Research Institute, 1991); and Douglas N. Jones, "Discussion of 'Regulatory Reform for Diversified Public Utilities: For Better or for Worse?' by Ronald Braeutigam," Resources and Energy 14 nos. 1/2 (April 1992): 123-28.

60

Page 73: IMPLICATIONS OF A NEW PUHCA FOR...Director Columbus, Ohio August 14, 1992 ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS The authors gratefully acknowledge the comments of Dr. Douglas N. Jones, Mr. Robert E. Burns,

CHAPTERS

CONCLUSIONS

A new PUHCA makes economic sense when independent power producers have

the potential to supply wholesale power markets with a low-cost source of generating

resources. The highly vertically integrated structure of the electric industry may no longer

serve the best interests of retail electricity consumers. Further, the displacement of

PURP A-qualifying facilities with independent power facilities may improve the economic

performance of the electric industry and benefit retail consumers. By lifting a costly

barrier for new power producers, a new PUHCA should help accentuate the competitive

forces currently propelling the electric industry. Such forces may push the industry closer

to a more economical structure where the industry's generation component will become

more controlled by profit-driven entrepreneurs and less by tight regulatory rules.

While the independent power industry (the major direct beneficiaries of a new

PUHCA) has barely gotten off the ground, it has a promising future. In addition to a

new PUHCA, the rapid growth of utility power procurement programs, the opening of

transmission systems to unaffiliated producers, and FERC's market-based pricing

together will nurture the growth of the independent power industry. As long as the

industry is given the chance to compete equally with other supply side and demand-side

resources, how much it actually grows becomes irrelevant from the perspective of society

at large.

The independent power industry may not suddenly take off over the next few

years, even in the presence of a new PUHCA. Producers will still have several obstacles

to clear before they attain the status of major players in the electric industry. They will

need to compete with other power sources as well as demand-side initiatives for gaining

acceptance by both utility buyers and their regulators.

Finally, a new PUHCA would offer new challenges to regulators. Easing the

constraints on utilities to form wholesale power subsidiaries would heighten their

opportunities to engage in anticompetitive activities potentially detrimental to retail

61

Page 74: IMPLICATIONS OF A NEW PUHCA FOR...Director Columbus, Ohio August 14, 1992 ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS The authors gratefully acknowledge the comments of Dr. Douglas N. Jones, Mr. Robert E. Burns,

electricity consumers. State regulators in particular may have to provide additional

safeguards so that consumers would be protected against such activities. Some, for

example, may intensify their oversight activities of utilities with wholesale power

subsidiaries, while others may decide on a new regulatory regime to protect the core

customers. Experience has shown that as an industry becomes more competitive its

regulators encounter greater pressure to ease the rigid principles of rate-of-return

regulation in accommodating new market conditions. This may happen in the case of

the electric industry in the coming years.

62

Page 75: IMPLICATIONS OF A NEW PUHCA FOR...Director Columbus, Ohio August 14, 1992 ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS The authors gratefully acknowledge the comments of Dr. Douglas N. Jones, Mr. Robert E. Burns,

APPENDIX

THE FINANCIAL LEVERAGE ISSUE

Introduction

One potential cost savings from nonutility power generation has sparked a great

deal of controversy, much debate in Congress with regard to PUHCA reform, and

undoubtedly has continued debate as the issue is likely to move to the state public utility

regulatory commissions. That controversy is the extent to which nonutility generators

(NUGs) have a lower cost of capital then their competing privately owned utilities

(IOUS).l Of course, if the alleged lower cost of capital is attributed to greater operating

efficiencies there would be little controversy; but conceivably a lower cost of capital

could result not from the NUGs doing a better job but from the effects of public utility

regulation on an IOU's capital structure and cost of capital. If this were the case, then

we would not have what some would call a "level playing field"; that is, more and more

capacity would flow to the NUGs not because of superior performance but because of a

quirk in the regulatory process.

This Appendix addresses this issue and its many ramifications for the cost of

electric power to consumers. The issue, in more definite terms, revolves around the

following suggestion: the cost of capital for an NUG is lower than the cost of capital for an

IOU because the utility is limited by the regulatory process in its ability to finance the assets

of the firm with debt capital whereas the NUG has no such limits. Specifically, a typical

IOU is limited to a debt capacity of approximately 50 percent, while in the unregulated

market of the NUG projects are often financed with higher levels of debt. Since debt

financing is generally less costly than equity financing, the common belief is that a higher

1 The cost of capital, for the purposes here, is defined as the weighted average of the annual percent interest cost of long-term debt, preferred dividends, and dividends and long-term capital appreciation of the common stock. Measurement is accomplished by market values.

63

Page 76: IMPLICATIONS OF A NEW PUHCA FOR...Director Columbus, Ohio August 14, 1992 ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS The authors gratefully acknowledge the comments of Dr. Douglas N. Jones, Mr. Robert E. Burns,

proportion of debt gives the NUG an inherent advantage with a lower cost of capital

unavailable to the IOU. Although the advantage is real it is unfair since the utility has

debt limits imposed by the regulatory commissions whereas the NUG has no such limits.

The issue, then, is a capital structure problem or more specifically an optimization

problem where the objective is to determine the optimum capital structure, which is

defined as the capital structure that maximizes the value of the firm or minimizes the

cost of capita1.2 The capital structure is defined as the mix of long-term debt and equity

financing. 3 Put another way, if a 50 percent debt capital structure is optimum then the

NU G will have no advantage and indeed may be disadvantaged by using higher levels of

debt. If on the other hand higher proportions of debt are optimum then the advantage

may shift to the NU G. In essence, knowing an optimum capital structure helps to

determine whether or not an NUG has a cost of capital advantage over an IOU when

bidding for new capacity.

The Naive Capital Structure

While determining an optimum capital structure is complex and no absolute

solution exists, a reasonable approximation can be made by applying a variety of

theoretical approaches. Consider two firms that are exactly alike in every respect except

that Firm A is financed entirely with equity and Firm B is financed with 50 percent debt

(at 9 percent interest expense) and 50 percent equity. Each firm has total assets of

$4,000, total sales of $2,000, and an operating margin of 40 percent. Each of these

2 The cost of capital literature is extensive and extremely detailed. The analysis to follow is a summary sketch of that literature. An excellent and thorough examination of the entire subject is presented in Richard A. Brealey and Stewart C. Myers, Principles of Corporate Finance, 4th ed. (New York: McGraw-Hill, Inc., 1991), Chpts. 16-19. Much of the discussion here draws on the work of Brealey and Myers.

3 The analysis to follow ignores the complications of preferred stock. This simplification will in no way materially affect the conclusions of the analysis on capital structure.

64

Page 77: IMPLICATIONS OF A NEW PUHCA FOR...Director Columbus, Ohio August 14, 1992 ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS The authors gratefully acknowledge the comments of Dr. Douglas N. Jones, Mr. Robert E. Burns,

factors is held constant to determine the effects of added debt upon the cost of capital.

The income statement of each firm is depicted in Table A-1 where the percent return on

equity is simply the net income divided by total equity, which is $4,000 in the case of

Firm A and $2,000 for Firm B.

Given these conditions, then, what value will the investment community place on

each firm assuming that each investor will attempt to maximize the return for a given

level of risk or correspondingly minimize risk for a given level of return? To solve this

question, consider for the moment two investment alternatives of $2,000 in Firm A or

$2,000 in Firm B. Which will be preferred? The obvious answer is the investment in

Firm B since that investment produces an annual income of 31 percent compared to the

investment in Firm A which produces only 20 percent annually. As a consequence, the

investment community will bid up the shares of Firm B, lowering its cost of capital and

giving Firm B an advantage over Firm A in any sort of competitive dual between the two

firms. This advantage will exist for any and all levels of debt. Graphically, Figure A-1

depicts the cost of capital as related to the capital structure or the amount of debt, given

the conditions just described.

TABLE A-I

HYPOTHETICAL INCOME STATEMENT

FirmA

Total Revenues $2,000

Operating Expenses 1.200

Operating Margin 800

Interest Payments @ 9% __ 0

Net Income 800

% Return on Equity 20%

65

Firm B

$2,000

1.200

800

~

620

31%

Page 78: IMPLICATIONS OF A NEW PUHCA FOR...Director Columbus, Ohio August 14, 1992 ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS The authors gratefully acknowledge the comments of Dr. Douglas N. Jones, Mr. Robert E. Burns,

Cost

o Ratio of Debt to

100

tal Value, Percent

KE = Cost of Equity

Ko = Cost of Debt

Kc = Cost of Captial

Fig. A .. L Graphical representation of the cost of capital.

66

Page 79: IMPLICATIONS OF A NEW PUHCA FOR...Director Columbus, Ohio August 14, 1992 ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS The authors gratefully acknowledge the comments of Dr. Douglas N. Jones, Mr. Robert E. Burns,

Does the NUG gain an advantage by the debt limits placed on the IOU by

regulatory bodies? The clear and unequivocal answer given the investment alternatives

as outlined and Table A-I and Figure A-I is that the NUG does indeed enjoy a

substantial advantage well beyond any operating efficiencies it mayor may not enjoy.

Either the IOU should be allowed to increase its debt or the NUG's debt levels should

be restricted.

The question is not so easily resolved, however. The behavior of the cost of

capital as a decreasing function of debt levels (as depicted in Figure A-I) has serious

flaws and perhaps can best be referred to as the naive model. It is naive in the sense

that it ignores the greater risk of higher levels of debt and the efficiency of modern

capital markets.

The Modi2liani and Miller Capital Structure

To adjust for these deficiencies, consider an investor with $2,000 to invest, and

who is willing to accept the risk of Firm B with its greater debt level. The investor

could, of course, purchase all of the shares of Firm B. The investor, on the other hand,

could also achieve exactly the same risk-return parameters by purchasing all of the

shares of Firm A with the same $2,000 and a personal loan amounting to 50 percent of

the cost of the shares of Firm A. In essence, the investor could substitute personal debt

for corporate debt. Table A-2 depicts these alternative investment strategies.

Each investment strategy yields exactly the same result: each has a return of 31

percent, the same business risk since the firms are identical in every resect except for the

use of debt, and the same financial risk since both investments employ $2,000 of debt at

an interest rate of 9 percent. The investment community therefore will be indifferent

between these investment alternatives. As a consequence neither firm will enjoy an

advantage because of different capital structures. The total value of the firm is

independent of the capital structure since the capital structure will not affect the risk­

return parameters of the investor even though it may affect the risk-return parameters of

the equity of the firm.

67

Page 80: IMPLICATIONS OF A NEW PUHCA FOR...Director Columbus, Ohio August 14, 1992 ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS The authors gratefully acknowledge the comments of Dr. Douglas N. Jones, Mr. Robert E. Burns,

TABLE A-2

ALTERNATIVE INVESTMENT STRATEGIES

Strategy Investment One Two

Personal Equity in Firm B $2,000

Personal Equity in Firm A $2,000

Personal Debt in Firm A @ 9% $2,000

Return to Investor

Net Dollars 620 620*

% Return on Personal Equity 31% 31%

*Equal to $800 income from the investment in Firm A less the 9 percent cost of the personal debt or $180.

Put another way, the investment community as a whole receives $800 from each

investment strategy. In the case of Strategy One, the investment community receives

$620 from the equity investment and $180 from the corporate debt sold to investors. In

Strategy Two, the investment community receives $620 from the equity investment and

$180 from the investor's personal debt borrowed from the investment community for a

total of $800 of income to the macro investment community.

This result is the now well known Modigliani and Miller (M & M) Propositions 1

& 11:4 the value of a firm is a function of the risk-return parameters of the assets of the

firm and the cost of capital is constant for all capital structures. This is because the cost

4 Franco Modigliani and Merton H. Miller, "The Cost of Capital, Corporation Finance and the Theory of Investment," American Economic Review, 48 (June 1958): 261-97.

68

Page 81: IMPLICATIONS OF A NEW PUHCA FOR...Director Columbus, Ohio August 14, 1992 ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS The authors gratefully acknowledge the comments of Dr. Douglas N. Jones, Mr. Robert E. Burns,

of equity will rise with greater debt to exactly offset the cost reducing properties of lower

cost debt.5 This cost of capital result is depicted graphically in Figure A-2.

Does the NUG have a cost advantage over the investor-owned utility? The

obvious answer is no, given the M & M conditions; there is no controversy--the playing

field is level, and state regulatory commissioners need not worry that the regulation of

the capital structure of a utility places them at a competitive disadvantage relative to

NUGs. A pretty easy and straightforward result.

Perfect Capital Markets

Like the naive model, however, the real world is not quite as simple and

straightforward as the M & M world just described; Modigliani and Miller would be the

first to agree. Before developing a capital structure approach more in keeping with

reality, however, it should be noted that one important assumption of the M & M

propositions is, in all probability, very close to the world of large electric utilities. M &

M assume a perfect capital market where personal debt can be substituted for corporate

debt at the same rate of interest and where assets with equal risk-return parameters will

have equal prices.

The literature and evidence on this subject is enormous and new evidence is being

developed continuously. Still in the case of large publicly traded firms in the United

States, any capital market imperfections without doubt are so small as to have negligible

effects on the cost of capital or the value of the firm. Furthermore, any potential

problems with the debt substitution assumption will also be inconsequential since there

are a whole host of active professional and institutional investors fully capable of

borrowing at corporate rates. Modern capital markets, as they present themselves to a

large utility or NUG, are close enough to the M & M assumptions to conclude the

validity of the M & M results for the purposes here.

5 See Figure A-2 for a graphical illustration of this cost of capital effect.

69

Page 82: IMPLICATIONS OF A NEW PUHCA FOR...Director Columbus, Ohio August 14, 1992 ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS The authors gratefully acknowledge the comments of Dr. Douglas N. Jones, Mr. Robert E. Burns,

Cost

o 100

Ratio of Debt to Total Value, Percent

KE = Cost of Equity

Ko = Cost of Debt

Kc = Cost of Captial

Fig. A-2. Graphical representation of the cost of capital under M & M conditions.

70

Page 83: IMPLICATIONS OF A NEW PUHCA FOR...Director Columbus, Ohio August 14, 1992 ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS The authors gratefully acknowledge the comments of Dr. Douglas N. Jones, Mr. Robert E. Burns,

Tax Modifications to the M & M Capital Structure

While the actual performance of modern capital markets does not negate the M

& M conclusions, the existence of taxes does. Up to this point the examples have

assumed a world of no taxes or more specifically a world where interest cost is not

deductible.

To clarify the effects of corporate taxes, Table A-3 is a partial reproduction of

Table A-I beginning with the operating margin for our two identical firms but adding

taxes at a rate of 35 percent. Table A-4 is a partial reproduction of Table A-2, which

describes two investment strategies of purchasing all of the shares of Firm B or all of the

shares of Firm A, with half the purchase price of Firm A obtained from personal

borrowing.

Clearly the inclusion of taxes, or more accurately the deductibility of interest

payments, has a major effect. The investment strategy of purchasing the shares of Firm

B which has 50 percent debt is more profitable then the purchase of Firm A with the use

of personal debt instead of corporate debt. Specifically, personal leverage has not

equated the investment strategies because the interest expense of Firm B represents a

tax deductible expense. The use of debt in the realistic taxable world has therefore given

Firm B a greater market value or lower cost of capital and a consequent competitive

advantage over Firm A because of its financial structure rather than any operating

efficiencies. (It should be noted here that the existence of personal taxes does not change

this conclusion given relatively similar corporate and personal tax rates.)

As before, we can depict this situation graphically as is done in Figure A-3, which

is close to the behavior of the cost of capital as depicted in Figure A-I, the naive model.

It is not exactly the naive model, but clearly the existence of taxes creates a decline in

the cost of capital with added debt. If this were the total story, then the NUG is

advantaged. There are, however, at least three factors that reduce the extent of the

decline and in fact cause the cost of capital curve to turn up at some level of debt.

71

Page 84: IMPLICATIONS OF A NEW PUHCA FOR...Director Columbus, Ohio August 14, 1992 ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS The authors gratefully acknowledge the comments of Dr. Douglas N. Jones, Mr. Robert E. Burns,

TABLE A-3

HYPOTHETICAL INCOME STATEMENT INCLUDING CORPORATE INCOME TAXES

FirmA

Operating Margin $800

Interest Expense @ 9% ~

Net Income Before Taxes 800

'!'axes @ 35% 280

Net Income 520

% Return on Equity 13.00%

TABLE A-4

ALTERNATIVE INVESTMENT STRATEGIES WITH CORPORATE INCOME TAXES

Investment

Personal Equity in Firm B

Personal Equity in Firm A

Personal Debt in Firm A @ 9%

Return to Investor

Net Dollars

% Return on Personal Equity

Strategy One

$2,000

403

20.15%

Firm B

$800

180

620 "' ... ,..., ~ll

403

20.15%

Two

$2,000

2,000

340*

17.00%

*Equal to $520 income from the investment in Firm A less the 9 percent cost of the personal debt of $180.

72

Page 85: IMPLICATIONS OF A NEW PUHCA FOR...Director Columbus, Ohio August 14, 1992 ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS The authors gratefully acknowledge the comments of Dr. Douglas N. Jones, Mr. Robert E. Burns,

Cost

o 100

Ratio of Debt to ~ tal Value, Percent

KE = Cost of Equity

Ko :: Cost of Debt

Kc :: Cost of Captial

Fig. A~3. Graphical representation of the cost of capital under M & M conditions including corporate taxes.

73

Page 86: IMPLICATIONS OF A NEW PUHCA FOR...Director Columbus, Ohio August 14, 1992 ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS The authors gratefully acknowledge the comments of Dr. Douglas N. Jones, Mr. Robert E. Burns,

Other Adjustments to the M & M Capital Structure

The first factor is that interest deductibility is an advantage only when the

corporation pays taxes; this is an obvious statement but one that will initially reduce the

cost of capital as small amounts of debt are added but at some point the cost of capital

would eventually increase. In the example, both firms earn $800 before interest and

taxes on average.

If, for example, this average consists of equal probabilities of $1,600 and $0 then

the tax deductibility of interest will benefit Firm B only when the earnings are $1,600.

At $0 earnings there is no tax benefit other than the possibility of a tax-loss carry­

forward which, while an advantage, is nevertheless a major detriment to the tax benefits

of debt financing.

The implication for the cost of capital is that it will decline initially from the tax

deductibility of interest when the probability that earnings do not exceed the interest

obligation is rather small. As the probability of net losses increases, however, the

benefits of tax deductibility decline and as a consequence the cost of capital begins to

increase. One cannot generalize what levels of debt will create an increase since

business risk differs from firm to firm. One can generalize, however, that the increasing

probability of loss created by higher levels of debt eventually will increase the cost of

capital after an initial decline.

A second factor contributing to an increase in the cost of capital beyond some

level of debt is the fact that as the capital structure of the firm shifts more toward debt

and away from equity, the business risks of the firm begin to shift to the debt

instruments; that is, at very small amounts of debt the probability of default on the

interest or principal obligations caused by a business downturn, poor management, or

just plain bad luck is also small. As debt levels increase, however, the probability of

default begins to increase as a function of business risk such that in the extreme (100

percent debt) the cost of capital must return to the cost of equity since 100 percent debt

is equivalent to 100 percent equity. This is, of course, precisely why (holding all other

74

Page 87: IMPLICATIONS OF A NEW PUHCA FOR...Director Columbus, Ohio August 14, 1992 ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS The authors gratefully acknowledge the comments of Dr. Douglas N. Jones, Mr. Robert E. Burns,

factors constant) lower bond ratings and the consequent rise in interest costs are directly

associated with higher levels of debt.

In essence, as debt is added to the capital structure the debt instruments begin to

take on the same risks as the firm's common stock. As a consequence, the cost of the

debt begins to approach the cost of the equity. The result is the cost of capital declining

with small amounts of debt when this risk shifting is insignificant, but beginning to rise as

larger and larger amounts of debt are used in the capital structure. The reason for this

is that the debt instruments begin to take on the business risk of the firm as equity is

replaced. In general, the effect is similar to the declining value of interest-payment tax

deductibility mentioned earlier.

The third factor relates to the costs of financial distress. These costs become very

difficult to quantify but exist nevertheless. They include the administrative, legal, and

accounting costs of bankruptcy as well as the costs of operating inefficiencies that result

inevitably when a firm is either close to bankruptcy or actually in bankruptcy. Examples

of such operating inefficiencies include deferred maintenance, a loss of the better

employees as they seek greater security with other firms, elimination of profitable but

cash poor activities, and the addition of unprofitable but cash rich activities. The list

could go on and on. The point is that as debt levels are increased the probability

increases that these costs will materialize. Furthermore, actual bankruptcy is not

required for many of these cost to exist nor can they be ignored if a recovery from

bankruptcy is expected.

As with the previous analysis, the potential costs of financial distress have very

little effect on the cost of capital with small amounts of debt. As debt levels increase,

however, there comes a point when the cost of capital begins to increase as the

possibility increases that some or all of these costs will enter into the income statement

of the firm.

The Real World Cost of Capital

To summarize, the tax deductibility of corporate interest payments creates a

condition where added levels of debt can be associated \vith a declining cost of capital.

75

Page 88: IMPLICATIONS OF A NEW PUHCA FOR...Director Columbus, Ohio August 14, 1992 ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS The authors gratefully acknowledge the comments of Dr. Douglas N. Jones, Mr. Robert E. Burns,

The decline is independent of operating efficiencies. Hence, a firm with higher levels of

debt is advantaged over an identical firm with lower levels of debt. This advantage,

however, exists only for moderate amounts of debt. As debt levels become large, the

firm's cost of capital begins to increase because of three factors: (1) a decline in the

value of the tax deductibility of interest payments caused by an increasing probability of

loss, (2) a shifting of greater amounts of business risk to the debt instruments of the firm

causing the cost of capital to approach the cost of equity, and (3) the increasing

probability that the firm will incur some or all of the very real costs of financial distress.

The result of these several factors is that the cost of capital initially declines with

added debt, but at some point begins to increase with higher and higher levels of debt.

Graphically, the general consensus is that the cost of capital curve is a saucer-shaped

curve as depicted in Figure A-4. There is in fact an optimum capital structure that will

minimize the cost of capital or maximize the value of the firm. Most financial experts

agree, however, that the optimum is not a point but rather a fairly large range of debt

and equity combinations.

The Cost of Capital Advanta2e for the NUG

What, then, does Figure A-4 reveal about the original question? Does the NUG

have a competitive advantage over the traditional IOU in terms of a lower cost of capital

resulting from the unregulated nature of the NUG and its consequent ability to establish

a capital structure with a larger amount of debt? As in most economic situations an

absolute, unambiguous answer cannot be established. Figure A-4 should allow a

reasonable approximation, however.

Assuming as before that an NUG has no operating or other nonfinancial edge,

Figure A-4 suggests that any advantage that an NUG may enjoy from its capital structure

is extremely limited and in all probability does not exist. In fact, Figure A-4 suggests

that, in virtually every situation, the capital structure of an NUG is more likely to be

neutral in its competition with the typical IOU. For an NUG to enjoy a capital structure

advantage the capital structure of the IOU is assumed to be less than optimum; that is,

76

Page 89: IMPLICATIONS OF A NEW PUHCA FOR...Director Columbus, Ohio August 14, 1992 ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS The authors gratefully acknowledge the comments of Dr. Douglas N. Jones, Mr. Robert E. Burns,

st

o Ratio of

100

ebt to Total Value, Percent

Kc = Cost of Captial

Fig. A .. 4. Consensus cost of capital reflecting real world conditions.

77

Page 90: IMPLICATIONS OF A NEW PUHCA FOR...Director Columbus, Ohio August 14, 1992 ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS The authors gratefully acknowledge the comments of Dr. Douglas N. Jones, Mr. Robert E. Burns,

if the amount of debt of an IOU is at the optimum which minimizes the cost of capital

the NUG cannot enjoy an advantage. At the minimum the capital structure effect is

neutral. If the IOU's capital structure falls within the large flat area of the cost of

capital curve of Figure A-4, the NUG's capital structure could only be neutral or a

disadvantage in its competition with the IOU in the unlikely event that the NUG does

not employ an optimum capital structure. The playing field is level and there is no

reason either to regulate the NUG or deregulate the IOU's capital structure. Both have

minimized the cost of capital and the consumer is well served.

Of course, it is possible that the IOU is not at the minimum cost of capital. In

Figure A-5, the IOU would employ an amount of debt that is less than the amount

implied at point A. Its amount of debt would be insufficient to minimize the cost of

capital. If, on the other hand, the actual amount of debt placed the capital structure of

the IOU at point B in Figure A-5, the NUG would enjoy a cost of capital advantage at

any debt level that was greater than point B but less than point C. Such a condition

could exist, but that would require the capital structures of virtually all of the IOUs to be

somewhat less than optimum, which may be possible. Such a situation seems highly

unlikely for several reasons, however.

First, the capital structure of a contemporary electric utility company is the result

of massive amounts of research, experimentation, experience, and good judgment by

utility executives, commissions, and academics with the general agreement that a capital

structure with approximately 50 percent debt is optimum.

Second, if the typical IOU were capable of reducing its cost of capital with added

debt, rates of return on the common stock of those IOUs would be lower than what one

would expect from equity securities with comparable levels of business and financial risk.

The existence of such abnormal returns has not been demonstrated to anyone's

satisfaction.

Third, cost of capital calculations by their nature are imprecise and should not be

applied in a way that calls for a great deal of accuracy. If the IOU is operating with a

suboptimum capital structure, it is reasonable to suggest that the deviations from the

78

Page 91: IMPLICATIONS OF A NEW PUHCA FOR...Director Columbus, Ohio August 14, 1992 ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS The authors gratefully acknowledge the comments of Dr. Douglas N. Jones, Mr. Robert E. Burns,

Cost

o atio of Debt to

100

tal Value, ercent

KC = Cost of Captial

Fig. A .. 5. Hypothetical electric utility cost of capital curve.

79

Page 92: IMPLICATIONS OF A NEW PUHCA FOR...Director Columbus, Ohio August 14, 1992 ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS The authors gratefully acknowledge the comments of Dr. Douglas N. Jones, Mr. Robert E. Burns,

minimum are not great and are more than likely within the measurement errors expected

when estimating the cost of capital.

Last, it is crucially important to recognize that if the IOU's capital structure

indeed is less than optimum, policymakers should not expend their energy on reducing

the amounts of debt issued by the NUGs. Instead, they should consider either

deregulating the capital structures of the IOUs or increasing the amounts of debt allowed

the IOU to benefit the consumer. In other words, if the IOU capital structure is

inappropriate the issue has nothing to do with the existence of the NU Gs. The cost of

capital is not at a minimum and should be reduced independent of the potential

competition from the NU G.

In addition, it should be noted that the greater use of debt by the NUGs has a far

better explanation then the possibility of suboptimum capital structures of the IOUs.

The most obvious explanation is that the capital structures of both the NUG and the

IOU fall within the large flat area of the cost of capital curve. More specifically, it is

reasonable to conclude that the typical IOU debt limits of approximately 50 percent are

at the minimum debt levels required to achieve an optimum, and that the NUG uses of

debt of 75 percent to 90 percent are also within the optimum range of the minimum cost

of capital.

It is also the case that the saucer-shaped cost of capital curve is perfectly

consistent with a state commission limiting debt to approximately 50 percent of capital

even though many utility executives and others believe there is greater debt capacity

within most electric utilities. If the 50 percent level occurs early within the large flat

area of the cost of capital curve, there is no compelling reason either from the

consumers' point of view or the stockholders' to expand the amount of debt within the

capital structure. The cost of capital has been minimized and adding debt is of no value

even though more debt could be carried without jeopardizing service to the customer.

It seems, then, that there is very little to suggest that the capital structure of the

IOU is producing a cost of capital greater than the minimum available, which is required

to conclude that the greater debt levels employed by the typical NUG provide a

80

Page 93: IMPLICATIONS OF A NEW PUHCA FOR...Director Columbus, Ohio August 14, 1992 ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS The authors gratefully acknowledge the comments of Dr. Douglas N. Jones, Mr. Robert E. Burns,

competitive advantage. Suboptimum behavior by the IOU is possible, but it would seem

that burden of proof lies with those who claim an advantage for the NUG.6

At this point, it should be noted that the NUG may have a lower cost of capital

than the IOU not because of a capital structure advantage but because of some other

business advantage that either increases the net income or reduces risk. As noted, these

factors could be operating or managerial efficiencies, a modern plant, even a variety of

risk reducing activities such as shifting market risk to the IOU. These activities,

however, are not capital structure issues, but asset issues. If they generate an unfair

competitive advantage, the commission should react not by becoming involved in a

capital structure debate but by focusing on the asset issue directly.

It is also important to recognize that this discussion has focused on the long-term

securities of the IOU. That is, long-term debt represents approximately 50 percent of

total capitalization but all debt, both short and long, represents approximately 65 percent

of all capital of the typical IOU. Correspondingly, it is less clear from the balance sheet

of the typical NUG whether or not the long-term debt on the books is permanent or

temporary in the sense that principal is repaid by substituting debt for equity or simply

replacing existing debt with new debt. These short-term, long-term aspects of the capital

structure issue are usually unique to the particular situation and typically are not

generalizable. They are mentioned to recognize that the use of debt of all types may not

be quite as different between the NUG and the IOU as is often portrayed. More

specifically, the IOU finances more than 50 percent of its assets with debt including

short-term debt. The NUG may, on a permanent basis, have less long-term debt than

the contemporary balance sheet would indicate. In other words, the flat area of the cost

6 It should be noted that these arguments do not rely on a saucer shaped cost of capital curve. The optimum could be a point with a curve shaped more like a "V." Such a curve prohibits a situation where both the IOU and the NUG are at optimums with different debt levels holding all other factors constant. It would still be the case, that to demonstrate an advantage, independent evidence would have to show that IOU debt levels are sub-optimum.

81

Page 94: IMPLICATIONS OF A NEW PUHCA FOR...Director Columbus, Ohio August 14, 1992 ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS The authors gratefully acknowledge the comments of Dr. Douglas N. Jones, Mr. Robert E. Burns,

of capital curve need not be very long for both the IOU and the NUG to be operating

with an optimum capital structure.

Summary and Conclusions

The cost of capital as related to the amount of corporate debt is neither the

constantly declining curve of the naive model, the M & M tax deductibility world, nor of

the constant value model of the nontax M & M model. Instead, the curve is more

complex describing a saucer shape where it initially declines from the tax-deductibility of

interest payments: it flattens out in an area where the tax deductibility is neutralized

from the increasing probability of eliminating the tax-deductibility value, the shifting of

business risk to the debt securities of the firm, and the increasing probability that some

or all of the costs of financial distress will be incurred by the firm. Eventually, these last

three factors will overwhelm the tax-deductibility value of debt and create an increasing

cost of capital curve. Under these conditions, it is unlikely that an NUG will have a cost

of capital advantage over the IOU. For such an advantage to exist one must assume that

the IOU's current debt level is less than optimum, which seems highly unlikely on several

counts.

As a consequence, it is reasonable to conclude that the NUG is not advantaged as

a result of the existence of debt limits placed upon the IOUs by regulators. The capital

structures of an NUG and IOU are neutral in the competition between them. It is

possible, however, that the NUG may be advantaged with a lower cost of capital not

because of capital structure differences but because of other advantages which could

include operating or managerial efficiencies, less risky or more lucrative markets, or a

more modern physical plant, to name a few of the many potential influences on the cost

of capital. The analysis here has held all of these factors constant to isolate the capital

structure effects. These other factors could be real and may give the NUG a major

advantage. The inescapable conclusion from the analysis here is that the greater

amounts of debt that an NUG is able to employ in its capital structure is unlikely to give

it a competitive advantage. If there is a cost of capital advantage it does not arise from

the capital structure but, instead, must be attributed to other operating factors.

82

Page 95: IMPLICATIONS OF A NEW PUHCA FOR...Director Columbus, Ohio August 14, 1992 ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS The authors gratefully acknowledge the comments of Dr. Douglas N. Jones, Mr. Robert E. Burns,
Page 96: IMPLICATIONS OF A NEW PUHCA FOR...Director Columbus, Ohio August 14, 1992 ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS The authors gratefully acknowledge the comments of Dr. Douglas N. Jones, Mr. Robert E. Burns,