interfirm relational exchange: the role of …

22
INTERFIRM RELATIONAL EXCHANGE: THE ROLE OF ANTECEDENTS AND PARADIGMS IN EXAMINING RELATIONSHIP QUALITY Wesley J. Johnston R. Edward Sibley Department of Marketing Georgia State University Atlanta, Georgia 30303 USA Phone: (404)651-2740 FAX: (404)651-4198 735.

Upload: others

Post on 03-Feb-2022

3 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

INTERFIRM RELATIONAL EXCHANGE: THE ROLE OF ANTECEDENTS AND

PARADIGMS IN EXAMINING RELATIONSHIP QUALITY

Wesley J. Johnston

R. Edward Sibley

Department of MarketingGeorgia State University

Atlanta, Georgia 30303 USAPhone: (404)651-2740FAX: (404)651-4198

735.

INTERFIRM RELATIONAL EXCHANGE: THE ROLE OF ANTECEDENTS AND

PARADIGMS IN EXAMINING RELATIONSHIP QUALITY

Abstract

Relational exchange is exerting a profound influence on business-to-business researchers and practitioners. While a number of paradigms have been proposed to evaluate interfirm relational exchange, little attention has been paid to why relationships are formed and what these antecedents require in terms of evaluative paradigms.

Six antecedents to relationship formation necessity, asymmetry, reciprocity, efficiency, stability, and legitimacy-are identified and a formal typology is developed that crosses these antecedents with the five leading paradigms for evaluating interfirm relational exchange- transaction cost analysis, agency theory, relational contracting theory, resource-dependence theory, and political economy theory. Conclusions are drawn regarding which paradigms are most appropriate for evaluating relational exchange under each antecedent condition.

The authors argue that, rather than competing views of a single reality, the five paradigms are complementary approaches that should be treated as a toolkit-applying each, in turn, under the appropriate conditions. As an exemplar, an argument for a comprehensive, dyadic firm-level measure of relationship quality is advanced and implications for relationship quality are examined in light of the antecedent/paradigm typology.

736.

INTERFIRM RELATIONAL EXCHANGE: THE ROLE OF ANTECEDENTS AND

PARADIGMS IN EXAMINING RELATIONSHIP QUALITY

Introduction

Relational exchange is exerting a profound influence on business-to-business researchers

and practitioners. While a number of paradigms have been proposed to evaluate interfirm

relational exchange, little attention has been paid to why relationships are formed and what these

antecedents require in terms of evaluative paradigms. Oliver, in a seminal 1990 work, distills

some 30 years of research into six identifiable "contingencies," or antecedents, for the formation of

interorganizational relationships: necessity, asymmetry, reciprocity, efficiency, stability, and

legitimacy. The purpose of this paper is to develop a formal typology that applies the OHver

(1990) antecedents to illustrate the contributions and limitations of each of the five leading

paradigms transaction cost analysis (TCA), agency theory, relational contracting theory, resource-

dependence theory, and political economy theory-when applied to relationship quality, a key

concept in interfirm relational exchange.

The next section delineates the concept of relational exchange and its importance.

Following that is a review of each of the six antecedent conditions that drive the formation of

interorganizational relationships. Next, the authors provide an overview of each of the five leading

paradigms that are used to evaluate aspects of relational exhange. The fourth section reviews the

concept of relationship quality a key concept in relational exchange which will be used as an

exemplar in developing a typology of antecedents and paradigms. Finally, the authors develop a

formal typology that crosses the antecedent conditions with the paradigms appropriate to the study

of the relationship quality aspect of relational exchange. A cell-by-cell perspective is given in Table

1; the text provides a comparison of the uses, strengths, and limitations of the applicable paradigms

under each antecedent condition.

"737.

Relational Exchange

Exchange is one of the cone concepts of modern marketing theory (Kotler 1972; Bagozzi

1975). Indeed, Hunt (1983), in summarizing years of debate on the conceptual domain of

marketing, concluded "... the primary focus of marketing is the exchange relationship" (p.9).

Dwyer, Schurr, and Oh (1987) note that one of the key conceptual benefits from the notion of

exchange is that: "Finally, and most important, as a critical event in the marketplace (emphasis in

the original) it allows the careful study of antecedent conditions and processes for buyer-seller

exchange" (p. 11).

Macneil's (1980) groundbreaking work provides a conceptual underpinning for much

current thought by introducing a formal conceptualization of exchange as either discrete or

relational. Macneil holds that discrete exchange consists of individual, non-recurring transactions

between independent parties, enforced, if necessary, through exercising legal and/or economic

sanctions. Discrete exchange was pithily exemplified by Dwyer, Schurr, and Oh (1987) as "a one-

time purchase of unbranded gasoline out-of-town at an independent station paid for with cash"

(P-12).

Macneil (1980) views relational exchange, to the contrary, as explicitly considering the

historical and social context surrounding the transactions. Kaufmann and Stern (1988) show that

compliance with obligations under relational exchange stems from a mutuality of interests rather

than from threats. Dwyer, Schurr, and Oh (1987) and Anderson and Weitz (1992) have adapted

Macneil's (1980) work specifically to a marketing context of interfirm exchange, noting that

relational exchange takes place: 1) over time; 2) in anticipation of future transactions between the

parties; and 3) in a spirit of making (and expecting the exchange partner to make) short-term

sacrifices, if necessary, to gain long-term benefits.

This body of thought has led many marketing scholars to the conclusion that most interfirm

exchange is relational exchange. Despite a notable dissent by Jackson (1985) as to when relational

exchange is appropriate, researchers and practitioners alike are rushing to embrace the relational

exchange taxonomy.

738.

Antecedents

Oliver (1990) conducted a sweeping review of the interorganizational relationship (IOR)

literature, in part "to integrate the existing IOR literature into a set of critical contingencies of

relationship formation" (p. 241). She isolates six contingencies, or antecedents, to relationship

formation that appear generalizable across different firms, settings, and types of relationships:

necessity, asymmetry, reciprocity, efficiency, stability, and legitimacy.

Necessity

Necessity refers to the establishment of interorganizational linkages to satisfy requirements

mandated by higher authorities generally, legal or regulatory requirements. Warren (1967)

distinguished a category of single IOR contexts, and Whetten (1981) explored corporate structures

of coordination, where interaction is dictated by a higher authority. Note that necessity is the only

non-voluntary antecedent condition to interorganizational relationship formation.

Asymmetry

Oliver (1990) views asymmetry as prompting relationship formation "by the potential to

exercise power or control over another organization or its resources" (p.243). Power, in this

sense, is conceptualized either as general economic power (e.g., firm size or control over the rules

governing exchange, cf. Emerson 1962; Blau 1964) or control over resources (e.g., concentration

of inputs, the ability to forego or substitute certain inputs, see Pfeffer and Salancik 1978; also

Whetten 1981).

Reciprocity

This contingency is based in the very core of the concept of exchange: that, in noncoercive

situations, two parties will engage in exchange only if both benefit. Thus, Levine and White

(1961) argue that interfirm relations are established to pursue common or mutually beneficial

interests. Oliver (1990, p. 244) summarizes that "motives of reciprocity emphasize cooperation,

collaboration, and coordination among organizations, rather than domination, power, and control."

"739.

Efficiency

The contingency of efficiency reflects classic microeconomic thought and is internally

rooted in the firm's drive to improve its cost structure or profitability (cf. Coase 1937; Williamson

1975). Empirical work on efficiency as an antecedent of relationship formation is sparse. As

Oliver (1990) notes, the logical vanguard of this effort, economists, have been more interested in

the suboptimal market consequences of interfirm relationships.

Stability

Establishment of interfirm relations as an adaptive response to conditions of

environmental uncertainty has been noted by many scholars (e.g., Etgar 1977; Pfeffer and Salancik

1978; Williamson 1981; Achrol, Reve, and Stern 1983; Amdt 1983; Anderson and Weitz 1992).

Firms seek relationships with other firms, Oliver (1990) notes, "as coping strategies to forestall,

forecast, or absorb uncertainty in order to achieve an orderly, reliable pattern of resource flows and

exchanges" (p. 246).

Legitimacy

Champions of institutional theory (e.g., Zucker 1977; Tolbert and Zucker 1983) argue that

environments put pressure on firms to justify their activities. Thus, organizations might elect to

target internal or external stakeholders, or legal or regulatory "higher authorities" (Galaskiewicz

1985) to convince them that the firm is "in agreement with the prevailing norms, rules, beliefs, or

expectations" (Oliver 1990, p.246) that these constituencies hold.

Paradigms

Five main paradigms have been proposed to explore interfirm relational exchange-­

transaction cost analysis, agency theory, relational contracting theory, resource-dependence theory,

and political economy theory.

Transaction Cost Analysis (TCA)

Transaction cost analysis (TCA) stems from work in microeconomics dating from Coase's

(1937) examination of "make or buy" decisions, but it was developed principally by Williamson

(1975, 1979,1981), who blends classic "rational actor" microeconomics with organization theory

and contract law. TCA is primarily an efficiency through structure argument. As Noordewier,

John, and Nevin (1990) put it, "a distinctive feature of TCA is that it is based on the assumption

that firms are motivated to craft efficient organizational forms or governance structures" (p. 80).

Williamson (1979) describes TCA as a system of bounded rationality that also guards the exchange

against opportunism, which he previously defined as "self-interest seeking with guile"

(Williamson 1975, p. 6).

Williamson (1975) conceptualizes the choice of governance structure as either "market"

(essentially governance via price-mediated mechanisms) or "hierarchy" (that is, governance via an

unified authority structure). In later formulations, Williamson (1985) introduces an intermediate

choice of governance structure "hybrid"--which combines elements of market governance and

hierarchy governance. He contends that "the principal dimensions for describing transactions are

asset specificity, uncertainty, and frequency" (p. 72). Williamson (1985) theorizes that, in the

presence of significant levels of these dimensions, transaction costs accrue that result in hybrid or

hierarchy replacing market as the more efficient choice of governance structure.

Agency Theory

Agency theory may be classified as somewhat of an offshot of TCA that derives from the

economics, finance, and contract law arenas. In law, an agency relationship exists when one party

depends on (and provides authorization) to a second party to undertake some action on the first

party's behalf (White 1985). Though this relationship traditionally (in law and, to some extent, in

economics) has been applied to explicit legal contracts, White (1985) cites a trend away from the

necessity of formal, explicit contracts. This allows social scientists to employ the theory to

evaluate implicit social contracts such as peer acceptance, peer pressure, and social norms.

Bergen, Dutta, and Walker (1992) in their comprehensive review of agency theory note:

"The focus of the theory is on determining the most efficient contract to govern a particular

relationship given the characteristics of the parties involved and the fact that environmental

uncertainty and the costs of obtaining information make it impossible for the principal to monitor

the agent completely" (p. 2). Bergen et al. (1992) point out some differences between TCA and

741.

agency theory: 1) the unit of analysis (the transaction, itself, in TCA versus the individual agent in

agency theory); and 2) TCA's emphasis on ex post transaction costs versus agency theory's

emphasis on reducing ex post costs through an ex ante alignment of incentives. However, they

cogently summarize the foremost drawback to agency theory in an exchange setting:

It is important to note that most agency models define efficiency from the principal's point of view. The assumption is that the prinicpal is the dominant party in the relationship. Thus, an efficient contract is one that brings about the best possible outcome for the principal (italics in the original) given the constraints imposed by the situation, rather than one that maximizes the joint utility of both principal and agent (p. 2).

Relational Contracting Theory

Relational contracting theory was developed (1980), extended (1981,1983) and

summarized (1987) by Macneil. It serves as a fundament in the conceptualization of exchange as

occurring between parties in patterns on a continuum from highly discrete to highly relational (or,

in later formulations, highly intertwined; Macneil 1987).

Macneil (1987) summarized relational contracting theory as: 1) encompassed by the world

of contract, which he definies (p. 274) as relations among parties "who have exchanged, are

exchanging, or expect to be exchanging in the future"; 2) several behaviors-notably reciprocity

and solidarity-are required for such relations to exist; 3) the behavior patterns lead to the formation

of norms; 4) exchange occurs in patterns along a continuum from highly discrete to highly

relational; 5) discrete contracts are of short duration with no expectation of future cooperation

between the parties, limited interaction, easily measured, without sharing of benefits or burdens;

and 6) relational contracts have the opposite characteristics of discrete contracts.

Relational contracting theory has proven to be a difficult paradigm to employ. This could

be because evaluation under either the Dubin (1979) or Bachrach (1989) criteria for organizational

theories leads to the conclusion that relational contracting theory is not a formal theory, but, rather,

is a framework. As such, it is difficult to reduce observations drawn to rigorously formulated,

testable hypotheses.

Political Economy Theory

The roots of the political economy paradigm trace from the development of modern

economics in the late 17th and early 18th centuries. Amdt (1983), in his seminal theoretical

explication, posits an"organizational approach to political economy" (p. 47) which began with the

work of Zald (1970). Stern and Reve (1980) conceived of social systems as "comprising

interacting sets of major economic and socio-political forces which affect collective behavior and

performance" (p. 53) of the focal social unit. Building on Stern and Reve, Arndt (1983) refines

this idea: "More specifically, political economy emphasizes the interplay of power, the goals of the

power wielders, and the productive economic exchange systems" (p. 47). In Arndt's (1983)

development of a taxonomy of political economy analysis, he makes the contribution of moving

beyond the traditional continua of external/internal and political/economic components of

differentiadon by separating out environmental influences as a fifth factor.

Nevertheless, while political economy theory has enjoyed some popularity, it has not been

accepted as widely as some of the other paradigms that are being reviewed. As Arndt (1983),

himself, points out: "The most important limitations of the political economy paradigm relate to the

methodological problems and the vagueness and incompleteness of the framework" (p. 52). This

is not surprising since, as is the case with the relational contracting paradigm, the political economy

paradigm is a framework, not a theory, under the Dubin (1979) and Bachrach (1989) criteria.

Resource-Dependence Theory

Resource-dependence theory derives directly from Emerson's (1962) work on the role of

power in social exchange. Emerson argues that the relative power between two parties in an

exchange relationship is determined by (and correlated inversely to) their relative dependence.

Relative dependence was defined as the other party in the relationship having resources the first

party needs and controlling the alternative sources of these resources. This is the rationale behind

Emerson's (1962) power-dependence model: the structural advantage accruing to one actor in a

relationship that can influence the other actor to comply with the former's needs or desires. This

model has been more fully conceptualized and developed as the resource-dependence model by

"743.

Pfeffer and Salancik (1978), who have applied it in the organizational behavior and organizational

design milieus.

Pfeffer and Salancik (1978) hold that, "in general, organizations will tend to be influenced

by those who control the resources they require" (p. 44). However, they suggest that three factors

determine one organization's dependence on another: 1) the importance of the resource; 2) the

extent to which one firm has discretion over the allocation and use of the resource; and 3) the extent

to which there are few alternatives, or the extent of control over the resource by the interest group.

These three factors enable one to gauge a firm's relative dependence vis-a-vis potential exchange

partners. Resource-dependence ties directly to our framework of relational interfirm exchange:

"The dependence we are describing results from exchange processes and from the requirements of

organizations to acquire resources and engage in exchange with their environments" (Pfeffer and

Salancik 1978, p. 52).

Relationship Quality

At the heart of the movement toward a relational exchange taxonomy is an assumption often

unstated and even more rarely demonstrated: high relationship quality engenders strong

relationships which lead to higher long-term sales and profits, with lower variability. What little

evidence that exists is anecdotal and contradictory (cf. Jackson 1985).

This state of affairs is understandable, however, since relationship quality must be defined

before this postulated chain of events can be empirically tested. Relationship quality is often

represented by one or another measure of satisfaction-usually as an outcome (e.g., Crosby,

Evans, and Cowles 1990), sometimes, as in attribution theory (Heider 1958), as an antecedent

(fairly common in the marriage literature in psychology; see Bradbury and Fincham 1990, for a

recent example). Psychologists also have resorted to studies that simply group and list attributes of

high- and low-quality relationships without attempting to provide an underlying theory (e.g., Cole

1985).

More usually, marketing scholars have attempted to import individual-level constructs,

such as commitment and trust, from psychology and adapt them to firm-level relationships (e.g.,

744.

Swan, Trawick, Rink and Roberts 1988; Crosby, Evans, and Cowles 1990; Anderson and Weitz

1992). This often results in confounding firm- and individual-level constructs, or gleaning only

single respondents' perceptions of the firm-level constructs. An additional issue is that many

researchers model only one party's perceptions of relationship quality (e.g., Anderson and Narus

1984,1990). Indeed, two of the paradigms previously discussed~TCA and, particularly, agency

theory-assume that a one-sided perspective is all that matters. However, as Rusbult (1980a;

1980b; 1983) and associates (Rusbult and Farrell 1983; Rusbult, Johnson, and Morrow 1986)

point out, any party will stay in a relationship only so long as the benefits of staying in outweigh

the costs of leaving when compared to the most attractive available alternative.

The authors argue that there exists an objective joint measure of relationship quality, and as

both Solomon, Suprenant, Czepiel, and Gutman (1985) and Anderson and Weitz (1992) point out,

a dyadic study is crucial to understanding the totality of relationships as opposed to one party's

perception of the relationship. The antecedent, or reason for the formation of the relationship,

holds different implications for relationship quality. So, too, does the selection of an evaluative

paradigm. A formal typology crossing the antecedents of interfirm relationship formation with the

paradigms utilized to study these relationships is provided in Table 1; a discussion of the differing

implications for relationship quality under each antecedent condition due solely to the evaluative

paradigm selected follows.

Table! About Here

A Typology of Antecedents and Paradigms

Necessity

Necessity is the only identifiable non-voluntary antecedent to interfirm relationship

formation (Oliver 1990), which serves to render relationship quality issues moot; if the relationship

is involuntary, it will persist no matter the relationship quality. Note that the definition of this

antecedent as occurring to meet the requirements of "higher" authority implicitly assumes

7445.

relationship formation outside the focal social unit; that is, with the firm's environment The

political economy paradigm is the only paradigm that explicitly considers the impact of the

environment.

Asymmetry

Asymmetry most likely would impact relationship quality when the stronger firm is

attempting to exercise power or control over the weaker firm. This antecedent may be explored

through four paradigms: TCA, agency theory, resource-dependence theory, and political economy

theory. Each model suggests that the relationship is not likely to dissolve immediately, but the

weaker firm is likely to: 1) search for and evaluate other alternate exchange partners; and 2) engage

in such balancing behavior as may be possible. The expected dynamics under each paradigm are

different since each is driven by different underlying assumptions.

Though asymmetry is not explicitly addressed in either the TCA or agency prescriptions,

the assumption permeates both paradigms. Under TCA, the weaker firm will enure in the

relationship under conditions of high transaction costs stemming from asset specificity,

uncertainty, and frequency (Williamson 1985). If the weaker firm has made a substantial

investment in transaction-specific assets, it may be largely helpless, as the cost of leaving this

relationship (even if an otherwise suitable alternate partner could be found) is very high. If

relational norms develop (Heide and John 1992), the weaker firm might petition its partners for an

increase in transaction frequency. Otherwise, it may act more opportunistically, which would

increase secondary uncertainty (Williamson 1985) for the stronger firm and lower its relationship

quality, leading both parties to the relationship to search for other possible partners.

In agency theory, as Eisenhardt's (1989) work in agency contracts assumes and Bergen et

al. (1992) note specifically, an efficient contract is one that maximizes the principal's utility. The

agent is allowed to remain in the relationship on the sufferance of the principal, who clearly has

the power within the relationship, resulting in asymmetry. If an agent is suffering from poor

relationship quality, then it is likely that the ex ante alignment of incentives has failed (Eisenhardt

1985; Bergen et al. 1992). While the asymmetry antecedent suggests that power and influence are

with the principal, actual control over the agent is not commensurate since "the costs of obtaining

information make it impossible for the principal to monitor the agent completely" (Bergen et al.

1992, p.2).

Thus, in a healthy relationship, the agent should be able to request and receive changes that

would increase its relationship quality (and, presumably, its performance). If the principal is

unwilling or unable to work with the agent, then the agent will likely increase its opportunistic

behavior, reducing the principal's relationship quality and sending the relationship toward

dissolution as both parties search for suitable alternate exchange partners.

If the asymmetry antecedent is due to one firm's dependence on the other for critical

resources, then this antecedent is best addressed by the reource-dependence paradigm. A salient

factor defining dependency is discretion over resource allocation and use. Pfeffer and Salancik

(1978) delineate four bases of this discretion: 1) possession of a resource; 2) ability to regulate

access to a resource; 3) use of a resource; and 4) the ability to make and enforce rules on other

firms regarding possession, allocation, and use of a resource. Additionally, the power-dependence

roots of the paradigm (Emerson 1962; Blau 1964) deal directly with the attempt of one party to the

relationship to influence or control the actions of another party.

As regards relationship quality, under the resource-dependence paradigm, the response by

the dependent firm to low relationship quality would be determined by the importance of the

resource, access to the resource, and available alternatives (Pfeffer and Salancik 1978). In the

short-run, the dependent firm is committed and may even have to expand the relationship to assure

a supply of the necessary critical resource. However, this weaker firm likely would place a

priority on finding alternate supplies of the resource, an alternative resource, or ways to reduce the

importance of the resource. This would reduce the asymmetry in the relationship and allow the

firm to press for changes that would improve its relationship quality.

Reciprocity

The reciprocity antecedent suggests that relationships are formed between parties

voluntarily on the expectation of mutual benefit Since, as Oliver (1990) suggests, this condition

74-7.

prompts "cooperation, collaboration, and coordination among organizations (p. 244)," there

should be few relationship quality issues and those that arise should be quickly resolved. Indeed,

relational contracting, the strongest evaluative approach under this antecedent, assumes the

development of relational norms of reciprocity and solidarity (Macneil 1987). Given a relationship

quality issue between partners, these norms would drive the firm experiencing low quality to make

reasonable requests of its partner that would alleviate the issues and increase the first firm's

relationship quality. Also, the partner firm would be inclined to work to grant those requests in the

interest of preserving a mutually beneficial ongoing relationship.

The reciprocity antecedent might also be addressed, under certain circumstances, through

the resource-dependence paradigm. Though this paradigm is more obviously appropriate under the

asymmetry or stability antecedents, some studies (Paulson 1976; Molnar 1978; Schermerhorn

1981) suggest that resource scarcity may induce cooperation, not competition particularly where

resources are scarce for all parties (or potential parties) to a relationship. Regarding relationship

quality, this paradigm would operate similarly to relational contracting in this instance. Firms

would cooperate in addressing relationship quality issues among partners because all partners are

necessary to find answers to the resource scarcity issue facing all the members of the partnership

(e.g., an entire industry facing scarce raw materials).

Efficiency

In a relationship formed on efficiency considerations, relationship quality issues would be

resolved on that same basis. Both TCA and agency theory are well-suited to evaluating

relationships established under this antecedent; the choice of paradigm depends primarily on the

type of relationship between the firms (again, with the caveat that agency theory, even more than

TCA, is a unilateral argument directed to the benefit of the principal, not a joint optimization of the

relationship as a whole). Under TCA, a firm experiencing relationship quality issues might simply

have to endure if transaction costs are high (particularly if it has made substantial investments in

transaction-specific assets). However, if this firm is able and willing to act opportunistically (more

likely in an agency relationship where there is a smaller chance of opportunism being detected and

748.

punished; Bergen et al. 1992), it may reduce the efficiency of the current relationship to the point

where either: 1) the benefits accruing to the firms decrease and alternate partners become more

attractive, or 2) the partner firm will agree to restructure the relationship to increase the first firm's

relationship quality.

Stability

The antecedent of stability may be captured in the TCA, resource-dependence, and

relational contracting models. This contingecy offers perhaps the widest divergence in implications

for relationship quality issues depending on the evaluative paradigm employed.

Stability is a secondary focus of TCA. Relationship quality issues evaluated under the

TCA paradigm would suggest a resolution in favor of continuity. The three dimensions-asset

specificity, uncertainty, and frequency-thai lead to the choice of a specialized governance structure

all imply a search for stability and predictability. However, this continuity may take different

forms. If the firm experiencing relationship quality problems values stability, has a large

investment in transaction-specific assets, and is unable or unwilling to act opportunistically, the

relationship may perist in the problem state until costs outweigh benefits or a prospective alternate

partner offers higher benefits (or affords a way to mitigate exit costs). If the partner firm values

stability, however, or knows that the other firm can and will engage in opportunistic behavior, it

may agree to adjusting the relationship to improve the first firm's relationship quality.

Under the relational contracting paradigm, the firms should move quickly out of any

relationship quality issues. Relational contracting requires a norm of solidarity between

organizations involved in relational exchange (Macneil 1980,1987). Consequently, the firm

perceiving relationship quality issues would expect to petition its partner for redress of the issues,

and the partner firm would expect to find a way to accomodate the first firm to avoid a breakdown

in a valued (and valuable) relationship.

Oliver (1990) conceptualizes stability, or predictability, as an adaptive response to

uncertainty. Thus, the resource-dependence paradigm is also appropriate under this antecedent.

Here, it is implicit that the firm facing the perceived relationship quality issue is the firm that is

dependent on its partner for necessary resources. In evaluating relationship quality issues,

resource importance, concentration, and scarcity must be explicitly considered. If these dimensions

are high, the relationship is likely to persist in an unbalanced fashion until the resource-dependent

firm is able to establish: 1) another source of supply; 2) an alternative critical resource (if such can

be found or developed); or 3) ways to reduce the criticality of the resource. Alternatively, to

maintain stability in an established relationship, the partner firm may allow the dependent firm

greater access to, use of, or control over decisions affecting the critical resource, thereby reducing

dependence and, presumably, addressing the dependent firm's relationship quality issues.

Legitimacy

Reationships formed for legitimacy reasons are likely to persist long-term despite the

presence of relationship quality issues since, under legitimacy, the firm is attempting to build a

relationship that seeks to justify its activities or outputs to its institutional environments (Oliver

1990). However, if both parties to the relationship (the firm and the environmental institutional)

experience problems with the quality of the relationship, the firm may be inclined to dissolve the

relationship (or, if it expects an unproductive, antagonistic relationship, may refuse to form

relationships with the institutional environment in the first place).

Summary of Typology Implications

Not surprisingly, the paradigms grounded in economic considerations~TCA, agency

theory, and resource-dependence theory deal extremely well with the efficiency and stability

antecedents. They also work satisfactorily with asymmetry, in which the key concepts of power

and influence are well-conceptualized, defined, and operationalized (cf. El-Ansary and Stem 1972;

Hunt and Nevin 1974; Frazier 1983; Gaski and Nevin 1985; Frazier and Rody 1991).

The behaviorally-based paradigms-political economy theory and relational contracting

theory-handle these antecedents less well, in part because they are more loosely defined

frameworks rather than tightly drawn theories that allow for formulation and empirical testing of

hypotheses (Dubin 1979; Bachrach 1989). However, the political economy paradigm is the only

one sufficiently broad to encompass the study of interfirm relationships formed via the impetus of

750.

necessity or legitimacy, and relational contracting embodies in its definition the concept of

reciprocity, an antecedent dealt with only hi one other paradigm (resource-dependence), and

obliquely, at that

It is the authors' contention that the paradigms currently in use to evaluate relational

interfirm exchange should not be considered as competing models of a single reality. Rather, they

should be viewed as complementary tools: appropriate for different antecedents to relationship

formation; evaluating different aspects of relational interfirm exchange; and, perhaps, leading to

different conclusions-a point we have illustrated is considering relationship quality under each

likely combination of antecedent and paradigm.

Directions for Future Research

The authors have developed a theoretical contingency approach to relationship quality that

is, given a particular antecedent condition driving interorganizational relationship formation, theory

suggests that some paradigms are more appropriate than others for use as evaluative tools. The

next step is to conduct an empirical examination of this contingency approach to provide

researchers and practitioners with a sounder understanding of the appropriateness and effectiveness

of these evaluative paradigms.

Researchers could then use these antecedent conditions to improve the effectiveness of the

evaluative "toolkit" by: 1) helping to refine the relational contracting and political economy

paradigms-the behaviorally-based paradigms-from loose frameworks into tight, workable

theories that would allow for the formulation and empirical testing of hypotheses; and 2)

broadening the microeconomics-based paradigms~TCA, agency theory, and resource-dependence

theory~to allow for the inclusion of the necessity, reciprocity, and legitimacy antecedent

conditions. Longer-term, an interweaving of individual-level variables such as commitment,

investment, and trust as well as the entire area of role theory into the proposed firm-level

typology might produce a general model of relationship quality.

751.

TA

BL

E 1

TY

POL

OG

ICA

L C

ON

SEQ

UE

NC

ES

FOR

HIG

H-L

OW

RE

LA

TIO

NSH

IP Q

UA

LIT

Y (R

Q)

NE

CE

SSIT

Y

TC

A

ASY

MM

ET

RY

RE

CIP

RO

CIT

Y

EFF

ICIE

NC

Y

STA

BIL

ITY

L

EG

ITM

AC

Y

STR

ON

GE

R F

IRM

WIL

L

AL

LO

W A

DJU

STM

EN

TS

TO

R

AIS

E R

Q T

O H

IGH

-HIG

H

OR

WE

AK

ER

FIR

M W

ILL

A

CT

OPP

OR

TU

NIS

TIC

AL

LY

T

O R

ED

UC

E R

Q T

O L

OW

- L

OW

PER

SIST

S IF

V

AR

IAB

LE

;T

RA

NSA

CT

ION

M

AY

PE

RSI

STC

OST

S A

RE

HIG

H;

OR

FIR

M W

ITH

INC

EN

TIV

E T

O

HIG

H R

Q M

AY

MO

VE

AS

UN

DE

R

AL

LO

WA

SYM

ME

TR

Y/

AD

JUST

ME

NT

ST

CA

T

O R

AIS

E R

Q

AG

EN

CY

N!

01 ruR

EL

AT

ION

AL

CO

NT

RA

CT

ING

SAM

E A

S T

CA

EX

CE

PT

AG

EN

T (W

EA

KE

R F

IRM

) M

OR

E L

IKE

LY

TO

AC

T

OPP

OR

TU

NIS

TIC

AL

LY

AC

CE

NT

LIK

EL

Y T

O

AC

TO

PPO

RT

UN

IST

ICA

LY

DR

IVIN

G R

Q T

O

LO

W-L

OW

IF

PR

INC

IPA

L A

CT

S U

NIL

AT

ER

AL

LY

NO

RM

SO

F

RE

CIP

RO

CIT

Y A

ND

SO

LID

AR

ITY

E

NC

OU

RA

GE

QU

ICK

A

DJU

STM

EN

TS;

RQ

M

OV

ES

TO

HIG

H-H

IGH

NO

RM

S C

AU

SE

QU

ICK

MO

VE

TO

A

DJU

STM

EN

TS

RA

ISIN

G R

Q T

O

HIG

H-H

IGH

RE

SO

UR

CE

-DE

PE

NC

EN

CE

PER

SIST

S; W

EA

KE

R

FIR

M S

EA

RC

HE

S FO

R

AL

TE

RN

AT

E

PAR

TN

ER

S

CO

OPE

RA

TIO

N

AL

LO

WS

AD

JUST

ME

NT

S T

O

RA

ISE

RQ

TO

HIG

H-

HIG

H (

RA

RE

CA

SE)

PER

SIST

S;D

EPE

ND

EN

TFI

RM

SEA

RC

HE

S FO

RA

LT

ER

NA

TIV

EPA

RT

NE

RS

PO

LIT

ICA

L E

CO

NO

MY

PER

SIST

S; N

O

INC

EN

TIV

E T

O

CH

AN

GE

PER

SIST

S; W

EA

KE

R

FIR

M S

EA

RC

HE

S FO

R

AL

TE

RN

AT

E

PAR

TN

ER

S

PER

SIST

S;

LIK

EL

Y T

O

PRO

MPT

E

FFO

RT

S T

O

Rtn

i n/

REFERENCES

Achrol, R. S., T. Reve, and L. W. Stern (1983), "The Environment of Marketing Channel Dyads: A Framework for Comparative Analysis," Journal of Marketing, 47 (October), 55-67.

Anderson, E. and B. A. Weitz (1992), "The Use of Pledges to Build and Sustain Commitment in Distribution Channels," Journal of Marketing Research, 29 (February), 18-34.

Anderson, J. C. and J. A. Narus (1984), "A Model of the Distributor's Perspective of Distributor- Manufacturer Working Relationships," Journal of Marketing, 48 (January), 62-74.

___ and ____ (1990), "A Model of Distributor Firm and Manufacturer Firm Working Partnerships," Journal of Marketing, 54 (January), 42-58.

Arndt, J. (1983), "The Political Economy Paradigm: Foundation for Theory Building in Marketing," Journal of Marketing, 47 (October), 44-54.

Bachrach, S. B. (1989), "Organizational Theories: Some Criteria for Evaluation," Academy of Management Review, 14 (4), 496-515.

Bagozzi, R. P. (1975), "Marketing as Exchange," Journal of Marketing, 39 (October), 32-39.

Bergen, M., S. Dutta, and O. C. Walker, Jr. (1992), "Agency Relationships in Marketing: A Review of the Implications and Applications of Agency and Related Theories," Journal of Marketing, 56 (July), 1-24.

Blau, P. M. (1964), Exchange and Power in Social Life. New York: John Wiley & Sons.

Bradbury, T. N. and F. D. Fincham (1990), "Attributions in Marriage: Review and Critique," Psychological Bulletin, 107 (1), 3-33.

Coase, R. H. (1937), "The Nature of the Firm," Economica, 4 (1937), 386-405.

Cole, C. L. (1985), "Relationship Quality in Long-Term Marriages: A Comparison of High Quality and Low Quality Marriages," Lifestyles: A Journal of Changing Patterns, (1985), 248- 257.

Crosby, L. A., K. R. Evans, and D. Cowles (1990), "Relationship Quality in Services Selling: An Interpersonal Influence Perspective," Journal of Marketing, 54 (July), 68-81.

Dubin, R. (1979), Theory Building, 2nd ed., New York: The Free Press.

Dwyer, F. R., R. H. Schurr, and S. Oh (1987), "Developing Buyer-Seller Relationships," Journal of Marketing, 51 (April), 11-27.

Eisenhardt, K. M. (1985), "Control: Organizational and Economic Approaches," Management Science, 31 (February), 134-149.

___ (1989), "Agency Theory: An Assessment and Review," Academy of Management Review, 14 (January), 57-74.

El-Ansary, A. I. and L. W. Stern (1972), "Power Measurement in the Distribution Channel," Journal of Marketing Research, 9 (February), 47-52.

"7S3.

Emerson, R. M. (1962), "Power Dependence Relations," American Sociological Review, 27 (February), 31-41.

Etgar, M. (1977), "Channel Environment and Channel Leadership," Journal of Marketing Research, 14 (February), 69-76.

Frazier, G. L. (1983), "On the Measurement of Interfirm Power in Channels of Distribution, "Journal of Marketing Research, 20 (February), 158-166.

____ and R. C. Rody (1991), "The Use of In fluence Strategies in Interfirm Relationships in Industrial Product Channels," Journal of Marketing, 55 (January), 52-69.

Galaskiewicz, J. (1985), "Interorganizational Relations," Annual Review of Sociology, 11 (1985), 281-304.

Gaski, J. F. and J. R. Nevin (1985), "The Differential Effects of Exercised and Unexercised Power Sources in a Marketing Chaim&l^ournal of Marketing Research, 22 (May), 130-142.

Heide, J. B. and G. John (1992), "Do Norms Matter in Marketing Relationships?" Journal of Marketing, 56 (April), 32-44.

Heider, F. (1958), The Psychology of Interpersonal Relations. New York: John Wiley & Sons.

Hunt, S. D. (1983), "General Theories and the Fundamental Explanada of Marketing," Journal of Marketing, 47 (October), 9-17.

____ and J. R. Nevin (1974), "Power in a Channel of Distribution: Sources and Consequences," Journal of Marketing Research, 11 (May), 186-193.

Jackson, B. B. (1985), Winning and Keeping Industrial Customers: the Dynamics of Customer Relationships. Lexington, MA: Lexington Books.

Kaufmann, P. J. and L. W. Stern (1988), "Relational Exchange Norms, Perceptions of Unfairness, and Retained Hostility in Commercial Litigation," Journal of Conflict Resolution, 32 (September), 534-552.

Kotler, P. (1972), "A Generic Concept of Marketing," Journal of Marketing, 36 (April), 46-54.

Levine, S. and P. E. White (1961), "Exchange as a Conceptual Framework for the Study of Interorganizational Relationships," Administrative Science Quarterly, 6,345-369.

Macneil, I. R. (1980), The New Social Contract, An Inquiry into Modern Contractural Relations. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.

____ (1981), "Economic Analysis of Contractual Relations: Its Shortfalls and the Need for a 'Rich Classificatory Apparatus'," Northwestern University Law Review, 75 1018-1063.

. (1983), "Values in Contract: Internal and External," Northwestern University LawReview, 78, 340-418.

. (1987), "Relational Contract Theory as Sociology: A Reply to Professors Lindenberg andde Vos," Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics, 143 (2), 272-290.

Molnar, J. (1978), "Comparative Organizational Properties and Interorganizational Interdependence," Sociology and Social Research, 63, 24-48.

Noordewier, T., G. John, and J. R. Nevin, (1990), "Performance Outcomes of Purchasing Arrangements in Industrial Buyer-Vendor Relationships," Journal of Marketing, 54 (October), 80- 93.

Oliver, C. (1990), "Determinants of Interorganizational Relationships: Integration and Future Directions," Academy of Management Review, 15 (April), 241-265.

Paulson, S. K. (1976), "A Theory and Comparative Analysis of Interorganizational Dyads," Rural Sociology, 41, 311-329.

Pfeffer, J. and G. Salancik (1978), The External Control of Organizations: A Resource- Dependence Perspective. New York: Harper & Row.

Rusbult, C. E. (1980a), "Satisfaction and Commitment in Friendships," Representative Research in Social Psychology, 11 (1980), 96-105.

___ (1980b), "Commitment and Satisfaction in romantic Associations: A Test of the Investment Model," Journal of Experimental Social Psychology, 16 (1980), 172-186.

___ (1983), "A Longitudinal Test of the Investment Model: The Development (and Deterioration) of Satisfaction and Commitment in Heterosexual Involvements," Journal of Personality andSocial Psychology, 45 (1), 101-117.

___ and D. Farrell (1983), "A Longitudinal Test of the Investment Model: The Impact on Job Satisfaction, Job Commitment, and Turnover of Variations in Rewards, Costs, Alternatives, and Investments," Journal of Applied Psychology, 68 (3), 429-438.

___, D. J. Johnson, and G. D. Morrow (1986), "Determinants and Consequences of Exit, Voice, Loyalty, and Neglect: Responses to Dissatisfaction in Adult Romantic Involvements," Human Relations, 39 (1), 45-63.

Schermerhorn, J. R. (1981), "Open Questions Limiting the Practice of Interorganizational Development," Group and Organization Studies, 6 (1981), 83-95.

Solomon, M. R., C. Suprenant, J. A. Czepiel, and E. G. Gutman (1985), "A Role Theory Perspective on Dyadic Interactions: The Service Encounter," Journal of Marketing, 49 (January), 99-111.

Stern, L. W. and T. Reve (1980), "Distribution Channels as Political Economies: A Framework for Comparative Analysis," Journal of Marketing, 44 (July), 52-64.

Swan, J. E., I. F. Trawick, Jr., D. R. Rink, and J. J. Roberts (1988), "Measuring Dimensions of Purchases Trust of Industrial Salespeople," Journal of Personal Selling & Sales Management, 8 (May), 1-9.

Tolbert, P. S. and L. G. Zucker (1983), "Institutional Sources of Change in the Formal Structure of Organizations: The Diffusion of Civil Service Reform, 1880-1935," Administrative Science Quarterly, 28,22-39.

Warren, R. L. (1967), "The Interorganization Field as a Focus for Investigation," Administrative Science Quarterly, 12,396-414.

755.

Whetten, D. A. (1981), "Interorganizational Relations: A Review of the Field," Journal of Higher Education, 52 (1990), 1-28.

White, H. (1985), "Agency as Control," in Principals and Agents: The Structure of Business, J. Pratt and R. J. Zeckhauser, eds. Boston: Harvard Business School Press, 187-212.

Williamson, O. E. (1975), Markets and Hierarchies, Analysis and Antitrust Implications. New York: The Free Press.

____ (1979), "Transaction Costs Economics: The Governance of Contractual Relationships," Journal of Law and Economics, 22 (1979), 223-260.

(1981), "The Economics of Organization: The Transaction-Cost Approach," AmericanJournal of Sociology, 81 (3), 548-577.

____ (1985), The Economic Institutions of Capitalism: Firms, Markets, Relational Contracting. New York: The Free Press.

Zald, M. N. (1970), Organizational Change: The Political Economy of the YMCA. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

Zucker, L. G. (1977), "The Role of Institutionalization in Cultural Persistence," American Sociological Review, 42, 726-743.

756.