international trade governance - home | princeton …pcglobal/conferences/glf/sharma_…  · web...

34

Click here to load reader

Upload: buihanh

Post on 10-Jun-2018

213 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: International Trade Governance - Home | Princeton …pcglobal/conferences/GLF/sharma_…  · Web view2010-04-23 · International Trade Governance: Re-considering the Alternatives

Draft

International Trade Governance:Re-considering the Alternatives

Pooja Sharma

April, 2010

This paper looks at international trade governance, which is taken to consist of the set of institutions and organisational structures that determine the formulation and enforcement of rules and the associated negotiations over policies. We first distinguish two forms of trade governance: regional arrangements and a global system of trade governance. The paper then proposes a framework for understanding the co-existence of these alternative forms of trade governance based on their major economic governance characteristics. We assess the nature of the two trade governance modes and compare and contrast them along their main institutional characteristics. The global mode may be characterised as largely rule-based in contrast to the regional mode, which is relationship-based with flexibility in incorporation of rules. We argue that countries may simultaneously engage in different modes of trade liberalisation due both to their trade and income, as well as, governance implications, including the interplay between alternative modes of governance.

Keywords: International Trade Organizations; Global Governance

1. Introduction

Are preferential trade agreements, particularly regional trade arrangements, harmful or beneficial for achieving global free trade? Should policymakers be urged to avoid such arrangements in principle or should they be supported for pursuing them? Two different strands of literature present somewhat competing views. Although plenty of disagreement exists within what I call the “trade-theoretic” view, according to a survey of the literature (Panagariya, 2000, pg. 328), “a consensus appears to be emerging…proliferation of free trade areas is leading to the creation of what Bhagwati … calls “spaghetti bowl” of tariffs....the best solution to this problem is to speed up MFN (most-favoured nation) liberalisation.” In general, the trade-theoretic literature concludes, preferential trade agreements may pose a threat to the existing global system of trade liberalisation (Bagwell and Staiger, 2002, pg. 9). A contrasting view, which I call the “governance” view, on the other hand, argues that all feasible modes of organization are flawed in comparison to a hypothetical ideal and societies create alternative institutions to provide the necessary governance, which entails mitigation of conflict and realisation of mutual gains (Williamson, 2005, 1996; Dixit, 2009, 2004). The governance view argues that adaptation is the central problem of organisation and one should explain the basis on which, in practice, the choice between alternatives is effected. The governance view suggests that the co-existence of alternative governance arrangements must be understood better if all potential gains from cooperation are to be harvested.

[email protected]

Page 2: International Trade Governance - Home | Princeton …pcglobal/conferences/GLF/sharma_…  · Web view2010-04-23 · International Trade Governance: Re-considering the Alternatives

This paper proposes a unified framework for understanding the co-existence of alternative modes of international trade governance by integrating the traditional trade-theoretic and economic governance views. It applies insights from the trade-theoretic and governance analyses, where the latter in turn combines economics, political science, anthropology, sociology and international law, to re-examine policymaker’s choice over alternative modes of trade liberalisation. At any given time, countries may engage, solely or simultaneously, in different modes of trade liberalisation – unilateral, bilateral, regional, sub-regional or global. According to international trade theory, under competitive settings, unilateral trade liberalisation by welfare-maximising small developing economies and reciprocal tariff reductions amongst larger countries, within a rules-based multilateral arrangement, are the most efficient alternatives for liberalizing international trade respectively. In the recent period, several developing countries liberalised international trade unilaterally during the 1980s and 1990s, largely as part of their broader economic reforms programme.1

Assessments (Irwin, 1995; Rose, 2004; Subramanian and Wei, 2007) of the performance of the global system of trade governance, as embodied in the erstwhile General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (GATT) and the current World Trade Organisation (WTO), find that the GATT/WTO system of trade liberalisation has been successful largely in implementing negotiated reciprocal tariff reductions in industrial products amongst the industrialised economies.2

More interestingly, however, preferential trade and integration arrangements are also a highly favoured mode for liberalising international trade despite inconclusive theoretical and empirical findings with respect to their impact on members’ welfare and implications for the alternative global trading system.3 Politicians and policymakers reveal a noteworthy inclination for the preferential, whether bilateral or plurilateral, mode of trade liberalisation and cooperation. Some 462 regional trade agreements were notified to the GATT/WTO from its inception in 1948 up to February 2010.4 It is estimated that up to one-third of world trade is carried under such preferential trade arrangements. The longstanding enthusiasm for regional arrangements underwent an upsurge in the early 1990s and has continued unabated since. In the period 1948-1994, the GATT received 124 notifications of regional agreements (relating to trade in goods), and since the creation of the WTO in 1995, almost 300 additional arrangements covering trade in goods or services were notified until December 2009 (WTO, 2009).5 At present, all 153 members of the WTO, barring Mongolia, are members of a regional trade arrangement. These statistics suggest that as the GATT migrated to the WTO and expanded its scope to incorporate a new general agreement on trade in services (GATS, protection (and enforcement) of trade related intellectual property rights (TRIPs) and a

1 Although liberalisation was on a unilateral basis, in several cases it was influenced by the conditionality imposed by other international organisations including the World Bank and the International Monetary Fund.2 Tomz, Goldstein and Rivers (2007) refute Rose (2004) results by employing a broader definition of GATT membership but Subramanian and Wei (2007) confirm differential impact on developed and developing country members of the GATT/WTO.3 See Panagariya (2000) for a survey.4 Of these, 345 RTAs were notified under Article XXIV of the GATT 1947 or GATT 1994; 31 under the Enabling Clause; and 86 under Article V of the GATS. At the same date, 271 agreements were in force.5 Although an overwhelming majority of the notified, signed and proposed preferential arrangements are bilateral, the WTO uses the term regional trade agreements for its preferential trade arrangements gateway (www.wto.org/english/tratop_e/region_e/region_ehtm).

2

Page 3: International Trade Governance - Home | Princeton …pcglobal/conferences/GLF/sharma_…  · Web view2010-04-23 · International Trade Governance: Re-considering the Alternatives

sharper more integrated dispute settlement understanding (DSU) as part of the Single Undertaking, which requires that all WTO members must agree on every decision to conclude the Round, the pace of regional integration picked up as well. Here, it is interesting to note that the industrialised economies, which have been the major beneficiaries of negotiated tariff reductions at the GATT/WTO, have also used the regional path of ordering trade transactions more effectively to increase trade and integration regionally.6 This is also manifest in the relative successes of the European Union (EU) and the North American Free Trade Agreement (NAFTA) pushing items of their interest on the global negotiating agenda, as discussed later.

Despite the demonstrated preference for regional trade agreements, spatially and temporally, it continues to remain a keenly contested area in the international trade literature. It appears that policymakers have a good sense of, or perceive, the benefits of regional trade liberalisation while trade economists remain unconvinced on the whole. Thus, an important gap continues to exist in our understanding of what makes regional trade integration, economically and politically, a preferred mode of trade liberalisation. Why do policymakers engage simultaneously in both regional and global trade liberalisation i.e. what explains the co-existence of alternative modes of trade liberalisation. Inevitably, the choice would be influenced by a number of economic, political and strategic considerations but the focus in this paper is on the major institutional and organizational, or the governance, dimension of the explanation.

This paper emphasizes the governance dimension of international trade relations to explain the co-existence of the alternative modes of trade governance. I distinguish two major forms of trade governance – regional and global governance modes and show that the two modes differ fundamentally in their basic competencies, costs and benefits. The paper argues that the adaptability accorded to governance is the key competency of the regional integration (RI) mode of contracting in contrast to the global integration (GI) mode, which is less adaptable and more fixed in form. The GI mode is largely rules-based in contrast to the RI mode, which can be characterized as relationship-based with flexibility in incorporation of rules. The ability to mould the agreement in accordance with membership’s priorities, to craft an enforcement mechanism in accordance with membership structure i.e. the inherent adaptability of the mode is considered the defining competency of the RI mode of trade governance. The adaptability of the RI contracting mode is inherent in its ability to exploit relations – informational and enforcement – based advantages whilst incorporating the role of rules in accordance with the specifics of the situation, including the priorities and any ex-ante bargaining asymmetries of potential partners. The GI mode, on the other hand, which is largely a rules-based universal trade governance system, suffers from significantly greater informational and enforcement disadvantages, albeit potential distortion-moderating and efficiency-enhancing advantages.

6 The EU and NAFTA are the largest and second-largest regional trade agreements respectively based on trade volumes and other indicators. Moreover, a significant proportion of intra-regional trade in these two blocs is policy-driven as compared to the more market-based rise in East Asian intra-regional trade in recent years. Intra-regional imports as a percentage of region’s total trade in 2006, based on IMF Direction of Trade Statistics, July 2006 was as follows: EU–63; NAFTA-34; ASEAN/AFTA-26; SAARC-4; Mercosur-19; Comesa-22.

3

Page 4: International Trade Governance - Home | Princeton …pcglobal/conferences/GLF/sharma_…  · Web view2010-04-23 · International Trade Governance: Re-considering the Alternatives

The paper illustrates that the strategic interplay between the alternative modes of trade governance is crucial for understanding the co-existence of the RI and GI modes for international trade governance. On one hand, regional arrangements can be useful as credible outside options for influencing governance and associated distributional outcomes at the global forum. On the other hand, highly unequal distribution of gains from the GI mode can strengthen the incentives for alternative regional modes of governance. The former aspect is evident in the cases of the NAFTA and the EU regional arrangements. For instance, it is commonly recognised that the United States effectively used the threat of bilateral and regional agreements to initiate and shape the Uruguay Round of global trade talks. Subsequently, during the Uruguay Round, the United States used its ongoing negotiations with Canada, particularly with regards to services, to set the GATT negotiating agenda (Whalley, 1996). It is also well acknowledged that one of the driving forces for European consolidation, in the second half of the twentieth century, was the object of increasing the region’s bargaining power for rule-making, agenda-shaping and policy-setting purposes vis-à-vis the United States at the GATT (Bagwell and Staiger, 2002). Strategic interplay is also present in the formation of the ASEAN, which was driven by the rise of the EU and China’s increased dominance in the region, as well as the recent attempts in Asia to build upon the ASEAN agreements regionally partly to influence global governance.

The remainder of the paper is organised as follows: In section 2, I set out the problem that trade governance attempts to resolve and the trade-theoretic and economic governance approaches to understanding this problem and interpreting the existing forms of trade governance. Section 3 distinguishes two forms of trade governance and then compares and contrasts them along their main institutional and organizational characteristics. Section 4 explores how the trade governance alternatives interact along their governance dimension. Section 5 concludes the paper.

2. Existing approaches to the problem of trade governance

In the trade-theoretic literature (Johnson, 1953-54; Mayer, 1981; Grossman & Helpman, 1995; Bagwell and Staiger, 1999, 2002), the problem of international trade agreements is characterised as a classic case of a Prisoner’s Dilemma. While cooperation is beneficial for all parties ex ante, the payoffs from unilateral defection or cheating are higher ex post in the absence of appropriate governance.7 This particular case of the dilemma is a terms-of-trade (ToT) driven dilemma, where unilateral tariffs are set too high and trade volumes are too low as a consequence. A government hesitates to liberalize unilaterally since it does not want to suffer a terms-of-trade loss that such an action would entail but if the governments were to liberalize reciprocally then the terms-of-trade would be preserved and the impediment to liberalization and associated gains from trade would be removed. One of the problems with this trade-theoretic view of the argument is that given the efficiency properties of a cooperative equilibrium, governments should be able to come to a self-enforcing tacit

7 There are two other economic explanations of international trade agreements: (i) The domestic-commitment theory (Maggi and Rodriguez-Clare, 2007, 1998; Staiger and Tabellini, 1987), which argues that trade agreements serve as credible instruments for governments to make commitments against their domestic constituents and (ii) Ethier’s (2004) reduced-form political economy explanation, which argues that unilateral trade liberalisation reduces political support for incumbent governments while sufficiently small reciprocal liberalisation may be desirable.

4

Page 5: International Trade Governance - Home | Princeton …pcglobal/conferences/GLF/sharma_…  · Web view2010-04-23 · International Trade Governance: Re-considering the Alternatives

agreement.8 This trade-theoretic literature is unable to explain the existence of an explicit contract or agreement and an organizational infrastructure to support that agreement such as the GATT/WTO. As posited by the main proponents of the ToT theory of trade agreements, “...given the efficiency-enhancing properties of the rules of the GATT/WTO, it is not obvious why governments could not come to a tacit understanding to follow the rules. Why is it necessary to have an actual institution?” (Bagwell and Staiger, 2003, pgs. 24-25). In other words, there exists a significant gap in the main trade-theoretic explanation of international trade agreements, which in practice take the form of explicit arrangements and organizational structures to support international trade agreements.9

As regards the RI mode of trade governance, although an extensive trade-theoretic literature on regional trade agreements and multilateral liberalization explores the relationship between the multilateral and regional modes of trade liberalization, it does so mostly within a narrow framework, potentially missing significant links, which may be important to understanding international trade governance. According to Whalley (1996), this literature analyzes regional trade agreements as simple preferential reductions in ad valorem tariff equivalent trade barriers and can be potentially misleading. This literature usually compares the liberalization, more specifically the tariff and associated welfare, outcomes resulting from the two alternatives and whether and how one affects the feasibility/efficiency of the other. The focus is on trade agreements as an instrument for tariff reductions as opposed to trade agreements as ways of organizing or ordering international trade transactions. The analytical focus on trade tariffs, in the international trade literature, has become limiting in understanding trade agreements as recent papers. According to Greif (1992), international trade literature distances itself from an examination of the institutions that govern trade.

This is where the literature on economic governance comes into play. It shifts the focus to the operational enforcement aspects of trade agreements. The new institutional economics (NIE) literature argues that institutions indeed arise as actors cannot independently achieve cooperative outcomes. North (1990) defines institutions as “the humanly devised constraints that structure human interaction”, which are made up of formal constraints (rules, laws, constitutions etc.), informal constraints (norms of behaviour, conventions, self-imposed codes of conduct) and their enforcement characteristics. Together, they define the incentive structures of societies and specifically economies. North’s (1990) makes a distinction between institutions and organisations. Institutions are defined as rules of the game or a framework within which interactions occur and that structure incentive in exchange. Organizations, on the other hand, are groups of individual bound by some common interest to achieve an objective through a combination of skills, strategies and coordination. Organizations can act as agents of institutional change. The sub-field of economic

8 Some of the other problems include the following: First, the ToT theory assumes that governments maximise social welfare, which is often at odds with political considerations of real-world policymakers. Although, the ToT theory extends to alternative specification of the objective function but remains rooted in the ToT externality. Second, Krugman (1997) and Ethier (2004) forcefully argue that optimal tariffs play little role in real-world trade policy considerations. However, Broda, Limao and Weinstein (2008) show that market power does explain more of the tariff variation than commonly used political economy variables in non-cooperative trade policy.9 The need for explicit agreements can be attributed to information related failures but the explanatory power of the ToT theory itself is based on the assumption of common knowledge in the repeated game framework (see Srinivasan, 2007).

5

Page 6: International Trade Governance - Home | Princeton …pcglobal/conferences/GLF/sharma_…  · Web view2010-04-23 · International Trade Governance: Re-considering the Alternatives

governance argues that alternative forms of governance co-exist (Williamson, 2005; Dixit, 2009). Williamson’s Transaction Cost Economics (TCE) analysis posits that the frequency of transactions and the nature of the assets involved determine the level and mode of governance. Greater frequency and specificity of assets would give rise to stronger forms of governance.10

Li (2003) distinguishes two main forms of governance: relation-based governance as against rule-based governance. The two forms are distinguished by the differences in their information and (transaction) cost structures. Rule-based governance relies largely on impersonal and explicit agreements while relation-based governance relies on more personal and implicit agreements although agreements may be made (partially) explicit for third-party verification. Two parties are said to have a relation if they share certain relevant private information about one another locally (i.e. mutually observable). Rule-based governance, on the other hand, largely relies on public (i.e. publicly verifiable) information.11 A stable and balanced relation-based governance system can enforce a larger set of agreements between transaction partners than rule-based governance (Li, 2003; Dixit, 2004). To induce efficiency ex ante, within a relation-based governance system, the bargaining power of all transacting parties must either be symmetrically distributed or decentralised. Alternatively, more powerful players could offer to limit their ex post bargaining power by surrendering power to either a third-party or specifying a much more complete contract.

In accordance with the literature on economic governance, the problem of trade governance may be reformulated in terms of information and enforcement of agreements. For instance, international trade governance may be characterized in terms of an absence of: a third-party enforcement authority akin to the state at the nation-state level; effective world-wide community type sanctions; second-party type enforcement through the threat of retaliation due to general lack of balance in trading relations at the bilateral level; similar social preferences or beliefs about behaviour for effective first-party type enforcement in general. In other words, the problem of governance arises as there is no supranational authority to enforce agreements between nation-states nor is there any form of effective international community type sanctions available as a substitute for a formal authority. Efficacy of second-party type enforcement through the threat of retaliation, in repeated interactions, also depends on reciprocity and balance in trading relation at the bilateral level as a pre-requisite for retaliation.3. A Framework for Understanding Co-existence of Trade Governance Institutions

We consider two alternative modes of trade governance: A universal global integration mode and an alternative regional integration mode.12 The GI mode is stylized after the current

10 This framework has been applied by Keohane (1984) to describe how international institutions may help to mitigate transaction costs and by Yarbrough and Yarbrough (1992) to explain the historical variety in institutions of trade governance.11 A rule-based governance system involves large total fixed transaction costs but low or negligible marginal cost of enforcing an (additional) contract between an (additional) transaction pair. The opposite holds for relation-based systems of governance, which may involve few fixed costs of formulating and implementing contracts and creating informational infrastructures but higher marginal costs of screening, testing and monitoring each and every transacting partner.12 It is acknowledged at the outset that an overwhelming majority of existing preferential arrangements notified to the GATT/WTO are on a bilateral than regional basis so that we are restricting attention to a

6

Page 7: International Trade Governance - Home | Princeton …pcglobal/conferences/GLF/sharma_…  · Web view2010-04-23 · International Trade Governance: Re-considering the Alternatives

system of international trade governance in the form of the WTO but mainly its predecessor the GATT. We stick to the terminology of global instead of multilateral as in its current form the GATT/WTO system is only partially multilateral even though it is commonly referred to as such. This is because the GATT/WTO adopts a largely bilateral or small group approach to negotiations and enforcement. Although the most-favoured-nation principle, which requires that the results of any reciprocal bargaining outcome between two or more members be multilaterised to all members, should render the GATT/WTO multilateral in terms of its negotiating function, the enforcement mechanism of the WTO, the other pillar of the WTO governance system, works largely on a bilateral basis. Moreover, there is considerable debate in both the theoretical and empirical literature on the practical effectiveness of the MFN rule in benefiting non-participating members13 as well as its weakening overtime.14

The RI mode is defined as an arrangement among two or more contiguous states, where the number of countries involved is taken to be small. Real world regional trade agreements tend to consist of geographically proximate countries and key trading partners from the region. However, countries participating in regional arrangements tend to have much more in common than simple geography. Many regional trade agreements are attempts to formalise pre-existing informal flows of goods and factors across national boundaries. In many cases, members of regional arrangements tend to share higher-order economic, political, legal and social institutions. Geographically proximate countries also inevitably tend to have commonalities in history, language, norms and beliefs about behaviour. It is recognized that real-world regional trade arrangements vary widely in terms of their membership, bargaining structures, objectives, outcomes and, more critically, their institutional and governance characteristics. The existing East Asian, European, North American and South American and African regional arrangements are very different in their structures and scope. But as will become apparent, this difference is fundamental to our understanding of the main competency of the RI mode of trade governance.

In what follows, it is argued that in comparison to the GI mode of trade governance, the RI mode has its governance related costs and benefits, which need to be understood better. The remainder of this section provides a comparative assessment of these costs and benefits based on these institutional characteristics, which are summarized in Table 1.

Table 1: Institutional Dimensions of Alternative Trade Governance ModesStructural Dimension GI Mode RI ModeBargaining Structure No formal recognition of

asymmetriesExplicit recognition of asymmetries

very small subset of preferential arrangements.13 See Horn and Mavroidis (2001) and Caplin and Krishna (1988) for surveys and Bagwell and Staiger (2009), Ludema and Mayda (2009) and Subramanian and Wei (2007) for recent developments in the theoretical and empirical literature respectively. The MFN principle is discussed further in the sections on bargaining and enforcement.14 Through the various exceptions made, such as the introduction of article 24 in 1958 permitting preferential trade arrangements followed by the US-Canada auto pact in 1965, the Generalised System of Preferences in 1971 and introduction of plurilateral agreements in the Tokyo Round (1973-79); through the use of discriminatory trade instruments like voluntary export restraints (VERs), anti-dumping and countervailing duties and US Section 301 (Cebi and Ludema, 2001).

7

Page 8: International Trade Governance - Home | Princeton …pcglobal/conferences/GLF/sharma_…  · Web view2010-04-23 · International Trade Governance: Re-considering the Alternatives

Transactions Historical focus on ad valorem tariffs;

Simple transaction technology or exchange – no linkage

Tariff plus other trade & domestic policies;

More complex transaction technology

Contract Relatively complete VariableOrganization Limited authority, no residual

rightsVariable

Information Standard institutional exchange Allows non-standard exchange such as selection and signaling

Enforcement Threat of retaliation, limited organizational (DSU) authority

Typically combination – value-based, linkage, organizational authority, third-parties

Bargaining StructureThe bargaining structure of international trade agreements plays out at two stages of the agreement. The first is at the stage of negotiation of the agreement and the second is at the level of enforcement. At the negotiation stage of the GI mode, there are a number of problems with regard to the bargaining structure. As mentioned earlier, according to the leading theory of trade agreements, the objective of global trade liberalisation is identified as solving the ToT driven prisoner’s dilemma. This means that, by definition, the GI mode is appropriate, as a negotiating forum, for relatively larger economies, which can influence world prices. The relevant WTO rule requires that there must be a “balance in exchange of concessions.” But in this sense the smaller countries cannot offer much to the larger countries because small countries by definition cannot influence world prices and therefore impose no negative externality on larger countries which could be resolved through a mutual arrangement based on reciprocity between these two groups of countries. Thus, reciprocity breaks down between larger and smaller countries.15 International trade related reciprocity can only be exchanged amongst countries that are more or less symmetric in terms-of-trade type bargaining power. This group of countries naturally become the major negotiators, not only of policies but also the rules within which policy concessions may be exchanged. However, the WTO’s current 153 membership consists of countries of varying sizes in terms-of-trade type market power. According to Mattoo and Subramanian (2008), part of the WTO’s current governance challenge in fact stems from the situation of its small country membership. They argue that on one hand, due to the Single Undertaking nature of ongoing negotiations, these countries have acquired a significant say and legal influence in the decision-making on the other hand, their interests are only imperfectly aligned with those of the system. This view argues that it is neither necessary nor desirable that all parties negotiate equally on all issues and that all are equally bound by the resulting rules.

15 Smaller countries may join global trade agreements for other reasons such as to provide a credible commitment mechanism for their governments with respect to their domestic interests (Staiger and Tabellini, 1987; Maggi and Rodriguez-Clare, 1999, 2007).

8

Page 9: International Trade Governance - Home | Princeton …pcglobal/conferences/GLF/sharma_…  · Web view2010-04-23 · International Trade Governance: Re-considering the Alternatives

This problem associated with the bargaining asymmetries amongst members is manifested in various aspects of governance at the GATT/WTO. Firstly, in the gap between the formal or de jure and informal or de facto modes of decision-making practiced at the GATT/WTO. Legally or formally, the WTO treats every member equally i.e. every member has equal weight and is equally bound by the negotiated outcome. Informally, however, the GATT/WTO negotiations in the past were largely amongst the so-called quad members consisting of the United States, the European Union, Japan and Canada.16 Another place where the governance problem of the GI mode is reflected is in the largely bilateral nature of GATT/WTO negotiation and enforcement. The GATT negotiations occurred largely on a bilateral or small-group basis. Until the fourth round (Geneva Round, 1956) negotiations were conducted on a product-by-product, principal supplier method, where a country could only be requested to give tariff concessions on a particular product by the principal supplier of that product to that country. Although the rules were subsequently altered to allow countries to act collectively in requesting concessions, additional factors prevented developing countries from making requests including exclusion of products and policies of their interest from the negotiating agenda and costs of co-ordination.

Moreover, although any concessions agreed upon among the negotiating parties are in principle subsequently extended to all members on an MFN basis, there is little theoretical or empirical support for the view that non-participating members have benefited much, in terms of increased export volumes, from such an arrangement. In theory, according to Bagwell and Staiger (2009), the twin pillars of MFN and reciprocity can be understood as minimizing third-country spillovers from bilateral tariff bargaining. They argue that the MFN rule permits the liberalising force of reciprocity to be harnessed in an essentially bilateral manner even in an explicitly multilateral arrangement. Empirically, Subramanian and Wei (2007) show that countries that engaged (industrialised countries) in reciprocal trade negotiations witnessed increases in trade and that the WTO, particularly its predecessor the GATT, has been a two-tier organization with far greater liberalization obligations undertaken by its developed than its developing country members.

The enforcement stage of the GATT/WTO system is also largely bilateral in its actual functioning. The corresponding WTO rule requires “withdrawal of substantially equivalent concessions”. Smaller countries are at a disadvantage in terms of their ability to retaliate. If the small country imposes retaliatory tariffs, it only increases its local price and is unable to inflict any effective punishment on the bigger trading party due to the small size of its market. Partly as a reflection of this inability there have been repeated calls for permitting multilateralism in retaliation (Maggi, 1999), tradability of retaliation rights (formally proposed by Mexico during the Doha Round (WTO, 2002)) or monetary compensation (Bronckers and Van Den Broek, 2005) or disproportionate retaliation. Developing countries first proposed the possibility of collective retaliation in 1965 to address violation of obligations by a large country against a smaller country (Hudec, 2000). The most recent proposal for instilling multilateralism in retaliation was made by Mexico in the ongoing Doha Round, proposing tradability of retaliation rights. Maggi (1999) underscores the

16 The Doha Round witnessed the emergence of a “new quad” comprising United States, European Union, Brazil and India and the G-6 consisting additionally of Australia and Japan.

9

Page 10: International Trade Governance - Home | Princeton …pcglobal/conferences/GLF/sharma_…  · Web view2010-04-23 · International Trade Governance: Re-considering the Alternatives

importance of multilateral enforcement mechanisms in the face of strong imbalances in bilateral trading relationship.

The RI mode tends to differ significantly from the GI mode in addressing bargaining asymmetries. Although economic power asymmetries exist in most regional arrangements, their impact on the reciprocity of exchange of concessions and ultimate distribution of gains is moderated through explicit recognition and addressal of such imbalances through a variety of governance arrangements. The regional agreements tend to explicitly recognise imbalances in bargaining power of partners and allow for solving the problem in one or more ways so that there usually isn’t any gap in the formal rules and the actual situation. In such cases, areas and policies for negotiations may be chosen to allow for reciprocity within the arrangement or by offering strategic advantages to the larger members for improving their outcomes at alternative negotiating forums. Asymmetry is often solved, at the negotiation stage, by creating linkage in other trade or domestic issue areas, especially in cases where reciprocity on mainly trade issues is not possible. This was particularly true in case of the proposals for a free trade arrangement with the United States first by Canada and later its extension to Mexico. As a much bigger economy, the United States was initially reluctant to expend and divert resources away from the GATT. Canada offered to incorporate services and investments into the agreement as an instrument to make the deal more attractive its US counterparts to enter into the agreement. “Canada consciously offered the U.S. the possibility of negotiating a regional arrangement in services, which was then an emerging issue in global negotiations, with the understanding that a prior regional agreement would give the U.S. more leverage in subsequently multilateralizing their preferred services agreement” as a result, “a number of seemingly largely content-less chapters appeared in the final agreement…for multilateral agenda shaping purposes” (Whalley, 1996, pg. 20). Similarly, Mexico was accorded tariff preferences in exchange for implementing various labour and environmental standards of value to the United States.

The RI mode is found to be especially efficient in innovating at the enforcement level. Asymmetry is addressed, either by larger countries agreeing to concede authority to a supranational organisation as in case of the EU or by allowing for stronger dispute settlement procedures as in case of the NAFTA. Also, in regional agreements which consist of more than two parties, under certain conditions, each party tends to act as a third-party enforcer given the easier flow of information and relation-based nature of these agreements (see section on information and enforcement below).

Transaction StructureIn the transaction structure, I consider both the transaction types as well as the transaction technology. Transaction type refers to the scope of the agreement in terms of areas of coverage and policies under consideration. Transaction technology is used to refer to the ability to exchange concessions across different issue-areas, including across trade and domestic policy areas, as well as the possibility of retaliation across issue-areas and policies, commonly known as linkage.

Historically, the GATT has focused on ad valorem tariffs in the industrial sector. Even within industry, whole sectors, such as textiles and clothing, were effectively excluded from

10

Page 11: International Trade Governance - Home | Princeton …pcglobal/conferences/GLF/sharma_…  · Web view2010-04-23 · International Trade Governance: Re-considering the Alternatives

the GATT and administrative regulations such as Voluntary export restraints (VERs), antidumping and countervailing duties were devised overtime to circumvent liberalisation in other areas. It was only during the eighth round, the Uruguay Round (1986-95), of trade talks that a range of new issue areas including trade in agriculture, trade and investment in services, protection for intellectual property, product standards and food safety were incorporated into the global trade negotiating agenda as part of the Single Undertaking at the WTO. Certain types of domestic subsidies for agriculture were also included. In general, however, WTO rules do not allow cross-issue linkage across trade and domestic policies. Recent attempts to include negotiations on areas like environment, labour and competition policies at the WTO have been highly contentious and so far resisted.

In contrast to the GATT, regional arrangements have tended to include a greater variety of trade related issue-areas and policy instruments as well as non-trade issues on the negotiating agenda. In general, RIAs are wider and deeper in terms of coverage of trade in goods and services, movement of people and capital, intellectual property rights, environment and labour standards and regulatory harmonization. For instance, the EU requires its members to submit decision-making authority, to the regional organisation, on a range of issues, including agricultural policy, environment and labour standards, intellectual property and human rights. Similarly, the NAFTA covers services and investments as well as clauses on enforcement of IPRs along with side agreements on labour and environment. The ASEAN has been most successful in achieving regional peace and stability, which has contributed to greater intra-regional trade. Regional arrangements have been used successfully to foster regional cooperation in areas ranging from infrastructure, energy and environment. In fact, recent research suggests that unlike the more ambiguous conclusions for goods trade, countries are likely to gain from preferential liberalisation of services trade, compared to the status quo, and regulatory cooperation may not only be more feasible but more desirable among a subset of countries than globally and for creation of regional public goods (Mattoo and Fink, 2002).

The GATT was historically based on a simple transaction technology i.e. trade tariff reductions in one sector in exchange for reciprocal tariff reductions in another sector. In contrast to the GATT, the WTO’s Single Undertaking effectively created a linked agreement by tying-in negotiations on different issue-areas. But the jury is still out on the efficacy of enlarging the scope of the global trade agreement as part of the Single Undertaking, which stipulates that all WTO members must agree on every decision to conclude the Round.17 The RI mode has been based on a more complex transaction technology. Concessions in a particular area may be exchanged for policy concessions in a different issue area, which might largely be a domestic policy concern. Sometimes, signing an agreement in one area, say trade, might be made conditional on signing of an agreement in another area, which again may be related to domestic policy, such as environment or labour standards or human rights issues. In fact, tariff preferences may be used as an instrument to promote cooperation in other areas as was the case in the NAFTA. Possibility of cross-issue negotiations may create cooperation, by allowing mutual gains, in situations where such cooperation may not be possible on a single-issue. In other words, when reciprocity in a single issue-area is not

17 See Mattoo and Subramanian (2008) and Martin and Messerlin (2007) for a critique of this constraint.

11

Page 12: International Trade Governance - Home | Princeton …pcglobal/conferences/GLF/sharma_…  · Web view2010-04-23 · International Trade Governance: Re-considering the Alternatives

possible between two countries then linkage may create the necessary conditions for potentially mutually beneficial exchange.

The RI mode of trade governance also explicitly allows for cross-retaliation where non-cooperation in any one policy can trigger punishment in any or all policies. Until recently, cross-retaliation was not permitted at the GATT/WTO.18 The new integrated Dispute Settlement Undertaking (DSU) of the WTO allows cross-retaliation within limits. The TRIPS agreement explicitly permits compliance with intellectual property rights to be enforced through the threat of import barriers. However, cross-issue retaliation, in general is looked upon unfavourably at the WTO. Article 3.10 of the WTO’s Understanding on Rules and Procedures Governing the Settlement of Disputes, or the DSU, states “It is also understood that complaints and counter-complaints in regard to distinct matter should not be linked”. Further, Article 22.3(a) of the DSU specifies the general principle that “...complaining party should first seek to suspend concessions or other obligations with respect to the same sector(s)” but Articles 22.3 (b) and (c) add “if that party considers it is not practical or effective” then suspension of concessions or retaliation can be sought in another sector but under the same agreement where the violation has occurred but should that also be impracticable or ineffective, retaliation can be sought under another agreement.

Studies on linkage make the following distinctions in evaluating the effectiveness of linkage in creating more balanced and enforceable agreements.19 First, whether issues are linked or tied-in, where the former refers to the possibility of forming agreements over multiple issues and the latter to the requirement that agreements cover multiple issues. While issue-linkage can be characterised as an equilibrium phenomenon, issue tie-in is in the form of an exogenous constraint on the set of possible agreements. The second distinction is made between, cross-issue negotiations – where concessions in a particular area may be exchanged for policy concessions in a different issue area, which might largely be a domestic policy concern - as against cross-issue retaliation – when non-cooperation in either issue can be met with punishment in either or all policies. Third, whether the policy issues to be linked are separable, substitutes or complements. For instance, according to Spagnolo (1999), when policy issues are separable, linkage can facilitate cooperation by reallocating enforcement power i.e. when expected gains from cooperation are small with respect to one issue and large with respect to another, linkage facilitates policy cooperation by allowing slack in enforcement present in the first issue to be disciplined by the stronger enforcement of the second issue. When policy issues are substitutes, issue linkage may further facilitate cooperation by increasing the amount of enforcement power as when countries do not cooperate on one issue they value relatively more cooperation on substitute issues and therefore a simultaneous threat of interruption of cooperation on both policy issues is relatively stronger. The opposite holds when issue are complements.20 Limao (2002) argues

18 The phrase cross-retaliation itself does not appear in the WTO’s DSU but it is commonly understood as describing a situation where the complaining country retaliates (i.e. suspends concession or other obligations) under a sector or an agreement which has not been violated by the defending country (WTO website).19 See Charnovitz (1984), Sebenius (1983), Spagnolo (1999), Limao (2002) and Conconi and Perroni (2002).20 Another linkage considered in the literature (Rama and Tabellini, 1998; Ederington, 2003) is between trade and domestic policy instruments as opposed to two policy issues. These studies find that trade

12

Page 13: International Trade Governance - Home | Princeton …pcglobal/conferences/GLF/sharma_…  · Web view2010-04-23 · International Trade Governance: Re-considering the Alternatives

that linkage leads to reallocation of enforcement in the linked policies and promotes cooperation in one policy at the expense of the other if the two policies are independent and there is asymmetry in the enforceability of each issue. For instance, if under no-linkage tariffs are closer to their cooperative optimum than e-taxes (environmental standards), then linkage leads to higher e-taxes at the expense of higher tariffs and vice-versa. However, if policies are strategic complements then linkage promotes cooperation in both issues. Limao (2002) concludes that if the goal of the WTO remains multilateral trade liberalisation then the current practice of the WTO with respect to limiting cross-retaliation across independent issues should be preserved but there is greater scope for the creation of enforcement through linkage within a regional context.

Nature of Contract and Organizational AuthorityThe penultimate dimension along which the trade governance alternatives are compared consists of the nature of the contract and organizational authority, if any. The first difference between the global and regional modes along this dimension is that while the GI mode in its current form is largely rule-based, the regional mode is relationship-based but flexible in its deployment of rules. The GI mode is based on an explicit set of agreements containing detailed specification of rules and procedures for interaction amongst contracting parties for negotiation of policies and settlement of disputes. The GI mode relies on publicly available and verifiable information and involves considerable costs in drafting, interpreting and implementing negotiated agreements. As a result, rule-based governance can only enforce a limited set of agreements, those which are mutually observable as well as verifiable by third-parties. The cost of adding more parties, however, to the negotiated agreements are relatively small.

In contrast to the global mode, the regional mode is a relationship-based system of governance as it is based on more local systems of information and small and close-knit group nature of contracting parties. Information is mutually held by concerned parties about each other based on geographical proximity and possible similarities in language, ethnicity and historical ties etc. It is easier to screen and monitor each and every partner given the small-size and closeness of the group. “Community” sanctions act as an additional third-party type enforcement mechanism in relationship-based systems as communication of violation, which is a function of group size, is much easier in these systems and interactions are also repeated. Third-parties here may not only comprise community sanctions but also a supranational organisation. Unlike the GI mode, it is more costly to extend membership as new members will increasingly be less well connected and the relationship will encounter increasing costs of communication and participation in punishment. As a result of all these properties, relationship-based governance can enforce a greater variety of agreements amongst a limited number of members.

The GATT itself did not have a de jure organisational form as the International Trade Organisation (ITO), contemplated in 1948, to provide the organisational structure to the GATT never came into existence despite detailed discussions. The GATT was therefore largely a forum for trade policy negotiations and for settlement of trade disputes, which

cooperation is best enforced through the trade policy instrument and that non-linkage in trade and domestic policies is optimal.

13

Page 14: International Trade Governance - Home | Princeton …pcglobal/conferences/GLF/sharma_…  · Web view2010-04-23 · International Trade Governance: Re-considering the Alternatives

operated through a well-defined system of rules. The GI mode was accorded formal organisational form only recently with the establishment of the WTO in 1995. The WTO may be characterised as a supranational organisation but with bounded authority.21 The GATT tended to underscore the self-enforcement properties of trade agreements and for this reason provided for safeguards and escape clauses as in-built flexibilities in the agreement to promote cooperation in a self-enforcing manner. These flexibilities allowed for volatility in trade volumes in the form of import surges etc. and for temporary suspension of obligations to prevent a complete breakdown of the agreement in such circumstances. The same logic can be used to explain gradualism of the GATT approach. As initial liberalisation promotes growth of export firms, these firms become better at what they do so that further liberalisation can be undertaken leading to virtuous cycles of liberalisation. For all these reasons the organizational authority of the GATT/WTO is limited.

In contrast, the regional modes of contracting display greater variety in the scope of the agreement, its form and specification. For instance, the NAFTA is a relatively complete intergovernmental contract with detailed description of rules and procedures for dispute settlement. On the other hand, the EU with its big bureaucracy, the Commission, the Parliament, the Court of Justice and even a new cultural programme is an incomplete supranational contractual arrangement, where residual authority is vested in these third-party institutions and where the organizational authority is high (Cooley and Spryut, 2009).

Information and Enforcement StructureIn comparison to the GI mode, the RI mode allows for a greater variety in information exchange and enforcement. One of the unique features of the RI mode is that even in the pre-negotiation stage, it allows for better exchange of information. Later, given the relation-based nature of the RI mode, information on violations of agreement is more readily available and transmittable. The RI mode is that it facilitates screening and selection of partners as well as signalling. In general, primary trading partners are implicitly or explicitly selected for regional cooperation arrangements. Most countries involved in regional arrangements are geographical neighbours that not only engage in a sizeable amount of trade but also share commonalities in history as well as higher order institutions like political, economic, legal and social institutional arrangements.

The RI mode also allows for signalling. For instance, governments may have different preferences on specific issues, say with respect to labour and environmental standards, and these preferences may not be immediately obvious to others. In other words, there is considerable information asymmetry and parties possess private information on the basis of which they can send signals to another party who then takes an action. By proposing or agreeing to enter a regional arrangement where the negotiating agenda includes higher standards, a government can signal to potential partners that it in fact has similar preferences and thus such provisions will be enforceable. For signalling explanation to make sense two conditions are required. One, there has to be considerable information asymmetry and second there has to be significant cost to entering an agreement as against exiting one. In game-theoretic terminology cheap talk is ruled out. This occurs when members are required

21 See Cooley and Spryut (2009) and Bagwell and Staiger (2002).

14

Page 15: International Trade Governance - Home | Princeton …pcglobal/conferences/GLF/sharma_…  · Web view2010-04-23 · International Trade Governance: Re-considering the Alternatives

to make significant institutional and regulatory changes prior to the entry into force of an agreement.

The main enforcement mechanism in the global system of trade governance is the threat of retaliation, which is codified in the dispute settlement procedures of the GATT/WTO. Incentives to deviate from the agreement are balanced against the anticipated cost of retaliatory response in a repeated game-theoretic interpretation of the dispute settlement procedures. The government’s incentive constraint requires that the gains from cheating in the short run be no greater than the discounted future value of gains foregone from non-cooperation. From this game-theoretic perspective, off-equilibrium path behaviour is unlikely to be observed as the credibility of the off-equilibrium-path threat enforces the equilibrium path rules. This perspective gives rise to questions regarding the need for explicit dispute settlement procedures in the GATT to begin with and their further strengthening in the WTO under the new integrated DSU. Also, the theory suggests that disputes would arise rarely in practice, which contrasts with observed practice. The gap in theory and practice and the need for GATT/WTO is attributed to the violations of usual assumptions, such as availability of perfect and costless information. However, Ludema (1991) argues that by improving communications and providing a forum for re-negotiation, the DSU in fact diminishes the deterrent effect of threatened punishments. As mentioned earlier, the need for an explicit agreement remains unresolved from this particular trade-theoretic view of trade agreement.

The RI mode has several enforcement advantages associated with the nature of the mode. The RI mode allows for a variety of enforcement mechanisms to operate simultaneously or sequentially to result in better enforcement of agreements. This range from better ex-ante alignment of preferences of potential members, the traditional threat of retaliation in repeated interaction, better organizational authority, if one exists, as well as community sanctions etc.

Regional arrangements by their nature allow for selection of potential partners. If members with similar preferences, social, political and economic institutions are selected then more cooperation can be sustained as these preferences and norms of behaviour may be taken to be exogenous in the near future. Social norms are well recognised to act as informal constraints on behaviour that are more deeply embedded than formal rules. If countries share these higher order institutions then actual governance at the lower level improves intrinsically. Evolutionary biology suggests that group selection can support high frequencies of cooperative behaviour but only if the groups are small. It has also been argued that cooperation can be viewed as a trade-off between material incentives and value-systems of members (Tabellini, 2008). So to the extent members share similar value-systems, ex post enforcement is enhanced. The selection of potential or natural trading partners based on similarity of preferences, shared commonalities in history, geography and other deep institutions provides for much better enforcement through better alignment of preferences and thereby incentives to cooperate than is feasible in the global mode consisting of a highly distant and diverse membership. The threat of retaliation tends to operate better in its RI avatar as policies are negotiated simultaneously and rules permit cross-retaliation i.e. non-cooperation in any policy can

15

Page 16: International Trade Governance - Home | Princeton …pcglobal/conferences/GLF/sharma_…  · Web view2010-04-23 · International Trade Governance: Re-considering the Alternatives

trigger punishment in any or all policies. Community sanctions work better in a regional context as even if one member is unable to retaliate in a particular case, another member could act as a third-party type enforcer. Thus each member can serve as a third-party enforcer but this power gets diluted as the number of parties involved increases as the third-party enforcer bears costs to confer benefits on other group members.

4. The interaction between trade governance modes

In this section, we explore how the two trade governance alternatives under consideration may interact in terms of their impact on governance. It is argued that there is a significant degree of interplay between the regional and global modes of trade governance. This strategic interaction occurs as much through agenda-setting and rule-making aspects of governance as through actual policy negotiations. However, the existing literature largely ignores this interactive dimension of regional organisations and global trade governance. In international trade negotiations, countries not only try to increase the overall gains through cooperation but also attempt to enhance their share of the gains arising from increased policy cooperation. The extent of the gains that a country is able to corner is shaped by a country’s bargaining power. But bargaining power in turn is shaped by the rules or by the agenda of negotiations. Regional organisations can act as agents of institutional change and influence the resulting redistribution in gains from cooperation.

We find several instances of interplay between regional organisations and the global trading rules. The interaction between preferential arrangements and global trading rules begins at the establishment of the GATT itself in 1948. Negotiations over the International Trade Organisation (ITO) and the GATT between the United States and Britain and other countries were marked by conflict over the British and French preference systems, under which (ex) colonies were granted preferential access to their markets and in turn granted preferences to British and French exports respectively. Later, the establishment of the European Economic Community (EEC) in 1958 and then the European Free Trade Association in 1960 raised concerns about their conformity with GATT Article 24, which required preferential agreements cover “substantially all trade”. However, inconclusive reporting by the GATT working party led to the undermining of Article 24 and erosion of MFN principle. The creation of the EEC led to an improvement in the bargaining leverage of Western European economies, vis-à-vis the United States.22 The EC took over the GATT membership of its six states. Individually, each European country had limited leverage against the United States but by coordinating through the regional organisation, they could improve their bargaining position. In fact, the EEC, renamed the European Community (EC) in 1967, emerged as a major player in GATT negotiations, contributing significantly to the making of rules at the global level.The interplay between regional organizations and global governance picked up with the Canada’s offer of a bilateral deal with the US. The United States used NAFTA, and its adoption of the multi-track approach to trade negotiations during the 1980s, to influence global trade negotiations by pushing for services on the global trade agenda and thereby shaping the direction of global negotiations to serve its own economic interests. According to Whalley (1996), Canada consciously offered the U.S. the possibility of negotiating

22 See Bagwell and Staiger (2002).

16

Page 17: International Trade Governance - Home | Princeton …pcglobal/conferences/GLF/sharma_…  · Web view2010-04-23 · International Trade Governance: Re-considering the Alternatives

regional arrangements in services in their bilateral agreement, which was then an emerging issue in multilateral negotiation, with the idea that a prior regional agreement would give the U.S. more leverage in subsequently multilateralizing their preferred services agreement. A number of seemingly largely content-less chapters appeared in the final agreement for multilateral agenda shaping purposes. Thus an advantage of regional trade agreements is that they can act as an important instrument in improving negotiating leverage against third-parties or for tactical play across organizational levels. The objective of increasing negotiating power at alternative forums or vis-à-vis third-parties has also been present in Latin American arrangements such as the MERCOSUR and is certainly a driving force in the Asian integration efforts in the forms of ASEAN and the East Asia Summit. Even smaller regional arrangements display adherence to rules within regional arrangements that members consider important in the corresponding global forum. For instance, the members of the South Asian Association for Regional Cooperation (SAARC), which have been a beneficiary of the Special and Differential Treatment (SDT) clause at the WTO, retain and accord a special place to SDT within their regional arrangement.

5. Concluding Remarks

The paper applies insights from international trade theory and the literature on economic governance to better understand the co-existence of alternative modes of international trade governance. In particular, we focus on two modes of trade governance and the strategic interaction between these two modes. We develop a framework to lay bare the fundamental differences in the nature of the global and regional modes of trade governance. The paper shows how trade agreements vary not only in terms of their trade and income implications but also along their governance dimension. Each mode has its basic competencies, which can be exploited more efficiently to better serve members’ interests and ultimate aim of free trade.

The GI mode may be characterised as largely rule-based and the RI mode as relationship-based with flexibility in incorporation of rules. It is argued that given the rule-based nature of the GI mode, it is more suitable for enforcing a limited set of agreements amongst a symmetric group of decision-making members. The trade-theoretic argument for the GI mode is based on an underlying assumption of symmetry, with respect to the ability to influence terms-of-trade. Thus, together the trade-theoretic and economic governance arguments delineate particular roles for the GI and RI modes in facilitating trade cooperation and increasing efficiency outcomes of trade agreements. The paper points to the nature of the challenges facing global trade governance by the multiplication of countries, of varying sizes and at different stages of development, as well as the multiplication of negotiating issues. These tensions in the global trade system are manifested in the significant gap in the multilateral liberalisation ideal analysed in economic theories of trade agreements and the real-world, bilateral or small group based nature of negotiations and enforcement, as practiced under the auspices of the GATT/WTO.

In contrast to the GI mode, the RI mode of trade governance has been found to facilitate greater innovation in terms of rules and other governance mechanisms and negotiations generally involve a wider set of disparate issues, of importance to negotiating partners, which

17

Page 18: International Trade Governance - Home | Princeton …pcglobal/conferences/GLF/sharma_…  · Web view2010-04-23 · International Trade Governance: Re-considering the Alternatives

allows for more effective negotiation and enforcement of resulting agreements. The regional governance mode, if designed appropriately in accordance with membership characteristics and priorities, may facilitate exploitation of the key advantages of relation-based governance systems. The RI mode is an inherently adaptable mode which must be explicitly and carefully aligned with membership structure and priorities so that it can be effectively deployed to increase regional trade and cooperation. Given its key competency in terms of innovation with regard to rules, scope and structure of the agreement, it must be tailored to the needs of the specific regional arrangement in question and its architecture will vary from regional agreement to regional agreement if benefits are to be derived. Finally, the RI mode could be tactically useful with respect to its interaction with the GI mode so as to make the latter more representative of overall membership and to bring about greater balance in the distribution of gains from global trade agreements.

To return to the questions posed at the start of this paper: Whether regional trade arrangements are a threat to the global trading system and whether policymakers and politicians should be advised to resist or embrace regional trade agreements? The foregoing discussion suggests that regional organisations can help their members cooperate in ways and areas not feasible at the global level. The RI mode can act as an agent of institutional change at the global level, improving the organisation’s distributional outcomes at alternative forums. Further research needs to be undertaken to better understand why only some regional arrangements have been successful so far in capturing these kinds of benefits and why other attempts have been less successful. The global mode of trade governance has its own in-built competency and should be mined for associated efficiency gains with the ultimate objective of reaching the trade economists’ ideal of global free trade.

References:

Bagwell, Kyle, and Robert Staiger. 1999. An economic theory of GATT. American Economic Review 89 (1):215-48.

———. 2002. The Economics of the World Trading System. Cambridge: The MIT Press.———. 2003. Economic theory and the interpretation of GATT/WTO. Columbia

University.———. 2009. The WTO: Theory and Practice. Stanford University.Broda, Christian, Nuno Limao, and David Weinstein. 2008. Optimal tariffs and market

power: the evidence. American Economic Review 98 (5):2032-65.Bronckers, Marco, and Naboth Van der Broek. 2005. Financial compensation in the

WTO: Improving the remedies of WTO dispute settlement. Journal of International Economic Law 8 (1):106-26.

Caplin, Andrew, and Kala Krishna. 1988. Tariffs and the most-favored nation clause: A game theoretic approach. Seoul Journal of Economics 1:267-89.

Cebi, Pinar, and Rodney Ludema. 2002. The rise and fall of the most-favored-nation clause. In USITR Working Paper: USITR.

Charnovitz, Steve. 1998. Linking topics in treaties. University of Pennsylvania Journal of International Economic Law 19 (2):329-45.

Conconi, Paolo, and Carlo Perroni. 2002. Issue linkage and issue tie-in in multilateral negotiations. Journal of International Economics 57 (2):423-47.

18

Page 19: International Trade Governance - Home | Princeton …pcglobal/conferences/GLF/sharma_…  · Web view2010-04-23 · International Trade Governance: Re-considering the Alternatives

Cooley, Alexander, and Henrik Spruyt. 2009. Contracting States: Sovereign Transfers in International Relations. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

Dixit, Avinash. 2004. Lawlessness and Economics: Alternative Modes of Governance. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

———. 2009. Governance institutions and economic activity. American Economic Review 99 (1):5-24.

Ederington, Josh. 2003. Policy linkage and uncertainty in internatioanl agreements. Economic Inquiry 41 (2):305-17.

Ethier, Wilfred. 2004. Political externalities, nondiscrimination, and a multilateral world. Review of International Economics 12:303-20.

Greif, Avner. 1992. Institutions and international trade: Lessons from medieval trade. American Economic Review 82 (2):128-33.

Grossman, Gene, and Elhanan Helpman. 1995. Trade wars and trade talks. Journal of Political Economy 103 (4):675-708.

Horn, Henrik, and Peter Mavroidis. 2001. Economic and legal aspects of the most-favored nation clause. Journa of Political Economy 17 (2):233-79.

Hudec, Robert. 2000. Broadening the scope of remedies in WTO dispute settlement. In Improving WTO Dispute Settlement Procedures Issues and Lessons from the Practice of Other International Courts and Tribunals, edited by F. Weiss and J. Weirs. London: Cameron May.

Irwin, Douglas. 1995. The GATT in historical perspective. American Economic Review 85 (2):323-8.

Johnson, Harry. 1953-54. Optimum tariffs and retaliation. The Review of Economic Studies 21 (2):142-53.

Keohane, Robert. 1984. After Hegemony. Princeton: Princeton University Press.Krugman, Paul. 1997. What should trade negotiators negotiate about? Journa of

Economic Literature 35:113-120.Li, John Shuh. 2003. Relation-based versus rule-based governance: An explanation of the

East Asian miracle and Asian crisis. Review of International Economics 11 (4):651-73.

Limao, Nuno. 2002. Trade policy, cross-border externalities and lobbies: Do linked agreements enforce more cooperative outcomes? : University of Maryland.

Ludema, Rodney. 1991. International trade bargaining and the most-favored nation clause. Economics and Politics 3 (1):1-20.

———. 1996. On the value of preferential trade agreements in multilateral negotiations. Georgetown University.

Ludema, Rodney, and Anna Maria Mayda. 2009. Do countries free ride on MFN. Journal of International Economics 77:137-50.

Maggi, Giovanni. 1999. The role of multilateral institutions in international trade cooperation. American Economic Review 89 (1):190-213.

Maggi, Giovanni, and Andres Rodriguez-Clare. 1998. The value of trade agreements in the presence of political pressures. Journa of Political Economy 106 (3):574-601.

———. 2007. A Poltical Economy Theory of Trade Agreements. American Economic Review 97 (4):1374-1406.

Martin, Will, and Patrick Messerlin. 2007. Why is it so difficult? Trade liberalisation under the Doha agenda. Oxford Review of Economic Policy 23 (3):347-66.

19

Page 20: International Trade Governance - Home | Princeton …pcglobal/conferences/GLF/sharma_…  · Web view2010-04-23 · International Trade Governance: Re-considering the Alternatives

Mattoo, Aaditya, and Carseten Fink. 2002. Regional agreements and trade in services: Policy issues. In World Bank Policy Research Working Paper. Washington DC: World Bank.

Mattoo, Aaditya, and Arvind Subramanian. 2008. India and Bretton Woods II. Economic and Political Weekly November:62-70.

Mayer, Wolfgang. 1981. Theoretical considerations on negotiated tariff adjustments. Oxford Economic Papers New Series 33 (1):135-53.

McCalman, Phillip. 2001. Reaping what you sow: an empirical analysis of international patent harmonisation. Journal of International Economics 55 (1):161-86.

North, Douglass. 1990. Institutions, Institutional Change and Economic Performance. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

Panagariya, Arvind. 2000. Preferential trade liberalisation: the traditional theory and new developments. Journal of Economic Literature 38 (2):287-331.

Rama, Martin, and Guido Tabellini. 1998. Lobbying by capital and labor over trade and labor market policies. European Economic Review 42 (7):1295-1316.

Rose, Andrew. 2004. Do we really know that the WTO increases trade. American Economic Review 94 (1):98-114.

Sebenius, James. 1983. Negotiation arithmetic: adding and subtracting issues and parties. International Organisation 37 (2):281-316.

Spagnolo, Giancarlo. 1999. Issue linkage, delegation and international policy cooperation. Stockholm School of Economics.

Srinivasan, T N. 2007. The dispute settlement mechanism of the WTO: a brief history and an evaluation from economic, contractarian and legal perspective. The World Economy 30 (7):1033-68.

Staiger, Robert, and Guido Tabellini. 1987. Discretionary trade policy and excessive protection. American Economic Review 77 (5):340-48.

Subramanian, Arvind, and Shang-Jin Wei. 2007. The WTO promotes trade, strongly but unevenly. Journal of International Economics 72 (1):151-75.

Tabellini, Guido. 2008. The scope of cooperation: Values and incentives. Quarterly Journa of Economics 123 (3):905-950.

Tomz, M, J Goldstein, and D Rivers. 2007. Do we really know that the WTO increases trade? Comment. American Economic Review 97 (5):2005-18.

Whalley, John. 1996. Why do countries seek regional trade agreements? NBER Working Paper 5552.

Williamson, Oliver. 1996. The Mechanisms of Governance. New York: Oxford University Press.

———. 2000. The new institutional economics: taking stock, looking ahead. Journal of Economic Literature 38 (3):595-613.

———. 2005. The economics of governance. American Economic Review 95 (2):1-18.WTO. 2002. Proposal by Mexico: Improvements and Clarifications of the Dispute

Settlement Understanding TN/DS/W/23.———. 2009. Database on Regional Trade Agreements.Yarbrough, Beth, and Robert Yarbrough. 1992. Cooperation and Governance in

International Trade. Princeton: Princeton University of Press.

20