introductory microeconomics es10001 topic 1: introduction to markets

117
Introductory Microeconomics ES10001 Topic 1: Introduction to Markets

Upload: ryan-mcnulty

Post on 28-Mar-2015

259 views

Category:

Documents


6 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Introductory Microeconomics ES10001 Topic 1: Introduction to Markets

Introductory Microeconomics ES10001

Topic 1: Introduction to Markets

Page 2: Introductory Microeconomics ES10001 Topic 1: Introduction to Markets

1. What is Economics?

Economics is ... the study of choice.

More formal definition might be:

.... the study of the allocation of scarce resources amongst competing users.

Page 3: Introductory Microeconomics ES10001 Topic 1: Introduction to Markets

1. What is Economics?

Some of the key concepts in Economics can be illustrated via. the Production Possibility Frontier (PPF).

Definition: The PPF shows for each level of the output of one good, the maximum amount of the other good that can be produced.

Page 4: Introductory Microeconomics ES10001 Topic 1: Introduction to Markets

1. What is Economics?

Definition: The PPF shows for each level of the output of one good, the maximum amount of the other good that can be produced.

See Figure 1

Page 5: Introductory Microeconomics ES10001 Topic 1: Introduction to Markets

Y

X 0 5 10 15 20 25 30

5

15

10

25

20

A B

C

D

E

G

F

Figure 1: Production Possibility Frontier

Page 6: Introductory Microeconomics ES10001 Topic 1: Introduction to Markets

1. What is Economics?

Points on PPF are Pareto-Efficient - unable to make one person better off without making someone worse off

Economist's job is to move society to PPF (i.e. efficiency)

Whereabouts on PPF is job for politicians (i.e. equity)

Page 7: Introductory Microeconomics ES10001 Topic 1: Introduction to Markets

2. Theories and Evidence

Definition: a model (or theory) makes a series of simplifying assumptions from which it is deduced how people will behave. It is a deliberate simplification of reality.

Linear example:

Page 8: Introductory Microeconomics ES10001 Topic 1: Introduction to Markets

y

x 0

Slope =

Figure 2: Linear Model

Intercept

Page 9: Introductory Microeconomics ES10001 Topic 1: Introduction to Markets

2. Theories and Evidence

N.B. = intercept; = slope

Consider, for example, a total cost function, where c denotes total cost and q denotes output.

i.e. Total Costs = Fixed Costs + Variable Costs

Assume = 10, = 2

Page 10: Introductory Microeconomics ES10001 Topic 1: Introduction to Markets

Output Fixed Cost Variable Cost Total Cost

q = α + βq = c

1 10 2 12

2 10 4 14

3 10 6 16

q = 10 + 2q = c

Page 11: Introductory Microeconomics ES10001 Topic 1: Introduction to Markets

c

q 0

c = 10 + 2q

10

1 2 3

16

14

12

Figure 3: Total Cost Function

Page 12: Introductory Microeconomics ES10001 Topic 1: Introduction to Markets

3. Markets

Definition: A market is a set of arrangements by which buyers and sellers are in contact to exchange goods or services.

To understand how markets work we therefore need to examine the behaviour of buyers and sellers

Otherwise known as ‘Demand’ and ‘Supply’

Page 13: Introductory Microeconomics ES10001 Topic 1: Introduction to Markets

3. Markets

Demand: Quantity of a good buyers wish to purchase at every conceivable price. Thus demand is not a particular quantity.

Supply: Quantity of a good sellers wish to sell at every conceivable price. Thus supply is not a particular quantity.

N.B. distinction between demand (supply) and quantity demanded (supplied).

Page 14: Introductory Microeconomics ES10001 Topic 1: Introduction to Markets

3. Markets

Demand / Supply denotes schedule of demands / supplies at each and every conceivable price.

Quantity demanded / quantity supplied defines a particular demand / supply at a particular price.

Hypothesis - at ‘high’ prices we have qd < qs and at low prices the converse. Moreover, at some intermediate ‘equilibrium’ price, p*, the market clears.

Page 15: Introductory Microeconomics ES10001 Topic 1: Introduction to Markets

3. Markets

We define the equilibrium price p* as the price which clears the market

Thus p > (<) p* implies excess supply (demand) and in a free market the actions of buyers and sellers move p towards p*.

Page 16: Introductory Microeconomics ES10001 Topic 1: Introduction to Markets

p

q 0

Figure 4: Market Equilibrium

Demand

Supply

q*

p*

Page 17: Introductory Microeconomics ES10001 Topic 1: Introduction to Markets

p

q 0

p1

Excess Supply

Demand

Supply

qd(p1) q* qs(p1)

p*

Figure 5: Price Floor

Page 18: Introductory Microeconomics ES10001 Topic 1: Introduction to Markets

p

q 0

p1

Excess Demand Demand

Supply

qs(p1) q* qd(p1)

p*

Figure 6: Price Ceiling

Page 19: Introductory Microeconomics ES10001 Topic 1: Introduction to Markets

p

q 0

Supply

Demand

p*

pf

q1 q*

pc

Figure 7: ‘Near Side’ is Satisfied

Page 20: Introductory Microeconomics ES10001 Topic 1: Introduction to Markets

4. Demand

The demand curve shows the relationship between price and quantity demanded (qd) ceteris paribus

That is:

(i) qd at particular price per unit;

(ii) (maximum) price per unit consumers willing to pay for a particular quantity.

Page 21: Introductory Microeconomics ES10001 Topic 1: Introduction to Markets

4. Demand

Formally

qd = qd(p)

Quantity demanded depends upon price

Normal Demand Function (Curve)

Page 22: Introductory Microeconomics ES10001 Topic 1: Introduction to Markets

q

p 0

qd

Figure 8: Normal Demand Curve; qd = qd(p)

10

5

Page 23: Introductory Microeconomics ES10001 Topic 1: Introduction to Markets

4. Demand

We can equivalently think of price depending upon the quantity consumed

pd = pd(q)

Inverse Demand Function

Page 24: Introductory Microeconomics ES10001 Topic 1: Introduction to Markets

p

q 0

pd

Figure 8: Inverse Demand Curve; pd = pd(q)

Page 25: Introductory Microeconomics ES10001 Topic 1: Introduction to Markets

p

q 0

Figure 10: (Inverse) Demand Curve; pd = pd(q)

5

10

… quantity demanded at a particular price

Page 26: Introductory Microeconomics ES10001 Topic 1: Introduction to Markets

p

p 0

Figure 11: (Inverse) Demand Curve; pd = pd(q)

5

10

… buyer’s reservation (i.e. maximum price buyer willing to pay per unit

Page 27: Introductory Microeconomics ES10001 Topic 1: Introduction to Markets

4. Demand

Usually, we presume that qd depends negatively on (own) price, but this is not always the case (i.e. Giffen goods)

Note: ‘Movements Along’: Arise as a result of changes in own price.

‘Shifts In’: Arise when anything else changes.

Consider the latter

Page 28: Introductory Microeconomics ES10001 Topic 1: Introduction to Markets

4. Demand

What are these ‘other things’ that might bring about a shift in the demand curve

To answer that question, we need to look ‘behind the demand curve’ and drop our assumption of ceteris paribus – that other things remain equal.

Consider each in turn

Page 29: Introductory Microeconomics ES10001 Topic 1: Introduction to Markets

4. Demand

Four factors that might not remain equal:

(1) Price of Related Goods

(2) Consumer Incomes

(3) Tastes

(4) Tax

Page 30: Introductory Microeconomics ES10001 Topic 1: Introduction to Markets

4. Demand

Price of Related Goods

Example: A rise in price of butter would:

Decrease quantity of butter demanded by consumers; Increase demand for margarine at each and every price of

margarine; Decrease demand for bread at each and every price of bread.

Page 31: Introductory Microeconomics ES10001 Topic 1: Introduction to Markets

4. Demand

That is:

Butter & margarine are substitutes for one another

Butter & bread are complements for one another

Note: Pairs of goods; most goods are substitutes.

Page 32: Introductory Microeconomics ES10001 Topic 1: Introduction to Markets

pMargarine

qMargarine 0

p0d

p1d

Figure 12: Substitutes (Rise in pButter)

Page 33: Introductory Microeconomics ES10001 Topic 1: Introduction to Markets

pBread

qBread 0

p0d

p1d

Figure 13: Complements (Rise in PButter)

Page 34: Introductory Microeconomics ES10001 Topic 1: Introduction to Markets

4. Demand

Consumer Income

A normal good is a good for which demand increases when incomes rises

A inferior good is a good for which demand falls when income rises.

Page 35: Introductory Microeconomics ES10001 Topic 1: Introduction to Markets

pPrivate Transport

qPrivate Transport 0

p0d

p1d

Figure 14: Normal Good (Increase in Income)

Page 36: Introductory Microeconomics ES10001 Topic 1: Introduction to Markets

pPublic Transport

qPublic Transport 0

p0d

p1d

Figure 15: Inferior Good (Increase in Income)

Page 37: Introductory Microeconomics ES10001 Topic 1: Introduction to Markets

4. Demand

Tastes

Consumer tastes or preferences regarding array of potential consumables.

Shaped by custom, attitude, advertising.

Page 38: Introductory Microeconomics ES10001 Topic 1: Introduction to Markets

4. Demand

Tax

Consider purchase tax (e.g. VAT)

Consumer liable for £x tax per unit purchased

Thus, imposition of tax will reduce consumer’s reservation price for the good

Note: Unit / Ad Valorem

Page 39: Introductory Microeconomics ES10001 Topic 1: Introduction to Markets

p

0 q

p

d

Figure 15: (Unit) Purchase Tax

Page 40: Introductory Microeconomics ES10001 Topic 1: Introduction to Markets

p

0 q

tax p

d

ptd

Figure 16: (Unit) Purchase Tax

Page 41: Introductory Microeconomics ES10001 Topic 1: Introduction to Markets

p

0 10 q

p

d

ptd

Figure 17: (Unit) Purchase Tax

5

3

t = £2

Page 42: Introductory Microeconomics ES10001 Topic 1: Introduction to Markets

5. Supply

The Supply Curve Shows the relationship between price and quantity supplied ceteris paribus; That is:

Quantity supplied at particular price per unit;

Minimum price per unit suppliers willing to accept for particular quantity.

Page 43: Introductory Microeconomics ES10001 Topic 1: Introduction to Markets

p

q 0

ps

Figure 18: (Inverse) Supply Curve

Page 44: Introductory Microeconomics ES10001 Topic 1: Introduction to Markets

p

q 0

5

10

… quantity supplied at a particular price

Figure 19: (Inverse) Supply Function ; ps = ps(q)

Page 45: Introductory Microeconomics ES10001 Topic 1: Introduction to Markets

p

q 0

5

10

… seller’s reservation price (i.e. minimum price seller wiling to accept per unit)

Figure 20: (Inverse) Supply Function ; ps = ps(q)

Page 46: Introductory Microeconomics ES10001 Topic 1: Introduction to Markets

5. Supply

Behind the supply curve (ceteris paribus)

Four factors:

(1) Technology;

(2) Input Costs;

(3) Government Regulation;

(4) Tax.

Page 47: Introductory Microeconomics ES10001 Topic 1: Introduction to Markets

5. Supply

Technology

Improvement in technology shifts supply curve to the right

Intuition?

Producers willing to supply higher quantity at each and every price

Page 48: Introductory Microeconomics ES10001 Topic 1: Introduction to Markets

Figure 21: Technological Advance

q 0

p0s

p1s

p

Page 49: Introductory Microeconomics ES10001 Topic 1: Introduction to Markets

5. Supply

Costs

If these fall then supply curve will shift to right for the same reason.

Government Regulation

Adverse technological change - i.e. safety / environmental regulations will shift supply curve to the left.

Page 50: Introductory Microeconomics ES10001 Topic 1: Introduction to Markets

p

q 0

p0s

p1s

Figure 23: Government Regulation

Page 51: Introductory Microeconomics ES10001 Topic 1: Introduction to Markets

5. Supply

Tax

Consider unit sales tax

Seller liable for £x tax per unit sold

Thus, imposition of tax will increase seller’s reservation price for the good

Page 52: Introductory Microeconomics ES10001 Topic 1: Introduction to Markets

p

0 q

Figure 24: (Unit) Sales Tax

Page 53: Introductory Microeconomics ES10001 Topic 1: Introduction to Markets

p

0 q

tax

Figure 25: (Unit) Sales Tax

Page 54: Introductory Microeconomics ES10001 Topic 1: Introduction to Markets

p

0 q

Figure 26: (Unit) Sales Tax

t = £2 11

9

10

Page 55: Introductory Microeconomics ES10001 Topic 1: Introduction to Markets

6. Linear Demand / Supply

Demand

Recall - the demand curve shows:

quantity demanded at particular price per unit.

(maximum) price per unit consumers willing to pay for particular quantity

Page 56: Introductory Microeconomics ES10001 Topic 1: Introduction to Markets

6. Linear Demand / Supply

Formally

qd = qd(p)

Assume demand curves are linear - i.e. straight lines. Thus:

qd(p) = a - bp

Page 57: Introductory Microeconomics ES10001 Topic 1: Introduction to Markets

6. Linear Demand / Supply

That is, when p = 0, individuals demand a maximum number of units of the good

qd(0) = a - b·0 = a

Simplistic, but useful, assumption

Page 58: Introductory Microeconomics ES10001 Topic 1: Introduction to Markets

p

q 0

a

1

d

d

q a bp

bp a q

ap q

b b

a/b

Figure 27: Linear Demand Curve

Page 59: Introductory Microeconomics ES10001 Topic 1: Introduction to Markets

p

q 0

Figure 28: Non-Linear Demand Curve

pd

Page 60: Introductory Microeconomics ES10001 Topic 1: Introduction to Markets

6. Linear Demand / Supply

Now consider slope b

The slope of the demand curve tells us how quantity demand changes in response to a change in price

Formally

Page 61: Introductory Microeconomics ES10001 Topic 1: Introduction to Markets

6. Linear Demand / Supply

(1) (2)

(3) = (2) - (1)

(3)

q0d a bp

0

q1d a bp

1

Page 62: Introductory Microeconomics ES10001 Topic 1: Introduction to Markets

p

q 0

a

p0

p1

q0 q1

E0

E1

qd a bp

q

0a bp

0

q1a bp

1

Figure 29: Slope of Demand Curve

a/b

Page 63: Introductory Microeconomics ES10001 Topic 1: Introduction to Markets

p

q 0

a

p0

p1

q0 q1

qd a bp

q bp

Figure 30: Slope of Demand Curve

E0

E1

a/b

Page 64: Introductory Microeconomics ES10001 Topic 1: Introduction to Markets

6. Linear Demand / Supply

Now consider two demand curves

(4)

where i = x, y. Thus:

(4a) (4b)

qid a

i b

ip

dy y yq a b p

qxd a

x b

xp

Page 65: Introductory Microeconomics ES10001 Topic 1: Introduction to Markets

6. Linear Demand / Supply

It must be the case that:

(5)

If by > bx then

Demand curve ‘y’ has a ‘bigger’ slope than demand curve ‘x’

But … it is ‘flatter’!!!

qid b

ip

Page 66: Introductory Microeconomics ES10001 Topic 1: Introduction to Markets

p

q 0

p0

p1

,di i i

i i

q a b p i x y

q b p

qxd

qyd

0q qx1

qy1

Figure 31: Slope of Demand Curve

Page 67: Introductory Microeconomics ES10001 Topic 1: Introduction to Markets

6. Linear Demand / Supply

Recall, we generally ‘write’ the normal demand function but ‘draw’ the inverse demand function

And if by > bx then 1/by < 1/bx

Such that the inverse demand function

(i.e. the one we draw) is flatter p

id

a

b

1

bq

Page 68: Introductory Microeconomics ES10001 Topic 1: Introduction to Markets

6. Linear Demand / Supply

The inverse demand curve maps the consumers’ reservation price schedule

i.e. as quantity increases consumers are willing to pay less per unit - diminishing marginal utility.

Also, it tells us the maximum price consumers are willing to pay for the first unit of the good

pd(0) = a/b

Page 69: Introductory Microeconomics ES10001 Topic 1: Introduction to Markets

6. Linear Demand / Supply

Supply

Recall, supply curve shows

Quantity producers willing/able to supply at particular price per unit.

(Minimum) price per unit sellers willing to accept for particular quantity.

Page 70: Introductory Microeconomics ES10001 Topic 1: Introduction to Markets

6. Linear Demand / Supply

qs = qs(p)

Linear form:

(1) qs = c + dp

or

(2)

Page 71: Introductory Microeconomics ES10001 Topic 1: Introduction to Markets

7. Equilibrium

Equilibrium

Assuming linear demands and supplies we can solve for the equilibrium prices and quantities in the market

qd = a - bp

qs = c + dp

Page 72: Introductory Microeconomics ES10001 Topic 1: Introduction to Markets

7. Equilibrium

Recall, there is a particular price vis. the equilibrium price, p*, at which the market clears

qd(p*) = qs(p*)

or

qd (p*) = a - bp* = c + dp* = qs(p*)

Page 73: Introductory Microeconomics ES10001 Topic 1: Introduction to Markets

7. Equilibrium

d sq p q p

a bp c dp

a c b d p

a cp

b d

Page 74: Introductory Microeconomics ES10001 Topic 1: Introduction to Markets

7. Equilibrium

d

d

d

a cq p a bp a b

b d

a b d b a c ab ad ab bcq p

b d b d

ad bcq p

b d

Page 75: Introductory Microeconomics ES10001 Topic 1: Introduction to Markets

7. Equilibrium

s

s

s

a cq p c dp c d

b d

c b d d a c bc cd ad cdq p

b d b d

ad bcq p

b d

Page 76: Introductory Microeconomics ES10001 Topic 1: Introduction to Markets

7. Equilibrium

Consider the following example:

Thus

20 4

8 2

d

s

q p p

q p p

* *20 4 8 2

20 8 4 2

d sq p p p q p

p

Page 77: Introductory Microeconomics ES10001 Topic 1: Introduction to Markets

7. Equilibrium

Such that:

Substituting equilibrium price, p*, into the demand and supply functions yields equilibrium quantity

qd(p*) =20 – 4p* = 8 + 2p* = qs(p*)

20 8 122

4 2 6

a cp

b d

Page 78: Introductory Microeconomics ES10001 Topic 1: Introduction to Markets

7. Equilibrium

Page 79: Introductory Microeconomics ES10001 Topic 1: Introduction to Markets

7. Equilibrium

or:

such that:

20 4

8 2

d

s

q p a bp p

q p c dp p

q*

ad bc

b d

20 * 2 4 *8

4 2

40 32

6

72

612

Page 80: Introductory Microeconomics ES10001 Topic 1: Introduction to Markets

8. Elasticity

Measuring the price responsiveness of demand

Consider problem of seller who want to maximise sales revenue.

R = p*q

But q = q(p) and p = p(q); i.e. q depends upon p and p depends upon q

Thus trade off!

Page 81: Introductory Microeconomics ES10001 Topic 1: Introduction to Markets

8. Elasticity

Revenue increases if price is raised ceteris paribus; but we cannot assume ceteris paribus

Strategy:

(i) sell few goods at high unit price; or

(ii) sell many goods at low unit price

Optimal choice depends upon price responsiveness of demand

Page 82: Introductory Microeconomics ES10001 Topic 1: Introduction to Markets

8. Elasticity

We could simply look at the slope of the demand curve

Recall two individuals, x and y, where:

And by > bx such that individual y is more responsive to a change in price than individual x.

Page 83: Introductory Microeconomics ES10001 Topic 1: Introduction to Markets

p

q 0

p0

p1

,di i i

i i

q a b p i x y

q b p

qxd

qyd

0q qx1

qy1

Figure 32: Slope of Demand Curve

Page 84: Introductory Microeconomics ES10001 Topic 1: Introduction to Markets

8. Elasticity

Slope is OK but:

(i) It is unit dependent i.e. £, £, quantity of laptops, bottles of wine

(ii) Does not convey relative strength of changei.e. price cut from £100 to £99 increases

demand by same amount as cut from £2 to £1

Page 85: Introductory Microeconomics ES10001 Topic 1: Introduction to Markets

8. Elasticity

Better concept

Elasticity of Demand

Definition: The (price) elasticity of demand is the percentage change in the quantity of a good demanded divided by the corresponding percentage change in its price.

%

%

dChange in qE

Change in p

Page 86: Introductory Microeconomics ES10001 Topic 1: Introduction to Markets

8. Elasticity

Example: Price rises from £10 to £12 and demand falls from 50 units to 30 units then:

E = (-40%) / (20%) = -2

In words: “A 1% rise in price will lead to a 2% fall in demand.”

N.B. For simplicity, we usually ignore the minus sign and define E as a positive number.

Page 87: Introductory Microeconomics ES10001 Topic 1: Introduction to Markets

8. Elasticity

Thus:

Define: E

%qd

%p 0

%x x

1 x

0

x0

100%

%x x

x0

100%

Page 88: Introductory Microeconomics ES10001 Topic 1: Introduction to Markets

8. Elasticity

Thus:

Recall our linear model:

E

qq

0

100%

pp

0

100%

q

q0

p

0

p

q

p

p0

q0

0

q0d a bp

0

Page 89: Introductory Microeconomics ES10001 Topic 1: Introduction to Markets

8. Elasticity

(1) (2)

(3) = (2) - (1)

(3)

q0d a bp

0

q1d a bp

1

Page 90: Introductory Microeconomics ES10001 Topic 1: Introduction to Markets

8. Elasticity

Thus:

Such that

qq b p b

p

Page 91: Introductory Microeconomics ES10001 Topic 1: Introduction to Markets

8. Elasticity

Note:

E is a number and as such it is unit dependent

E conveys the relative strength of changes in price and demand

Along a linear demand curve, slope (i.e. b) is constant but elasticity [i.e. b(p/q)] varies.

Page 92: Introductory Microeconomics ES10001 Topic 1: Introduction to Markets

8. Elasticity

E > 1: Demand is Elastic

1% rise in p leads to a more than 1% fall in qd

E < 1: Demand is Inelastic

1% rise in p leads to a less than 1% fall in qd

E = 1: Demand is Unit Elastic

1% rise in p leads to same 1% fall in qd

Page 93: Introductory Microeconomics ES10001 Topic 1: Introduction to Markets

8. Elasticity

Recall our linear function

with p = p0 and q = q0.

where is this equal to 1?

i.e. find the (p, q) at which E = 1

Page 94: Introductory Microeconomics ES10001 Topic 1: Introduction to Markets

8. Elasticity

Thus, solve E for

Page 95: Introductory Microeconomics ES10001 Topic 1: Introduction to Markets

8. Elasticity

Such that:

Page 96: Introductory Microeconomics ES10001 Topic 1: Introduction to Markets

p

q 0

E

1E

0E

1E

1E

a

Figure 33: Elasticity of Demand

Page 97: Introductory Microeconomics ES10001 Topic 1: Introduction to Markets

8. Elasticity

Point and Arc Elasticities

So far - point elasticities

If considering responsiveness over a range of prices / quantities then arc elasticity is more appropriate

Page 98: Introductory Microeconomics ES10001 Topic 1: Introduction to Markets

8. Elasticity

Define:

Thus:

Page 99: Introductory Microeconomics ES10001 Topic 1: Introduction to Markets

p

q 0

p0

p1

q0 q1

a b

a

Figure 34: Arc Elasticity of Demand

Page 100: Introductory Microeconomics ES10001 Topic 1: Introduction to Markets

8. Elasticity

Arc elasticity between, e.g., p0 and p1 (q0 and q1) is equivalent to point elasticity at:

Or:

Page 101: Introductory Microeconomics ES10001 Topic 1: Introduction to Markets

8. Elasticity

Determinants of Elasticity

Ultimately a matter of tastes - how essential is the good; how much do individuals want it.

Also time; more elastic in long run as consumers can substitute away.

Most important consideration is the ease with which consumers can substitute another good that fulfils approximately the same function

Page 102: Introductory Microeconomics ES10001 Topic 1: Introduction to Markets

8. Elasticity

Applications of Elasticity

Determining price and quantity the maximises revenue.

Seller can choose either how many goods to sell or the price at which to sell them, but not both. i.e:

R = p*q

Page 103: Introductory Microeconomics ES10001 Topic 1: Introduction to Markets

8. Elasticity

Consider effect of cut in price on Revenue (R)

(i) R falls because sell fewer goods at lower p;

(ii) R rises because sell more goods at higher p.

Thus trade off!

Question: Where is trade off optimised?

Page 104: Introductory Microeconomics ES10001 Topic 1: Introduction to Markets

8. Elasticity

Recall: If E > 1 then a 1% cut in p will lead to a more than 1% increase in qd

Thus R will rise since increase in qd dominates fall in p

Conversely if E < 1.

Page 105: Introductory Microeconomics ES10001 Topic 1: Introduction to Markets

8. Elasticity

Strategy

If E > 1 then cut price to increase revenue.

If E < 1 then raise price to increase revenue.

Optimum point is where E = 1

From this point, an x% change in p leads to same x% change in q, such that revenue is unchanged

Page 106: Introductory Microeconomics ES10001 Topic 1: Introduction to Markets

8. Elasticity

This point occurs half-way down the demand curve at and

Rectangle below demand curve at this point is biggest rectangle possible under the demand curve.

And since the rectangle represents sales revenue, then this is where sales revenue is maximised.

Page 107: Introductory Microeconomics ES10001 Topic 1: Introduction to Markets

p

q 0

1E

0E

a b

a

Maximum Revenue

Figure 35: Elasticity of Demand

Page 108: Introductory Microeconomics ES10001 Topic 1: Introduction to Markets

8. Elasticity

Example:

Page 109: Introductory Microeconomics ES10001 Topic 1: Introduction to Markets

8. Elasticity

Strategy

If E > 1 then cut price to increase revenue.

If E < 1 then raise price to increase revenue.

Optimum point is where E = 1

From this point, an x% change in p leads to same x% change in q, such that revenue is unchanged

Page 110: Introductory Microeconomics ES10001 Topic 1: Introduction to Markets

8. Elasticity

Thus, a producer could do no better than to put 10 units of the good onto this market.

This is interesting!

Had the producer gone to market with 12 goods, it would have been in his interest to destroy two of them!

Intuitive??????

Page 111: Introductory Microeconomics ES10001 Topic 1: Introduction to Markets

8. Elasticity

Cross Price Elasticity

Define: Cross price elasticity of demand for good i with respect to changes in price of good j equals % change in quantity of good y demanded divided by corresponding % change in price of good j

i.e.

Page 112: Introductory Microeconomics ES10001 Topic 1: Introduction to Markets

8. Elasticity

Eij > 0 Increase in pj leads to fall in qi

thus i and j are substitutes for one another

Eij < 0 Increase in pj leads to fall in qi

thus i and j are complements for one another

Page 113: Introductory Microeconomics ES10001 Topic 1: Introduction to Markets

8. Elasticity

Income Elasticity

Define: Income elasticity of demand for a good is % change in quantity demanded divided by corresponding % change in income (M).

EM > 0: 1% increase in M leads to rise in demand thus the good is normal

EM < 0: 1% increase in M leads to fall in demand thus good is inferior

Page 114: Introductory Microeconomics ES10001 Topic 1: Introduction to Markets

8. Elasticity

We can distinguish:

EM > 1 Luxuries

0 < EM < 1 Necessities

Page 115: Introductory Microeconomics ES10001 Topic 1: Introduction to Markets

9. Final Comments

Free markets are one way for society to solve the basic economic questions of what, how, and for whom to produce.

We have begun to see how the market allocates scarce resources amongst competing users.

The market will decide:

Page 116: Introductory Microeconomics ES10001 Topic 1: Introduction to Markets

9. Final Comments

How much of a good is producedBy finding price that equates demand and supply.

For whom a good is producedGood is purchased by all those willing to pay at least equilibrium price

By whom a good is producedGood is supplied by all those willing to supply at equilibrium price

What goods are producedThrough the supply curve

Page 117: Introductory Microeconomics ES10001 Topic 1: Introduction to Markets

9. Final Comments

N.B. We will also see later in the course that the market can tell us how goods are produced!

In conclusion, we should note that societies may not like the answers that the market provides.

Free markets do not produce enough food for everyone to go without hunger; or enough medical care to treat all the sick.