jerusalem papers in regulation & governanceregulation.huji.ac.il/papers/jp13.pdf · this...

41
ISSN: 2079-5882 Jerusalem Papers in Regulation & Governance Working Paper No. 13 June 2010 POLITICAL DETERMINANTS OF LIBERALIZATIONS; NEW EVIDENCE FROM OECD NETWORK INDUSTRIES Filippo Belloc Department of Economics, Faculty of Economics “R. M. Goodwin” University of Siena, Italy P.zza S. Francesco 7 53100 Email: [email protected] Antonio Nicita Department of Economics, Faculty of Economics “R. M. Goodwin” University of Siena, Italy P.zza S. Francesco 7 53100 Homepage: http://www.antonionicita.it Email: [email protected] Jerusalem Forum on Regulation & Governance The Hebrew University Mount Scopus Jerusalem, 91905, Israel הפורום הירושלמי לרגולציה וממשליות האוניברסיטה העברית הר הצופים ירושלים, 91905 Email : [email protected] http://regulation.huji.ac.il

Upload: others

Post on 09-Aug-2020

3 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Jerusalem Papers in Regulation & Governanceregulation.huji.ac.il/papers/jp13.pdf · This research is part of the REFGOV project. 2 ISSN: 2079-5882 Political Determinants of Liberalizations;

ISSN: 2079-5882

Jerusalem Papers in Regulation & Governance

Working Paper No. 13 June 2010

POLITICAL DETERMINANTS OF LIBERALIZATIONS;

NEW EVIDENCE FROM OECD

NETWORK INDUSTRIES

Filippo Belloc

Department of Economics,

Faculty of Economics “R. M. Goodwin”

University of Siena, Italy

P.zza S. Francesco 7 53100

Email: [email protected]

Antonio Nicita

Department of Economics,

Faculty of Economics “R. M. Goodwin”

University of Siena, Italy

P.zza S. Francesco 7 53100

Homepage: http://www.antonionicita.it

Email: [email protected]

Jerusalem Forum

on Regulation & Governance

The Hebrew University

Mount Scopus

Jerusalem, 91905, Israel

הפורום הירושלמילרגולציה וממשליות

האוניברסיטה העברית הר הצופים

91905, ירושלים

Email :[email protected]

http://regulation.huji.ac.il

Page 2: Jerusalem Papers in Regulation & Governanceregulation.huji.ac.il/papers/jp13.pdf · This research is part of the REFGOV project. 2 ISSN: 2079-5882 Political Determinants of Liberalizations;

1 ISSN: 2079-5882

Political Determinants of Liberalizations;

New Evidence from OECD Network Industries

Filippo Belloc and Antonio Nicita

Abstract: We investigate the political determinants of liberalization in OECD network

industries. Performing a panel estimation over thirty years, through the largest and most

updated sample available, we find that right-wing governments liberalize less than left-

wing ones. This result, which contrasts conventional wisdom, is confirmed when

controlling for the existing regulatory conditions that executives find when elected.

Furthermore, governments‟ heterogeneity, proportional electoral rules, and European

Union membership all show positive and statistically significant effects on liberalization

in network industries. We conclude that traditional ideological cleavage does not

provide a political-economic rationale for the observed liberalization paths.

Acknowledgements:

We would like to thank for previous discussions on the issue or comments Carlo

Cambini, Xavier Fernandez I Marin, Philippe Martin, Fabio Padovano and Stefan

Voigt,. Usual disclaimers apply. This research is part of the REFGOV project.

Page 3: Jerusalem Papers in Regulation & Governanceregulation.huji.ac.il/papers/jp13.pdf · This research is part of the REFGOV project. 2 ISSN: 2079-5882 Political Determinants of Liberalizations;

2 ISSN: 2079-5882

Political Determinants of Liberalizations;

New Evidence from OECD Network Industries

1. Introduction

One of the distinguishing features of the last three decades has been the wave of market-

oriented policies experienced worldwide (Conway and Nicoletti, 2006; Armstrong and

Sappington, 2006; Guriev and Megginson, 2007; Pitlik, 2007).

In particular, in network industries, which cover crucial sectors for national economies

such as passenger air transport, telecommunications, electricity, gas, post, rail and road,

privatization and liberalization are among the market-oriented policies which registered

the largest convergence across OECD countries.

Beside the analysis of economic determinants (Vickers and Yarrow, 1991; Levy and

Spiller, 1996; Newbery, 1997; 2002; Armstrong and Sappington, 2006), a large group

of scholars have investigated the role of institutional and political determinants of

market-oriented policy in network industries, following the „political economics‟

approach (Alesina, 1988; Alesina and Rosenthal, 1995; Perrotti, 1995; Garrett, 1998;

Persson and Tabellini, 2000; Persson, 2002; Besley and Case, 2003; Besley, 2007;

Besley, Persson and Sturm, 2010).

While the political economy of privatization in network industries has been largely

investigated and measured, little of this literature, with some relevant exceptions,

addresses the role of political parties and institutions as determinants of liberalization

policy.

In this paper we attempt to fill this gap, analyzing liberalization policies over the last

three decades in seven OECD network industries, whose relevance is crucial both in

Page 4: Jerusalem Papers in Regulation & Governanceregulation.huji.ac.il/papers/jp13.pdf · This research is part of the REFGOV project. 2 ISSN: 2079-5882 Political Determinants of Liberalizations;

3 ISSN: 2079-5882

terms of their impact on per capita consumption and as suppliers of intermediate inputs

(Conway and Nicoletti, 2006). Liberalization here refers mainly to policy aimed at

reducing economic, institutional and legal barriers to entry in sectors previously

dominated by legal state-owned monopolies and in which access to essential facility

networks is crucial to develop downstream competition.

Our analysis is based on the largest updated data set available, provided by the latest

releases of ETCR economic indicators for liberalization (OECD, 2009) and by political

indicators of the World Bank‟s Database of Political Institutions (World Bank, 2009).

This allows us to consider a larger group of countries and a longer period of time with

respect to previous empirical studies. In particular, we perform a panel analysis on a

sample of 30 OECD countries over the 1975-2006 period, and circumvent omitted

variable bias and endogeneity problems by estimating a time/country fixed effects lag-

model. Our results, firstly, reveal – contrary to previous analyses (Pitlik, 2007, Potrafke,

2009) - that left-wing governments have been more active in promoting liberalization

policies than right-wing ones. Secondly, they suggest that the traditional claim of right-

wing governments to be the biggest promoters of market-oriented policies may need to

be reconsidered when the deregulation process is analyzed in its entire accomplishment

from the Seventies to date.

Moreover, our analysis reveals that government heterogeneity and proportional electoral

systems show a positive and statistically significant effect on the decision to liberalize.

Also international openness of internal markets and European Union membership, show

a positive and statistically significant effect on the intensity of liberalization policies. In

addition, adoption of the euro currency shows a statistical significant effect on

liberalization in network industries, as pointed out by Høj, Galasso, Nicoletti and Dang

(2006). Finally, a strong path-dependency is found for OECD liberalization patterns, as

past deregulation initiatives not only show a remarkable „ratchet effect‟ but also seem to

generate a positive attitude in governments towards launching new liberalization

programs.

We conclude that traditional ideological cleavage does not provide, as in the past, a

political-economic rationale behind liberalization paths in network industries.

Page 5: Jerusalem Papers in Regulation & Governanceregulation.huji.ac.il/papers/jp13.pdf · This research is part of the REFGOV project. 2 ISSN: 2079-5882 Political Determinants of Liberalizations;

4 ISSN: 2079-5882

Two caveats arise: we do not explore whether political parties properly reflect, in their

liberalization choices, the interests of their constituents; and we do not measure

economic liberalization outcomes such as prices, market structure, investments and so

on. The paper proceeds as follows. In Section 2 we briefly review the existing empirical

literature. In section 3 we outline some styized facts over political determinants of

liberalization in selected OECD countries. In Section 4 we describe our data and

empirical strategy, while in Section 5 we summarize our main results. Section 6

discusses our findings and Section 7 concludes.

2. Related Literature

We devote here our attention to the literature on the political and institutional

determinants of privatization and liberalization policies in network industries.

Many scholars have attempted to analyze and measure the political and institutional

determinants of privatization in network industries, interpreting the degree of public

ownership as the most significant, if not exhaustive, proxy for the adoption of market-

oriented policies in developed economies (Perotti, 1995; Boix, 1997; Meggison and

Netter, 2001; Li and Xu, 2002; Biais and Perotti, 2002; Schneider, Fink, and

Tenbucken, 2005; Dinc and Gupta, 2007; Bortolotti and Pinotti, 2008; Schneider and

Häge, 2008; Biørnskov and Potrafke, 2009; Arin and Ulubasoglu, 2009) .

The regularity observed by these empirical investigations shows that „politics matter‟

for the adoption of privatization policy and that the decision to privatize is significantly

influenced by majoritarian and right-wing governments, while proportional electoral

rules and left-wing governments seem traditionally to have hindered it.

While the political economy of privatization choices has been largely investigated, the

analysis of institutional and political determinants of liberalization policy is still in its

infancy. In the light of the evidence on the determinants of privatization, some scholars

have concluded that additionally other market-oriented policies in network industries,

such as liberalization, are mainly driven by right-wing parties in office. Duso (2002),

Page 6: Jerusalem Papers in Regulation & Governanceregulation.huji.ac.il/papers/jp13.pdf · This research is part of the REFGOV project. 2 ISSN: 2079-5882 Political Determinants of Liberalizations;

5 ISSN: 2079-5882

studying regulatory intervention and entry liberalization within the mobile

telecommunications industry in OECD countries during the 1990s, shows how countries

with majoritarian elections liberalize more, with left-wing governments liberalizing less

than right-wing governments. Pitlik (2007) finds, for 22 OECD countries, that a left-

wing orientation of government and a high degree of legislative fragmentation are

negatively related to deregulation of markets. Duso and Seldeslachts (2009) investigate

liberalization in mobile telecommunications in 24 OECD countries, showing how a

majoritarian political system induces a faster liberalization, with right-wing parties

pushing more for market-oriented reforms. Finally, Potrafke (2009) analyzes the impact

of government ideology on the liberalization of network industries in 21 OECD

countries, showing how market-oriented and right-wing governments have been more

active in deregulating product markets, while European Union membership does not

turn out to be statistically significant.

The limited empirical literature so far available confirms, for liberalization policy in

network industries, the same conclusions as those reached in the literature on

privatization: a strong role for right-wing governments and majoritarian systems.

Besides, the impact of international policy diffusion and supranational determinants,

such as European Union membership, in inducing the adoption of market-oriented

policies seems more controversial, as Pitlik (2007) and Potrafke (2009) respectively

find the effects to be weak or absent, while Høj, Galasso, Nicoletti, and Dang (2006)

measure a significant impact of adoption of the euro for liberalization policies.

Page 7: Jerusalem Papers in Regulation & Governanceregulation.huji.ac.il/papers/jp13.pdf · This research is part of the REFGOV project. 2 ISSN: 2079-5882 Political Determinants of Liberalizations;

6 ISSN: 2079-5882

3. Some Puzzling Stylized Facts

Some of the above preliminary conclusions reached in the literature, on the prominent

role of right wing party in promoting liberalization, turn out to be puzzling on empirical

grounds. Indeed, they seem apparently inconsistent with some relevant experiences of

liberalization processes observed in many developed economies. Several liberalization

reforms in network industries have been led by left-wing and centrist and/or

independent governments, proportional electoral rules and heterogeneous and „weak‟

governmental coalitions (Figure 1).

Figure 1: Aggregate liberalization race in seven network industries for 30 OECD

countries and right-wing/left-wing governments over the last decade.

(OECD, 2009; World Bank, 2008)

0

0.05

0.1

0.15

0.2

0.25

0.3

0.35

<2000 2000-2001 2002-2003 2004-2005 2006-2007

Right

Left

Note: liberalization is measured by subtracting the OECD‟s (2009) indicator of entry barriers

from its maximum value (the index ranges from 0 to 6): the liberalization initiatives‟ intensity

(Y axis) is then calculated as two-year variations of the liberalization index. On the right side of

the graph the average intensity before 2000 is displayed, on the left side two-year variations

after 2000 are shown.

Figure 1 above reports the aggregate liberalization race in seven network industries for

30 OECD countries. On the right side of the graph the average liberalization intensity

before 2000 is displayed, on the left side two-year variations after 2000 are shown.

Figure 1 makes it clear first of all that, within a sample of 30 OECD countries, before

2000 left-wing governments implemented some liberalization (measured by two-year

Page 8: Jerusalem Papers in Regulation & Governanceregulation.huji.ac.il/papers/jp13.pdf · This research is part of the REFGOV project. 2 ISSN: 2079-5882 Political Determinants of Liberalizations;

7 ISSN: 2079-5882

variations in the inverse of ECTR index (OECD, 2009)) in the same vein as right-wing

governments, which however seem to have undertaken a higher level of liberalization

from an inferential point of view, as outlined by Pitlik (2007) and Potrafke (2009), who

study a smaller sample of OECD countries through 2002-03.

The new evidence clearly shows that, from the late Nineties onward, left-oriented

governments undoubtedly have been more active than right-oriented ones in

liberalization policies, while both right-wing and left-wing executives appear to have

reduced liberalization activity after 2006, having approached in many sectors the floor

of entry barrier reductions in the OECD indicator.

Some stylized facts, picked from the communications and electricity sectors, confirm

this pattern.

Some evidence of Left-Wing Liberalizations in the Communications Sector

With regard to the Danish communications sector, in 1999 the Social Democrats

approved an agreement enabling the establishment of alternative infrastructures in the

access network through the public tendering of frequency resources, in order to enhance

competition in the market. At the end of the same year, the Danish parliament, again

under the leadership of the Social Democrats, approved Act No. 1996 (amending the

Act on Radio-communications and Assignment of Radio Frequencies and the Act on

Public Mobile Communications) that substantially increased competition in broadband

services and in the mobile market. Similarly, in Portugal a government led by the

Socialist Party fully liberalized the telecommunications services between 1998 and

2000; in 2000, in particular, Portugal Telecom lost its exclusive rights as a telecoms

service provider. More generally, in the telecommunications sector, left-wing

governments have led substantive liberalization processes in several countries. In

France, the Socialists approved an unbundling decree in 2000 that mandated France

Telecom to provide both raw copper unbundling and shared access to its loops. In

Germany, the left-wing SPD approved in 2003 a new Telecommunications Act reducing

entry barriers. In Greece, Law No. 2246 of 1994 (introduced by the Pan-Hellenic

Page 9: Jerusalem Papers in Regulation & Governanceregulation.huji.ac.il/papers/jp13.pdf · This research is part of the REFGOV project. 2 ISSN: 2079-5882 Political Determinants of Liberalizations;

8 ISSN: 2079-5882

Socialists) liberalized all telecommunications services and the mobile market. In

Hungary, the Hungarian Socialist Party enacted a number of regulatory initiatives

concerning licensing in telecommunications services between 1996 and 1998. In Italy,

the liberalization of satellite services and the voice telephony market started with Law

No. 249/97 by the Center-Left Ulivo alliance. In the Netherlands, the Labor Party

implemented the liberalization of telecommunications infrastructure and of all

telecommunications services between 1996 and 1997. In Poland, several ordinances

between 1996 and 2001 were implemented by SRP, and then by SLD, concerning

various aspects of the telecommunications market. In Spain, in 1995 the PSOE

approved the Satellite Telecommunications Act and the Cable Telecommunications Act

that authorized the concession for cable services through a call for tenders. In Turkey,

the parliament, led by the Democratic Left Party, approved the end of the monopoly of

Turk Telekom in 2000. In Canada, a number of liberalization initiatives for the

telecommunications market were implemented by the Liberal Party, starting from 1994.

Some evidence of Left-Wing Liberalizations in the Electricity Sector

Also in the electricity sector, left-wing governments have implemented pro-competitive

policies in the past. We recall here some concrete initiatives in brief. In Australia, the

left-wing government of Victoria passed an Electricity Industry Act in 1993 which

created a wholesale market. In Canada, the Electric Utilities Act was approved in

Alberta in 2001, and the Energy Competition Act passed in Ontario in 1998, both

through the promotion of the Liberal Party, completely liberalizing electricity supply. In

the Czech Republic, the Energy Act of 2000 was approved by a parliament dominated

by the Social Democratic Party – CSSD. In Denmark, the Amendment to the Danish

Electricity Supply Act issued in 1996 was approved by the Social Democrat-led

parliament, so permitting private companies and distribution companies of sufficient

size to buy power from third parties. In France, in 2000, Law No. 2000-108 concerning

the access of new entrants to both distribution and transmission networks was enacted

by the National Assembly under the Socialists. In Greece, the Electricity Law of 1999,

complying with Directive 96/92/EC and applying free market rules to electricity

generation and supply, was introduced by the Pan-Hellenic Socialists. In Italy, in 1999,

Page 10: Jerusalem Papers in Regulation & Governanceregulation.huji.ac.il/papers/jp13.pdf · This research is part of the REFGOV project. 2 ISSN: 2079-5882 Political Determinants of Liberalizations;

9 ISSN: 2079-5882

with the Bersani Decree (Decree 79/99), the liberalization of the electricity sector and

the establishment of a sectoral Regulatory Authority were introduced by the Center-Left

coalition. In Japan, the first left-wing government since 1975 (led by the Social

Democratic Party – SDPJ) approved the Amendment to the Electricity Utility Law in

1995, introducing a system of competitive tendering in the wholesale electricity market.

In the Netherlands, with the Electricity Act of 1998 introduced by the Labor Party,

decentralized energy generation was favored. In Poland, the Energy Act was issued by

the SRP in 1997, allowing large electricity users to negotiate directly with generators of

power. In Spain, the Electricity Act was promoted by the Socialist Party – PSOE - in

1994, creating the Independent System and setting up competition for the access to

electricity networks. In Sweden, the Law for the Supply of Electricity 10/95 in 1995

was introduced by the Social Democrats, making it possible to generate and trade

electricity in a competitive environment. In Turkey, the Electricity Market Law of 2001,

establishing a new entity to oversee all energy market activities, was promoted by the

Democratic Left Party – DSP. Finally, in the USA, the Public Utility Regulatory

Policies Act – PURPA –, aimed at encouraging decentralized energy production, was

promoted by the Democrats in 1978 (approved along with the Airline Deregulation

Act).

General evidence of Left-Wing Liberalization Race in Network Industries

Besides the mentioned instances of launching liberalization in the communications and

electricity sectors, left-wing governments have been active – to differing extents - in

other industries, such as air transport, gas, post, rail and road.

As reported in Figure 2, with the exception of the road sector (where right-wing

governments seem to be far more active than left-wing ones) and of the post and gas

sector (where parties of either political leaning show a similar intensity in

liberalization), left-wing governments perform better than right-wing ones as to

liberalization intensity. We therefore claim that empirical analyses that refer to a limited

number of countries and that do not consider the deregulation process in its entirety

(from the Seventies to date) may lead only to partial conclusions. Indeed, especially in

Page 11: Jerusalem Papers in Regulation & Governanceregulation.huji.ac.il/papers/jp13.pdf · This research is part of the REFGOV project. 2 ISSN: 2079-5882 Political Determinants of Liberalizations;

10 ISSN: 2079-5882

the last decade, many left-wing governments seem to have pushed convincingly towards

liberalization.

Figure 2: Liberalization race in seven network industries for 30 OECD countries and right-wing/left-wing governments over the 1975-2006 period.

(OECD, 2009; World Bank, 2008)

0

0.05

0.1

0.15

0.2

0.25

Electricity Gas Post Rail Road Telecom Air

Left

Right

Note: liberalization is measured by subtracting the OECD‟s (2009) indicator of entry barriers

from its maximum value (the index ranges from 0 to 6); liberalization initiatives‟ intensity (Y

axis) is then calculated as two-year variations of the liberalization index and expressed as an

average over the 1975-2006 period.

Finally, Figure 3 reports all the liberalization patterns (as an average for seven network

industries) observed in 15 of the 30 OECD countries analyzed in this paper in which

left-wing governments seemed to have pushed towards liberalization. The liberalization

race under left-wing governments is labeled by „L‟, whereas „R‟ stands for right-wing

governments, and NC for „other‟ parties according to the World Bank (2009)

classification.

Page 12: Jerusalem Papers in Regulation & Governanceregulation.huji.ac.il/papers/jp13.pdf · This research is part of the REFGOV project. 2 ISSN: 2079-5882 Political Determinants of Liberalizations;

11 ISSN: 2079-5882

Figure 3: Performance of Left-Wing Governments on liberalization policy for seven

Network Industries

Source: Elaboration from OECD (2006, 2009) and World Bank (2009); L= left-wing;

R= right-wing; NC= non classified.

L R R R R R R R R L L L L L L L

L L L

L L

L

R

R

R R R R R RR R

23

45

6

Lib

era

lizatio

n

1970 1980 1990 2000 2010Years

Australia

L L L L L R L L L L

R R

R

R R R R R R L

L

L L L

L L L

L L L L L

12

34

5

Lib

era

lizatio

n

1970 1980 1990 2000 2010Years

Canada

L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L NCNCR R

R

R RR L

L

L

L L

L

L

L

02

46

Lib

era

lizatio

n

1970 1980 1990 2000 2010Years

Czech Republic

R L L L L L L L R R R R R R

R R R R

R

L

LL L

L

L

LL

R RR

R R

02

46

Lib

era

lizatio

n

1970 1980 1990 2000 2010Years

Denmark

R R NCNCR R R L L L L

L R R

L L L L

L R R R R

LL

L L

L

R R

R R

01

23

45

Lib

era

lizatio

n

1970 1980 1990 2000 2010Years

France

NCNCNCNCNCNCR R R R R R L L L L R R

R L L L L L L L

L

L L L

R

R

01

23

4

Lib

era

lizatio

n

1970 1980 1990 2000 2010Years

Greece

Page 13: Jerusalem Papers in Regulation & Governanceregulation.huji.ac.il/papers/jp13.pdf · This research is part of the REFGOV project. 2 ISSN: 2079-5882 Political Determinants of Liberalizations;

12 ISSN: 2079-5882

L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L R R

R

R L L L L LL

L

L

L

L L L

01

23

4

Lib

era

lizatio

n

1970 1980 1990 2000 2010Years

Hungary

NCNCNCNCNCNCNCNCNCL L L L NCNCNCNCNC

L R

R LL L

L

L

L

R R

RR R

01

23

45

Lib

era

lizatio

n

1970 1980 1990 2000 2010Years

Italy

L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L

L

L

L L L

R R R RR R

0.5

11

.52

2.5

Lib

era

lizatio

n

1970 1980 1990 2000 2010Years

Mexico

L L L R R R R R R R R R R R R R R

R

R

R L

L

L L

L

L L L L R R R1

23

45

Lib

era

lizatio

n

1970 1980 1990 2000 2010Years

Netherlands

L L L L L L L R R R R R

L L L

R

L L

L L

L L L

R

R R R

R R R R L

01

23

4

Lib

era

lizatio

n

1970 1980 1990 2000 2010Years

Norway

L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L NCNCNCNCNC

L L

L

L

L

L

L

L

L

L R

01

23

45

Lib

era

lizatio

n

1970 1980 1990 2000 2010Years

Poland

Page 14: Jerusalem Papers in Regulation & Governanceregulation.huji.ac.il/papers/jp13.pdf · This research is part of the REFGOV project. 2 ISSN: 2079-5882 Political Determinants of Liberalizations;

13 ISSN: 2079-5882

L L NCNCNCNCNCNCR L LR R R R R R R

R R

R

L L L L

L

L

L R R

R L

01

23

4

Lib

era

lizatio

n

1970 1980 1990 2000 2010Years

Portugal

L L NCNCL NCNCNCL L L L L L L L

L R

R

R

L

L L L

L L L L LL L L

12

34

56

Lib

era

lizatio

n

1970 1980 1990 2000 2010Years

Sweden

L NCNCNCL NCNCNCNCR R R R R R

R R R R R R R R

R R

L

L

L NCNCNCNC

01

23

4

Lib

era

lizatio

n

1970 1980 1990 2000 2010Years

Turkey

R R L L L

L R R RR

R R R R R R RR L L

L L L

LL L R R R R R R

22

.53

3.5

44

.5

Lib

era

lizatio

n

1970 1980 1990 2000 2010Years

USA

According to Figure 3, the historical evidence of liberalization policies adopted in seven

network industries (communications, electricity, air transport, gas, post, rail and road)

over the last two decades under left-wing governments – as in Australia, Canada, Czech

Republic, Denmark, France, Greece, Hungary, Italy, Mexico, the Netherlands, Norway,

Poland, Portugal, Sweden and even the USA – shows relevant exceptions to the

empirical findings supporting the view that the right wing favors liberalization and the

left wing is against it.

We point out that the stylized facts shown in the above figures are hard to reconcile

with earlier empirical findings unambiguously attributing a significantly greater impact

of right-wing governments upon liberalization than of left-wing ones, at least with

reference to the most updated OECD sample we have reported and employed in our

analysis (OECD, 2009).

Page 15: Jerusalem Papers in Regulation & Governanceregulation.huji.ac.il/papers/jp13.pdf · This research is part of the REFGOV project. 2 ISSN: 2079-5882 Political Determinants of Liberalizations;

14 ISSN: 2079-5882

To contribute to solving the above empirical puzzle, we investigate the following

hypothesis:

Left-wing governments have been as active as right-wing ones in adopting

liberalization of network industries.

In doing so, we also explore whether homogeneous coalitions and majoritarian systems

induce a higher level of liberalization of network industries than do heterogeneous

coalitions and proportional electoral systems.

4. Data and empirical strategy

4.1 Data and variables

In order to perform the empirical analysis we collect a well-suited data set in which we

link information on countries‟ liberalization outcomes to various characteristics of

national governments. We use data from various sources over the 1975-2006 period.

The base sample we use is the largest possible given the data availability (30

countries);1 moreover, our sample period covers entirely the liberalization wave

observed in Western countries in the last three decades through 2006, whereas previous

analyses focused on a smaller number of countries and on a shorter period coverage.

To construct an index of economic liberalization (which we call Liberalization in our

empirical analysis) we use the entry barriers index measured by the Indicators of

Regulation in Energy, Transport and Communications – ETCR – (OECD, 2009) and

1 Australia, Austria, Belgium, Canada, Czech Republic, Denmark, Finland, France, Germany, Greece,

Hungary, Iceland, Ireland, Italy, Japan, Luxembourg, Mexico, Netherlands, New Zealand, Norway,

Poland, Portugal, Slovakia, South Korea, Spain, Sweden, Switzerland, Turkey, United Kingdom, United

States.

Page 16: Jerusalem Papers in Regulation & Governanceregulation.huji.ac.il/papers/jp13.pdf · This research is part of the REFGOV project. 2 ISSN: 2079-5882 Political Determinants of Liberalizations;

15 ISSN: 2079-5882

calculate the variable Liberalization by subtracting the OECD (2009) entry barriers

measure from its maximum value. The OECD (2009) entry barriers index is calculated

by OECD as the simple average of seven sectoral indicators that, in turn, measure the

strictness of the legal conditions of entry in the following non-manufacturing sectors:

passenger air transport, telecommunications, electricity, gas, post, rail and road. Our

final Liberalization index ranges from 0 to 6.2

To identify the government party‟s political orientation with respect to economic policy,

we use information from the Database of Political Institutions (World Bank, 2008),

which has been routinely used in cross-country quantitative studies (see, among others,

Dutt and Mitra (2005), Krause and Méndez (2005), and Giuliano and Scalise (2009)).

We construct three dummy variables – Left, Right and Other – which respectively equal

1 if: the government party is defined as socialist, social-democratic, communist or left-

wing (Left); it is defined as conservative, Christian democratic or right-wing (Right); or

it is defined as centrist or does not fit into the two previously mentioned categories

(Other).3

The relation between the executive‟s orientation and economic liberalization outcomes

may be dependent also on a government's other characteristics, the omission of which

might cause estimation bias. For example, as suggested by Bortolotti and Pinotti (2008),

the effective lawmaking power of the government is (possibly) relevant to the

executive‟s capacity to implement economic policies, so that a low legislative power

may affect the executive‟s initiatives regardless of its political orientation. We cope

with this problem by including a set of legislature-specific variables in the econometric

analysis.

In particular, we consider the following variables.

2 For a comprehensive description of the ETCR indicators see Conway and Nicoletti (2006).

3 A detailed description of the main variables that we use is provided in the Appendix.

Page 17: Jerusalem Papers in Regulation & Governanceregulation.huji.ac.il/papers/jp13.pdf · This research is part of the REFGOV project. 2 ISSN: 2079-5882 Political Determinants of Liberalizations;

16 ISSN: 2079-5882

GovHeterogeneity: this variable is defined as the probability that two deputies picked at

random from among the government parties will be of different parties (source: World

Bank, 2008);

Majority: this measures the margin of majority, that is the fraction of seats held by the

government, calculated by dividing the number of government seats by total seats

(source: World Bank, 2008);

AllHouse: this is a dummy variable that equals 1 when the party of the executive has an

absolute majority in the houses that have lawmaking powers (source: World Bank,

2008);

YearsInOffice: this is defined as the number of years the chief executive has been in

office (source: World Bank, 2008);

YearsLeft: this is the number of years left in the current term (source: World Bank,

2008);

Proportional: this is a dummy variable equal to 1 if representatives are elected based on

the percentage of votes received by their party and/or the electoral system is specifically

called „proportional representation‟ (source: World Bank, 2008).

Several authors highlight that a government‟s economic policies do not depend only on

the executive‟s political motivation and lawmaking power but are shaped also by the

country‟s economic characteristics. We control for this possibility and consider a set of

further covariates.

First, we use government debt as a percentage of GDP (GovDebt) in order to control for

the central government's financial situation. This variable measures the entire stock of

direct government fixed-term contractual obligations to others, outstanding on a

particular date. It includes domestic and foreign liabilities such as currency and money

deposits, securities other than shares, and loans; it is the gross amount of government

liabilities reduced by the amount of equity and financial derivatives held by the

government (source: World Development Indicators, World Bank, 2009).

Page 18: Jerusalem Papers in Regulation & Governanceregulation.huji.ac.il/papers/jp13.pdf · This research is part of the REFGOV project. 2 ISSN: 2079-5882 Political Determinants of Liberalizations;

17 ISSN: 2079-5882

Second, the country‟s general economic situation as measured by the gross domestic

product may be important as well. Thus we include GDP converted to 2005

international dollars using purchasing power parity rates (Gdp), and its per capita value

(GdpPerCap). Both these variables are obtained from World Bank (2009).

Third, labor market conditions are another factor potentially relevant to economic

liberalization. For instance, Blanchard and Giavazzi (2003) point out that product and

labor market regulation are likely to be linked. Accordingly, we consider an indicator of

the degree of employment protection (EmplProtection), obtained from OECD (2008),

the employment in industry as a percentage of total employment (Employment),

obtained from World Bank (2009). EmplProtection is calculated as an unweighted

average of 12 sub-indicators for regular contracts and six sub-indicators for temporary

contracts; this variable is a synthetic index of the strictness of the country‟s employment

protection legislation.

Fourth, we include a dummy variable that records whether a given country has a civil

law legal system – CivilLaw – (source: La Porta et al., 1998). Pitlik (2007) finds

evidence that „legal families‟ play a role in affecting market-oriented policies.

Finally, we also include two dummy variables that record, respectively, the country‟s

membership of the European Union (EUMember) and adoption of the euro (Euro) to

test whether policy diffusion plays a role in affecting parties in office, irrespective of

their political ideology, as a supranational driver of national governments‟ initiatives

(Levi-Faur, 2003; Simmons and Elkins, 2004; Comin and Diaz Fuentes, 2006; Høj,

Galasso, Nicoletti and Dang, 2006; Pitlik, 2007).

TABLE 1. Descriptive statistics (left-wing and right-wing governments).

Right Left

Page 19: Jerusalem Papers in Regulation & Governanceregulation.huji.ac.il/papers/jp13.pdf · This research is part of the REFGOV project. 2 ISSN: 2079-5882 Political Determinants of Liberalizations;

18 ISSN: 2079-5882

Variable Obs. Mean Obs. Mean Source

Liberalization

359 1.889 336 2.042 Authors‟ elaboration on OECD

(2009) data World Bank (2008)

Majority 294 0.614 301 0.668 World Bank (2008)

AllHouse 358 0.276 331 0.280 World Bank (2008)

YearsInOffice 359 3.988 335 3.814 World Bank (2008)

YearsLeft 359 1.682 334 1.652 World Bank (2008)

GovHeterogeneity 354 0.288 326 0.194 World Bank (2008)

GovDebt 101 56.638 113 59.564 World Bank (2008)

EmplProtection 246 2.166 236 2.233 OECD (2008)

Employment 287 28.608 247 28.308 World Bank (2009)

Gdp 320 1.22e+12 284 8.78e+11 World Bank (2009)

GdpPerCap 320 23281.64 284 23242.69 World Bank (2009)

EUMember 359 0.200 336 0.300 Authors‟ coding

Euro 359 0.075 336 0.026 Authors‟ coding

Proportional 358 0.793 332 0.789 World Bank (2008)

CivilLaw 359 0.239 336 0.214 La Porta et al. (1998)

Note: we have dropped from the sample the Czech Republic‟s and Hungary‟s observations

referring to the years of communist dictatorship, while Slovakia‟s observations refer to the

period after it was declared a sovereign state; Switzerland is removed from the final sample

because of missing data on the main political characteristics of the government.

Generally, as policy initiatives take time to generate an observable economic (or legal)

outcome, we regress our liberalization variable on one-year-lagged covariates. So, on

the one hand, we avoid attributing an economic outcome, resulting perhaps from a

Page 20: Jerusalem Papers in Regulation & Governanceregulation.huji.ac.il/papers/jp13.pdf · This research is part of the REFGOV project. 2 ISSN: 2079-5882 Political Determinants of Liberalizations;

19 ISSN: 2079-5882

laborious political process, to an executive just elected; on the other hand, we do not

incur endogeneity or reverse causality problems due to the simultaneous determination

of liberalization and certain types of labor market institutions (as measured by

EmplProtection) and/or the general economic conditions of countries (measured, for

instance, by Gdp).

In our final dataset, the countries with the highest liberalization score at the end of the

period considered are Denmark (5.7), Germany (5.6) and Sweden (5.5), while those

with the lowest are Mexico (2.4), South Korea (3.1) and Turkey (3.6). The countries

that saw left-oriented governments most often between 1975 and 2006 are Austria,

Canada, Mexico and Sweden; conversely, Belgium, Japan and South Korea show the

highest number of right-oriented governments in the period under consideration. On

average, the government heterogeneity index is about 0.25 and the margin of majority

of governments is about 0.64 (both these indexes range from 0 to 1).

A synthetic description of all the variables is provided in Table 1.

4.2 Empirical strategy

Even if we include in our analysis all the variables which we deem potentially relevant

to economic liberalization, it may be argued that unobservable or unmeasurable factors,

such as national culture or traditions, also affect the economic policies of governments

(La Porta et al., 1999; Guiso, Sapienza and Zingales, 2006). Furthermore, time

tendencies may shape countries‟ liberalization patterns regardless of the political beliefs

of individual governments (e.g., the „globalization wave‟).

To cater for this, we undertake a panel analysis in which we include country- and time-

fixed effects. Time-fixed effects, in particular, capture the time pattern that is constant

across countries. Having done so, what we finally obtain is an estimate of the marginal

effect of country-specific and legislature-specific variables on the variations of

liberalization outcomes across countries and years, also controlling for time tendencies.

Page 21: Jerusalem Papers in Regulation & Governanceregulation.huji.ac.il/papers/jp13.pdf · This research is part of the REFGOV project. 2 ISSN: 2079-5882 Political Determinants of Liberalizations;

20 ISSN: 2079-5882

Formally, we focus on the following population regression function:

scsctionLiberalizat tt βxxE 0,, (1)

where x = 1xt1 +…+ KxtK, and xtj indicates variable j at time t, and where the omitted

variable country-specific c is time-constant, while the omitted variable time-specific s is

constant across countries. In model (1) it is assumed that c has the same effect on the

mean response in each time period and that s has the same effect on the mean response

in each country.

In our context, the basic unobserved effects model (UEM) can be written as:

Liberalization it= βxit+ci+st +uit , t = 1975, 1976, …, 2006 (2)

where xit is a 1 K vector, ci and st are unobserved components which account for the

unobserved heterogeneity, and uit are idiosyncratic disturbances that change across t and

across i.

In a fixed-effects estimation, ci and st are allowed to be correlated with xit, so that the

assumption of zero correlation between the observed explanatory variables and the

unobserved effects is not imposed. By doing so, we obtain results that are more robust

than those obtained through a random effects analysis. However, as Wooldridge (2002)

points out, this robustness comes at a price; specifically, we cannot include factors

Page 22: Jerusalem Papers in Regulation & Governanceregulation.huji.ac.il/papers/jp13.pdf · This research is part of the REFGOV project. 2 ISSN: 2079-5882 Political Determinants of Liberalizations;

21 ISSN: 2079-5882

constant across countries and periods in xit. In our estimation, we respect this

restriction.4

Finally, we calculate one-period-lagged values of the explanatory variables and include

them in the operative model. Hence, making the response variable and the government‟s

political orientation explicit, we can write model (2) in the following lag UEM form:

ittiititit uscRight-wingβLeft-wingβtionLiberaliza -1it-1itλω δκ 12110 (3)

with t = 1975, 1976, …, 2006, and where κit-1 is a vector that contains the legislature-

specific variables, ωit-1 is a vector of controls referring to the country‟s economic

characteristics, δ and λ are vectors of parameters, 0 is the model constant, ci and st are

unobserved components which account respectively for the unobserved country-specific

(constant over time) and time-specific (constant across countries) heterogeneity, and uit

are idiosyncratic disturbances that change across t and i.

Notice that Otherit-1 is the benchmark class for the government‟s political orientation

dummies.

As a robustness check, we perform two model specifications in which we consider also

the one-year lagged deregulation level (observed in each country) and a linear time

trend explicitly included as one of the covariates.

When we include the one-year-lagged deregulation level, model (3) becomes:

4 Note that in one model specification, we include a country‟s legal family variable (CivilLaw) that is time

constant. In order to perform this individual regression, we use a random effects model.

Page 23: Jerusalem Papers in Regulation & Governanceregulation.huji.ac.il/papers/jp13.pdf · This research is part of the REFGOV project. 2 ISSN: 2079-5882 Political Determinants of Liberalizations;

22 ISSN: 2079-5882

1312110 itititit onDeregulatiβRight-wingβLeft-wingβtionLiberaliza

itti usc -1it-1itλω δκ (3′)

The deregulation level is measured using an indicator obtained by subtracting the

OECD (2009) ETCR index to its maximum value. The OECD (2009) ETCR index is

calculated by OECD as the simple average of seven sectoral indicators that, in turn,

measure the strictness of the legal conditions of entry, the level of public ownership, the

characteristics of vertical integration and the market structure in the above mentioned

non-manufacturing sectors. Including the one-year-lagged deregulation level allows us

to estimate the autoregressive component of liberalization policies. By doing so, we can

observe the effect of governments’ political orientation independently of the existing

regulatory conditions which executives find when elected.

When we include the time trend, model (3) can be written as:

itititit TrendβRight-wingβLeft-wingβtionLiberaliza312110

itti usc -1it-1itλω δκ (3′′)

Including a time trend allows us to estimate the effect, if any, of time factors

(independent of country-specific variables) influencing the average pattern of

deregulation in OECD countries. As will be shown in the next section, estimation

results remain substantially similar across different model specifications.

Page 24: Jerusalem Papers in Regulation & Governanceregulation.huji.ac.il/papers/jp13.pdf · This research is part of the REFGOV project. 2 ISSN: 2079-5882 Political Determinants of Liberalizations;

23 ISSN: 2079-5882

5. Results

The estimation results are presented in Table 2. We have considered 15 panel model

specifications, which are constructed in such a way that multicollinearity problems are

avoided. Notice that the model specifications from (1) to (15) show an increasing

explicative power, as we progressively add control variables. In the last specification –

(15) – the R-square indicates that the proportion of variability in liberalization outcomes

that is accounted for by the statistical model is almost 80%.

In all the model specifications in which the governments‟ political orientation dummies

are included, we find that left-oriented governments have a positive and statistically

significant effect on the observed level of economic liberalization. Conversely, right-

oriented governments do not show statistically significant effects in most of the model

specifications, while they show a positive and statistically significant effect in models

(11), (13), (14) and (15). Notice, moreover, that the estimated effect of right-wing

governments on liberalization always shows a lower intensity and a lower statistical

significance than those of left-wing governments.

It is worth emphasizing that we estimate the effect of left-wing and right-wing political

ideology with respect to centrist or non-classifiable governments (as they are defined in

the Appendix); thus, what we are able to infer is the effect of a given political

orientation relative to another and not the absolute effect. It follows that our result must

be interpreted as a sign of an influence of left-oriented governments on liberalization

which is greater than that of right-oriented governments, while our estimation result

does not indicate that right-wing executives do not liberalize in absolute terms.

With respect to the institutional determinants of liberalization in network industries, we

obtain several interesting results. First, we find that the government‟s heterogeneity

(GovHeterogeneity), which is a proxy of the political fragmentation of the government,

has a positive influence on liberalization. Second, model specifications (3), (7), (8), (10)

and (11) show that the margin of majority of the government‟s parties (Majority) has a

negative effect on the level of economic liberalization, which is consistent with the

Page 25: Jerusalem Papers in Regulation & Governanceregulation.huji.ac.il/papers/jp13.pdf · This research is part of the REFGOV project. 2 ISSN: 2079-5882 Political Determinants of Liberalizations;

24 ISSN: 2079-5882

previous result. Third, in model specifications (7) and (8) we also find a positive effect

of proportional representation systems (Proportional).5 The variables AllHouse,

YearsInOffice and YearsLeft, on the other hand, do not turn out to be statistically

significant.

When we move to consider pre-existing country economic conditions, we obtain further

interesting results. Model specifications (12), (13), (14) and (15), indeed, show that the

strictness of the employment protection legislation (EmplProtection) is a negative and

statistically significant influence on economic liberalization, and so too is the relative

amount of employment in industry (Employment), as shown in model (15).

Supranational drivers of liberalization initiatives may be important as well. In particular,

model specifications (13), (14) and (15) show that EU membership (EUMember) plays

a positive and statistically significant role in the reduction of entry barriers. A positive

and statistically significant effect is also found for the introduction of the euro (as has

already been suggested by Høj, Galasso, Nicoletti, and Dang (2006)), as is shown by

model specification (12). Estimated coefficients suggest, in particular, that the effect of

EU membership is greater than that of adoption of the euro.

Finally, models (12) and (15) reveal that the country‟s GDP (Gdp) has a negative effect,

while models (12), (13) and (15) show that the GDP per capita (GdpPerCap) has a

positive one. According to model specification (11), the legal family (CivilLaw) seems

to be statistically irrelevant.

As a robustness check, in model specifications (14) and (15), we have added to country-

and time-fixed effects respectively the one-year-lagged value of deregulation and a

linear time trend, in order to estimate the (possibly) relevant effect of time patterns that

5 Unreported estimations show that in the sub-group of countries that adopt proportional representation

systems, the effect of the government‟s colour has a lower intensity than elsewhere. It is also worth

noting that the representation system that countries adopt is not correlated in a statistically significant way

with the probability of having a left-wing or a right-wing government.

Page 26: Jerusalem Papers in Regulation & Governanceregulation.huji.ac.il/papers/jp13.pdf · This research is part of the REFGOV project. 2 ISSN: 2079-5882 Political Determinants of Liberalizations;

25 ISSN: 2079-5882

are virtually constant across countries. While the estimated parameters relating to both

these additional factors turn out to be positive and statistically significant, our main

results do not change and are shown to be robust across the different specifications.

Specifically, the positive effect exerted by the one-year-lagged value of deregulation

indicates that liberalization policies follow a path in which past initiatives stimulate

subsequent interventions, in a progressive process characterized by a ratchet effect. This

confirms a strong path-dependency effect of liberalization policy in network industries.

The diagnostic analysis, furthermore, allows us to reject the null hypothesis of joint

statistical insignificance of all the parameters, in all the considered model specifications.

Consistently, our findings show that partisanship and political institutions have a

significant, predictable impact on the intensity of liberalization policy in network

industries, with left-wing parties choosing higher levels of liberalization compared to

right-wing parties.6

Our main findings contrast with some statistical results in extant empirical literature

(e.g., Pitlik, 2007; Potrafke, 2009). While we find that left-wing governments have a

positive impact on liberalization in network industries and that the effect of right-wing

governments is lower in terms of both estimated intensity and statistical significance,

previous investigations, considering a shorter period and a smaller sample, show the

opposite7.

6 Notice that unreported GLM estimations, in which we add alternatively time and country dummies,

show substantially similar final results. These estimations are available upon request. show substantially

similar final results. These estimations are available upon request.

7 We believe that such a difference is mainly due to two elements.On the one hand, we use different

variables in order to account for the effect of governments‟ political ideology. For instance, the two

indices used by Potrafke (2010) are compact variables which oppose left with right and which weight the

ideology scores with the government party‟s relative share of seats in parliament; similarly, Pitlik (2007)

measures political orientation of governments by means of a five-year averaged index of left-wing party

cabinet positions over total cabinet seats. The World Bank (2008) index that we use, in contrast, is

composed of a set of three dummies that allow us to study separately the effect of right-wing and left-

wing governments with respect to that of non-classifiable governments, which are considered as the

reference group. Moreover, we do not weight the index for the relative lawmaking power of the

executive‟s leading party, while we include various measures of lawmaking power of governments as

separate covariates. On the other hand, we consider a longer period than that examined by previous

literature along with a larger set of factors. Our estimation results partially converge with those of Pitlik

Page 27: Jerusalem Papers in Regulation & Governanceregulation.huji.ac.il/papers/jp13.pdf · This research is part of the REFGOV project. 2 ISSN: 2079-5882 Political Determinants of Liberalizations;

26 ISSN: 2079-5882

(2007) and Potrafke (2010) when we restrict our analysis to the 1975-1999 period, as unreported

estimations show.

Page 28: Jerusalem Papers in Regulation & Governanceregulation.huji.ac.il/papers/jp13.pdf · This research is part of the REFGOV project. 2 ISSN: 2079-5882 Political Determinants of Liberalizations;

27

TABLE 2. Cross-country panel estimation results. Dependent variable: Liberalization.

(1)

PANEL

(2)

PANEL

(3)

PANEL

(4)

PANEL

(5)

PANEL

(6)

PANEL

(7)

PANEL

Variable Coef. (Std.Err.) Coef. (Std.Err.) Coef. (Std.Err.) Coef. (Std.Err.) Coef. (Std.Err.) Coef. (Std.Err.) Coef. (Std.Err.)

Left 0.430 (0.197) ** 0.473 (0.204) ** 0.545 (0.225) ** 0.432 (0.200) ** 0.415 (0.198) **

Right 0.240 (0.193) 0.161 (0.198) 0.342 (0.221) 0.242 (0.197) 0.212 (0.195)

GovHeterogeneity 0.903 (0.354) ** 0.689 (0.344) **

Majority -2.419 (0.381) *** -2.513 (0.383) ***

AllHouse -0.292 (0.187)

YearsInOffice 0.025 (0.020)

Proportional 2.913 (0.539) ***

YearsLeft

Page 29: Jerusalem Papers in Regulation & Governanceregulation.huji.ac.il/papers/jp13.pdf · This research is part of the REFGOV project. 2 ISSN: 2079-5882 Political Determinants of Liberalizations;

28

GovDebt

Employment

EmplProtection

Gdp

GdpPerCap

Euro

EUMember

CivilLaw

Deregulation

Trend

Constant 1.648 (0.163) *** 1.466 (0.195) *** 3.240 (0.305) *** 1.729 (0.169) *** 1.565 (0.176) *** 1.785 (0.103) *** 1.352 (0.503) ***

Time and country FE Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

Time and country RE No No No No No No No

Number of obs. 805 782 681 795 802 782 666

Page 30: Jerusalem Papers in Regulation & Governanceregulation.huji.ac.il/papers/jp13.pdf · This research is part of the REFGOV project. 2 ISSN: 2079-5882 Political Determinants of Liberalizations;

29

F-Statistics 7.02 6.68 7.54 6.22 6.77 7.05 8.76

H0: bi=bj=0 (p-v.) 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000

R-sq. 0.014 0.016 0.078 0.027 0.021 0.002 0.001

Note: * = 0.10 confidence level, ** = 0.05 confidence level, *** = 0.01 confidence level.

TABLE 2. (Continued)

(8)

PANEL

(9)

PANEL

(10)

PANEL

(11)

PANEL

(12)

PANEL

(13)

PANEL

(14)

PANEL

(15)

PANEL

Variable Coef. (Std.Err.) Coef. (Std.Err.) Coef. (Std.Err.) Coef. (Std.Err.) Coef. (Std.Err.) Coef. (Std.Err.) Coef. (Std.Err.) Coef. (Std.Err.)

Left 0.488 (0.233) ** 0.464 (0.206) ** 0.515 (0.234) ** 0.574 (0.224) *** 0.432 (0.161) *** 0.586 (0.273) * 0.446 (0.215) ** 0.224 (0.096) **

Right 0.251 (0.230) 0.167 (0.202) 0.313 (0.230) 0.368 (0.221) * 0.226 (0.159) 0.526 (0.277) * 0.408 (0.218) * 0.180 (0.095) *

GovHeterogeneity 0.845 (0.368) ** -0.100 (0.141)

Majority -2.597 (0.384) *** -2.349 (0.391) *** -2.311 (0.379) ***

AllHouse -0.160 (0.199) -0.214 (0.196) -0.239 (0.185) 0.042 (0.073)

Page 31: Jerusalem Papers in Regulation & Governanceregulation.huji.ac.il/papers/jp13.pdf · This research is part of the REFGOV project. 2 ISSN: 2079-5882 Political Determinants of Liberalizations;

30

YearsInOffice 0.020 (0.021) 0.038 (0.024) 0.042 (0.023) * -0.008 (0.008)

Proportional 2.888 (0.537) ***

YearsLeft -0.010 (0.043) 0.013 (0.046) 0.010 (0.045) -0.019 (0.016)

GovDebt 0.007 (0.006) 0.007 (0.004)

Employment 0.058 (0.035) -0.057 (0.014) ***

EmplProtection -1.259 (0.119) *** -1.056 (0.186) *** -0.757 (0.148) *** -0.326 (0.078) ***

Gdp -0.001 (0.000) ** 0.001 (0.001) -0.001 (0.000) ** -0.001 (0.001)

GdpPerCap 0.001 (0.000) *** 0.001 (0.000) *** -0.000 (0.000) 0.001 (0.000) ***

Euro 0.422 (0.149) ***

EUMember 1.584 (0.237) *** 1.165 (0.183) *** 0.347 (0.074) ***

CivilLaw -0.064 (0.428)

Deregulation 0.967 (0.041) ***

Trend 0.259 (0.026) ***

Constant 1.109 (0.535) *** 1.461 (0.239) *** 3.118 (0.348) *** 3.190 (0.385) *** -1.278 (0.444) *** -4.562 (1.005) *** -3.852 (1.275) *** 1.834 (0.514) ***

Page 32: Jerusalem Papers in Regulation & Governanceregulation.huji.ac.il/papers/jp13.pdf · This research is part of the REFGOV project. 2 ISSN: 2079-5882 Political Determinants of Liberalizations;

31

Time and country FE Yes Yes Yes No Yes Yes Yes Yes

Time and country RE No No No Yes No No No No

Number of obs. 782 681 795 672 538 204 193 465

F-Statistics 8.42 6.14 6.57 -- 31.87 18.93 12.54 19.73

H0: bi=bj=0 (p-v.) 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000

R-sq. 0.001 0.023 0.088 0.091 0.416 0.415 0.241 0.793

Note: * = 0.10 confidence level, ** = 0.05 confidence level, *** = 0.01 confidence level

Page 33: Jerusalem Papers in Regulation & Governanceregulation.huji.ac.il/papers/jp13.pdf · This research is part of the REFGOV project. 2 ISSN: 2079-5882 Political Determinants of Liberalizations;

© Filippo Belloc & Antonio Nicita

6. Discussion

Our analysis confirms that politics matter for liberalization of network industries

(Duso, 2002; Høj, Galasso, Nicoletti, and Dang, 2006; Pitlik, 2007; Potrafke, 2010).

The conclusion we reach - that right-wing governments on average liberalize less than

left-wing ones - while reversing related literature, is rather general, being found in all

the specifications analyzed and taking into account the existing regulatory conditions

that executives are faced with when elected. This means that our results are fairly

robust and are not affected by initial local conditions, in one sense or another.

Figure 4 outlines the estimated liberalization trends of left-wing governments for each

of the model specifications reported in Table 2, in which political orientation

dummies are included. Trends are calculated considering the estimated effect of

having a left-wing government rather than another one, starting from an initial

situation of null liberalization, and considering this effect, for each time interval, with

respect to the previous level of liberalization. As we can see, all the model

specifications confirm a significant growing trend in left-wing liberalizations. The one

referring to the last specification (15), which includes the largest set of control

variables, shows a similar but flatter trend. Figure 4 also outlines the strong path-

dependency effect we actually found for every political color in office. The level of

past deregulation turns out to be particularly relevant, suggesting that liberalization

processes follow a progressive path with a ratchet effect, both for the aggregate

indicators and for sectoral ones.

Moreover, as the estimated positive effect of the autoregressive component suggests,

rather than observing strong discontinuity and shocks, we registered a gradual

implementation of liberalization policies. This implies that once a liberalization

process is launched, its intensity may depend on the political color of the party in

office, but it is never retracted.

Page 34: Jerusalem Papers in Regulation & Governanceregulation.huji.ac.il/papers/jp13.pdf · This research is part of the REFGOV project. 2 ISSN: 2079-5882 Political Determinants of Liberalizations;

Jerusalem Papers in Regulation & Governance

© Filippo Belloc & Antonio Nicita

Work

ing P

aper

No.

13 |

June 2

010

Figure 4

Estimated liberalization trends of left-wing governments (coefficients derived from

Table 2).

Model (15)

Models (1), (2), (3),

(4), (5), (8), (9), (10),

(11), (12), (13), (14)

0

1

2

3

4

5

6

1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005

Surprisingly, we did not find a statistically significant effect of legal origins on

network industry liberalization, contrary to what might be expected according to the

general insights of La Porta et al. (1999) and Pitlik‟s (2007) findings for liberalization

policies. We cannot however exclude that this could be due to the strong role played

by the country-specific variables that we considered in our analysis, which are

partially correlated with the legal origin of nations. Some legal scholars, in addition,

have recently cast doubts on the assumption that legal origins are the foundation of

legal institutions and economic outcomes (see, for example, Roe, 2006).

As to political determinants, our findings contrast with the empirical literature

available so far (Pitlik, 2007; Potrafke, 2010), probably due, as we argued, to the

broader dimensions of the sample we study - both in terms of OECD countries

included and number of years covered – and to the different indicator we adopted for

governments‟ political color, with respect to previous analyses.

The „political economy of economic policies‟ so far has simply neglected the left-

wing issue, falling into line with conventional wisdom, confirmed by the empirical

literature, on significantly greater right-wing adoption of other market-oriented

policies, such as privatization. However, the liberalization paths we observed in

Page 35: Jerusalem Papers in Regulation & Governanceregulation.huji.ac.il/papers/jp13.pdf · This research is part of the REFGOV project. 2 ISSN: 2079-5882 Political Determinants of Liberalizations;

Jerusalem Papers in Regulation & Governance

© Filippo Belloc & Antonio Nicita

Work

ing P

aper

No.

13 |

June 2

010

network industries force economic theory to give a reason for the political-economic

rationale behind them.

We do not attempt here to solve this puzzle, rather we simply raise insights and

questions for further research on the issue.

7. Conclusions

According to conventional wisdom, right-wing parties should, in principle, promote

market-oriented outcomes, as this is embedded in their traditional ideological

adherences. This prediction has been confirmed by many empirical findings with

reference to privatization policies. Some recent empirical findings seem to confirm

these results also for liberalization policies in network industries, arguing that the

likelihood of liberalization increases under majoritarian rules and right-wing

governments.

Firstly, looking at some stylized facts we have argued that these results contrast with

single-nation case studies, such as Austria, Canada, France, Italy, Mexico and Sweden

among others, where left-wing governments have significantly introduced

liberalization in network industries.

Then we have investigated, through an econometric analysis, whether right-wing

governments have been more active in adopting liberalization of network industries

than left-wing ones, and whether homogeneous coalitions and majoritarian systems

have induced a higher level of liberalization of network industries than heterogeneous

coalitions and proportional electoral systems have done. Our sample included the

largest and most updated data set available on 30 OECD countries, provided by the

latest releases of ETCR economic indicators for the liberalization of seven network

industries (OECD, 2009) and by political indicators of the World Bank‟s Database of

Political Institutions (World Bank, 2009). This allows us to study a larger group of

countries with respect to previous empirical studies and to perform the first

econometric analysis that considers the entire liberalization wave observed in OECD

Page 36: Jerusalem Papers in Regulation & Governanceregulation.huji.ac.il/papers/jp13.pdf · This research is part of the REFGOV project. 2 ISSN: 2079-5882 Political Determinants of Liberalizations;

Jerusalem Papers in Regulation & Governance

© Filippo Belloc & Antonio Nicita

Work

ing P

aper

No.

13 |

June 2

010

countries from the Seventies to date. By so doing, we show that a study of the

liberalization wave in its entirety reverses the findings reached so far by empirical

literature on liberalization of network industries.

Contrary to traditional ideological cleavages, we find that right-wing governments

liberalize less than left-wing ones. This result is confirmed when controlling for the

existing regulatory conditions that executives find once elected.

In particular, in all the model specifications in which we have included the

executive‟s political orientation dummies, we have found that left-oriented

governments had a positive and statistically significant effect on the observed level of

economic liberalization, while right-oriented governments did not show statistically

significant effects or showed a smaller one. We have found also that EU membership

and adoption of the euro strongly encouraged liberalization policies.

We believe our findings are relevant in two main respects.

First, they question the conventional wisdom predicting that all market-oriented

policies – including liberalization and privatization in network industries – are almost

exclusively adopted by right-wing governments, as the consequence of traditional

ideological cleavages for governments‟ policy choices. We show not only that left-

wing governments do liberalize network industries, but that they progressively even

increased the intensity of liberalization over time, in almost all the seven sectors

studied. On the contrary, right-wing liberalization registered a smooth, but significant,

decline. This conclusion implies that, for some reasons to be further investigated,

liberalization of network industries differs from other market-oriented policies in

terms of its political appeal and rationale. Thus, one first consequence of our

investigation is that the measurement of political determinants of market-oriented

policies in network industries should disentangle liberalization and other deregulation

policies.

Secondly, our results raise a new puzzle with more general implications for the

theoretical analysis of the political-economic meaning and extent of liberalization

policy in network industries: why do left-wing parties in office liberalize, and why do

Page 37: Jerusalem Papers in Regulation & Governanceregulation.huji.ac.il/papers/jp13.pdf · This research is part of the REFGOV project. 2 ISSN: 2079-5882 Political Determinants of Liberalizations;

Jerusalem Papers in Regulation & Governance

© Filippo Belloc & Antonio Nicita

Work

ing P

aper

No.

13 |

June 2

010

they seem to liberalize, on average, to a greater extent than right-wing governments

do?

Our results contrast with the superficially self-evident thesis that right-wing

governments should always maintain the same aligned incentives towards

privatization and liberalization. Left-wing governments have been at least as active as

right-wing ones in adopting liberalization of network industries. Our empirical results

confirm that, contrary to conventional wisdom, the political-economic rationale

behind liberalization paths in network industries is far from being assessed and a

comprehensive theoretical framework on the political determinants of liberalization

policies is still needed.

Page 38: Jerusalem Papers in Regulation & Governanceregulation.huji.ac.il/papers/jp13.pdf · This research is part of the REFGOV project. 2 ISSN: 2079-5882 Political Determinants of Liberalizations;

Jerusalem Papers in Regulation & Governance

© Filippo Belloc & Antonio Nicita

Work

ing P

aper

No.

13 |

June 2

010

Bibliography

Alesina, A. (1988) „Macroeconomics and Politics‟, in Fisher S. (ed.) NBER

Macroeconomics Annual, MIT Press, Cambridge (MA), pp.17-52.

Alesina, A. and Giavazzi, F. (2007) Il Liberismo è di Sinistra, Il Saggiatore, Milano.

Arin, K. and Ulubasoglu, M. (2009) „Leviathan Resists: The Endogenous

Relationship between Privatization and Firm Performance‟, Public Choice,

140(1): 185-204.

Armstrong, M. and Sappington, D. (2006) „Regulation, Competition and

Liberalization‟, Journal of Economic Literature, 32(2): 353-380.

Besley, T. (2007) „Electoral Strategy and Economic Policy‟, unpublished manuscript.

Besley, T. and Case, A. (2003) „Political Institutions and Policy Choices: Evidence

from the United States?‟, Journal of Economic Literature, 41(1): 7-73.

Besley, T., Persson T. and Sturn, D.M. (2010) „Political Competition, Policy and

Growth: Theory and Evidence from the United States‟, Review of Economic

Studies, forthcoming.

Biais, B. and Perotti, E. (2002) „Machiavellian Privatization‟, American Economic

Review, 92(1): 240-258.

Biørnskov, C. and Potrafke, N. (2009) „Political Ideology and Economic Freedom

across Canadian Provinces‟, Université Libre de Bruxelles.

Blanchard, O. and Giavazzi, F. (2003) „The Macroeconomic Effects of Regulation

and Deregulation of Goods and Labor Markets‟, Quarterly Journal of

Economics, 118(3):879-907.

Boix, C. (1997) „Political Parties and the Supply Side of the Economy: The Provision

of Physical and Human Capital in Advanced Economies, 1960-90‟, American

Journal of Political Science, 41(3): 814-845.

Bortolotti, B. and Pinotti, P. (2008) „Delayed Privatization‟, Public Choice,

136(3):331-351.

Conway, P. and Nicoletti, G. (2006) „Product Market Regulation in the Non-

Manufacturing Sectors of OECD Countries: Measurement and Highlights‟,

OECD Economics Department Working Papers No. 530.

Dinc, S. and Gupta, N. (2007) „The Decision to Privatize: The Role of Political

Competition and Patronage‟, MIT, unpublished manuscript.

Duso, T. (2002) „On Politics of the Regulatory Reform: Evidence from the OECD

Countries‟, WZB Discussion Paper No.FS-IV-02-07.

Page 39: Jerusalem Papers in Regulation & Governanceregulation.huji.ac.il/papers/jp13.pdf · This research is part of the REFGOV project. 2 ISSN: 2079-5882 Political Determinants of Liberalizations;

Jerusalem Papers in Regulation & Governance

© Filippo Belloc & Antonio Nicita

Work

ing P

aper

No.

13 |

June 2

010

Duso, T. And Seldeslachts, J. (2009) „The Political economy of Mobile

Telecommunications Liberalization: Evidence from OECD Countries‟,

Journal of Comparative Economics, doi: 10.1016/j.jce.2009.09.001.

Dutt, P. and Mitra, D. (2005) „Political Ideology and Endogenous Trade Policy: An

Empirical Investigation‟, Review of Economics and Statistics, 87(1):59-72.

Garrett, G. (1998) „Global Markets and National Politics: Collision Course or

Virtuous Cycle?‟, International Organization, 52(4): 787-824.

Giuliano, P. and Scalise, D. (2009) „The Political Economy of Agricultural Market

Reforms in Developing Countries‟, The B.E. Journal of Economic Analysis,

9(1), doi: 10.2202/1935-1682.2023.

Guiso, L., Sapienza, P. and Zingales, L. (2006) „Does Culture Affect Economic

Outcomes‟, Journal of Economic Perspective, 20(2):23-48.

Guriev, S. and Megginson, W. (2007) „Privatization: What Have We Learned?‟, in

Bourguignon, F. and Pleskovic, B. (eds) Beyond Transition, Proceedings of

the 18th

ABCDE, World Bank, Washington D.C.

Høj J., Galasso V., Nicoletti G., and Dang T., (2006) "The Political Economy of

Structural Reform: Empirical Evidence from OECD Countries," OECD

Economics Department Working Papers 501, OECD, Economics

Department.

Krause, S. and Méndez, F. (2005) „Policy Makers‟ Preferences, Party Ideology, and

the Political Business Cycle‟, Southern Economic Journal, 71(4):752-767.

La Porta, R., Lopez-de-Silanes, F., Shleifer, A. and Vishny, R.W. (1998) „Law and

Finance‟, Journal of Political Economy, 106(6):1113-1155.

La Porta, R., Lopez-de-Silanes, F., Shleifer, A. and Vishny, R.W. (1999) „The Quality

of Government‟, Journal of Law, Economics and Organization, 15(1):222-

279.

Levi-Faur, D. (2003) „The Politics of Liberalization‟, Nuffield College Working Paper

in Politics 2002-W13, Oxford.

Levy, B. and Spiller, P. (1996) „A Framework for Resolving the Regulatory Problem‟,

in Levy, B. and Spiller, P. (eds) Regulations, Institutions and Commitment:

Comparative Studies in Regulation, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge,

pp. 121-144.

Li, W. and Xu, L.C. (2002) „The Political Economy of Privatization and Competition:

Cross-Country Evidence from the Telecommunications Sector‟, Journal of

Comparative Economics, 30(3): 439-462.

Newbery, D.M. (1997) „Privatization and Liberalization of Network Utilities‟,

European Economic Review, 41(3-5): 357-383.

Page 40: Jerusalem Papers in Regulation & Governanceregulation.huji.ac.il/papers/jp13.pdf · This research is part of the REFGOV project. 2 ISSN: 2079-5882 Political Determinants of Liberalizations;

Jerusalem Papers in Regulation & Governance

© Filippo Belloc & Antonio Nicita

Work

ing P

aper

No.

13 |

June 2

010

Newbery, D. M., (2002) "Problems of liberalising the electricity industry," European

Economic Review, Elsevier, vol. 46(4-5), pages 919-927, Ma

OECD (2008) Indicators on Employment Protection, available at http://www.oecd.org

(December 2009).

OECD (2009) ETCR Indicators, available at http://www.oecd.org (February 2010).

Perotti, E. (1995) „Credible Privatization‟, American Economic Review, 85(4): 847-

859.

Persson, T. (2002) „Do Political Institutions Shape Economic Policy?‟, Econometrica,

70(3): 883-905.

Persson, T. and Tabellini, G. (2000) Political Economics: Explaining Economic

Policy, MIT Press, Cambridge (MA).

Pitlik, H. (2007) „A Race to Liberalization? Diffusion of Economic Policy Reform

among OECD Economies‟, Public Choice, 132: 159-178.

Potrafke, N. (2009) „Does Government Ideology influence Deregulation of Product

Markets? Empirical Evidence from OECD Countries‟, Public Choice,

forthcoming.

Roe, M. (2006) „Legal Origins, Politics, and Modern Stock Markets‟, Harvard Law

Review, 120(2): 460-527.

Schneider, V., Fink, S. and Tenbucken, M. (2005) „Buying Out the State: A

Comparative Perspective on the Privatization of Infrastructures‟,

Comparative Political Studies, 38(6): 704-727.

Schneider, V. and F. M. Häge (2008) “Europeanization and the Retreat of the State.”

Journal of European Public Policy 15(1):1–19.

Simmons, B. and Elkins, Z. (2004) „The Globalization of Liberalization: Policy

Diffusion in the International Political Economy‟, American Political Science

Review, 98(1): 171-189.

Trebilcock, M.J. and Daniels, R.J. (2008) Rule of Law Reform and Development:

Charting the Fragile Path of Progress, Elgar Press, Cheltenham.

Vickers, J. and Yarrow, G. (1991) „Economic Perspectives on Privatization‟, Journal

of Economic Perspectives, 5(2): 111-132.

Wooldridge, J.M. (2002) Econometric Analysis of Cross Section and Panel Data, The

MIT Press, Cambridge (MA).

World Bank (2008) Database of Political Institutions, available at

http://econ.worldbank.org (February 2010).

World Bank (2009) World Development Indicators, Washington.

Page 41: Jerusalem Papers in Regulation & Governanceregulation.huji.ac.il/papers/jp13.pdf · This research is part of the REFGOV project. 2 ISSN: 2079-5882 Political Determinants of Liberalizations;

Jerusalem Papers in Regulation & Governance

© Filippo Belloc & Antonio Nicita

Work

ing P

aper

No.

13 |

June 2

010

Appendix: main indicators’ description.

Variable Description

Liberalizati

on

We calculate the variable Liberalization by subtracting the

OECD‟s (2009) entry barriers measure from its maximum value.

The OECD‟s (2009) entry barriers index is calculated by OECD as

the simple average of seven sectoral indicators that, in turn,

measure the strictness of the legal conditions of entry in the seven

non-manufacturing sectors. The OECD‟s (2009) sectoral indicators

focus on sector-specific aspects of entry regulation, as follows.

Passenger air transport: the focus is on open skies agreements

with the USA, regional agreements, and restriction on the number

of domestic airlines allowed to operate on domestic routes.

Telecom: the focus is on the legal conditions of entry into the

trunk telephony market, the international market, and the mobile

market. Electricity: the focus is on the conditions of third-party

access to the electricity transmission grid and on the conditions of

the competition in the market for electricity. Gas: the focus is on

the conditions of third-party access to the gas transmission grid, on

the share of the retail market open to consumer choice, and on the

existence of any regulation that restricts the number of competitors

allowed to operate in the market. Post: the focus is on the existence

of any regulation that restricts the number of competitors allowed

to operate in the national market of basic letter services, basic

parcel services, and courier activities. Rail: the focus is on the

legal conditions of entry into the passenger and the freight

transport rail markets. Road: the focus is on the criteria considered

in decisions on entry of new operators.

Left

Dummy variable that equals 1 for parties that are defined as social

democratic, left-wing, communist, socialist (source: World Bank,

2008).

Right

Dummy variable that equals 1 for parties that are defined as

conservative, Christian democratic, or right-wing (source: World

Bank, 2008).

Other

Dummy variable that equals 1 for parties that are defined as

centrist, and for all those cases which do not fit into the above-

mentioned categories (e.g. party‟s platform does not focus on

economic issues), or no information (source: World Bank, 2008).