lecture notes - agricultural and food policy analysis (eng)

Upload: ewmi-access

Post on 02-Mar-2016

926 views

Category:

Documents


9 download

DESCRIPTION

This course material was prepared with he financial support of EWMI G-PAC. The content is the responsibility of the International School of Economics (ISET) and do not necessarily reflects the view of USAID, the United States Government, or EWMI.

TRANSCRIPT

  • Agricultural Economics I:

    Agricultural and Food Policy Analysis

  • Adam Smith (1776): It is not from the benevolence of

    the butcher, the brewer, or the baker, that we expect our

    dinner, but from their regard to their own interest.

  • Ricardos (1817) theory of

    comparative advantage

    used wine and cloth as

    the example.

    Anderson, Kym (2007). Distortions to Agricultural Incentives: A Global Perspective, 1955-2007. The World Bank and Palgrave Macmillan.

    http://www.econlib.org/library/Ricardo/ricP.html

  • The Agricultural Roots of The Economist:

    Created in opposition to the protectionist Corn Laws in the UK

  • Theodore Shultz on Agricultural Economics

    Most of the people in the world are poor, so if we knew the economics of being poor we would know

    much of the economics that really matters. Most of

    the worlds poor people earn their living from

    agriculture, so if we knew the economics of

    agriculture we would know much of the economics

    of being poor.

    T.W. Schultz (1979)

    Nobel Prize Lecture

  • This Course

    An introduction to the field of agricultural and food policy analysis

    Primarily developed for use in the MA Program in Economics at the International School of Economics at Tbilisi State University (ISET)

    14 class sessions, 1 hour each

    We will assess a variety of topics related to the economics (and political economy) of agricultural and rural development

  • Courses at ISET

    Agricultural Economics:

    Agricultural Economics I: Agricultural and Food Policy

    Analysis

    Agricultural Economics II: Agricultural Product and Factor

    Market Analysis

    Agricultural Economics III (planned): International Agricultural Trade

    Additional courses:

    Cost-Benefit Analysis

    Development Economics

    Program Evaluation

    Trade Policy

    Transition Economics

  • Agricultural and Food Policy Analysis

    Agricultural and food policy analysis Subfield of agricultural economics Focus on market specifics, agriculture in transition, agricultural and rural

    development

    Incorporation of insights from the literatures on development economics, political economy, new institutional economics, field experimental research methods Emphasis on the importance of the institutional environment for an

    economy, for the agricultural and food sector, and for understanding policy formulation

    A rich methodology Neoclassical economic analysis is enriched by insights and tools from the

    above fields

  • Acemoglu on Development Economics

    Development economics investigates the causes of

    poverty and low incomes

    around the world and seeks to

    make progress in designing

    policies that could help

    individuals, regions, and

    countries to achieve greater

    economic prosperity.

    Acemoglu, Daron (2010). Theory, General Equilibrium, and

    Political Economy in Development Economics. The Journal of

    Economic Perspectives, 24(3), 1732.

  • The Institutional Environment

    In Institutions, Institutional Change, and Economic Performance, Douglass North wrote that (p. 3):

    Institutions are the rules of the game in a society or, more

    formally, are the humanly devised constraints that shape human interaction. In consequence they structure incentives in human exchange, whether political, social, or economic. Institutional change shapes the way societies evolve through time and hence is the key to understanding historical change.

    The rules of the game and their enforcement Organizations as the players of the game

    North, Douglass (1990). Institutions, Institutional Change, and Economic Performance. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge UK.

  • Source: Williamson, Oliver (2000). The New Institutional Economics: Taking Stock, Looking Ahead. Journal of Economic

    Literature, XXXVIII: 595-613.

    Williamsons

    Four Levels of

    Social

    Analysis

    Solid arrows

    signify

    that the

    higher level

    imposes

    constraints

    on the level

    immediately

    below.

    Reverse

    arrows

    signal

    feedback

  • A Public Choice Analysis of Agricultural

    and Food Policies

    Involves examining why agricultural and food policies are the way they are

    Calls for a positive economic analysis of policy formulation, decision making, and resource allocation

    James Buchanan: public choice is politics without romance.

    Contrasts with a normative approach to these issues What policies should be developed

    Though some normative criteria will be discussed (and debated!)

  • Washington is awash in rumors this week that the White House is planning major changes in the way the U.S. donates food to fight hunger in some of the worlds poorest countries.

    It has set off an emotional debate. Both sides say they are trying to save lives.

    Americas policies on food aid are singularly generousand also unusually selfish. On the generous side, the U.S. spends roughly $1.5 billion every year to send food abroad, far more than any other country.

    On the other hand, the rules for this program, known as Food for Peace, ensure that much of the money stays in American hands. Most of the food, which commonly includes wheat, corn, and soy meal, and vegetable oil, has to be bought from U.S. farmers, processed here and delivered to its destination by U.S. shippers.

    Listen: http://www.npr.org/blogs/thesalt/2013/04/04/176154775/a-political-war-brews-over-food-for-peace-aid-program

  • Why U.S. Taxpayers Pay Brazilian Cotton Farmers

    Contrary to WTO rules, the U.S. subsidizes domestic cotton farmers (by $1.5 to $4 billion per year)

    Brazil complained. The WTO ruled against the U.S., but it went nowhere because of a series of appeals.

    So Brazil retaliated and threatened to tax imports of specific goods from the U.S. (in line with WTO rules). They grouped up with powerful U.S. industries (who would face the Brazilian import tax) to lobby the government.

    What eventually happened? The U.S. now pays Brazilian cotton farmers $147 million a year. And the U.S. still subsidizes cotton farmers.

    Source: http://www.npr.org/blogs/money/2011/01/26/131192182/cotton

  • A Public Choice Approach to

    Agricultural Economics

    What role do economists have in influencing the policy process if stakeholders have vested interests and influence in legislation?

    Explains why policies may not be changed even if economists and the vast majority of citizens would like them to be changed

    Fundamentally deals with issues related to good governance and the development of good political institutions

  • Course Goals

    Broad goals: Improve skills in applied economics Improve critical thinking, writing and co-authoring, and

    presentation skills

    Specific goals: Become acquainted with the effects of agricultural and food

    policies and programs

    Assess the role of government in a market economy Understand the importance of institutions and organizations in a

    market economy

    Identify potential policy problems related to rural and agricultural development

  • Course Goals

    Specific goals, continued: Study the transition of the agricultural sector and

    models of rural and agricultural development

    Become familiar with the basic concepts and frameworks used in agricultural and food policy analysis

    Assess how policies are designed, implemented, and evaluated in practice, with a clear understanding of the political economy of agricultural and food policy analysis

    Become equipped with skills for analyzing agricultural and food policies and monitoring and evaluation of their impacts ex ante and ex post

  • This Course

    For examples and empirical evidence, much focus on the countries of the South Caucasus

    (Armenia, Azerbaijan, and Georgia) and other

    former Soviet republics

    Well also examine the reform experiences of other countries in Central and Eastern Europe

  • Course Structure and Evaluation

    Lectures and class discussions

    Assigned readings

    A short co-authored paper

    Presentations and discussions in a short conference

    Final exam

  • Lectures, Discussions, and Readings

    The content of the lecture notes is not identical to the content of the reading materials It is important to read the assigned texts carefully in

    order to fully understand and appreciate the context and contributions of each article

    The reading material is meant to widen the scope of analysis beyond the content of the lecture

    We will discuss the readings in class, in addition to having regular lecture sessions

  • Lectures, Discussions, and Readings

    At the beginning of each lecture, please feel free to raise questions to clarify the content of the

    preceding lecture or to clarify the content of the

    assigned readings

    Dont hesitate to ask questions and critique the materials!

  • Tentative Lecture Schedule

    Lecture Topic

    Lecture 1 Introduction to Agricultural and Food Policy Analysis

    Lecture 2 The Puzzle of Agricultural Productivity in Georgia

    Agriculture in Transition

    Lecture 3 Agriculture in Transition (Continued)

    Lecture 4 Agricultural Market Specifics

    Lecture 5 Insights from New Institutional Economics

    Lecture 6 Case Study: Embedded Institutions and the Persistence of Large Farms in Russia

    Case Study: Property Rights in Mestia

    Lecture 7 Agricultural and Food Policy Objectives

    Lecture 8 Agricultural and Food Policy Objectives, Continued

    Lecture 9 Agricultural and Food Policy Evaluation

    Lecture 10 Impact Evaluation and Field Experimental Methods

    Lecture 11 Impact Evaluation and Field Experimental Methods: Specific Studies

    Lecture 12 The Political Economy of Agricultural Policy

    Lecture 13 The Political Economy of Agricultural Policy, Continued

    Lecture 14 Conference: Presentations and Discussant Comments

  • The Puzzle of Agricultural Productivity

    Agriculture in Transition

  • Section Readings

    Ellman, Michael. (1988). Soviet Agricultural Policy. Economic & Political Weekly, 23(24): 1208-1210.

    The Arena and the Common Heritage, Chapter 2. Lerman, Zvi, Csaba Csaki, and Gershon Feder. (2004). Agriculture in Transition: Land Policies and Evolving Farm Structures in Post-Soviet Countries. Lexington Books, Maryland.

    Rozelle, Scott and Johan F. M. Swinnen. (2004). Success and Failure of Reform: Insights from the Transition of Agriculture. Journal of Economic Literature, XLII: 404-456.

    The ISET Economist, October 11, 2012. The Puzzle of Agricultural Productivity in Georgia (and Armenia). http://www.iset.ge/blog/?p=836

  • The Puzzle of Agricultural Productivity

    According to official statistics, Georgia is the only former Soviet republic in which labor

    productivity in agriculture hasnt returned to or

    exceeded its level in 1992

    Agricultural labor productivity: value added in agriculture per agricultural worker, constant 2000 US

    dollars from the World Banks World Development

    Indicators dataset

  • 0200

    04

    00

    06

    00

    0

    Ag

    ricu

    lture

    va

    lue a

    dde

    d p

    er

    work

    er

    1990 1995 2000 2005 2010Year

    Data source: World Bank

    Agricultural Productivity

    0

    200

    04

    00

    06

    00

    0A

    g

    1990 1995 2000 2005 2010Year

    Armenia Azerbaijan

    Belarus Estonia

    Georgia Kazakhstan

    Kyrgyz Republic Latvia

    Lithuania Moldova

    Russian Federation Tajikistan

    Turkmenistan Ukraine

    Uzbekistan

    Agricultural Productivity

    The ISET Economist, October 11, 2012. The Puzzle of Agricultural Productivity in Georgia (and Armenia). http://www.iset.ge/blog/?p=836

  • 0100

    200

    300

    400

    Ag

    ricu

    lture

    va

    lue a

    dde

    d p

    er

    work

    er

    rela

    tive to

    199

    2

    1990 1995 2000 2005 2010Year

    Data source: World Bank

    Agricultural Productivity Relative to its 1992 Level

    0

    100

    200

    300

    400

    Ag

    1990 1995 2000 2005 2010Year

    Armenia Azerbaijan

    Belarus Georgia

    Kazakhstan Kyrgyz Republic

    Latvia Moldova

    Russian Federation Tajikistan

    Turkmenistan Ukraine

    Uzbekistan

    Ag

    The ISET Economist, October 11, 2012. The Puzzle of Agricultural Productivity in Georgia (and Armenia). http://www.iset.ge/blog/?p=836

  • Inputs

    Rozelle, Scott and Johan F. M. Swinnen. (2004). Success and Failure of Reform: Insights from the Transition of Agriculture. Journal of Economic

    Literature, XLII: 404-456.

  • Irrigation

    Lerman, Zvi, and David Sedik. (2010). Rural Transition in Azerbaijan. Lexington Books, UK.

  • Land Reform

    Rozelle, Scott and Johan F. M. Swinnen. (2004). Success and Failure of Reform: Insights from the Transition of Agriculture. Journal of Economic

    Literature, XLII: 404-456.

  • Land Reform

    Lerman, Zvi. (2007). Land Reform, Farm Structure, and Agricultural Performance in CIS Countries. Hebrew University, Discussion Paper No. 7.07

  • The Puzzle of Agricultural Productivity

    What is agricultural and rural development?

    Is agricultural productivity necessarily the key variable of interest? If not, what metrics of

    agricultural development should we consider?

    These are just a few of the questions well be thinking about

  • Considerations

    How is value added calculated? How were agricultural product price data collected and calculated? How valuable are existing inputs to the agricultural production

    process?

    How is employment calculated?

    How large is the informal agricultural sector? Schneider, Buehn, and Montenegro (2010) estimate that the total

    size of the overall shadow economy in Georgia was about 62 percent of officially recorded GDP in 2007, which suggests that there is indeed much economic activity occurring in the informal economy

    Schneider, Friedrich, Andreas Buehn, and Claudio E. Montenegro. (2010). New Estimates for the Shadow Economies all over

    the World. International Economic Journal, 24(4): 443-461.

  • Measurement Error?

    0

    200

    04

    00

    06

    00

    0

    Ag

    ricu

    lture

    va

    lue a

    dde

    d p

    er

    work

    er

    1990 1995 2000 2005 2010Year

    Data source: World Bank

    Agricultural Productivity

    0

    200

    04

    00

    06

    00

    0A

    g

    1990 1995 2000 2005 2010Year

    Armenia Azerbaijan

    Georgia

    Agricultural Productivity

    The ISET Economist, October 11, 2012. The Puzzle of Agricultural Productivity in Georgia (and Armenia). http://www.iset.ge/blog/?p=836

  • Definitely Measurement Error Here!

    Source: http://databank.worldbank.org/data/home.aspx. April 2, 2013.

  • Reform and Agricultural Labor

    Productivity

    Rozelle, Scott and Johan F. M. Swinnen. (2004). Success and Failure of Reform: Insights from the Transition of Agriculture. Journal of Economic

    Literature, XLII: 404-456.

  • How

    Productive

    Was Georgia

    During the

    Soviet Era?

    What issues might there be

    with a data source like the

    Statistical Yearbook of the

    USSR?

    Lerman, Zvi, Yoav Kislev, David Biton, and Alon Kriss. (2003). Agricultural Output and Productivity in the Former Soviet Republics. Economic

    Development and Cultural Change, 51(4): 999-1018.

  • Different Calculations

    Lerman, Zvi, Yoav Kislev, David Biton, and Alon Kriss. (2003). Agricultural Output and Productivity in the Former Soviet Republics. Economic

    Development and Cultural Change, 51(4): 999-1018.

  • Additional Considerations

    How efficient are agricultural producers?

    Supporting environment Estonia, Latvia, and Lithuania are members of the EU

    and agricultural producers benefit from EU support measures

    A rights-based approach to agricultural development Forced labor in the cotton fields in Uzbekistan to

    increase cotton exports; should we discount these data because of rights violations?

  • Its Not

    Agricultural

    Productivity

    Per Se That

    Matters

  • A Rights-Based Approach to

    Agricultural Development

    Human Rights Watch:

    For the 2012 harvest, the Uzbek government forced over a million of its own citizens, children and adults including its

    teachers, doctors, and nurses to harvest cotton in abusive

    conditions on threat of punishment, Human Rights Watch

    found. The authorities harassed local activists and journalists

    who tried to report on the issue. In 2011, Uzbekistan was the

    worlds fifth largest exporter of cotton.

  • Additional

    Considerations

    The agricultural sector is much more complex than is suggested by macro-level statistics on productivity or output

    A caveat about growth

    Source: Paul Samuelsons textbook; Marginal Revolution

  • An Enabling Environment

    Rozelle and Swinnen (2004): our analysis suggests that, above all, success requires two key

    elements: good rights and an institutional

    environment within which agents can exchange

    goods and services and access inputs.

    Rozelle, Scott and Johan F. M. Swinnen. (2004). Success and Failure of Reform: Insights from the Transition of Agriculture. Journal of Economic

    Literature, XLII: 404-456.

  • What is Development, After All?

    In Development as Freedom, Amartya Sen argued that development can be seen as:

    as a process of expanding the real freedoms that people enjoy. Focusing on human freedoms contrasts with narrower views of development, such as identifying development with the growth of gross national product, or with the rise in personal incomes, or with industrialization, or with technological advance, or with social modernization. Growth of GNP or of individual incomes can, of course, be very important as means to expanding the freedoms enjoyed by members of the society. But freedoms also depend on other determinants, such as social and economic arrangements (for example, facilities for education and health care) as well as political and civil rights (for example, the liberty to participate in public discussion and scrutiny).

    Sen, Amartya. (1999). Development as Freedom. Anchor Books, New York.

  • Development as Freedom

    Sen (1999) argued that real development requires the removal of major sources of

    unfreedom: poverty as well as tyranny, poor

    economic opportunities as well as systematic

    social deprivation, neglect of public facilities as

    well as intolerance or overactivity of repressive

    states.

    Sen, Amartya. (1999). Development as Freedom. Anchor Books, New York.

  • The Capability Approach

    Amartya Sen View that income and wealth are not ends, but means

    Instruments for other purposes

    Sen argues that the capability to function is what really matters

    Functionings: what a person does (or can do) with the commodities of given characteristics that they come to possess or control.

    Freedom of choice (control over ones own life)

    Todaro, Michael and Stephen Smith (2012). Economic Development, Addison-Wesley.

  • Sources of Disparity Between

    Income and Development Personal heterogeneities

    E.g. disabilities, illnesses, age, gender

    Environmental diversities Variations in social climate

    Crime, violence, and social capital

    Distribution within the family Family resources may be distributed unevenly (e.g. on

    the basis of gender)

    Relational perspectives Demand for some commodities to function in different

    societies

    Todaro, Michael and Stephen Smith (2012). Economic Development, Addison-Wesley.

  • Agricultural Productivity

    Rising agricultural productivity is often viewed as a key policy goal Rozelle and Swinnen (2004): Rising productivity through

    policies that provide better incentives and reduce resource wastewill a.) lead to rising food and non-food agricultural production; b.) contribute to higher income; and c.) make the sector more modern.

    because its seen as important for poverty reduction.

    Well look at the sources of growth in agricultural output per worker (per person) later in the course

    Rozelle, Scott and Johan F. M. Swinnen. (2004). Success and Failure of Reform: Insights from the Transition of Agriculture. Journal of Economic

    Literature, XLII: 404-456.

  • 01

    02

    03

    04

    05

    06

    0

    % o

    f T

    ota

    l E

    mplo

    ym

    ent

    1990 1995 2000 2005 2010Year

    Data source: World Bank

    Employment in Agriculture (% of Total Employment)

    30

    35

    40

    45

    50

    55

    Ag

    1990 1995 2000 2005 2010Year

    Armenia Azerbaijan

    Georgia

    XX

  • 02

    04

    06

    08

    0

    % o

    f G

    DP

    1990 1995 2000 2005 2010Year

    Data source: World Bank

    Agriculture value added (% of GDP)

    02

    04

    06

    08

    0A

    g

    1990 1995 2000 2005 2010Year

    Armenia Azerbaijan

    Belarus Estonia

    Georgia Kazakhstan

    Kyrgyz Republic Latvia

    Lithuania Russian Federation

    Tajikistan Turkmenistan

    Ukraine Uzbekistan

    XX

    Note: Moldova is not included because of measurement error.

  • 0200

    04

    00

    06

    00

    0

    Ag

    ricu

    lture

    va

    lue a

    dde

    d p

    er

    work

    er

    1990 1995 2000 2005 2010Year

    Data source: World Bank

    Agricultural Productivity

    0

    200

    04

    00

    06

    00

    0A

    g

    1990 1995 2000 2005 2010Year

    Armenia Azerbaijan

    Belarus Estonia

    Georgia Kazakhstan

    Kyrgyz Republic Latvia

    Lithuania Moldova

    Russian Federation Tajikistan

    Turkmenistan Ukraine

    Uzbekistan

    Agricultural Productivity

    The ISET Economist, October 11, 2012. The Puzzle of Agricultural Productivity in Georgia (and Armenia). http://www.iset.ge/blog/?p=836

  • Source:

    http://www.feradi.in

    fo/en/visualizations/

    2012-2016-georgian-

    budget-for-

    agriculture

    In Georgian:

    http://www.feradi.in

    fo/ka/visualizations/

    soplis-meurneobis-

    biujeti-2012-2016

  • Average monthly salary of employees by economic activity GEL

    2011

    Total 636.0

    Agriculture, hunting and forestry 392.6

    Fishing 271.1

    Mining and quarrying 838.6

    Manufacturing 552.2

    Production and distribution of electricity, gas and water 877.0

    Construction 738.5

    Wholesale and retail trade; repair of motor vehicles and personal and

    household goods 548.9

    Hotels and restaurants 342.4

    Transport and communication 873.8

    Financial intermediation 1386.3

    Real estate, renting and business activities 674.3

    Public administration 998.8

    Education 319.6

    Health and social work 522.9

    Other community, social and personal service activities 511.5

    Georgias Agricultural Sector

    Source: http://www.geostat.ge/

  • OUTPUT OF AGRICULTURAL PRODUCTS IN GEORGIA (mil. GEL)

    Cereals and other crops n.e.c. 471.3

    Fruit, nuts, beverage and spice crops 476.5

    Vegetables, horticultural specialities and nursery 290.1

    Live animals and animal products 1,336.8

    Agricultural services 99.3

    Total 2,674.0

    OUTPUT OF FOOD PRODUCTS MADE BY PROCESSING AGRICULTURAL

    PRODUCTS (mil. GEL)

    Grain mill products, starches and starch products; prepared animal feeds 476.9

    Bread, fresh pastry goods and cakes; rusks and biscuits; preserved pastry goods and cakes 1,255.6

    Meat and meat products; processed and preserved fish and fish products 124.7

    Dairy products and ice cream 463.2

    Alcoholic beverages 443.2

    Other food products 792.0

    Total 3,555.6

    Total output of agrobusiness, mil. GEL 6,229.6

    Total output by economy, mil. GEL 36,430.7

    Share of agrobusiness in the output of total economy (%) 17.1

    Source: http://www.geostat.ge/

    Georgias Agrobusiness Sector in 2011

  • Source: http://www.geostat.ge/

    Georgias Agrobusiness Sector

    0.0

    5.0

    10.0

    15.0

    20.0

    25.0

    2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011

    Share of Agrobusiness in Total Economic Output (%)

  • Georgias Employment Situation

    Source: http://www.geostat.ge/

  • Kan, Iddo, Ayal Kimhi, and Zvi Lerman. (2006). Farm Output, Non-farm Income and Commercialization in Rural Georgia.

    Journal of Agricultural and Development Economics, 3(2): 276-286.

  • Transition in Agriculture

    Institutional changes: Property and land use rights

    Their definition and enforcement, whether formal or informal

    Contract enforcement Constraints on executive authority

    Macroeconomic changes (LCF 2004: p. 5): Abolition of central planning Reduction of government intervention Elimination of central controls Price and trade liberalization Economic stabilization

    Lerman, Zvi, Csaba Csaki, and Gershon Feder. (2004). Agriculture in Transition: Land Policies and Evolving Farm Structures in Post-Soviet

    Countries. Lexington Books, Maryland.

  • Transition in Agriculture

    Sectoral policies (LCF 2004: p. 5)

    Demonopolized and competitive upstream and downstream industries

    Rural credit institutions

    Technological improvements

    New capital investment patterns in agriculture

    Rural non-farm job creation

    Lerman, Zvi, Csaba Csaki, and Gershon Feder. (2004). Agriculture in Transition: Land Policies and Evolving Farm Structures in Post-Soviet

    Countries. Lexington Books, Maryland.

  • Transition in Agriculture

    Land reform (LCF 2004: p. 5)

    Restructuring of Soviet farms

    Privatization of state-owned farms

    The political environment shapes how land reform and farm restructuring will occur

    Lerman, Zvi, Csaba Csaki, and Gershon Feder. (2004). Agriculture in Transition: Land Policies and Evolving Farm Structures in Post-Soviet

    Countries. Lexington Books, Maryland.

  • Agriculture in the Soviet Period

    (LCF, 2004: 25-26) Large-scale collective and state farms

    Subsistence agriculture on small rural household plots A dual farm structure Entire value chain (e.g., upstream input industries) controlled by

    state organizations In practice, gray/black market activity

    95% of agricultural land publicly controlled Yet the individual sector had a far higher level of land productivity

    than did the socialized farm sector

    Centrally dictated production targets Soft budget constraints

    Lerman, Zvi, Csaba Csaki, and Gershon Feder. (2004). Agriculture in Transition: Land Policies and Evolving Farm Structures in Post-Soviet

    Countries. Lexington Books, Maryland.

  • Agriculture in the Soviet Period

    (LCF, 2004: 25-26)

    Soviet state farms ( , sovkhoz) and collective/cooperative farms ( , kolkhoz)

    Sovkhoz: Productive assets owned by the state, farm workers were mainly salaried state employees; land state

    owned

    Kolkhoz: Productive assets jointly owned by members, compensated by distribution of farm earnings; land state

    owned

    Also a guaranteed minimum wage since the Khrushchev era

    No freedom of exit from cooperatives/collectives

    Lerman, Zvi, Csaba Csaki, and Gershon Feder. (2004). Agriculture in Transition: Land Policies and Evolving Farm Structures in Post-Soviet

    Countries. Lexington Books, Maryland.

  • Agriculture in the Soviet Period

    (LCF, 2004: 28) Housing, power, water, heat provided in villages by local farm

    enterprises

    Salaries of teachers, doctors, postal workers paid by government, but disbursement carried out by local farm enterprises

    Subsidized inputs, financial transfers to loss-making farms, redistribution of funds from profitable to unprofitable farms

    Allocation of often interest-free long-term government credits

    Lerman, Zvi, Csaba Csaki, and Gershon Feder. (2004). Agriculture in Transition: Land Policies and Evolving Farm Structures in Post-Soviet

    Countries. Lexington Books, Maryland.

  • Efficiency and Profitability

    (LCF, 2004: 29-30)

    Socialist collective and state farms: woefully inefficient

    Efficiency and profitability were not the focus; improving production was the focus

    Lerman, Zvi, Csaba Csaki, and Gershon Feder. (2004). Agriculture in Transition: Land Policies and Evolving Farm Structures in Post-Soviet

    Countries. Lexington Books, Maryland.

  • Operating Decisions in Market-based and Socialist Farms

    Business component Decisions in a market

    economy

    Decisions in a socialist

    economy

    Sales Choose where =

    centrally imposed

    Costs Cost minimization Cost overruns covered by

    state

    Labor Adjust labor force to

    changing production

    volume/mix

    Labor force fixed;

    workers guaranteed

    lifetime employment

    Inputs Seek best suppliers,

    control purchase

    quantities

    Inputs at state-fixed

    prices; in quantities

    determined by production

    quotas

    Lerman, Zvi, Csaba Csaki, and Gershon Feder. (2004). Agriculture in Transition: Land Policies and Evolving Farm Structures in Post-Soviet

    Countries. Lexington Books, Maryland.

  • Operating Decisions in Market-based and Socialist Farms

    Business component Decisions in a market

    economy

    Decisions in a socialist

    economy

    Depreciation New capital investment if

    needed for profitability

    New capital investment if

    decided by the plan

    Credit/financial expenses Hard budget constraints Credit allocated centrally

    to cover deficits (soft

    budget constraints)

    Profit Maximize profit

    (minimize cost) by

    producing where =

    Profit uncontrollable

    Lerman, Zvi, Csaba Csaki, and Gershon Feder. (2004). Agriculture in Transition: Land Policies and Evolving Farm Structures in Post-Soviet

    Countries. Lexington Books, Maryland.

  • Inefficiencies of Soviet Agriculture

    Attribute Inefficiencies due to..

    Centrally commanded production targets Lack of consumer orientation; insensitivity

    to market signals

    Soft budget constraints Lack of profit orientation; reliance on

    writeoffs and subsidies

    Collective organization of production Free riding, moral hazard, lack of individual

    incentives; payment not linked to effort

    Large farms (2,000 ha; 500 workers) High monitoring costs, anonymity, lack of

    transparency

    Lifetime employment Inability to control costs by adjusting labor

    No effective individual ownership of land

    and productive assets

    Nontransferability of land and assets; lack

    of incentives associated with property rights

    Lerman, Zvi, Csaba Csaki, and Gershon Feder. (2004). Agriculture in Transition: Land Policies and Evolving Farm Structures in Post-Soviet

    Countries. Lexington Books, Maryland.

  • Optimal Farm Sizes

    Super large farms relatively inefficient due to high transaction costs (agency costs with hired management, costs of labor monitoring) (LCF, 2004: 45)

    Allow farm sizes to be decided in land markets (LCF, 2004: 35)

    But there may be other political determinants of the optimal size of a farm as well, something we will look at later

    Lerman, Zvi, Csaba Csaki, and Gershon Feder. (2004). Agriculture in Transition: Land Policies and Evolving Farm Structures in Post-Soviet

    Countries. Lexington Books, Maryland.

  • Agricultural Markets

  • Section Readings

    Binswanger, Hans P. and Klaus Deininger (1997). Explaining Agricultural and Agrarian

    Policies in Developing Countries. Journal of

    Economic Literature, XXXV: 1958-2005.

    Bezemer, Dirk and Derek Headey (2008). Agriculture, Development, and Urban Bias.

    World Development, 7: 1-40.

  • Income from Agriculture

    To improve farmers incomes, policies must somehow increase farmers revenues or reduce

    their costs (Gardner, 1987)

    Sometimes this comes about through efforts to restrict supply or increase demand, so that there is

    an increase in farmers receipts

    Lets consider a few different policy approaches and their market effects

    Source: Gardner, Bruce (1987). The Economics of Agricultural Policies. Macmillan Publishing Company, New York.

  • The Market Price

    Quantity

    Supply

    Demand

  • Quota

    Price

    Quantity

    Supply

    Demand

    Source: Gardner (1987)

  • Quota

    Price

    Quantity

    Supply

    Demand

    Source: Gardner (1987)

    Effective Supply

  • A Quota

    Quotas limit how much each farmer can supply to the market

    A quota reduces quantity supplied from to and increases the market price from to .

    Producers therefore receive a higher price for each of the units (up to ) supplied to the market. The total area under the supply curve from to indicates the industrys cost

    savings from reducing output.

    However, these units could have been sold at market price and these units therefore would have had marginal revenues exceeding marginal costs, resulting in producer benefits.

    Therefore the total gain to producers is . The loss in consumer surplus is represented by areas + . From societys point of view, the quotas result in a net loss of + since these

    units were never produced and traded, whereas they would have been under baseline market conditions. This net loss therefore represents a misallocation of resources.

    Source: Gardner, Bruce (1987). The Economics of Agricultural Policies. Macmillan Publishing Company, New York.

  • Price Supports

    Price

    Quantity

    Supply

    Demand

    Source: Gardner (1987)

  • Price Supports

    Producers receive price (up to a certain point, say ), which is higher than the market price. They choose to produce more than they would under normal market

    conditions.

    With price supports, producers gain area . Consumers gain area because at the quantity being supplied due to

    the price support, they pay and demand the quantity . Yet there is a cost! The cost of the price support program to taxpayers.

    Taxpayers must fund the area which can be rather substantial. These payments equal + + so net of the producer () and

    consumer () gains, there is a social net loss of . This area also represents the misallocation of resources that occur since the units are produced at the expense of something else.

    Source: Gardner, Bruce (1987). The Economics of Agricultural Policies. Macmillan Publishing Company, New York.

  • Prices and Incomes in Agriculture

    Is the agricultural sector affected more or less than other sectors in an economy during a

    recession?

    Consider the case of a closed economy with a simple supply and demand model

    Source: Koester, Ulrich and Ali El-Agraa (2003). The Common Agricultural Policy. In Ali El-Agraa (ed.), The European Union:

    Economics and Policies. Seventh Edition. Pearson Education Limited. Harlow, Essex, UK, pp. 354-390.

  • Prices and Incomes in Agriculture

    If = (, ) and =

    =

    +

    Let

    = < 0 and

    = > 0

    Then

    =

    +

    Source: Koester, Ulrich and Ali El-Agraa (2003). The Common Agricultural Policy. In Ali El-Agraa (ed.), The European Union:

    Economics and Policies. Seventh Edition. Pearson Education Limited. Harlow, Essex, UK, pp. 354-390.

  • Prices and Incomes in Agriculture

    We also know that since = () then

    =

    and let

    = > 0

    Then

    =

    Source: Koester, Ulrich and Ali El-Agraa (2003). The Common Agricultural Policy. In Ali El-Agraa (ed.), The European Union:

    Economics and Policies. Seventh Edition. Pearson Education Limited. Harlow, Essex, UK, pp. 354-390.

  • Prices and Incomes in Agriculture

    Since = we know that

    +

    =

    Thus

    =

    So prices for agricultural products will decline more,

    given an income shock (

    < 0), when, ceteris paribus,

    The income elasticity of demand is larger

    The price elasticity of demand is smaller

    The price elasticity of demand is smaller

    Source: Koester, Ulrich and Ali El-Agraa (2003). The Common Agricultural Policy. In Ali El-Agraa (ed.), The European Union:

    Economics and Policies. Seventh Edition. Pearson Education Limited. Harlow, Essex, UK, pp. 354-390.

  • Prices and Incomes in Agriculture

    0

    1

    0

    0

    1

    0

    1

    0

    1

    Large supply

    overhang for the

    manufacturing

    sector

    Small supply

    overhang for the

    agricultural

    sector

    Yet the

    percentage

    change of prices

    in the agricultural

    sector is much

    higher

    1

    Source: Koester, Ulrich and Ali El-Agraa (2003). The Common Agricultural Policy. In Ali El-Agraa (ed.), The European Union:

    Economics and Policies. Seventh Edition. Pearson Education Limited. Harlow, Essex, UK, pp. 354-390.

  • Prices and Incomes in Agriculture

    With relatively small price elasticities of supply and demand, small changes in supply or demand will have significant implications for the prices for agricultural products seen by farmers and thereby their incomes

    Agriculture may thereby suffer more during business cycles than other sectors (though this is a closed economy model)

    What might happen in an open economy setting?

    Source: Koester, Ulrich and Ali El-Agraa (2003). The Common Agricultural Policy. In Ali El-Agraa (ed.), The European Union:

    Economics and Policies. Seventh Edition. Pearson Education Limited. Harlow, Essex, UK, pp. 354-390.

  • Income Elasticity of Demand for

    Calories

    Income elasticity of demand for calories:

    Percentage change in calories consumed given a percentage change in household income

    Among the poor in developing countries, this may range anywhere from 0 to 0.5

    Depends on region, statistical methods

    Banerjee, Abhijit V. and Esther Duflo. (2011). Poor Economics: A Radical Rethinking of the Way to Fight Global Poverty. New York:

    Perseus Books.

  • Income Elasticity of Demand for

    Calories

    Income is spent on other goods rather than food Medicine, media, festivals, weddings, funerals, etc.

    Increases in food variety (especially better tasting foods) without a necessary increase in caloric consumption

    Income consumption of better-tasting, more expensive calories (rather than calories altogether or more micronutrients)

    Banerjee, Abhijit V. and Esther Duflo. (2011). Poor Economics: A Radical Rethinking of the Way to Fight Global Poverty. New York:

    Perseus Books.

  • Studies on Caloric Intake Among the

    Poor (B&D, 24)

    Robert Jensen and Nolan Miller

    Two regions of China

    Offered randomly selected poor households a large subsidy on the price of the basic staple (wheat

    noodles in one region, rice in the other)

    Effectively decreasing the price

    What happens?

    Banerjee, Abhijit V. and Esther Duflo. (2011). Poor Economics: A Radical Rethinking of the Way to Fight Global Poverty. New York:

    Perseus Books.

  • Studies on Caloric Intake Among the

    Poor (B&D, 24)

    Jensen and Miller:

    Households receiving subsidies for rice or wheat consumed less of those two items and ate more shrimp and meat

    Caloric intake of those who received the subsidy did not increase (and may have very well decreased)

    No real improvement in nutritional content of total food consumption

    Banerjee, Abhijit V. and Esther Duflo. (2011). Poor Economics: A Radical Rethinking of the Way to Fight Global Poverty. New York:

    Perseus Books.

  • Giffen Good

    Classic case of the Giffen good The price of a commodity decreases and you consume less of it

    because of the magnitude of the income effect

    Because the prices of rice and wheat declined, they were able to spend more money on all other commodities and they actually consumed less rice and wheat as a result

    Because all Giffen goods are inferior goods, it must be the case that those receiving subsidies for purchases of rice or wheat saw them as inferior to consumption of other types of foods

    Banerjee, Abhijit V. and Esther Duflo. (2011). Poor Economics: A Radical Rethinking of the Way to Fight Global Poverty. New York:

    Perseus Books.

  • Agricultural Markets

    Non -

    governmental

    organisations

    L E

    U

    R U S

    Agriculture Upstream

    sectors

    Downstream

    sectors

    Consumers

    Government

    The red arrows affect activities of organisations. The green arrows affect exchange between the organisations.

    Source: Koester (2012) Lecture

    R L E S

  • Imperfect and Missing Markets

    Rural credit markets and insurance markets Especially important given volatility of income from the agricultural

    sector (Bezemer and Headey, 2008)

    Land markets Heterogeneous labor market arrangements Markets for research and development

    Developing new technologies, crop varieties, etc.

    Lack of information What options exist for value chain integration

    Asymmetric information Different information sets for smallholder farmers, wholesalers, input

    suppliers, etc.

    High transaction costs

    Bezemer, Dirk and Derek Headey (2008). Agriculture, Development, and Urban Bias. World Development, 7: 1-40.

    Binswanger, Hans P. and Klaus Deininger (1997). Explaining Agricultural and Agrarian Policies in Developing Countries. Journal of Economic Literature,

    XXXV: 1958-2005.

  • Income Risk and Insurance

    IN INDIA, when monsoons are delayed and crops fail as a result, farmers often dont know how to pay back the debts they have taken on to purchase seeds. More than 15,000 commit suicide every year. These fates are a shocking reminder of a global problem caused by global warming. Farming has always been a gamble, but the growing number of unusual weather events, as experts call them, make seeding and harvesting an even riskier business.

    The Economist

  • A Land Market Without Exchange

    Price

    Quantity

    Supply

    Demand

    Illustrates the importance of

    insights from new institutional

    economics (e.g., informal norms,

    the importance of transaction

    costs, property rights, etc.)

    Source: Koester, Ulrich and Ali El-Agraa (2003). The Common Agricultural Policy. In Ali El-Agraa (ed.), The

    European Union: Economics and Policies. Seventh Edition. Pearson Education Limited. Harlow, Essex, UK, pp. 354-390.

    Suppliers: High

    reservation

    prices for land

    (e.g., because of

    risk hedging,

    tradition, etc.)

    Buyers:

    Uncertainty

    about future

    returns from

    land

  • A Land Market Without Exchange

    Back to the institutional environment

    Poorly defined and enforced property and land use rights

    Uncertainty due to political instability, conflict, economic environment

    Attachment to land as a function of the risk environment Land owners may be hesitant to sell land since its a critical asset for

    risk hedging (Koester and Petrick, 2010)

    Low access to credit

    Koester, Ulrich and Martin Petrick (2010). Embedded Institutions and the Persistence of Large Farms in Russia. In Imre Ferto,

    Csaba Forgacs, Attila Jambor (eds.), Essays in Honour of Professor Csaba Csaki, Budapest, pp. 57-76.

  • Rural Insurance Markets

    How is risk managed in rural areas in developing countries? Individuals often have to manage

    considerable risks, including but not limited to

    weather shocks (e.g., too much precipitation or

    too little), price shocks, and even risks which are

    more political in nature, like land tenure

    insecurity.

  • Source: http://www.civil.ge/eng/article.php?id=25021

  • Rural Financial Markets

    Besley (1994): A market failure [in rural credit markets] occurs when a competitive market fails

    to bring about an efficient allocation of credit.

    Potential for poor financial intermediation

    How are savers and borrowers matched up when there is no intermediary?

    Besley, Timothy (1994). How Do Market Failures Justify Interventions in Rural Credit Markets? The World Bank Research

    Observer, 9(1): 27-47.

  • Rural Insurance Markets

    Cole, Gin, Tobacman, Topalova, Townsend, and Vickery (2013) use randomized field experiments to evaluate demand for a rainfall insurance product in rural areas in Andhra Pradesh and Gujarat, India

    Premiums are higher than expected payouts in many developing countries, including India

    Along with being price sensitive, demand seems to be limited by a lack of trust, liquidity constraints, and relatively low product salience

    Cole, Shawn, Xavier Gin, Jeremy Tobacman, Petia Topalova, Robert Townsend, and James Vickery (2013). Barriers to Household Risk Management:

    Evidence from India. American Economic Journal: Applied Economics, 5(1): 104-135.

  • Rural Private Banking Sector

    Problem areas (Koester, 2001):

    Small amount of credit needed, though high transaction costs for a bank

    Knowledge and capacity limitations with respect to assessing creditworthiness

    Also uncertainty with respect to return on investment

    Risk level associated with agricultural credit

    Geographic dispersion

    Low average incomes

    Koester, Ulrich (2001). Agricultural Finance and Institutional Reforms in Transition Economies: The 1990s and Challenges Ahead. Quarterly Journal of

    International Agriculture, 40(4): 301-323.

  • Rural and Agricultural Credit

    Cooperatives

    Koester (2001):

    May lower transaction costs if smaller, village based, and have better knowledge of credit

    history/creditworthiness

    Preference for small loans

    Koester, Ulrich (2001). Agricultural Finance and Institutional Reforms in Transition Economies: The 1990s and Challenges Ahead. Quarterly Journal of

    International Agriculture, 40(4): 301-323.

  • Rural Financial Markets

    Importance of the overall institutional environment for the functioning of rural credit markets (see,

    e.g., Koester, 2001)

    Particularly with regard to the quality of legal institutions, their transparency and efficiency

    Protection of property rights

    Unbiased enforcement of contracts

    Koester, Ulrich (2001). Agricultural Finance and Institutional Reforms in Transition Economies: The 1990s and Challenges Ahead. Quarterly Journal of

    International Agriculture, 40(4): 301-323.

  • The Institutional Environment

  • Section Readings

    North, Douglass (1991). Institutions. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 5(1): 97-112.

    Olson, Mancur. (1996). Distinguished Lecture on Economics in Government: Big Bills Left on the Sidewalk: Why Some Nations are Rich, and Others Poor. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 10(2): 3-24.

    Lindsay, Stace (2000). Culture, Mental Models, and National Prosperity. In Lawrence E. Harrison and Samuel P. Huntington (eds.), Culture Matters: How Values Shape Human Progress, Basic Books, pp. 282-295.

    Williamson, Oliver (2000). The New Institutional Economics: Taking Stock, Looking Ahead. Journal of Economic Literature, XXXVIII: 595-613.

  • Section Readings

    Koester, Ulrich (2005). A Revival of Large Farms in Eastern EuropeHow Important Are Institutions? Agricultural Economics, 32(s1): 103-113.

    Koester, Ulrich and Martin Petrick (2010). Embedded Institutions and the Persistence of Large Farms in Russia. In Imre Ferto, Csaba Forgacs, Attila Jambor (eds.), Essays in Honour of Professor Csaba Csaki, Budapest, pp. 57-76.

    Swinnen, Johan F. M., Anneleen Vandeplas, and Miet Maertens. (2010). Liberalization, Endogenous Institutions, and Growth: A Comparative Analysis of Agricultural Reforms in Africa, Asia, and Europe. World Bank Economic Review, 24(3): 412-445.

    Problems Related to the Protection of Property Rights The Case of Mestia. Available at: http://transparency.ge/en/post/report/problems-related-protection-property-rights-case-mestia-july-2011.

  • The Institutional Environment

    In Institutions, Institutional Change, and Economic Performance, Douglass North wrote that (p. 3):

    Institutions are the rules of the game in a society or, more

    formally, are the humanly devised constraints that shape human interaction. In consequence they structure incentives in human exchange, whether political, social, or economic. Institutional change shapes the way societies evolve through time and hence is the key to understanding historical change.

    The rules of the game and their enforcement Organizations as the players of the game

    North, Douglass (1990). Institutions, Institutional Change, and Economic Performance. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge UK.

  • The Institutional Environment

    North (1991):

    Institutions may consist of either:

    Informal constraints

    Sanctions, customs, traditions, etc.

    Formal rules

    Constitutions, codified laws, recorded and enforced property rights

    North, Douglass (1990). Institutions, Institutional Change, and Economic Performance. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge UK.

  • The Institutional Environment

    Another widely accepted view is that institutions are rules of human interaction that

    constrain possible opportunistic and erratic

    behavior, thereby making human behavior more

    predictable and thus facilitating the division of

    labour and wealth creation (Kasper and Streit,

    1999: 30).

    Kasper, Wolfgang and Manfred E. Streit (1999). Institutional Economics: Social Order and Public Policy. Edward Elgar Publishing.

  • Focusing on Institutions

    Two broad views of economics:

    Economics as the study of the allocation of resources

    Economics as the study of coordination and exchange

    Buchanan (1964): economists should focus on the latter

    Buchanan, James (1964). What Should Economists Do? Southern Economic Journal, 30(3): 213-222.

  • Coordination and Exchange

    A market is not competitive by assumption or by construction. A market becomes competitive, and competitive rules come to be established as institutions emerge to place limits on individual behavior patterns. It is this becoming process, brought about by the continuous pressure of human behavior in exchange, that is the central part of our disciplineA general solution, if there is one, emerges as a result of a whole network of evolving exchanges, bargains, trades, side payments, agreements, contracts which, finally at some point, ceases to renew itself. At each stage of this evolution towards solution, there are gains to be made, there are exchanges possible, and this being true, the direction of movement is modified.

    Buchanan, James (1964). What Should Economists Do? Southern Economic Journal, 30(3): 213-222.

  • Coordination and Exchange

    Individuals are observed to cooperate with one another, to reach agreements, to trade. The network of relationships that emerges or evolves out of this trading process, the institutional framework, is called the market.

    Economists should concentrate attention on the institutions, the relationships, among individuals as they participate in voluntarily organized activity, in trade or exchange, broadly considered.

    Buchanan, James (1964). What Should Economists Do? Southern Economic Journal, 30(3): 213-222.

  • Source: Williamson, Oliver (2000). The New Institutional Economics: Taking Stock, Looking Ahead. Journal of Economic

    Literature, XXXVIII: 595-613.

    Williamsons

    Four Levels of

    Social

    Analysis

    Solid arrows

    signify

    that the

    higher level

    imposes

    constraints

    on the level

    immediately

    below.

    Reverse

    arrows

    signal

    feedback

  • The Coordinating Role of Institutions

    The institutional environment

    influences how

    different agents

    interact and

    coordinate in a

    market economy

  • Big Bills Left on the Sidewalk: Why Some

    Nations are Rich, and Others Poor.

    Mancur Olsen

    1996 Journal of Economic Perspectives

  • Inclusive Economic Institutions

    Acemoglu and Robinson (2012: 74) define inclusive economic institutions as those that allow and encourage participation by the great mass of people in economic activities that make best use of their talents and skills and that enable individuals to make the choices they wish. To be inclusive, economic institutions must feature secure private property, an unbiased system of law, and a provision of public services that provides a level playing field in which people can exchange and contract; it also must permit the entry of new businesses and allow people to choose their careers.

    Acemoglu, Daron and James A. Robinson (2012). Why Nations Fail: The Origins of Power, Prosperity, and Poverty. Crown

    Publishers, New York.

  • Inclusive Economic Institutions

    Acemoglu and Robinson (2012: 75) argue that Inclusive economic institutions foster economic

    activity, productivity growth, and economic prosperity. Secure private property rights are central, since only those with such rights will be willing to invest and increase productivity. A businessman who expects his output to be stolen, expropriated, or entirely taxed away will have little incentive to work, let alone any incentive to undertake investments and innovations. But such rights must exist for the majority of people in society.

    Acemoglu, Daron and James A. Robinson (2012). Why Nations Fail: The Origins of Power, Prosperity, and Poverty. Crown

    Publishers, New York.

  • North Korea

    South Korea Henderson and Storeygard

    (2012). Measuring

    Economic Growth From

    Outer Space. American

    Economic Review, forthcoming.

  • Easterly on Institutional Design

    The top down view of institutions sees them as determined by laws written by political leadersthe bottom up view sees

    institutions instead as emerging spontaneously from the social

    norms, customs, traditions, beliefs, and values of individuals

    within a society, with the written law only formalizing what is

    already maintained by the attitudes of individuals

    Institutional change in the bottom up view is always gradual, evolutionary rather than revolutionary.

    Easterly, William (2008). Institutions: Top Down or Bottom Up? American Economic Review,

    98(2): 95-99.

  • Easterly on Institutional Design

    Even if the bottom up economists can think of NO reason why a particular institution exists, they are still cautious about

    changing existing institutions abruptly (assuming such

    institutions are not too obviously destructive) with the

    knowledge that there is SOME reason, not yet understood and

    perhaps never to be understood, for their existence.

    As Richard Dawkins said about the analogous exercise in evolutionary biology of trying to understand the rationale for the

    anatomy of each species, evolution is smarter than you are.

    Easterly, William (2008). Institutions: Top Down or Bottom Up? American Economic Review,

    98(2): 95-99.

  • A Rights-Based Approach

    Property rights -- 2012 According to information obtained by Transparency

    International Georgia, government representatives pressured land owners in Anaklia into giving up their lands during the period 2009-2010. While this information was previously known to the public, now for the first time the victims have been openly discussing the alleged cases. A video shows government officials threatening landowners with arrest or the dismissal of family members from their work if they failed to relinquish their property.

    Source: http://transparency.ge/en/blog/property-seizure-officials-case-anaklia

  • Important Topics in New Institutional Economics

    Relevant for Agricultural Development

    Trust and informal norms Without trust in exchange partners, transactions will be

    limited or will have high costs (Koester and Petrick, 2010)

    Particularly important for agriculture considering that most farm products are experience goods (quality is revealed upon consumption) or credence goods (neither the quality nor the production process are known ex ante) rather than search goods (quality is known at the time of purchase) (Koester and Petrick, 2010)

    Transaction costs Enforcement costs Institutional change and development

    Koester, Ulrich and Martin Petrick (2010). Embedded Institutions and the Persistence of Large Farms in Russia. In Imre Ferto,

    Csaba Forgacs, Attila Jambor (eds.), Essays in Honour of Professor Csaba Csaki, Budapest, pp. 57-76.

  • Transaction Costs

    Transaction costs The time, effort, and other resources needed to

    search out, negotiate, and complete an exchange (Gwartney, Stroup, Sobel, and Macpherson, 2011: 31)

    Suggests the importance of brokers who bring buyers and sellers of agricultural products together and arrange trades

    Help to reduce transaction costs

    Gwartney, James D., Richard L. Stroup, Russell Sobel, and David A. MacPherson (2011). Microeconomics: Private and Public Choice,

    South-Western, Cengage Learning.

  • Transaction Costs

    Transportation infrastructure

    Internal transaction costs For example, managing and monitoring workers and enforcing labor contracts

    Evaluating agricultural productivity levels among different farmers

    External transaction costs For example, negotiating with input suppliers, finding buyers and export markets Uncertainty with respect to others behavior

    Can input suppliers be trusted? Are they reliable? How can this be evaluated ex ante? As producers of agricultural products, the quality of these products may need to be

    inspected by end users (consumers or processors, for instance), which lead to the incurrence of transaction costs as well

    Biased contract enforcement or weak definition and enforcement of property rights also lead to uncertainty

  • Transaction Costs

    These transaction costs are then added to the transformation costs

    Transformation costs: the pure costs of production (transforming inputs into final output)

  • Implications of Transaction Costs for

    the Optimal Farm Size

    Farm Size

    Average

    Costs Internal transaction costs

    (e.g., monitoring labor)

    External transaction costs

    Transformation costs

    (Costs of production)

    Average

    Total costs

    Optimal

    Farm Size

  • Implications of Transaction Costs for

    the Optimal Farm Size

    Is there just one optimal farm size?

    No; it varies considerably based on different cost structures and the relative profitability of different farming activities

    Depends on management, production methods, etc.

    The previous graph is just one potential setup of a cost structure for a farm

    Illustrates that small farms may indeed be profitable, perhaps more so than relatively large farms

  • Implications for Transaction Costs for

    Farm Gate Prices

    With a given market price, the presence of high transaction costs will reduce farm gate prices

    If transaction costs were lower, this would thereby improve the prices seen by farmers for their agricultural products

    This could be seen as one policy objective in order to support incomes in rural regions

    Market price Farm gate

    price

    Transaction costs

  • Embedded Institutions and the

    Persistence of Large Farms in Russia

    Lets look at a specific case study to better understand the importance of institutions for

    the agricultural sector

    The paper by Koester and Petrick (2010) illustrates:

    The importance of embedded or informal institutions

    The role played by mental models in policy reform and current sector structure

    Why neoclassical economic approaches alone cannot explain the structure of the farm sector in Russia

    Koester, Ulrich and Martin Petrick (2010). Embedded Institutions and the Persistence of Large Farms in Russia. In Imre Ferto,

    Csaba Forgacs, Attila Jambor (eds.), Essays in Honour of Professor Csaba Csaki, Budapest, pp. 57-76.

  • Embedded Institutions and the

    Persistence of Large Farms in Russia

    The original expectation was that state and collective farms would be transformed into family farms

    The starting point was state and collective farms, as well as household farms

    Yet the actual development was relatively few family farms, super large corporate and cooperative farms, and extended family farms

    Some agroholdings have more than 50,000 hectares

    Koester, Ulrich and Martin Petrick (2010). Embedded Institutions and the Persistence of Large Farms in Russia. In Imre Ferto,

    Csaba Forgacs, Attila Jambor (eds.), Essays in Honour of Professor Csaba Csaki, Budapest, pp. 57-76.

  • Embedded Institutions

    These are the first level institutions identified in Williamson (2000)

    They are deeply ingrained, based on tradition, religion, and culture

    The informal institutions are informal rules of the game and their enforcement

    They influence the mental models of individuals

    Individuals beliefs, inferences, and goals

    Koester, Ulrich and Martin Petrick (2010). Embedded Institutions and the Persistence of Large Farms in Russia. In Imre Ferto,

    Csaba Forgacs, Attila Jambor (eds.), Essays in Honour of Professor Csaba Csaki, Budapest, pp. 57-76.

  • Koester, Ulrich (2005). A Revival of Large Farms in Eastern EuropeHow Important Are Institutions? Agricultural Economics,

    32(s1): 103-113.

  • Koester, Ulrich (2005). A Revival of Large Farms in Eastern EuropeHow Important Are Institutions? Agricultural Economics,

    32(s1): 103-113.

  • Koester, Ulrich and Martin Petrick (2010). Embedded Institutions and the Persistence of Large Farms in Russia. In Imre Ferto,

    Csaba Forgacs, Attila Jambor (eds.), Essays in Honour of Professor Csaba Csaki, Budapest, pp. 57-76.

  • Koester, Ulrich and Martin Petrick (2010). Embedded Institutions and the Persistence of Large Farms in Russia. In Imre Ferto,

    Csaba Forgacs, Attila Jambor (eds.), Essays in Honour of Professor Csaba Csaki, Budapest, pp. 57-76.

  • Koester, Ulrich and Martin Petrick (2010). Embedded Institutions and the Persistence of Large Farms in Russia. In Imre Ferto,

    Csaba Forgacs, Attila Jambor (eds.), Essays in Honour of Professor Csaba Csaki, Budapest, pp. 57-76.

  • Embedded Institutions in Russia

    Potential farmers relatively less willing to take risks, make changes, and be entrepreneurial Employees preferring to work on large farms

    Mental models of large farm managers, policy makers, and bureaucrats orienting them toward viewing large farms as having a comparative advantage Also with regard to ensuring food security

    Distrust of markets in ensuring food security

    Facing soft budget constraints, still Managers feeling partly obliged to provide social services

    Low willingness to rely on credit among farmers; issues with ascertaining credit-worthiness of potential clients among banks

    Koester, Ulrich and Martin Petrick (2010). Embedded Institutions and the Persistence of Large Farms in Russia. In Imre Ferto,

    Csaba Forgacs, Attila Jambor (eds.), Essays in Honour of Professor Csaba Csaki, Budapest, pp. 57-76.

  • Koester, Ulrich and Martin Petrick (2010). Embedded Institutions and the Persistence of Large Farms in Russia. In Imre Ferto,

    Csaba Forgacs, Attila Jambor (eds.), Essays in Honour of Professor Csaba Csaki, Budapest, pp. 57-76.

  • Economic Implications

    Sectoral production is fairly high, but

    Distorted markets

    High unemployment in rural areas

    Overly capital-intensive production

    High level of political influence of super-large farms

    Koester, Ulrich and Martin Petrick (2010). Embedded Institutions and the Persistence of Large Farms in Russia. In Imre Ferto,

    Csaba Forgacs, Attila Jambor (eds.), Essays in Honour of Professor Csaba Csaki, Budapest, pp. 57-76.

  • Prospects

    With market-driven structural change, the situation may change Yet this requires better functioning land, credit, insurance markets Better information and training

    Along with economies of scale arising from technological change, the return of the family farm is unlikely Will drive down internal transaction costs due to new monitoring

    technologies

    Will drive down transformation costs External transaction costs are biased in favor of large farms

    Think about political economy considerations here

    Koester, Ulrich and Martin Petrick (2010). Embedded Institutions and the Persistence of Large Farms in Russia. In Imre Ferto,

    Csaba Forgacs, Attila Jambor (eds.), Essays in Honour of Professor Csaba Csaki, Budapest, pp. 57-76.

  • Prospects

    With policy driven structural change, the situation may change Yet mental models are sticky over time Path dependence in agricultural organizational

    arrangements, institutional arrangements, and economic behavior

    Political influence of large agroholdings

    May have unintended consequences, high transition costs in the short run with policy driven structural change

    Koester, Ulrich and Martin Petrick (2010). Embedded Institutions and the Persistence of Large Farms in Russia. In Imre Ferto,

    Csaba Forgacs, Attila Jambor (eds.), Essays in Honour of Professor Csaba Csaki, Budapest, pp. 57-76.

  • Agricultural and Food Policy

  • Section Readings

    Koester, Ulrich and Ali El-Agraa (2003). The Common Agricultural Policy. In Ali El-Agraa

    (ed.), The European Union: Economics and Policies.

    Seventh Edition. Pearson Education Limited.

    Harlow, Essex, UK, pp. 354-390.

  • Agricultural and Food Policies

    Some often stated objectives among agricultural and food policy analysts (which may be [or are!] in discord with one another):

    1. Food security

    2. Agricultural income

    3. Efficiency in the agricultural sector

    4. Price stability

    5. Food safety

    6. Environmental concerns

    Source: Koester, Ulrich and Ali El-Agraa (2003). The Common Agricultural Policy. In Ali El-Agraa (ed.), The European Union:

    Economics and Policies. Seventh Edition. Pearson Education Limited. Harlow, Essex, UK, pp. 354-390.

  • Food Security

    Food security, as defined at the World Food Summit in 1996:

    Food security as existing when all people at all times have access to sufficient, safe, nutritious food

    to maintain a healthy and active life.

    Source: Koester, Ulrich and Ali El-Agraa (2003). The Common Agricultural Policy. In Ali El-Agraa (ed.), The European Union:

    Economics and Policies. Seventh Edition. Pearson Education Limited. Harlow, Essex, UK, pp. 354-390.

  • Food Insecurity

    Food insecurity exists, as defined in Cafiero (2013): (a) When people cannot access food, simply because food is

    not physically available where and when it is needed;

    (b) When people do not have economic access to food, meaning they lack the means to acquire the food even if the food would be at their physical reach;

    (c) When people can only afford to procure and eat combinations of foods that do not meet their preferences, are not safe, or are nutritionally unbalanced;

    (d) When any one of the above conditions holds even occasionally.

    Source: Cafiero, Carlo (2013). What Do We Really Know About Food Security? NBER Working Paper No. 18861.

  • Source: http://www.geostat.ge/

  • Monthly Real Food Price Indices (FAO, 2002-2004=100)

    0.0

    50.0

    100.0

    150.0

    200.0

    250.0

    300.0

    350.0

    1/

    1990

    7/

    1990

    1/

    1991

    7/

    1991

    1/

    1992

    7/

    1992

    1/

    1993

    7/

    1993

    1/

    1994

    7/

    1994

    1/

    1995

    7/

    1995

    1/

    1996

    7/

    1996

    1/

    1997

    7/

    1997

    1/

    1998

    7/

    1998

    1/

    1999

    7/

    1999

    1/

    2000

    7/

    2000

    1/

    2001

    7/

    2001

    1/

    2002

    7/

    2002

    1/

    2003

    7/

    2003

    1/

    2004

    7/

    2004

    1/

    2005

    7/

    2005

    1/

    2006

    7/

    2006

    1/

    2007

    7/

    2007

    1/

    2008

    7/

    2008

    1/

    2009

    7/

    2009

    1/

    2010

    7/

    2010

    1/

    2011

    7/

    2011

    1/

    2012

    7/

    2012

    1/

    2013

    Food Price Index

    Meat Price Index

    Dairy Price Index

    Cereals Price Index

    Oils Price Index

    Sugar Price Index

    Source: http://www.fao.org/worldfoodsituation/wfs-home/foodpricesindex/en/

  • Monthly Real Food Price Indices (FAO, 2002-2004=100)

    0.0

    20.0

    40.0

    60.0

    80.0

    100.0

    120.0

    140.0

    160.0

    180.0

    1/

    1990

    7/

    1990

    1/

    1991

    7/

    1991

    1/

    1992

    7/

    1992

    1/

    1993

    7/

    1993

    1/

    1994

    7/

    1994

    1/

    1995

    7/

    1995

    1/

    1996

    7/

    1996

    1/

    1997

    7/

    1997

    1/

    1998

    7/

    1998

    1/

    1999

    7/

    1999

    1/

    2000

    7/

    2000

    1/

    2001

    7/

    2001

    1/

    2002

    7/

    2002

    1/

    2003

    7/

    2003

    1/

    2004

    7/

    2004

    1/

    2005

    7/

    2005

    1/

    2006

    7/

    2006

    1/

    2007

    7/

    2007

    1/

    2008

    7/

    2008

    1/

    2009

    7/

    2009

    1/

    2010

    7/

    2010

    1/

    2011

    7/

    2011

    1/

    2012

    7/

    2012

    1/

    2013

    Food Price Index

    Food Price Index

    Source: http://www.fao.org/worldfoodsituation/wfs-home/foodpricesindex/en/

  • Monthly Real Food Price Indices (FAO, 2002-2004=100)

    0.0

    20.0

    40.0

    60.0

    80.0

    100.0

    120.0

    140.0

    160.0

    180.0

    9/

    2006

    11/

    2006

    1/

    2007

    3/

    2007

    5/

    2007

    7/

    2007

    9/

    2007

    11/

    2007

    1/

    2008

    3/

    2008

    5/

    2008

    7/

    2008

    9/

    2008

    11/

    2008

    1/

    2009

    3/

    2009

    5/

    2009

    7/

    2009

    9/

    2009

    11/

    2009

    1/

    2010

    3/

    2010

    5/

    2010

    7/

    2010

    9/

    2010

    11/

    2010

    1/

    2011

    3/

    2011

    5/

    2011

    7/

    2011

    9/

    2011

    11/

    2011

    1/

    2012

    3/

    2012

    5/

    2012

    7/

    2012

    9/

    2012

    11/

    2012

    1/

    2013

    Food Price Index

    Food Price Index

    Source: http://www.fao.org/worldfoodsituation/wfs-home/foodpricesindex/en/

  • Can the FAO Food Price Index Be Seen

    as a Measure of Food Security?

    Perhaps not.

    as more evidence is gathered on actual food availability and food consumption worldwide, there

    appears to be very limitedif anyrelationship

    between the time evolution of the FAO Food

    Price Index and the dynamics of supply and

    demand, what should be considered the

    fundamentals of price formation and food security

    (Cafiero, 2013)

    Source: Cafiero, Carlo (2013). What Do We Really Know About Food Security? NBER Working Paper No. 18861.

  • Food Security

    Roles played by transaction costs, market integration, and information flows

    Focus on understanding the policy and institutional environment

    Specific factors (e.g., extractive political and economic institutions) may be hindering trade flows

    across regions or investments in stockpiling

    Source: Koester, Ulrich and Ali El-Agraa (2003). The Common Agricultural Policy. In Ali El-Agraa (ed.), The European Union:

    Economics and Policies. Seventh Edition. Pearson Education Limited. Harlow, Essex, UK, pp. 354-390.

  • Back to Thinking About Policy

    Objectives

    With which other policy objective(s) might the objective of food security conflict?

    With the agricultural income objective If price support is used a policy instrument this would

    likely reduce food security

    With the efficiency objective Keeping farm prices artificially low wouldnt be cost-

    effective and may have other (political) economic distortions

    With other objectives it may be difficult to say

    Source: Koester, Ulrich and Ali El-Agraa (2003). The Common Agricultural Policy. In Ali El-Agraa (ed.), The European Union:

    Economics and Policies. Seventh Edition. Pearson Education Limited. Harlow, Essex, UK, pp. 354-390.

  • Given the Objective of Efficiency

    May seek to improve household incomes of those working in the rural economy or agricultural sector by improving incentives (e.g., not violating property rights) and promoting an enabling environment All of which require some form of redistributive

    transfers or taxation (even if just to invest in legal capacity for improving the definition and enforcement of property rights and the unbiased enforcement of contracts)

    Overarching roles of income and food prices

    Source: Koester, Ulrich and Ali El-Agraa (2003). The Common Agricultural Policy. In Ali El-Agraa (ed.), The European Union:

    Economics and Policies. Seventh Edition. Pearson Education Limited. Harlow, Essex, UK, pp. 354-390.

  • Income Growth in Agriculture

    There is a perception that income from the agricultural sector doesnt increase as much as

    income from other sectors in a growing

    economy

    Consider the following closed economy model with limited mobility of labor.

    Somewhat similar to the model above, but with some additional variables to consider.

    Source: Koester, Ulrich and Ali El-Agraa (2003). The Common Agricultural Policy. In Ali El-Agraa (ed.), The European Union:

    Economics and Policies. Seventh Edition. Pearson Education Limited. Harlow, Essex, UK, pp. 354-390.

  • Income Growth in Agriculture

    Let demand for an agricultural product () depend on income (), the price of the product () and the size of the population (N):

    = (, , )

    Let the supply of an agricultural product () depend on the price of the product () and technology ():

    = ,

    Assume that supply and demand are equated by the prevailing price, or that:

    =

    Source: Koester, Ulrich and Ali El-Agraa (2003). The Common Agricultural Policy. In Ali El-Agraa (ed.), The European Union:

    Economics and Policies. Seventh Edition. Pearson Education Limited. Harlow, Essex, UK, pp. 354-390.

  • Source: http://www.fastcoexist.com/1680400/100-years-ago-french-artists-predicted-the-future-with-eerie-accuracy#4

  • Income Growth in Agriculture

    Fully differentiating , we find the following:

    =

    +

    +

    Let =

    =

    and

    = 1; then we have

    =

    +

    +

    Source: Koester, Ulrich and Ali El-Agraa (2003). The Common Agricultural Policy. In Ali El-Agraa (ed.), The European Union: Economics and Policies. Seventh Edition. Pearson Education Limited. Harlow, Essex, UK, pp. 354-390.

  • Income Growth in Agriculture

    =

    +

    +

    (Let be negative)

    Letting

    = 1, we also have

    =

    +

    Because we assume that = , we have the following:

    +

    +

    =

    +

    We can solve for

    =

    Source: Koester, Ulrich and Ali El-Agraa (2003). The Common Agricultural Policy. In Ali El-Agraa (ed.), The European Union:

    Economics and Policies. Seventh Edition. Pearson Education Limited. Harlow, Essex, UK, pp. 354-390.

  • Income Growth in Agriculture

    =

    If the rate of technological change (

    ) is larger

    than the sum of the growth rate of income per

    person (times the income elasticity of demand)

    plus the growth rate of the population, then the

    price of the agricultural product will decrease

    (This is because < 0)

    Source: Koester, Ulrich and Ali El-Agraa (2003). The Common Agricultural Policy. In Ali El-Agraa (ed.), The European Union:

    Economics and Policies. Seventh Edition. Pearson Education Limited. Harlow, Essex, UK, pp. 354-390.

  • Income Growth in Agriculture

    Thus, technological change in agriculture will depress prices, but only under certain conditions

    With growth in income and population only, this would increase agricultural prices

    Yet technological change in agriculture has been sufficiently large to offset these effects for most of the past 50 years Along with a declining income elasticity of demand with

    higher incomes, flattening of population growth, technological progress has led to a lowering of food prices

    Yet think about the recent price spikes in food prices and other changes in supply and demand of agricultural products

    Source: Koester, Ulrich and Ali El-Agraa (2003). The Common Agricultural Policy. In Ali El-Agraa (ed.), The European Union:

    Economics and Policies. Seventh Edition. Pearson Education Limited. Harlow, Essex, UK, pp. 354-390.

  • Income Growth in Agriculture

    What happens to labor income with falling prices?

    Labor income in agriculture may not decline that much with growth in agricultural technology

    Depends critically on the price elasticities of supply and demand, which are functions of how well

    integrated sectoral labor markets may be

    Source: Koester, Ulrich and Ali El-Agraa (2003). The Common Agricultural Policy. In Ali El-Agraa (ed.), The European Union:

    Economics and Policies. Seventh Edition. Pearson Education Limited. Harlow, Essex, UK, pp. 354-390.

  • Growth in Different Sectors

    Idea that growth in the agricultural sector sparks growth in other sectors (Bezemer and Headey, 2008)

    Agricultural growth as pro-poor growth, especially if occurring on small family farms

    May aid growth by providing cheap food, raw materials, labour, savings, and demand for non-agricultural goods (Bezemer and Headey, 2008).

    Bezemer, Dirk and Derek Headey (2008). Agriculture, Development, and Urban Bias. World Development, 7: 1-40.

  • What Are Some (But Not All) Potential Sources of

    Agricultural Growth?

    Improvements in the institutional environment Importance of the absence of political violence The rule of law Constraints on the executive Protection of property rights Unbiased contract enforcement

    Market access Import bans or regulated and protected markets distort the prices seen by

    farmers in developing countries for their agricultural products

    Reduction of transaction costs Information flows, research and development, extension Development of rural markets for credit (e.g., micro-finance, rural

    banks, training of those working in these institutions to assess credit-worthiness, etc.), insurance, inputs, and outputs

  • Why Isnt Neoclassical Growth Theory

    Very Helpful?

    Not all factors may be employed

    (Restrictive) assumptions regarding the role of capital in the production process

    Other important inputs not considered

    Doesnt consider the sources of long run economic growth, how reorganization of the

    factors of production plays a role

  • Rodrik (2005)

    Policies that promote growth tend to be context specific and context appropriate

    Rodrik, Dani (2005). Growth Strategies. In Philippe Aghion and Steven Durlauf, eds.

    Handbook of Economic Growth, Amsterdam: North-Holland.

  • Rodrik, Dani (2005). Growth Strategies. In Philippe Aghion and Steven Durlauf, eds.

    Handbook of Economic Growth, Amsterdam: North-Holland.

  • Income Support Measures

    A large literature on the role of (conditional) cash transfers aimed at poverty reduction, improvements in child health and education

    In general: policy measures aimed at poverty reduction should focus as near as possible to the source of the problem and not its symptom(s) By-product distortions should be avoided as much as possible

    Lets think about the behavior of subsistence farmers and what policies may help reduce poverty among such farm households

  • Efficiency in Agriculture

    Importance of information about new technologies, production methods Research and extension

    Role of property rights and title transferring May incur high transaction costs if improper registration Uncertainty about the future returns of the land, interest rates for

    both buyers and sellers of land

    May be market challenges with respect to markets for land, rural credit, and insurance as a result of the general institutional environment, which may reduce the efficiency of the agricultural sector

    Source: Koester, Ulrich and Ali El-Agraa (2003). The Common Agricultural Policy. In Ali El-Agraa (ed.), The European Union:

    Economics and Policies. Seventh Edition. Pearson Education Limited. Harlow, Essex, UK, pp. 354-390.

  • Price Stability

    Consider a simple closed economy case in which supply is perfectly price inelastic. Suppose there is no storage and that all which is produced in the current period must be consumed at the same time:

    =

    Let = such that

    =

    =

    With = then

    =

    1

    Here, the percentage change in the price with a 1 percent change in quantity supplied will be larger when the price elasticity of demand is lower (in absolute terms)

    Of course, in the real world there will also be storage, so that market demand will be a function of current demand and of demand for storage The latter is a function of expected agricultural prices in future periods, storage

    costs

    Source: Koester, Ulrich and Ali El-Agraa (2003). The Common Agricultural Policy. In Ali El-Agraa (ed.), The European Union:

    Economics and Policies. Seventh Edition. Pearson Education Limited. Harlow, Essex, UK, pp. 354-390.

  • Policy Against Price Increases

    Quantity

    (khachapuris)

    2 GEL

    D1

    S1

    Price (khachapuri)

    Q1 Q2

    1 GEL

    D2

    Quantity Doesnt Increase

    Price Doesnt Change

    Results in Shortages of Khachapuris!

    <

    Q3

    Price ceiling

  • Food Safety

    Most farm products are experience goods (quality is revealed upon consumption) or credence goods

    (neither the quality nor the production process are

    known ex ante) rather than search goods (quality is

    known at the time of purchase)

    Incentives to create and preserve trust among producers, traders, especially with brand name products

    Yet there may be issues related to water quality, failures in supply chains, principal-agent problems, etc.

    Source: Koester, Ulrich and Ali El-Agraa (2003). The Common Agricultural Policy. In Ali El-Agraa (ed.), The European Union:

    Economics and Policies. Seventh Edition. Pearson Education Limited. Harlow, Essex, UK, pp. 354-390.

  • Environmental Concerns

    May be positive and negative externalities with agriculture

    Rapid transformation of the agricultural sector may induce environmental damage unless handled properly

    Source: Koester, Ulrich and Ali El-Agraa (2003). The Common Agricultural Policy. In Ali El-Agraa (ed.), The European Union:

    Economics and Policies. Seventh Edition. Pearson Education Limited. Harlow, Essex, UK, pp. 354-390.

  • Source: Yandle, Vijayaraghavan,

    and Bhattarai (2002)

  • Source: Yandle, Vijayaraghavan,

    and Bhattarai (2002)

  • Additional Objectives

    Agricultural development and rural development

    Solely supporting the former may not have the intended poverty alleviation effects

    Importance of investments in rural i