limits to urban growth: who benefits, who pays, who

38
LIMITS TO URBAN GROWTH: WHO BENEFITS, WHO PAYS, WHO DECIDES? A Commentary on the Current Planning Climate in Toronto L.S. Bourne Research Paper No. 68 Revised draft prepared for: Conference and Annual Meeting Canadian Council on Urban and Regional Research Toronto, September 19th, 1975 Centre for Urban and Community Studies University of Toronto August 1975

Upload: others

Post on 28-Apr-2022

3 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: LIMITS TO URBAN GROWTH: WHO BENEFITS, WHO PAYS, WHO

LIMITS TO URBAN GROWTH: WHO BENEFITS, WHO PAYS, WHO DECIDES?

A Commentary on the Current Planning Climate in Toronto

L.S. Bourne

Research Paper No. 68

Revised draft prepared for:

Conference and Annual Meeting Canadian Council on Urban and Regional Research

Toronto, September 19th, 1975

Centre for Urban and Community Studies

University of Toronto

August 1975

Page 2: LIMITS TO URBAN GROWTH: WHO BENEFITS, WHO PAYS, WHO

Preface

This paper represents a strictly personal interpretation of,

or more appropriately a reaction to, the current planning situation

and political climate in Toronto. It does not represent a position

taken by the Centre for Urban and Connnunity Studies, nor by any

of the projects or programs associated with the Centre.

The paper's concern is simple and certainly not original: de­

spite the considerable and obvious benefits achieved through the

evolution of the planning process in Toronto over the last two de­

cades, there has also been an increase in the negative side-effects

of that process. ~lost of these effects appear as higher costs for

those sectors of society least able to afford them; and most have

not been duly acknowledged. In the last few years as rigid physical

controls on urban growth - limiting suburb development and ceneral

area redevelopment in particular - have proliferated, these nega­

tive effects have in turn multiplied. This increase is unnecessary,

inequitable and regressive.

The central argument in the paper is, first, that we should

openly debate the redistribution of benefits and costs resulting from

limits on development, and second, that we should not introduce such

limits until that debate is satisfactorily resolved. Otherwise we

could inherit the worst of both urban worlds - the planned and the

unplanned. There is, as one reference to this paper notes, a cer­

tain viciousness to easy solutions which can and should be avoided.

Page 3: LIMITS TO URBAN GROWTH: WHO BENEFITS, WHO PAYS, WHO

LIMITS TO URBAN GROWTH: WHO BENEFITS, WHO PAYS, WHO DECIDES*

A Commentary on the Current Planning Climate in Toronto

L.S. Bourne University of Toronto

A great deal has been written both in Canada and abroad on the

management and control of growth in large metropolitan centres. One

example of this literature, and of the differing views on limiting urban

growth, is a three volume collection of papers released by the Urban

Institute in Washington (Scott, 1975). Everywhere the issues seem the

same: how to prevent or at least reduce the negative consequence of rapid

urban growth.

Much of the discussion in the Canadian context generally, and in

Toronto in particular, has, however, been superficial and, in many

instances, misleading. In part it is misleading because of a confusion

of concepts and goals. In part it is misleading and superficial

because it fails to account for the distribution of costs of alternative

solutions to the problems of growth. One result is that a number of

important questions, on what alternative futures for our cities are

feasible and/or desirable, which should be entering the growth debate,

are assigned low priority or are completely ignored. Another conse-

quence, evident in our newspapers, and in radio and television commen-

taries, is an increasing polarization of public opinion on what futures

are preferred and what policy actions are needed to achieve these

Page 4: LIMITS TO URBAN GROWTH: WHO BENEFITS, WHO PAYS, WHO

futures.

This concern is not new, and the author is by no means the first

or last to speak out on the subject. Nor is it intended here to create,

with the stroke of a pen, a single and widely acceptable perspective.

Instead, this paper simply attempts to clarify some basic but misused

concepts underlying the current debate, and to raise a number of diffi­

cult but essential questions relating to limits on urban growth. What

purposes are limits to growth designed to achieve? Who benefits (and

loses) from such limits. Who should decide if, when and how they are

to be applied?

All of the specific examples chosen for discussion relate to re­

cent events in Toronto, but most should be equally applicable to other

cities. The author's personal bias, as will be immediately evident to

the reader, is to oppose severe limits on growth (exch1ding obv.i.ous

abuses) until we can answer three basic questions: 1) what are the pur­

poses of such limits; 2) what are the consequences, intended and unin­

tended, of the application of these limits for different areas of the

city and for different sectors of society; and, 3) where should that

growth be redirected? I would be willing to argue that if responses to

these questions were obtained from many of the current advocates of

growth limits they would turn out to be, under close scrutiny, contra­

dictory. Of course we need to re-evaluate our attitudes to and

policies for urban and economic growth, and then if appropriate apply

limits to that growth. But only after we have effectively answered the

above questions and clarified what we believe the problem to be.

2

Page 5: LIMITS TO URBAN GROWTH: WHO BENEFITS, WHO PAYS, WHO

3

DEFINING GROWTH

First, what is urban growth and why is it a problem? Clearly, in

the Alice-in-Wonderland context of planning in Metro Toronto, the term

means whatever the individual writer or commentator wishes it to mean.

A quick content analysis of our daily newspapers reveals an almost

endless list of definitions and interpretations: the spread (or sprawl)

of urban land uses into the rural countryside, the construction of more

high-rises, more expressways, increased congestion, immigration, or

higher taxes; in other words, more people crowding in on your neighbour-

hood and preferred style of life.

One advantage of this multiplicity of interpretations is obvious.

Special interest groups with very diverse objectives can find agreement

on the need to introduce greater limits on growth without ever having

to specify exactly what and to whom they are to be applied. Politicians

can claim to be doing something for one group while actually assisting

another group. Many of these groups, in fact, are not even talking about

the same issues. Without a set of common premises from which to begin,

it is not surprising that the recent debate thus far has been largely un-

productive. That debate has awakened a renewed interest in the growth

issue, and in the quality of urban life generally. That interest must be

encouraged not confused and thwarted.

Is it possible to define terms such as growth more explicitly?

Growth is not one but a complex set of processes. To retreat into

theoretical terms for the moment, three basic types of growth, which

Kenneth Boulding (1953, 1970) has titled population, demographic and

1 structural growth, can be differentiated. The first, population growth

Page 6: LIMITS TO URBAN GROWTH: WHO BENEFITS, WHO PAYS, WHO

represents an absolute increase in the physical size of the body (or

system) under study, such as a geographic increase in the area or pop­

ulation size of a city. The second, demographic growth refers to

changes in the vertical or hierarchical ordering of elements in that

system. The term demographic growth is traditionally used in this con­

text because the most obvious example is the orderly movement of a popu­

lation over time through the sequence of age cohorts. Third, structural

growth, includes all changes in the relationships between parts or

elements of that same system.

4

While the meanings of the first two types of growth are relatively

straight-forward, that of structural growth is not. The essence of the

concept of structural growth is in the dynamic aspects of the organization

of the system under review. Structural growth is important precisely

because modern systems, such as cities, are dynamic interrelated entities.

A change in one area o~ sector has effects throughout the system. The

point might best be illustrated by referring, briefly, to the most

important of Boulding's principles of structural growth. In short, these

are: 1) that any increase in the size of a system necessitates a change

in the organizational structure of that system; 2) at any point in time

that organizational structure represents the sum of the laws of growth

affecting the system as a whole up to that time; 3) while the laws of

growth may determine the initial form or organization of the system, with

increasing size and complexity that form in turn begins to dominate in

shaping the structure of future growth; and 4) the critical link in

understanding growth is identifying the manner in which the parts of the

system interact.

Page 7: LIMITS TO URBAN GROWTH: WHO BENEFITS, WHO PAYS, WHO

5

Cities, obviously, display all three types of growth. Moreover

the growth of cities can be shown to follow the principles outlined by

Boulding for systems in general. The interested reader can make the

translation easily. Each of the three types is important in its own

right and each should be approached with appropriately sensitive policy

measures. The complex relationships between the three types are also

significant. For example the third type, structural growth, can occur

without the first two, such as with shifts in government forms or through

the:impact of social or technological change on the mix of housing or

transportation, but the reverse in terms of Boulding's principles is

not possible.

All three types of growth may present problems, but they are not

necessarily the same problems. This simple fact is the source of much

of our confusion. If, for instance, the absolute growth or expansion of

our cities was to be severely limited, structural change would likely

continue apace if not accelerate. In fact most people react to the rate

of demographic and particularly structural change, rather than to an

absolute increase in population size. In Toronto the rate of structural

change has of late been hectic. Sudden and often unanticipated social

changes, massive and frequently ugly developments in both the suburbs

and the city, widespread demolition of familiar landmarks and buildings

through redevelopment, increasing visual chaos, traffic congestion, air

pollution, noise, and excessive demands on social services, housing and

transportation, are obvious examples. Among the many implications of

these changes has been the growing feeling that existing institutions and

the legislative machinery for public policy formulation are inadequate to

Page 8: LIMITS TO URBAN GROWTH: WHO BENEFITS, WHO PAYS, WHO

6

deal with the. complexities of contemporary growth.

These trends are valid concerns for urban planning and must be

dealt with as soon and as intelligently as possible. Where necessary. new

institutional forms must be introduced and new policies devised to meet

these problems. But these policies should not be introduced so as to

create new and potentially larger problems and certainly not at the cost

of introducing new or greater social inequalities. This, unfortunately,

is what in many instances we are presently doing.

Our local politicians have frequently acted to deceive us. The

above growth-related issues, and the suggestions made as solutions, are

not nearly as clear-cut or as strongly polarized, as they often argue

or imply. Instead, we are confronted in discussing problems of urban

growth with what are classic examples of complex and highly inter­

dependent "mega problems", which in some instances seem almost intract­

able. Some politicians have seen fit to polarize the issues in order,

they say, to add clarity to the alternatives. Instead they have distorted

the real issues and the potential consequences of their actions.

DEFINING THE AREA OF INTEREST

A secondary, but nonetheless significant source of confusion in

mat~hing problems with solutions in the current growth debate, is the

different meanings assigned to the terms of city and urban. The diffi­

culty is a common one. In the media reference is made to, say, the

city, or simply Toronto, but seldom with a note on what area or popu­

lation is intended. To some it refers only to the core area, to others

it is the political city area, or the metropolitan municipality, while

Page 9: LIMITS TO URBAN GROWTH: WHO BENEFITS, WHO PAYS, WHO

7

to others it means the extended region (i.e. Toronto-centred region) for

which Toronto serves as the central focus.

Although each concept of what is urban area of interest is valid

for particular purposes, none are valid for all purposes. Only one is

suitable as a basis for the debate on growth - the geographic area which

is the economically functioning urban unit that is the organizational

entity through which growth occurs (i.e. the metropolitan area, or the

political unit closest to it). This does not mean that the debate on

growth should not go on at more local levels within. Rather, it argues

that the fundamental context for that debate must be the system ex­

periencing growth. Needless to say, confusion in the simple frame of

reference used for discussing policy seriously undermines the potential

utility of those policies.

MYTHS

Canadian thinking on the problems of our cities is also heavily

clouded by the myth of the inevitability of recent trends in urban growth.

One aspect of this myth (using the term broadly) relates to the pre­

vailing effect of images of the American "urban model" on our policy think-

ing. We are flooded in the popular media by reports on the deter-

iorating conditions in American cities. Forecasts of our urban fate are

made by drawing parallels with what has or is currently happening to

American urban areas. It is argued, for instance, that if continued high­

rise construction is allowed we will eventually have a Manhattan in

central Toronto; and, that if Ne build expressways, or a new airport, or

permit more housing on the fringe of the built-up urban area, then Toronto

Page 10: LIMITS TO URBAN GROWTH: WHO BENEFITS, WHO PAYS, WHO

8

will become another Los Angeles. Further it seems to be taken for granted

that more people, housing, office buildings and expressways mean more

crime ands:>cial unrest. Why? Because American cities appear to show all

of these properties. Therefore, there must be a cause and effect relation­

ship. This is largely nonsense (spurious correlations as the analyst

might say). Such cause-and-effect relationships are very difficult to

substantiate. Clearly limits to physical growth will not prevent crime.

The latter is a far more complex problem. Nor is it apparent that re­

lationships identified in U.S. cities will necessarily hold in the

Canadian context. American and Canadian cities may in fact grow less,

not more, alike in the future.

The above criticism should not be interpreted as saying that

American cities do not have serious problems, or that we in Canada cannot

learn from their experience in dealing with these problems. They do and

we can. But it does suggest that we must stop importing simplistic

parallels in urban development and correlates of social change from

south of the border, or from abroad. Certainly they should not be used

as a means of defending positions on the kind of cities we want in Canada.

Instead, we should be able to defend these preferences in our own terms.

What we need are our own ideal urban models as guides in the growth

debate, and in selecting alternative urban forms.

Much of the anti-American city feeling implicit in the above

parallels, as well as in the arguments for physical limits on urban growth,

also contains an element of environmental determinism. That is, the po­

sition that particular kinds of architecture, housing or site planning or,

more generally, specific physical environments will produce certain types

Page 11: LIMITS TO URBAN GROWTH: WHO BENEFITS, WHO PAYS, WHO

9

of social outcomes. It is said, for example, that some environments in­

evitably lead to crime, social alienation and civic disorder. Of course,

physical environments can accommodate, if not stimulate certain types of

behaviour, both social and anti-social, but they generally do not produce

that behaviour. Physical planning clearly should do all that it can to

facilitate and stimulate positive social behaviour, and to encourage a

more sensitive and positive attitude toward environmental considerations

in the planning and developing of our cities. We certainly need a change

in attitudes. But deviant behaviour is a social problem not a physical

or architectural one.

Environment determinism is not just an outdated perspective, it

is potentially dangerous. Using the physical environment, or in the

context of this paper, limits on physical growth, densities, land use

change, etc, to achieve social goals, is doomed to failure. Those goals

should be approached directly, through social rather than physical

policies. Worst still, since we do not adequately understand the complex

relationships between urban environments and human behaviour in cities,

we may simply create new forms of social problems through ill-advised

policies. At a minimum, by arguing that physical limits to growth can

solve social problems, we will raise aspirations which cannot be satis­

fied in the short run, and in the process divert attention from the real

social issues. One reason that we hear so much of this line of argument,

based on physical environmental determinism, from local politicians and

planners is because physical planning is essentially all that they

exercise direct control over.

Another catch-phrase, or more appropriately a blatant misuse of

Page 12: LIMITS TO URBAN GROWTH: WHO BENEFITS, WHO PAYS, WHO

10

terms, adding further to the confusion of issues, is urban sprawl.

Everyone is against sprawl, and with good reasons. But in many Canadian

cities these days every new development proposed for the fringe of the

built-up urban area regardless of its need or merit, is classed as

sprawl, and therefore must be stopped. In Toronto at least this inter­

pretation is often intentional, designed precisely to polarize public

opinion against new development proposals. Sprawl, in fact, is a highly

loaded term. It means the ugly, discontinuous, largely unplanned and

inefficient spread of urban development into rural areas. Land is

wasted, local services are often poor or non-existent and viable public

transportation is next to impossible. No one supports that kind of

development, but there are other ways and means of preventing it.

As such, urban sprawl is a very different phenomenon from that of

a well-planned, orderly extension of the suburban margin of a growing

city. In most Canadian cities, and certainly in the Toronto region, we

have both sprawl and planned extensions. Unfortunately both are fre­

quently lumped together in discussing the options for redistributing new

growth. What we need to do is to identify what quantity and quality of

growth is necessary and then to seek ways of accomodating or redirecting

it in desired directions. Even the latter - suburban extension - is

not desirable if allowed to continue at an excessive rate, or indef~

initely, or if permitted to destroy in the process critical environmental

resources. It is, however, preferable to a rapid escalations in land

costs, and severe housing shortages. To recommend stopping it, period,

as has been suggested in Toronto, before the rate of population growth

and thus the demand for land, slows or-is effectively diverted elsewhere,

Page 13: LIMITS TO URBAN GROWTH: WHO BENEFITS, WHO PAYS, WHO

11

is irresponsible. How else are we to provide the homes and job locations

for those future generations of households who wish to locate in these

cities?

WHO BENEFITS AND WHO PAYS?

Solutions proposed to the above complex problems of urban growth,

by definition, involve difficult decisions on trade-offs. That is, the

difficult question lies in assessing the relative incidence or distri­

bution of benefits and costs from urban growth and planning policies.

Who pays for and who benefits from physical limits imposed on suburban

extension, on densities, on traffic, on the mix of housing provided,

or on urban redevelopment generally? The same concern applies for that

matter to any public action since most have a differential impact on

sectors of the population they are intended to serve.

That there are always some winners and losers in the urban

planning and political game is inevitable. Who these people are is not

always clear, except that is for the usual group of losers: the poor

and the unrepresented. While we may not be able to completely remove

such inequalities, without at least a more equalitarian social system,

we should be willing to acknowledge their existence and seek to reduce

their most serious impacts. Generally, and in my view unacceptably,

our politicians have failed to fully appreciate the substantial and un­

equal redistributive effects of their actions. The rush to impose phy­

sical limits on urban growth is but one case illustrating the general

point.

Consider a few other examples from Toronto's recent planning

Page 14: LIMITS TO URBAN GROWTH: WHO BENEFITS, WHO PAYS, WHO

experience. A uniform one-fare transit price was recently introduced

across Metro, replacing the previous two-fare system oriented to the

subway system. Those not living within the central zone (zone one),

and not within walking distance of the subway, paid a double fare. The

argument for uniform pricing was, simply, that people living in the

outer suburbs (zone two) should not pay more to travel downtown than

those in the inner zone. This was, in fact, a remarkably broad pers­

pective for an urban community increasingly dominated by local area

interests. And it also has on the surface an equalitarian touch. But

what specific redistributive consequences does it have?

12

One obvious question is to again ask, who benefits? Clearly a

shift in the burden of costs of public transit usage has taken place~ _For

instance, the relatively less affluent of the inner-city(who, on

average make short transit trips and because of their more central

locations pay more for their housing per square: foot), now face an in­

crease in the subsidy they effectively pay to the more affluent resi­

dents in the outer part of the city and in the suburbs (who tend to make

longer trips to work and who initially at least paid less for their land

and housing). In fact the choice of higher transit costs (in both money

and time) to obtain lower house prices was a major consideration affecting

the decisions these people made to live in outlying locations. Another

obvious consequence of this change in transit pricing has been to add

substantially to the rapidly rising deficits of the public transit system

and thus to contribute to the recent substantial increase in fares.

Higher fares, of course, again penalize the frequent short-distance

riders most severely, and are thus essentially a regressive tax. Further,

Page 15: LIMITS TO URBAN GROWTH: WHO BENEFITS, WHO PAYS, WHO

13

a lower fare from the suburbs to downtown has the effect of encouraging

longer commuting trips, particularly to the central core - a result

which conflicts with other stated policy goals, such as the reduction

of long-distance commuting and the decentralization of employment.

People will be encouraged to live further out from downtown and house

prices will rise. The only uniform fare structure which makes much

sense is free public transit. That policy at least has less obvious re­

distributive effects. 2

Or, think of some of the consequences of recent pressures to in-

crease residential densities. At present zoning policies encourage a

distinct polarization of opportunities for new households to purchase

housing: into those groups who can afford housing on 50 to 60 foot-

wide lots, and those in ro~ housing on 20 to 25 foot lots (or in apart-

ments). This is obviously discriminatory. A much wider range of

zoned lot sizes is appropriate and financially necessary. Without that

greater range pressures to increase densities will, simply and directly,

increase land costs.3

Again, the benefits of higher land prices will

be received primarily by existing landowners and landlords. The costs

will be paid by ~enters and by future generations.

Investment in urban parks provides another illustration. Pres-

sures for improving the quality of local residential environments have

increased, and appropriately so. One direction these arguments have

taken is for the provision of new parkland and for the expansion of

existing parks within heavily built-up areas. No one could possibly

oppose such objectives. The problem again is one of allocating costs

and benefits. First, there are always alternative uses for scarce re-

Page 16: LIMITS TO URBAN GROWTH: WHO BENEFITS, WHO PAYS, WHO

14

sources in the public sector, and so more parks has to be justified

against other priorities. Assuming we can make this justification, the

second problem is to decide how these resources are to be allocated to

different special interest groups and to different areas of the city,

both of which have a tremendous impact on patterns of social welfare in

our cities. Which groups and areas receive most of these resources?

Obviously it is those who scream the loudest, those who are well­

organized, and those who haunt the corridors of municipal power. In

other words, the wealthy and professional classes, those who already

control most of the resources.

In Toronto recently we have seen major extensions to several

existing urban parks, at a cost of several million dollars. Most of the

additions are needed, and can easily be justified in total. Many,

however, as in the recent example of Ramsden Park in the northcentral

part of the city, are located in relatively prosperous neighbourhoods.

As a result of park expansions adjacent houses secure a net positive

capital gain, at no cost to them (except taxes, which everyone pays).

They gain through substantially increased housing prices, yet do not pay

the costs. Meanwhile those areas initially poorly endowed with parks,

but who also pay taxes, are still without parks. This is not to question

the need for parks, but the inequitable distribution of benefits which

can result from public decisions on park location.

Numerous other examples of the problem could be cited. The first

subway in Toronto along Yonge Street was built through predominately

high-income residential and commercial areas. The substantial land

value increments which resulted from its construction went primarily

Page 17: LIMITS TO URBAN GROWTH: WHO BENEFITS, WHO PAYS, WHO

15

to those who already owned land or had purchased homes in such areas.

This is the well-known conflict between public costs and private gains.

Returning to the central point of this paper, politicians sel­

dom publicly evaluate the balance and distribution of costs and benefits.

Some argue for limiting the spread of the suburbs without asking whose

future homes and job opportunities they are reducing by doing so. New

density and height by-laws are introduced in the central core to pro­

vide two years for planners to work out new development controls and

planning objectives. Aside from the inherent difficulty of using phy-

sical controls to achieve non-physical objectives, such time delays are

a luxury only some can afford. The demand for housing and jobs cannot

sit out for two years while new objectives are sought.4

If the impression is coming through to the reader from the above

arguments that much of the recent anti-growth debate in my view smacks

of elitism and self-interest, the impression is correct. There are

no doubt good reasons for each of the above policies. But good reasons

for whom? In the specific example of political pressures to limit

urban growth, without providing alternative locations for that growth,

before such limits are imposed, the social costs are clearly too high.

Moreover the costs are generally placed, as previously noted, on those

sectors of society who can least afford them. In each case cited one

of the obvious results is to redistribute wealth within the city -

largely, as noted above, to those who already have houses or land, or

professional status. The actual redistribution of real wealth may be

less than that which our capitalistic system inevitably achieves in the

normal course of events. But why should the public sector add to it?

Page 18: LIMITS TO URBAN GROWTH: WHO BENEFITS, WHO PAYS, WHO

16

THE OPTIONS

What are some of the options for redirecting growth at the local

level? One of the points the author has made elsewhere (Globe and Mail,

November 30, 1974; Toronto Star, February 5, 1975), is that a single

municipality cannot determine its future growth path alone. Certainly,

in the case of Toronto, the central city cannot. To attempt to do so,

as is so often the case, in splendid isolation, may seriously distort

patterns ofvelfare and the distribution of social opportunities within

the urban area. It could do so by adding to the cost and difficulty

of building the homes, workplaces, schools and services which we so ob-

viously need, and by assigning higher net positive benefits (external~

ities) through public actions to specific groups ( and areas ) without

a corresponding increase in the social costs these groups must bear.

Physical limits to urban growth as such may be counter-produc-

tive for other reasons. First, there are few examples of situations in

which they have worked as anticipated. Often, where their application

has heen.ma~estly successful, as in England, many of the old problems

have simply arisen in other locations, and new problems have appeared

5 in place of the old. And to be even modestly successful such limits

generally require vast expenditures to encourage that growth to locate

elsewhere. Debates on whether the results have justified the costs con-

tinue (Rose, 1974). Physical limits also focus attention on artifacts

(i.e. buildings) rather than people. While one can freeze land uses,

or densities, or housing, one cannot freeze-in the occupants.

Second, and perhaps the most important reason why such limits

may be increasingly counter-productive, is that the conditions which

Page 19: LIMITS TO URBAN GROWTH: WHO BENEFITS, WHO PAYS, WHO

17

generated the need for such limits are changing and changing rapidly.

Absolute growth is declining. Birth rates have reached their lowest

level since the 1930's. Economic growth is increasingly uncertain.

Unemployment is up and labour mobility is down. Migration patterns are

changing. The trend is away from the major metropolises toward medium

and small urban centres. Toronto (the 1971 census metropolitan area),

for instance, is now sending more migrants to other metropolitan areas

inOmada (except to Montreal and cities in the Maritimes) than it re­

ceives. This trend may well accelerate if the differential in the cost

of living between cities expands. In Toronto this differential is due

in part to continued political uncertainty and ad hoc limits on develop­

ment. Toronto's population is still growing relatively rapidly because

of foreign in-migration.

The options then, in terms of redirecting absolute growth, are

severely limited and are decreasing. There is also a great deal of

inertia in the locational decisions of households and firms. While all

three levels ofg>vernment in Canada, in twenty years, may be able to

achieve some redistribution of population growth away from the main

metropolitan areas, it is more likely that external events will con­

tinue to overtake such policies. A further decline in birth rates,

reduced rates of rural out-migration, possibly lower immigration levels,

continued economic difficulties and inflation - will combine to produce

slower overall growth rates, and some redistribution of that growth,

without government intervention.

The point is that conditions external to an individual city will

largely determine the future course of population growth and change in

that city. This does not imply that local urban planning is irrelevant.

Page 20: LIMITS TO URBAN GROWTH: WHO BENEFITS, WHO PAYS, WHO

18

Much can and should be done by local authorities to improve the quality

of the local urban environment. Specifically, they can act to shape or

to allocate that externally-derived growth between areas within the

city and between the central city, the suburbs and the rural fringe.

Rather, the argument is that we must have co-ordinated (rather than con­

tradictory) planning at the three levels of government to achieve what­

ever overall rate and distribution of urban growth that is desired

and appropriate.

One popular option which can be immediately dismissed is to

freeze development generally or to fix an optimal size for a city.

Numerous observers have pointed out that no such optimum exists (Rich­

ardson, 1972). Even if it did exist we could not get there, nor

could we stay there once we arrived. The same applies to local areas

within the city. Neighbourhood stability, for example long a pet

policy objective of our politicians and planners, cannot mean a fixed

population or housing stock, although this is the impression they often

seem to give, unless the neighbourhood becomes a prison. Instead it

means the absence of abrupt and unexpected changes. There will in­

evitably be a steady throughput of population,and gradual environ­

mental change, in any neighbourhood. Stability then means change

which is ordered and balanced and which leads to (or allows for)

evolutionary rather than revolutionary social change.

What may be more appropriate for policy-makers is to search for

optimal rates of urban change - in terms of population, demographic and

structural growth as previously defined - for neighbourhoods, larger

areas, and for cities as a whole. To do so, however, requires full co-

Page 21: LIMITS TO URBAN GROWTH: WHO BENEFITS, WHO PAYS, WHO

operation from all parties involved. A complete or selective growth

freeze, as argued above, without well thought out alternatives, simply

freezes the opportunities available to some members of society but not

others.

19

There is little evidence in the urban growth literature that the

size of a city is strongly correlated with any of our major policy

problems, at least not on a statistically consistent basis. There are

large cities in Canada which are ugly, polluted, congested, costly-to­

live-in and saddled with serious social problems. There are also small

cities with the same problems ~ttributes) or with others equally serious.

The origin of these urban problems lies elsewhere - in social inequities,

inadequate income and tax policies, limited imagination in urban design,

governmental inertia, the lack of pollution controls, and in social

attitudes. Such problems should be tackled directly, not indirectly

through limits on city size.

It should be emphasized, however, that excessively high rates of

population growth and structural change render solutions to such problems

and the attainment of other social goals, all that more difficult.

Rapid growth increases uncertainty and telescopes planning activities

on predominantly short-term problems. Longer term perspectives become

less relevant and more difficult to sustain.

MISUSE OF URBAN LAND

One partial solution to the problem of improving urban environ­

ments without severe limits on growth is through the more rationale

use of existing urban land. Hundreds of vacant sites within our

Page 22: LIMITS TO URBAN GROWTH: WHO BENEFITS, WHO PAYS, WHO

20

cities could be used for homes or small parks, offices and industries.

There are also many marginally used and under-used areas, particularly

in connnercial, industrial, warehousing and railroad districts, for

which redevelopment to higher densities would be a welcome environmental

improvement. Granted, some are already scheduled for future redevelop­

ment, and others are held in speculation of future development. But

most are likely to continue to be marginally used because the property

tax system allows them to continue in that situation (by taxing actual

improvements rather than development potential), ·and because our out­

moded zoning system discourages a mixture of different activities within

small areas and slows the process of space rationalization through land

use change.

Selective redevelopments in such areas, for mixed or purely resi­

dential use, using tax incentives or public acquisition if necessary,

would expand housing and job opportunities available throughout our

urban areas. Redevelopment can increase the population within easy

reach of public transit, augment the municipal property tax base and

generally improve the visual texture and quality of the built environ­

ment; all without the widespread destruction of existing and viable

neighbourhoods or without severely limiting the opportunities for new

developments on the margins of the urban area.

A simple fact commonly overlooked in the current growth debate

is that the city, to quote a well-known phrase, is an interrelated

system. Limits on development in one area or sector, usually result in

increased pressures in other areas or sectors. Conversely, since the

demand for urban space is, in the short term at least, finite, develop-

Page 23: LIMITS TO URBAN GROWTH: WHO BENEFITS, WHO PAYS, WHO

ment incentives applied in one area or sector can act to relieve press-

6 ures elsewhere. In particular, development on the fringe of a city and

redevelopment of the central core are interrelated. In other words,

the reuse of existing urban land can take the heat off older neighbour-

hoods and provide new housing, while at the same time achieving other

secondary goals (i.e. more transit riders, environmental conservation,

7 But who do we preserve old neighbourhoods for? etc.).

It is also possible through redevelopment to increase gross

residential densities (based on the proportion of land in housing

21

relative to all other uses) without necessarily increasing net densities

(the amount of residential land per person of household). This dis-

tinction is seldom made explicit. It is not clear that a reduction in

the amount of residential land (or housing space) in our cities is

socially warranted. At least we do not know the consequences of such

a reduction. On the other hand, it is clear that gross residential

densities can be increased, with apparently positive consequences in

large part.

WHO DECIDES?

Who determines what these goals should be? How are priorities

to be set? Who is to decide on the options? In the current debate

on limits to urban growth, in Toronto at least, there are many who

assume that they have the insight and the right, to specify the goals

and to select the options. In some instances these options are, as

noted in the introduction, polar opposites and in most cases they are

clearly elitist. 8

Page 24: LIMITS TO URBAN GROWTH: WHO BENEFITS, WHO PAYS, WHO

Some argue that we should substantially increase densities in

housing construction. Some say flatly that no more single-family

homes should be built in Toronto because they consume too much land;

22

or that all new growth should be redirected elsewhere, anywhere but

here. Others say the automobile and the high-capacity road are dead;

public transit is the only hope. Some argue for freezing employment

growth in the central core of our cities and the redistribution of

those jobs to suburban mini-downtowns and to outlying centres.9 Still

others want to build residential units into downtown high-rise office

buildings to achieve some mysterious "balance" of land uses in the core.

But whose preferences do these proposals reflect? How is land

to be valued? By whom? Whose jobs are to be decentralized? What is

this balance of land uses? Whether the above preferences derive from

the relevant subset of the general public is not known. At least the

proplonents of such policies do not likely know. The point here is not

that any of these positions or proposals are in themselves wrong, but

that we do not know whose views they represent. Clearly the problem is

one of free public choice.

People simply have not in most instances been presented with the

alternatives and asked to choose between them (i.e. loss of rural land

to obtain single-family homes), given a set of possible consequences from

each choice. Public hearings on development proposals, and the organi­

zation of local (territorial) special interest groups do not solve the

problem. The former are artificial and non-participatory. The latter

are dominated by self-interest, by a desire to preserve the status-quo

and are usually non-representative of the groups they affect. As special

interest groups, almost by definition, they cannot raise or resolve

Page 25: LIMITS TO URBAN GROWTH: WHO BENEFITS, WHO PAYS, WHO

23

questions of trade-offs in public choice.

Somehow the planning process must facilitate if not encourage a

diversity of input to the setting of development goals and in the choice

of alternative policies. These should reflect the diversity of preferen­

ces, opinions and needs represented in any large city. The purpose is

to achieve a more balanced set of future options than we are receiving

in the current polarized world of urban planning in Toronto. Equally

important, the needs of those not usually represented in the debate (i.e.

those not yet of voting age, potential migrants, non-participants and

the disenfranchised), must also be considered.

Possibly we need a reorganized governmental structure in the larger

Canadian cities fo facilitate this expression of opinions. (Golden, 1975).

Not more levels of government, but different levels in which the dis­

tribution of responsibilities for planning and urban development more

closely approximates the realities of a changing urban environment.

Some decision-making responsibilities clearly need to be decentralized,

others centralized.

The political municipality of Metro Toronto, as was true of the

City of Toronto in 1953, is currently too small for many planning pur­

poses; if for no other reason than the obvious fact that most suburban

extensions are now taking place outside its present boundaries. Within

the next decade virtually all suburban growth will be outside Metro.

That is, Metro will become the central city of an even larger urban

mass.10 But Metro is also too large at present for other purposes.

Similarly, thelnroughs are too large to represent cohesive communities

in any sense of the word. On the other hand, neighbourhood groups are often

Page 26: LIMITS TO URBAN GROWTH: WHO BENEFITS, WHO PAYS, WHO

small, and too provincial, to carry responsibilities for all but very

local planning activities. Are we seriously looking for solutions in

government structure, or are we masking the important questions on

social responsibility with trivial debates on physical limits to urban

growth?

THE WORST OF BOTH WORLDS?

Present trends in urban planning in many Canadian cities, cer-

tainly in Toronto, leave one with the impression that we may be

heading for some of the worst results (or costs) of both the planned

and the unplanned urban worlds. Compare our present situation with

that in Britain and the U.S. for instance. In the former planning and

local development controls are both elaborate and rigid, while in the

latterruch controls are generally inconsistent, weak and in many in-

stances, simply non-existent. Again taking Toronto as an example, we

have witnessed many of the same negative consequences (or social costs)

as have occurred through stricter planning measures in Britain, where

constraints on urban development and land use, particularly around

London, have been operating since before WWII;1

It should not surprise

24

us to find that there are costs attributable to British planning measures

or that some sectors of society have lost and others have benefitted

handsomely from development controls such as green-belts, rural land

preservation and the like. Hall and Clawson (1973) have documented a

number of these consequences in a recent comparison of British and

American planning experience.

On the other hand we seem to have few of the benefits of British

Page 27: LIMITS TO URBAN GROWTH: WHO BENEFITS, WHO PAYS, WHO

25

urban planning: such as the relative absence of urban sprawl, a more

rationale use of urban land, the stricter preservation of historical

landmarks, and the conservation of rural environments and valuable agri­

cultural land; combined with an on-going program to stimulate housing

construction while decentralizing population into new towns and alter­

native growth centres. Such benefits can to some extent be balanced­

off against the social costs of strict growth limits in other locations

(i.e. London). In Toronto, as in London, these costs have included

very high land and housing prices (Toronto and Vancouver, for example,

now have about the highest housing prices on this continent), high

commercial rents, a declining choice in housing through limits on the

amount of housing and service land provided, higher overall (net)

densities, and increased traffic congestion. These conditions, notably

increased costs, have a tendency to sort out the populations of urban

areas by income and occupation, and to redistribute income from

renters to owners. Donnison and Eversley (1973) have argued this case

in London.

Compared to most U.S. cities, in contrast, we fortunately do not

have many of their same severe social and fiscal problems. But we also

now seem to be missing many of the benefits deriving from their weaker

planning controls (yes, there still are such benefits). These benefits

include relatively more abundant and substantially lower-cost housing,

lower net residential densities and,although open to argument, a some­

what greater variety-in the choice of places to live and work. Yet we

still have many of the disadvantages typically equated with the lack of

planning in American cities - discontinuous, ugly and often inefficiently

serviced suburban areas, the destruction of viable communities, the loss

Page 28: LIMITS TO URBAN GROWTH: WHO BENEFITS, WHO PAYS, WHO

of historical and architectural heritage, poor public transit, and the

growing destruction of our rural countryside - the characteristics of

urban sprawl and unplanned redevelopment cited above.

On the whole most Canadian cities, even Toronto, are still

relatively pleasant places to live. Some of their advantages over

American cities are a direct result of planning and political action.

But most are fortunate outcomes or factors (accidents) of timing and

circumstances. These factors include the relative absence in the inner

cities~f large concentrations of distinctively disadvantaged minorities;

the absence of a massive highway building fund, at the same time as

expressway construction was popular, as existed during the 1950's and

1960's in the U.S.; our relatively late arrival (except for Montreal) in

the competition to build large civic monuments; and somewhat more inno­

vative attempts at local government reorganization to improve the pro­

vision of urban services.

26

Our cities can be better, but only through a co-ordination of

government activities within and between different levels of Government,

and on the basis of a full and honest debate of the pros and cons of

alternative development strategies. Growth can be the vehicle to achieve

desired alternatives. Growth limits, without positive directives for re­

distributing or reshaping that growth, are both a waste of effort and

likely a very costly proposition. Why not seek the best of both

worlds?

WHAT AND WHOSE FUTURE?

The assertion "our city (neighbourhood, ward, block etc.) should

Page 29: LIMITS TO URBAN GROWTH: WHO BENEFITS, WHO PAYS, WHO

27

determine its own future", is frequently heard in the current debate

as a rationale for limiting growth at specific locations. But such

assertions are not very helpful and may in fact be misleading. Of

course everyone should determine his or her our future. The more

appropriate and difficult questions, however, are: to what degree can

an individual city or community determine its future rate of growth?

What effect will this have on other cities or communities? How should

the desire to alter growth patterns at one level in the urban hierarchy

(i.e. the municipal city) be integrated with other desires at other

levels (i.e. the urban region or the nation). How might this balance of

objectives be determined? What types of growth can be accommodated and

what types need to be altered? What (and whose) future opportunities

are we thinking of? What we must continually ask is the question: who

benefits and who pays?

CONCLUSIONS

Many of the above criticisms may seem to be basically conservative.

Others may appear to reject outright controls on urban growth and govern­

ment intervention in urban development generally. They are not meant to

do so. Rather, the reverse is true. The author would in fact argue for

much tighter controls on development, and specifically for greater public

sector ownership and participation in the land market, but only in a

responsible and open manner. This paper is not the place to go into such

details of personal preferences and biases.

The preceding criticisms are directed against the ad hoc and un­

even application of ~igid planning controls. That is, controls which are

Page 30: LIMITS TO URBAN GROWTH: WHO BENEFITS, WHO PAYS, WHO

28

often designed to serve particular vested interest groups, and which are

applied with little or no thought to those negatively affected by the

controls. What is particularly annoying to this observer is the use of

one set of quite valid controls (i.e. historic building preservation) to

12 justify another set (i.e. density)~. The examples picked for discussion

in the paper are intentionally those which are in principle easily

justified and widely acceptable, i.e. more urban parks, improved public

transit and environmental quality, but in which current policies can and

do produce inequitable results.

Four conclusions, none of which are particularly novel, should

stick in the reader's mind. First, urban growth is an inherently complex

and multifaceted phenomena. It incorporates different but parallel pro-

cesses, each of which is reflected in variable forms of urban change,

and all of which are interdependent. Second, limits to urban growth

are essentially conservative measures, which seldom work as intended, are

often contradictory and which, without corresponding ideas and incentives

to redirect growth elsewhere, are largely a waste of effort. Third,

physical planning instruments are crude and inappropriate means of

achieving what are primarily social goals (i.e. social stability, housing

quality, etc.) Fourth, and most important, the application of such

limits, as presently conceived, generally results in a redistribution of

wealth and social opportunities within an urban area, largely in socially-

regressive directions. This redistribution may in many instances be

greate~ for those who can least afford it, than the practice of doing

nothing. In a capitalistic urban society in which land is held in-private

ownership, by a few, it may not be possible to avoid these negative con-

Page 31: LIMITS TO URBAN GROWTH: WHO BENEFITS, WHO PAYS, WHO

29

sequences of planning. We should at least debate the issue. In Toronto

there has been plenty of debate on growth, but as noted, little of that

debate has been concerned with questions of distributing costs and

benefits.

We need to dispense with our preoccupation with limits as such.

Instead our attention should shift to more basic concerns of defining

human needs and goals in the context of our future cities, and then of

actually creating the processes necessary to attain these goals. In

other words, we should design the future through goal-oriented planning

rather than back into the future with increasing limits on the present

urban form.

Page 32: LIMITS TO URBAN GROWTH: WHO BENEFITS, WHO PAYS, WHO

FOOTNOTES

1. There are,of course, numerous classifications of growth processes. The follow-up report to the Club of Rome on "Limits to Growth" (see M. Hesarovic and E. Pestel, Man­kind at the Turning Point, Hutchinson, London, 1975), argues that absolute growth is not itself the major pro­blem. Rather, difficulties arise because of the present distribution or pattern of what it calls "undifferentiated" growth. The latter i::; contrasted with "organic" growth, which. is stable and in harmony with global constraints.

2. For further discussions on the question of transit pricing and subsidies, see A. Altshuler, "Transit Subsidies: By Whom, For Whom?", Journal American Institute of Planners, 35, March, 1969, pp. 84-89.

3. It is also true that policies to increase densities by reducing lot sizes, without a parallel increase in the supply of land available, will also increase land prices.

4. A classic example of the intentional use of time delays (and of the use of non-existent alternatives to justify growth limits) is given by the residential community around Toronto's proposed second airport at Pickering. At a meeting in 1971, this author posed a question to the Minister responsible for housing in Ontario at the time as to where the 50,000 or so net annual additions to Toronto's population would find housing if his government followed through with limits to suburban growth to the north. He replied that one alternative would be the new Pickering community, which could house up to 150,000 persons within five years. At the time of writing, four years later, no houses had been built and the whole project is still in some doubt.

5. An interesting interpretation of this problem is given in B. Hudson and F. Sullivan, "Limited Growth, Problems of Full Employment and the Viciousness of Easy Solutions", Socio-Economic Planning Sciences, June, 1974.

6. In this regard, one could also argue that specific projects such as the vast docklands redevelopment in London (which is going ahead) and Metro Centre in Toronto (which is stal­led) should be encouraged by those who favour the retention of low-density neighbourhoods near the commercial city cen­tre. These projects would likely result in lower pressures

30

Page 33: LIMITS TO URBAN GROWTH: WHO BENEFITS, WHO PAYS, WHO

for redevelopment in other areas and thereby help to pre­serve existing neighbourhood units near the core. They would do so simply by absorbing a substantial proportion of the demand for central city housing. Further, since their construction does not involve the removal of any existing housing the net gain in new units would equal the number of new units.

7. This is precisely the difficulty with the popular neigh­bourhood stability argument, at least given the preceding definition of neighbourhoods as dynamic entities. To at­tempt to freeze inner-city neighbourhood housing in low­density use for low-income occupants is virtually impossible in a market economy. It (old housing) will almost certainly become more attractive for higher-income groups who will simply out-bid low-income groups for that housing and for the convenient location it provides. Both the old and new residents may actually benefit through this arrangement, the former through increased equity to buy housing else­where and the latter through greater accessibility to the city centre. But the neighbourhoods will change dramati­cally. The losers again are the renters.

31

8. Most American connnunities which have instituted, or attempted to institute strict growth limits (see Scott, 1974), tend to be relatively high-income and predominately middle class. This is the well-known "lifeboat" principle of limiting the accessibility of others to opportunities. The same concern applies to the conflict between developed and developing nations in the debate on global limits to growth (see foot­note 1).

9. The question of physical limits to redevelopment in the cen­tral connnercial core in Toronto is debated in a recent and provocative report by W. Code (1975) to the Mayor's Industry and Labour Advisory Committee. That report goes considerably further than this paper in making explicit policy suggestions, which may or may not be justified given the conflicting evi­dence demonstrated here.

10. Failure to let the Metropolitan municipality expand in line with the geographic growth of the urban area as a physical, economic and social system, is primarily attributable to pro­vincial government policy, and it mirrors government atti­tudes to growth. Visual the year 2000, Metro proper, with 2.6 to 2.8 million people, will be completely developed, at relatively high densities and under continuous pressures for redevelopment. It will be surrounded by regional (but sub­urban) municipalities, with a total population of probably 2.0 million, each acting independently and each resisting pressures from the central city to acconnnodate more employ-

Page 34: LIMITS TO URBAN GROWTH: WHO BENEFITS, WHO PAYS, WHO

32

ment growth, offices, public housing, garbage, or whatever. Will it be 1953 all over again?

11. A thoughtful review of the development approval process in municipal planning in Ontario,by the Ontario Economic Council (Subject to Approval, Toronto, 1973), also acknowledges the enormous costs in land and housing re~ulting from current planning practices in the province. They also stress (p. 145) that such cost increases need not have occurred. They could have been reduced by traditional means: increasing the supply of land in line with, if not ahead of, demand; and by speeding­up considerably the presently over-complicated and time-con­suming approval process. It is interesting to note in Britain that restrictions have recently been proposed on the planning process - that is, governments must deal with development ap­plications within specified periods of time. Needless to say, these are much shorter periods than those presently connnon in Ontario.

12. Or, the universal argument for encouraging neighbourhood im­provement and continuity (of which we all approve), is used to justify almost any form of planning control on residential areas regardless of the unequal consequences (of which I dis­approve).

Page 35: LIMITS TO URBAN GROWTH: WHO BENEFITS, WHO PAYS, WHO

* An earlier and much shorter version of this paper appeared in the Toronto Star, February 5,1975. The views expressed in this paper are those of the author only.

REFERENCES

33

Boulding, K. (1953) "Toward a General Theory of Growth", Canadian Journal of Economics and Political Science, XIX: 326 - 340.

Boulding, K. (1970) and Development.

A Primer on Social Dinamics. Histo.EY as Dialectics New York: The Free Press.

Burchell, R.W. and Listokin, D. eds. (1975) Future Land Use: Environmental and Legal Constraints. New Brunswick, N.J.: University.

Energy, Rutgers

City of Toronto Planning Board (1974). Report of the Core Area Task Force. Toronto

Clawson, M. and Hall, P. (1973) Planning and Urban Growth. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press.

Code, W. (1975) Controlling the Physical Growth of the Urban Core. Report to the Mayor's Industry and Labour Advisory Committee, Toronto.

Dennison, D. and Eversley D.E.C. eds (1973) London: Urban Patterns, Problems and Policies. London: Heinemann

Golden, A. (1975) "The Form of Local Government: What are the Options for Metro?" Background Paper No. 1, Bureau of Municipal Research Conference "Metro Toronto Under Review".

Harvey, D. (1973) Social Justice in the City London: Edward Arnold.

Listokin, D. ed. (1975) Land Use Controls: Present Problems and Future Reforms New Brunswick, N.J.: Rutgers University

Nowlan, D. (1975) "Planning Responsibilities in Metro: A Search for the new Consensus", Background Paper No. 4, Bureau of Municipal Re-search Conference "Metro Toronto Under Review" .

Richardson, H. (1972) "Optimality in City SizepSystems of Cities and Urban Policy: A Skeptic's View" 1 Urban Studies, 9: 29-48.

Rose, R. ed. (1974) The Management of Urban Cfiange in Britain and Germany~_ Beverley Hills: 8age Publications.

Page 36: LIMITS TO URBAN GROWTH: WHO BENEFITS, WHO PAYS, WHO

34

Scott, R.W. (1975) Management and Control of Growth: Techniques, Problems Trends. Volume I, II, III. The Urban Institute.

Issues, Washington:

Winnick, L. (1966) "Place Prosperity vs People Prosperity: Welfare Considerations in the Geographic Redistribution of Economic Activity", in Essays in Urban Land Economics. Los Angeles: University of California Press.

Page 37: LIMITS TO URBAN GROWTH: WHO BENEFITS, WHO PAYS, WHO

34

Scott, R.W. (1975) Management and Control of Growth: Techniques, Problems Trends. Volume I, II, III. The Urban Institute.

Issues, Washington:

Winnick, L. (1966) "Place Prosperity vs People Prosperity: Welfare Considerations in the Geographic Redistribution of Economic Activity", in Essays in Urban Land Economics. Los Angeles: University of California Press.

Page 38: LIMITS TO URBAN GROWTH: WHO BENEFITS, WHO PAYS, WHO