linking local government discretion and accountability in decentralisation

Upload: pham-phuong-mai

Post on 05-Apr-2018

220 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

  • 8/2/2019 Linking Local Government Discretion and Accountability in Decentralisation

    1/35

    Development Policy Review, 2010, 28 (3): 259-293

    The Authors 2010. Journal compilation 2010 Overseas Development Institute.

    Published by Blackwell Publishing, Oxford OX4 2DQ, UK and 350 Main Street, Malden, MA 02148, USA.

    Linking Local Government Discretion andAccountability in DecentralisationSerdar Yilmaz, Yakup Beris and Rodrigo Serrano-Berthet

    Decentralisation offers significant opportunities to improve governmentaccountability by exerting stronger pressures both from below (demand)and above (supply). The literature contains many examples, however,where the potential has not been realised, partly because decentralisationreforms have often been introduced without thinking through theiraccountability implications. Even when accountability is taken intoaccount, the efforts tend to emphasise either the supply or the demand side

    of the equation, but not both. Drawing on the sets of literature on fiscal,administrative and political decentralisation, this article presents amethodology for studying this.

    Key words:Decentralisation, local governance, accountability

    1 The local governance challenge: linking discretion andaccountabilityEstablished theories in economics and political science have articulated the efficiencyand accountability gains that could accrue from decentralisation reforms.

    1They include

    the internalisation of spillover effects (Oates, 1972; Mueller, 1996), the alleviation of

    information asymmetry and better accountability due to the proximity of principals and

    agents (Cremer et al., 1996; Raff and Wilson, 1997; Bucovetsky et al., 1998) and

    competition among local governments (Tiebout, 1956). Nevertheless, the empirical

    literature is full of examples of failures or mixed results in delivering these gains

    (Asthana, 2003; Akin et al., 2005). Part of the reason and the starting point of this

    article is that both the theory and practice of decentralisation have suffered from a

    partial and fragmented approach, undermining the comprehensive and strategic

    sequencing required for effective decentralisation reforms. We argue here that toincrease the developmental impact of decentralisation to receive the biggest

    development bang for the buck it is essential to get the right local governance

    framework, balancing discretion and accountability.

    Respectively, Social Development Department, World Bank, 1818 H Street, NW, Washington, DC 20433

    ([email protected]); United Nations Development Program; and World Bank. The findings and

    conclusions are entirely those of the authors, and do not represent the views of the World Bank, its

    executive directors, or the countries they represent.

    1. In this article we use the term decentralisation to refer to devolution central governments transfer of

    administrative and financial decision-making authority to local governments that have clear and legally

    recognised jurisdictions within which they provide public services to constituents to whom they are

    accountable and not deconcentration and delegation.

  • 8/2/2019 Linking Local Government Discretion and Accountability in Decentralisation

    2/35

    260 Serdar Yilmaz, Yakup Beris and Rodrigo Serrano-Berthet

    The Authors 2010. Journal compilation 2010 Overseas Development Institute.

    Development Policy Review 28 (3)

    Although decentralisation reforms have been at the centre of public-sector reforms

    around the world, they come in different types political, administrative, fiscal and

    forms deconcentration, delegation, devolution in each country. Furthermore,

    implementation of these reforms is always partial, based on the political context of a

    country; any illustration is therefore selective and incomplete.

    As decentralisation reforms become more widespread across the world,2

    they often

    try to increase the autonomy and discretion of local governments without thinking

    through the accountability incentive structures that are crucial to obtain more responsive

    and accountable governments. Even when accountability is taken into account, the

    efforts tend to emphasise only internal governmental mechanisms, neglecting external

    citizen vigilance and political oversight, or vice versa. In addition, the relationship

    between discretion and accountability in decentralisation reforms is further complicated

    when fiscal, administrative, and political aspects are separated a point often missed in

    such reform efforts.

    If the practice of decentralisation has been fragmented and incomplete, it is, to a

    certain extent, because of the separate and parallel pathways that its political and fiscal

    theories have followed. Public-finance economists have emphasised the allocative

    efficiency gains produced by fiscal decentralisation, downplaying the importance of the

    political dynamics surrounding the capture of those benefits by local elites. Political

    scientists have highlighted the potential for democratic deepening and citizen oversight,

    overlooking the fiscal underpinnings required to make local governments work. This

    article is part of an ongoing attempt to bring these two strands closer together.

    The first-generation theory of fiscal federalism made the case for decentralised

    fiscal choice based on its superior allocative efficiency. In his work on the theory of

    public finance, Musgrave (1959) argued that the policies of subnational branches ofgovernments should be permitted to differ in order to reflect the preferences of

    residents. Carrying Musgraves arguments further, Oates (1972: 87) formulated the

    decentralisation theorem as each public service should be provided by the jurisdiction

    having control over a minimum geographic area that would internalise benefits and

    costs of such provision. One of the shortcomings of first-generation theory was that it

    largely assumed that local public officials seek the common good. The more empirical

    literatures from political science and political economy prove this to be wrong,

    highlighting in particular the problem of capture by the local elite.

    An emerging second-generation theory of fiscal federalism is bridging the gap

    between the economic and political approaches to decentralisation, taking as its point ofdeparture the assumption that participants in political processes (both voters and

    officials) have their own objective functions that they seek to maximise in a political

    2. In 1994, Dillinger reported that of the 75 developing countries with populations greater than 5 million, all

    but 12 claimed to have embarked on some form of transfer of power from central to local governments.

    Since then this transfer has been occurring even in inherently centralised countries, such as Jordan

    (World Bank, 2002), Morocco (Vaillancourt, 1998), Egypt (UNDP, 2004), Yemen (UNCDF, 2007), the

    Peoples Republic of China (Wong, 1997), Turkey (Tosun and Yilmaz, 2010), and Central and Eastern

    European countries (Dunn and Wetzel, 2000; Bird et al., 1995) as well as authoritarian regimes likeAngola (Felicio and Yilmaz, 2009), Burkina Faso (World Bank, 2009), Ethiopia (Yilmaz and Venugopal,

    2008) and Pakistan (World Bank, 2009).

  • 8/2/2019 Linking Local Government Discretion and Accountability in Decentralisation

    3/35

    Linking Local Government Discretion and Accountability in Decentralisation 261

    The Authors 2010. Journal compilation 2010 Overseas Development Institute.

    Development Policy Review 28 (3)

    setting that provides the constraints on their behaviour. Officials dont simply act on

    behalf of the welfares of their constituents (Oates, 2005: 356).

    Decentralisation reforms often lead to tensions among various stakeholders, not

    surprisingly because decentralisation is about redistribution of power within and

    between levels of government, with different actors having conflicting interests

    (Hiskey, 2006). Analysing the political-economy drivers of these reforms is a crucial

    element of implementing a coherent, well-thought-out decentralisation strategy. Often

    decentralisation reforms are poorly designed and implemented, due to the lack of

    understanding of the power and accountability relationship among various actors. The

    political-economy approach highlights the influence of politics in framing and

    implementing the reforms, showing that decentralisation is ultimately a highly political

    process since it seeks to redistribute resources within the territorial confines of a given

    nation-state (Agrawal et al., 1999: 2) and that the advantage of decentralisation is

    compromised by capture by the local elites (Seabright, 1996; Bardhan and Mookherjee,

    1998).

    This article adds to this new more integrative body of literature by presenting a

    methodology to better analyse the linkages between local discretion and accountability

    in three dimensions: political, administrative, and fiscal. It argues that the relationship

    between local discretion and accountability is far more complex than accountability

    being an automatic outcome of increased discretion. In fact, increasing resources

    allocated for public services and expanding local government discretion over the use of

    these resources require a special attention to fixing accountability incentive structures.

    Otherwise, decentralisation efforts will most likely not translate into more accountable

    government.

    Furthermore, all these relationships between discretion and accountability (brokendown into the supply and demand side

    3of fiscal, administrative, and political aspects)

    are far from being static. In all its aspects, decentralisation reshapes power relations

    among the local residents, local governments, producers of local government services,

    and higher levels of government (including central government). It sets new rules of the

    3. The supply side of accountability, which is also known as public accountability, is the hallmark of and a

    sine qua non for good governance (Bovens, 2005). It is the obligation of public authorities (governments,

    elected representatives, corporate, and other governing bodies) to explain publicly, fully and fairly, how

    they are conducting responsibilities that affect the public in important ways. Public accountability refers to

    the institutionalised practice of account giving; it focuses on public-sector managers who spend publicmoney, exercise public authority, and manage a corporate body under public law. Until recently, efforts to

    foster good governance focused on strengthening the supply side of accountability within state institutions.

    Accordingly, donor initiatives supported institution-building in developing countries to increase thesupply

    of governance processes by reforming public institutions. Recently, the development community has

    concluded that domestic demandfor accountability, originating within civil-society entities and the public

    at large, is at least as important for development as supply-side mechanisms. Also referred to as social

    accountability, the demand side refers to an approach to building accountability that relies on civic

    engagement in which ordinary citizens and/or civil-society organisations demand accountability.

    Recognising the limitations of both electoral and public accountability mechanisms, demand-side/social-

    accountability approaches require concerted civic education efforts during the decentralisation reform

    process. This new understanding encouraged an expansion in the repertoire of instruments through which

    citizens can hold the state to account, beyond voting. These instruments include traditional practices suchas public demonstrations, protests, and investigative journalism, as well as more innovative ones such as

    participatory budgeting, social audits, or citizen report cards.

  • 8/2/2019 Linking Local Government Discretion and Accountability in Decentralisation

    4/35

    262 Serdar Yilmaz, Yakup Beris and Rodrigo Serrano-Berthet

    The Authors 2010. Journal compilation 2010 Overseas Development Institute.

    Development Policy Review 28 (3)

    political game, helping new local leaders to emerge in the political competition. It thus

    redefines the interactions between local leaders and their constituencies. Similarly, as a

    result of new regulatory and financial powers over procurement and service delivery,

    the decisions and actions of local governments have a greater impact on local

    economies. Decentralisation thus leads to new interactions and contractual relationships

    between local governments, between small and big private firms, and between providers

    and producers of services and communities and non-governmental organisations.

    The methodology presented here is not intended as a one-size-fits-all solution to

    the complex public policy issue of decentralisation. We are aware of the risk of

    generalising issues that are mostly specific to the local context; thus, our aim is not to

    offer a universal prescription. However, in the analysis we do not distinguish among

    different types of local governments, i.e. urban vs. rural, small vs. big, or among

    provinces in a federal system vs. local governments in a unitary system. We argue that

    factors presented in the methodology that affect discretion and accountability are valid,

    regardless of the size or location of the local governments. This is not to suggest that the

    size and location of the local governments do not matter in a decentralisation context.4

    They are relevant during the decision-making process on what kind of discretion over

    which services should be accorded to local governments. However, the issues of

    optimal size and location of local governments are beyond the scope of this article. Our

    methodology recommends that, once a decision on according a certain level of

    discretion is made, balancing discretion and accountability is important to increase the

    developmental impact of decentralisation.

    In balancing discretion and accountability, the relationship between the central

    government or its deconcentrated units and local governments presents challenges.

    Central governments or their deconcentrated units may set the rules under which localgovernments operate, and provide a portion of the local governments financial

    resources for service delivery. In these cases, local governments are accountable to

    higher-level hierarchies for their conduct. This often creates a relationship of upward

    accountability or dependence on central authorities, which may contradict the

    arguments about local discretion and accountability. While warning against these risks,

    the goal here is not to dismiss the important role of central governments in

    accountability relationships in decentralisation. Provided with a meaningful level of

    discretionary space, local governments need to be checked and balanced against abuse

    of their discretions. In this respect, central governments have a set of accountability

    instruments. However, such formal accountability rules and norms can be too vague andincomplete to deal with every situation and circumstance. They also tend to favour

    upward accountability towards upper levels of government. In these situations, there

    is a need for a minimum level of rule of law that will allow local governments to

    challenge central government encroachment (Bahl and Martinez-Vazquez, 2006). Such

    4. The size or the nature of local government (urban vs. rural) should be resolved in the discussion over the

    kind of expenditure assignments to be allocated to local governments, taking into account efficiency and

    effectiveness factors and the demands of local populations. Studies about the size of local governments

    examine the efficiency implications of size in service delivery. According to this literature, smallergovernments that are closer to the people should be better able to provide the tax/service delivery package

    that citizens want (Fox and Gurley, 2006).

  • 8/2/2019 Linking Local Government Discretion and Accountability in Decentralisation

    5/35

    Linking Local Government Discretion and Accountability in Decentralisation 263

    The Authors 2010. Journal compilation 2010 Overseas Development Institute.

    Development Policy Review 28 (3)

    minimum guarantees will allow independent bodies (such as courts) to arbitrate between

    the central and local governments in case of conflict or disagreement.5

    Although we accept the general notion of sequencing6

    in decentralisation reforms,

    we regard it as essential to conduct systematic analyses of country-specific local power

    structures, interests, and socio-economic conditions to decide the best sequence for a

    country. Beyond the elements of our methodology, any analysis of local governance

    structures needs to pay particular attention to the way local governments (both

    appointed and elected local officials) establish and maintain accountability relationships

    with their surrounding local actors. Accordingly, the methodology put forward here is

    simply a diagnostic tool for policy-makers to use when deciding on policy actions, not a

    panacea. Following this introduction, Section 2 presents the key components of the

    local political setting and discusses how to make local politics more accountable.

    Section 3 introduces different dimensions of local administrative discretion and

    accountability, and Section 4 discusses the linkage between discretion and

    accountability in fiscal decentralisation. The final section puts forward possible

    scenarios (trajectories) to achieve a high level of discretion and accountability in

    decentralisation.

    2 The local political setting and accountabilityAnalysing the local political setting is crucial to understanding the factors that drive

    accountability (Lankina, 2008).7

    Decentralisation reforms can restructure the local

    political setting, reshaping local actor and voter incentives in many ways, such as

    changing the size of municipalities, reformulating local electoral legislation, and

    redefining formal relationships between the representative and executive bodies

    (Keating, 1995). They can also change the structure of legislative bodies, the balance

    5. This was the case when the Supreme Court of the Philippines ruled that the central government had to pay

    the entitlements it was withholding from the local governments (Bahl and Martinez-Vazquez, 2006).

    6. Sequencing in this particular context refers only to some preconditions for a successful decentralisation

    reform. However, there is a broader debate on sequencing. The theoretical literature provides normative

    discussions on broad steps for sequencing and implementing decentralisation programmes. But this is

    limited to discretion (devolution of power) and is not linked to accountability. From our perspective,sequencing poses a big question: Can any one of three dimensions of decentralisation (political,

    administrative, or fiscal) survive without the presence of the others? This is especially the case when

    countries introduce only fiscal decentralisation without the other dimensions (for example, China and Viet

    Nam). This article tries to partially address the sequencing issue in the last section under the discussion on

    trajectories but refrains from making conclusive statements as it treats these cases as incomplete

    decentralisation. The methodology does not present one or the other dimension as superior or conditional

    for the other dimensions. But it presents different scenarios (trajectories) to reach the ultimate goal of a

    high level of discretion and accountability in all three dimensions. The decision on how and whether to

    reach this ultimate goal is a political one shaped by the local conditions and preferences in each country.

    Our methodology presents a menu of options and possible trajectories. It would be too prescriptive if it

    were to suggest a preference in these key and mostly political decisions.

    7. The premise that the local political and institutional setting might substantially affect local performanceand accountability is extensively theorised and documented in institutionalism-inspired studies of

    decentralisation (Lankina et al., 2007).

  • 8/2/2019 Linking Local Government Discretion and Accountability in Decentralisation

    6/35

    264 Serdar Yilmaz, Yakup Beris and Rodrigo Serrano-Berthet

    The Authors 2010. Journal compilation 2010 Overseas Development Institute.

    Development Policy Review 28 (3)

    between elected local authorities and local executives and administrators,8

    the way

    councils are elected, the way executives are elected or appointed, and the structures for

    local legislative and executive bodies to relate to citizens (Lankina, 2008).

    The following sub-sections identify the key structural elements at the local level

    that define the setting for political action and set out some accompanying arrangements

    needed to improve the downward accountability relationships of local authorities with

    the citizens.

    2.1 Factors defining the local political setting

    An appropriate political setting for downward accountability requires a suitable

    environment for local elected leaders to act independently (even if it conflicts with their

    own parties or with the central government) and responsively (in line with the demands

    of the local population). The local leadership will be influenced by at least three sets of

    factors: (i) the institutional arrangements for separation of powers among the executive,

    legislative, and judicial bodies; (ii) the election laws and the electoral system; and (iii)

    the existence and functioning of a party system and political party laws.

    Institutional separation of powers at the local level

    Strongly influencing the quality of local decision-making are the checks and balances

    between the executive, legislative, and judicial branches of local government and the

    clear separation of powers among them. With roles and functions clearly identified,

    local councillors are expected to undertake independent oversight over local executive

    bodies, and local courts take the role of impartially resolving conflicts arising from localgovernments administrative actions. Accordingly, a key prerequisite for the separation

    of powers, at least in theory, is a specialised local court system able to resolve such

    conflicts. In many countries, this is done through administrative courts or alternative

    dispute-resolution mechanisms that mediate between local governments and citizens

    about administrative actions, such as land use, zoning, and business regulations.9

    Another important component of the institutional separation of powers is the

    relationship between the executive and the legislative. The relationship between and the

    relative weight of the local executive and the local council establish how local decisions

    8. We make a distinction between the elected and executive bodies within local governments because theyhave distinct roles in local decision-making. Schroeder (2004) depicts local governments (elected and

    executive bodies) as the provision units rather than producers of services, meaning that they make

    decisions about the type, quantity, and quality of services to be made available in the locality, how those

    services are to be financed, and how produced. He ascribes the production of services to local public

    employees, private contractors, or higher jurisdictions under contract with the local government. In this

    sense, bureaucracy (and its supporting personnel) is the set of actors that either carry out the production of

    local services or help to oversee the private (or public) contractors that serve as production units

    (Schroeder 2004: 9). We use the term local appointed official interchangeably with local bureaucracy

    and emphasise the important role of local elected representatives in local accountability systems,

    especially in the oversight of local governments.

    9. However, in less developed countries such formalised court systems usually do not extend to jurisdictions

    below a certain level of government or do not always respond to certain types of small-scale conflicts.Frequently, traditional and informal structures may also address cases resulting from local government

    actions, before a formal recourse to the judicial system.

  • 8/2/2019 Linking Local Government Discretion and Accountability in Decentralisation

    7/35

    Linking Local Government Discretion and Accountability in Decentralisation 265

    The Authors 2010. Journal compilation 2010 Overseas Development Institute.

    Development Policy Review 28 (3)

    are made. Different institutional mechanisms for assigning the weight to the respective

    bodies are possible:

    Strong mayor system. Under the mayor-council set-up, also called a strong mayor

    system, a popularly elected mayor wields strong executive, often charismatic,

    authority, deciding public policy and with a strong symbolic role in representing the city

    (Sisk, 2001).10

    This arrangement is detrimental to local accountability if local councils

    are marginalised and their role reduced to rubber-stamping the preferences of the local

    executive (Lankina, 2008). In Cte dIvoire and Uganda, for example, use of the strong

    mayor system has led to mayoral domination of local councils (Crook and Manor, 1998;

    Wunsch, 2001).

    Strong council. The second type of institutional arrangement is the election of a

    mayor by the council, usually from council members, giving the council more weight

    than the executive. This system is also referred to as parliamentary system. The risk of

    this type of local government is that debating chambers are not able to implement

    sound policy decisions (Lankina, 2008).

    Council-manager. The third type, frequent under many strong council systems, is

    the council-manager arrangement. The council appoints and contracts with a politically

    neutral administrator to run and manage the city. Such an arrangement can preclude

    politically motivated patronage (Montjoy and Watson, 1995).11

    Commissioner. Under a commission form of municipal government, elected

    commissioners also manage separate departments. They are both legislators and

    department chairs, all with equal powers though one may have the title of mayor. The

    system has been criticised for violating the principle of division of powers (Montjoy and

    Watson, 1995).

    Existence and quality of local electoral systems

    Electoral systems change the incentives of elected local leaders and voters, during and

    between elections.12

    An electoral system may favour big parties, undermine alternative

    10. Various arrangements exist for governing the mayor-council relationship. For example, the mayor may

    have charter-based veto authority over council decisions, and procedures may exist for the council to

    override this veto. Or the mayor may lack veto power. Mayor-council set-ups might have an adverse effect

    on policy outcomes because political and administrative roles are not sharply distinguished under thisarrangement. Empirical studies have shown how electoral turnover, particularly when a new mayor defeats

    an incumbent, results in proclivities for greater public expenditures and policy changes (Wolman et al.,

    1996).

    11. It has been suggested that city managers are more likely to pursue policy innovations than elected mayors

    because they are ostensibly guided more by actual effectiveness and efficiency, rather than short-term

    electoral considerations and pressure-group demands, which would have been the case with elected

    political executives (Montjoy and Watson, 1995). City managers are not subject to frequent turnover and

    thus are more likely to ensure policy continuity and to have credible commitments to other actors in local

    development (Clingermayer and Feiock, 1997).

    12. The concept of electoral systems is defined narrowly to refer only to the rules that determine the means

    by which votes are translated into seats in the process of electing politicians into office (Farrell, 2001:

    15). Electoral laws is a broader concept that includes the laws regulating all facets of the electionprocess, including nomination procedures, the characteristics of the franchise, and how campaigns are

    conducted (ibid.).

  • 8/2/2019 Linking Local Government Discretion and Accountability in Decentralisation

    8/35

    266 Serdar Yilmaz, Yakup Beris and Rodrigo Serrano-Berthet

    The Authors 2010. Journal compilation 2010 Overseas Development Institute.

    Development Policy Review 28 (3)

    voices and dissent, or encourage strict hierarchies within parties.13

    More important, it

    can be structured in such a way as to systematically exclude certain groups. Or it may

    encourage political parties to simply win the votes of particular groups over others. In

    sum, the structure of local electoral systems has an impact on the quality of local

    representation and its responsiveness, and therefore the performance of decentralisation

    reforms (Hiskey, 2006).

    Scholars of decentralisation assert that fair, competitive and regular elections

    compel local politicians to exercise power in a way that allows decentralised institutions

    to provide efficient and fair outcomes (Echeverri-Gent, 1993; Crook and Manor, 1998;

    Blair, 2000; Faguet, 2008). But if an electoral system does not secure real competition

    among local politicians, decentralisation reforms might end up strengthening the hands

    of local political strongmen. Competition among local politicians increases the chances

    for vulnerable groups to be included in decision-making (Lankina, 2008). However, few

    scholars provide systematic insight into whether certain electoral arrangements produce

    better outcomes than others (Packel, 2008). A host of factors may shape the

    effectiveness of elections as an instrument of local citizens voice. Key among them:

    whether elections are based on individuals or party-nominated candidates; whether

    officials being elected are perceived to wield sufficient power; whether local elections

    are held concomitantly with national elections; and, of course, whether elections are

    manipulated (Sisk, 2001).

    In this context, the choice between proportional representation and election

    through single-member districts and plurality votes, also known as first-past-the-post, is

    a key institutional variation. In the emerging systems of democratic decentralisation in

    the developing world, there is more variation, ranging from pure PR systems, systems

    mixing PR with elections from single-member districts, first-past-the-post elections insingle-member districts, to arrangements where the winning party takes all the council

    seats allocated through the election (Packel, 2008).

    In PR systems, voters generally vote for a political party rather than a specific

    candidate. Electoral districts contain multiple representatives, and the share of votes

    received by a party is translated by a fixed formula into the number of seats to be held

    by that party. So PR works to ensure that a partys degree of representation

    appropriately reflects its electoral support (ibid.).

    The alternative to PR systems is majority or plurality voting within single-member

    districts. Here, voters in a given electoral district vote for a specific candidate. With

    only one representative per electoral district, voters have greater clarity ofrepresentation they have no doubt who is directly charged with accounting for their

    interests. The chief drawback is that there is no guarantee that minority interests receive

    any representation (ibid.). This arrangement becomes a particular concern where

    minority interests are equally distributed across the polity. A party or group that has

    only a slight minority could easily lose elections in each electoral district, leaving it

    with no representation whatsoever (Farrell, 2001; Gallagher and Mitchell, 2005).

    There are very few systematic studies evaluating the relationship between varying

    institutional electoral arrangements and accountability in local governments (Packel,

    13. Rules for candidacy may force party members to have closer ties with the centre rather than their local

    constituency.

  • 8/2/2019 Linking Local Government Discretion and Accountability in Decentralisation

    9/35

    Linking Local Government Discretion and Accountability in Decentralisation 267

    The Authors 2010. Journal compilation 2010 Overseas Development Institute.

    Development Policy Review 28 (3)

    2008). This is true for both advanced industrial democracies and developing countries.

    It is therefore very important to develop this research agenda further to better

    understand how the quality of local electoral systems reflects the local electorates

    preferences, the nature of local campaigning and the performance of elected leaders.

    Nature of party system and structures

    The rules and structures of local political representation create (positive or negative)

    incentives for local elected leaders to be downwardly accountable to all citizens.

    Political parties lie at the heart of this representation. They articulate and aggregate

    interests, provide channels for the recruitment of leadership, adjudicate disputes

    between conflicting interests, and engage in government decision-making. They provide

    the linkage between the ruler and the ruled, the policy-maker and the citizen (Lawson,

    1980). Given the critical importance for local governance, it is essential to understand

    the features affecting the party system and structures, namely, the existence of partisanor non-partisan systems, the role of national parties in nominating local candidates,

    rules governing the financing of parties and the participation of disadvantaged groups

    such as women or certain minorities, and the availability of parties based on ethnicity or

    religion.

    Partisan or non-partisan. Although a growing literature is looking at the

    relationship between electoral competition and local government performance, a smaller

    literature focuses on partisan systems compared with non-partisan ones (Packel, 2008).

    Advocates of non-partisanship in local elections maintain that local government pertains

    to bread and butter issues, on which there can be no division along party lines (Olowu,

    2003). According to this understanding, the inclusion of parties at the local level risksallowing policy-making to become contaminated by patronage and clientelism instead

    of focusing on long-term benefits (Packel, 2008). The literature argues that elected

    officials may be focused on securing re-election or delivering benefits to their narrow

    client base, rather than delivering policies that benefit the entire community in the long

    run (Lankina, 2008). In addition, officials may be more concerned with taking measures

    to ensure their promotion and advancement within the internal party structure, rather

    than in promoting policies that benefit the community (Ahmad et al., 2005). In Ghana,

    for example, parties have been outlawed in local elections, based on an argument that

    merit, not party affiliation, is the basis of representation (Crook, 1999; Francis and

    James, 2003). Indias panchayats also operate on a non-partisan basis by law(Venugopal and Yilmaz, 2009).

    Allowing parties to participate in local government, by contrast, acknowledges the

    link between local and national government. Examples of systems allowing partisanship

    in local elections are nearly all from the recently decentralising Latin American

    countries, including Bolivia and Mexico. In Africa, prominent examples of party-based

    systems are Cte dIvoire, Kenya, Nigeria, Senegal and South Africa (Packel, 2008).

    Role of national parties in nominating local candidates. The membership and

    loyalty structure of the parties, the role of national party leaders in selecting candidates

    and preparing party lists for local elections, and the hierarchy structure within parties

    can also shape the behaviours of political parties. These factors can have direct orindirect effects on the ability of local political leaders to exercise their powers and may

  • 8/2/2019 Linking Local Government Discretion and Accountability in Decentralisation

    10/35

    268 Serdar Yilmaz, Yakup Beris and Rodrigo Serrano-Berthet

    The Authors 2010. Journal compilation 2010 Overseas Development Institute.

    Development Policy Review 28 (3)

    create an environment where national priorities and national party leaders dominate

    local priorities and agendas.

    In many countries, parties do not command stable loyalties, with elections

    focusing on elites or personalities (Azfar et al., 2001). A review of relevant case studies

    shows that national parties play a role in nominations (Packel, 2008), which may affect

    party loyalties. Where local elections occur on a partisan basis, nomination rules that

    favour national parties can serve as impediments to downward accountability. This is

    the case in Senegal, where only nationally registered parties can field candidates for

    local elections. In a study comparing six Latin American countries that have taken

    formal measures to decentralise forest management, Larson (2003) notes with concern

    that in Bolivia, Brazil, Costa Rica, Honduras and Nicaragua, local candidates are

    selected by national parties. These arrangements are also likely to diminish the capacity

    of local actors to demand accountability from local elected officials, because their

    choices for selecting representatives are likely to be limited (Packel, 2008).

    Financing of parties. Local party financing is also critical in analysing local governance

    structures. Corrupt practices related to covert party funding streams, influence peddling,

    and leveraging state resources for party purposes may compromise the faith of ordinary

    citizens in the political processes. A recent study by the National Democratic Institute

    of 22 countries highlights many areas of concern, such as the role of wealthy business

    interests in funding campaigns to gain access to lucrative state contracts (Bryan and

    Baer, 2005). This is still an area with a scant literature. In many developing countries,

    accurate information about party funding sources and political spending practices is not

    available to the public.

    Participation of disadvantaged groups. Without clear rules stipulating the inclusion of

    certain disadvantaged or minority segments of society, a party system may easily engender asystem of dominance by majority and more powerful social groups. Exclusion from the party

    system based on race, gender, ethnicity, or religion reflects a party agenda (and inevitably, a

    local council and government agenda) favouring the majority and the more powerful. In the

    absence of sanctions against such exclusion, downward accountability of locally elected

    leaders is damaged, leading to skewed policy-making and greater rent-seeking.

    All the elements discussed in this section define the local political setting in which

    local elected officials interact with the other actors within the government and with the

    citizens. There is no one-size-fits-all setting that these elements would produce; many

    different combinations could be determined, depending on the country context and

    preferences of the local leaders. No matter what combination is chosen, however, thegoal is to provide a setting conducive to downward accountability. The following

    section discusses the key aspects that need to be taken into account.

    2.2 Making local politics downwardly accountable

    Political accountability is a process whereby citizens hold elected officials to account

    for their behaviour and performance say, through elections (Aucoin and Heintzman,

    2000). Political accountability can also be improved by having elected local officials

    oversee local executives, or by involving citizens directly in decision-making beyond

    elections.

  • 8/2/2019 Linking Local Government Discretion and Accountability in Decentralisation

    11/35

    Linking Local Government Discretion and Accountability in Decentralisation 269

    The Authors 2010. Journal compilation 2010 Overseas Development Institute.

    Development Policy Review 28 (3)

    Strengthening the political dimension of local accountability requires some

    safeguards on the supply side regarding local electoral systems and local council

    oversight (public accountability). On the demand side, political accountability measures

    allow for citizen-initiated legislation (petitions), referenda, or recalls of elected public

    officials, including procedures for petitions to adopt, amend, or repeal an act, law, or

    executive order, to demand public hearings on policy decisions and action and to appeal

    to ombudsman offices in local governments (social accountability).

    Public accountability approaches

    Introducing safeguards into the electoral system. Despite many weaknesses, elections

    remain the principal method whereby all eligible local residents can have a voice in the

    outcome and can hold decision-makers accountable (Schroeder, 2004: 9). They legitimise

    local authority and provide elected representatives with a mandate for action. But little

    attention has been devoted to how specific electoral mechanisms fare in deliveringaccountability, or even whether voters use elections to hold officials accountable for

    certain policy decisions (Rodden, 2004). Nevertheless, the general literature on

    elections does show that differing electoral arrangements shape how citizens exercise

    influence on policy-makers (Powell, 2000).

    An established body of literature on Western local governance suggests that, even

    under perfect conditions, a voice in local elections fails to ensure that elected officials

    will exercise power on behalf of all segments of the community.14

    These studies suggest

    structural biases against marginalised and non-elite groups built into elections even in

    Western democracies. Hunter (1953) shows how power in US cities is concentrated in,

    and exercised on behalf of, a narrow group of elite interests. Studies on the involvementof underprivileged segments in decision-making processes demonstrate that they

    rubber-stamp decisions already reached by other interests (Schattschneider, 1960;

    Bachrach and Baratz, 1962). And other studies reveal a middle-class, white-collar, male

    bias in the composition of elected bodies (Balme, 1989; Newton, 1976; Mabileau, 1989;

    Mabileau et al., 1989; Stone, 1989).

    Some countries allow independent candidates to run in local elections, reserve

    seats for women and other vulnerable groups, allow for recalls of elected officials and

    limit the length of the term they may remain in office. These mechanisms are important

    in countries where money, violence, and corruption dominate elections, and politics

    are based on kin, personality, or patronage (Olowu et al., 2004: 71).The impact of such measures is complex. For example, re-election procedures

    could determine political accountability, although two opposing relationships are

    possible (Packel, 2008). Term limits could foster accountability by preventing local

    politicians from becoming entrenched in their positions and locked into relationships of

    patronage. Representatives who were recently private citizens would thus be more

    14. As a result of a decline in faith in representative democracy, turnouts in local elections have gradually

    declined over the past few decades in many countries. Elections focused on parties have likewise alienated

    voters, as parties are often perceived to have lost touch with the electorate. In some countries, like Canada,

    parties are now banned from participating in local elections; it is assumed that party-free elections ensurethat elected officials speak on behalf of the community and do not espouse narrow party agendas (Sisk,

    2001).

  • 8/2/2019 Linking Local Government Discretion and Accountability in Decentralisation

    12/35

    270 Serdar Yilmaz, Yakup Beris and Rodrigo Serrano-Berthet

    The Authors 2010. Journal compilation 2010 Overseas Development Institute.

    Development Policy Review 28 (3)

    attuned to the concerns and interests of the community than career politicians (Packel,

    2008). But if term limits are too restrictive, council members may not be able to master

    the responsibilities of their position before their terms expire.

    The theory of retrospective control of politicians asserts that, given perfect

    information, voters use elections to reward or punish politicians. But without the

    possibility of re-election, elections lose their power of control, and politicians may

    engage in more rent-seeking (Maravall, 2007). Even with imperfect information,

    eliminating the possibility of re-election may at the very least reduce opportunities for

    accountability (Packel, 2008). Mexico is one country that imposes term limits of three

    years on local elected officials and bars them from holding the same position again for

    one term. Researchers argue that these limits impede performance (Cleary, 2007;

    Grindle, 2006).

    Recall gives councils or popular bodies the ability to dismiss elected leaders for

    wrongdoing. Unlike elections, however, the decision is confined more to evaluations of

    past actions. In Africa, recall provisions exist in Ethiopia and Nigeria (Olowu, 2003).

    Indias panchayati raj law varies across different States, but some of the most

    progressive legislation for recall exists in Madhya Pradesh, with detailed regulations for

    gram panchayataction (Mathew and Mathew, 2003) and where thegram sabha (village

    assembly open to all adult residents) has the right to dismiss the panchayat

    chairperson in the event of wrongdoing (Johnson et al., 2005).

    If a provision for recall exists, its design matters if it is to be an instrument of

    accountability. Recall alone may not engender downward accountability if the only

    actors capable of exercising this power are beholden to national political parties (Packel,

    2008). In Bolivia, the widespread use of the law allowing the town council to recall

    mayors in cases of misconduct, known as the voto constructivode censura (constructivecensorship vote), illustrates this risk. In 1997, one year after the first mayors entered

    office following implementation of decentralising reforms, 30% of them were replaced,

    indicating that the voto constructivo was being used as a political manoeuvre, not a

    response to corruption (Hiskey and Seligson, 2003). Indeed, this high use demonstrated

    that the recall hindered accountability, as mayors wound up being selected by council

    members rather than by the electorate, and with less citizen support for the political

    system than in municipalities where the recall was not exercised (ibid.).

    Improving local council oversight. Local councils are the core units of

    representative governments. Improving local council oversight therefore constitutes an

    important part of public accountability approaches, relying as it does on the assumptionthat local elected representatives have more incentive to respond to the needs and

    preferences of local populations and are more downwardly accountable than local

    bureaucrats. The relationship between elected local councillors and executives also

    pertains to budget planning, execution, and monitoring and evaluation. Local

    councillors are supposed to oversee the executive branch during the entire process of

    public financial management and provide local executives with constant feedback.

    A number of factors interfere with the oversight responsibility of local councillors.

    First, there is the status of local councillors (Lankina, 2008). Although executive

    positions are generally considered to be full-time, in many settings councillors are low

    paid and part-time, their council duties motivated by civic spirit and volunteerism(Pelissero and Krebs, 1997). Second, there is the lack of safeguards against dual

  • 8/2/2019 Linking Local Government Discretion and Accountability in Decentralisation

    13/35

    Linking Local Government Discretion and Accountability in Decentralisation 271

    The Authors 2010. Journal compilation 2010 Overseas Development Institute.

    Development Policy Review 28 (3)

    structures of accountability (Lankina, 2008). In some developing countries, councillors

    often occupy dual roles as full-time executive functionaries dependent on, and

    accountable to, higher-up bureaucracies and elected local officials. In some parts of

    Russia, local councils are packed with senior professional employees of medical and

    educational institutions (Lankina, 2004). Such councillors are less likely to aggregate

    and articulate the preferences of the citizens who elected them.15

    Other countries demonstrate similar conflicts of interest. In Ghana, a third of local

    councillors are formally appointed by state bodies, while in Kenya as well as Ghana,

    members of parliament can be ex officio members of local councils (Olowu et al., 2004).

    In India, some states have power to remove elected representatives or even dissolve

    panchayats (Mathew and Mathew, 2003). In many countries, councillor positions also

    overlap with key patrimonial, social, or other structures in the locality, impeding

    accountability.

    Social accountability approaches

    Social accountability mechanisms can give poor and marginalised people a more direct

    voice in the policies that local governments formulate and implement than through

    elections and local councils. Studies of African countries where elections are in place

    show that local citizens fail to sanction poorly performing officials effectively (Azfar et

    al., 2001). Patronage, clientelism, elite capture and elite biases are still widespread.

    Social accountability mechanisms are often part of broader efforts to deepen democracy

    and ensure a robust public sphere for citizens to give feedback and control government

    action.16

    The practical form of such participatory arrangements includes public meetings,citizen juries, forums for various social groups, such as the young or the elderly,

    neighbourhood assemblies, multi-choice referenda accompanied by active public debate

    and discussion, and activism by non-governmental organisations and other community

    groups. In some settings citizens are excused from work and asked to meet to make

    recommendations about local issues, thus drawing even the normally passive and

    uninterested citizens into public life (Lankina, 2008).17

    Logistically, some of these

    deliberative forums could be complicated and time-consuming, but observers point to

    their merits, namely, that consensus-based decision-making may be more legitimate

    than that of elected officials which cannot be realistically scrutinised on a daily basis

    (Sisk, 2001).

    15. In some instances, public employees, such as school principals, appointed by higher-level bureaucracies

    on a contract basis, sit in local councils. They tend to satisfy the political preferences of regional

    authorities because their jobs are subject to short-term contracts, which could be revoked. Even heads of

    private enterprises are subject to control and manipulation by higher authorities because their tax

    privileges and licences could be withdrawn at random (Lankina, 2004).

    16. These efforts represent a new approach to democratic governance that some scholars have called

    Empowered Participatory Governance (Fung, 2004). It looks at how alternative political and

    administrative designs can surpass conventional democratic institutional forms on the quite practical aims

    of enhancing the responsiveness and effectiveness of the state while making it more fair, participatory,

    deliberative, and accountable (Fung and Wright, 2001: 8).17. The size of the locality and its cohesiveness are important factors determining the effectiveness of such

    forums (Sisk, 2001).

  • 8/2/2019 Linking Local Government Discretion and Accountability in Decentralisation

    14/35

    272 Serdar Yilmaz, Yakup Beris and Rodrigo Serrano-Berthet

    The Authors 2010. Journal compilation 2010 Overseas Development Institute.

    Development Policy Review 28 (3)

    These powers to hold political leaders accountable may be expanded: (i) by

    generic legislation empowering citizens to demand explanations and justifications from

    local governments; (ii) by setting up specific bodies and processes for citizen oversight;

    and (iii) by creating a political culture for citizen oversight.

    Generic legislation. Some initiatives introduce legal mechanisms empowering

    citizens to redress grievances or request explanations of municipal legislation. Public

    hearings and consultations, the right to demand a public hearing, public petitions, and

    the right to initiate a recall or referendum are examples.

    Specific bodies and processes. These can comprise all citizens in the municipality

    (gram sabha in India), several citizen representatives (Vigilance Committee in Bolivia),

    or an elected position (citizen ombudsman in Japan). In some countries local

    development programmes transfer discretionary resources to local governments on

    condition that they create multi-stakeholder forums, with representation from civil

    society, local councillors, and deconcentrated offices.18

    In the Philippines, for example,

    the Local Government Code mandates all provincial, municipal, and village

    governments to establish local development councils to set the direction for economic

    and social development and review local government budgets, one-quarter of the

    members to come from non-governmental and community-based organisations (Estrella

    and Iszatt, 2004).

    Creating a political culture. By introducing mechanisms for poor and marginalised

    people to participate in decision-making and for local transparency and accountability,

    community-driven development programmes have promoted a culture of citizen

    oversight.19

    A community-based programme that empowers citizens to be informed and

    have a say over local public expenditure creates the expectation that all programmes

    should follow the same standards.

    3 Local administrative discretion and accountabilityTo have flexibility in delivering services and the opportunity to respond to local needs,

    local governments need administrative autonomy. We identify three broad areas of

    authority as being crucial for local governments to be administratively autonomous:

    power to make, change and enforce regulatory decisions/laws; to govern a procurement

    system (based on national standards); and to make civil service/employment decisions.

    18. Although these forums provide a venue for greater co-ordination and control, they need to be properly

    designed to complement the role of the local council.

    19. A community-driven development approach tries to improve the well-being of poor people by increasing

    their control over the way investment resources are planned, executed and managed. Because communities

    do not act in isolation but in a local space where they interact with local governments, sectoral service

    delivery units, the private sector, and civil-society organisations, the community-driven approach hasrecently been expanded into a broader local governance approach that captures the quality of these local

    interactions (Helling et al., 2005; McLean et al., 2006).

  • 8/2/2019 Linking Local Government Discretion and Accountability in Decentralisation

    15/35

    Linking Local Government Discretion and Accountability in Decentralisation 273

    The Authors 2010. Journal compilation 2010 Overseas Development Institute.

    Development Policy Review 28 (3)

    3.1 Factors affecting local administrative discretion

    Ability to regulate

    As part of administrative autonomy, local governments need a minimum set of powersand capacities to initiate, amend and enforce regulatory legislation on issues within their

    jurisdiction, subject to national and state laws. Their powers usually extend to local

    economic development, land-use planning and management, zoning, and public safety

    and in certain cases, some aspects of public health, social protection, education, and

    environmental protection. These enhance their discretionary authority to make decisions

    and take actions concerning who can benefit from given resources or opportunities,

    how, and to what extent (Agrawal and Ribot, 1999: 480). For example, research on

    environmental regulatory networks for shrimp farming in Thailand shows that local

    governments are the most effective regulators (Vandergeest, 2007).

    They also need the power to sanction and punish non-compliance, one such toolbeing the administrative penalty, usually a monetary fine or the revocation of licences

    or rights related to, say, an economic activity or land use. Although the power to

    sanction requires a qualified workforce to monitor non-compliance, endowing local

    governments with such power could prove more practical and cost-effective than

    prosecution through litigation.20

    Discretion to procure and administer services

    Expanded mandates and responsibilities for new services require local governments to

    be given discretion over procurement processes for goods and services,21

    which in turn

    requires flexibility in procurement laws and regulations and high-quality employees

    well trained in public procurement, ethics, and contract management (Brennan and

    Miller, n. d.). Such discretion implies that, under strictly stipulated national standards

    and regulations, local governments can develop procurement strategies,22

    identify

    associated processes, and issue contracts for goods and services.23

    Discretion over civil service and employment policies

    In many countries political and fiscal devolution may have proceeded apace, but

    administrative changes may only approximate deconcentration, the result being

    20. Administrative penalties do not replace criminal prosecution, and the legal system is important for local

    administrative autonomy. Enforcing local administrative rulings is effective and legitimate only when

    there is recourse to challenging local government decisions. As discussed in Section 2, the existence of a

    specialised administrative court system for local affairs would be instrumental in establishing checks and

    balances between local executive and legislative bodies.

    21. Private-sector participation in service delivery through service and management contracts, leasing,

    concessions and joint ventures alleviates pressures on budgets. It also brings in skills and knowledge,

    improves the efficiency of service delivery and insulates operations from political interventions.

    22. A procurement strategy should stipulate mechanisms for assuring compliance with the competitive bidding

    and against abuses, such as bid splitting, change of orders, and restrictive bid specifications.

    23. A local government procurement policy is closely associated with the quality of service administration andthe way contracts are awarded to partnerships in service delivery, including for firms of various sizes,

    social enterprises, minority groups businesses, and voluntary and community organisation suppliers.

  • 8/2/2019 Linking Local Government Discretion and Accountability in Decentralisation

    16/35

    274 Serdar Yilmaz, Yakup Beris and Rodrigo Serrano-Berthet

    The Authors 2010. Journal compilation 2010 Overseas Development Institute.

    Development Policy Review 28 (3)

    weakened accountability for service delivery, and conflicts of interest (Ahmad et

    al., 2005: 10). Civil servants form a crucial link in moving government closer to people;

    therefore civil service management or more broadly human resource management

    should be seen as an essential component in the design of decentralisation rather than a

    separate, stand-alone process (Green, 2005: 129).

    Local government competency and discretion over civil service and employment

    policies ideally cover autonomy and transparency in pay policy (overall wage rates as

    well as allowances), control of budget and establishment, autonomy in recruitment,

    control of career management, and performance management (Evans, 2004: 24).24

    The

    degree of autonomy differs across countries; Table 1 provides a general picture of the

    situation in East Asia.Each of these factors increases a local governments administrative autonomy and

    influences its accountability relationship with local bureaucracies. However, many

    countries suffer from misaligned structures of accountability in decentralisation

    (Lankina, 2008). In Pakistan, for example, despite devolution of responsibility for

    education to school districts, teachers remained provincial government employees, with

    the elected district executive, nazim, having little authority over them (Ahmad et al.,

    2005). Similarly in Uganda, despite devolution in health care, key decisions and drug

    provision remain the prerogative of the centre, but salaries and staffing are that of the

    District, undermining local incentives for efficiency and responsiveness (Azfar et al.,

    2001).

    Granting administrative autonomy to local governments in civil service

    management results in reallocating powers and jobs, geographically and institutionally.

    Issues related to status, prestige and labour mobility often impede relocation or

    dislocation of civil servants across tiers of government. Bureaucracies tend to resistdecentralisation reforms because of career perspectives and institutional and political

    allegiances. Such resistance can lead to field officers maintaining strong links with their

    original line ministries, thereby enjoying some insulation against local control. This is

    often the case in countries where central government officials were simply transferred to

    local governments after decentralisation reforms were instituted. The result is that staff

    burdens are transferred to local governments, without the discretionary powers over the

    civil service. In India, for instance, though most State legislation has clarified the

    functions to be devolved, the States have frequently been unable to transfer

    administrative and technical and technical controls over locally administered

    programmes. In China, on the other hand, although subnational employees make up90% of total government employment, the central government retains a significant

    degree of control over numbers and wage levels, structure and career and performance

    management of the subnational civil service (Green, 2005). Both in China and the

    Philippines, the double subordination of local government staff to the local executive

    and the relevant central agency weakens the downward accountability of local civil

    servants (ibid.).

    24. Some form of accountability to higher levels of authority may be unavoidable for local authorities

    performing state-delegated or -funded tasks. It is, however, important that there be no confusion aboutresponsibilities or distorted incentive structures whereby the local authorities are deprived of leverage over

    service providers within their jurisdictions.

  • 8/2/2019 Linking Local Government Discretion and Accountability in Decentralisation

    17/35

    Linking Local Government Discretion and Accountability in Decentralisation 275

    The Authors 2010. Journal compilation 2010 Overseas Development Institute.

    Development Policy Review 28 (3)

    Table 1: Staffing authority among subnationalgovernments in East AsiaEnabling mechanisms

    Cambodia

    China

    Indonesia

    Philippines

    Thailand

    Vietnam

    Budget control

    Determine wage

    Dismiss surplus staff

    Establishment control

    Control overall staffing

    numbers

    in individual offices

    and facilities

    Recruitment

    Formal employer

    Have authority to hire

    Have independent

    merit-based recruitment

    mechanism

    Career management

    Promotion available

    Internal transfers

    possible

    Horizontal mobility

    Performance management

    Direct and supervise

    Conduct evaluations

    Offer financial rewards

    Discipline and fire

    Pay policy

    Set overall wage rates

    Set local incentives/

    top-ups

    Note: = yes; = partial; = no. Ratings refer to the subnational level and de facto practices as well as de

    jure authority. Data are for most recent available year, ranging from 2000 to 2003.

    Source: Green (2005).

    3.2 Making local administration downwardly accountable

    Accountability for the exercise of administrative powers requires avenues for

    complaints and redress, accessible to officials and others. Oversight of the use of civil

    service control includes measures to improve budget transparency on staff payments, on

    policies and practices for new appointments, and on practices for budget and

  • 8/2/2019 Linking Local Government Discretion and Accountability in Decentralisation

    18/35

    276 Serdar Yilmaz, Yakup Beris and Rodrigo Serrano-Berthet

    The Authors 2010. Journal compilation 2010 Overseas Development Institute.

    Development Policy Review 28 (3)

    establishment control. Similar measures are needed to ensure transparency and openness

    of the procurement process to avoid misconduct and corruption. These measures call for

    appropriate channels for administrative audits that can be initiated by bureaucrats or

    elected leaders and by civil-society groups.

    Public accountability approaches

    Public accountability in the administrative sphere refers to local civil servants being

    accountable to their top administrative officers and to outside officials or entities such

    as public audit officers, ombudsmen, regulators, a particular administrative agency, or a

    board or committee. Three major mechanisms that public sector approaches rely on to

    improve this accountability are structures within bureaucratic hierarchies, specially

    designed independent bodies, and administrative courts.

    Accountability structures in the bureaucratic hierarchy enable higher authorities to

    instigate investigations or audits of the use of administrative discretion by lowerbureaucrats, and are important as a first step to uncover information about

    misadministration by local governments. Issues arising due to lack of sound control and

    audit systems range from collusive practices in procurement in Indonesia (World Bank,

    2003) to a lack of compliance with procurement laws in the Philippines (World Bank,

    2004b).

    Specially designed independent bodies authorised to conduct administrative audits

    on local governments have emerged in response to increased complexities requiring

    specific expertise, and have become a widespread accountability measure. Examples

    include independent/external auditors who scrutinise the use of public funds,

    ombudsmen who hear citizens complaints about regulations, decisions and actions,25

    and theme-specific bodies (such as the anti-corruption commissions, environmental

    review boards, or commissions for sustainable development) that analyse whether local

    administrative decisions are in line with national sectoral strategies.26

    Administrative courts with local expertise address local conflicts arising from local

    governments regulatory and administrative decisions, and can ensure compliance with

    national laws and regulations. Such a court system issues binding decisions and may

    resolve cases that the local governments and associated independent bodies fail to

    address. In France, for example, les tribunaux administratifs are the court of first

    instance with full jurisdiction over disputes related to local government actions.

    25. The office of the Ombudsman in the Indian State of Kerala is a 7-member body consisting of a High Court

    judge as the chairperson, other judges and non-political representatives appointed after consultation with

    opposition parties. In addition, there are appellate tribunals as a source of appeal against panchayat

    decisions. Only impeachment could remove members of these bodies, which minimises the chance of

    executive interference with their work (Mathew and Mathew, 2003).

    26. Legislatures set up these agencies to make inquiries, obtain information, and issue (limited) regulations or

    judgments (Zarei, 2000). In some African countries, like Ghana and Uganda, there are local judicial orconflict-resolving agencies, run by volunteers, which may be customary, providing sound redress for local

    grievances (Olowu et al., 2004).

  • 8/2/2019 Linking Local Government Discretion and Accountability in Decentralisation

    19/35

    Linking Local Government Discretion and Accountability in Decentralisation 277

    The Authors 2010. Journal compilation 2010 Overseas Development Institute.

    Development Policy Review 28 (3)

    Social accountability approaches

    Public accountability approaches are necessary to provide channels for uncovering basic

    information on regulatory decisions and civil service practices and services. But public

    approaches alone fall short of ensuring proper use of administrative discretion. Citizen-based efforts concentrate on producing the information that is most relevant for local

    citizens welfare monitoring the quality of services and the way contracts and tenders

    are given at the local level. Recent approaches emphasise the need for citizens to initiate

    administrative audits to reveal more information on employment and pay policies as

    well as relationships between local governments and service providers.

    Information provision as a basis for citizen monitoring. Lack of information on

    financial allocations often leads to the abuse of funds; making information available to

    the public is thus the starting point for many social accountability initiatives. In India,

    social audit committees, comprising individuals with impeccable reputations, scrutinise

    local decision-making and publicise findings on how public money is allocated andspent (Mathew and Mathew, 2003). In the State of Rajasthan, public hearings with wide

    publicity and social mobilisation forced public officials to return public money they had

    misallocated (ibid.).

    Monitoring procurement and implementation. The contracting and implementation

    of public works and services suffer from a high risk of corruption and mismanagement.

    Citizen-based initiatives complement government accountability mechanisms that

    manage these risks supervising contracting and bidding, monitoring construction, and

    auditing budget execution.

    A typical source of corruption and collusion involves drafting tender documents in

    ways that unfairly benefit one contractor over others. Citizens have organised publicconsultations in which different parties get a chance to comment on draft tender

    documents, and independent outsiders conduct an in-depth analysis before the start of

    bidding. In the Philippines, the Local Government Code defines ways in which

    accredited non-governmental and community-based organisations can have a seat on the

    prequalification, bid, and award committee for local contracts. In Argentina, the

    Municipality of Morn, assisted by the local chapter of Transparency International,

    introduced two mechanisms to monitor the contracting of the waste collection service,

    which had been widely criticised for alleged corruption. At an extraordinary session of

    the city council, attended by 500 people, the value of the contract was reduced from

    about $45 million to $32 million.Citizens have also been involved in overseeing the opening and analysis of bidding

    offers, as with the Social Investment Fund in Nicaragua (Grun, 2000). They can also

    oversee construction while it is taking place, and are trained to see that funds are spent

    as allocated and that the construction follows the standards agreed to in the contract.

    Monitoring local service provision. The level and quality of service provision are

    probably what citizens care about most. Participatory assessments and feedback surveys

    are often accompanied by agreements on the standards of services expected.

    One of the main innovations that drew attention to the potential of the social

    accountability approach was the citizen report cards in Bangalore, India (Paul, 2002).

    The cards are participatory surveys that solicit user feedback on the performance ofpublic services. They are used in situations where there are no demand-side data, such

  • 8/2/2019 Linking Local Government Discretion and Accountability in Decentralisation

    20/35

    278 Serdar Yilmaz, Yakup Beris and Rodrigo Serrano-Berthet

    The Authors 2010. Journal compilation 2010 Overseas Development Institute.

    Development Policy Review 28 (3)

    as user perceptions of the quality and satisfaction with public services, and they gather

    demand-side data about state-owned monopolies, many of which lack incentives to be

    responsive. The report-card process relies on extensive media coverage and civil-society

    advocacy to achieve greater accountability in other Indian States, Ghana, Malaysia,

    Senegal and Uganda. In Uganda, a recent report-card project, aimed at reinforcing

    health providers accountability to citizen-clients by enhancing communities ability to

    monitor providers, increased the quality and quantity of primary health-care provision

    (Bjorkman and Svensson, 2007).

    Another example of social scrutiny of local governments is social funds

    committees, user groups that ensure that services are delivered as intended.27

    A

    complement is the citizen charter, a pact between the community and service providers

    that spells out expectations and roles, enabling citizens to interact more effectively with

    the local authority. An example is the Citizens Charter of the Municipality of Mumbai,

    India, which covers detailed public services for each municipal department. Other

    strategies have relied on the creation of new multi-stakeholder institutions to promote

    citizen oversight over a specific local government service. Examples include the local

    school councils in Chicago in the United States (Fung, 2004) and citizen community

    boards and school management committees in Pakistan (ADB/DFID/World Bank,

    2004).

    Citizen monitoring of administrative decisions should be seen as a complement

    and not a substitute for public accountability mechanisms. Citizen-based actions may in

    fact fail to provide effective oversight. Local citizens often lack the knowledge to assess

    adequately the quality of complex services, which results in market imperfections in

    the sense that they cannot properly hold local policy-makers accountable (Lankina,

    2008). What voters can assess is often wasteful, but highly visible, projects, whoseimplementation also rewards narrow clients, not the broader citizenry (Ahmad et al.,

    2005). This was the case in the Czech Republic, where one badly performing

    municipality decided on a very costly but also highly visible bridge across the river

    running through the city (Lankina et al., 2007). Similar caution is needed to judge the

    quality of participation in community activities to monitor local government service

    delivery. Even if participatory mechanisms are in place, which might boost a given

    localitys overall economic development, the levels of participation within the

    community are likely to be lower among those less economically advantaged and the

    benefits of the new participatory arrangements biased toward those who are better-off

    (Lankina, 2008). A study in Uganda found that education and income weredeterminants of membership in such key local government committees as health and

    school management (Azfar et al., 2001).

    27. The empirical record of these mechanisms is mixed, and there is no systematic evaluation of their

    effectiveness (Olowu et al., 2004).

  • 8/2/2019 Linking Local Government Discretion and Accountability in Decentralisation

    21/35

    Linking Local Government Discretion and Accountability in Decentralisation 279

    The Authors 2010. Journal compilation 2010 Overseas Development Institute.

    Development Policy Review 28 (3)

    4 Fiscal discretion and accountability28Local government performance is intrinsically linked to the scope and nature of

    intergovernmental fiscal arrangements. If local governments are denied the fiscal

    instruments and funding to make real use of their political and administrative autonomy,

    decentralisation is doomed.29

    Intergovernmental fiscal rules determine the expenditure

    responsibilities and revenue resources of local governments as well as the design of the

    transfers system and local governments access to capital markets (Bird, 2000).

    4.1 Determinants of local fiscal discretion

    Expenditure assignment

    Devolving expenditure responsibilities to local governments is an important step in

    increasing the participation of citizens in local decision-making.30

    A genuine spirit ofdecentralisation requires assigning a meaningful level of expenditure responsibilities to

    local governments with service autonomy so that they can respond to local needs. More

    importantly, they need the discretion to make their own allocation decisions (with the

    necessary reporting, monitoring and sanctioning).

    In this devolving of responsibilities there should be no room for ambiguity. Clear

    assignment of roles and responsibilities is decisive in shaping accountability

    relationships. If the contest over service-delivery responsibilities is not resolved, it can

    easily constrain local autonomy and reduce the local governments credibility and

    responsiveness. A related issue is unfunded mandates imposed from above. These

    reduce local budgetary autonomy, as was the case in East European countries as theyembarked on decentralisation in the early 1990s (Bird et al., 1995).

    A clear assignment of service responsibilities requires a well-defined institutional

    framework that describes the roles and responsibilities of different levels of government. Lack

    of this is a common problem in East Asia. In Indonesia, for example, although the

    decentralisation law of 1999 gave all authorities to local governments, since authorities are

    broader than functions there is confusion about who is responsible for what, from legislation to

    planning to implementation (Mountfield and Wong, 2005: 95). Clear assignment of

    expenditure responsibilities becomes even more important in sectors where line ministries and

    other government agencies may also deliver services at the local level often in the same

    geographic area. This situation often exists for education, health, and social services in manydeveloping countries. In China and Vietnam, for example, the administrative system

    28. There is a robust literature on the theoretical and implementation aspects of fiscal decentralisation the

    intergovernmental framework (IGF). On the other hand, the interaction between IGF and the political and

    administrative dimensions as well as fiscal discretion and accountability are inadequately studied. Thus,

    this section does not provide an extensive review of IGF issues, but focuses on the linkage between IGF

    and discretion and accountability.

    29. Fiscal decentralisation requires public services with high local-public-good characteristics to be assigned to

    local governments and the rearrangement of roles and responsibilities among different levels of government.

    30. In countries where decentralisation does not end up transferring such responsibilities to local governments,central government departments and public-sector companies continue to deliver most services with high

    local characteristics, such as primary education, health, and public security.

  • 8/2/2019 Linking Local Government Discretion and Accountability in Decentralisation

    22/35

    280 Serdar Yilmaz, Yakup Beris and Rodrigo Serrano-Berthet

    The Authors 2010. Journal compilation 2010 Overseas Development Institute.

    Development Policy Review 28 (3)

    operates as nested hierarchies, and this creates ambiguity about the distribution of

    functions in a multi-tiered setting (Mountfield and Wong, 2005).

    Revenue assignment

    Oatess decentralisation theorem (1972) states that local governments should provide

    services to identifiable recipients up to the point where the value placed on the last

    (marginal) amount of services for which recipients are willing to pay is equal to the

    benefits they receive. The implication is that local governments must be given the

    authority to exercise own-source taxation to self-finance local services at the margin,

    on the premise that local governments are more accountable when relying on their own

    tax bases (Faguet, 2008), and would be less accountable when the pleasure of

    expenditure benefits is separated from the pain of taxation (Bahl and Schroeder, 1983).

    Significant revenue autonomy and some tax-effort incentives are critical to

    encourage downward accountability and increase the efficiency of local governmentoperations.

    31Although there is no set of prescribed rules in revenue assignment,

    subnational governments should at least have rate-setting authority over locally

    assigned revenues (Bahl, 1999a). A completely local tax is one that is assessed and

    collected by local governments at rates decided by and with proceeds accruing to local

    governments (Bird, 2000; Bird and Vaillancourt, 1998).

    In many countries, the central government interferes with local revenue autonomy,

    putting direct or indirect restrictions on local governments discretionary space. In

    Uganda, local governments may impose additional taxes, but only with the approval of

    the Ministry of Local Government; however, there are no standards established for

    approval or rejection (Azfar et al., 2001). Restrictions on revenue generation are similarin the Philippines; the Local Government Code constrains local revenue collection

    through rules on rates, assessments, appeals, and administrative responsibilities

    (USAID, 1999). The accountability implication of each constraint is that they might

    create incentives to make inefficient investment decisions, especially if costs can be

    shifted to central budgets (Campos and Hellman, 2005: 242).

    Financing the fiscal gap

    The design of intergovernmental transfer systems has implications for accountability

    because it affects the fiscal dependence on central government and local revenue-raising

    ability. Four elements determine this dependence (Yilmaz and Bindebir, 2003): the rulesdetermining the total amount of transfer the distributable pool; the way the pool is

    allocated among local governments; the purpose of the transfer system an

    unconditional general purpose grant versus a conditional specific transfer; and the

    design and management of the system.

    A high degree of dependence on transfer revenues and a poorly designed system

    shift the focus of local government accountability away from citizens to central

    31. In some cases, local governments do not seek revenue-raising discretion to avoid accountability. In other

    cases, they do not collect taxes assigned to them. In China, for example, local governments have takenback door approaches, for example, contracts with enterprises, tax holidays, tax administration, and

    trades for investment in public services (Bahl, 1999b: 79).

  • 8/2/2019 Linking Local Government Discretion and Accountability in Decentralisation

    23/35

    Linking Local Government Discretion and Accountability in Decentralisation 281

    The Authors 2010. Journal compilation 2010 Overseas Development Institute.

    Development Policy Review 28 (3)

    governments. In other words, they create an imbalance between downward and upward

    accountability incentives at the local level, negatively affecting local government

    discretion and the incentive to respond to citizen demands. In Nigeria, for example,

    local governments over-dependence on intergovernmental transfer revenues, coupled

    with uncertainty about the amount and timing, facilitates local evasion of responsibility

    under the guise of fiscal powerlessness (Khemani, 2006: 22), while in Uganda, where

    transfers, as earmarked conditional grants, finance more than 80% of local government

    expenditures, a substantial degree of line ministry control over local expenditure

    decisions is maintained.32

    Financing infrastructure: local government borrowing

    Local borrowing is the fourth pillar of the intergovernmental fiscal system. Access to

    capital markets gives local governments an opportunity to finance local investment

    needs. However, heavy reliance on borrowing has put macroeconomic stabilisation atrisk. In the late 1990s, in Argentina, for example, perversely structured

    intergovernmental systems destabilised the economy.

    In countries where central government cannot credibly commit to a hard budget

    constraint, there are irresistible incentives for local governments to exploit borrowing

    and extend their budgets beyond their means (Faguet, 2008). In Bra