lueber swiss debt brake,, pol econ of fiscal deficits

70
The political economy of public debt and budget deficits The Swiss debt brake as a model for sustainable fiscal policy

Upload: benjamin-lueber

Post on 20-Jan-2017

40 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Lueber Swiss Debt Brake,, pol econ of fiscal deficits

The political economy of

public debt and budget deficits

The Swiss debt brake as a model

for sustainable fiscal policy

Page 2: Lueber Swiss Debt Brake,, pol econ of fiscal deficits

2

Master Thesis

Author: Benjamin Lueber

Technical University Dresden

Study program: International Relations,

Global Political Economy

Supervisors: Prof. Dr. Alexander Kemnitz,

Patrick Zwerschke

July 19, 2016

Student number: 3799471

Page 3: Lueber Swiss Debt Brake,, pol econ of fiscal deficits

3

Abstract

English

The debt containment rule adopted in Switzerland in 2003, called the debt brake, is a

Swiss made fiscal rule. The Swiss debt brake has been very successful in reducing

Switzerland’s federal public debt levels, thus leading the federal budget on a

sustainable path. The debt brake as a model for sustainable fiscal policy, however, must

be viewed in light of Switzerland’s specific political context and its unique institutions

that support the Swiss fiscal framework. The most notable political factors include a

general culture of fiscal conservatism, which also becomes evident with the

constraining elements of government expenditure at the cantonal and municipal level,

and a strong parliamentary majority for reining in the growth of federal government

expenditure since the 1990s. The debt brake is the culmination of previous efforts to

constrain public spending and its design is a good reflection of the policymakers’

shared preference for the primacy of automatic stabilizers over discretionary fiscal

policy. The constrains of direct democracy on public spending on Switzerland’s federal,

cantonal, and municipal government level does not singularly limit spending, but

profits from the existence of a federal structure with strong fiscal autonomy and fiscal

referendums in place.

Page 4: Lueber Swiss Debt Brake,, pol econ of fiscal deficits

4

Abstract

German/Deutsch/Allemand/Tedesco

Die Schweizer Schuldenbremse, eingeführt im Jahr 2003, ist das Kind von deutlichen

Schweizer Einflüssen; im Gegensatz beispielsweise zu den supranationalen

Fiskalregeln des Europäischen Stabilitätspakts. Die Bestimmungen der Fiskalregel

führten zu einer nachhaltigen Fiskalpolitik. Die Schuldenbremse als Erfolgsmodell für

Fiskalregeln bedarf allerdings eines genauen Verständnisses seiner landesspezifischen

Erfolgsgrundlagen. Als die wesentlichsten politischen Faktoren gelten: eine

konservative Kultur hinsichtlich staatlicher Ausgaben, welche sich auf kantonaler und

kommunaler Ebene institutionalisiert hat, und eine seit den neunziger Jahren

vorherrschende starke parlamentarische Mehrheit zur Eindämmung der Ausgaben des

Bundeshaushalts. Die Schuldenbremse ist das letzte Element einer schrittweisen

Verstärkung der Mittel zur Schuldenbegrenzung. Die sehr restriktive Fiskalregel

funktionierte auch deshalb, weil seine Ausgestaltung der passende Ausdruck des

politischen Willens einer Präferenz für das Primat von automatischen Stabilisatoren,

verbunden mit einer Abkehr der aktiven Fiskalpolitik, ist. Der direkten Demokratie

wird in der Mehrzahl der Studien ein zu hoher mäßigender Einfluss auf die

Staatsausgaben auf föderaler, kantonaler und Gemeindeebene zugesprochen, da dieses

institutionelle Mittel nur dank anderer Elemente wie einer starken Ausprägung von

Finanzautonomie der Kantone und Gemeinden diese Wirkung ausüben kann.

Page 5: Lueber Swiss Debt Brake,, pol econ of fiscal deficits

5

Acknowledgements

I would like to express my deep gratitude to my master thesis advisors, Professor Dr.

Alexander Kemnitz and PhD student Patrick Zwerschke. I am thankful for their

academic and personal support during the process of writing my master thesis.

While conducting studies on the topic of my thesis, I was able to speak to people

involved with the legislative and executive branches of the government as well as

academia. First, I am grateful for the opportunity to speak with Leo Müller, President

of the Finanzkommission of the CVP (Christian Democratic People’s Party of

Switzerland) and member of the Swiss National Council (Nationalrat). I would also like

to thank Adrian Martínez, economist in the fiscal-policy section of the Swiss Ministry

of Finance (Eidgenössisches Finanzministerium), for his expert advice and for sharing

his insights on Swiss fiscal policy, particularly on the debt brake. Professor Gebhard

Kirchgässner of the University of St. Gallen has published several influential scientific

articles on Swiss fiscal policy and has kindly shared his wide knowledge about this

subject with me. Finally, I would like to thank Dr. Frank Bodmer, who was formerly

employed at the Eidgenössisches Finanzministerium and who published several

scientific investigations on the Swiss debt brake, for a fruitful discussion on the most

important aspects of the functioning of the Swiss debt brake.

Page 6: Lueber Swiss Debt Brake,, pol econ of fiscal deficits

6

List of Illustrations

Figure 1: Gross public debt for the Eurozone, UK, and US, 1970–2004. ..................... 12

Figure 2: General government net lending for the Euro area and OECD countries

(1970–2010). ................................................................................................................. 13

Figure 3: EU countries: Precrisis fiscal performance and national fiscal rules. .......... 17

Figure 4: Budget planning and the use of medium-term budget frameworks (MTBFs).

Average three-year-ahead forecast error. ..................................................................... 21

Figure 5: Cyclically adjusted budget (CAB) balance, CHF million (1980-2012). ......... 31

Figure 6: Budget deficits/surpluses and business cycles, 1970-2000. The red lines

indicate real GDP growth; the blue lines show the balance of the federal budget

(million CHF) ................................................................................................................ 32

Figure 7: Switzerland: Debt-to-GDP ratio of the federal government, cantons, and

communes, 1980-1999. ................................................................................................ 33

Figure 8: Switzerland: International comparison of general government debt ratio (in

percentage of GDP). ...................................................................................................... 33

Figure 9: “Iceberg” metaphor for the Swiss debt brake as the most visible part of the

much larger Swiss fiscal framework. ............................................................................ 35

Figure 10: Correlation between the fiscal stance and the output gap ......................... 39

Figure 11: Ideal development of public expenditure under the provisions of the debt

brake. ............................................................................................................................ 43

Figure 12: Switzerland, gross federal debt (1980–2011). LHS: left-hand side; RHS:

right-hand side. Gross federal debt levels started to decline in 2005, two years after

the introduction of the debt brake due to an economic recession. .............................. 46

Figure 13: Fiscal impulse of the federation and social insurances (1951–2007).

Vertical axis left side: fiscal impulse as a percentage of GDP; right side: real GDP

growth (in percentage points). ..................................................................................... 47

Figure 14: Investment spending (1980–2011). The cyclical nature of investment

spending stopped and steadied under the debt brake. ................................................ 49

Figure 15: Decentralization across the world (98 countries – average 1972–2000);

subnational and expenditure shares. ........................................................................... 52

Figure 16: Swiss parties and their number of votes won (as a percentage of the total

amount of seats) in the elections for the Swiss federal parliament (Nationalrat). ......61

Page 7: Lueber Swiss Debt Brake,, pol econ of fiscal deficits

7

List of abbreviations

EU

European Union

GDP

Gross domestic product

IMF

International Monetary Fund, international organization based in Washington D.C.

MTBF Medium-term budget framework

MTEF Medium-term expenditure framework

OECD

Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development, international organization based in Paris

PFM

Public financial management

SGP Stability and Growth Pact of the European Union

UK

United Kingdom

US

United States of America

Page 8: Lueber Swiss Debt Brake,, pol econ of fiscal deficits

8

List of Contents

1. Introduction ...................................................................................................................... 10

2. Fiscal institutions and their effects on fiscal performance ................................................12

Fiscal institutions’ background and motivation ....................................................................12

Fiscal transparency, fiscal councils, and fiscal rules as the three main ingredients of public

financial management ........................................................................................................... 13

The role and modalities of fiscal rules ...................................................................................16

Fiscal rules and their effects and fiscal outcome ...............................................................16

Ensuring the effectiveness of fiscal rules: A question of institutional environment .........19

3. Political economy of fiscal deficits .................................................................................... 23

Why fiscal planners must be political economists ............................................................... 23

Preference heterogeneity between policymakers and voters ............................................... 24

Heterogeneity of interests across politicians ....................................................................... 25

Heterogeneity of interests across social groups or regions .................................................. 26

Smart reforms of the budget process as an instrument against the common pool problem26

Two forms of fiscal governance: The delegation and contracts approaches ........................ 28

4. Swiss debt brake as a case study for analyzing the effect of political context on the

performance of fiscal rules ....................................................................................................... 30

Background and rationale of the introduction of the Swiss debt brake ............................... 30

Deterioration of public debt levels across all federal levels .............................................. 30

The institutional context of the debt brake ....................................................................... 34

Political culture: Fiscal conservatism as a strong norm in Swiss society ............................ 36

Structural reforms as a means of tackling the procyclical stance of federal fiscal policy .... 38

Characteristics and optimization of the Swiss budget process ............................................ 40

Characteristics of the Swiss debt brake as a type of fiscal rule .............................................41

Page 9: Lueber Swiss Debt Brake,, pol econ of fiscal deficits

9

The operation of the mechanism .......................................................................................41

Enforcement: The functioning and importance of the compensation account ................... 44

Effect and relative success of the fiscal rule since its introduction .................................. 45

Reforms of the budget process resulting from the debt brake ............................................. 49

5. The effect of political context on the performance of the Swiss debt brake ...................... 51

The unique characteristics of the Swiss institutional system and their influence on public

spending ................................................................................................................................ 51

Political environment ............................................................................................................ 51

Fiscal federalism ................................................................................................................ 51

Direct democratic elements .............................................................................................. 53

Primacy of automatic stabilizers .......................................................................................... 56

Made in Switzerland: Political context and the Swiss debt brake ........................................ 62

6. Conclusion ........................................................................................................................ 64

Page 10: Lueber Swiss Debt Brake,, pol econ of fiscal deficits

10

1. Introduction

Before the 2015 parliamentary elections in the United Kingdom (UK) in 2015, the

British Labour Party made fiscally responsible behavior its top priority in the election

campaign. The Budget Responsibility Lock, as the fiscal plan is called in the Labour

manifesto, puts a premium on the national finances by making the plan the basis of all

proposed campaign plans. The commitment to sound public finances is on the cover of

the manifesto, and Ed Miliband, leader of the Labour Party at the time, said his party

was the “party of fiscal responsibility.”1 The party pledges to bind its policies to fiscally

prudent behavior and to achieving deficit reduction every year.2 This focus on solid

public finances is indicative of the heightened importance of fiscal responsibility in

politics and society. Not only in Britain, but also in the majority of countries, both

politicians and the public have realized the relevance of sustainable fiscal policy. But

how can those in power materialize their electoral promises or make efforts to assert

control of public finances? This is the leading question behind this study.

In Switzerland, a fiscal rule called the Swiss debt brake has largely been responsible for

a strong reduction of federal public debt since its introduction in 2003. The fiscal rule,

which requires expenditures to equal revenue, has gained considerable attention

among policymakers and international organizations such as the Organisation for

Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD) and the International Monetary

Fund (IMF) because if its success. For this reason, a better understanding of why and

how this fiscal rule was able to put public finances in Switzerland on a sustainable path

could potentially help other countries to improve their unique fiscal frameworks and

budgetary processes. This study will thus analyze the Swiss debt brake as a model for

controlling public finances and achieving more effective fiscal policies.

The first chapter of this study will introduce the current state of thinking on fiscal

institutions (such as fiscal rules) as well as technical aspects related to the

improvement of public financial management. The discussion provides the necessary

background for understanding the manner in which the design of fiscal institutions

(such as the Swiss debt brake) may increase a country’s fiscal performance. The second

chapter provides theoretical input for assessing how the Swiss debt brake was

1 Buchsteiner (2015): 5 2 The Labour Party (2015)

Page 11: Lueber Swiss Debt Brake,, pol econ of fiscal deficits

11

successful in changing the spending behavior of the political actors responsible for

federal expenditure. Enhancing fiscal policy requires theoretical insights relating to

political economy, since it is as much a political as an economic question.

Subsequently, the Swiss debt brake as a fiscal policy instrument will be studied

regarding the motivation behind its introduction and the structural reforms following

from compliance with its provisions. Thus, this chapter’s analysis will provide

important explanations on the particular conditions that created the necessary political

commitment to the rule, thereby contributing to the rule’s success. Lastly,

Switzerland’s political context will be analyzed in order to determine how its

institutions served to constrain public spending. Another reason for this case study is

the absence of a good understanding of which Switzerland’s political factors made the

rule function. This analysis also makes a general contribution to the assessment of

institutions’ effects on public expenditures; the most relevant institutions for public

spending in Switzerland include its strong federal structure, direct democracy, and a

tradition of power sharing.

This study thus strives to contribute to the evolution of fiscal policy. While the benefits

to the economy via more effective fiscal policy are straightforward, better fiscal

performance is not only a matter of economics and economic welfare: ensuring all

citizens’ trust and belief in public finance forms a major part of democracy (and indeed

of every political system). The debate over effective fiscal policies should not neglect

the way in which citizens consider sustainable fiscal policy to be a central issue for

future generations and a general question of responsible government and legitimacy.

Page 12: Lueber Swiss Debt Brake,, pol econ of fiscal deficits

12

2. Fiscal institutions and their effects on fiscal

performance

Fiscal institutions’ background and motivation

In the course of the last few decades, spurring public debt as a percentage of gross

domestic product (GDP) has been a common concern for most advanced economies.

As illustrated in figure 1, debt levels have accumulated from the late 1970s onward in

most of Europe as well as in the United States of America (US). Pointing to the same

trend, figure 2 demonstrates how governments since the 1970s have consistently run

budget deficits. These numbers are a reflection of a phenomenon called deficit bias.

Although countries have strengthened their fiscal frameworks and have increased their

knowledge about fiscal policy, the quest for sustainable finances will remain a sensitive

issue for the near future.3 This has led many countries to launch structural reforms in

an effort to achieve fiscal discipline and to reduce debt levels to a sustainable level;

these efforts may be summarized as institutional budget reforms.

Figure 1: Gross public debt for the Eurozone, UK, and US, 1970–2004.

Wyplosz (2005): 65

3 See also: Wyplosz (2005): 64-65. In contrast with the evolution of monetary policy, Wyplosz is very

negative on the state and performance of fiscal policy and fiscal rules in the year 2005. He regards it as

“no surprise […] that debts and deficits continue to flourish in many countries.”

Page 13: Lueber Swiss Debt Brake,, pol econ of fiscal deficits

13

It is important to note that fiscal discipline does not demand budgets to be balanced

each year, but deficits do need to be matched by budget surpluses, which is why

focusing on business cycles has proven to be beneficial. In addition, achieving a

sustainable fiscal policy does not necessarily require lowering public debt in absolute

terms: the imperative is to keep the development of public debt stable in relation to

GDP. The growth of public debt must not be higher than GDP growth. The factors

related to the proper implementation of fiscal institutions to reach the goal of solid

fiscal finances will be the focus of this paper.

Figure 2 General government net lending for the Euro area and OECD countries (1970–2010).

Hagemann (2011): 77

Fiscal transparency, fiscal councils, and fiscal rules as the three main

ingredients of public financial management

The management of a country’s public finances is an essential task of government.

Fiscal policy is the means and primary tool by which governments can influence

macroeconomic stability, growth, and income distribution. Due to the key importance

of budgetary policy, numerous studies by international organizations such as the IMF

and the OECD, as well as those conducted within academia, have investigated

Page 14: Lueber Swiss Debt Brake,, pol econ of fiscal deficits

14

institutional budget reforms and best practices for achieving sustainable public

finances.

The proper institutional arrangements that support fiscal policy may be summarized

by the term public financial management (PFM). According to North, PFM is defined

as:

“PFM is concerned with the laws, organizations, systems and procedures

available to governments wanting to secure and use resources effectively,

efficiently and transparently.”4

For example, fiscal sustainability as a key goal of fiscal policy will be strengthened if

budget institutions are properly put in place.5 PFM accordingly is of strong relevance,

since it has a clear bearing on the effectiveness of fiscal policy. Specifically, researchers

have identified three categories of institutional reforms of PFM: fiscal transparency,

fiscal councils, and fiscal rules.6 The transparency of fiscal accounts is strongly linked

with effective fiscal policy; the requirements of fiscal transparency are

“comprehensiveness, quality, and timeliness” in reports on public finances.7 Put

differently, public fiscal reports must be understandable, thus putting citizens in a

position where they can hold the government accountable for fiscal policy.

Furthermore, reports must be reliable and must not leave room for the manipulation

of fiscal positions.8

Fiscal disclosure has improved in recent years, since countries have tried to implement

a “set of internationally accepted standards for fiscal transparency.”9 With good fiscal

transparency in place, it is possible to strongly mitigate fiscal risk; because the financial

crisis has revealed large gaps in fiscal transparency, however, standards and practices

related to fiscal transparency have been refined in recent years.10

Second, various considerations of supporting mechanisms for fiscal policy have

emphasized the importance of fiscal councils. As a result of the allegedly positive effects

of such councils, Canada, Ireland, Portugal, Sweden, and the UK have introduced such

4 Allen, Hemming, Potter (2013b): 1 5 Allen, Hemming, Potter (2013b) 6 Hemming (2013c): 36 7 IMF (2012): 3 8 Ibid. 5 9 IMF (2013): 39 10 IMF (2012): 3

Page 15: Lueber Swiss Debt Brake,, pol econ of fiscal deficits

15

councils in the past few years.11 Both the growing number and the prominence of fiscal

councils have stemmed from their endorsement by international organizations such as

the IMF and the OECD as well as the positive effects illustrated by existing fiscal

councils.12 It should be clear, however, that as with fiscal institutions in general, the

role and modalities of fiscal councils have to be adapted to a country’s unique political

and economic configurations.13 By focusing on the Swiss debt brake, this paper will

provide further analytical backing for this specific argument. Thus, the various fiscal

councils in existence have different mandates, rights, and functions.14

Fiscal councils can potentially have a strong role to play in enforcing fiscal rules.15

Because they are independent and publicly funded, they can inform public debates in

a neutral manner; their analysis of fiscal developments can facilitate budget

preparation and can also prevent politicians from making unrealistic promises by

providing input on the budgetary effects of proposed spending programs.16

Before introducing the third component—fiscal rules—it should be stressed that all

three sets of institutional reforms are linked. In other words, the success and potential

of fiscal rules do not work in isolation and will depend to a large extent on the degree

of fiscal transparency and the configuration of fiscal councils.17 The analysis of the

Swiss debt brake and the Swiss fiscal framework as a whole in the following chapters

will also serve to highlight this central argument. One should also not expect that fiscal

rules will miraculously put public finances on a sustainable path.18 Similarly, the

effectiveness of fiscal rules will be enhanced if they operate within a framework. A

strong argument in favor of framework-based rules is that they are more aligned with

the particular economic conditions and political culture of a country.19 We should bear

11 Hagemann (2011): 76 12 Hagemann (2011): 82 13 Hemming (2013c) 14 IMF (2013): 44 15 Ibid.

16 Frankel, Schreger (2012): 268-270 17 Kopits, Symansky (1998): 1; Schick (2010) makes a similar argument on page 48 of his article, but puts more emphasis on political commitment and disciplined budget procedures. As will be shown in the chapter on the analysis of the Swiss fiscal framework, the Swiss debt brake serves as a neat example of a disciplined budget procedure. It has improved the Swiss fiscal framework decisively with regards to establishing a disciplined budget procedure. 18 Kopits, Symansky (1998): 17 19 Schick (2010): 44

Page 16: Lueber Swiss Debt Brake,, pol econ of fiscal deficits

16

in mind that more variance is to be found in fiscal rules than in monetary or exchange-

rate rules; fiscal rules are also more complex.

Fiscal rules constrain fiscal policy because they track the numerical development of a

certain fiscal indicator and require political decisions in case inconsistent fiscal policies

are enacted. Fiscal rules may be grouped into four different categories: expenditure

rules, budget-balancing rules, debt rules, and revenue rules; the rules are classified

according to the fiscal indicators or target variables they use. The first category,

expenditure rules, are also called “ceilings” because they predetermine a given level of

government expenditure before budget preparations begin. The second type (budget-

balancing rules) limit government spending by capping spending to the amount of

revenues; those rules may require the budget to be balanced over a business cycle,

meaning that budget deficits must be subsequently matched by surpluses.20 Third, debt

rules are limits that apply to the amount of government debt; these limits may be set

in nominal terms or as a ratio to GDP.

The role and modalities of fiscal rules

Fiscal rules and their effects and fiscal outcome

In most developed countries, fiscal rules have been established against the background

of such rules’ potential role in reaping the benefits of solid finances; it appears that EU

countries with national fiscal rules in place have generally achieved better fiscal

performance than those without. Graph 3 shows the average structural balance of 27

EU countries over the time period of 2002 to 2007. The effect of these rules on sound

fiscal outcomes can yield positive results through macroeconomic stability, fiscal

responsibility, and overall policy credibility.21 Macroeconomic stability is largely

strengthened through the following channels. Fiscal rules that increase fiscal discipline

can provide stability, because the very notion of fiscal sustainability implies that fiscal

policies may be maintained indefinitely; unsustainable fiscal policy, in contrast, will

have negative implications on the economy by creating an atmosphere of uncertainty.

This occurs because businesses and consumers will ultimately expect the government

20 Wyplosz (2005): 69 21 Kopits, Symansky (1998): 6

Page 17: Lueber Swiss Debt Brake,, pol econ of fiscal deficits

17

to introduce changes to fiscal policy.22 Alongside other negative effects, this type of

situation might lead companies to withhold investments, as occurred in 2013, when

the US government experienced a deadlock in negotiations on a debt-reduction plan.23

Figure 3: EU countries: Precrisis fiscal performance and national fiscal rules.

IMF (2013): 43

Fiscal rules may also serve as a deterrent of procyclical fiscal policy, thereby weakening

fluctuations of the business cycle; such rules may then support a key element of fiscal

policy, which is the stabilization of production and employment. Although most

governments understand the need for countercyclical fiscal policy, actual practice has

shown that most countries will increase their government spending when more

revenue becomes available during economic upswings. Fiscal rules may therefore lack

the required political commitment to correct the imbalance that was described above

as deficit bias. Fiscal expenditure rules, for example, leave less room for political

22 European Central Bank (2009): 17 23 New York Times (2014). The Article called “Uncertainty in Washington poses long list of economic perils” describes the negative effect of uncertain US fiscal policy on US businesses and economic growth. The Business Roundtable (a representation of the main executives of the nation’s biggest companies) is quoted as using their leverage to achieve stability in tax and fiscal policy.

Page 18: Lueber Swiss Debt Brake,, pol econ of fiscal deficits

18

bickering because they clearly set a ceiling for spending. Violation of the expenditure

rule is also made more difficult, since the rule’s operations are transparent.24

It is equally important to emphasize the correlation between persistent fiscal deficits

and high debt (on one side) and economic growth on the other. The main result of an

empirical study by Rogoff and Reinhart (“Growth in a Time of Debt,” published in

2010) was that countries with levels of public debt over roughly 90 percent of GDP will

experience significantly lower levels of economic growth. 25 Their study served as a

strong reference in the public debate over public finances and elevated public debt

levels at the time of the paper’s publication. For example, advocates of austerity

measures during the Eurozone debt crisis used the Rogoff/Reinhart investigation as

part of their scientific evidence in favor of austerity.26 Fiscal rules, when they are

effective, create fiscal space, thus allowing for fiscal policy responses to economic

crises, natural disasters, or other obligations.27 If countries that lack fiscal buffers

spend money in response to critical situations, the chances will be even higher that

fiscal sustainability or the stability of the economy will be compromised.28

Another significant advantage of fiscal rules is that they can lead to lower borrowing

costs for public debt on the capital market. This financial gain is materialized indirectly

through fiscal responsibility, as perceived by financial actors.29 One reason many

emerging economies have introduced fiscal rules is because they want to reinforce the

image that they are fiscally disciplined, which will then allow them to profit from open

capital markets.

24 Anderson, Sheppard (2009): 20 25 Rogoff, Reinhart (2010) 26 In 2013, Jens Weidmann, president of the German Bundesbank, defended the need for fiscal consolidation in the European Union and argued against critics who raised doubts about the scientific value of the study by K. Rogoff and C. Reinhart. Source: http://www.zeit.de/wirtschaft/2013-04/weidmann-rogoff-reinhart-studie 27 Hemming (2013c): 32-33 28 Marcel (2013): 10 29 Hemming (2913c): 29-34

Page 19: Lueber Swiss Debt Brake,, pol econ of fiscal deficits

19

Ensuring the effectiveness of fiscal rules: A question of institutional

environment

This section discusses fiscal rules and the conditions related to their effects on fiscal

performance. As was briefly noted earlier, the specific contributions of fiscal rules and

fiscal institutions in general on fiscal outcomes are difficult to assess.30 Stated another

way, causality between good fiscal rules and the effects of those rules is difficult to

ascertain. Although data might indicate correlations, empirical studies may be flawed

due to the “endogeneity” problem. In other words, the fiscal rules themselves might

only be expressions of the already-established preference and commitment to sound

public finances that are shared by voters and politicians alike.31 Indeed, in cases where

fiscal discipline is maintained without restraints by rules, fiscal rules might be

redundant; alternatively, fiscal rules will lose their strength when governments do not

provide proper enforcement and commitment over a medium time frame.32

Despite the reservations enumerated above, it is possible to make a few valid points

about the design and performance of fiscal rules. As a general rule, fiscal rules fare

better when governments maintain good formulation and good operation of the rules.

Fiscal rules must first be applied before the budget is approved; apart from this

commonality, fiscal rules feature different characteristics. Allen Schick, professor and

leading scholar in the field of budget policy and budget processes, has identified five

criteria regarding the improvement and evaluation of fiscal rules:

i. The time frame should be lengthened from a single year to the medium term;

ii. Baseline projections (or forward estimates) should be created of future

budgetary conditions;

iii. Estimates should be made of the impact of policy changes on future budgets;

iv. (Procedures should be enacted for monitoring budget out-turns and for taking

corrective action when necessary; and)

v. Enforcement mechanisms should be put in place to prevent opportunistic

politicians from breaching the rules.33

30 Anderson, Sheppard (2009): 21 31 Millar (1997): 18-19 32 Anderson, Sheppard (2009): 21 33 Schick (2003): 8-9

Page 20: Lueber Swiss Debt Brake,, pol econ of fiscal deficits

20

First, the performance of fiscal rules will be jeopardized if budget-making is

constrained by a short-term focus (annual or biennial), since this can allow

governments to evade fiscal pressures by shifting expenditures to the following fiscal

years or by gaining short-lived increases in government income. Governments can

avoid this short-term focus by extending the time frame, for example by applying a

medium-term expenditure framework (MTEF). This framework imposes limits on

expenditures for each fiscal year during a three- to five-year time frame.

Second, fiscal rules’ performance will be strengthened by using medium-term budget

frameworks (MTBF); these enhance fiscal-policy planning in several ways, one of

which is to provide an improved perspective of future budgetary conditions (ii). The

path of public expenditure will be more clearly delineated under such frameworks, thus

allowing for more accurate projections of fiscal developments. Baseline projections

show how the budget develops when current spending policies are maintained when

operating under certain demographic, macroeconomic, microeconomic, and other

assumptions, which allows governments to measure the impact of different policy

proposals on the budget balance. Governments can also use these projections to trace

future fiscal pressures, including any significant changes in demographics, such as

aging (iii). MTBFs can thus be seen as a support element for fiscal rules.34

In addition, a 2013 study by Harris et al. provided evidence that countries with strong

and binding MTBFs, as is the case with Sweden and the UK, are more accurate in

predicting expenditure and revenue levels.35 Figure 4 provides an illustration of the

differences in forecasting errors between EU countries; the numbers in the graph

demonstrate how forecasting expenditures and revenue improve due to the existence

of binding MTBFs. EU member countries with indicative (or no) MTBFs, in contrast,

generally show more forecasting errors. It would appear to be good practice to make

long-term fiscal projections of ten years or more; in addition, reports on fiscal

projections should be announced every year.36

34 Schick (2003): 8-9 35 Harris et al. (2013): 145 36 Anderson, Sheppard (2009): 8-10

Page 21: Lueber Swiss Debt Brake,, pol econ of fiscal deficits

21

Figure 4: Budget planning and the use of medium-term budget frameworks (MTBFs). Average three-

year-ahead forecast error.

IMF (2013): 38

The intelligent design of fiscal rules is essential with enforcement mechanisms; the

general advice is that fiscal constraints must dovetail with the prevailing political

culture.37 For example, fiscal rules that are formulated as hard constraints will have no

value if they ignore political realities. This argument seems to favor country-specific

rules over supranational rules. As an external constraint on fiscal policy, for example,

the EU’s Stability and Growth Pact (SGP) is a uniform rule for all EU member states:

all member states must comply with its specifications regardless of their political

commitment and political culture. The performance of supranational rules can be

improved, however, if they are combined with national fiscal rules that are more

binding.38 Empirical evidence on the fiscal performance of EU countries with

additional fiscal rules in place supports this argument. Figure 3 demonstrates the

difference in average structural balance from 2002-2007.

Finally, it is important to consider the question of which fiscal aggregate should be

targeted. As was discussed earlier, fiscal rules may be categorized into four types;

among these four types, choosing expenditure rules is arguably the best option,

because doing so has several advantages. First, expenditure rules are more credible.

37 Schick (2010): 36-37 38 Ibid. 43

Page 22: Lueber Swiss Debt Brake,, pol econ of fiscal deficits

22

Credibility comes from increased transparency, since the operation of the rules is easier

to monitor and follow. Second, expenditure rules allow for improved verification.

Third, it has been brought forward that expenditure rules correlate better with

macroeconomic stabilization than deficit rules.; while deficit rules work procyclically

in fiscal expansions and fiscal recessions, expenditure rules work countercyclically.

Part of their explanation for this is that expenditure rules do not infringe on the

operation of automatic stabilizers.39 Fourth, Anderson and Sheppard (who were

officials at the OECD at the time of their study’s publication) argue that spending rules

are more effective in ensuring fiscal responsibility.40 The crucial test of fiscal rules is

whether or not they create budget surpluses in good economic conditions. A 2013 study

by the IMF supports this argument; it concurs that fiscal constraints must be strong

under favorable economic circumstances. The study adds that fiscal policy must have

more flexibility in unfavorable economic circumstances. Because spending rules are

less rigid in terms of deficits, such rules provide policymakers with more flexibility in

terms of fiscal policy.41

39 Anderson, Sheppard (2009): 20-21 40 Ibid. 41 IMF (2013): 41-44

Page 23: Lueber Swiss Debt Brake,, pol econ of fiscal deficits

23

3. Political economy of fiscal deficits

Why fiscal planners must be political economists

The preceding discussion on the design of fiscal institutions, with its special focus on

fiscal rules, has highlighted several key issues related to the way in which well-designed

fiscal institutions can lead to improved fiscal performance. In this sense, the analysis

yielded several insights into the ways that political factors shape the effect of fiscal

institutions. Yet these considerations took a somewhat technocratic approach by

discussing institutional budgetary reforms without having a firm grasp of the

underlying political realities. Public finance managers have become better about

incorporating the necessary political elements in recent years. In order to provide a

more comprehensive picture of the design of fiscal institutions, this chapter will

present the most relevant theoretical concepts and arguments on the topic that have

been put forth to date. It should be noted, however, that these theoretical ideas taken

together do not represent one unified theory (which might be called the “political

economy theory of fiscal deficits”); still, it is crucial to understand the theoretical

arguments for the implementation of fiscal rules as a means to address each country’s

unique fiscal problems.

A reasonable starting point for investigating the underlying causes of deficit bias is

politicians’ propensity for spending public money. For this reason, electoral pressures

are generally considered to be a major root cause of deficit spending, since one could

argue that politicians will not resist the popular effects of government spending. Put

simply, stimulating the economy brings votes. As researchers have moved ahead in

examining this argumentation, however, they have shown that statement to be both

vague and simplified. Theoretical classifications that narrow down the politico-

institutional determinants of government budgets—as Marcela Eslava did in her survey

study on “the political economy of fiscal deficits”—distinguish between three kinds of

preference heterogeneities. Eslava makes the general point that preference

heterogeneities lead to conflicts of interest. According to Eslava, preference

heterogeneities can be classified in three different ways:

i. Preference heterogeneity between policymakers and voters,

ii. Heterogeneity of fiscal preferences across politicians, and

Page 24: Lueber Swiss Debt Brake,, pol econ of fiscal deficits

24

iii. Heterogeneity of fiscal preferences across social groups or regions42

Preference heterogeneity between policymakers and voters

A central element in the first grouping of theoretical models is the assumption of

opportunism as a key driving force of politicians’ excessive use of public money. But

transforming fiscal-policy measures into better chances of staying in office is only a

feasible option as long as stimulus packages remain popular among the electorate: in

other words, such transformations rest on the premise of “fiscal illusion.” According to

this concept, voters favor current spending because voters underestimate the future

costs of spending programs. This early theoretical concept has lost much of its

explanatory power, however; one of its shortcomings is the assumption that the

electorate does not learn the basic lesson of the implicit future costs of deficit spending

nor of the short-lived nature of the engineered economic expansion.43

This assumption is also inconsistent with studies that have demonstrated that voters

support conservative fiscal policies. In many cases, governments that embark on fiscal-

adjustment programs will align with voters’ fiscal preferences. The majority of studies

have suggested that office holders who choose to rein in deficits will be more likely to

be rewarded at the polls.44 Another factor that needs to be taken into account is that

fiscal contraction need not stifle economic activity, which should have a positive effect

on the public’s perception of fiscal adjustments.45 Some have argued that when

governments introduce structural reforms during periods of fiscal tightening they build

the foundation for dynamic economic activity, thus increasing the popularity of these

reforms among voters. The UK’s achievement of solid economic growth from 2013-

2015 after implementing a fiscal-adjustment that started in 2010 is a good illustration

of this point.46

42 Eslava (2011): 646 43 Ibid. 647 44 Ibid. 650 45 Ibid.; See also Alesina et al (1998) for a more extensive study. The authors studied episodes of fiscal adjustment in 19 countries from 1960-1995 and did not find general evidence for fiscal adjustments causing economic downturns. 46 According to Eurostat, the country manifested economic growth rates in these years of 2.3, 2.9 and 2.3 per cent of GDP, respectively.

Page 25: Lueber Swiss Debt Brake,, pol econ of fiscal deficits

25

Still, the opportunism theory remains valuable in countries whose citizens have a

limited understanding of the government’s budget. The government’s ability to

monitor fiscal policy is conditioned by the “government’s accounting practices, media

development, and the sophistication of voters,” not to mention low transparency as a

general element.47 Alt and Lassen argue that fiscal expansions before elections are

more likely to take place in countries with low levels of budget transparency.48 In

general, empirical studies tend to support the argument that pre-electoral spending

increases in political environments with the lack of monitoring capacity described

earlier.49 In her survey study, Eslava summarizes that politicians adapt fiscal policy as

a response to upcoming elections in the form of changes in the composition of

spending; she argues that under certain conditions, policymakers shift financial

resources between spending categories because some expenditures will have a more

positive impact on voters.50

Heterogeneity of interests across politicians

Theoretical models in this grouping operate under the premise that budget decision

makers who run fiscal deficits are motivated by competition with other political parties

(which hold different views of spending priorities). One explanation focuses on office

holders’ strategic use of fiscal deficits as a way to limit the fiscal room that is available

to opposing political parties. Within this logic, the prospect of losing at the polls

increases the probability of budget deficits; the level of polarization or degree of

partisanship in a political system thus plays a crucial role. Not surprisingly, several

investigations of fiscal preferences of left- and right-wing governments have been

conducted; evidence in this field tends to attribute a higher propensity for fiscal deficits

to left-leaning governments, because leftist ideology generally considers that a key task

of the government is to take an active role in income redistribution. In other words,

left-wing ruling parties are more likely to assume a larger role in steering and

intervening in the economy.51

47 Eslava (2011): 648 48 Alt, Lassen (2006) 49 Eslava (2011): 650 50 Ibid. 651-652 51 Leachman et al. (2007): 372-374

Page 26: Lueber Swiss Debt Brake,, pol econ of fiscal deficits

26

Left-wing governments are also more likely to use fiscal-policy tools to target and

reduce unemployment. It is generally known that right-wing governments, on the

contrary, are more fiscally conservative. Countering inflation, for example, will be of

more importance to such parties, because higher inflation creates more “uncertainty

[about] the return on financial and physical capital.”52 For the strategic reasons

mentioned above, however, right-wing governments may nevertheless feel urged to use

deficits to constrain the spending possibilities of a possible rival party that will succeed

the conservative party’s time in power.53

Heterogeneity of interests across social groups or regions

Finally, conflicts of interest may arise through different fiscal preferences across social

groups or regions. In effect, this problem stems from central revenue being

administered and distributed in a way that benefits certain social groups, while the

costs are shared by all taxpayers.54 This is known as the “common pool resource”

problem, where the common pool represents government revenue. Jürgen von Hagen

uses the common pool problem as the starting point for ways to alleviate the inherent

challenges of budget processes. His thinking has influenced strategies to modify budget

processes in a manner that will ultimately lead to more effective controls of public

finances.

Smart reforms of the budget process as an instrument against the

common pool problem

This section provides additional analyses of the budget process and demonstrates how

political dynamics are contained in the budget process and display themselves during

the process’s various phases. This analytical step also shows more precisely how fiscal

institutions (such as fiscal rules) have the capacity to enable changes. Von Hagen and

Harden have characterized the budget process in three phases: the executive planning

stage, the legislative approval stage, and the implementation stage; to these three

52 Leachman et al. (2007): 372 53 Eslava (2011): 652-655 54 Ibid. 655-569

Page 27: Lueber Swiss Debt Brake,, pol econ of fiscal deficits

27

stages, the ex post accountability stage, in which the final budget documents are

scrutinized, could also be added. Formulating the budget is ultimately a political

exercise; as Wildavsky argues, it is a result of “political interest groups [that engage in

bargains] over conflicting goals, make side payments, and try to motivate one another

to accomplish their objectives.”55 Because these actions have become formalized in the

budget process, the process is a specification of the different dynamics involved in

preparing and implementing the budget.56

During the first stage, the executive department of the government proposes and plans

the budget; the budget is then passed to the legislature, where debate, amendment, and

voting take place. The final phase is the implementation of the budget by the respective

bureaucratic departments. The executive planning stage, as its name implies, sets

spending and deficit targets, all the while reconciling the interests of all of the actors

involved. An important note is that fiscal rules must already be respected at this stage,

which means that the fiscal targets that are written into the fiscal rules should already

be observed. Provisions of fiscal rules should also be directed toward facilitating

agreement between spending ministries/departments;57 this is the case when the rules

strengthen the public’s collective interest in achieving a balanced budget versus the

incentives of the respective ministries/departments.58 The procedures that govern

budgetary voting will have decisive leverage over the final budget outcome;

participants in the process will generally pay particular attention to restraining

spending decisions that depart from the agreed-upon budget. It would thus seem

advisable to strengthen the role of the finance minister in overseeing and controlling

government expenditures during the fiscal year.59

55 Wildavsky (1975): 4. The academic work of political scientist Aaron Wildavsky on the budget process has had a seminal influence on the field. His work has helped understanding the politics in budget making and the budget process and guided later work on the political economy of public debt. 56 Von Hagen, Harden (1995): 771-772 57 Hallerberg, Yläoutinen (2010): 47 58 Von Hagen, Harden (1995): 775 59 Hallerberg, Yläoutinen (2010): 47

Page 28: Lueber Swiss Debt Brake,, pol econ of fiscal deficits

28

Two forms of fiscal governance: The delegation and contracts

approaches

Hallerberg and Yläoutinen’s 2010 study is a good example of how analyses of the

effective implementation of fiscal institutions can be enriched by including

considerations of political economy. Their study incorporates the specific rules, norms,

and institutions that are in place in different Eastern European countries as a means

of examining which fiscal rules and institutions can be successfully combined with the

existing form of government. The paper builds on previous work that distinguished

between two forms of fiscal governance, with the effectiveness of their established

mechanisms depending largely on the respective configurations of the political system.

A central result of their study is that fiscal performance is weakened when countries do

not opt for the best form of fiscal governance to adopt for their unique situations.60

The two forms of fiscal governance are the delegation and contracts approaches; each

has different guidelines for modeling the budget process. The delegation form of fiscal

governance emphasizes the centralization of the budget process as a key requirement;

in this approach, budgeting power is placed in the hands of a “fiscal entrepreneur,” who

is usually the finance minister. Ideally, such ministers’ authority will allow them to

fulfill the following responsibilities: 1) assuming the function as head negotiator of the

diverging interests between spending departments, 2) setting the budget outline, 3)

ensuring that other participants in the process stick to the fiscal plan, 4) monitoring

the executive members of government, and 5) punishing or sanctioning spending

decisions that are not in accordance with the determined budget plan. To be clear,

these functions demand the presence of hierarchical structures within the government

as well as between government and the legislature.61

Although the literature lends much credence to the benefits of centralizing the

budgetary process on the balancing of the budget, strong objections could be raised

that the effects of such centralization will be counterproductive in those countries with

political traditions of power sharing or the existence of coalition governments. A

contracts form of fiscal governance would arguably be a better solution for these

60 Hallerberg, Yläoutinen (2010) 61 Von Hagen, Harden (1995); Von Hagen (2006): 470-473.

Page 29: Lueber Swiss Debt Brake,, pol econ of fiscal deficits

29

political settings, because concentrating budgetary capacity in one ministry contradicts

the idea of power sharing in a ruling coalition.62

This approach instead works with contracts as a way to make the agreements of the

fiscal plan more binding: more specifically, the ruling parties will agree to a multi-

annual fiscal plan. This form of fiscal governance essentially provides an adequate

mechanism for improving the bargaining process; its main advantage lies in its ability

to mitigate distributional conflicts between the parties, because it sets boundaries for

the spending authorities. These limits can then be defined in the coalition agreement,

for example. At the beginning of the budgeting process, the cabinet (which will include

members from different parties) decides to set a spending cap for each individual

ministry. In this approach, the responsibility and power to monitor compliance with

the spending limits are in the hands of the legislature, which in general plays a larger

role than the executive branch in this form of fiscal governance. An additional

observation may be made about the trade-offs between these two approaches.

Hallerberg and Yläoutinen have argued that hierarchical institutions, as the modus

operandi within the delegation approach, are more effective in targeting persistent

deficits and achieving overall fiscal discipline.63 In contrast, Alesina and Perotti note

that the contract approach’s key strength is its ability to reconcile the interests of

different partisan groups: in this approach, budget outcomes do not merely include the

interests of the governing majority.64

62 Von Hagen (2002): 275-278 63 Hallerberg, Yläoutinen (2010): 46-53 64 Alesina, Perotti (1995): 17

Page 30: Lueber Swiss Debt Brake,, pol econ of fiscal deficits

30

4. Swiss debt brake as a case study for analyzing the effect

of political context on the performance of fiscal rules

Background and rationale of the introduction of the Swiss debt brake

Deterioration of public debt levels across all federal levels

The numbers and data on the development of public finances in Switzerland reveal

trends that are similar to the acceleration of public debt for most other advanced

economies from roughly the 1970s on. Figure 5 tracks the development of the cyclically

adjusted budget balance for the Swiss federal budget between 1980 and 2012. The data

reveals that the deficit bias pervaded fiscal policy in Switzerland as well as in these

other nations; the numbers also demonstrate a strong increase in federal debt levels

from the 1990s on. In the Swiss federal system, the cantonal and municipal levels (the

two layers of government below the federal level) demonstrated a similarly negative

fiscal performance as the federal level. Figure 6 shows that strong budget deficits

occurred against the background of an economic recession that started around 1990,

from which the Swiss economy emerged only around 1998. Economic growth was

remarkably low during that entire decade, with average growth rates of less than 0.4

percent per year.65 Including all three government layers of the Swiss federal system,

the gross debt-to-GDP ratio saw a steep rise from 31 percent of GDP in 1990 up to 54

percent of GDP in 1998.66 The share of federal government debt was at approximately

25 percent (see figure 6).

65 Bodmer (2006): 310 66 Danninger (2002): 4

Page 31: Lueber Swiss Debt Brake,, pol econ of fiscal deficits

31

Figure 5: Cyclically adjusted budget (CAB) balance, CHF million (1980-2012).

The graph clearly demonstrates the improvement of the Swiss budget balance from the year 2003 on.

Beljean and Geier (2013): 119

The fiscal situation seems less severe, however, when compared with other countries’

states of public debt at the time (see figure 7); Switzerland’s fiscal record scores well in

international comparisons, and its fiscal situation would have permitted the country to

join the Euro zone had it desired to do so. The EU Growth and Stability Pact requires

Euro zone candidates to have a debt-to-GDP ratio of less than sixty percent.

Although debt-to-GDP ratios were below the OECD average,67 the resoluteness in

response to the fiscal malady was not. The Swiss debt brake, which represents a forceful

restraint on fiscal policy, is the culmination of a series of previous attempts and

deliberations on regulating fiscal policy. The fiscal expenditure rule went into effect in

67 Bodmer (2006): 310

Page 32: Lueber Swiss Debt Brake,, pol econ of fiscal deficits

32

2003 and is called “debt brake” because its target is to put a brake on the accumulation

of debt.

Figure 6: Budget deficits/surpluses and business cycles, 1970-2000. The red lines indicate real GDP

growth; the blue lines show the balance of the federal budget (million CHF)

Beljean (2001): 35

Page 33: Lueber Swiss Debt Brake,, pol econ of fiscal deficits

33

Figure 7: Switzerland: Debt-to-GDP ratio of the federal government, cantons, and communes, 1980-

1999.

Communes is a different word for municipalities, meaning the lowest urban administrative division. In

Switzerland, they possess considerable powers of self-government and jurisdiction. Danninger (2002):

4

Figure 8: Switzerland: International comparison of general government debt ratio (in percentage of

GDP).

Danninger (2002): 4; slightly modified.

Page 34: Lueber Swiss Debt Brake,, pol econ of fiscal deficits

34

The institutional context of the debt brake

The introduction of the debt brake, and the stringent and restrictive quality of that debt

brake, must be seen in light of previous Swiss measures that aimed to achieve solid

finances. The growing realization of the role of structural imbalances in promoting

fiscal deficits played a central role in policymakers’ strong resolve to find rules-based

responses. Since 1958, a specific article of the Swiss constitution demands the

reduction of federal debt.

The constitutional provision, however, was unable to stop the rise of public debt in the

wake of the long economic recession of the 1990s. Similarly, other policy measures that

aimed to constrain fiscal policy proved to be ineffective, although they did provide a

good foundation for the introduction of the debt brake. In 1995, the government

implemented a fiscal rule that increased the voting requirements in parliament for new

spending items; this rule, called the “expenditure brake,” is still binding on spending

decisions and works alongside the debt brake. In the three years following the

introduction of that brake, the Swiss government enacted legislation on a budgetary

goal for the year 2001 as well as a fiscal-adjustment program for 1998. The latter

consisted of specific consolidation measures that aimed to reduce the structural deficit

to 2 percent by the year 2001.

The budget is considered to be in a structural deficit if the budget is in permanent

deficit, regardless of whether the general economic conditions are improving or

deteriorating. In this case structural reasons are responsible for the accumulation of

debt. In other words, favorable economic conditions will not lead to a balanced budget.

One could argue that the fiscal consolidation that Switzerland achieved thus provided

fertile ground and a good transitioning phase for the introduction of the debt brake in

2002. For example, the policy programs were stringent in demanding a reduction of

the structural deficit.

Page 35: Lueber Swiss Debt Brake,, pol econ of fiscal deficits

35

Figure 9: “Iceberg” metaphor for the Swiss debt brake as the most visible part of the much larger Swiss

fiscal framework.

In addition, the move toward a federal debt brake must be assessed against the

increased utilization of debt brakes that was initiated at the cantonal level in the

1990s.68 Because the cantonal governmental level has considerable spending authority,

the institutional reforms may have stimulated thinking about the proper technical

design of a debt brake at the federal level. According to an empirical study performed

in 2002, fiscal rules that have been established at the cantonal level have had a

significant effect on constraining public finances in the time frame from 1980 to

1998.69

68 Kirchgässner (2013): 123-124 69 Schaltegger (2002)

Budget Objective 2001

Previous constitutional requirement regarding budget balance and debt

reduction (since 1958)

Previous expenditure brake ("Ausgabenbremse," 1995)

Debt stabilization plan 1998

Constitutional limits on federal tax increases

Parallel fiscal institutions on lower levels of government (cantons and communes) with considerable fiscal autonomy:

- Most cantons provide for fiscal and budget referendums

(influence on public finances through direct democracy and the elaborate federal structure; positive effects on fiscal transparency)

- Debt brakes were established in some cantons before the debt brake was introduced on the federal level (e.g., St.Gallen 1929; Freiburg and Basel-

Stadt)

Other

elements of the

Swiss fiscal

framework

Surface of

the water Tip of the iceberg. The

most visible part of the

Swiss fiscal framework.

Page 36: Lueber Swiss Debt Brake,, pol econ of fiscal deficits

36

Political culture: Fiscal conservatism as a strong norm in Swiss society

The Swiss political culture also seems to have been a driving force behind the search

for improved fiscal performance. In comparison with other OECD countries, public

finances in Switzerland were not particularly worrisome during the 1990s. Yet

according to Swiss standards, the debt-to-GDP ratio had reached a critical level at the

time, which was widely considered to be unacceptable.70 One example was the rise of

federal public debt from 11.8 percent of GDP in 1990 to 27 percent in 1998, which some

described as an “explosion” of public debt.71 Swiss academics and politicians alike

found drastic words to signal the need to reverse the tendency toward debt

accumulation. As can be seen in figure 8 above, the majority of countries in Europe had

higher levels of public debt than Switzerland.

In 1999, the Swiss Federal Council adopted a policy document of guiding principles for

fiscal policy that established two central goals of fiscal policy: a balanced budget over

the business cycle and the elimination of the structural deficit. While it is true that the

relevance of this document is limited, it is important to note that the policy document

was worked out by all of the members of the Federal Council together. Its importance

should not be understated, since this basic agreement over the management of the

country’s public finances now serves as the foundation for fiscal measures; it also

managed to capture a consensus view of the guiding principles and therefore helped

build a consensus for the strict fiscal measures that were adopted in the years that

followed.

The political-culture component should not be overlooked: growing concern over

rising levels of public debt arguably permeated not only Swiss society but also the ranks

of policymakers. It would seem plausible that this culture was at least partially

responsible for the deliberations that were enacted to create institutional mechanisms

to target the budget deficits. Graph 16 (page 59) shows how the right-wing Swiss

People’s Party (Schweizerische Volkspartei, or SVP) found success during federal

elections in the 1990s. One of the SVP’s positions is small government size (i.e.,

controlling or stabilizing the growth of government expenditures). It is quite evident

70 Bodmer (2006): 310 71 Frey (2007): 21

Page 37: Lueber Swiss Debt Brake,, pol econ of fiscal deficits

37

that growing frustration with the public finances was also an element that could be

seen in official documents that were published in the 1990s.72

Polls show that sound fiscal policy consistently enjoys broad support among the Swiss

people. Voters’ control and supervision of the government’s finances fit well with the

limited authority of the Swiss government to tax its citizens. Legislative changes to

increase the most decisive types of taxes (direct federal taxes and value-added taxes)

consistently face strong barriers, since they require constitutional amendments,

although this anti-taxation element—a fiscal institution in itself—has provided for an

asymmetry between spending and revenue.”73 A “revenue brake” in its effect, it has

arguably contributed to the deficit bias because it strengthened the incentive “towards

excessive expenditure”.

The expenditure-limiting mechanism (i.e., the debt brake) was brought to an

obligatory referendum in 2001 after being prepared by the federal council and

parliament, because the Swiss political system requires that amendments to the

constitution be approved through a referendum. In a strong manifestation of domestic

support for prudent fiscal policy, the referendum was approved by an overwhelming

majority (84.7 percent) of voters. The successful referendum resulted in a

constitutional amendment, thus embedding the debt brake in the constitution. The

transcription of the fiscal rule in the Swiss constitution is a distinctive element that

may be compared with the design of fiscal rules in most other countries.74

The involvement of Swiss citizens in the creation of the debt brake is important to

consider. Direct democracy has shown strong potential to contribute to the

effectiveness of the Swiss debt brake (and to fiscal rules in general). The major impact

of the citizens’ involvement may be to ensure compliance with the rule and to

strengthen the rule’s credibility. Beljean and Geier (officials at the Swiss Ministry of

Finance) suggest that enforcement of Switzerland’s political architecture depends on a

bottom-up channel as opposed to top-down approaches, as is the case under the SGP

of the European Monetary Union. The authors argue that the public inclination for

72 See for example Bundesrat (1997): 206. (The Bunderat is the federal government of Switzerland.) The Budget Objective is said to be the “logical response” to “very concerning federal budget problems.” See also chapter 13 page 211 and following in which sustained budget deficits are decried and regarded as connected with multiple negative effects. They would also lead to a loss of trust of citizens and companies in the state. 73 Beljean, Geier (2013): 132 74 Bundesrat (1997): 212

Page 38: Lueber Swiss Debt Brake,, pol econ of fiscal deficits

38

solid public finances serves as a strong and continuous support of the stipulations of

the debt brake. According to these officials, this is especially true due to the absence of

a constitutional court (such as the Supreme Court in the USA) that could rule on and

oversee the government’s budgetary practices.75

Structural reforms as a means of tackling the procyclical stance of

federal fiscal policy

Prior to the adoption of the debt brake, the fiscal policy of the federal government has

exhibited strong procyclical tendencies. According to an empirical study published in

2010 (covering the time period between 1951 and 2007), Swiss federal fiscal policy

delivered the preferred anticyclical effect in only 60 percent of cases.76 This finding was

supported by a 2002 study by Joumard and Giornio on the effectiveness of public

spending in Switzerland.77 As illustrated by graph 10, Switzerland had applied

procyclical fiscal policy in each decade in the time period from 1970-2000. Compared

to other OECD countries that were included in the study, fiscal policy performed poorly

at all governmental levels during that time.

The defining characteristic of procyclical fiscal policy is that it intensifies the

fluctuations of a business cycle. Fiscal policy should instead be anticyclical, thus

smoothing business output in order to provide macroeconomic stability. Among other

benefits, such policies can limit the negative consequences of unemployment. Although

the harmful effects of procyclical fiscal policy are known in theory, governments during

economic upswings seem to find it difficult to resist spending the additional revenue

they have at their disposal. Procyclical fiscal policy also contributed to the deterioration

of public accounts in the 1990s. For example, the persistent budget deficit of that

decade started during an economic upturn in 1990, when the influx of revenue was

converted into new spending items and projects.78 During economic recessions,

procyclical fiscal policy will deepen the recession, because spending cuts cannot be

avoided. This description fits the case of Switzerland in the 1990s, when the

government was confronted with a prolonged economic recession.

75 Beljean, Geier (2013): 131-133 76 Schaltegger (2010) 77 Joumard, Giornio (2002) 78 Beljean, Geier (2013): 115

Page 39: Lueber Swiss Debt Brake,, pol econ of fiscal deficits

39

Figure 10: Correlation between the fiscal stance and the output gap

Journard, Giornio (2002): 12

In a 2001 study, Martin analyzed the use of fiscal stimulus in Switzerland from 1970

through 2007 and found evidence for the claim that Swiss public finances served to

reinforce economic cycles during this time period. According to the author, a common

theme of Swiss fiscal policy is that expenditures react to increases in revenue.79 In

addition, the anticyclical effect of automatic stabilizers was undermined because of

long delays in collecting income.80

“Automatic stabilizers” is the label used for government spending that rises and falls

in response to economic conditions. In times of economic recessions, expenditure-side

79 Martin (2001): 45-48 80 Danninger (2002): 16

Page 40: Lueber Swiss Debt Brake,, pol econ of fiscal deficits

40

automatic stabilizers (such as unemployment insurance and other social insurances)

kick in, automatically providing fiscal stimulus, working anticyclically while doing so.

Characteristics and optimization of the Swiss budget process

The following section focuses on the characteristics of the budgetary process in

Switzerland. The Swiss case shows that fiscal-policy rules and measures failed before

the enactment of the debt brake because they left the budgetary process untouched.

The political culture and institutions of Switzerland fit the model of consociational

democracies (i.e., those with profound regional differences, such as Belgium or

Malaysia). In such democracies, the theory holds that political stability is maintained

despite the existence of established clefts between political forces that represent

different factions of society.81 The concept of consociational democracy is related to the

question of why effective governance might be achieved in these kinds of political

scenarios that would otherwise appear ripe for factionalism or even civil war. Part of

the answer is that political elites in Switzerland were able to accommodate their

differences; as a result, these elites created and designed political institutions in such

a way that these institutions could cope with and incorporate the fragmented nature of

the political system.

Four different official languages and strong regional identification are only two

examples of fragmentation in Switzerland. In a small country with 26 cantons, local

political autonomy is strong.82 Accordingly, these characteristics of the political system

translate into the budgeting process, which in Switzerland might be even more

influenced by the system of consensus than in other OECD countries that have a strong

tradition of consensus, because shared decision making is firmly grounded in the Swiss

constitutional structure. For example, the structure provides for cantonal vetoes and

popular votes as a powerful means to counter the tendencies of majority rule.

Before reforms were enforced under the provisions of the Swiss debt brake,

hierarchical elements were strikingly absent during the different stages of the

budgeting process. Budgetary matters (like government policies in general) were

81Bohn (1980) 82 Mueller (2011)

Page 41: Lueber Swiss Debt Brake,, pol econ of fiscal deficits

41

driven by the political desire to achieve consensus. The political system works without

a prime minister and without a coalition agreement. The executive branch, the Swiss

Federal Council, is composed of seven members who all enjoy equal powers, at least in

principle.

During the first stage of budget creation (the executive planning stage) before the

arrival of the debt brake, political bargaining started with the announcement of the

seven Swiss ministries’ spending desires. (The seven include foreign affairs, interior

affairs, justice and police, defense, finance, economic affairs and education and

research, and environment, including transportation, energy and communication).

Because the Finance Ministry did not hold any special authority in the process, it could

not interfere. The proposed spending decisions were then added together to form an

aggregate budget. In the next step, the budget was handed over to parliament, where

amendments could be introduced with simple majorities in both chambers.83

Characteristics of the Swiss debt brake as a type of fiscal rule

The operation of the mechanism

The expenditure-limiting mechanism, or the debt brake, has two central objectives: the

first is the medium-term control of public debt by avoiding budget deficits, while the

second aims to achieve the necessary flexibility to absorb any fluctuations of the

business cycle. Each year fiscal planning under the provisions of the debt brake

prescribes the application of the rule. The debt brake could essentially be classified as

an expenditure rule, because its target variable is the level of expenditures for each

fiscal year. The government (i.e., the department of finance) pre-determines an

expenditure ceiling and stipulates the maximum amount of spending that will be

possible for all seven ministries. The second objective (flexibility) is still met by

allowing for budget deficits if the economy is in a downswing; the underlying restrictive

bias of the mechanism is not violated in such cases, however, because the debt brake

guarantees that income and expenditure will be kept in balance over the course of the

business cycle. When the economy is performing well, surpluses are required.

83 Bodmer (2006): 311-312

Page 42: Lueber Swiss Debt Brake,, pol econ of fiscal deficits

42

The restrictive quality of the debt brake becomes clearer with a formal presentation of

the basic debt brake formula:

�̅� = 𝑘t𝑅t 𝑤𝑖𝑡ℎ 𝑘t = 𝑦t∗

𝑦t

The formula describes that for any calculation period (t) the level of expenditure (G)

must not exceed the amount of revenues (R) after multiplication by the business cycle

adjustment factor (k). Thus, business activity is accounted for in the formula. For the

calculation of the business cycle adjustment factor (k), predictions of trend output (yt)

and actual output (y) are used. If the numbers of trend output are higher than actual

output, the economy is in recession. This is expressed by the factor k being larger than

1. While deficits (cyclical deficit) are allowed in this case, (cyclical) budgetary surpluses

are “required” if the factor k is smaller than 1.84

Without including a variable for economic fluctuations, expenditure (G) would follow

the changing path of revenue. This would be the scenario demanded by overall balance

or debt rules. Policy planners in Switzerland wanted to overcome the shortcomings of

such rules, which lie in the compulsory reaction to output shocks. The Swiss debt brake,

in contrast, allows a different path for expenditure. This is illustrated by graph 11,

which shows how spending is decoupled from the variations in government income.

The intention for spending levels is instead oriented toward trend-line GDP. The debt

brake should ideally keep expenditure fluctuations within a tighter boundary, as shown

by the linear development of expenditure in the graph. In addition, the shaded areas

in the graph demonstrate when surpluses are required and deficits are permitted.

84 Beljean, Geier (2013): 118

Page 43: Lueber Swiss Debt Brake,, pol econ of fiscal deficits

43

Figure 11: Ideal development of public expenditure under the provisions of the debt brake.

Eidgenössisches Finanzdepartment (2016); text translated.

That being said, expenditure rules such as the debt brake have an important

implication. The reduced availability of discretionary fiscal policy as a fiscal tool and

its reliance on the use of automatic stabilizers could be interpreted as a disadvantage.

Discretionary fiscal policy describes the types of expenditure that are available to

governments as an instrument for manipulating economic activity. Under the

provisions of the debt brake, however, the use of fiscal stimulus is compromised, if not

given up almost completely. Because automatic stabilizers instead retain a primary

role, governments must emphasize the smooth functioning of automatic stabilizers.

In this sense, fiscal policy acquires a certain passiveness and a willingness on the part

of politicians (or spending agencies) to place trust in the role of automatic stabilizers

as the primary means of expenditure adjustment.85 In choosing the means of

implementation as described above, Swiss politicians and voters have expressed their

preference for automatic stabilizers over discretionary fiscal policy. One specific

motivation for this choice is the presumed superiority of automatic stabilizers in

ensuring the stabilization of the economy and a sustainable development of the

85 Compare Beljean, Zurbrügg (2009): 16

Page 44: Lueber Swiss Debt Brake,, pol econ of fiscal deficits

44

federation’s public finances.86 The technical design of the debt brake thus incorporates

the intention to allow automatic stabilizers to work in full. The mechanism facilitates

the functioning of automatic stabilizers, since it provides for a flexible response to the

swings of business activity. Even when revenue diminishes, significant expenditure-

side automatic stabilizers (such as unemployment insurance) are allowed to work in

full because expenditure moves in relation to structural (i.e., cyclically adjusted)

revenue.

Finally, it must be added that the legal text of the debt brake provides a framework for

fiscal responses in exceptional circumstances. These stipulations make the fiscal rule

more stringent because they hinder opportunistic politicians from providing excuses

to escape from the fiscal constraints. The particular clause specifies that unforeseen

events such as deep recessions allow for deviation from the expenditure ceiling;

spending can be raised if it is accepted by qualified majorities in both houses. Such

spending constitutes extraordinary expenditure and is registered in a special

amortization account. As a general rule, debits on this account have to be cleared

within six years.

Enforcement: The functioning and importance of the compensation

account

With the introduction of the debt brake, a compensation account was created that

carries an important enforcement mechanism. Its intention is to control the actual

amounts of federal money spent and to implement sanctions if the final budget

outcome exceeds the expenditure limit set when the budget was approved. After the

end of the fiscal year, the balance of the compensation account allows for inferring

compliance with the debt brake. More precisely, when actual data on revenue and GDP

growth is available, the balance of the account is determined by the accumulated

difference between the amounts of actual revenue and actual expenditures. If the

account shows a debit, the law requires corrective action in terms of lowering the

expenditure ceiling. In this way the expenditure ceiling al1so becomes binding for the

budget execution stage. In cases where a surplus on the account exists (due to

86 Bundesrat (2013): 25-28. This chapter also explains reasons why the government turned away from procyclical fiscal policy. (“Abkehr von einer prozyklischen Fiskalpolitik”).

Page 45: Lueber Swiss Debt Brake,, pol econ of fiscal deficits

45

underspending or overcollecting), the credit on the account cannot be used for

additional spending but is instead intended for debt reduction. The compensation

account also serves another important purpose: it counteracts the willful and

deliberate manipulation of budget forecasts.87 Revenue forecasts, for example, can be

overestimated in order to increase the expenditure ceiling. The compensation account,

however, takes away this incentive because estimation errors will become evident.

Effect and relative success of the fiscal rule since its introduction

After more than ten years in existence, it is possible to draw several conclusions about

the fiscal performance of the debt brake and to adequately assess and evaluate the

brake. In general, the debt brake has proven to be effective. The relative success of the

expenditure-limiting mechanism will be measured in the following section against its

two main objectives described earlier. In terms of its first objective, the accumulation

of debt in relative terms has not only been stopped but has even been reduced. Figure

12, which illustrates gross federal debt levels from 1980 to 2011, demonstrates this

remarkable performance. After a difficult start (from 2003 to 2005), the debt brake

contributed to setting debt levels on a clear downward trajectory: as a percentage of

GDP, federal debt levels were reduced from 28.2 percent at the end of 2002 to 19.5

percent in 2012.88 While successful compliance with the rule was initially

overshadowed by economic stagnation and falling revenue, the existence of the rule

proved to be beneficial because it prompted a quick response by policymakers, who

worked out a consolidation program in order to meet the brake’s legal requirements

and to overcome the various fiscal challenges they faced. In this sense, the debt brake

manifested its usefulness in spurring quick fiscal responses to fiscal deficits.

87 Danninger (2002): 5-6 88 Numbers on federal debt levels in Switzerland can be found at www.de.statista.com

Page 46: Lueber Swiss Debt Brake,, pol econ of fiscal deficits

46

Figure 12: Switzerland, gross federal debt (1980–2011). LHS: left-hand side; RHS: right-hand side.

Gross federal debt levels started to decline in 2005, two years after the introduction of the debt brake

due to an economic recession.

Beljean and Geier (2013): 116

The debt brake also proved to be an effective impediment to the procyclical tendencies

of Swiss fiscal policy, meaning that the second objective of the brake (i.e., achieving the

necessary flexibility to absorb fluctuations of the business cycle) was largely met.

Switzerland achieved significant budget surpluses during the economic boom period

from 2005-2008 (see graph 5) due to its debt brake; in 2008 the nation achieved a

budget surplus of 2.3 percent of GDP.89 The crucial point here is that the debt brake

was able to avoid the use of revenue increases for permanent expenditure increases;

this puts fiscal development in stark contrast with the financial situation during the

89 IHS Global Insight (2011): 17

Page 47: Lueber Swiss Debt Brake,, pol econ of fiscal deficits

47

1990s. As graph 5 shows, the cyclically adjusted budget balance exhibited a positive

balance from 2006 to 2012 (the last date included).

In addition, the intention of the debt brake was to attribute a larger role to the fiscal

impulse of automatic stabilizers (as compared to the discretionary use of fiscal

stimulus). The Swiss scholars Christoph A. Schaltegger and Martin Weder analyzed the

composition of fiscal impulse in 2010; their results are presented in graph 13, which

illustrates the composition of the fiscal impulse from the years 1951–2007.90 The

graph distinguishes between those elements of the fiscal impulse that stemmed from

discretionary measures and those that stemmed from automatic stabilizers. The

authors found that the introduction of the debt brake resulted in automatic stabilizers

delivering a stronger fiscal impulse; a comparison between the years 1991–2000 and

2001–2007 also reveals a diminished use of discretionary fiscal stimulus.91 Although

more recent statistical investigation would be necessary to allow for a better correlation

with the introduction of the debt brake in 2003, it would appear that Swiss

policymakers adhered to the envisioned role of a less-active fiscal-policy intervention.

Figure 13: Fiscal impulse of the federation and social insurances (1951–2007). Vertical axis left side:

fiscal impulse as a percentage of GDP; right side: real GDP growth (in percentage points).

Schaltegger and Weder (2010): 52

90 Schaltegger, Weder (2010) 91 Schaltegger, Weder (2010): 153-155

Page 48: Lueber Swiss Debt Brake,, pol econ of fiscal deficits

48

Switzerland consequently entered the financial crisis in 2008 with solid public

finances, thus enabling the country to weather the global economic turbulence without

jeopardizing its fiscal situation. The health of the public finances at the time speaks to

the advantages of fiscal space; in particular, the Swiss government was able to launch

several economic stimulus packages in late 2008 and early 2009 without having to be

concerned with financial stability. The debt brake provided a stable financial

environment during the crisis because it strengthened confidence in the long-term

soundness of the Swiss federal public finances; the consistent generation of surpluses

was a strong demonstration of compliance with the rule.

On another level, the effect of the debt brake on the level of investments requires closer

scrutiny; one line of criticism against expenditure rules holds that expenditures will be

stabilized at the cost of investment spending. Two theoretical arguments could be

raised to support this claim. First, in contrast to entitlement spending (such as social

security), investment spending is part of discretionary fiscal policy and is therefore

more prone to expenditure cuts. Second, because the benefits of investment projects

usually materialize in the future, opportunistic politicians might withdraw from

investment spending since such spending has no immediate costs.92 More specifically,

Dur et al. have argued (in their 1997 study) that public debt rules “shift strategic

manipulation to public investment.”93

The experience of the debt brake, however, shows that Switzerland achieved its fiscal

targets without stifling investment spending. Graph 14 shows that since the

introduction of the Swiss debt brake in 2003, investment spending as a percentage of

GDP was approximately 1 percent on average during this whole period. The graph also

reveals that public spending developed in a much more stable manner and with fewer

fluctuations than was the case from 1980 to 2003. In addition, the numbers on

investment spending as a percentage of total expenditure weaken the argument that

meeting the constraints of the expenditure ceiling would only be possible by crowding

out expenditures for investment purposes.

92 Beljean, Geier (2013): 126. Krogstrup, Wyplosz (2009) 93 Dur et al. (1997): 12

Page 49: Lueber Swiss Debt Brake,, pol econ of fiscal deficits

49

Figure 14: Investment spending (1980–2011). The cyclical nature of investment spending stopped and

steadied under the debt brake.

Beljean and Geier (2013): 128

Reforms of the budget process resulting from the debt brake

The debt brake has also been responsible for profound changes in the Swiss budgeting

process. The Swiss government introduced elements of centralization to the system,

which essentially created a top-down budgeting process. The changes overall have

followed the predicaments of the “delegation” form of fiscal governance described

earlier; this is remarkable, because the “contracts” form of fiscal governance would

seem to be a more appropriate solution for the Swiss political system. Policymakers did

not likely make a conscious choice for a particular form of fiscal governance, however,

since the changes have mainly stemmed from the strict requirements of the maximum

expenditure amounts. The expenditure target puts the finance minister in a top

position in which he or she is able to “enforce fundamental budgetary targets.”94

Because the debt brake requires the determination of binding fiscal targets at the

beginning of the process, the various spending ministries and offices have a reduced

ability to bargain over the allocated level of expenditures. The rule requires the various

94 Beljean, Geier (2013): 123

Page 50: Lueber Swiss Debt Brake,, pol econ of fiscal deficits

50

parties involved to pay strict attention to spending amounts, because ultimately the

sum of expenditures may not pass the expenditure ceiling; any room for maneuvering

is thus constrained, which causes the parties involved to become more disciplined.

It would appear that the transformation to a top-down budgeting process has

eliminated the previous incentives for bargaining between the seven spending

ministries; in this sense, the debt brake represents a radical transformation from the

previous bargaining that occurred during the budgeting process. The strict

requirements of the debt brake have given more power to the finance ministry for

disciplining the other six ministries.

To conclude this section, the implicit transformation to a top-down budgeting process

could thus be considered a critical reform that has made for a strong commitment to

compliance with the expenditure ceiling.

Page 51: Lueber Swiss Debt Brake,, pol econ of fiscal deficits

51

5. The effect of political context on the performance of the

Swiss debt brake

The unique characteristics of the Swiss institutional system and their

influence on public spending

The argument was presented earlier that political context is important to consider

when examining the introduction of fiscal rules; a political-economy approach was

thus used to better understand the modalities of the proper implementation of fiscal

rules. The following section will present the features of the institutional arrangement

in Switzerland that have exhibited a dominating influence on the functioning of fiscal

rules and will present several characteristics of the Swiss budgeting system that have

been highlighted in the academic literature.

As we saw, the debt brake was on balance able to live up to its purpose and intentions.

This section will seek to measure the particular influence of the political context of

Switzerland for its success. Doing so will allow for an analysis of the particular political

elements that distinguish the Swiss scenario.

Political environment

Fiscal federalism

The Swiss political environment has three main features—direct democracy,

federalism, and a tradition (and system) of achieving consensus—all of which are

aspects that will inevitably influence the working of a fiscal rule. A 2006 OECD study

that focused on improvements of the Swiss fiscal framework argued that the nation’s

institutional system (with elements of direct democracy and federalism) generally has

a constraining effect on spending.95 Fiscal federalism in Switzerland is more

pronounced than in other federal countries: the country has the second-highest level

of decentralization among OECD countries, with only around one quarter of public

expenditure accounted for by the federal government (see figure 15). Less than one

third of federal expenditure is used for the tasks of the federation; the rest is transferred

95 OECD (2006): 68

Page 52: Lueber Swiss Debt Brake,, pol econ of fiscal deficits

52

to the cantons and municipalities, social security funds, and other semi-autonomous

public institutions. The federal budget could thus be described as a “transfer” budget.

This characteristic could be seen as another central feature of the Swiss budgeting

system.

The Swiss cantons provide for many public services, with education, health, and social

expenditures amounting to almost 60 percent of the cantonal budgets.96 This

considerable degree of fiscal autonomy is a characteristic of all Swiss government

levels. One particular result of the federal system, which also has beneficial

implications for direct democracy, is that the elaborate federal system narrows the

distance between policymakers and voters.

Figure 15: Decentralization across the world (98 countries – average 1972–2000); subnational and

expenditure shares.

IMF (2006): 6

96 Funk, Gathmann (2013): 302

Page 53: Lueber Swiss Debt Brake,, pol econ of fiscal deficits

53

Direct democratic elements

The Swiss political system grants citizens direct popular rights, which allows for fiscal

referenda at both the cantonal and local levels. Switzerland has a firm tradition of

including its citizens in the political decision-making process. At the cantonal level, two

types of constitutional or statutory clauses serve as institutional mechanisms to allow

citizens to influence public spending: direct popular rights and formal fiscal restraints.

According to Funk and Gathmann, budget referenda “represent an important and

direct tool to influence fiscal policy.”97 While budget referenda in Switzerland are not

exclusively based on public expenditures, they do focus primarily on issues that are

related to public spending.98

The majority of cantons provide for mandatory budget referenda that stipulate that

new government programs exceeding a certain financial sum must be put to a

referendum; in addition, any changes to the constitution also lead to mandatory

referenda. Popular rights include the possibility of starting a referendum to introduce

amendments to the constitution. Finally, Swiss citizens have the legal means to initiate

referenda against all federal laws and executive orders; the necessary requirement is

to collect 50,000 signatures in no fewer than 100 days after the publication of the

contested legal document. One might ask if fiscal referenda could be considered

institutions that reduce government spending in Switzerland. Their long existence as

an institution of direct democracy has certainly made them an important element of

the Swiss fiscal framework.

From a theoretical perspective, direct democracy and fiscal federalism constrain public

expenditure in the following way. Part two of this thesis provided theoretical input on

the conditions in which voters’ preferences can shape fiscal outcomes. At this point we

should ask how these theoretical considerations square with the findings on the Swiss

institutional mechanisms for direct democracy. It would appear that the existing

channels of direct involvement increase voters’ sophistication. Part two discussed the

idea that when voters lack sophistication—or when they lack control and monitoring

powers—the opportunistic use of deficit spending will be more likely to occur. As we

saw in part two, fiscal illusion can be a contributing factor to budget deficits. It would

97 Funk, Gathmann (2013): 302 98 Ibid.

Page 54: Lueber Swiss Debt Brake,, pol econ of fiscal deficits

54

seem plausible that citizens’ involvement in expenditures will decrease the effect of

fiscal illusion, because citizens have a clearer picture of what is involved in the

spending. Similarly, the direct democratic elements support a sense of civic

responsibility that is particularly strong at the local and cantonal levels.99 It also seems

plausible that Switzerland’s fiscally conservative political culture developed as a result

of its citizens’ involvement in the nation’s fiscal policy. The empirical results of Funk

and Gathmann’s 2013 study, in which the authors compared data from cantons that

have mandatory budget referenda with those that lack these kinds of referenda,

support this argument.100 The common pool problem discussed earlier also seems to

become less of a problem under such circumstances. Spending policies such as pork-

barrel projects101 will become less feasible, since citizens will be more informed of the

details of spending items.

Because direct democracy is one of the best-known features of the Swiss political

system, several studies have focused on this form of democracy’s relation to (and effect

on) the constraining of fiscal policy. A consensus appears to have emerged within the

scientific debate that direct democratic elements increase the effectiveness of fiscal

rules. For example, Kirchgässner and Feld argue that direct democracy is the most

important factor in constraining Swiss fiscal policy; they consider direct democracy to

be more important than any institutional solutions to addressing the common pool

problem, such as centralization of the budget process.102 The authors also recommend

the adoption of direct democratic elements in other European countries as a means of

strengthening the effectiveness of fiscal rules.103 Schaltegger similarly argues that the

functioning of fiscal rules is critically dependent on direct popular rights, and

especially on fiscal referenda.104 These findings appear to demonstrate that the

prevailing form of fiscal governance in Switzerland draws from direct democratic

elements that constrain fiscal policy. It should be noted that Beljean and Geier argue

that the functioning of the debt brake in Switzerland depends on a political bottom-up

channel: it is the popular Swiss fiscal-prudence stance that has continuously ensured

99 OECD (2006): 68 100 Funk, Gathmann (2013): 311 101 The term pork barrel or pork barrel politics captures the notion that politicians use spending for a particular part of the population, or particular constituents, in return for achieving political support or popularity. 102 Feld, Kirchgässner (2001) 103 Schaltegger (2002) 104 Ibid.: 364-365

Page 55: Lueber Swiss Debt Brake,, pol econ of fiscal deficits

55

the credibility of the debt brake.105 In other words, the form of fiscal governance is

supported by (and depends on) direct democratic elements. These considerations

suggest that either the “contracts” or “delegation” approach in their forms would be

inadequate for explaining the functioning of the Swiss debt brake.

The present study, however, views direct democracy as only one factor among a

broader set of political factors and institutions that originally provided the fertile

ground for the success of the Swiss debt brake. As a result, the introduction of direct

democratic rights (such as fiscal referenda) in other European countries or other

advanced economies would not on their own improve these countries’ fiscal

performance if their whole fiscal frameworks were weak or otherwise failed to provide

good foundations (such as fiscal transparency and fiscal planning). Direct democracy

in Switzerland should receive less credit in regulating Swiss fiscal policy than has

generally been the case in most studies to date on this causal relationship.

Feld and Matsusaka’s 2003 statistical investigation found that mandatory budget

referenda in Switzerland reduced government spending by 19 percent for the median

canton.106 Their statistical investigation was undertaken for the period 1980–1998 and

distinguished between cantons with mandatory and optional referenda; in 1996,

budget referenda were mandatory in 17 of Switzerland’s 26 cantons.

Funk and Gathmann’s 2013 empirical study similarly investigated the effect of direct

democracy on fiscal outcomes in Switzerland; they concluded that the effect of direct

democratic institutions on fiscal policy has been overstated in previous studies. Still,

their study did support these earlier studies’ findings that direct democracy constrains

government spending.107 Policymakers have also put forth proposals to strengthen the

fiscal framework in Switzerland by installing fiscal referenda at the federal level (rather

than only the cantonal or municipal levels).108 These policy recommendations provide

further support for the effective link between fiscal referenda and public-spending

constraint. But, as was argued earlier, these earlier studies have most likely assumed

the existence of other conducive fiscal-framework elements in Switzerland or they have

implicitly included these elements in the setups of their statistical investigations. The

105 Beljean, Geier (2013): 132 106 Feld, Matsusaka (2003) 107 Funk, Gathmann (2013) 108 OECD (2006): 71; Frey (2007): 27

Page 56: Lueber Swiss Debt Brake,, pol econ of fiscal deficits

56

present thesis finds that without elements such as a political culture of fiscal

conservatism in place, direct democracy would have had less of a positive impact on

constraining fiscal policy.

This analysis has shown that the Swiss political environment is characterized by

effective control mechanisms for public spending at both the cantonal and municipal

levels; one could argue that these fiscal constraints have become more relevant in light

of the nation’s strong fiscal autonomy. This institutional characteristic has likely

influenced the efforts and moves toward constraining public finances at the federal

level. One reason for this is that the absence of fiscal constraints at the federal level has

become more difficult to justify.

The institutional elements of the combination of fiscal federalism and direct

democracy have provided an institutional context that created a supportive

environment for the functioning of the Swiss debt brake at the federal level. The

institutional channels that are in place at the sub-federal levels form a parallel and

supporting movement to the efforts to constrain federal expenditures. A 2002 study by

the OECD found that since 1993, a restrictive fiscal policy was followed in Switzerland

at the federal, cantonal, and municipal levels of government.109 As such, this

environment formed part of the institutional context in which the debt brake was able

to thrive.

In conclusion, the preceding analysis strongly suggests that in Switzerland, fiscal

federalism by itself does not constrain public spending. Rather, the analysis suggests

that only in combination with direct democratic institutions (such as the use of fiscal

referenda) does the federal structure possess the capability to constrain public

spending.

Primacy of automatic stabilizers

The third key characteristic of the Swiss budgetary system is the classification of

Switzerland as a consociational democracy, in which negotiation and compromise play

an essential role in all political processes. It was mentioned earlier that the

109 OECD (2002): 11

Page 57: Lueber Swiss Debt Brake,, pol econ of fiscal deficits

57

introduction of the debt brake introduced elements of centralization to the Swiss

budgetary process; in this way, the budgeting process was transformed (to a certain

extent) along the lines of the delegation form of fiscal governance. The results would

have a profound impact on delegating authority to the finance minister, which in turn

led to stronger fiscal discipline by all of the other spending ministries.

One interesting question to ask is how the tradition of achieving consensus helped to

institutionalize the political commitment to the expenditure ceiling that had been set

by the debt brake. One could argue that this system made it easier to stick to the debt

brake, since the parties involved were accustomed to working in consensus. One reason

for this is that all of the political players involved place trust in the political agreements,

since this is the modus operandi they are accustomed to. Because consensus-based

decision making is such a key principle, it will thus become difficult for any one

individual in the federal parliament to violate the consensus view. This, in turn, will

reduce the potential conflicts of interest that inevitably arise from different preferences

between politicians. This situation was described earlier in the theoretical

considerations section of chapter two, which stated that budget deficits generally result

from politicians’ tactical and strategic motives. The logic of such motives, however, are

lost within the confines of the consensus-oriented budgeting process in Switzerland.

It would appear that the evolution of the concept and contours of fiscal policy among

policymakers played a central role in this success: in particular the reorientation of the

priorities of fiscal policy toward other goals. In other words, discretionary fiscal policy

as a policy instrument was reconsidered, ultimately no longer being really at disposal

as a policy instrument with the introduction of the debt brake (and the subsequent

commitment to that brake). As a result, a different understanding of the role of fiscal

policy emerged that made it more acceptable to assume a passive role in fiscal policy,

which in turn increased the commitment to binding fiscal-policy choices to the

demands of an expenditure rule.

A consensus emerged among Swiss policymakers and academics during the 1990s on

the limited purpose and usefulness of discretionary fiscal measures.110 As a result, the

use of discretionary fiscal policy would enjoy less and less political support from then

on. The question of why the use of discretionary fiscal policy lacked support is complex

110 Frick et al. (2012): 40

Page 58: Lueber Swiss Debt Brake,, pol econ of fiscal deficits

58

and deserves more attention; several factors seem to have played a role. First, previous

fiscal-policy experiences served to shape the new understanding: by the 1990s, the

policymakers had realized the limited use of discretionary fiscal policy as a

countercyclical tool. Second, as was suggested in chapter 4, the frustration with the

procyclical nature of fiscal policy due to discretionary fiscal policy was pronounced

among policymakers, which certainly made it easier for them to reduce the role of

discretionary fiscal policy. Third, the government deemed monetary policy to be more

appropriate for assuring countercyclical policy (see chapter 4). Fourth, fiscal policy

should give preference to automatic stabilizers, since they are better able to provide

stabilization than other tools.111 One could argue that the primacy of automatic

stabilizers relates to a redefinition of fiscal policy objectives in the 1990s that made the

maintenance of fiscal discipline a key objective.

Fifth, some have described the influence of discretionary fiscal measures to stimulate

the economy as being weak. According to Schaltegger, for example, calculations of the

long-term-multiplier effect based on economic models was always below 1.112 Because

Switzerland has a small and open economy, the active use of fiscal policy measures has

had limited benefits in terms of fiscal response to economic crises. This might have

been an additional reason for Switzerland to diminish the role of discretionary fiscal

policy. For example, Frick et al. have argued that the Swiss economy saw strong profits

from fiscal stimuli that had been implemented in other countries during the world

financial crisis that started in 2008.113

Previous government efforts to achieve a balanced budget are indicative of the shared

political commitment to sustainable public finances. The primary legal text on

measures related to a balanced budget, Switzerland’s Budget Objective 2001 (from

1997), also hints at the consensus among policymakers at the time for a different role

for fiscal policy to take in the future.114 The plan delineated the way in which fiscal

policy would be tied to rules in order to be bound to the parameters of the new

understanding of fiscal policy; the plan has also demonstrated how the government

chose a gradual path for increasing the soundness of the Swiss fiscal framework. Part

of the purpose of the fiscal measures that were taken in the Budget Objective 2001

111 Schaltegger (2010): 170-171 112 Schaltegger (2010): 170 113 Frick et al. (2012) 114 Bundesrat (1997)

Page 59: Lueber Swiss Debt Brake,, pol econ of fiscal deficits

59

(“Haushaltsziel 2001”) were to serve as preparation for the more restrictive

introduction of the debt brake. One component of the Budget Objective 2001 was the

adoption of a stabilization plan in 1998. Similarly to the objective of the debt brake, the

main aim of this plan was to control expenditures. With the adoption of this fiscal plan,

and the achievement of a balanced budget in 2000, the main players had already shown

the political will to implement consolidation programs.

It must be emphasized again that the debt brake is the culmination of consistent and

intensive efforts by the Swiss government. Already in the 1990s, the Swiss government

had demonstrated the political willingness to pursue consolidation programs. The

provisions of the Budget Objective 2001 already showed how the Swiss authorities

intended to implement strong fiscal policy measures.

As part 2 has shown, however, politicians’ behavior is not determined by economic

considerations alone but rather by opportunistic incentives such as using public money

in order to increase their chances of remaining in office. A stronger explanation would

therefore point to the idea that because of the specific Swiss political system, the

opportunistic use of deficit spending was no longer a useful instrument. One could

argue that consensus as the usual and accepted principle in the decision-making

process made it more difficult for a single party to break the rule. Another important

factor is that voters’ fiscal preferences were locked in due to their strong vote in favor

of fiscal discipline. As a result, the parties involved likely realized that deficit spending

did not represent a good way to win elections. And once the consensus became

institutionalized (and the centralization of the budget process had added an element of

discipline to the ministries), it became very costly for any single minister to deviate

from the agreed-on rule. One reason for this is that the expenditure ceiling in

Switzerland is transparent, and thus any ministers who “spoiled the party” would risk

great damage to their political factions in the face of strong voter disapproval.

One of the most important points to bear in mind is that voters’ fiscal preferences

became part of the process. In other words, the new budgeting system made it possible

for their preferences to influence policymakers’ fiscal decisions. It would appear that

political commitment was already high before the debt brake was introduced. Since the

introduction of the debt brake, compliance with the rule has profited from broad

Page 60: Lueber Swiss Debt Brake,, pol econ of fiscal deficits

60

acceptance by the “major players in the Swiss budget process.”115 Getting all political

parties onboard and complying with the predetermined expenditure levels was

certainly facilitated by the step-by-step approach to a rigorous and strict expenditure

rule.

A clear parliamentary majority has emerged in favor of fiscal discipline since the 1990s;

the rise of the aforementioned Swiss People’s Party (SVP) certainly played a part in

this. One of its strongest political demands was to have a balanced budget at the federal

level: a demand that echoes across Swiss culture and society. SVP and two other Swiss

parties located near the center of the political spectrum are grouped together as

bürgerliche or “civic parties”;116 the other two are the Christian Democratic People’s

Party (CVP) and the Free Democratic Party (FDP). The legislative push for balanced

budgets and a reduction of the absolute number of federal debt levels (which then

culminated in the debt brake) are arguably the outcomes of the shared interests of

these three civic parties. Their influence in parliament was abetted by the weakness of

the other two left-leaning Swiss parties, the Social Democratic Party (SP) and the Green

Party (GPS). As graph 16 demonstrates, since the 1990s, the civic parties have

possessed a two-thirds majority.117

115 OECD (2005): 57 116 Bürgerliche Partei or “civic party” is a political term probably exclusively used in German speaking or Scandinavian countries. The term means to ascribe parties influenced by their bourgeois or middle-class origin. 117 I want to thank Leo Müller (CVP), President of the Finanzkommission in the Swiss Parliament, for providing me with information on the Swiss budget process and budget politics.

Page 61: Lueber Swiss Debt Brake,, pol econ of fiscal deficits

61

Figure 16: Swiss parties and their number of votes won (as a percentage of the total amount of seats)

in the elections for the Swiss federal parliament (Nationalrat).

Longchamp (2011)

The fiscal rule also aligned with voters’ fiscal preferences and came into being through

strong voter acceptance. This point arguably contributed to maintaining and enforcing

policymakers’ political commitment. Compliance with the debt brake was also

increased, because the stakes of escaping the clauses of the debt brake were raised.

Breaking the constitutional rule would have had severe repercussions, since a policy

change away from the debt brake would have required the voters’ approval in a

referendum. The stakes have been raised for Swiss political parties, because it has

become hard for them to justify non-compliance in the face of a strong political culture

that demands fiscal discipline. It has also become difficult for a single ministry to

ignore the expenditure ceiling. Non-compliance is made even more difficult because

transparency makes it easy to recognize ministries that do not play by the rules, which

means that any party that does so will be punished in the next election. These points

also serve as a good illustration of how opportunistic incentives for incumbent

Page 62: Lueber Swiss Debt Brake,, pol econ of fiscal deficits

62

politicians’ use of deficit spending have been effectively undermined by the Swiss debt

brake.

Made in Switzerland: Political context and the Swiss debt brake

The government’s fiscal preferences were also well transcribed and integrated into the

design of the debt brake, the technical design of which is a very precise reflection and

implementation of the shapes that fiscal policy should take according to Swiss

policymakers; for example, their preference for how automatic stabilizers would work

was translated into the design of the fiscal rule. Another point that should be taken into

account is that the political parties together adopted the stipulations of the expenditure

rule; in other words, the fiscal rule was the creation of all of the political parties. This

aspect thus follows the “contracts” form of governance.

This point supports the argument that national rules are more effective than

supranational rules, since the former are generally the product of the particular

political motivations of a given country; in contrast to supranational rules, they are the

outcome of political will. Politicians in other countries could arguably find the rigid

nature of the debt brake to be a straitjacket. In Switzerland, however, the voters and

the broad majority of legislators deemed a forceful response to taking control of the

structural causes of persistent budget deficits to be both acceptable and necessary. One

indicator of a broader move toward fiscal constraints may be found in the Swiss

institutional environment, which features a political culture that is conducive to

conservative fiscal policy. The present study’s analysis of the institutional

environment—one that features both fiscal federalism and direct democracy as two

strong institutional characteristics—has shown that the Swiss preference for control of

public money has been firmly established. In this sense, the fiscal preferences for

conservative public finances are not only a strong element of political culture but have

also been translated into specific institutions.

This analysis has shown how political context has had a strong influence on the gradual

increase in the strictness of the Swiss fiscal framework. The intentions behind the

implementation of the fiscal rule were not predominantly economic motivations, such

as macroeconomic stability, fiscal responsibility, or overall policy credibility. In other

Page 63: Lueber Swiss Debt Brake,, pol econ of fiscal deficits

63

words, this analysis has found that political commitment to a fiscal rule will be frail if

that commitment is created mainly because of economic benefits, which suggests that

the political players must adopt the fiscal measures so that they may take root in the

country’s political system. The analysis also suggests that the debt brake was successful

in Switzerland because the Swiss political class embraced it for political reasons. As a

result, this analysis cautions against a predominant focus on economic and technical

aspects of a fiscal rule.

This argument is supported by the fact that policymakers’ efforts toward a strict fiscal

rule were not directed primarily toward the improvement of public financial

management and fiscal policy; these sorts of motivations and considerations were not

the main driving forces for abandoning the use of discretionary fiscal policy. This

explanation serves to highlight the argument that fiscal rules should not be created out

of economic motives alone or because of recommendations by international

organizations such as the IMF or the OECD. This would help to explain why (rule-

based) improvements of monetary policy are generally easier to implement in

countries than improvements of fiscal policy.118 The evolution of monetary policy is

likely more of a technical issue than the evolution of fiscal-policy. The standardization

of monetary policy in the EU (via the European Monetary Union) by 19 eurozone

countries underlines the fact that finding common rules without considering country

differences is simpler to do with monetary policy than it is with fiscal policy.

118 Wyplosz (2005): 64-65

Page 64: Lueber Swiss Debt Brake,, pol econ of fiscal deficits

64

6. Conclusion

This study has demonstrated significant results related to the various factors that have

allowed the Swiss debt brake to fulfill its mandate. Above all, the success of the debt

brake has depended on three points:

1. the gradual increase of the fiscal framework and commitment to sound public

finances, which resulted in a solid architecture of fiscal institutions;

2. the shared interest and preference for the passive role of fiscal policy and the

primacy of automatic stabilizers by the broad majority of the political

leadership; and

3. designing and implementing the fiscal rule in a manner that incorporates the

shapes fiscal policy should take according to Swiss policymakers.

First, the successful control of public expenditure cannot be attributed to the debt

brake as a single fiscal rule. Although the debt brake deserves the most credit among

all of the pieces in the set of fiscal institutions, the foundation of its success was paved

before its introduction. Careful analysis has revealed that the debt brake can be seen

as the expression and outcome of several institutions and factors that have

strengthened fiscal discipline. In this sense, this result should be viewed as a caution

of the dangers of implementing a rigid fiscal rule in countries with weak fiscal

frameworks and the lack of a conducive political context.

Second, the political leadership in Switzerland (which has always been consensus

oriented) converged on a consensus belief in the role of fiscal policy. It seems likely

that the consensus on a passive role of fiscal policy already manifested itself during the

end of the nineties when the wish for decisive action was shown by the measures

introduced by the Budget Objective 2001. Moving discretionary fiscal policy to the

margins and leaving fiscal policy intervention to automatic stabilizers did not

encounter significant opposition. The design of the debt brake accordingly transformed

the primacy of automatic stabilizers into specific obligations; the acceptance of these

obligations had thus already been established by that point. Legislation for stricter

expenditure control was also facilitated by the strong majority of the three “civic

parties” in the federal parliament, which pushed for balanced budgets.

Page 65: Lueber Swiss Debt Brake,, pol econ of fiscal deficits

65

Third, the technical design of the Swiss debt brake is a very precise reflection of the

shapes that fiscal policy should take according to Swiss policymakers. For example, the

preference for the working of automatic stabilizers was translated into the design of

the fiscal rule.

Finally, this study supports the existing arguments that hold that the choice between

the delegation and contracts approaches should depend on the political characteristics

of a country. In a similar sense, the study suggests the importance of examining

politico-institutional factors for the successful adoption of fiscal rules. The study thus

supports a political-economy approach toward the subject of sustainable public

finances; its results stress that policymakers should have a proper understanding of a

country’s particular institutional environment (including the quality and quantity of

its fiscal framework and fiscal institutions) before they contemplate making any

changes. The policy implication for countries that wish to control their public debt is

thus that policymakers should demonstrate that they have this proper understanding

before adopting a given type of fiscal rule. In some scenarios, for instance, introducing

gradual improvements of the fiscal framework will be more advisable than starting off

with a strong fiscal rule.

Page 66: Lueber Swiss Debt Brake,, pol econ of fiscal deficits

66

Bibliography

Alesina, A., R. Perotti, and J. Tavares. "The Political Economy of Fiscal Adjustments." Brookings

Paper on Economic Activity 1 (1998): 197-248.

Alesina, Alberto, and Roberto Perotti. "The Political Economy of Budget Deficits." IMF Staff Papers

42.1 (1995): 1-31.

Allen, Richard, Richard Hemming, and Barry Potter, eds. The International Handbook of Public

Financial Management. Palgrave Macmillan, 2013a.

---. "Introduction: The Meaning, Content and Objectives of Public Financial Management." The

International Handbook of Public Financial Management. Eds. Richard Allen, Richard

Hemming, and Barry Potter. Palgrave Macmillan, 2013b. 1-10.

Alt, James E., and David Dreyer Lassen. "Fiscal Transparency, Political Parties, and Debt in OECD

Countries." European Economic Review 50 (2006): 1403-39.

Anderson, Barry, and James Sheppard. "Fiscal Futures, Institutional Budget Reforms, and their

Effects: What can be Learned?" OECD Journal on Budgeting 3 (2009): 7-117.

Beljean, Tobias. "Schuldenbremse - Konjunkturverträgliche Konsolidierung des Bundeshaushalts." 11

(2011): 34-7. " Die Volkswirtschaft 11 (2011): 34-7.

Beljean, Tobias, and Alain Geier. "The Swiss Debt Brake - has it been a Success?" Swiss Society of

Economics and Statistics 149.2 (2013): 115-35.

Bodmer, Frank. "The Swiss Debt Brake: How it Works and what can Go Wrong." Schweizerische

Zeitschrift für Volkswirtschaft und Statistik 142.3 (2006): 307-30.

Bohn, David Earle. "Consociational Democracy and the Case of Switzerland." The Journal of Politics

42.1 (1980): 165-79.

Buchsteiner, Jochen. "Vergessene Verantwortung: Ed Miliband Präsentiert Das Programm Der Labour

Party." Frankfurter Allgemeine Zeitung: 5. 14.04.2015.

Page 67: Lueber Swiss Debt Brake,, pol econ of fiscal deficits

67

Bundesrat. "Botschaft zum Bundesbeschluss über Massnahmen zum Haushaltsausgleich." (1997).

---. “Die Schuldenbremse des Bundes: Erfahrungen und Perspektiven.“ (2013)

Danninger, Stephan. "A New Rule: "the Swiss Debt Brake"." IMF Working Paper 18 (2002): 1-26.

Dur, Robert A. J., Ben D. Peletier, and Otto H. Swank. "The Effect of Fiscal Rules on Public Investment

if Budget Deficits are Politically Motivated." Tinbergen Institute Discussion Papers (1997).

Eidgenössische Finanzverwaltung. "Schuldenbremse: Der Mechanismus." 03.06.2016. Web.

Eslava, Marcela. "The Political Economy of Fiscal Deficits: A Survey." Journal of Economic Surveys

25.4 (2011): 645-73.

European Central Bank. "Fiscal Sustainability and Policy Implications for the Euro Area." Working

Paper Series 994 (January 2009).

Feld, Lars P., and Gebhard Kirchgässner. "Does Direct Democracy Reduce Public Debt? Evidence from

Swiss Municipalities." Public Choice 109 (2001): 347-70.

Feld, Lars P., and John G. Matsusaka. “Budget Referendums and Government Spending: Evidence

from Swiss Cantons.” Journal of Public Economics 87 (2003): 2703-2724.

Frankel, Jeffrey A., and Jesse Schreger. "Over-Optimistic Official Forecasts in the Eurozone and Fiscal

Rules.” Review of World Economics 149. (2013): 247-272.

Frey, René L. Finanzpolitik des Bundes seit 1960. Basel, Schweiz: Center of Research in Economics,

Management and the Arts, 2007.

Frick, Andres, et al. "Are there Free Rides Out of a Recession? the Case of Switzerland." International

Review of Applied Economics 26.1 (2012): 27-45.

Funk, Patricia, and Christina Gathmann. "Voter Preferences, Direct Democracy and Government

Spending." European Journal of Political Economy 32 (2013): 300-19.

Page 68: Lueber Swiss Debt Brake,, pol econ of fiscal deficits

68

Hagemann, Robert. "How can Fiscal Councils Strengthen Fiscal Performance?" OECD Journal:

Economic Studies 11.1 (2011): 75-98.

Hallerberg, Mark, and Sami Yläoutinen. "Political Power, Fiscal Institutions and Budgetary Outcomes

in Central and Eastern Europe." Journal of Public Policy 30.1 (2010): 45-62.

Hemming, Richard. "The Macroeconomic Framework for Managing Public Finances." The

International Handbook of Public Financial Management. Eds. Richard Allen, Richard

Hemming, and Barry Potter.Palgrave Macmillan, 2013c. 17-37.

IHS Global Insight. "Switzerland Country Monitor." (2011).

International Monetary Fund. Fiscal Transparency, Accountability, and Risk. (2012)

---. "Reassessing the Role and Modalities of Fiscal Policy in Advanced Economies." IMF Policy Paper

(2013).

---. "Switzerland: Selected Issues." IMF Country Report No. 6 /203 (2006).

Joumard, Isabelle, and Claude Giornio. "Enhancing the Effectiveness of Public Spending in

Switzerland." OECD Economics Department Working Paper 332 (2002).

Kirchgässner, Gebhard. "Fiscal Institutions at the Cantonal Level in Switzerland." Swiss Society of

Economics and Statistics 149.2 (2013): 139-66.

---. "On the Political Economy of Public Deficits and Debt." German Economic Review 15.1 (2013):

116-30.

Kopits, George, and Steven A. Symansky. "Fiscal Policy Rules." IMF Occasional Paper 162 (1998).

Kraan, Dirk-Jan, and Michael Ruffner. "Budgeting in Switzerland." OECD Journal on Budgeting 5.1

(2005).

Page 69: Lueber Swiss Debt Brake,, pol econ of fiscal deficits

69

Krogstrup, Signe, and Charles Wyplosz. "Dealing with the Deficit Bias: Principles and Policies." Policy

Instruments for Sound Fiscal Policies. Eds. Joaquim Ayuso-i-Casals, et al. Palgrave Macmillan

UK, 2009. 23-50.

The Labour Party. Britain can be better: The Labour Party Manifesto 2015. One Brewer’s Green,

London. 2015.

Leachman, Lori L., et al. "The Political Economy of Budget Deficits." Economics & Politics 19.3 (2007):

369-420.

Longchamp, Claude. "Die Volatilität von Schweizer Wahlen."

http://www.zoonpoliticon.ch/blog/15352/die-volatilitat-bei-schweizer-wahlen. Web.

Marcel, Mario. "Budgeting for Fiscal Space and Government Performance Beyond the Great

Recession." OECD Journal on Budgeting 2 (2013): 9-47.

Martin, Marc-Jean. "Les Dépenses Politiques ont-elles Exercées des Dépenses Procycliques ou

Anticycliques de 1970 à 2007." Des Politiques au Chevet de la Conjoncture. Die Politiken als

Retterinnen der Konjunktur. Ed. Nils C. Soguel. Lausanne: Presses polytechniques et

universitaires romandes, 2001. 27-50.

Millar, Jonathan. "The Effects of Budget Rules on Fiscal Performance and Macroeconomic

Stabilization." Bank of Canada Working Paper 15 (1997).

Mueller, Sean. “The Politics of Local Autonomy: Measuring Cantonal (De)centralization in

Switzerland.” Space and Polity 15.3 (2011): 213-39

OECD. "Improving the Fiscal Framework." OECD Economic Surveys: Switzerland. Organisation for

Economic Cooperation and Development, 2006. 67-73.

Reinhart, Carmen M., and Kenneth S. Rogoff. "Growth in a Time of Debt." American Economic

Review: Papers & Proceedings 100.2 (2010): 573-8.

Page 70: Lueber Swiss Debt Brake,, pol econ of fiscal deficits

70

Schaltegger, Christoph A., and Martin Weder. "Fiskalpolitik als Antizyklisches Instrument? Eine

Betrachtung der Schweiz." Perspektiven der Wirtschaftspolitik 11.2 (2010): 146-77.

Schaltegger, Christoph A. "Budgetregeln und ihre Wirkung auf die öffentlichen Haushalte: Empirische

Ergebnisse aus den US-Bundesstaaten und den Schweizer Kantonen." Schmollers Jahrbuch

122.369 (2002): 413.

Schick, Allen. "Post-Crisis Fiscal Rules: Stabilising Public Finance while Responding to Economic

Aftershocks." OECD Journal on Budgeting 2 (2010).

Von Hagen, Jürgen, and Ian J. Harden. "Budget Processes and Commitment to Fiscal Discipline."

European Economic Review 39 (1995): 771-9.

Von Hagen, Jürgen. “Fiscal Rules, Fiscal Institutions and Fiscal Performance.” The Economic and

Social Review 33.3 (2002): 263-84.

---. "Political Economy of Fiscal Institutions." The Oxford Handbook of Political Economy. Ed. Barry

R. Weingast. Oxford University Press, 2006. 464-478.

Weisman, Jonathan. "Uncertainty in Washington Poses Long List of Economic Perils." New York

Times December 2 2014

Wildavsky, Aaron. Budgeting and Governing. Transaction Publishers, New Brunswick, NJ, 2001.

Wyplosz, Charles. "Fiscal Policy: Institutions Versus Rules." National Institute Economic Review 191

(January 2005): 64-78.