macroeconomic factors and the cross-section of commodity ... · macroeconomic factors and the...

47
Macroeconomic Factors and the Cross-Section of Commodity Returns Hua (Helen) Shang y February 15, 2011 Abstract This study explores an economic explanation of commodity prices by con- sidering the macro-economic exposure of commodity returns. Through esti- mating the stochastic discount factor representation of the linear asset pricing model, we nd that investors are compensated for exchange-rate risk. The result is robust to di/erent estimation methods, to di/erent data sets and to longer periods of time. I am grateful to Nikolay Gospodinov for guidance and encouragement. I am indebted to Fisher Gordon for his help. I would like to thank seminar participants at the 2010 Canadian Economics Association Conference for helpful comments. y Mailing address: Department of Economics, Concordia University, 1455 Maisonneuve Blvd. West, Montreal, Quebec, Canada H3G 1M8. Email: [email protected] 1

Upload: others

Post on 19-Feb-2020

2 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Macroeconomic Factors and the Cross-Section of Commodity ... · Macroeconomic Factors and the Cross-Section of Commodity Returns Hua (Helen) Shangy February 15, 2011 Abstract This

Macroeconomic Factors and the Cross-Section of

Commodity Returns

Hua (Helen) Shang�y

February 15, 2011

Abstract

This study explores an economic explanation of commodity prices by con-

sidering the macro-economic exposure of commodity returns. Through esti-

mating the stochastic discount factor representation of the linear asset pricing

model, we �nd that investors are compensated for exchange-rate risk. The

result is robust to di¤erent estimation methods, to di¤erent data sets and to

longer periods of time.

�I am grateful to Nikolay Gospodinov for guidance and encouragement. I am indebted to FisherGordon for his help. I would like to thank seminar participants at the 2010 Canadian EconomicsAssociation Conference for helpful comments.

yMailing address: Department of Economics, Concordia University, 1455 Maisonneuve Blvd.West, Montreal, Quebec, Canada H3G 1M8. Email: [email protected]

1

Page 2: Macroeconomic Factors and the Cross-Section of Commodity ... · Macroeconomic Factors and the Cross-Section of Commodity Returns Hua (Helen) Shangy February 15, 2011 Abstract This

1 Introduction

The surge in commodity futures prices in recent years has engendered renewed inter-

est in commodities from investors, policy makers and �nancial economists. Since the

third quarter of 2007, the nominal prices of most commodities have reached record

highs. Now, commodities are considered an alternative asset class due to their excel-

lent ability to o¤er diversi�ed bene�ts compared with other assets.1 Understanding

how commodity prices are determined or why some commodities pay high average re-

turns than others, can help investors to grasp trading opportunities and guide public

and private project decisions.

Research has revealed that historical average returns of long-only portfolios of

commodity futures are similar to the average equity returns. For example, Bodie

and Rosansky (1980) form an equally-weighted portfolio of 23 commodities from

December 1949 to December 1976. They �nd that the portfolio has an excess annual

return 9.77% which is close to that of common stock 9.42%. Erb and Harvey (2006)

obtain a comparable result using the Goldman Sacks Commodity Index (GSCI) from

December 1969 to May 2004. Evidently, the annualized compound returns of the

GSCI and S&P 500 are 12.24% and 11.20%, respectively. A similar result is formed

in this paper with the GSCI from January 1986 to July 2008.2 Commodities are also

very heterogeneous. For example, from January 1986 to July 2008, the historical

average return of crude oil is 1.2671% with a standard deviation 9.6858%, while the

average return of cotton is 0.0638% with a standard deviation 7.1053%.3

1For example, Greer (2000).2See table 1.3See table 2.

2

Page 3: Macroeconomic Factors and the Cross-Section of Commodity ... · Macroeconomic Factors and the Cross-Section of Commodity Returns Hua (Helen) Shangy February 15, 2011 Abstract This

The historical evidence indicates that investors are able to obtain excess returns

by investing in commodity futures. However, some studies [Arnott and Bernstein

(2002), Erb and Harvey (2006)] point out that the performance of returns in the

future should not be inferred from the past performance of returns. Forward-looking

returns should be based on an understanding of the fundamental determinants of

assets returns. Further, compared to stocks and bonds, which are determined by fu-

ture cash �ows of companies, commodities are a¤ected by demand and supply. This

implies that macroeconomic variables may play an important role in the price deter-

mination of commodities. Therefore this paper investigates the macroeconomic or

fundamental risks, faced by those US investors who employ a buy and hold strategy,

from investing in commodity futures in equilibrium.

The results reveal that investors are compensated on average for taking on ex-

change rate risk. If a commodity futures contract o¤ers a low return when the US

dollar appreciates (or other currencies(y) depreciate(s)), investors in this contract,

expect to obtain an excess return in equilibrium. This is reasonable since, when

the dollar increases, for some commodities world demand decreases and foreign ex-

porters will be willing to export more commodities to the US. Thus, both the spot

prices and futures prices will decrease. Such commodities therefore o¤er low returns.

US investors who hold contracts in these commodities require compensation for the

exchange rate risk.

There have been several studies investigating how commodity futures prices are

determined in equilibrium. Most of the research is based on the hypothesis that

commodity (futures) are assets. Consequently, asset pricing models constructed for

3

Page 4: Macroeconomic Factors and the Cross-Section of Commodity ... · Macroeconomic Factors and the Cross-Section of Commodity Returns Hua (Helen) Shangy February 15, 2011 Abstract This

equities should also apply to commodity futures. However, the results emerging from

application of this hypothesis are mixed until now. Dusak (1973) is the �rst to �t

commodity futures returns into a capital asset pricing model. She examines three

commodity futures contracts in the agriculture sector from 1952 to 1967. But she

does not �nd that the commodity futures are exposed to the stock market factor.

Bodie and Rosansky (1980) analyze the quarterly returns of 23 commodities from

1950 to 1976 and �nd a signi�cant negative market risk premium. Jagannathan

(1985) tests the consumption-based Intertemporal Capital Asset Pricing Model us-

ing corn, wheat and soybeans from January 1960 to December 1978. This speci-

�cation is not supported by the data. Bessembinder (1992) tests whether futures

and equities have uniformity in their risk and return relationships. Using both eq-

uity returns and 22 futures returns from January 1967 to December 1989, he �nds

that the integration of the equities and futures markets can�t be rejected. The data

include �nancial futures, agriculture futures, foreign currency futures and mineral

futures. More recently, Roache (2008) estimates an asset pricing model by using the

Fama-Macbeth procedure with time varying betas. He uses 17 nearest-to-maturity

commodity futures contracts constructed by the Commodity Research Bureau (CRB)

from January 1973 to February 2008. He �nds that investors are compensated for

bearing interest rate risk.

This paper di¤ers from previous literature in several respects: �rst, the potential

factors included in the model are chosen based on a theoretical background; second,

these factors are widely believed to possess the ability to determine commodity prices

and have been found to be priced by equity returns; third, the S&PGSCI returns used

4

Page 5: Macroeconomic Factors and the Cross-Section of Commodity ... · Macroeconomic Factors and the Cross-Section of Commodity Returns Hua (Helen) Shangy February 15, 2011 Abstract This

are known to be capable of re�ecting the returns earned by investors through holding

commodity futures well; fourth, the estimation method applied is more conservative

than other available methods; �fth, the results are robust to di¤erent estimation

methods, to di¤erent data sets and to longer time series.

There are several methodologies used to estimate and test a linear asset pric-

ing model: for example, the Fama-Macbeth procedure, the Generalized Method of

Moments Stochastic Discount Factor (GMM-SDF) method. However, when macro-

economic variables are included in the model, many complications are created in

applying these methods. These complications comprise inference problems arising

from weak identi�cation, low variability of the factors and misspeci�ed models. In

order to alleviate these problems, a conservative approach is employed by adopting

a recently proposed demeaned GMM-SDF method. This method has been argued

to be invariant to a¢ ne transformations of the factors, and to have better power in

rejecting misspeci�ed models when the factors have low correlation with returns [see,

for example, Cochrane (2005), Burnside (2007) and Kan and Robotti (2008)]. Most

importantly, in determining whether a factor is priced, account is taken of possible

model misspeci�cation. This point is often ignored in corresponding research.

The rest of the paper is organized as follows. Section 2 explains the determination

of commodity returns. Section 3 reviews the models and the demeaned GMM-SDF

methodology. Section 4 describes the properties of the data. Section 5 explains the

empirical evidence and discusses the results. Section 6 discusses the conclusions.

5

Page 6: Macroeconomic Factors and the Cross-Section of Commodity ... · Macroeconomic Factors and the Cross-Section of Commodity Returns Hua (Helen) Shangy February 15, 2011 Abstract This

2 The determination of commodity returns

Unlike the prices of equities, which depend on the future cash �ow of companies,

commodities are a¤ected by demand and supply. Gospodinov and Ng (2010) derive

the determination of the expected spread of commodity prices. The model applied

in this paper resembles theirs. Let Ft;T denote time t price of a futures contract

which matures at time T . St is the underlying commodity�s spot price at time t.

it;T is the nominal interest rate from time t to T . The theory of storage shows that

the futures price is determined by two components: 1) the gain forgone from buying

the commodity instead of investing in riskless assets, St(1 + it;T ); 2) the marginal

convenience yield (net of storage cost) by holding a unit of commodity. Convenience

yield is the bene�t from holding commodities. It varies with the supply and demand

of the commodities. For example, convenience yield of a particular commodity tends

to be small when there are many supplies of the commodity. Gorton, Hayashi and

Rouwenhorst (2008) show that convenience yield has a decreasing, nonlinear rela-

tionship with inventories. Bollinger and Kind (2010) extract convenience yield from

the Schwartz (1997) three-factor futures pricing model using the Kalman �lter. They

�nd risk premiums embeded in convenience yield. The relation can be formulated

as:

Ft;T = St(1 + it;T )� CYt;T : (1)

The theory of storage implies that the norminal interest rate and the convenience

yield have some information on the determination of the futures price.

An alternative view of the determination of the futures prices is the theory of

6

Page 7: Macroeconomic Factors and the Cross-Section of Commodity ... · Macroeconomic Factors and the Cross-Section of Commodity Returns Hua (Helen) Shangy February 15, 2011 Abstract This

normal backwardation. This theory reveals that a futures price is a biased predictor

of the expected future spot price. Keynes (1930) proposes that producers short

contracts in the futures market to hedge risks due to possible spot price decreases.

Thus, they transfer these risks to long-side investors of the contracts. Long-side

investors should be compensated with a risk premium. This indicates that the risk

premium, or the components of the risk premium (e.g. possibly some �nancial or

macroeconomic variables), a¤ect futures prices. De�ne t;T as the risk premium.

Then

Ft;T = Et(ST )�t;T : (2)

From the previously two equations, the expected spread of spot prices can be

derived, yielding

Et(ST � St) = Stit;T � CYt;T +t;T :

Dividing throughout by St and let RT�t = ST�StSt

, cyt;T =CYt;TSt

and 't;T =t;TSt

yields

Et(Rt;T ) = it;T � cyt;T + 't;T : (3)

Since it;T = irt;T +EIt, where EIt is the expected in�ation at time t, the expected

return can also be represented as

Et(Rt;T ) = irt;T + EIt � cyt;T + 't;T : (4)

7

Page 8: Macroeconomic Factors and the Cross-Section of Commodity ... · Macroeconomic Factors and the Cross-Section of Commodity Returns Hua (Helen) Shangy February 15, 2011 Abstract This

Equation (4) implies that the expected spot return from time t to T comprises

four parts: the real interest rate, expected in�ation, the convenience yield and the

risk premium. From the theory of normal backwardation, 't;T includes information

on the futures price and the spot price, implying that it is not mutually exclusive

with the �rst three terms in the right hand side of the equation (4).

3 Estimation and testing procedures

In this section, we �rst review the SDF representation of a linear factor model. Then,

we describe the demeaned GMM-SDF procedure. In the end, the statistics for testing

the slope parameters of the SDF model are presented.

3.1 The stochastic discount factor representation

The SDF representation of an asset pricing model explains directly how an asset is

priced. The price of an asset equals its expected discounted payo¤s. Since the price

of the return of an asset is one, we obtain the following pricing formula

E(mtRt) = �N : (5)

where mt is the SDF, Rt is a vector of gross returns on N test assets and �N is a

N by 1 vector of ones. The SDF form is a generalization of all asset pricing models.

It encompasses, for example, the linear asset pricing models and the consumption-

based asset pricing models. It is also applicable to all assets, including stocks, bonds,

commodities, and so on. Di¤erent asset pricing models imply di¤erent SDFs. For a

8

Page 9: Macroeconomic Factors and the Cross-Section of Commodity ... · Macroeconomic Factors and the Cross-Section of Commodity Returns Hua (Helen) Shangy February 15, 2011 Abstract This

linear asset pricing model, mt = a+ b0Ft, where a and b are coe¢ cients; Ft is a K by

1 vector, representing K �nancial or macroeconomic factors at time t, from which

the return Rt is generated.

In the empirical asset pricing literature, excess returns are more often used than

gross returns. Since the risk free rate also satis�es equation (5), it can be written as

E(mtRet ) = 0N : (6)

where Ret = Rt �Rft is the excess return and 0N is a vector of zeros.

The left hand side of the equation (6) can be called the pricing error. We denote

it as e = E(mtRet ), that is the pricing error is zero when the SDF is in the set of

correct SDFs.

The idea of the linear asset pricing model is simple. However, until now, there is

no consensus about which model is correct despite the large number of investigation

in the literature. Evidently what factors should be contained in the model is a rather

di¢ cult question.

3.2 Estimation

3.2.1 The demeaned GMM-SDF method

The GMM-SDF method is used in the literature to estimate the SDF form of linear

asset pricing models. In order to estimate equation (6), the SDF expressed as mt =

a + b0Ft is not identi�able. For example, if a = 0 and b = 0, the pricing errors are

zero. The mean of the SDF can�t be identi�ed either. For example, E(2 �mtRet ) =

9

Page 10: Macroeconomic Factors and the Cross-Section of Commodity ... · Macroeconomic Factors and the Cross-Section of Commodity Returns Hua (Helen) Shangy February 15, 2011 Abstract This

E(mtRet ) = 0. The common practice is to estimate a normalized version of the SDF,

namely,mt = 1�bn0(Ft�E(Ft)) ormt = 1�bn0Ft. The former is called the demeaned

GMM-SDF method. The latter is named the traditional GMM-SDF method.

Both the demeaned GMM-SDF method and the traditional GMM-SDF method

are documented in Cochrane (2005). The demeaned procedure can be viewed as a

regression of expected excess returns on the covariance of the returns and the factors.

In comparison, the traditional one can be considered a regression of expected returns

on the second moments of the returns and the factors. Kan & Robotti (2008) point

out that the demeaned procedure is invariant to a¢ ne transformations of the factors.

However, the traditional GMM is not. Thus, the traditional HJ-distance will possibly

provide erroreous model rankings if the mean of the SDF is not restricted to be the

same. For example, by modifying the mean of the factor, the GMM procedure could

potentially favor a very poor model4. Kan and Robotti (2008) also provide a modi�ed

HJ-distance for the demeaned method. The demeaned SDF is

mt = 1� bd0(Ft � �F ); (7)

where �F = E(F ).

The moment conditions of the GMMprocedure areE(gt) =

264 E(Ft � �F )

EfRet [1� (Ft � �F )0bd]g

375The parameters � = [�0F b

d0]0 can be estimated by minimizing a quadratic function

4Details can be found in page 818-819 in Kan and Robotti (2008).

10

Page 11: Macroeconomic Factors and the Cross-Section of Commodity ... · Macroeconomic Factors and the Cross-Section of Commodity Returns Hua (Helen) Shangy February 15, 2011 Abstract This

Qn = gT (�)0ATgT (�)

where gT (�) =

264 g1T (�)g2T (�)

375 = 1T

TPt=1

gt(�) =

26641T

TPt=1

(Ft � �F )

1T

TPt=1

fRet [1� (Ft � �F )0bd]g

3775 is

the sample counterpart of the previously metioned moment conditions, gt(�) =264 g1t(�)g2t(�)

375 =264 Ft � �FRet [1� (Ft � �F )0bd]

375. AT is the prespeci�ed weighting matrix rep-resented as AT =

264 IK 0KN

0KK bV 0RFW2

375, where bVRF = 1T

TPt=1

(Ret � b�R)(Ft � b�F )0, b�R =1T

TPt=1

Ret ; 0KN and 0KK denote K by N and K by K matrices of zeros respectively; IK

is a K by K identity matrix; W2 is the weighting matrix in the quadratic form Q2n =

g2T (bd)0W2g2T (b

d). In this paper, we let W2 = bV �1RR = [1T

TPt=1

(Ret � b�R)(Ret � b�R)0]�1,which is the variance of the returns. This permits the calculation of the modi�ed

HJ-distance measure which will be reviewed later. Therefore,

b� = argminQ(�)By solving the minimization problem, we obtain

b�F = 1

T

TPt=1

Ft

bbd = (bV 0RF bV �1RRbVRF )�1bV 0RF bV �1RRb�R (8)

11

Page 12: Macroeconomic Factors and the Cross-Section of Commodity ... · Macroeconomic Factors and the Cross-Section of Commodity Returns Hua (Helen) Shangy February 15, 2011 Abstract This

The variance of b� = [b�0F bbd0]0 can be estimated byb = 1

T(ATD

dT )�1ATcV dAT (Dd0

TA0T )�1 (9)

where DdT =

264�IK 0KKb�R bba0 �bVRF375.

In order to account for possible serial correlation in the moment conditions, we

choose the Newey and West (1987) estimator which values the variance and covari-

ance containing the most information and ensures that cV d is positive de�nite. It canbe calculated as

cV d = bvd(0) + mXj=1

(1� j

m+ 1)( bvd(j) + bvd(j)0); (10)

where bvd(j) = 1T

TXt=1

gt(b�)gt+j(b�).Since the sample size is only 271, m is set to 2.

When a model is misspeci�ed, the variance of b� can be derived by the deltamethod: bm = 1

T

1Xj=�1

1

T

TXt=1

qt(b�)q0t(b�) (11)

where qt(b�) = bH bV 0RF bV �1RR(Ret�b�R)(1�byt)+ bH[(Ft�b�F )� bV 0RF bV �1RR(R

et�b�R)]bat+ bbd

with bH = (bV 0RF bV �1RRbVRF )�1, byt = 1� bd0(Ft � b�F ), bat = be0mbV �1RR(R

et � b�R) andbem = b�R � bVRF bbd.

Kan & Robotti (2008) argue that the traditional HJ-distance is not appropriate

here since it measures the distance between the proposed SDF to the set of all correct

12

Page 13: Macroeconomic Factors and the Cross-Section of Commodity ... · Macroeconomic Factors and the Cross-Section of Commodity Returns Hua (Helen) Shangy February 15, 2011 Abstract This

SDFs. In this case, the mean of the SDF has been restricted to be 1. A more suitable

HJ-distance will be the distance of the proposed SDF to the set of correct SDFs with

a unit mean.

The modi�ed sample HJ-distance can be calculated as the following:

HJ(b�) =qg02T (bbd)bVRRg2T (bbd); (12)

where g2T (bbd) = 1T

TPt=1

(Ret (1� (Ft � b�F )0 bbd)):The modi�ed HJ-distance has an empirical distribution of

T [HJ(b�)]2 ~ N�KXi=1

�di vi as T !1 (13)

where��diN�Ki=1

are (N�K) nonzero eigenvalues of Ld = X(VRR)1=2V22(VRR)1=2X

with X = [IN � (VRR)1=2VRF (V 0RFVRRVRF )�1V 0RF (VRR)1=2]. (VRR)1=2 is the upper-

triangular matrices from the Cholesky decomposition of VRR = E((Ret��R)(Ret��R))

and �R = E(Ret ). fvig

N�Ki=1 are N-K independent �2(1) distributed random variables.

Let bu = N�KXi=1

b�di vi, where b�i is the sample counterpart of �di . The empirical p-value of the modi�ed HJ-distance can be calculated by simulating di¤erent samples

of fbujgJj=1 and comparing them with the estimated T [HJ(b�)]2. The empirical p-valueis de�ned as

pHJ =1

J

JXj=1

I(buj � T [HJ(b�)]2) (14)

J being the number of simulations. I(�) is an indicator function. I(�) = 1 if

13

Page 14: Macroeconomic Factors and the Cross-Section of Commodity ... · Macroeconomic Factors and the Cross-Section of Commodity Returns Hua (Helen) Shangy February 15, 2011 Abstract This

buj � T [HJ(b�)]2, otherwise, zero.5

4 The data

4.1 Commodity futures returns

The futures data used are components of S&P GSCI Excess Returns obtained from

Morningstar, Inc. All the commodities included in the GSCI are chosen due to its

liquidity. The returns are constructed from the prices of nearest-to-maturity and

second nearest-to-marturity futures contracts. The contracts are rolled to the next

nearest-to-maturity contracts on the �fth to ninth business days in the month before

the maturity month.6 Ideally, all the 24 components should be included. However,

in order to have a long time series, 14 commodities which can be dated back to

January 1986 are selected. Platinum is also included. The return series of platinum

is constructed the same way as the components of the GSCI Excess Return. So

there are 15 commodities starting from January 1986 to July 2008, altogether 271

data points. The 15 commodities belong to �ve sectors: 7 in agriculture (cocoa,

co¤ee, corn, cotton, soybean, sugar, wheat), 2 in livestock (lean hogs, live cattle), 2

in industrial metals (copper, platinum), 2 in precious metals (gold, silver) and 2 in

the energy sector (crude oil and heating oil). The monthly returns are compounded

5The calculation of the empirical p-value of the modi�ed HJ-distance is similar to that of thetraditional HJ-distance described in Jagannathan and Wang (1996).

6The description of the data can be found in the following link:http://www.standardandpoors.com/servlet/BlobServer?blobheadername3=MDT-

Type&blobcol=urldata&blobtable=MungoBlobs&blobheadervalue2=inline%3B+�lename%3DMethodology_SP_GSCI_Web.pdf&blobheadername2=Content-Disposition&blobheadervalue1=application%2Fpdf&blobkey=id&blobheadername1=content-type&blobwhere=1243629616412&blobheadervalue3=UTF-8

14

Page 15: Macroeconomic Factors and the Cross-Section of Commodity ... · Macroeconomic Factors and the Cross-Section of Commodity Returns Hua (Helen) Shangy February 15, 2011 Abstract This

on a daily basis.

4.2 The factors

From equation (4), expected spot returns are determined by the real interest rate,

the factors a¤ecting convenience yield and components of risk premiums. The theory

of storage and the theory of normal backwardation demonstrate that the real interest

rate and components of the risk premiums comprise information on the determina-

tion of futures prices. Erb and Harvey (2006) point out that futures returns (or the

change of the futures prices) are a combination of the spot returns and roll returns.

Therefore, there are reasons to believe that the real interest rate includes information

on the generation of futures returns. Further, the commodities are dollar denomi-

nated. The variation of the exchange rate is widely believed to a¤ect the supply and

demand of commodities. Therefore, exchange rate growth should be an important

factor in the determination of futures returns. In addition, we include stock market

returns. There is no consensus on the variables in�uencing the convenience yield and

the components of the risk premium. The stock market returns can be used as a

proxy for all the other information aside from the real interest rate and exchange rate

growth. The factors are described and our choices are elaborated in the following

paragraphs.

The market factor is obtained from Kenneth R. French�s website. It is the value-

weighted return on all NYSE, AMEX, and NASDAQ stocks in excess of the one-

month T-bill rate. Market indices are included based on the following considera-

tions. According to Chen, Roll, and Ross (1986), macroeconomic factors can�t be

15

Page 16: Macroeconomic Factors and the Cross-Section of Commodity ... · Macroeconomic Factors and the Cross-Section of Commodity Returns Hua (Helen) Shangy February 15, 2011 Abstract This

expected to possess all the information available to the market in a month. It is thus

necessary to include market indices since the stock prices are a¤ected instantly by

public information. Furthermore, the theory of ICAPM demonstrates that market

indices represent stock market performance, while, macroeconomic factors represent

investment opportunities. Investors make investment decisions based on these two

criteria. Ideally, the market factor should include all the assets available to investors.

It should thus include commodity futures. However, since the commodity futures are

only a small fraction compared to stock returns, it is reasonable to include stock re-

turns alone.

The real interest rate is measured by subtracting expected in�ation from the

norminal interest rate. The nominal interest rate is the three month T-bill rate

obtained from Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louise. Frankel (2006) proposes an

overshooting theory to argue that commodity prices have an inverse relation with

the real interest rate. Speci�cally, high interest rates decrease the demand for storable

commodities and increase their supply. As the interest rate decreases, investors move

their money from equities into commodities. Therefore, commodities are expected

to have a low return.

The real interest rate can be considered a proxy for the state of investment

opportunities [e.g. Merton (1973) and Cox, Ingersoll and Ross (1985)]. It is the real

interest rate which a¤ects consumers intertemporal consumption and investment

decisions.

The exchange rate is the US e¤ective exchange rate on major currencies. It is

constructed by the Federal Reserve with the object of inducing market pressure on

16

Page 17: Macroeconomic Factors and the Cross-Section of Commodity ... · Macroeconomic Factors and the Cross-Section of Commodity Returns Hua (Helen) Shangy February 15, 2011 Abstract This

the US dollar. Commodities have a global market. Their price depends on global

supply and demand. Many commodities are denominated in US dollars. Therefore,

investors face a risk of exchange rate �uctuations. For example, both Mundell (2002)

and Frankel (2008) have documented a link between the commodity price cycle and

the dollar cycle.

The exchange rate variable is priced in international asset pricing models. The

idea is that world security markets can be viewed as one market. Investors from

di¤erent countries face di¤erent exchange rates. Investors demand higher expected

returns to be compensated for the exchange rate risk. The discussion of exchange

rate risk is included in Solnik (1974), Adler and Dumas (1983), among others.

4.3 Summary Statistics

4.3.1 Properties of the returns and the factors

In Table 1, commodity returns are compared with equity returns. Stock returns are

represented by the return on the SP 500 index. The bond is the Ibborton US long

term coporate bond. The compound annualized average is 8.0460, which is similar

to that of the stock returns 7.2063. Each is larger than the average of bond returns,

3.9171. Commodities have a standard deviation 18.8482, which is 4% more than that

for stocks and 11.6% more than that for bonds. Commodity has the lowest Sharpe

ratio due to its high volatility.

Table 2 summarizes the statistical properties of individual commodity returns.

Most commodities have positive returns in this period. Energy and industrial metals

have larger average returns than other commodities. Compared to the sample period

17

Page 18: Macroeconomic Factors and the Cross-Section of Commodity ... · Macroeconomic Factors and the Cross-Section of Commodity Returns Hua (Helen) Shangy February 15, 2011 Abstract This

in Erb and Harvey (2006), gold and silver perform much better in the sample period.

The returns increase from -4.81 and -5.30 to 1.0374 and 2.7119 for gold and silver

respectively. Agriculture and energy tend to have large standard deviations. The

risk premiums are signi�cant for industrial metals and energy. All commodities have

positive skewness, except lean hogs and live cattle. The large excess kurtosis indicates

that many commodity futures returns have fatter tails than a normal distribution.

The �rst-order autocorrelations of commodity returns are very small, indicating that

these returns are not persistent.

Since it is typically believed that some commodities act as a hedge against in-

�ation, some unconditional correlations between these asset returns and in�ation

are considered. Table 3 shows the correlation of excess returns and in�ation in two

di¤erent sample periods. One is from January 1986 to July 2008, the other from

June 2004 to July 2008. Commodity returns have negative correlations with both

stocks and bonds and a positive correlation with in�ation. The magnitude of the

correlations is pretty small in the whole sample period. The correlations become

larger in the more recent sample period. For example, the correlation of the returns

of stocks and commodities is -0.1157 for the more recent sample period rather than

-0.0699 for the whole sample period.

Table 4 presents the properties of the factors. The market factor has a monthly

average of 0.5731 and nearly zero autocorrelation. It is the most volatile among the

three factors. The monthly average of the exchange rate growth is negative, with a

�rst-order autocorrelation 0.3357. The real interest rate has an annualized average

of 1.4638 and very persistent with an autocorrelation of 0.9627.

18

Page 19: Macroeconomic Factors and the Cross-Section of Commodity ... · Macroeconomic Factors and the Cross-Section of Commodity Returns Hua (Helen) Shangy February 15, 2011 Abstract This

Table 5 summarizes the correlations of the factors. All these factors have very

small correlations with each other.

Table 6 shows the estimated betas. Most commodities tend to have negative betas

associated with real interest rate. This is consistent with Frankel (2006) who argues

that a low real interest rate leads to high commodity prices. Gold and silver have

signi�cantly negative relations with the commodity returns at the 5% signi�cance

level. When the value of US dollar decreases, the price of commodities tends to

decrease. Gold and industrial metals show signi�cant relations with the exchange

rate at the 5% signi�cance level. Gold is the only commodity which has a signi�cant

beta with market returns at the 5% signi�cance level. This is consistent with the

argument that commodity futures do not have close relations with stocks.

4.3.2 Commodity Returns over the business cycles

Gorton and Rouwenhorst (2006) argue that the negative correlation of the com-

modity porfolio returns and the equity returns is due to the di¤erent behavior of

the commodity index over the business cycles. Their results are based on analyz-

ing an equally weighted commodity index from July 1959 to December 2004. They

show that the commodity index earns higher returns in the late expansion and early

recession than those in their counter-stages of the business cycles, on average.

In this part, we examine the performances of the GSCI excess index returns and

some individual commodity returns from the �ve sectors over the di¤erent stages

of business cycles on average. We also investigate their performances in the latest

business cycle, which is the cycle from March 2001 to December 2007. The business

19

Page 20: Macroeconomic Factors and the Cross-Section of Commodity ... · Macroeconomic Factors and the Cross-Section of Commodity Returns Hua (Helen) Shangy February 15, 2011 Abstract This

cycles are identi�ed by the National Bureau of Economic Research. The commodity

returns are dated back to its earliest initiation time7. The GSCI index, the agriculture

commodities and live cattle involve 6 expansions and 5 recessions.

Table 7 presents the averages of commodity returns at di¤erent stages of the

business cycles. The GSCI index behaves in a similar pattern as that reported by

Gorton and Rouwenhorst (2006). Most representative individual commodities have

positive returns during expansions. In particular, the return of the crude oil 1.5068,

which is the highest among all commodities. In the early expansion, the index return

is very small and all individual commodities show negative returns except for live

cattle and crude oil. The crude oil is very unique in the sense that it has much higher

returns in the early expansion than in the late expansion. It is also interesting to

notice that gold and silver have negative returns during all stages of the expansion.

Commodities do not seem to perform well in recessions on average. The index

and most of the commodities demonstrate negative returns. Even though crude oil

has a positive return, the magnitude is not large. Most individual commodities show

negative returns in early stages of recession on average. However, the index return

is positive. It is most probably due to the crude oil. It performs very well in early

expansion, with a return 7.1822. Nevertheless, its return in the latest recession is

-6.2941, far less than the other commodities. Gold and silver seem to be a very good

hedge against the late recessions on average. They have the best performances among

all the commodities. However, their returns in the early stage of the recessions are

the smallest among all the commodites. It is also interesting to notice that even

7The initiation date can be found at the bottom of the table.

20

Page 21: Macroeconomic Factors and the Cross-Section of Commodity ... · Macroeconomic Factors and the Cross-Section of Commodity Returns Hua (Helen) Shangy February 15, 2011 Abstract This

though the index shows a higher return on average in the early recession than that

in the late recession, most individual commodities provide smaller returns than those

in the late recession.

Table 8 presents the results for the latest business cycle, from March 2001 to

December 2007. The GSCI provides a higher return in the early expansion than in

the late expansion, which is di¤erent from its average over multiple business cycles.

Most of the commodities show positive returns during all stages of expansion. Copper

has an exceptional performance with average returns above 2% at all stages. Further,

the behavior of the gold and silver are quite di¤erent from their averages. Both of

them have substantial positive returns.

In the latest recession, from March 2001 to November 2001, the GSCI index

performs much worse than its historical average, with a return 2.36% lower than the

average. Soybean and gold have positive returns. Crude oil performs much worse

than its average. Soybean has an exceptional return in the early recession, which is

5.33%. The index shows a smaller return in the early recession than that in the late

recession, which is consistent with the case in Table 6. But the four commodities in

the agricultural and live stock sectors perform better in the early recession than in

the late recession in this case.

4.3.3 Predictability of Commodity Returns

There is a strand of literature analyzing the prediction of commodity returns using

common predictors similar to those predicting equity returns. Since commodity

returns are also assets, the prediction of commodity returns should have the same

21

Page 22: Macroeconomic Factors and the Cross-Section of Commodity ... · Macroeconomic Factors and the Cross-Section of Commodity Returns Hua (Helen) Shangy February 15, 2011 Abstract This

explanation as equities. One is due to market ine¢ ciency, which means prices deviate

irrationally from fundamentals. The other is due to the changing of equilibrium

expected returns through time. If some variables are able to predict commodity

returns, it may imply that the asset pricing model holds from time to time conditional

on the information proxied by these variables.

In this part, the results of the predictive ability of three variables are presented:

the yield spread (YS), the dividend yield (DY) and the short rate (SR). The yield

spread and the dividend yield have been argued to be proxies for the business cycle

[see, for example, Fama and French (1989)]. Bessembinder and Chan (1992) analyze

12 futures markets from January 1975 to December 1989 and document that T-bill

yield, dividend yield and yield spread have the ability to predict commodity returns.

More recently Hong and Yogo (2009) construct an equally-weighted portfolio using

34 fully collaterized commodity futures and �nd that the short rate and yield spread

possess the ability to predict commodity returns in the sample period from January

1965 to December 2008.

The dividend yield is constructed using the value-weighted return including div-

idends and excluding dividends as described in Fama and French (1988). It is the

summation of the 12-month dividends over the price at the beginning of the period.

The yield spread is the di¤erence between Moody�s seasoned Aaa corporate bond

yield and the 1-month T-bill rate following Fama and French (1989). The short

rate is the 1-month T-bill rate obtained from Kenneth R. French�s website. Table

9 presents the properties of the three information variables from December 1985 to

June 2008. The �rst-order autocorrelation of the dividend yield is 0.9855, which is

22

Page 23: Macroeconomic Factors and the Cross-Section of Commodity ... · Macroeconomic Factors and the Cross-Section of Commodity Returns Hua (Helen) Shangy February 15, 2011 Abstract This

the largest among all three variables. The yield spread is the least persistent, with

the autocorrelation 0.9051. Furthermore, the correlation of the yield spread and the

dividend yield is very small (-0.0249). In comparison, the correlations of the short

rate with the dividend yield and the yield spread are much larger.

In Table 10, we report the regression of the commodity returns on the lagged

information variables as in Hong and Yogo (2009). The variables are detrended

by subtracting the previous 12-month moving average to guard against spurious

regression bias as suggested by Ferson, Sarkissian, and Simin (2003). The results

show that these variables do not have statistically signi�cant power to predict the

GSCI index in the sample period. For individual commodities, we observe that the

dividend yield is signi�cant for copper and wheat at the 5% signi�cant level. The

yield spread and the short rate exhibit some predictive power only for copper at the

5% signi�cance level and for crude oil at the 10% signi�cance level.8 The results are

somehow consistent with the results in Hong and Yogo (2009). They do not �nd

that these variables possess signi�cant power in predicting commodity index returns

in the sample period from 1987 to 2008.

8We then experiment the combination of two information variables out of these three in aconditional asset pricing model with the market, real interest rate and exchange rate as the statevariables. We do not �nd any signi�cant results.

23

Page 24: Macroeconomic Factors and the Cross-Section of Commodity ... · Macroeconomic Factors and the Cross-Section of Commodity Returns Hua (Helen) Shangy February 15, 2011 Abstract This

5 Empirical Evidence

5.1 Estimation Results

The results investigating the validity of CAPM are presented in panel A of Table 11.

The demeaned method shows that the t-value for the market factor is 1.5055 assum-

ing a correctly speci�ed model and 1.2632 under a potentially misspeci�ed model.

This result is consistent with Dusak (1973) and Bodie and Rosansky (1980). The

HJ-distance measure is not statistically di¤erent from zero at the 10% signi�cance

level. This is attributable to the very volatile nature of commodity returns.

The results from the three-factor model are shown in panel B of Table 11. The

demeaned method provides similar results under a correctly speci�ed model and

under a misspeci�ed model. This is expected since the HJ-distance is 0.2135 with

a p-value 0.8166. The pricing error is very small in this case. The t-values of the

exchange rate growth are -2.8925 under a correctly speci�ed model and -2.6936 under

a misspeci�ed model. Therefore, it can be concluded that the exchange rate growth

is priced but the real interest rate is not. This indicates that investors will not

be compensated for the real interest rate risk. This result is di¤erent from Roache

(2008), who shows that the real interest rate is priced for the period from January

1973 to February 2008. However, based on the theory of storage and the theory of

backwardation, the real interest rate does a¤ect commodity returns. Furthermore,

from Table 5, we observe that its correlation with the market factor and the exchange

rate is very small. This implies that it also brings extra information in explaining

commodity returns. Therefore, the 3-factor model is favoured.

24

Page 25: Macroeconomic Factors and the Cross-Section of Commodity ... · Macroeconomic Factors and the Cross-Section of Commodity Returns Hua (Helen) Shangy February 15, 2011 Abstract This

In order to compare di¤erent models visually, the scatter graphs of the estimated

expected returns versus realized average returns under di¤erent model speci�cations

are plotted. The lines in the graphs are 45-degree lines: the closer the scatter points

are to the line, the better the �t of the model. Figure 1 shows the plots of di¤erent

model speci�cations. From top to bottom, the models are CAPM with stock market

returns as the only factor and the three-factor model. The points in the �rst graph

spread out widely. The estimated expected returns of many commodities are very

di¤erent from the corresponding realized expected returns. This indicates that the

CAPM has a very poor �t. The second graph shows that, after including the exchange

rate and the real interest rate to the model, the estimated expected returns become

much closer to the corresponding realized returns. This reinforces the belief that the

three-factor model is much better than the CAPM.

5.2 Robustness Check

For a robustness check, we �rst apply the traditional GMM to estimate the above

models. The advantage of the traditional GMM-SDF to the demeaned method is

that the traditional method is a one-step method, while the demeaned method is

a two-stage procedure. In Table 12, the results for the 3-factor model estimated

by the traditional method are reported. The results are quite similar to the those

estimated by the demeaned method in terms of both sign and statistical signi�cance.

The exchange rate is more signi�cant this time with a t-value -2.9823.

We also tried the estimation using the Fama-Macbeth method to estimate the

risk premiums directly. Table 13 shows that the exchange rate is also priced by using

25

Page 26: Macroeconomic Factors and the Cross-Section of Commodity ... · Macroeconomic Factors and the Cross-Section of Commodity Returns Hua (Helen) Shangy February 15, 2011 Abstract This

the method with and without Shanken�s correction [see Shanken (1992)].

In order to check whether the results hold in a long period, returns are constructed

using commodity data obtained from US Commodity Research Bureau (CRB). Since

CRB only has price data instead of return data, returns are constructed by adding

the percentage net basis to the percentage change of the commodity price. The

percentage net basis is de�ned as the ratio of the net convenience yield �marginal

convenience yield minus per-unit storage cost �to the previous period�s price. The

marginal convenience yield is obtained from the theory of storage. By using the same

15 commodities from April 1983 to July 2008, we �nd that the exchange rate is also

priced. Table 14 shows that the t-value is -3.7238 assuming the model is correct and

-3.3136 under a potentially misspeci�ed model.

There is still controversy over the stationarity of the real interest rate process.

In the model, the level of the real interest rate was used. Also, some experimenta-

tion with di¤erent real interest rate processes are undertaken: for example, the real

interest rate constructed by subtracting the previous 12-month moving average and

a process that subtracts the previous 3-year moving average. In all these cases, the

exchange rate is found to be signi�cant at the 5% signi�cance level.

5.2.1 Possible Economic Explanations

The result using the GSCI excess commodity futures from January 1986 to July 2008

indicates that, after controlling for real interest rate movements and the market

returns, the risk premium of the exchange rate is signi�cant and has a negative

sign. This means that commodities whose returns are negatively correlated with

26

Page 27: Macroeconomic Factors and the Cross-Section of Commodity ... · Macroeconomic Factors and the Cross-Section of Commodity Returns Hua (Helen) Shangy February 15, 2011 Abstract This

the exchange rate should be expected to have higher returns, in equilibrium. For

example, as the US dollar appreciates or other currencies depreciate relative to the US

dollar, prices of some dollar-denominated commodities drop. The reason can be that

the world demand for these commodities decreases. It can also be due to the increased

supply of commodities. Foreign exporters, especially the suppliers of storable goods,

are willing to provide more commodities because the appreciation of the dollar o¤ers

them higher returns. This is because the supply of storable commodities is able to

increase in the short term, given enough inventories. Therefore, the return to US

investors on these commodities decreases. They are expected to receive a reward for

bearing the risk in equilibrium.

6 Conclusion and Discussion

This study contributes to the empirical literature that explores the determination

of commodity futures prices in equilibrium. It also sheds some light on the current

debate on the pro�tability of investing in long-only portfolios of commodity futures

and the predictability of common futures returns.

In this study, macroeconomic determinants of the commodity returns in both

a static asset pricing model framework and by allowing the risk premiums to vary

over time, has been investigated. The macroeconomic factors included are the stock

market factor, the real interest rate and the exchange rate. These factors have been

argued to be the main determinants of commodity prices. They have also been found

to be priced by equity returns. This study also considers the predictability of the

27

Page 28: Macroeconomic Factors and the Cross-Section of Commodity ... · Macroeconomic Factors and the Cross-Section of Commodity Returns Hua (Helen) Shangy February 15, 2011 Abstract This

commodity futures returns using three variables: the short rate, the dividend yield

and the yield spread. The results show that these variables tend to have very weak

predictive power for copper and wheat among all the 15 commodities.

The model is estimated in its SDF representation using the demeaned GMM-SDF

method. This method is invariant to linear transformations of the factors. It also

has some power to detect useless factors. We report both results under the correctly

speci�ed model and under model misspeci�cation. Since the GMM method we are

using is not an e¢ cient GMM (because it uses a prespeci�ed weighting matrix), the

standard errors obtained might be larger than those with the e¢ cient GMM. This

could be one reason for statistical insigni�cance for the interest rate. On the other

hand, this method allows us to make objective comparisons across di¤erent SDF and

model speci�cations using a common weighting matrix.

The main result of the paper is that the exchange rate risk is priced. Speci�cally,

the commodities which are negatively related to the exchange rate provide higher

expected returns in equilibrium. A possible explanation could lie in the willingness

of commodity suppliers to provide more commodities or the world demand shrinks

when the dollar value increases, or both. Thus, the prices of some commodities fall.

US investors are worse o¤ and they ask for compensation for the exchange rate risk

they are bearing. The results are robust across di¤erent estimation methods and

di¤erent data sets and over a longer time period.

28

Page 29: Macroeconomic Factors and the Cross-Section of Commodity ... · Macroeconomic Factors and the Cross-Section of Commodity Returns Hua (Helen) Shangy February 15, 2011 Abstract This

References

[1] Adler, Michael, and Bernard Dumas (1983), "International portfolio choice and

corporation �nance: A synthesis," Journal of Finance 38, 925-984.

[2] Ang, Andrew, Geert Bekaert, and Min Wei (2007), "Do macro variables, asset

markets, or surveys forecast in�ation better?" Journal of Monetary Economics

54, 1163-1212.

[3] Arnott, Robert D., and Peter L. Bernstein (2002), "What Risk Premium is

Normal?" Financial Analysts Journal 58: 64-85.

[4] Bessembinder, Hendrik (1992), "Systematic Risk, Hedging Pressure, and Risk

Premiums in Futures Markets," Review of Financial Studies 5: 637-667.

[5] Bessembinder, Hendrik, and Kalok Chan (1992), "Time-varying Risk Premia

and Forecastable Returns in Futures Markets," Journal of Financial Economics

32: 169-193.

[6] Bodie, Zvi, and Victor Rosansky (1980), �Risk and Return in Commodity Fu-

tures,�Financial Analysts Journal 62: 27-39.

[7] Burnside A. Craig (2007), "Empirical Asset Pricing and Statistical Power in the

Presence of Weak Risk Factors," NBER Working Paper No. W13357.

[8] Chen, Nai-Fu, Richard Roll, and Stephen A. Ross (1986), �Economic Forces and

the Stock Market,�Journal of Business 59: 383�403.

[9] Cochrane, John H. (2005), Asset Pricing, Princeton, New Jersey.

29

Page 30: Macroeconomic Factors and the Cross-Section of Commodity ... · Macroeconomic Factors and the Cross-Section of Commodity Returns Hua (Helen) Shangy February 15, 2011 Abstract This

[10] Cox, John C., Jonathan E. Ingersoll Jr., and Stephen A. Ross, "A Theory of

the Term Structure of Interest Rates," Econometrica 53: 385-407.

[11] Dusak, Katherine (1973), �Futures Trading and Investor Returns: An Investi-

gation of Commodity market Risk Premiums,�Journal of Political Economy 81:

1387-1406.

[12] Erb, Claude B, and Campbell R Harvey (2006), "The Strategic and Tactical

Value of Commodity Futures," Financial Analysts Journal 62: 69-97.

[13] Fama, Eugene F., and Kenneth R. French (1988), "Dividend yields and expected

stock returns," Journal of Financial Economics 22: 3-25.

[14] Fama, Eugene F., and Kenneth R. French (1989), "Business Conditions and

Expected Returns on Stocks and Bonds," Journal of Financial Economics 25:

23-49;

[15] Ferson, Wayne E, and Campbell R. Harvey (1991), �The Variation of Economic

Risk Premiums,�Journal of Political Economy 99: 385�415.

[16] Frankel, Je¤rey (2006), "The E¤ect of Monetary Policy on Real Commodity

Prices," NBER Working Paper No. W12713.

[17] Frankel, Je¤rey (2008), "Monetary Policy and Commodity Prices,"

http://www.voxeu.org/index.php?q=node/1178.

[18] Greer, Robert J. (2000), "The nature of commodity index returns," Journal of

Alternative Investments 3, 45-52.

30

Page 31: Macroeconomic Factors and the Cross-Section of Commodity ... · Macroeconomic Factors and the Cross-Section of Commodity Returns Hua (Helen) Shangy February 15, 2011 Abstract This

[19] Gorton, Gary, and K. Geert Rouwenhorst (2006), "Facts and fantasies about

commodity futures," Financial Analysts Journal 62, 47-68.

[20] Hansen Lars Peter, Ravi Jagannathan (1997), " Assessing speci�cation errors

in stochastic discount factor models," Journal of Finance 52, 557-590.

[21] Hong, Harrison, and Motohiro Yogo (2009), "Digging into Commodities," Work-

ing Paper, Princeton University.

[22] Jagannathan, Ravi (1985), "An Investigation of Commodity Futures Prices Us-

ing the Consumption-Base Intertemporal Capital Asset Pricing Model," Journal

of Finance 40, 175-191.

[23] Jagannathan, Ravi, and Zhenyu Wang (1996), "The conditional CAPM and the

cross-section of expected returns,"-Journal of Finance 51, 3-53.

[24] Kan, Raymond, and Robotti Cesare (2008), "Speci�cation tests of asset pricing

models using excess returns," Journal of Empirical Finance 15, 816-838.

[25] Merton, Robert C. (1973), �An Intertemporal Capital Asset Pricing Model�,

Econometrica 41: 867�887.

[26] Mundell, Robert (2002), "Commodity Prices, Ex-

change Rates and the International Monetary System,"

http://www.fao.org/docrep/006/y4344e/y4344e04.htm.

[27] Newey, Whitney K, and Kenneth D. West (1987), "A simple, positive semi-

de�nite, heteroskedasticity and autocorrelation consistent covariance matrix,"

Econometrica 55: 703-708.

31

Page 32: Macroeconomic Factors and the Cross-Section of Commodity ... · Macroeconomic Factors and the Cross-Section of Commodity Returns Hua (Helen) Shangy February 15, 2011 Abstract This

[28] Roache, Shaun K (2008), "Commodities and the Market Price of Risk," IMF

working paper WP/08/221.

[29] Solnik, B.H. (1974), "The international pricing of risk: An empirical investiga-

tion of the world capital market structure," Journal of Finance 29, 365-378.

[30] Thomas Jr. Lloyd B. (1999), "Survey measures of expected US in�ation," Jour-

nal of Economic Perspectives 13, 125-144.

32

Page 33: Macroeconomic Factors and the Cross-Section of Commodity ... · Macroeconomic Factors and the Cross-Section of Commodity Returns Hua (Helen) Shangy February 15, 2011 Abstract This

Figure 1: estimated expected returns versus realized expected returns

­0.6 ­0.4 ­0.2 0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1 1.2 1.4­0.6

­0.4

­0.2

0

0.2

0.4

0.6

0.8

1

1.2

1.4CAPM­demean

­0.6 ­0.4 ­0.2 0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1 1.2 1.4­0.6

­0.4

­0.2

0

0.2

0.4

0.6

0.8

1

1.2

1.43fac­demeaned

Noto: The lines in the graphs are the 45-degree lines. The closer the scatter

points to the line, the better the �t of the model. The top graph is the plot of the

CAPM. The bottom graph is the plot of the 3-factor model including the market

factor, the real interest rate factor and the exchange rate factor.

33

Page 34: Macroeconomic Factors and the Cross-Section of Commodity ... · Macroeconomic Factors and the Cross-Section of Commodity Returns Hua (Helen) Shangy February 15, 2011 Abstract This

Table 1: comparison of the commodity futures return and the equity returnsaverage std Sharpe ratio

GSCI 8.0469 18.8482 0.4269stock 7.2063 14.8252 0.4861bond 3.9171 7.2492 0.5404

Note: the results in the table are compound annualized average returns, standard

deviation and Sharpe ratio calculated from monthly returns from January 1986 to

July 2008. The "GSCI" is the Goldman Sacks Commodity Index. The "stock"

represents the SP 500 index. The "bond" is the Ibborton US long term coporate

bond.

34

Page 35: Macroeconomic Factors and the Cross-Section of Commodity ... · Macroeconomic Factors and the Cross-Section of Commodity Returns Hua (Helen) Shangy February 15, 2011 Abstract This

Table 2: properties of commodity futures returnsaverage std Sharpe ratio t-stat skewness kurtosis AR(1)

cocoa -4.9755 28.5666 -0.1742 -0.8472 0.8144 4.6795 -0.0921co¤ee -3.5780 39.2194 -0.0912 -0.4408 1.0009 5.5533 -0.0064corn -4.4866 24.6998 -0.1816 -0.8815 0.9764 9.1980 0.0022cotton 0.7681 24.6135 0.0312 0.1478 0.5133 3.9885 -0.0370soybean 4.8681 22.3462 0.2178 1.0128 0.1194 4.3608 -0.0781sugar 7.7525 33.0563 0.2345 1.0768 0.6191 5.0380 0.0622wheat -1.9706 23.0627 -0.0854 -0.4098 0.2630 3.2178 0.0098lean hogs -0.8684 24.6725 -0.0352 -0.1679 -0.0440 3.8812 -0.0698live cattle 3.9797 13.5684 0.2933 1.3691 -0.5231 5.9874 0.0102copper 17.9205 26.5776 0.6743 2.9678 0.8521 5.8556 0.1009gold 1.0374 13.7073 0.0757 0.3579 0.5178 3.8144 -0.0169silver 2.7119 24.1948 0.1121 0.5261 0.4050 4.1099 -0.0969platinum 9.9803 20.7606 0.4807 2.1862 0.7086 6.8081 -0.0484crude oil 16.3114 33.5526 0.4861 2.1536 0.1253 7.1596 0.1106heating oil 13.6952 33.7044 0.4063 1.8194 0.5315 4.3133 0.0295

Note: This table summarizes the average, standard deviation, Sharpe ratio, t-

statistic, skewness, kurtosis and the �rst-order autocorrelation of the individual com-

modity returns. The data series are from January 1986 to July 2008.

35

Page 36: Macroeconomic Factors and the Cross-Section of Commodity ... · Macroeconomic Factors and the Cross-Section of Commodity Returns Hua (Helen) Shangy February 15, 2011 Abstract This

Table 3: correlation of stocks, bonds, commodity futures and in�ationGSCI stock bond

January 1986-July 2008stock -0.0699 - -bond -0.0517 0.1681 -inf 0.0744 -0.1666 -0.1677

June 2004-July 2008stock -0.1157 - -bond -0.0865 0.0059 -inf 0.1341 -0.2793 -0.3780

Note: The results are correlations of the excess returns and in�ation in two

di¤erent sample periods. One is from January 1986 to July 2008. The other one is

from June 2004 to July 2008. The "GSCI" is the Goldman Sacks Commodity Index.

The "stock" represents the SP 500 index. The "bond" is the Ibborton US long term

coporate bond. The "inf" represents the in�ation.

36

Page 37: Macroeconomic Factors and the Cross-Section of Commodity ... · Macroeconomic Factors and the Cross-Section of Commodity Returns Hua (Helen) Shangy February 15, 2011 Abstract This

Table 4: properties of factorsmarket rir ex

average 0.5731 1.4638 -0.1984std 4.3318 1.7198 1.6645AR(1) 0.0466 0.9627 0.3357

Note: The table summarizes the average, standard deviation and �rst-order au-

tocorrelation of the factors. The "market" is the market factor, which is the value-

weighted return on all NYSE, AMEX, and NASDAQ stocks in excess of the one-

month T-bill rate. The "rir" represents the real interest rate measured by subtract-

ing the expected in�ation (constructed by the survey research center of University

of Michigan) from the three month T-bill rate. The "ex" represents the US e¤ective

exchange rate on major currencies. The data series are from January 1986 to July

2008.

37

Page 38: Macroeconomic Factors and the Cross-Section of Commodity ... · Macroeconomic Factors and the Cross-Section of Commodity Returns Hua (Helen) Shangy February 15, 2011 Abstract This

Table 5: correlation of the factorsmarket rir ex

market 1 - -rir 0.0190 1 -ex -0.0469 0.0693 1

Note: The results are the correlations of the four factors. The "market" is the

market factor, which is the value-weighted return on all NYSE, AMEX, and NAS-

DAQ stocks in excess of the one-month T-bill rate. The "rir" represents the real

interest rate measured by subtracting the expected in�ation (constructed by the sur-

vey research center of University of Michigan) from the three month T-bill rate. The

"ex" represents the US e¤ective exchange rate on major currencies. The data series

are from January 1986 to July 2008.

38

Page 39: Macroeconomic Factors and the Cross-Section of Commodity ... · Macroeconomic Factors and the Cross-Section of Commodity Returns Hua (Helen) Shangy February 15, 2011 Abstract This

Table 6: estimated betasmarket rir ex R2

cocoa -0.1828* -0.6051* -0.2934 0.0296co¤ee 0.1349 -0.2816 0.2945 0.0058corn 0.1101 -0.1085 0.3449 0.0108cotton 0.0814 0.4381 0.0503 0.0142soybean 0.0530 -0.4834* 0.1057 0.0179sugar -0.0177 0.1902 -0.0307 0.0012wheat 0.1020 -0.1983 0.1018 0.0072lean hogs 0.0236 0.4161* -0.0424 0.0103live cattle 0.0706 0.0989 -0.0322 0.0083copper 0.1316 0.1433 -0.8284** 0.0394gold -0.1418*** -0.2766** -0.4826*** 0.0809silver 0.0866 -0.5699*** -0.1059 0.0236platinum 0.1204 -0.1747 -0.5280*** 0.0337crude oil -0.1665 0.3393 -0.5474 0.0164heating oil -0.1252 0.1551 -0.6664* 0.0158

Note: The results in this table are the estimated betas obtained from regressions

of the individual commodity returns on the four factors. * , **, and *** denote

signi�cance at 10%, 5% and 1% levels, respectively. The standard errors are the

robust standard errors. The "market" is the market factor, which is the value-

weighted return on all NYSE, AMEX, and NASDAQ stocks in excess of the one-

month T-bill rate. The "rir" represents the real interest rate measured by subtracting

the expected in�ation (constructed by the survey research center of University of

Michigan) from the three month T-bill rate. The "ex" represents the US e¤ective

exchange rate on major currencies. The data series are from January 1986 to July

2008.

39

Page 40: Macroeconomic Factors and the Cross-Section of Commodity ... · Macroeconomic Factors and the Cross-Section of Commodity Returns Hua (Helen) Shangy February 15, 2011 Abstract This

Table 7: commodity futures returns at di¤erent stages of business cyclesexpansion EE LE recession ER LR

GSCI ex 0.6017 0.0896 1.1137 -0.3283 0.5439 -1.2005corn 0.0002 -0.5531 0.5535 -0.4630 -0.6007 -0.3252soybean 0.8204 -0.0211 1.6620 -0.1982 0.4789 -0.8762wheat 0.3475 -0.5766 1.2715 -1.2735 -2.3201 -0.2270live cattle 0.4676 0.2226 0.7127 -0.0229 -0.2102 0.1643copper 0.6546 -0.2703 1.5795 -1.3774 -2.6062 -0.1486gold -0.5733 -0.9277 -0.2190 -0.6994 -3.3943 1.9955silver -0.2720 -0.4643 -0.0797 -3.5543 -8.8481 1.7395crudeoil 1.5068 2.1263 0.8873 0.4440 7.1822 -6.2941

Note: The table presents the averages of commodity returns at di¤erent stages

of the business cycles. The "EE", "LE", "ER" and "LR" represent early expansion,

late expansion, early recession and late recession, respectively. The "GSCI ex" is the

excess return of the GSCI.

40

Page 41: Macroeconomic Factors and the Cross-Section of Commodity ... · Macroeconomic Factors and the Cross-Section of Commodity Returns Hua (Helen) Shangy February 15, 2011 Abstract This

Table 8: commodity futures returns at the most recent business cycle from March2001 to December 2007

expansion EE LE recession ER LRGSCI ex 1.9607 2.1584 1.7631 -2.6914 -1.2211 -4.1617corn -0.2437 -1.0865 0.5992 -1.1782 0.1428 -2.4992soybean 1.6521 1.7765 1.5276 0.7564 5.3306 -3.8177wheat 0.5210 -0.7081 1.7501 -0.3670 0.3255 -1.0594live cattle 0.3476 0.9129 -0.2178 -1.7189 -0.2370 -3.2009copper 2.6161 2.1555 3.0767 -1.0948 -3.1392 0.9497gold 1.3417 1.3376 1.3457 0.6013 0.6422 0.5605silver 1.7878 1.8713 1.7043 -0.7048 -0.8218 -0.5877crudeoil 2.1599 3.6392 0.6807 -3.9537 -0.5335 -7.3739

Note: The table presents the averages of commodity returns in the latest business

cycle, which is the cycle from March 2001 to December 2007. The "EE", "LE",

"ER" and "LR" represent early expansion, late expansion, early recession and late

recession, respectively. The "GSCI ex" is the excess return of the GSCI.

41

Page 42: Macroeconomic Factors and the Cross-Section of Commodity ... · Macroeconomic Factors and the Cross-Section of Commodity Returns Hua (Helen) Shangy February 15, 2011 Abstract This

Table 9: descriptive statistics for the information variablesvariable average std deviation AR(1) correlation with- - - - DY YSDY 2.4885 0.9276 0.9855 - -YS 0.2437 0.1161 0.9051 -0.0249 -SR 0.3727 0.1597 0.9441 0.5731 -0.6684

Note: The table shows the average, standard deviation, �rst-order autocorrelation

and correlations of the lagged information variables as in Hong and Yogo (2009).

The variables are detrended by subtracting the previous 12-month moving average

to guard against spurious regression bias as suggested by Ferson, Sarkissian, and

Simin (2003). The "YS", "DY" and "SR" denote the yield spread, the dividend

yield and the short rate. The sample period is from January 1965 to December 2008.

42

Page 43: Macroeconomic Factors and the Cross-Section of Commodity ... · Macroeconomic Factors and the Cross-Section of Commodity Returns Hua (Helen) Shangy February 15, 2011 Abstract This

Table 10: descriptive statistics for the information variablesYS t-stat DY t-stat SR t-stat R^2 F-test p-value

GSCI 8.0636 1.03 2.0439 1.33 8.8100 1.13 0.0099 1.28 0.2822cocoa 9.1266 0.67 4.5242 2.03 -2.3725** -0.18 0.0184 1.52 0.2083co¤ee 32.0250 1.38 0.6530 0.20 34.4274 1.49 0.0118 0.76 0.5157corn -6.8258 -0.68 2.3170 1.22 -7.5948 -0.72 0.0070 0.70 0.5505cotton -15.5306 -1.38 0.4804 0.25 -8.0599 -0.66 0.0095 1.02 0.3821soybean 4.2501 0.46 3.2902 1.82* -3.9814 -0.42 0.0158 1.16 0.3247sugar 4.2315 0.20 3.3032 1.34 11.6557 0.55 0.0111 1.04 0.3743wheat -15.7846 -1.29 4.4718 2.83** -9.6880 -0.85 0.0376 4.75 0.0030**lean hogs -12.6071 -0.98 -2.9985 -1.60 -6.8207 -0.53 0.0112 1.02 0.3824live cattle 0.6386 0.09 -.9399 -0.79 4.3353 0.60 0.0060 0.48 0.6976copper 40.3744 2.53** 4.4327 2.19** 50.9769 3.13*** 0.0733 4.77 0.0030**gold -6.6495 -0.95 0.8339 0.80 -4.2106 -0.61 0.0078 0.84 0.4754silver -16.2367 -1.50 0.4405 0.24 -13.5693 -1.28 0.0073 0.94 0.4202platinum -16.2026 -1.50 1.0737 0.58 -10.8188 -0.99 0.0137 1.17 0.3202crude oil 25.4334 1.95* 3.0207 1.00 28.7395 1.94* 0.0154 1.91 0.1284heating oil 20.7057 1.11 2.8047 0.97 19.4677 1.12 0.0089 0.69 0.5592

Note: The table shows the results from a regression of the commodity returns

on the lagged information variables as in Hong and Yogo (2009). The variables are

detrended by subtracting the previous 12-month moving average to guard against

spurious regression bias as suggested by Ferson, Sarkissian, and Simin (2003). The

"YS", "DY" and "SR" denote the yield spread, the dividend yield and the short

rate. The sample period is from January 1965 to December 2008.

43

Page 44: Macroeconomic Factors and the Cross-Section of Commodity ... · Macroeconomic Factors and the Cross-Section of Commodity Returns Hua (Helen) Shangy February 15, 2011 Abstract This

Table 11: estimation results using demeaned SDF methodpanel A

risk permiums market rir ex HJ-distestimates 0.0745 - - 0.2949t 1.5055 - - -t_mis 1.2632 - - -p_value - - - 0.1156

panel Bestimates 0.1263 0.0264 -0.4193 0.2135t 1.9048 0.1722 -2.8925 -t_mis 1.8594 0.1450 -2.6936 -p_value - - - 0.8166

Note: The table shows the estimation results from the CAPM and our four-factor

asset pricing model. They are estimated by the demeaned GMM/SDF method. The

"t_mis" represents the t value under a misspeci�ed model. The "HJ-distance" is the

HJ-distance statistic. The "market" is the market factor, which is the value-weighted

return on all NYSE, AMEX, and NASDAQ stocks in excess of the one-month T-bill

rate. The "rir" represents the real interest rate measured by subtracting the expected

in�ation (constructed by the survey research center of University of Michigan) from

the three month T-bill rate. The "ex" represents the US e¤ective exchange rate on

major currencies. The data series are from January 1986 to July 2008.

44

Page 45: Macroeconomic Factors and the Cross-Section of Commodity ... · Macroeconomic Factors and the Cross-Section of Commodity Returns Hua (Helen) Shangy February 15, 2011 Abstract This

Table 12: estimation results using traditional SDF methodrisk permiums market rir ex HJ-distestimates 0.0842 0.1359 -0.3226 0.1591t 1.7523 1.3361 -2.9823 -p_value - - - 0.8266

Note: The table shows the estimation results from the 3-factor asset pricing

model. It estimated by the traditional GMM/SDF method. The "HJ-distance" is the

HJ-distance statistic. The "market" is the market factor, which is the value-weighted

return on all NYSE, AMEX, and NASDAQ stocks in excess of the one-month T-bill

rate. The "rir" represents the real interest rate measured by subtracting the expected

in�ation (constructed by the survey research center of University of Michigan) from

the three month T-bill rate. The "ex" represents the US e¤ective exchange rate on

major currencies. The data series are from January 1986 to July 2008.

45

Page 46: Macroeconomic Factors and the Cross-Section of Commodity ... · Macroeconomic Factors and the Cross-Section of Commodity Returns Hua (Helen) Shangy February 15, 2011 Abstract This

Table 13: estimation results using the Fama-Macbeth two-pass regressionrisk permiums market rir exestimates 1.1518 0.4634 -1.3476t 0.8991 1.2448 -3.1022t_SK 0.7137 0.9183 -2.3564

Note: The table shows the estimation results from the 3-factor asset pricing

model. It estimated by the Fama-Macbeth method. The "market" is the market fac-

tor, which is the value-weighted return on all NYSE, AMEX, and NASDAQ stocks

in excess of the one-month T-bill rate. The "rir" represents the real interest rate

measured by subtracting the expected in�ation (constructed by the survey research

center of University of Michigan) from the three month T-bill rate. The "ex" repre-

sents the US e¤ective exchange rate on major currencies. The data series are from

January 1986 to July 2008.

46

Page 47: Macroeconomic Factors and the Cross-Section of Commodity ... · Macroeconomic Factors and the Cross-Section of Commodity Returns Hua (Helen) Shangy February 15, 2011 Abstract This

Table 14: estimation results using demeaned SDF method with CRB datarisk permiums market rir ex HJ-distestimates 0.2065 -0.0316 -0.7114 0.3253t 2.4104 -0.2650 -3.7238t_mis 2.3176 -0.2220 -3.3136 0.6686

Note: The table shows the estimation results from the 3-factor asset pricing

model. It estimated by the demeaned GMM/SDF method. The returns are con-

structed using the prices from CRB. The "market" is the market factor, which is

the value-weighted return on all NYSE, AMEX, and NASDAQ stocks in excess of

the one-month T-bill rate. The "rir" represents the real interest rate measured by

subtracting the expected in�ation (constructed by the survey research center of Uni-

versity of Michigan) from the three month T-bill rate. The "ex" represents the US

e¤ective exchange rate on major currencies. The data series are from April 1983 to

July 2008.

47