may 2020 | drug pricing lab report · may 2020 | drug pricing lab report . an opportunity with...

12
Anna Kaltenboeck, M.A. Raina H. Jain Jennifer A. Ohn, M.P.H. Peter B. Bach, M.D., M.A.P.P . May 2020 | Drug Pricing Lab Report

Upload: others

Post on 08-Jul-2020

1 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: May 2020 | Drug Pricing Lab Report · May 2020 | Drug Pricing Lab Report . An Opportunity with Challenges: ... One benefit of this approach is that patient OOP would be determined

February 2020

Anna Kal tenboec k, M .A.

Raina H. Jain

Jenni fer A. Ohn, M .P.H.

Peter B. Bac h, M .D., M .A.P.P.

May 2020 | Drug Pricing Lab Report

Page 2: May 2020 | Drug Pricing Lab Report · May 2020 | Drug Pricing Lab Report . An Opportunity with Challenges: ... One benefit of this approach is that patient OOP would be determined

An Opportunity with Challenges: Blueprints for Indication-Specific Pricing in the United States 2

Overview.............................................................................................................................................................................................. 3

Model 1: Pre-distribution Model – Packaging by indication ........................................................................................... 3

Model 2: Post-distribution Model (Conventional and Simplified) – Varying price along the supply chain .. 5

Medical Benefi t Drugs – Conventional supply chain ........................................................................................................ 5

Medical Benefi t Drugs – Simpli fied supply chain .............................................................................................................. 6

Pharmacy Benefi t Drugs – Conventional supply chain ................................................................................................... 7

Pharmacy Benefi t Drugs – Simplified supply chain .......................................................................................................... 8

Model 3: Post-distribution Discount Card Model – Using copayment and coinsurance cards ........................ 8

Medical Benefi t Drugs – Using copayment and coinsurance cards ............................................................................. 9

Pharmacy Benefi t Drugs – Using copayment and coinsurance cards ......................................................................10

Discussion ........................................................................................................................................................................................10

Page 3: May 2020 | Drug Pricing Lab Report · May 2020 | Drug Pricing Lab Report . An Opportunity with Challenges: ... One benefit of this approach is that patient OOP would be determined

An Opportunity with Challenges: Blueprints for Indication-Specific Pricing in the United States 3

Interest in value-based pricing has increased in recent years as an analytic alternative to current pric ing methods

that are distorted by financial incentives across the industry and supply chain. 1-4 Because value-based pricing links

a drug’s price to the magnitude of the benefit it provides, the approach must accommodate the frequent reality that

a single drug can have different benefit profiles in different conditions. For instance, one study describes a four-fold

difference in the value-based price for Roche’s drug Herceptin (trastuzumab) when used in different indications

(metastatic and adjuvant HER-2 positive breast cancer).5

A solution to this problem is for Herceptin to have two prices, one for its metastatic indication, and another for its

adjuvant indication. Termed “indication-specific pricing” (ISP), this approach is being tested by ExpressScripts and

CVS Caremark, who each announced that they had implemented strategies to manage certain drugs according to

price relative to indication-specific value. 6Its advantages aside, ISP requires mechanisms to reimburse by indication,

which are hampered by the complexities of drug purchasing and delivery.7 In the absence of more formal pathways,

we propose several approaches that rewire existing reimbursement conventions as alternatives to facilitate ISP.

These alternatives can be broadly categorized into three models, with each model distinct in the point of the supply

chain at which payment and reimbursement for a drug diverges by indication:

1. Pre-distribution Model – Packaging by indication

2. Post-distribution Model (Conventional and Simplified) – Varying prices along the supply chain

3. Post-distribution Discount Card Model – Using copayment and coinsurance cards

Within these models, mechanisms are further tailored, depending on whether the therapy is covered by the pharmacy

benefit or the medical benefit.

Overview: The most straightforward approach to indication-specific pricing for a drug approved for two different

indications is to simply treat it as two different drugs (Figure 1, Figure 2). This would require two types of packaging,

unique sets of National Drug Codes (NDC)8 for each of the packages, and for injectable drugs, two different Healthcare

Common Procedure Coding System (HCPCS) J codes. This requires manufacturers to produce packaging according to

indication and U.S. Centers for Medicare and Medicaid Services (CMS) to assign separate J Codes, which contrary to

convention. Average Sales Price (ASP) and Medicaid Best Price reporting would be separate as well, giving the drug two

separate reimbursement and payment rates. Using this approach, the manufacturer would introduce the drug at a value-

based list price for each indication. This would allow different formulary treatment of the drug by indication and would also

align patient out-of-pocket (OOP) costs with the value of the drug in each indication.

Page 4: May 2020 | Drug Pricing Lab Report · May 2020 | Drug Pricing Lab Report . An Opportunity with Challenges: ... One benefit of this approach is that patient OOP would be determined

An Opportunity with Challenges: Blueprints for Indication-Specific Pricing in the United States 4

Challenges and limitations: There are three potential challenges to this model. For medical benefit drugs, CMS would

need to assign unique HCPCS J codes for each indication. The availability of one produc t at multiple price points also

presents opportunities for fraud and diversion. With ill intent, medical offices or pharmacies could obtain the drug

packaged for the lower priced indication, but then dispense or deliver it to patients with the higher price d indication,

charging the patient and insurer at the higher reimbursement rate associated with it and pocketing the difference. The

more closely monitored prescribing is, the lower the risk of such fraud; if perpetrated in government programs it would

constitute a false claim. This type of diversion should be nearly impossible in the context of drugs customized to the

patient, such as CAR-T therapies, where the chain of custody and manufacturing is specific to a patient.

Drugs are introduced at a value-based list price by the manufacturer and treated as two separate drugs.

Drugs are introduced at a value-based list price by the manufacturer and treated as two separate drugs.

Page 5: May 2020 | Drug Pricing Lab Report · May 2020 | Drug Pricing Lab Report . An Opportunity with Challenges: ... One benefit of this approach is that patient OOP would be determined

An Opportunity with Challenges: Blueprints for Indication-Specific Pricing in the United States 5

Overview: Another approach to implement ISP is to alter purchasing and reimbursement practices within the supply

chain. This approach would have different details depending on whether the drug is paid for through the medical benefit

or pharmacy benefit. In either case, the essential feature is a rebate after administration or dispensing, paid in a manner

that yields different net prices by indication.

An alternative to operating within the existing supply chain is to simplify it, particularly as it relates to the la st step in which

providers and pharmacies acquire the product before administering or dispensing it. Instead, a large -scale distributing

intermediary would differentiate the product by indication and then match distribution to individual patients who are to

receive it. This intermediary would also reconcile the price differences between indications.

Achieving multiple prices for a single drug that is administered in the doctor’s office or hospital outpatient clinic (e.g.,

paid for by the medical benefit) begins with the provider purchasing the drug at a single price (Figure 3). The provider

then differentiates the net price of the drug by billing according to indication. For instance, the provider would bill the

insurer at the full cost of the drug if used for the higher-value indication. But for the lower-priced indication the

provider would bill the insurer a reduced amount, equating to the value-based price for that indication, and would

bill the remaining portion to the manufacturer and receive a rebate. Both approaches would include the customary

proportional markup, known as “Buy-and-Bill”, but index it on the ISP. This approach would keep the provider whole

on the purchase of the drug, but the provider’s mark-up would be based on the lower-priced indication. Patient co-

Purchasing and reimbursement practices are altered at the provider billing level- the key component being a rebate to providers yielding billing net price difference

Page 6: May 2020 | Drug Pricing Lab Report · May 2020 | Drug Pricing Lab Report . An Opportunity with Challenges: ... One benefit of this approach is that patient OOP would be determined

An Opportunity with Challenges: Blueprints for Indication-Specific Pricing in the United States 6

insurance would align with the drug’s price for that indication, as it is based on the reimbursed amount from the

insurer.

A related approach would have the insurer reimburse the provider in full, with no variation in mark-up. The insurer

would then reconcile the price with the manufacturer through a rebate arrangement. Although the provider would

likely receive the mark-up on the higher priced indication and the patient co-insurance would be based on that as

well, the approach reduces billing complexity and offers economies of scale that providers are too decentralized to

capture.

Rather than reimbursing the doctor’s office or hospital outpatient clinic for drugs they purchase and mark up, payers

could instead require that providers order and receive the drug from a specialty pharmacy or wholesaler on behalf

of the patient (Figure 4). Once it is administered to the patient, the physician’s office would be responsible for

submitting a claim to the payer for the services rendered in administering the drug, inc luding the diagnosis code.

However, they would not bill for the drug itself; instead, the “distributor” would submit a separate claim to the payer

for the drug. The payer would then reimburse this distributor based on ISP, and the manufacturer would provid e

them with a rebate or chargeback for the difference with the purchase price. In part, this model has already been

tested by private payers (known as “white bagging”), and in the form of the Competitive Acquisition Program (CAP),

in which claims for medical products and devices were submitted by the distributor to Medicare Part B.9

Purchasing and reimbursement practices altered throughout the supply chain, with the financial exchange occurring between wholesaler and health insurer, rather than providers -the key component being a rebate to

wholesalers.

Page 7: May 2020 | Drug Pricing Lab Report · May 2020 | Drug Pricing Lab Report . An Opportunity with Challenges: ... One benefit of this approach is that patient OOP would be determined

An Opportunity with Challenges: Blueprints for Indication-Specific Pricing in the United States 7

Challenges and limitations: Both variations of this model face technical pitfalls. One is that to implement ISP,

diagnosis must be tracked, and this is not currently a core capability of distributors. To address this, a third party to

collect diagnosis codes or analyze claims from the distributor and the physician’s office would need to be involved.

More complicated are the issues of Average Sale Price (ASP) and Best Price. Unless exempted by CMS through a

waiver that exempts indication-specific payments from the ASP calculation, reimbursement for physicians not

participating in the model would erode. Without similar provisions for Best Price, manufacturers might also prefer to

avoid taking this route. Additionally, the storage and handling of some specialty drugs makes white -bagging

burdensome for physicians.

As with medical benefit drugs, prescription (pharmacy) benefit drugs (e.g., those dispensed to the patient by

pharmacies) could have indication-specific prices by altering reimbursement after they are dispensed (Figure 5).

Specialty pharmacies, which have the capability to capture and track indication with claims, would obtain contracted

reimbursements from the PBM that vary by each indication, and then collect a rebate from the manufacturer for the

lower-priced indication. One benefit of this approach is that patient OOP would be determined based on the

indication-specific rate from the PBM, resulting in a lower payment burden for patients using the drug for the

indication in which it is less effective.

After purchasing and reimbursement practices at the pharmacy billing level to the PBM, with the key component being a rebate to pharmacy yielding billing net price difference

Page 8: May 2020 | Drug Pricing Lab Report · May 2020 | Drug Pricing Lab Report . An Opportunity with Challenges: ... One benefit of this approach is that patient OOP would be determined

An Opportunity with Challenges: Blueprints for Indication-Specific Pricing in the United States 8

Alternatively, the PBM could provide full reimbursement to the pharmacy regardless of indication, a nd then obtain

indication-specific rebates from the manufacturer. Under some interpretations of the law, rebates to PBMs need not

be reported as part of Best Price, which may advantage this approach. However, unless these rebates are factored

into the patients’ payments at point of sale, they would likely face higher OOP costs for the lower -priced indication

than under the pharmacy-based approach.

For pharmacy benefit drugs, this approach would rely on a limi ted number of specialty pharmacies with exclusive

distribution rights to ship the drug directly to the patient (Figure 6). The differential prices would be reconciled at the

specialty pharmacy level. In this scenario, the specialty pharmacy would submit a claim to the plan with the diagnosis

code, and the plan would be responsible for paying a negotiated price and dispensing fee to the pharmacy. The plan

would then report the claims with the lower-priced indication to the manufacturer, which would issue a rebate to

attain the ISP. This model is particularly appealing for Part D plans (PDPs) – no statutory changes would be needed,

and manufacturers already pay rebates to PDPs

Challenges and limitations: Even more so than for drugs administered in the doctor’s office or hospital outpatient

clinic, the tracking of indication poses a significant challenge for prescription drugs. At least in the near term, this

limits opportunities to specialty pharmacies, unless retail pharmacies begin to develop this capability. Further

complexities also include the need for a waiver or alternative reporting mechanism to address implications for Best

After purchasing and reimbursement practices within the supply chain, providing a rebate after dispensing at the

pharmacy

Page 9: May 2020 | Drug Pricing Lab Report · May 2020 | Drug Pricing Lab Report . An Opportunity with Challenges: ... One benefit of this approach is that patient OOP would be determined

An Opportunity with Challenges: Blueprints for Indication-Specific Pricing in the United States 9

Price, although this is not a concern in Medicare Part D, as discounts and rebates in Part D are not incorporated

into Best Price determinations.

Manufacturer copayment coupons and coinsurance cards serve to lower a drug’s net price by replacing part or all

of the patients’ OOP payment with funds provided by the drug’s manufacturer. This means that by varying the

amount of copay support it provides by indication, a manufacturer could align net price with ISP. In effect, a patient

obtaining a drug for its higher priced indication would be charged a lower co-insurance amount by the payer than a

patient using it for the lower-priced indication. The difference in patient OOP would be covered through a copayment

coupon from the manufacturer. Today’s transactions involving copayment cards are often invisible to providers and

pharmacies, so that they would not be burdened administratively, or face any risk that the cards are not delivered or

result in payments. Copayment support is also not included in the determination of ASP or Medicaid Best Price,

reducing the complexity of this approach.

Under the medical benefit, the provider and insurer would operate as they do currently for the higher-priced indication

(Figure 7). For the lower-priced indication, the insurer would reduce the amount it pays to the provider to attain the

net price (to the insurer) appropriate for that indication. The remaining difference between this net price and the list

price would then be added to the patient’s coinsurance obligation. To pay for this, the patient would reimburse the

provider by using a manufacturer copay or coinsurance assistance card, which would act as a voucher for the

provider to send to the manufacturer in exchange for payment. Because this approach directly focuses on patient

Provide patients with a copay coupon yielding net price difference

Page 10: May 2020 | Drug Pricing Lab Report · May 2020 | Drug Pricing Lab Report . An Opportunity with Challenges: ... One benefit of this approach is that patient OOP would be determined

An Opportunity with Challenges: Blueprints for Indication-Specific Pricing in the United States 10

OOP costs, the manufacturer and insurer could construct such an arrangement to also allow a lower patient out -of-

pocket obligation for the lower-priced indication. The provider would be kept whole, as the patient obligation would

be simply calculated as the appropriate share of the contracted reimbursement amount.

Under the pharmacy benefit, a similar transaction would take place, in which the pharmacy would receive

reimbursement from the PBM that would vary based on the indication for the dispensed medication (Figure 8). For

the lower value indication, the out-of-pocket expense for the patient would be higher, but the manufacturer would

provide a coinsurance coupon or card that would cover that larger amount.

Challenges and limitations: The approach would require that insurers be able to take on coinsurance charges

whether or not the patient has exceeded their out-of-pocket maximum, which may conflict with some state and

Federal regulations. Another drawback is that copayment support to Medicare beneficiaries violates the anti-

kickback statute, limiting this approach to only commercially insured patients. Finally, copayment and coinsurance

cards remain uncommon in outpatient practice settings, which lack the technology that allows pharma cies to process

them. However, use of prepaid debit cards, which have become increasingly popular among manufacturers in lieu

of copay coupons, could be feasible in this setting.

Value-based pricing rests on the idea that when a drug is priced according to evidence of its value, payers make

them available without restrictions driven by financial incentives, offering access to those patients who would stand

to benefit. However, in many instances, the benefits and harms of many recently approved d rugs vary substantial ly

Provide patients with a copay coupon yielding net price difference

Page 11: May 2020 | Drug Pricing Lab Report · May 2020 | Drug Pricing Lab Report . An Opportunity with Challenges: ... One benefit of this approach is that patient OOP would be determined

An Opportunity with Challenges: Blueprints for Indication-Specific Pricing in the United States 11

across their indicated uses, and in comparison, with existing treatment options. Indication-specific pricing aims to

address this problem by creating separate mechanisms for reimbursement depending on a drug’s use. Both

manufacturers and patients benefit from less onerous coverage restrictions when a drug is used for lower value

indications.10

A shift to ISP requires adjustment to existing purchasing and reimbursement practices. Although the implementation

models we have outlined offer options for a path forward, each requires that its participants be “bought in”, which

runs afoul of a basic tension between interests of business and policy. ISP requires that prices be value-based,

which in and of itself represents a departure from the status quo. Absent an explicit link between a drug’s benefits

and other features to the price in a given indication, implementing the proposed models will do litt le to disrupt the

persistent distortions in the purchasing and reimbursement environment. Chandra and Garthwaite summarized this

potential risk, noting that monopolists can capture more surplus, leaving less to the consumer, if they can price

maximize by indication.11 In other words, only by aligning prices with benefits in each indication using a systematic

analytic approach can the surplus be appropriately shared between the manufacturer, patient, and payer. Particularly

for high-priced drugs with multiple indications, that is often not the case, and it would be financially unfavorable in

the short term for the manufacturer and other stakeholders to depart from the existing pricing model. At the same

time, implementation must be feasible under existing business models in order to be practical.

Compatibility with existing practice is a barrier for ISP and addressing it will likely entail resource and capital

commitments only possible for organizations with sufficient size and scale, at least initially. A number of the proposed

models may be too complex to be practical, or only of interest for specific scenarios, particularly in the short term.

Those that are more broadly feasible will need strong political and organizational will to justify the investment and

properly scope the commitments. Initial efforts would likely be focused on the drugs with the highest unit prices and

the greatest differences in value by indication, with the ambition of scaling up at a later time. Even so, the investment

would likely only make sense for the largest players - payers, providers, pharmacies, and providers with the scale

to implement the changes and to benefit from them.

However, recent policy actions may prove helpful in easing the transition. Development of HCPCS and NDC coding

standards that allow claims to simultaneously capture the drug and its indication would allow payers and other

intermediaries to more easily develop the tools needed to efficiently determine reimbursement levels. CMS has

recently signaled that it is exploring ways to enhance Part D plans’ abilities to implement ISP. A proposed

demonstration program in Part B that resuscitates the Competitive Acquisition Program may also build operational

expertise across the industry and offer and opportunities to put ISP into practice. In August 2018, CMS announced

it will allow indication-based formulary design for Medicare Part D to take effect in 2020.

Industry, regulators, and legislators can take further steps to enable ISP. One is to learn from and build on the

experience CMS has gained with Kymriah (tisagenlecleucel), which is currently being reimbursed at different prices

for its two indications. Efforts to alter the price of Avastin (bevacizumab) and Tecentriq (atezolizumab) when used

in together, rather than as single agents may help to build this momentum. Another is to explore the development of

a system for implementing HCPCS that require certain ICD-10 codes to qualify for reimbursement. Pilot programs

by the Center for Medicare and Medicaid Innovation (CMMI) and state Medicaid programs may offer practical

opportunities to explore implementation.

Page 12: May 2020 | Drug Pricing Lab Report · May 2020 | Drug Pricing Lab Report . An Opportunity with Challenges: ... One benefit of this approach is that patient OOP would be determined

An Opportunity with Challenges: Blueprints for Indication-Specific Pricing in the United States 12

References

1. Institute for Clinical and Economic Review (ICER). Dupilumab and Crisaborole for Atopic Dermatitis: Effectiveness and Value-Final Evidence Report and Meeting Summary. https://icer-review.org/wp-content/uploads/2016/10/M WCEPAC_ATOPIC_FINAL_EVIDENCE_REPORT_060717.pdf.

Published June 2017. Accessed August 21, 2019.

2. IBM Micromedex, Red Book. Accessed August 21, 2019.

3. Institute for Clinical and Economic Review (ICER). Institute for Clinical and Economic Review Report Finds Costs of Approved CAR-T Therapies Align with Clinical Benefit. https://icer-review.org/announcements/car-t-evidence-report/. Published February 2018. Accessed August

21, 2019.

4. Institute for Clinical and Economic Review (ICER). Institute for Clinical and Economic Review

Posts Updated Economic Analyses for PCSK9 Inhibitor Evolocumab, Finds Less Favorable Cost-Effectiveness. https://icer-review.org/announcements/pcsk9 -neu/. Published September 2017. Accessed August 21, 2019.

5. Bach PB. Indication-specific pricing for cancer drugs. JAMA. Oct 2014;312(16):1629-1630. doi:10.1001/jama.2014.13235.

6. Ramsey L. Indication based pricing for Novartis. Business Insider. Published May 7, 2018. https://www.businessinsider.com/indication -based-pricing-for-novartis-car-t-cell-therapy-kymriah-2018-5.

7. Institute for Clinical and Economic Review (ICER). Indication-specific pricing of pharmaceuticals in the United States health care system-A Report from the 2015 ICER Membership Policy Summit. http://icer-review.org/wp-content/uploads/2015/03/Final-Report-2015-ICER-Policy-Summit-on-Indication-specific-Pricing-March-2016_revised-icons-002.pdf.

Published March 2016. Accessed August 21, 2019.

8. U.S. Food and Drug Administration. National Drug Code Directory.

https://www.fda.gov/drugs/drug-approvals-and-databases/national-drug-code-directory. Updated September 2019. Accessed October 30, 2019.

9. Bach PB. Competitive Acquisition Program. Drug Pricing Lab. https://drugpricinglab.org/wp-content/uploads/2018/05/DPL-Policy-Brief_Competi tive-Acquisi tion-Program_051418_v2.pdf. Published 2018. Accessed May 1, 2019.

10. Kaltenboeck A, Bach PB. Value-Based Pricing for Drugs: Themes and Variations. JAMA. 2018;319(21):2165–2166. doi:10.1001/jama.2018.4871.

11. Chandra A, Garthwaite C. The economics of indication-based drug pricing. The New England journal of medicine. 2017;377(2):103-106.