microsoft vs netscape - davidallen.org policy.pdf · in this opposition, netscape first carried the...

60
PART II Consequences of State Interference and Non-interference 98

Upload: others

Post on 24-Jun-2020

7 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Microsoft vs Netscape - davidallen.org Policy.pdf · In this opposition, Netscape first carried the standard against Microsoft, with the “browser wars” setting off the tu-mult—Netscape’s

PART IIConsequences of State

Interference andNon-interference

98

Page 2: Microsoft vs Netscape - davidallen.org Policy.pdf · In this opposition, Netscape first carried the standard against Microsoft, with the “browser wars” setting off the tu-mult—Netscape’s

Chaper IV

Microsoft vsNetscape�Policy for

Dynamic Models

Anti-trust and Intellectual Property RightsRevisited

The current version has benefited from comments by participantsin a seminar at the Ecole Polytechnique, Paris, May 21, 1997,organized by Petros Kavassalis; also a session at Global Networking�97, Calgary, June 15-18, 1997. I particularly appreciate insights fromthree discussants, Dieter Elixmann, WIK; Laurent Caby, CNET; andChristian Licoppe, CNET. More generally, this paper is a successorto a work presented at the Schumpeter Society meeting a yearearlier, Stockholm, June 2�5, 1996. I especially thank DonLamberton and Gunnar Eliasson for exhaustive reviews, includingcomments from two anonymous reviewers which Don arranged.

David AllenDAVID ALLENCo-editor, Information Economics and Policy, 316 Heaths BridgeRoad, Concord, MA 01742, USA, phone +1 978 287 0433,fax +1 978 287 0434, cell +1 508 423 5750,e-mail [email protected]

99

Page 3: Microsoft vs Netscape - davidallen.org Policy.pdf · In this opposition, Netscape first carried the standard against Microsoft, with the “browser wars” setting off the tu-mult—Netscape’s

100

1 New York Times, June 12, 1997, p D1.2 As quoted in Web Week, Vol 2 (1996), No 11 (August 5), p 45. For the purposeshere, it is useful to have a record of recent industry history; Web Week [the namehas subsequently changed to Internet World] serves as one excellent chronology.3 New York Times, August 25, 1997, p D7.

�There is this enormousmarket, which follows from theinteroperability and commonstandards firstly, andsecondly�sort of ironically butappropriately�by thetremendous competition thereis to try to put extensions ontop, to produce the smartestway of leveraging thecommon standards.�

Tim Berners-Lee 2

Netscape goes back to thetrenches as it revives thebrowser war: Remember thebrowser war? Well, it�s back witha vengeance. �[B]y officiallyreviving hostilities withMicrosoft last week, Netscape �[has begun] a new assault onthe � market.

Steve Lohr, reporter,New York Times, August �97 3

�And so we have people here,engineers here [at the WorldWide Web Consortium/W3C],who have been forming theWeb for a long time, and theykeep in the back of their mindsthe long-term vision, thelong-term goals of a cleanarchitecture, of makingdecisions now which won�thamper us tomorrow for thethings that we haven�t evendreamed of yet, but still makingsure that the Web will be ableto encompass them.�

�This is unprecedented, butwe realized we need to worktogether [with Netscape] forthe common good. Wedecided we should not proposeseparate standards for privacysoftware.�

David Fester, Microsoft,June �97 1

Page 4: Microsoft vs Netscape - davidallen.org Policy.pdf · In this opposition, Netscape first carried the standard against Microsoft, with the “browser wars” setting off the tu-mult—Netscape’s

AbstractTraditional static approaches to competition policy are coming under

increasing scrutiny in dynamic technology markets. Beginning with

the face-off between Microsoft and Netscape, the torrent of innovation

which is the ‘Net and the Web yields a model to capture the essential

dynamics. Simple at its core, the novel model unfolds to the natural

richness of the evolving Web (with, among others, flexible industry

structure, an information ‘product’ distinct from the industry

behavior which creates it, variety and commonality as part and whole,

shared protocols to guide process, and a working definition for

“openness”). Inference derives from industry and technology cases,

throughout. Now with a template in hand to describe the evolutionary

scenario, anti-trust and intellectual property rights can begin to be

retooled, to suit the dynamics of change. At stake are productivity and

a society’s standard of living.

The Internet and Web, in the last few years, have been party to one

of the more surprising runs in the annals of innovation. Sustained

innovation—and with that the prospect for long-term productivity

increase—lie at the root of a society’s capacity to improve its standard

of living. Development of the ‘Net and Web carries encapsulated

within its story a model for industry organization. In this story, the

borders that define industry actors shift dynamically, contrary to

convention. I suggest this model is pivotal in the remarkable capacity

to sustain innovation.

This paper, beginning from the intense commercial conflict

particularly between Netscape and Microsoft, goes to some pains to

elucidate the embedded industry model. With the model in hand, the

question becomes, and the paper turns to, comparisons against

prevailing theories and policy prescriptions.

101

Page 5: Microsoft vs Netscape - davidallen.org Policy.pdf · In this opposition, Netscape first carried the standard against Microsoft, with the “browser wars” setting off the tu-mult—Netscape’s

The agenda

Since Microsoft swung its guns onto the Internet in late‘95 / beginning ‘96, there ensued an intense and fero-ciously fought commercial battle, in the first instance be-

tween the upstart wunderkind Netscape and Microsoft thenew Goliath. In their public profiles, the two seem to epito-mize fundamentally opposed and contending styles of indus-try organization. Netscape, on its side, seems to carry into theprivate sector the novel model for industry organizationwhich has propelled the ‘Net so far. Microsoft, for its part, hasseemed to embody the very extreme for the currently prevail-ing policy mandate: competitive behavior—to the point fi-nally of crossing irretrievably into anti-competitive territory.

With the first and major part of this paper devoted to eluci-date the novel ‘Net model for industry organization, the firsthalf of the first part delineates the two opposed approachesNetscape and Microsoft seem to offer. Others, such as Sun,also play a key role. We find this is useful introduction, but afull description of the novel model requires we turn back intime to the story of ‘Net development itself. This is the secondhalf of the first part. Here positive description begets norma-tive prescription as well. Sub-sections focus on industry con-duct and structure in the model, also on the information“product.”

With the novel model in hand, the paper can turn to itsbriefer second part, to prepare the ground for comparing thenew model against prevailing theories and policy. Anti-trustand intellectual property rights policy are both reconsidered.

102

Page 6: Microsoft vs Netscape - davidallen.org Policy.pdf · In this opposition, Netscape first carried the standard against Microsoft, with the “browser wars” setting off the tu-mult—Netscape’s

Part oneA novel model for industry

organization

1 Microsoft and NetscapeThe Internet and now the Web have been the occasion for a re-markably rapid and sustained run of innovation, even accel-erating in recent years. The pace of change is such that ‘Webyears’ has become a common term, where a single calendaryear is thought somehow to shoehorn perhaps seven Webyears inside. Customers have been noted to lament, “I can’ttake this much innovation this quickly.”4 The ability to inno-vate so nimbly lies at the heart of a society’s capacity to im-prove its lot markedly, its standard of living.

Coming upon this scene about two years ago, in late 1995,Bill Gates found that his Microsoft was caught flat-footed. Thecompany’s cash flows were tied to desktop computing, butthere was a fundamental shift underway, toward networkedcomputing. Remarkably, among many such performances bythe man, he turned his leviathan virtually “on a dime” andsteamed it off in relentless and vigorous pursuit of the Inter-net. There quickly arose a most intense opposition.

On the one side, an informal group emerged for whom“anyone but Microsoft” was the rallying cry. This could on oc-casion include Netscape, Sun, Oracle, Apple, or IBM, alongwith an entire contingent of the developer community whofelt palpable antipathy to the threat of Microsoft hegemony.Microsoft has, by appearances, often seemed alone in itsstruggle against this opposition. Often, in a given fight, it isthe bogey arrayed against one or the other of the informalsometimes-allies. In its efforts to make and keep dominance,Microsoft’s behavior has regularly reinforced its isolation,confirming that Microsoft is the company everyone loves-to-hate.

103

4 Eric Schmidt, now the head of Novell, when he was chief technology offi-cer at Sun, as reported in Web Week, Vol 2 (1996), No 4 (April), p 10.

Page 7: Microsoft vs Netscape - davidallen.org Policy.pdf · In this opposition, Netscape first carried the standard against Microsoft, with the “browser wars” setting off the tu-mult—Netscape’s

In this opposition, Netscape first carried the standardagainst Microsoft, with the “browser wars” setting off the tu-mult—Netscape’s Navigator versus Microsoft’s Internet Ex-plorer. The antipathy has renewed and continued, across re-peated conflicts, including standards for style sheets and laterpush technology, to name a couple. Over the time, thebrowser has metamorphosed into a vastly multi-functionalgroupware client; the conflict which began with clients spreadfar and wide, to servers and beyond.

In a finish to setting this scene, Sun has lately started to carrythe standard against Microsoft. Sun’s Java computing—boththe Java programming language and the from-the-ground-upoperating system/OS based on new Java chips, along withSun’s championing of a Network Computer/NC—squaresoff directly against Microsoft’s prime preserve in the desktopOS. Microsoft, for its part, has demonstrated that it can findpartners, certainly among major hardware vendors, beyondthose industry actors who simply take comfort behind a Mi-crosoft shield.

1.1 The two provisional models comparedWith this as setting, our interest for this paper is the way inwhich Netscape and Microsoft came, at least initially, to ty-pify two alternatives to industry organization. In the crispestcomparison, Netscape promotes inclusiveness for people andideas, across the industry; Microsoft by contrast maneuvers atall costs to keep control to itself. Related to this, Netscape pro-motes “open” standards; Microsoft instead aims for what herewill be called “vertical integration.” These are the ideal char-acterizations, unmuddied by the reality of actual behavior.

We will see how the first of the contrasts—inclusiveness vscontrol—regards industry organization, its conduct andstructure finally. The second of the contrasts regards the infor-mation “product” of industry behavior—the shared (or not-so-shared) conceptual/logical structure that emerges. To in-troduce this notion, consider an example of contrasting ‘infor-mation products:’ The cross-platform Java language serves asan intermediary layer between server and any of several clientplatforms, such as PC, Mac or UNIX. The information product

104

Page 8: Microsoft vs Netscape - davidallen.org Policy.pdf · In this opposition, Netscape first carried the standard against Microsoft, with the “browser wars” setting off the tu-mult—Netscape’s

is, in this case, layered. By contrast, ActiveX worked only ver-tically to connect client and server, that is just within the Mi-crosoft Wintel world, at the outset anyway. (Graphics to de-pict the contrast are developed from page 116 on.)

NetscapeNetscape actively espoused participation, by individualsacross the industry, in the development of innovations. Thiswas particularly in contrast to a Microsoft, characterized astrying to set all the standards by itself. Netscape’s public ad-vocacy was in addition to the concrete steps which it took. Forinstance, Netscape early-on published some of its code, as aninvitation to outside input. Now it has made the source codefor Navigator available explicitly to encourage input from thewhole developer community.

Open standards were certainly a talisman. ‘Open’ wasmeant in practice to be the ability to substitute different com-panies’ products for each other. In fact the main symbol foropenness became operability across OS platforms, particu-larly against Microsoft’s devotion to Windows by itself.

MicrosoftMicrosoft’s prowess as competitor—the epitome of the policyideal—proved almost legendary. Surely, by prevailing stan-dards Microsoft pushed so far that it fell over into being mark-edly anti-competitive. The story of Microsoft’s zeal in pursuitis fascinating. Microsoft seemed to have written the book oncornering a market (for which in this case read ‘predation’),then added new wrinkles for good measure. Microsoftseemed massively to deserve its reputation for being devotedentirely to control, against inclusion.

Gates is quoted as saying in December 1995 that he intendedto make browsers a “zero-revenue business.”5 By zero-pricingboth Microsoft’s browser and Microsoft’s server, he moved todeny his main competitor, Netscape, revenues in its principalmarkets. This, when Microsoft had at the time a $2 billion cashhoard, and its upstart competitor depended entirely on itscapital financing and the ability to prosecute a few limitedmarkets. And the story certainly did not stop there. Microsoft

105

5 Web Week, Vol 2 (1996), No 15 (October 7), p 19.

Page 9: Microsoft vs Netscape - davidallen.org Policy.pdf · In this opposition, Netscape first carried the standard against Microsoft, with the “browser wars” setting off the tu-mult—Netscape’s

made tying deals with sites which provide content. Access tothe site would be free, but only to those who used the Micro-soft browser, Explorer.

Microsoft also made real an innovation on monopolistic be-havior, a theory originally presented in a Silicon Valley whitepaper.6 Microsoft levered its high-dominant position in thedesktop OS, to overpower competitors in adjacent nascentmarkets. The company had no more position than did othersin the new market, of course. But because of the technical in-terconnection among markets, Microsoft could use its over-whelming dominance in the mature market to extend itspower, above other entrants, into the new market.

Specifically, Microsoft made online services a deal theycould not refuse. In return for a place on the dominant Win-dows desktop, the online services gave Microsoft’s Explorer afavored position over Netscape’s Navigator. Netscape an-nounced a deal to be that favored browser, and one day laterwas reversed by Microsoft. One by one, each of the onlineservices fell to Microsoft’s Explorer—America Online,CompuServe, and so on. With online service interconnectedto the desktop, Microsoft dominance in the desktop was irre-sistible to the online companies, who would control the newuse of browsers in their services.

In just the same vein, Microsoft has moved to convert thedesktop to a Webtop. The browser interface becomes thedesktop, as well. Netscape is doing the same, but its softwareis a layer on top of the Windows system. Because Microsoft’snew Webtop integrates directly into Windows, it will alwaysenjoy some better functionality for Windows users. In thiscase, interconnection itself, specifically the closer integration,conveys advantage over Netscape, the other entrant to theWebtop. Dominance in the original market, the OS, is not onlyextended, but reinforced.

Other moves have been subtler. Though Microsoft later con-cluded that its reputation against public standards bore toogreat a cost, Microsoft pointedly omitted Netscape from somekey, early deliberations over standards-setting, such as re-garding push technology. Once again Microsoft proved exclu-

106

6 Though not formally attributed, said to have been authored by two Stan-ford economists.

Page 10: Microsoft vs Netscape - davidallen.org Policy.pdf · In this opposition, Netscape first carried the standard against Microsoft, with the “browser wars” setting off the tu-mult—Netscape’s

sive, rather than inclusive, even though the new standardwould purportedly be open. Or again: When Microsoft finallycommitted ActiveX to a standards body, the Open Group, itclosely controlled the process, seeming to arrange a ‘friendly’caretaker, even excluding an alternate body, the Open Man-agement Group.

In perhaps the grandest statement of Microsoft in control,Gates convened a “summit.” Held at his palatial new home,still under construction, numerous CEO’s of major companiesgathered from around the world. To underline the exclusive-ness, apparently some companies in a given industry sectorwere favored, when others were not invited. To bring homethat the influence extends beyond just industry, to the highestpolitical realm, the Vice-President of the United States wasalso in attendance.

Microsoft richly earned its reputation as favoring controlover inclusion. Vertical integration, the counterpoint to openstandards, is the other element in the comparison withNetscape. What is vertical integration (in information pro-duct, not traditional vertical integration in industry organiza-tion—so, hereafter “idea-vertical integration”7)?

Microsoft idea-vertically integrates, as an example, by tyingto its existing—“legacy”—desktop Windows OS. The move toa Webtop, described above, is a case. The new Webtop inter-face, because it is more tightly integrated, helps to preserveMicrosoft’s position in its legacy desktop software and so re-inforces it. Another example is preservation of Microsoft’slegacy object model, Object Linking and Embedding/OLE,which it developed for Windows. Other industry membersmoved toward the Common Object Request Broker Architec-

107

7 The reader naturally associates vertical integration with industry organi-zation, not with the present topic of information product (and industry or-ganization is also a key topic in this paper, which increases the potential forconfusion—indeed, later in the paper a similarity emerges to connect idea-and organization- integration). But the notion of vertical integration suits theinformation product phenomenon too aptly to be substituted with somethingelse less descriptive, even if a substitute would not so directly conflict. To helpdistinguish the two uses of the notion, between information product and in-dustry organization, the balance of this paper uses ‘idea-vertical integration.’More rigorous attention to the particulars of information (and communica-tion) in the economy, as Don Lamberton encourages, will likely lead to othersimilar distinctions. [See for instance Lamberton’s “Information : pieces,batches or flows?” Stirling: Loasby Conference, 1997.]

Page 11: Microsoft vs Netscape - davidallen.org Policy.pdf · In this opposition, Netscape first carried the standard against Microsoft, with the “browser wars” setting off the tu-mult—Netscape’s

ture/CORBA and its Internet InterORB Protocol/IIOP. ButMicrosoft fought fiercely to sustain its old OLE technology byextending it to network play, cloaked there as the DistributedCommon Object Model/DCOM.

Before leaving the direct comparison of Microsoft andNetscape, we should note a point that will presage later dis-cussion. While Microsoft has used zero-pricing in classicpredatory fashion, Netscape made a point early-on also togive away some of its software, mainly to students (and nowhas been forced by Microsoft’s zero-pricing to make theNetscape browser free, too).

Not revealed by either case, however, is a more basic phe-nomenon. The server software, Apache, which continues todominate the Web—its share is on the order of three times thatfor either Netscape’s or Microsoft’s servers—is freeware. Themotivation behind this zero price is, however, essentially op-posite to Microsoft’s. The freeware tradition (a traditionstrong in the university world of Netscape’s origins) makescode available to build a better system, and with it a bettercommunity. The emphasis is on the community of referenceand its better future (not on a positive price for one or theother of the community members).

1.2 Summarizing � with conflicting strawsin the wind

The comparisons and contrasts, so far, are clear. Netscapechampions inclusion, which is paired with open stan-dards/cross-platform interoperability. Microsoft epitomizesthe opposite with its lust for control and exclusion, which ispaired with a penchant for vertical integration.

But Sun, demonstrably on the Netscape side, has pursuedexactly the same course as Microsoft—vertical integra-tion—for its Java language. To keep Java “100% pure,” Sunhas tried tightly to control the standardization process,among others submitting Java to the unaccustomed Interna-tional Standards Organization/ISO. Vertical integration, andcontrol, apparently have their place on the opposite,‘Netscape’ side of the contrast, too.

108

Page 12: Microsoft vs Netscape - davidallen.org Policy.pdf · In this opposition, Netscape first carried the standard against Microsoft, with the “browser wars” setting off the tu-mult—Netscape’s

Beyond that, not just Microsoft but also Netscape has bro-ken the mold of a standard, previously committed, to extendcapabilities in a proprietary way. Both, as an early for in-stance, wrote proprietary tags to extend Hypertext MarkupLanguage/HTML.

How do we understand the conclusions to be drawn?Netscape we characterized as bringing the style (withoutspecifying what that was) which earlier had served the ‘Net sowell. The contrast between Netscape and Microsoft might, itseems we could hope, illuminate what makes for the remark-able success with innovation. But the comparison, though itwill prove useful, encounters the two inconsistencies justabove.

We can resolve these contradictions, and also build on thecontrasts, if we move beyond the essentially static characteri-zations in the comparison so far—if for instance we incorpo-rate the dynamics behind both the Netscape and Microsoftproprietary extensions to HTML. The process by which the‘Net originally developed seems to offer such a dynamicmodel. We now (re)turn to it.

In preparation, what in summary can we conclude so farabout the results of the opposition that set Microsoft and theNetscape/Sun/allies coalition against each other?

In fact, Microsoft is now seen as innovative, when previ-ously it was taken more to be a copycat. The competitionseems to have been effective in that regard. (Microsoft has alsoembraced the standards process, for instance with the fourthlargest contingent pre-registered for a recent Internet Engi-neering Task Force/IETF meeting. It has even grown morecross-platform, with for instance one of the largest Mac devel-oper teams outside of Apple. But many doubt the motivationsbehind both the standards and the cross-platform work. Andthe cross-platform implementations often do not performnearly as well as on Windows. Nor is it uncommon to findNetscape lambasted for contravening its own public rhetoricto be open.)

The competition may have worked; the consensus, how-ever, failed. Despite fleeting occasions for agreement (as cap-tured for instance in one of the opening quotations), long-

109

Page 13: Microsoft vs Netscape - davidallen.org Policy.pdf · In this opposition, Netscape first carried the standard against Microsoft, with the “browser wars” setting off the tu-mult—Netscape’s

running feuds continue to separate Microsoft particularlyfrom Netscape and Sun, some of the cases being those above.

2 The IETF�a dynamic modelThe history of the ‘Net now covers several decades. We focuson the recent period of accelerating innovations.

The ongoing flow of innovations in the ‘Net is constructedfrom a simple building block. For each innovation, the ‘Netcommunity first generates, then incorporates the new idea.This simple, though dynamic, building block—a cycle be-tween first innovation, then standardization8—is repeated foreach new step.

In the first half of the cycle, a new idea generates, which mayspur other new ideas on the same topic. These new possibili-ties must be tried out, in a competition with each other—theymust be tested for their usefulness.9 After a period of trial, themode switches to the second half of the cycle. Now the newpossibilities must be winnowed, perhaps melded with eachother, to find a ‘best’ composite.

In the first—innovation—phase of the cycle, the communitydevolves to its individual elements. Each competes with theother to produce the best innovation. In the second—stan-dardization—phase, the group re-assembles to sort the trialresults and reach consensus on a new, perhaps melded, stan-

110

8 Petros Kavassalis has developed a set of ideas focused on just the samephenomena. A recent paper with Richard Solomon, for instance, discusses aniteration between fragmentation and convergence (which specific phenom-ena we will see in industry structure), “Mr Schumpeter on the telephone : pat-terns of technical change in the telecommunications industry before and afterthe Internet,” in Communications & Strategies, 1997, No 26 (2nd quarter), p 371.There are earlier papers on the subject from Kavassalis. See also my “Tele-communications policy between innovation and standardization : the evolv-ing network.” Sophia-Antipolis, France: Ninth Biennial ITS Conference, 1992.9 Gunnar Eliasson has particularly emphasized the ‘experimental economy.’His policy conclusions differ a bit from those here, but the work is parallel insome other key respects. Among his several contributions on the subject, for adiscussion of experimentation that parallels the innovation phase here, seehis “Commentary” on “Gateway technologies and the evolutionary dynam-ics of network industries : lessons from electricity supply history,” by David,P A & Bunn, J A, in Evolving technology and market structure : studies in Schum-peterian economics, by Heertje, A & Perlman, M (eds). Ann Arbor: University ofMichigan Press, 1990, pp 157–163.

Page 14: Microsoft vs Netscape - davidallen.org Policy.pdf · In this opposition, Netscape first carried the standard against Microsoft, with the “browser wars” setting off the tu-mult—Netscape’s

dard for the best future system. With its committees and chairstructure, the Internet Engineering Task Force/IETF forms aloose hierarchy to reach consensus (however the idea of hier-archy may contravene ‘Net ideology).

Thus Netscape’s inclusiveness is appropriate, indeed fun-damental, to consensus for the standardization phase. But thehierarchy does take control over the outcome. Though Micro-soft failed to situate control in appropriate hands, control isnecessary, as we saw also with Sun and its Java. And Micro-soft’s fierce competitiveness is essential to the innovationphase.

Thus is innovation both generated and incorporated. In factthe cycle is a necessity—here we come to the normative. Net-work technology must interconnect10, and this drives the re-sult. An innovation by its nature breaks the connection; for in-terconnection to be re-established, the innovation must even-tually be resolved into a new, interconnecting standard.

We can test this, with results from the opposition betweenMicrosoft and Netscape, Sun et al. As noted in the summaryabove, competition produced more innovation from Micro-soft; but consensus failed. The test of our normative proposi-tion is whether failed consensus retarded the uptake of inno-vation [implicitly, but nonetheless from the opening lines ofthe paper, the objective function in this dynamic model is suc-cessful adoption of innovation11]—did the failure to agreearound successive new standards prevent new uses whichmight otherwise emerge? Decidedly.

For instance, developers regularly report that they avoidnew technology which they would otherwise choose, becauseMicrosoft and Netscape have failed to agree on a standard ap-proach. Instead a developer will use an existing lower com-mon denominator, avoiding investment in more interestingtechnology because it is of uncertain future.

111

10 Computing, in contrast to networked computing, is an intermediate case,one where there is some interconnection—externalities—but where strict in-terconnection is not a necessity. Though not dealt with in this discussion, thecase is included elsewhere.11 This relatively straightforward objective function creates a basis to intro-duce the model, which is the purpose of this paper. In other discussion, thereal complexity of (technical) change in human affairs—certainly, limits onthe rate of desirable change—takes due place.

Page 15: Microsoft vs Netscape - davidallen.org Policy.pdf · In this opposition, Netscape first carried the standard against Microsoft, with the “browser wars” setting off the tu-mult—Netscape’s

One news report even attributes multi-millions of dollars ofloss to the failure of consensus, in this case the choice betweenthe two distributed object models, DCOM and CORBA. Lack-ing a clear industry choice, the Union Bank of Switzerland, orUBS, was unable to deploy an intranet application related toits role as a clearing-house. Without the application, the bankloses $10 million a day—and a delay of even a calendar quarteris about a hundred days, or the vicinity of a billion dollars.12 13

With this dynamic cycle there are two points of inflection.First, in the shift to the innovation phase, the cloak of hierar-chy falls away and the industry actors assert their individualpositions; thought turns from consensus standards to newpossibilities; consensus shifts to competition.

Thus we see, through this dynamic lens, how both Microsoftand Netscape served the cycle when they extended the HTMLstandard with proprietary tags.

Second, in the shift back to the standardization phase,14 focusmoves from individual ideas and individual betterment toconcern for the best technology that will suit the group; theroles and rules for conduct in the loose IETF hierarchy onceagain become the harness; competition shifts to consensus.

These essential dynamics distinguish this model; they con-vey its power both to explain and to guide. The two points ofinflection are of course captured by the two opening quotesfrom Tim Berners-Lee, one of the originators of the Web. Like-wise, the two parallel quotes from the Microsoft-Netscapesaga chronicle the two points of turn—perhaps largely unbe-knownst but nonetheless, Netscape and Microsoft vivify thedynamic ‘Net model, despite an imbalance with too little con-sensus between them. (Both pairs of quotes are presented inthe reverse order: shift to standardization, then to innovation.)

We should also notice that a zero price philosophy pro-foundly undergirds the proceedings. A torrent of innovationhas been necessary to fuel the development of the ‘Net and

112

12 Inter@ctive Week, Vol 4 (1997), No 11 (April 14), p 47.13 Almost a year later as the stand-off between DCOM and CORBA continuesto fester, the effect is sufficiently debilitating across the entire industry that In-tel has undertaken to negotiate a ‘middleware’ middle ground between thewarring sides. See InfoWorld, Vol 20 (1998), No 9 (March 2), pp 1, 3.14 Petros Kavassalis has spoken of “creative accumulation,” ibid.

Page 16: Microsoft vs Netscape - davidallen.org Policy.pdf · In this opposition, Netscape first carried the standard against Microsoft, with the “browser wars” setting off the tu-mult—Netscape’s

Web. Hackers make their code freely available for the pur-pose. Their interest is a better ‘Net. As an example, we have al-ready seen the case of Apache freeware for servers. This un-derlines the shift at the second inflection point: the commu-nity and its larger interests become the object of the consensusdecision, instead of individual gain from (positive) prices.

Finally, we turn to the conflict over generic top level do-main/gTLD names, to illustrate a last feature of the model.The IETF undertook to expand the number of gTLD’s, such as.com, also to change the regime for assigning names. To as-semble the necessary consensus, it consulted and brought intothe process a large number of actors. This included severalparties not ordinarily thought of as participants. Despite this,both the United States Government and the European Com-mission expressed public dissatisfaction with the process andoutcome.

The purpose of this case is to illustrate the expansion of thecommunity. Though the IETF is vastly inclusive, it is finally,of course, only a sub-community within a larger group. It is a(loose) hierarchy nested within a larger (loose) hierarchy—infact I will use ‘nest’ rather than ‘hierarchy,’ to signify theloose/tight flexibility of the bonds. In the gTLD case, theboundary would expand to bring inside those who had previ-ously been outside (or two groups may merge to form a newencompassing entity). Then the group’s implicit ground-rules—such as for handling disagreement, and for assemblingconsensus—are no longer shared among all parties.

The routine shifts between individual and group, which arecharacteristic of the cycle, also amount to an expansion andcontraction. But they take place within a given group, and sowith an implicitly shared set of behavioral protocols acrossthe cycle. In the expansion of the group itself, however, thegroundrules become indeterminate. Groundrules from theoriginal group collide with different groundrules held bythose outside the group. A new set of shared groundrules mayeventually emerge, for the merged sub-groups, but there is a“law of the jungle” in the interregnum. Dissatisfactions, suchas with the new gTLD’s and with the process surroundingthem, are a symptom.

113

Page 17: Microsoft vs Netscape - davidallen.org Policy.pdf · In this opposition, Netscape first carried the standard against Microsoft, with the “browser wars” setting off the tu-mult—Netscape’s

To summarize the model: At its core is a simple repeated itera-tion, between innovation and standardization. The behavioraland social implications may seem less simple. Individuals orindividual firms, promoting new ideas, repeatedly alternatetemporally with loose hierarchies of these same individuals,now harnessed to the work of the larger community with pur-suit of individual gain momentarily submerged. In this dy-namic characterization of industry, borders repeatedly shift inresponse to the on-going cycle between fragmentation and(re-)coalescence. Expansion of the community engaged in thecycle unsettles the shared social protocols, which are the glueholding together the process in the first place.

The foregoing is the model I see embedded within the de-velopment of the ‘Net, now Web. This dynamic model hasbeen pivotal, I suggest, in the extraordinary flow of innova-tions, successfully implemented. Besides the evidence of suc-cess, the model is self-confirming, through its internal norma-tive logic.

Now we can turn to the implications for industry structureand conduct; also to the raison d’être for the cycle, its output,namely, the ‘information product.’

2.1 Industry organization: model structureand conduct

What are the implications for industry organization, bothmodel structure and model conduct?

Conduct (individual and group)Industry participants are expected to interleave two oppositebehaviors temporally—competition, then consensus, and re-peatedly. First, in the innovation phase of the cycle, classic com-petition is essential to bring out and test the best new ideas. Asnoted, Microsoft’s competitive fervor, at least, is some sort ofideal.

Second, in the standardization phase, the opposite behavior isrequired. A constellation of behaviors make up a consensus.In a shift away from the individual and self-aggrand-izement—just for this phase of the cycle, of course—the focusturns to a better ‘Net and improving the lot of the group as a

114

Page 18: Microsoft vs Netscape - davidallen.org Policy.pdf · In this opposition, Netscape first carried the standard against Microsoft, with the “browser wars” setting off the tu-mult—Netscape’s

whole. This means an openness to new ideas from others—ac-cess for them—to enable the best result. So Netscape’s advo-cacy for inclusiveness is fundamental. To sift and meld con-testing innovations into the best standard requires that eachparticipant take an allotted part in the standards-makingloose hierarchy. An implicit set of group groundrules guidesthe behavior in the hierarchy.15 As evident from the standardsprocess, there is a conscious choosing of the best outcome.

With shared protocols across the group, at some level eachmember also engages in evolving forward the shared visionsof the ‘good’ ‘Net, the shared groundrules, and the shared ob-jectives overall.

StructureMimicking an accordion, the oscillating musical instrument,the dynamic industry structure alternately fragments to its at-oms, for the competition among new ideas; then re-gels intothe loose hierarchy—the nest—for consensus around a newstandard. This virtual industry organization is, at one point,disparate individual and corporate actors; then at a laterpoint, it becomes a loose group, transcending the individualand corporate borders and linking them inside a larger com-mon, if loose, border—borders are dynamic in the model.

Perhaps the single constant is the sharing of behavioral pro-tocols, the groundrules, across the whole group.

What of the notion of ‘openness’? Does everyday usage ofthe word denote and intend the intricacies of the foregoingdynamics? Is this what industry participants mean when theysay ‘open’? A recent example offers some evidence. Objec-tions heard during Apple’s forced end to Macintosh cloningseem clearly to plead for the importance of a community ofprotagonists, if the Macintosh platform is to have any hope.More than the ability to substitute one company’s machine foranother (certainly more than cross-platform operability), thesentiments expressed seem to recognize the primacy of an ‘in-clusive community.’ There was no reference to the detail gyra-tions used here to analyze the basic cycle, but there seems to

115

15 Sometimes the groundrules are even explicit, such as in FAQ´s about ac-ceptable behavior for IETF newcomers.

Page 19: Microsoft vs Netscape - davidallen.org Policy.pdf · In this opposition, Netscape first carried the standard against Microsoft, with the “browser wars” setting off the tu-mult—Netscape’s

be deep recognition of the competitive/cooperative tensionessential to a vibrant, ongoing enterprise of improvement.

The dynamic structure�graphicallyTo represent the dynamic model graphically, imagine athree-company industry, say, Microsoft, Netscape and oneother. In the innovation phase, the three actors are disparate.

Figure 1

The innovation phase [industry structure]

For the shift to the standardization phase, the three assem-ble into a loose hierarchy.

Figure 2

The cycle, innovation to standardization

116

Page 20: Microsoft vs Netscape - davidallen.org Policy.pdf · In this opposition, Netscape first carried the standard against Microsoft, with the “browser wars” setting off the tu-mult—Netscape’s

For the next cycle of innovation and standardization, thetwo phases repeat, and so on with each cycle.

Figure 3

The cycle, repeating

To visualize the expansion of community, the case ofgTLD’s for instance, we start from the two steps in the basicinnovation and standardization cycle, in other words webuild from Figure 2. For expansion of community, there is ef-fectively a third step, to bring in those who do not ordinarilyparticipate.

Figure 4

The expansion of community: Three levels

2.2 Information productA shared view—the information product—is a key resultfrom a group’s interaction. Each person has a different experi-ence of the world, and so sees phenomena of concern with aneye that has some privileged access. Information is a confec-tion that arises as the experiences of separate individuals aremingled together. Nor can the mingling be avoided; even theframeworks for thought—the categories into which raw per-ceptions are fitted—are a legacy of those who have come be-

117

Page 21: Microsoft vs Netscape - davidallen.org Policy.pdf · In this opposition, Netscape first carried the standard against Microsoft, with the “browser wars” setting off the tu-mult—Netscape’s

fore. The raw input is individual, but the resultant—informa-tion—is conjoint. Done right, the joint result is stronger, tak-ing advantage of each person’s different access to the realworld.

Of course a ‘strong’ information end product is the wholepoint of the dynamic alternations in the model, specificallythe model conduct and structure just reviewed—it is thewhole reason to foment and support this complex ritualacross time.

Open standards versus idea-vertical integration were thetwo extremes in Netscape against Microsoft. These two tem-plates for an information product implicitly argued, one forlooser integration among the logical parts, the other fortighter integration. Choosing where to fall between the twodetermines the number of points at which new variety may beintroduced—idea-vertical integration offers fewer points, andopen layering more points. (See the graphics immediately be-low.)

In fact neither open standards nor idea-vertical integrationproved to be a naturally correct choice. This is despite therhetoric for openness (not to be confused with inclusion).16 Afundamental thrust of this paper, of course, is to deconstructthe architecture of the information product from the industrybehaviors which produce it.

For an example that ‘open or vertical’ (in information prod-uct) is a choice and not normative, we saw how the-usually-castigated integration was in fact important for Sun with Java.Beyond that, both penalties and benefits have accrued to bothends of the loose/tight scale in logical structure; for example:

• Tighter integration—idea-vertical integration—could servebadly. We have seen already that Microsoft fought to keep

118

16 There is a pivotal case for the view that ‘open or vertical’ (again, in logicalstructure, not in organization) is a choice, and not dictated normatively: thatis the case in which vertical integration in logical structure is not incompatiblewith inclusion for industry organization. The original Apple model for ‘clo-ning’ its Macintosh was such a case. That Apple model carefully balanced in-puts from multiple industry participants with protection for the Mac’s hard-ware/software integration, a key to the Mac’s appeal. Though Apple’s clon-ing model has now failed, in fact was not ever fully implemented, it appearsclear that the reasons for failure were other than the practicability of themodel. This test case will have to be a discussion for another occasion, how-ever.

Page 22: Microsoft vs Netscape - davidallen.org Policy.pdf · In this opposition, Netscape first carried the standard against Microsoft, with the “browser wars” setting off the tu-mult—Netscape’s

its old Windows-based component architecture, OLE,though OLE is pretty widely seen not to rival even closely a“modern” alternative, such as OpenDoc. In fact, the Micro-soft juggernaut helped to kill OpenDoc. Outdated but verti-cally protected technology stopped a (much) better new al-ternative.

• Or, vertical integration could serve well. Sun’s Java was acase. The Microsoft Webtop we also saw to be such a case,where closer integration meant better performance. Thesame holds for ActiveX performance, because it is inte-grated with Windows. The hardware/software integratedMac is one of the most obvious cases.

• Open standards may offer benefits. The PC/Wintel openhardware platform, with many more points at which vari-ety may be introduced, has allowed the rapid introductionof some innovations.

• Or, open standards may perform less well. Microsoft strug-gles to keep a vertically-integrated software OS (Windows),in part as a response to the great difficulty presented by somany variations in the open hardware PC platform! Slowperformance by cross-platform Java is another case.

As these (implicitly 2x2) cells suggest, one of the trade-offsis between the performance which idea-vertical integrationmay bring as against opportunity for more innovation at moreentry points with the opposite. In turn, the degree to whichthe performance of a given technology benefits from idea-vert-ical integration—the “system-ness” of the technology, wemight say—becomes a parameter. This just sketches the com-plexity of the choice.

Where to land on the choices between open and verticallogical structure, including when and how to shift the mix, isone of the most important decisions. It is high on the agendaof the consensus decision-taking in the second phase of the cy-cle.

Both industry organization and its information product be-come looser or tighter hierarchies, with variety nested atlower levels. For the industry organization, that is in the con-

119

Page 23: Microsoft vs Netscape - davidallen.org Policy.pdf · In this opposition, Netscape first carried the standard against Microsoft, with the “browser wars” setting off the tu-mult—Netscape’s

catenated communities and sub-communities into which thegroup fragments and alternately rejoins. For the informationproduct, that is the looser or tighter logical structures, and thegreater or lesser variety enabled. It is this which brings themodel, and its analysis, real complexity.

Since industry organization and its information product areboth looser/tighter hierarchies, both can be described by thesame analytic graphics. The above graphic which portrays thedynamics (see Figure 4 on page 117, the fullest, three-stage dia-gram) effectively illustrates the concatenation of variety atlevels in the organizational ‘nests.’ Earlier, or disaggregated,stages display variety which subsequently is subsumed atlater, or higher, stages (for a given cycle). (And now we canalso notice that only the relevant variety is subsumed into anew standard; other variety continues to persist at the disag-gregated layer.)

If we switch to a more typical static view, the layering of va-riety in an information product will be more obviously on dis-play. Here I use the convention that a pyramid may representa [static] hierarchy. To convert from the dynamic stages in thegraphic above to a static pyramid, each of the three stagesabove becomes a layer in a pyramided stack. Each stage is asuccessively higher aggregation, across time. To convert tothe static view, and so omit a time dimension, the first stageabove becomes the foundation layer, the second stage/aggre-gation the second layer, and so on (with the largest aggrega-tion converting, perhaps unintuitively, to the narrowestlayer).

Figure 5

Looser/tighter hierarchy: Static view

120

Page 24: Microsoft vs Netscape - davidallen.org Policy.pdf · In this opposition, Netscape first carried the standard against Microsoft, with the “browser wars” setting off the tu-mult—Netscape’s

For the information product, looser coupling among the lay-ers—‘open layering’—allows more points at which new vari-ety may be introduced. Tighter coupling—idea-vertical inte-gration—offers fewer points.

Figure 6a Figure 6bOpen layering Idea-vertical integration

Open vs vertical and access for innovation

In fact, both the dynamic and the static graphics character-ize both loose/tight hierarchies (notwithstanding that one orthe other graphic fits more closely our predilections for or-ganization or for its information product)—this because dy-namic or static, both describe the same thing analytically, onlyfrom different views. A single analytic device characterizesindustry organization and its information product.

To summarize overall: A key function of the industry organ-izational dynamics is to choose an information product. Ana-lytically, both the organizational dynamics and the informa-tion product entail the same interplay between whole andpart, as a central feature. When viewed dynamically [for or-ganization], across time the interplay between whole and partjuxtaposes variety, the trace left by innovation, against com-monalties necessary for a standard (other variety continues topersist at ‘lower’ levels in the nest). When viewed as a staticslice across the time stream [for information product], we canchoose the relative number of points at which the variety frominnovation may enter, as against performance of the technol-ogy system.

121

Page 25: Microsoft vs Netscape - davidallen.org Policy.pdf · In this opposition, Netscape first carried the standard against Microsoft, with the “browser wars” setting off the tu-mult—Netscape’s

Part twoTheory and policy

3 The model and prevailing theoryHow does this new model comport with prevailing views?The bluntest comparison is with neoclassical views. There isalso one observation about evolutionary economics. The notesbelow intend just to prepare the ground for a comparison.

3.1 Comparisons with the neoclassical viewpointThe neoclassical position is founded on the individual, and in-dividual action. This new model treats the individual in acommunity. The neoclassical position is wary at best of socialties, particularly the threat that group power may overwhelmindividual choice. The new model celebrates social ties—forthe ‘better’ shared information;17 but underlying that, for thepower of social ties18 to lift joint performance.19

But to say, as I do above, that “the community and its largerinterests become the object of the consensus decision” invitesneoclassical exasperation at defining the ‘community inter-est.’20 Thoughtful neoclassicists have created the lively litera-

122

17 Though, stalwart neoclassicists also appreciate shared information. I amindebted to Don Lamberton for bringing to my attention Kenneth Arrow onthe subject (“Some ordinalist-utilitarian notes on Rawls’s Theory of justice,”in The Journal of Philosophy, Vol 70 (1973), No 9 (May), pp 245–263). A phrasefrom Don’s note to me captures it most succinctly: Arrow especially applaudsRawls's Theory of Justice for arguing the “importance of the ‘natural comple-mentarity’ amongst people because no one has all information.” The Austrianschool also takes the assembly of shared information as a major departure.Perhaps ironically, the view is commonly considered staunchly conservative,with laissez faire producing an ”autonomous, decentralized, non-bureaucratic information system.” The seminal work is Friedrich A Hayek,The road to serfdom, Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1944. (My apprecia-tion to Marcellus Snow for his guidance about the Austrian school.)18 Hierarchy is of course one element in the Coase/Williamson school ofwork.19 For instance in the case above, re objections to the forced end of Macintoshcloning.

Page 26: Microsoft vs Netscape - davidallen.org Policy.pdf · In this opposition, Netscape first carried the standard against Microsoft, with the “browser wars” setting off the tu-mult—Netscape’s

ture on [not] comparing preferences; but the shared notion ofcommunity seeks an analytic approach which will be fash-ioned anew, expressly for the purpose.

The prospect for group dominance is more than athreat—the news headlines daily remind us of human nature.But humans operate in groups—exclusively in groups. Virtu-ally all our proudest achievements have depended in someway on group ties. Certainly, today’s complex innovations de-pend intimately on close human interaction, and always a mixof the push and the pull. Economics is a science of aggre-gates—it seems appropriate to try and incorporate that mostfateful of aggregates, the human group. To deal explicitlywith the power of the group is essential. That is why the sharedethic of group behavior—here, the mandates around industryconduct and structure—plays a central role in this thinking.The embedded power-sharing is carefully balanced. Otherpower outcomes are possible, even prevalent; but if we are tograsp the essence, we had better start with the productiveform.

An adequate characterization in this model becomes a littlecomplex, to represent experience with some fidelity—but it isno more complex than the daily reality of all economic activ-ity. And the IETF process for developing the ‘Net indulgesthis complexity with stunning results—and seeming effort-lessly!

What are the “primitive” assumptions, the bedrock? The ob-jective function is speed and quality of innovations incorpo-rated.21 Does the model falter, if this is suspended? A more so-phisticated treatment, for another occasion, would makemore explicit the group evolution of objective function.

Will the model extend to non-networked industries?Though hardly a question for this paper, I believe we can lookto another question and its answer: Will the quintessentialnetwork industry, telecommunications, become a ‘normal’ in-dustry? Yes—in that the ‘normal’ industries will prove tohave the characteristics essential to network industries whengroup dynamics are incorporated into the analysis.22

123

20 My balance between individual and community is of course not collectiv-ism. Though not for this paper, I have in other places scrupulously workedout nominal group phenomena in terms of individual action.

Page 27: Microsoft vs Netscape - davidallen.org Policy.pdf · In this opposition, Netscape first carried the standard against Microsoft, with the “browser wars” setting off the tu-mult—Netscape’s

3.2 Evolutionary economics and the selectionenvironment

This paper is of course implicitly in the tradition of evolution-ary economics. Though a bit self-reflective, there is one obser-vation.

Defining the selection environment is an interesting ques-tion. The new model makes it even more interesting. Oncegroup choice is recognized, what may previously have beenseen as a selection environment can shape itself proactively,both the human and tool-based environments.

4 PolicyNetwork—for which currently read telecommunica-tions—policy is headed massively in the direction of competi-tion. This model is clear about an alternation between compe-tition and consensus (with no diminution of the importance ofcompetition, [though competition in the model focusesamong ideas, not commodities]).

In the model, a group “picks winners,” to which those whoeschew industrial policy would object strenuously. The keypoint, however, is that the correct layer of ‘private govern-ment’ is identified to do the ‘picking’—in the ‘Net case, that isthe IETF ‘layer.’ The conceptualization as concatenated hier-archy, or nest, provides new tools for identifying who/whatlayer appropriately chooses. Rather than a blunt divide be-tween government and private sector, there is a gradation oflevels each of which has a distinctive sphere of competence.

Anti-trust and intellectual property rights are two policy ar-eas where the impact of the new model is particularly plain.

124

21 However, see footnote 11.22 Further to be noted: It is not uncommon to equate standards with neoclas-sical scale economies. The notion of scale is often taken in a narrow sense, dis-tilled essentially to a continuing decline in costs. Because the standards phe-nomenon is multi-faceted, certainly involving organization among others (asdescribed), I have not chosen to invoke neoclassical scale as a descriptor.

Page 28: Microsoft vs Netscape - davidallen.org Policy.pdf · In this opposition, Netscape first carried the standard against Microsoft, with the “browser wars” setting off the tu-mult—Netscape’s

4.1 Anti-trustThe root proposition for anti-trust holds that corporate sizemust not be allowed to become dominant. Otherwise in thisview, size will be used to disadvantage other actors (withdeleterious effect economically). This proceeds, of course,from neoclassical protection for the individual and freedom ofmovement. In contrast the model here, which has producedsuch successful innovation, holds that it is crucial to use thepower of the group—not just of some large company, but ofthe entire group. But the point is to use that power produc-tively.

Lying behind these contrasting models seem to be two di-vergent conceptions of human nature. One extols self-interest,even avarice; the other sees self-interest set in the social con-text. In fact, the protocols into which we are socialized mayemphasize one outcome or the other—what we get is to someextent what we preach and ask for. Evidence in the casesabove makes clear that both outcomes are possible, interest-ingly even within the same US culture.

How does the model modify traditional anti-trust? Two ba-sic differences are worth inspection, alongside the many de-tails.

First, the concern in the model is not size, but behavior. Themodel relies on relatively sophisticated social protocols,which allow for fluid transversal of the cycle, between self-interest and shared objectives, repeatedly. How is a “spoiler”handled, the actor who transgresses the protocol?23 TheAmish in the US for instance use ‘shunning’—the exclusion ofthe offender from usual social perquisites—and so do all so-cial groups, in one way or another. (Recent treatment of Sad-dam Hussein in Iraq is just another example.) That illustratesthe role of informal social processes, over the relative formal-ity of judicial systems.

Does size matter? Yes, both in that the power of the wholegroup is needed for successful outcomes and in that the atom-ized individual actor is also cherished for the creativity of un-

125

23 For a more detailed treatment of this and other previous topics here, seemy “Beyond competition : where are we in the dialog about policy for tele-communications?” in Lamberton, D (ed), Beyond competition. Amsterdam: El-sevier, 1995.

Page 29: Microsoft vs Netscape - davidallen.org Policy.pdf · In this opposition, Netscape first carried the standard against Microsoft, with the “browser wars” setting off the tu-mult—Netscape’s

fettered impulse. Perhaps most to the point, the joining ofideas, not the joining of people into relatively inflexible‘merged’ organizations, is the objective. The creativity of thesmaller group, with equal ability temporarily to join otherswhen indicated, is the model of course.

Second, the focal scenario is dynamic, not the static concep-tion of a relatively frozen ‘market.’ The furor between Micro-soft and the US Department of Justice, over whether thebrowser Internet Explorer is part of Windows 95, amply illus-trates. Object-oriented software design only recapitulates thejuxtaposition between part and whole, which we have seenunderlies useful understanding of organization and ofidea-vertical integration.24 Explorer, as an accumulation of ob-jects ‘in’ Windows, is a part which is to be understood relativeto a whole. Only when we take a dynamic view do we see thatit may be both a separate part and part of the whole, depend-ing on where we are in the basic organizational cycle.

Rather than caught in a conundrum which serves really nouseful purpose, trying to parse Explorer re Windows in astatic world,25 we might take a dynamic view, which insteadgives a framework to take sensible steps. Then we can bendourselves to the real, hard work of sorting out choices for theExplorer/Windows information product (among others), be-tween vertical and open.

PracticeWhat are the practical implications for policy? A quite signifi-cant change is indicated, obviously. An ‘ideal,’ up-and-working new regime is one topic; requirements for transitionis another.

A new regime requires (quite) different institutions. Ratherthan an approach in which compliance is forced from outside,by some policing agency such as the US Department of Justiceor other competition authority, the outcomes depend on inter-nalized protocols of conduct. The pivotal institutions are theloose hierarchies, such as the IETF. In fact, a given hierarchy

126

24 I am grateful to John Markoff for reminding me of the object-oriented de-sign. See for instance his New York Times article, March 2, 1998, p D5.25 Or the equally hollow conundrum: Microsoft is a predating monopolist,but sets [bad] standards that are necessary.

Page 30: Microsoft vs Netscape - davidallen.org Policy.pdf · In this opposition, Netscape first carried the standard against Microsoft, with the “browser wars” setting off the tu-mult—Netscape’s

or group must be able to find common ground with othersuch groups; that means that even looser aggregations, at‘higher’ levels, finally extend up to what we ordinarily thinkof as government (so the ‘expansion of community,’ earlier, isactually necessary for coherence across a society—a topictouched again below). Early socialization is the real source ofthe behavioral outcomes which are the focus of a dynamic ap-proach.

Are there difficulties deciding whether a given behavior is a‘good’ consensus or an abuse of the group’s power? Of course.(Schisms internationally over how to treat Saddam Husseinare also a useful illustration of such problems in more infor-mal systems.) Do our present anti-trust regimes also fail tostop predation? The answer seems decidedly to be yes. Thequestion is which process can work effectively.

From the cases above, it is clear that the new model canwork remarkably well. All social groups come equipped withinternal policing mechanisms, in some form. Gunnar Eliassonhas suggested an encapsulation: that in this policy we do notallow “predation of the family.” That is the succinct summary,I think (with thanks to Gunnar). Then we ask about our abilityto mobilize those devices, when the participants may startfrom (very) different cultures, in a globalizing world.

Transition is another large topic. Ultimately, the emphasishas to be on early socialization. Immediately, there would beacute problems with the ‘spoilers’ who already have huge po-sitions and have no intention of abandoning their style. ‘Shun-ning’ in this case could take very large proportions, such asnot buying from internal company units which were not al-lowed the freedoms endemic to the innovation phase of thecycle,26 even removing offending magnates.

The implications are too blasphemous, generally, to be con-sidered—except that we are addicted to the success of justsuch a policy model for the dynamics of innovation. Are thepolicy dictates too fanciful to be taken seriously?

127

26 An extreme case would be an (unacceptably unfreed) internal unit whichsells a popular OS. Then the ‘shun’ would entail shifting to purchase an alter-nate OS, rather than buying from that unit—with all the profound economicramifications.

Page 31: Microsoft vs Netscape - davidallen.org Policy.pdf · In this opposition, Netscape first carried the standard against Microsoft, with the “browser wars” setting off the tu-mult—Netscape’s

FundamentalsConstantly shifting organizational borders are hard to squarewith notions about firm identity, for instance. Consider the‘social architecture’ which underlies the experience each of ushas every day (and also underlies the analysis of the model,above). We are each members of several different‘groups’—family, work, play, perhaps religion and so forth.For any group we have membership in a widening set of con-centric circles, with the bonds looser as the circle widens—atwork, for instance, the most intent links are typically with thework group, but there may also be affiliation with a division,the company, even the industry. (The axes through the centersof each set of concentric circles—family, work and soforth—may overlap to some extent, but they will also be sig-nificantly orthogonal.)

Many times during the day, for any of the several groups,each person first exercises judgment based on membership ina circle of given scope (the work group, say), then may imme-diately shift to consider a question for a wider or narrower cir-cle (the industry, for instance). Daily experience reproducesconstantly shifting borders, our preconceptions notwith-standing.

Actually to sanction the power of the group, then to managethat informally rather than through strict rule-based proce-dures, seems to ignore, even threatens to trample cherishedicons in our (Western) ideology. In the Asian financial crisisthe regime in Indonesia has been held up as illustrating the ex-cesses of ‘crony capitalism,’ when the Indonesian constitutionenshrines the family as a model for economic policy-making.27

With the net wealth of Suharto’s ruling family thought to be inthe same league as Bill Gates’ ($30 billion and beyond), con-cern about informal mechanisms and about trusting a group’suse of power does have to be taken seriously.

The discussion here can only frame a dialog on these twofundamentals, to be taken up later. The arguments favoringthe novel model—dramatic productivity enhancements—areclear; it is the concomitants which may give pause. Let’s be

128

27 The 1945 Indonesian Constitution holds that, “The economy shall be or-ganized as a common endeavor based upon the principle of the family sys-tem.”

Page 32: Microsoft vs Netscape - davidallen.org Policy.pdf · In this opposition, Netscape first carried the standard against Microsoft, with the “browser wars” setting off the tu-mult—Netscape’s

plain about the main elements; then we can ask how differentthey are from actual practice today:

Some coherence is maintained between ‘higher’ and‘lower’ layers, ultimately throughout a society.Equally, there is opportunity for entry by new—dis-senting—ideas. This is the essential, careful ten-sion—coherence and, at the same time, entry for thenovel idea—carried forward by agreed social proto-cols. The protocols are maintained by active ‘jawbo-ning,’ including shunning for spoilers (those whowould spoil the process; ‘spoiling’ a soon-to-be-outmoded idea is indicated of course). Care is taken todistinguish the inclusion of voices with new ideas fromthe choices to be made about the degree of integrationfor a given system—including individuals and choos-ing technology are not to be confused with each other.

Then a Microsoft is expected—not to wrest the control ofstandards to itself—but to join with the community, bringingits contribution alongside others and taking its part in thechoices. For an example (again), the IETF has been remarkablygood at keeping the use of power exercised by the group trust-worthy. The difficulties arise at the ‘higher’ layers, wheremore tenuous ties (with implicitly greater differences at the[submerged] ‘lower’ layers) make consensus a greater chal-lenge. Despite the intrusion of some hierarchy, this regimeseems hard to distinguish from cherished notions of democ-racy. How different, in the end, is the maintenance of (theseprocedural) ‘informal social protocols’ from the evolution oflaw in formal judicial systems? Which is the more robust?(Steps for an Indonesia which has got off-track will open,hopefully, to the dialog which should be framed here forlater.)

4.2 Intellectual property rightsThere have recently in the US been two interesting lawsuitsabout Web content. Both concerned information—Web

129

Page 33: Microsoft vs Netscape - davidallen.org Policy.pdf · In this opposition, Netscape first carried the standard against Microsoft, with the “browser wars” setting off the tu-mult—Netscape’s

pages—that one service had “linked” from another service. Inone suit, a group of newspapers objected to their site contentbeing linked by another news service. In the other, Ticketmas-ter sued Microsoft for linking in a fashion that bypassed Tick-etmaster’s home page.

We have already seen how the hackers who largely createdthe ‘Net and Web operate with freeware and typically disre-gard their intellectual property rents. The Web’s fundamen-tal, distinguishing quality—its hypertext links, which tie oneset of information to another—is orthogonal to the usual ten-ets of intellectual property rights/IPR.28 Elements of informa-tion, rather than being strictly compartmentalized as to onesource or another, are linked, much in the way that individualideas also connect in human cognition.

That is the parallel with individual thought; if we analogizewith the social production of information: The architecture ofhyperlinking recapitulates the creation of the informationproduct, where each person’s separate ideas may also contrib-ute to a larger, joint whole. In hypertext linking, the loose de-pendence between whole and part, each upon the other, isperhaps nowhere clearer. The two lawsuits only begin tobring to the surface the inherent conflict between IPR and realworld complexities of information which the Web can finallyspin.

How does the model impinge on the regime of intellectualproperty rights? In basic terms, IPR is inflexible relative to thedynamics endemic to the model. Also, the control in IPR issituated with the individual, rather than socially. Finally, thesocial context essential to innovation is underplayed or miss-ing entirely. IPR does protect the individual’s pivotal role increativity.29 Can we operate without IPR? John Perry Barlow30

argues that authors’ incomes will actually rise, absent rent-accumulating intermediaries in the distribution chain.

130

28 For a classic treatment of IPR, see Kenneth Arrow, “Economic welfare andthe allocation of resources for inventions,” in Nelson, R (ed), The rate and direc-tion of inventive activity: economic and social factors. Princeton: Princeton Uni-versity Press, 1962, pp 602–627.29 A full treatment of the question is in my “Intellectual property rights : anevolutionary reappraisal,” in Lamberton, D (ed), Communication & trade :essays in honor of Meheroo Jussawalla. Creskill NJ: Hampton Press, forthcoming.30 See for instance http://www.eff.org/~barlow.

Page 34: Microsoft vs Netscape - davidallen.org Policy.pdf · In this opposition, Netscape first carried the standard against Microsoft, with the “browser wars” setting off the tu-mult—Netscape’s

But more profound are the implications for social and eco-nomic organization which arise, once the shortcomings of IPRare confronted. Rather than reward an individual with over-flowing rents, for a big ‘hit,’ benefits would be spread amongthe entire social group. By raising the basic questions aboutproperty itself,31 the implications for economic organization,for ‘making a living,’ become fundamental. To pursue a dia-log about a future intellectual property rights regime, I believethe focus needs to be on actual practice among those whowould espouse the new model: namely, there is both attribu-tion (to individual authors) for ‘good’ ideas and a sense ofshared ownership of the resultant information product.

For both theory and policy, a single thread underliesthe new model. That is a back-and-forth, a tension, analternation between order and its opposite, whether wewant to call that opposite by the name disorder, chaos,non-structure or use another label. We find this tensionthroughout. In industry structure: hierarchical formand inchoate atomization alternate to provide both forthe stable agreements which are necessary and for theflights of creative fancy which are equally necessary. Inindustry conduct: fidelity to agreed norms alternateswith self-propelled choices for innovative directions. Inthe underlying, basic cycle—and in its information‘product’: the order of standards alternates with a free-form for innovation—the ideas themselves are alter-nately congealed with the consensus and made fluidfor independent, creative thinking.

We might speculate that some order is essential to gain theadvantages of its opposite: that innovation flowers whenthose who would create also have some stable footing fromwhich to launch. That parallels a ‘market place’ set within amore ordered context or ‘level playing field.’ However we dospeculate, which later we then need test, the implicationsacross both theory and policy are unmistakable.32

131

31 Wherein important classes of real property are, alongside intangibles suchas information, also ‘both-shared-and-individual.’

Page 35: Microsoft vs Netscape - davidallen.org Policy.pdf · In this opposition, Netscape first carried the standard against Microsoft, with the “browser wars” setting off the tu-mult—Netscape’s

One of the most remarkable runs in the annals of innovationhas apparently been the product of a novel model for industryorganization. With dynamic borders and alternating behav-iors, the model stands at some variance from the prevailingviews. But it builds, or tries to anyway, faithfully upon the un-derlying human experience. At stake in our choice of suchmodels are the productivity and standards of living for oursocieties.

132

32 A conversation with Bertil Thorngren, during a respite between ITS delib-erations and the Calgary conference, brought out how pervasive is the alter-nation between order and its opposite, particularly as he traced through hisprior analysis of the phenomenon in the practicalities of managing an organi-zation.

Page 36: Microsoft vs Netscape - davidallen.org Policy.pdf · In this opposition, Netscape first carried the standard against Microsoft, with the “browser wars” setting off the tu-mult—Netscape’s

The Limits ofGovernment

On Policy Competence andEconomic Growth

Papers from the Sixth Conference of theInternational Joseph A Schumpeter Society in

Stockholm

David AllenFredrik Bergström

Jean-Philipe BonardiRichard H Day

Erik GørtzErik Moberg

Karl Heinrich OppenländerBertrand Quélin

Andrew ReedClas Wihlborg

Editors:Gunnar Eliasson & Nils Karlson

CityU N I V E R S I T Y P R E S S

Page 37: Microsoft vs Netscape - davidallen.org Policy.pdf · In this opposition, Netscape first carried the standard against Microsoft, with the “browser wars” setting off the tu-mult—Netscape’s

The City University Press is the publishing house of the CityUniversity of Stockholm, a small private university engagedin research and teaching in social sciences. The CUPpublishes research at the City University and from otherresearch institutions as well as classical titles. Focus is oninnovative new research of relevance to the economic, social,and constitutional development of society.

The City University Press publishes in Swedish and inEnglish. The City University Press encourages an opendialogue between the authors and readers. E-mail isforwarded to the authors.

City University PressP O Box 5095SE-102 42 Stockholm, Swedenphone +46-8-587 054 00fax +46-8-587 054 05e-mail [email protected]://www.cityuniv.se

© 1998 the authors and Stiftelsen City-universitetetPrinted at Fingraf, Södertälje, 1998ISBN 91-7562-083-9

Page 38: Microsoft vs Netscape - davidallen.org Policy.pdf · In this opposition, Netscape first carried the standard against Microsoft, with the “browser wars” setting off the tu-mult—Netscape’s

ContentsACKNOWLEDGEMENTS 8

FOREWORD 11

INTRODUCTION

The state as a supporter ordisorganizer of themarket economy 13Gunnar Eliasson and Nils Karlson

PART I THEORIES OF STATE INTERFERENCE

I An evolutionary theory ofdemocratic capitalism 33Richard H Day

II The expanding public sector—athreat to democracy? 45Erik Moberg

III The role of enabling and mandatorycompany law for financial systemsefficiency 69Clas Wihlborg

Page 39: Microsoft vs Netscape - davidallen.org Policy.pdf · In this opposition, Netscape first carried the standard against Microsoft, with the “browser wars” setting off the tu-mult—Netscape’s

PART II CONSEQUCENCES OF STATEINTERFERENCE AND NON-INTERFERENCE

IV Microsoft vs Netscape—policy fordynamic modelsAnti-trust and intellectual propertyrights revisited 99David Allen

V Regulatory body, rent-seeking andmarket activitiesThe case of telecommunications in Europe 133Jean-Philippe Bonardi and Bertrand Quélin

VI Russia’s agrarian dilemmaThe legacy of an economy without innovation,entrepreneurs or market competition 181Andrew N Reed

VI Private and public expenditures andthe Faeroese business cycle 235Erik Gørtz

VIII Problems in assisting new businessstart-ups in Germany 253Karl Heinrich Oppenländer

IX Do public capital subsidies to firmsincrease employment? 269Fredrik Bergström

THE AUTHORS 293

INDEX 295

Page 40: Microsoft vs Netscape - davidallen.org Policy.pdf · In this opposition, Netscape first carried the standard against Microsoft, with the “browser wars” setting off the tu-mult—Netscape’s

Acknowledgements

The Sixth Biennial Conference of the InternationalSchumpeter Society was held in Stockholm, June 2–5,1996. The Conference drew a record number of submis-

sions and participants. In all more than 100 papers were pre-sented. This volume, entitled The limits of government, is a setof nine essays drawn from some 30 papers presented at theConference related to the role of government in economicgrowth. A set of 22 essays have been published seperately inanother volume entitled The microfoundations of economicgrowth : a Shumpeterian perspective, by the University of Michi-gan Press.

The Conference was made possible by a generous grantfrom the Marcus Wallenberg Foundation for InternationalScientific Cooperation and from several Swedish corpora-tions. Because of the generosity of the Swedish State Railways(Statens Järnvägar), some sessions were conducted on a con-ference train between Falun and Stora. Stora, the world’s old-est corporation, a mining and forestry firm founded in 1288,hosted the society’s General Assembly. We are grateful to theCity of Stockholm for the magnificent reception in the CityHall on the opening day. To the members of the ScientificCommittee and to the persons who handled local organizing,notably Monica Hamrén, Christina Carlsson, Staffan Laesta-dius, and Per Storm, we wish to say thanks for a job well done.Finally, we wish to thank Erik Kristow and Wera Nyren foreditorial and secretarial services in the preparation of this vol-ume on the role of government.

8

Page 41: Microsoft vs Netscape - davidallen.org Policy.pdf · In this opposition, Netscape first carried the standard against Microsoft, with the “browser wars” setting off the tu-mult—Netscape’s

The following firms and institutions contributed to the SixthConference of the International Joseph A Schumpeter Society.

ALMI Företagspartner

ASTRA

ABB

ERICSSON

OM-Börsen

PERSTORP

The SAAB Group

Statens Järnvägar

SCANIA

STORA

TELIA

Other contributors include:

The Marcus Wallenberg Foundation for InternationalScientific Cooperation

The City of Stockholm

The Industrial Institute for Economicand Social Research (IUI)

9

Page 42: Microsoft vs Netscape - davidallen.org Policy.pdf · In this opposition, Netscape first carried the standard against Microsoft, with the “browser wars” setting off the tu-mult—Netscape’s

Foreword

There is no way to understand how an economy at largebehaves without taking a close look at the actors whomake it behave. There is no way to understand the

agents operating in markets without placing them in the con-text of the institutions that determine the incentives that pull,and the competition that pushes them in different directionsand together co-ordinate all actors into a fairly consistentmacro-economic whole. This also means that successfulpolicy-making, whether directed at the macro or micro levelsof the economy, demands insights on the part of the policy-maker that go far beyond what mainstream economic theoryis capable of providing.

The Sixth Conference of the International Joseph A Schum-peter Society, June 2–5, 1996, in Stockholm was arranged bythe Royal Institute of Technology, in collaboration with theCity University of Stockholm. The theme of the Conferencewas “The Microfoundations of Economic Growth.” Thenumber of papers submitted and accepted for presentationwas larger than ever before. Two volumes from the Confer-ence are therefore being published.1

Many interesting and excellent papers presented at the Con-ference focused on the role of institutions, notably govern-ment, in economic growth. The most interesting of these pa-pers are collected in this volume.

Stockholm in February 1998

Gunnar EliassonRoyal Institute of TechnologyPresident of the Joseph A Schumpeter Society 1995/1996

Nils KarlsonPresident of the City University of Stockholm

11

1 One volume with the title The microfoundations of economic growth, editedby Gunnar Eliasson and Christopher Green with the assistance of CharlesMcCann, is published by the University of Michigan Press 1998.

Page 43: Microsoft vs Netscape - davidallen.org Policy.pdf · In this opposition, Netscape first carried the standard against Microsoft, with the “browser wars” setting off the tu-mult—Netscape’s

Introduction

The State as a Supporter orDisorganizer of the Market

EconomyGunnar Eliasson & Nils Karlson

GUNNAR ELIASSONThe Royal Institute of Technology,SE-100 44 Stockholm, Sweden,phone +46 8 790 68 03, fax +46 8 622 69 14,e-mail [email protected]

NILS KARLSONThe City University of Stockholm,P O Box 5095, SE-102 42 Stockholm, Sweden,phone +46 8 587 054 01, fax +46 8 587 054 05,e-mail [email protected]

13

Page 44: Microsoft vs Netscape - davidallen.org Policy.pdf · In this opposition, Netscape first carried the standard against Microsoft, with the “browser wars” setting off the tu-mult—Netscape’s

The limits of government and the consequences of gov-ernment interference in markets for economic growthare the central themes in this collection of papers from

the Sixth Conference of the International Joseph A Schum-peter Society in Stockholm, June 2–5, 1996. Theoretical as wellas case-oriented empirical studies are included. When andwhy does government interference in the market process suc-ceed and when and why does it fail?

For obvious reasons the selected papers do not cover all ofthis field, but the authors have been asked to revise their pa-pers to fit the overall theme. And with this introduction weare also trying to fill in missing links to the extent possible.

Actors in markets need various forms of support: legal, so-cial and moral. Institutions or infrastructures such as these arepart of all functioning market economies and are necessaryfor economic progress. Even though neglected for years bythe economics profession and the growth theorists, theirstudy is a must for anyone with the ambition to understandeconomic growth. Such institutions can be public or private,including the externalities emanating from the joint actions ofall actors in the economy.

Collective infrastructures and other institutions facilitateexchange outside equilibrium (Day 1986) and as such contrib-ute significally to the wealth of nations. But the same infra-structures can also operate as negative externalities and con-strain and inhibit important market activities. In a sense allsuch infrastructures have emerged in response to a demand,government being only one among many market actors initi-ating the establishment of infrastructures or externalities inthe economy. The volume includes several papers suggestingthat a reduction of government would benefit the economy,notably in areas where market arbitrage exhibits clear advan-tages over policy control or regulation in allocating resources,and where policy-makers lack the necessary competence tocontribute positively to economic development. The processof the establishment of infrastructures, their composition andthe outcome of their influence on the economy, therefore, arean important area of scientific inquiry.

In particular, this volume focuses on the supporting collec-tive institutions of the market processes, including the role of

14

Page 45: Microsoft vs Netscape - davidallen.org Policy.pdf · In this opposition, Netscape first carried the standard against Microsoft, with the “browser wars” setting off the tu-mult—Netscape’s

big government. The selection of papers can be seen as com-plementary to a first volume from the Stockholm Conference,The microfoundations of economic growth (Gunnar Eliasson &Christopher Green (eds), University of Michigan Press, 1998).

One question addressed in this volume is the lack of neces-sary institutions, and why market incentives and/or govern-ment action fail to establish them. This is typically the situa-tion in the formerly planned East European economies. An-other question concerns the overestablishment of infrastruc-tures and institutions, notably by government origin, that hin-ders or even blocks economic progress, i e when the stateturns into a disorganizer of the market economy. This is oftenthe case in pronounced welfare economies (Karlson 1993,Karlson 1995, Eliasson 1998).

In the tradition of Joseph Schumpeter, notably his Capital-ism, socialism and democracy (1942), society is composed of ac-tors and institutions which partly reinforce and partly conflictwith each other and the economy at large. This line of reason-ing from a theoretical point of view dominates the chapters inPart I of the book: “Theories of state interference.”

Democracy, as argued by Richard Day in Chapter I, can be anecessary and efficient institution to resolve and soften socialinstabilities caused by efficient market behavior. The same in-stitutions, if not properly organized, argues Erik Moberg inChapter II, may also lead to an excessive expansion of thepublic sector and long-term economic inefficiency. To make itworse, it may also cause an institutional (or political) lock-inthat is almost impossible to get out of through a democraticprocess (also see Chapter VI by Reed, Karlson 1993, Eliasson1986). While the first volume from the 1996 Schumpeter Con-ference (Eliasson & Green 1998) looked at technological lock-ins, we are here concerned with the incidence of possible par-allel institutional lock-ins.

Is there a way out of such an unfortunate situation? Howcan institutional trimming or creative institutional destruc-tion be organized in the welfare economies of the West? ClasWihlborg, in Chapter III, discusses the introduction of ena-bling law as one possible institutional innovation that mayhelp distressed welfare economies and East European econo-mies out of their institutional lock-ins. However, it is far from

15

Page 46: Microsoft vs Netscape - davidallen.org Policy.pdf · In this opposition, Netscape first carried the standard against Microsoft, with the “browser wars” setting off the tu-mult—Netscape’s

clear that the necessary incentives and the relevant politicalcompetence for such a change are at hand.

While the individual actors in the market can pursue indi-vidual gains with a fair probability of success, his or her ef-forts in the political system (in the political market), as notedby Schumpeter (1942, p 261), are far less likely to contribute tohis or her personal well-being. As “a member of an unwork-able committee, the committee of the whole nation, and this iswhy he expends less disciplined effort on mastering a politicalproblem than he expends on a game of bridge … the typicalcitizen drops down to a lower level of mental performance assoon as he enters the political field.”

In fact, it may be far more profitable for the individual to actrationally in the political market by pursuing personal rentsoffered by vote-seeking politicians, while at the same time op-timally allocating his or her income in the real markets forgoods and services. If the political system is so organized as tomake these two rational individual decisions inconsistent thepolitical process may create strong internal tensions in theeconomy (Eliasson 1986a,b), which are inflationary and mayeventually be socially disruptive. This is in fact very likely tobe the case, looking at Moberg’s analysis in Chapter II.

While economic theory has conventionally conferred a su-pervising role of the markets to the government to minimizemarket failure, the theory has consistently failed to recognizethat unique and scarce competence is required for that moni-toring. Hence, mistaken identification of market failureand/or inconsequent policy action to correct for politicallyperceived market failure and/or inconsequent policy actionto correct for actual market failure, may result in governmentfailure, most likely on a grander scale than the market failuresupposed to have been corrected.

Part II of the book focuses on empirical issues: “Conse-quences of state interference and non-interference.”

Governments can act on the economy in two capacities; (1)modestly, by reforming the institutions and circumstances con-ditioning the behavior of the market actors and (2) ambitiouslyand dangerously, by attempting to influence the actual out-comes of the market processes. Most chapters address “type(1)” policy, as was the design of the Conference. Most evi-

16

Page 47: Microsoft vs Netscape - davidallen.org Policy.pdf · In this opposition, Netscape first carried the standard against Microsoft, with the “browser wars” setting off the tu-mult—Netscape’s

dence, however, is on the outcomes of “type (2)” policies, no-tably Gørtz (in Chapter VII) who observes the disastrous out-come of “type (2)” policies on a very small economy, andnotes that little harm and much good could have beenachieved, easily, with more modest “type (1)” policies di-rected at the micro-economic circumstances.

Both David Allen (Chapter IV) and Jean-Philipe Bonardiand Bertrand Quélin (Chapter V) address the design of mar-ket institutions directly. Looking at the fast computer andcommunications markets Allen shifts policy emphasis awayfrom formal property rights towards anti-trust policy, but heasks for a much more sophisticated policy than current USpractice. Bonardi & Quélin are concerned with the design ofderegulation. How do you eliminate inefficient rent-seekingbehavior in favor of productive, Adam Smith-type competi-tion?

The rent-seeking and monopolizing behavior discussed byAllen and Bonardi & Quélin opens up a vast range of unpro-ductive political activities, not in the least the destructive re-distributive policies of democratic parties discussed byMoberg and—in a similar vein—vote-seeking through egali-tarian policies.

In Chapter VI Andrew Reed discusses the institutional fail-ures of government in the agricultural sector of Russia. Old,centralist and inefficient ways of doing things persist. In partthis is, perhaps paradoxically, caused by Western organiza-tions involved in technical assistance who naturally team upwith the old bureaucracy. The result is that proper market in-stitutions do not evolve, at least not at the pace required. Thepolitical as well as the market demand for change is too weak.

An example of a more, perhaps extreme, activist approachof state interference is provided, as noted, by Erik Gørtz inChapter VII in his study of government subsidies to the fish-ing industry of the Faeroe Islands. The results were, to put itmildly, frightening. On a smaller scale, the same kind of nega-tive consequences of state subsidies occurs in Fredrik Berg-ström’s paper in Chapter IX on government support to corpo-rations in order to increase employment. No positive effectscan be identified.

17

Page 48: Microsoft vs Netscape - davidallen.org Policy.pdf · In this opposition, Netscape first carried the standard against Microsoft, with the “browser wars” setting off the tu-mult—Netscape’s

A more optimistic view on this account, however, is pro-vided by Karl Heinrich Oppenländer in Chapter VIII. In hisstudy of equity support to new business start-ups in Germanyhe concludes that, yes, subsidies may in fact under certainconditions be helpful. Market failure caused by asymmetricalinformation in investment markets may indeed be a reasonfor government interference. If modesty pursued as “type (1)”policy aimed at improving micro-market conditions, the risksfor significant government failure at the macro level are fairlysmall.

To summarize, three themes run through the papers of thisbook: (1) lack of policy-making competence to correct marketfailure turns into government failure; (2) the critical choice ofinstitutions for good economic performance; and (3) the riskof institutional lock-in. A finger of warning is raised for ambi-tious “type (2)” policies attempting to control the actual out-comes of the market processes. It seems fair to say that thereare strong limits to government interference in markets to suc-cessfully promote growth—and other targets as well.

It might be objected, however, that our choice of articles andexamples are biased. Selections of articles in social sciences al-ways, to some extent, become political and it may seem as ifthe selection to be presented here is biased by negative evi-dence on the role played by government.

First we can say that this is a fairly representative selectionof the papers presented at three sessions on Government andinstitutions at the 1996 Schumpeter Conference. Second, thereis one good reason for this seemingly negative bias.Schumpeterian-type analytical approaches of course domi-nated the papers. We, therefore, indirectly avoided having thetraditional policy analysis based on intellectually controlledequilibrium models dominate. In such a traditional modelanalysis the central policy-maker is always in intellectual pol-icy control conveying the idea that he may also be in practicalpolicy control of the economy. In a realistic policy setting herarely is, so in this sense our selection is both good contrast totraditional analyses and fair. In fact, it highlights the need toformulate better theory of policy analysis that explains thereasons for both policy failure and success, and removes the

18

Page 49: Microsoft vs Netscape - davidallen.org Policy.pdf · In this opposition, Netscape first carried the standard against Microsoft, with the “browser wars” setting off the tu-mult—Netscape’s

impression of a supremely competent and fully informed pol-icy actor in central control.

Democracy as a softener of marketsRichard Day (in Chapter I, “An evolutionary theory of demo-cratic capitalism”) provides a useful format for discussing thecollection of papers presented in this volume. His analysis be-gins by arguing that institutions are needed to support dy-namic market behavior and the efficient functioning of AdamSmith’s coordinating invisible hand. Realistically, institutionsevolve in response to a demand for such collective services.

Even though institutions evolve to intermediate activitiesout of equilibrium, the currently fashionable repertoire of eco-nomic theory provides practically no intellectual help in deal-ing with this important socio-economic problem.

Above all, Day argues, when out of equilibrium adjust-ments become too rough and/or when the existing institu-tions are not up to their task of softening the consequences ofchange for people, “the imbalances spill over into the politicalsystem.” Government institutions have evolved to deal withthose instabilities to preserve a politically orderly economicprocess. Democracy, Day emphasizes, is a cost-efficient insti-tution to deal with social conflicts caused by economic imbal-ances.

Even though democracy undoubtedly is an important sof-tener of markets, if inappropriately designed it can cause seri-ous functional problems within the economy.

When and why democracy may runout of control

Erik Moberg (in Chapter II, “The expanding public sector—athreat to democracy?”) takes a, from Day, different public-choice-oriented, approach to democracy. He develops a po-litical decision theory of delegation and instruction. Constitu-tional environments, he argues, which favor delegation tendto be presidential ones, with a strong executive power sepa-

19

Page 50: Microsoft vs Netscape - davidallen.org Policy.pdf · In this opposition, Netscape first carried the standard against Microsoft, with the “browser wars” setting off the tu-mult—Netscape’s

rately elected, but also with very independent legislators, asin the US. The instruction-based, parliamentary political sys-tem, on the other hand, features strong parties canvassing themarket for votes, offering to sell, through formulated pro-grams, favors to special interest groups and minorities, at theexpense of the powerless majority.

Moberg’s theoretical argument is that the parliamentary-based political agenda of instructions is inherently spend-thrift and oriented towards politically engineered redistribu-tion of favors, using the tax system and the public sector as avehicle. Therein lies an inevitable expansion of the public sec-tor (in percent of total output) in such political regimes. Whenmanipulated extensively parlamentarism easily turns intoparty dictatorship, but also, Moberg argues, winds up in anover-dimensioned public sector and economic crisis, with nodemocratically determined exit. The people have democrati-cally imprisoned themselves. The inevitable economic crisis,if sufficiently deep, may resolve the situation, or people willvote with their feet physically and/or economically leavingthe country, thereby undermining the tax base of the publicsector and forcing economic collapse.

The Moberg view constitutes a serious catch that wouldmake economists and political scientists alike very pessimis-tic. Is there no nice way out?

Enabling law may break institutional lock-inClas Wihlborg (in Chapter III, “The role of enabling and man-datory company law for financial systems efficiency”) intro-duces enabling law as an institution that gives parties to anagreement: (1) freedom to design contracts to suit their localneeds; and (2) predictability in the sense that enabling law maybe made to dominate other law (old and new) in case of con-flict and to guide precedent formation. The first attribute isobtained by allowing the parties to deviate from a standardcontract by mutual consent. The second attribute is obtained ifthe constitution specifies that enabling law dominates manda-tory law in case of conflict. This applies also in countries withdeveloped legal systems where mandatory law is used to

20

Page 51: Microsoft vs Netscape - davidallen.org Policy.pdf · In this opposition, Netscape first carried the standard against Microsoft, with the “browser wars” setting off the tu-mult—Netscape’s

achieve other objectives than economic efficiency, for instancepursuing extreme egalitarian objectives.

At a first glance, the two dimensions of enabling law mayseem to contradict one another, when they really complementeach other. The second attribute was first established in Elias-son, Rybczynski & Wihlborg (1994) as a “means” to overcomethe contradictory institutions in formerly planned economieswhen trying to introduce market regimes. Rather than takingon the impossible task of attempting to specify an entirelynew institutional code for the desired market regime, a fewdominant principles of enabling law could be introduced as a“constitutionally based” principle to override all earlier andnew mandatory legislation that contradicted the new princi-ples and thus enforce new precedent. Legal and institutionalpredictability would be established. Enabling law in this sec-ond sense, hence, offers a way out (Eliasson 1998), not only forsocially and politically distressed formerly planned econo-mies, but also for overdimensioned parliamentary welfare re-gimes bogged down in the marshes of rent-seeking, rationalvoters. (See Karlson 1993 for an alternative way to escape thelock-in.)

The recent decision (April 1998) passed down by the EUCourt imposing the free trade principle in services as well ongovernment provided health insurance and health care provi-sion is an excellent example of enabling law as a “constitu-tional principle.” The Court judgment overrides local (na-tional) mandatory law that restricts the freedom of nationalsto shop for health care services across the EU. It (1) raises eco-nomic efficiency through removing public monopolies inhealth care, and (2) introduces consumer sovereignty in a pre-viously government controlled market and, hence, is in everyrespect a positive measure consistent with the EU principlesof economic freedom.

The EU Court decision, Wihlborg observes, runs counter toprevious precedent formation. At least in Sweden, it appears,the more detailed and prespecified mandatory law, the moreit seems to take precedent over principles of enabling law inhigher court decisions.

Enabling law as defined here, hence, can substitute as a con-stitutional principle that carries certain efficiency characteris-

21

Page 52: Microsoft vs Netscape - davidallen.org Policy.pdf · In this opposition, Netscape first carried the standard against Microsoft, with the “browser wars” setting off the tu-mult—Netscape’s

tics associated with flexibility and predictability. Wihlborgthen goes on to illustrate the two laws with examples from fi-nance. His general conclusion is that mandatory law specify-ing one compulsory “standard-form contract” can never beefficient since the circumstances always vary to the extent thatcustomized contracts are more efficient. Excessive use of de-tailed mandatory contracts, therefore, typically signal thatother objectives than efficiency are pursued by the lawmak-ers.

The significance of the designof market supporting institutions

David Allen (in Chapter IV, “Microsoft vs Netscape—policyfor dynamic models : anti-trust and intellectual propertyrights revisited”) hits the core of the Schumpeter, or ratherAustrian, problem when attempting to resolve the balance be-tween innovative activity and the economies of scale emanat-ing from standardization, on the one hand, and to clarify thenature of intellectual property rights in the world of rapidlymerging computing and communications industries, on theother.

The neoclassical, and perhaps outdated, standard view isthat legal protection should be available to guarantee an in-centive rent to the innovator, a standard argument rephrasedby Arrow (1962) to mean that efficiency and welfare will per-haps be maximized if R&D is socialized and the results madeavailable free of charge. This view, derived from the standardWalrasian model, disregards the influence on research pro-ductivity of the organization and incentives of R&D produc-tion. It also sets the stage for R&D, the winner takes all, races.

Allen’s view is different. First, he observes that in the rap-idly changing and complex network of merging computingand communications technology legal property rights mayget in the way of innovative change. Second, he says, look atthe Microsoft-Netscape fracas and Microsoft’s predatory be-havior as a temporary monopolist. Perhaps the best protec-tion for the innovator Netscape, after all, is protection fromthe competitor and predator monopolist imposing a standard

22

Page 53: Microsoft vs Netscape - davidallen.org Policy.pdf · In this opposition, Netscape first carried the standard against Microsoft, with the “browser wars” setting off the tu-mult—Netscape’s

that kills the innovator, and locks the industry into an obsoletetechnology, let us say Esperanto instead of English. But (andthird), Allen argues, antitrust legislators have little under-standing of the dynamics of this industry. They use overlyblunt instruments to curb monopolist behavior, and, after all,the industry needs a standard, at least temporarily during aconsolidation period, after a solution has been sorted out dur-ing an earlier innovation phase. Perhaps even an inferior stan-dard will be better than no standard at all, provided it is not al-lowed to impede innovative progress, to the extent of soonbreaking itself up. What can be done? Well, let us look at Al-len’s argument by looking at the members of a functioningfamily. To make the family business work the individualmembers have to behave. You cannot have one family mem-ber predate on the other members. They will stop contributingand leave the family. Big is good only as long as big behaves asa member of the family. The complex and rapidly movingcomputing and communications innovation game requiresthat the players work together in order not to break up devel-opment. They have to follow the norms of well behaved teamparticipation. The delicate team cohesion cannot take a spoilerlike Microsoft, aiming for family (market) control, Allen ar-gues. Hence, if the spoiler does not voluntarily behave, anti-trust authorities have to use their very blunt second best in-struments to contain him.

Can deregulation succeed?Jean-Philippe Bonardi and Bertrand Quélin (in Chapter V,“Regulatory body, rent-seeking and market activities : thecase of telecommunications in Europe”) study what happenswhen a formerly regulated market, often a state monopoly, isderegulated, when the government moves out. What condi-tions are necessary to end the rent-seeking activities and topromote a competitive market?

Focusing on Public Telecommunications Operators inEurope, Bonardi & Quélin observe that deregulation is a slowand complex process. More than ten years after its beginningit has not been completed and rent-seeking activities are still

23

Page 54: Microsoft vs Netscape - davidallen.org Policy.pdf · In this opposition, Netscape first carried the standard against Microsoft, with the “browser wars” setting off the tu-mult—Netscape’s

frequent. The operators possess strong political resourceswhich they devote to various activities aimed at influencinggovernment policies, to get subsidies, to restrict competitionetc. Moreover, they are extremely competent when it comes toachieve their ends, due to their direct access to public deci-sions, lengthy relations with government agencies and infor-mational asymmetries that work to their advantage. The samephenomena can of course be observed in a number of otherEuropean industries, i e in rail and air transport, in education,television, health care, etc.

Bonardi & Quélin argue, from a comparative study of Ger-man, French and British examples, that deregulation will onlybe successful, at least among Public Telecommunications Op-erators, if a specific regulatory body is created that has thepower to change the regulatory governance of the sector. Suchpower, in turn, must be based on (1) freedom of action, i e in-dependence from political authorities, and (2) a clear incen-tive to favor the entry of competitors into the industry. If not, ie if such a body lacks the required incentives and autonomy,rent-seeking and quasi-monopolies will persist.

There is always a risk, however, they observe, that such anagency may itself turn into a rent-seeker. The way out of theinstitutional lock-in, hence, creates its own problem.

Institutional failureAndrew Reed (in Chapter VI, “Russia´s agrarian dilemma :the legacy of an economy without innovation, entrepreneursor market competition”) provides an interesting illustrationfrom Russian agriculture of how regulation that restricts theways to organize production, that reduces economic incen-tives and that lowers competition, cripples the ability of theformerly planned economy to allocate resources efficiently forsustained long-term economic growth. Understanding thissituation has been a perplexing experience for the West, nota-bly its advisors, approaching post-Soviet Russia with the apriori textbook “understanding” that economic infrastructureis lacking. Since it appears not to be lacking in the conven-

24

Page 55: Microsoft vs Netscape - davidallen.org Policy.pdf · In this opposition, Netscape first carried the standard against Microsoft, with the “browser wars” setting off the tu-mult—Netscape’s

tional sense, the problem must lie in lacking institutions, aproblem formulation unfamiliar to western advisors.

The main culprit, Reed argues, is the lingering hierarchical(Soviet) tradition of discriminating against alternative, inno-vative ways of doing things. Since organizations in the Westinvolved in technical assistance typically approach their prob-lem with a centralist, interventionist mind set, they tend toteam up with the bureaucracy of the past, rather than to at-tempt to break it up. The traditional Soviet policy of mobiliz-ing resources for planned growth rather than using resourcesin an economically efficient way has made the Russian agri-cultural industry deficient in acquiring new technology andutterly helpless in coping with privatization, new competitionand change.

With a system that favored high-cost production of lowquality products in large volumes, deregulation producedtwo expected outcomes; some producers were able to adjust,others not. Those who could adjust increased their profits andcould afford to pay high wages. People with relatively highand rising incomes are demanding a high quality and a morevaried food that Russian agricultural industry cannot supply.This demand, hence, can only be satisfied through imports.The outcome has been catastrophic for Russian agriculture.Most problematic of all, Reed notes, is the inability of the Rus-sian mind to grasp the concept of an economy with a self-organizing structure.

The evolution of a market economy can be described as achaotic development with feedback mechanisms that allowagents to make qualitative assessments of alternatives. The“Perestroika” jump started the feedback mechanisms, but theSoviet system had a seriously impaired ability to respond.

Reed also notes the similarities with the European,Brussels-regulated and subsidized agriculture and the Rus-sian dilemma. While Russian agriculture underproduces withno quality variation and little appeal to customers, the Westoverproduces. In both cases Government has contributed tothe inefficient outcome. When Government intervenes inmarkets with lacking insight and competence, problems arecreated rather than solved.

25

Page 56: Microsoft vs Netscape - davidallen.org Policy.pdf · In this opposition, Netscape first carried the standard against Microsoft, with the “browser wars” setting off the tu-mult—Netscape’s

Policy failure on a grand scalein a small place

The consequences of policy action are best highlighted whenpolicies are extreme, and the economy is small and simple(two sectors). Such an economy is not robust, and ill-conceived policies typically hit hard and fast. Erik Gørtz’story (in Chapter VII, “Private and public expenditures andthe Faeroese business cycle”) of the policy disaster of the Fae-roese islands provides a perfect and very pedagogical settingfor the analysis of grand-scale government failure.

During the 1980s the small Faeroese economy was exces-sively primed by investment subsidies. For some years the in-vestments amounted to 40–50 percent of GDP, practicallynone of it being filtered by market criteria. Rates of return toinvestments were driven down far below market interestrates. Since most investments went into one production sec-tor, fishing, or associated public infrastructure, the resultingexpansion depleted the stock of fish. This in turn resulted, af-ter some years, in a sudden collapse of both output and the(only) exports of the islands. 25 percent unemployment, an ex-plosion of public debt and the emigration of ten percent of thepopulation followed, the last consequence being already pre-dicted in Moberg’s analysis (in Chapter II).

How could such a destructive policy be politically allowedand sustained?

Well, Erik Gørtz concludes, with a fragmented political sys-tem, with self-centered rational local politicians, with the ab-sence of political responsibility and without direct economicfeed-backs a touch of public-choice analysis would predict thepolitical system’s failure.

But the Faeroese problem was not really created by policy,Gørtz continues. It would have happened anyway. It was onlymade worse by misdirected attempts at macro stabilization,he argues. The real problem was micro-economic and one ofinstitutional design. And understanding that would havesuggested much easier solutions.

26

Page 57: Microsoft vs Netscape - davidallen.org Policy.pdf · In this opposition, Netscape first carried the standard against Microsoft, with the “browser wars” setting off the tu-mult—Netscape’s

An example of a fairly successfulintervention

Markets fail for several reasons, and the government has arole to play in attempting to remedy such situations. Correct-ing market failure, however, requires unique competence onthe part of the policy-maker, notably a thorough understand-ing of the dynamics of an experimentally organized marketeconomy (Eliasson 1992). This understanding is not typicallypresent outside the business community, and economic the-ory guiding policy advisors is grossly inadequate in this con-text. Hence, government attempts to correct market failureeasily lead to significant government failure, if not cautiouslyand competently administered. We have one fairly successfulattempt, and one failure to report on.

Karl Heinrich Oppenländer (in Chapter VIII, “Problems inassisting new business start-ups in Germany”) studies theGerman equity assistance program for new business start-ups. He observes that market failure appears to be characteris-tic of the venture end of the capital markets, caused primarilyby informational asymmetries. He wants to know whetherthis can be remedied by an equity capital assistance programimplemented by the German government.

His conclusion is that, indeed, the program has been valu-able in financing new firms and innovations at the micro levelin a way that had positive consequences for economic growth.Because the participants had to fulfill certain requirementsand provide information about themselves, the informationalasymmetries were reduced and thereby also the risk to thelender/investor.

We also have to observe that the German intervention in themarkets was very cautious and concerned with remedying aparticular situation in the market, not with achieving certainoutcomes or social policy ends. The risks for creating macro-economic disturbances were minimal. While the German pol-icy results appear promising, the Swedish employment-oriented support programs do not fare well in a similar analy-sis.

27

Page 58: Microsoft vs Netscape - davidallen.org Policy.pdf · In this opposition, Netscape first carried the standard against Microsoft, with the “browser wars” setting off the tu-mult—Netscape’s

Policy failure on a small scaleFredrik Bergström (in Chapter IX, “Do public capital subsi-dies to firms increase employment?”) is very explicit in hisempirical analysis of the two kinds of failures, market andgovernment. Incompetent government action to correct mar-ket failure, in fact often seems to result in a much bigger gov-ernment failure.

Employment support of failing firms, for instance, often re-sults in industrial technological lock-ins. As shown already inEliasson & Lindberg (1981), it is all right for firms to make sig-nificant investment or business mistakes. The economy atlarge can sustain such mistakes, which are in fact a normalcost for economic learning in a dynamic market economy (Eli-asson 1992). The really large, negative macro-economic effectsoccur when production is allowed to go on in the failed invest-ments. Such sustained failure could not occur in the market,only under a protective government subsidy umbrella. And ademocratic political institution will, by its very political char-ter, be bad at correcting or terminating mistakes (Eliasson1990, p 285). Carlsson, Bergholm & Lindberg (1981), Carlsson(1983), furthermore, show that it is normally far better forlong-term employment to subsidize the most profitable firms,if you have to subsidize at all, and disregard possible directnegative employment effects. The same study also demon-strates that when subsidy support of defunct firms is pushedto the extreme, as in the case of Swedish shipyards during the1970s, severe negative macro-economic effects can be ob-served. Bergström observes that the symptoms are very simi-lar in his sample of firms, but that they only constitute a mini-example of the shipyard debacle of the 1970s.

Bergström’s case is, however, clear. The Swedish Govern-ment, when subsidizing industrial firms, has in fact engagedin a significant government failure under the cover of at-tempting to correct market mistakes. Subsidies have tended togo to inferior, low productivity firms, reinforcing the negativeeffects through both creating additional negative productivityeffects in the firms receiving subsidies, and holding back in-vestment and growth in other, non supported firms.

28

Page 59: Microsoft vs Netscape - davidallen.org Policy.pdf · In this opposition, Netscape first carried the standard against Microsoft, with the “browser wars” setting off the tu-mult—Netscape’s

In addition, Bergström observes, by engaging in life-supporting measures on obsolete firms, the Government maynot only slow growth but also create lock-in effects in obsoleteindustries and technologies.

Bibliography

Arrow, K J (1962), “Economic welfare and the allocation of re-sources for invention.” Ch 7 in Nelson, R (ed), The rate and di-rection of inventive activity : economic and social factors. Prince-ton: NBER, Princeton University Press, 1962.

Carlsson, B (1983), “Industrial subsidies in Sweden : simula-tions on a micro-to-macro model,” in Microeconometrics, IUIYearbook 1982–83. Stockholm: IUI.

Carlsson, B, Bergholm, F & Lindberg, T (1981), Industristödspo-litiken och dess inverkan på samhällsekonomin (Industry subsidypolicy and its macro-economic impact). Stockholm: IUI.

Day, R H (1986), “Disequilibrium economic dynamics : apost-Schumpeterian contribute.” Ch 3 in Day, R H & Eliasson,G (eds), The dynamics of market economies. Stockholm: IUI &Amsterdam: North-Holland, 1986.

Day, R H & Eliasson, G (eds) (1986), The dynamics of marketeconomies. Stockholm: IUI & Amsterdam: North-Holland.

Eliasson, G (1986a), “A note on the stability of economic or-ganizational forms and the importance of human capital,” inDay, R H & Eliasson, G (eds), The dynamics of market economies.Stockholm: IUI & Amsterdam: North-Holland, 1986.

Eliasson, G (1986b), “The economics of institutions and mar-kets : the organization of research at IUI.” Ch I in The economicsof institutions and markets. Stockholm: IUI.

Eliasson, G (1992), “Business competence, organizationallearning and economic growth : establishing the Smith-

29

Page 60: Microsoft vs Netscape - davidallen.org Policy.pdf · In this opposition, Netscape first carried the standard against Microsoft, with the “browser wars” setting off the tu-mult—Netscape’s

Schumpeter-Wicksell (SSW) connection,” in Scherer, F M &Perlman, M (eds), Entrepreneurship, technological innovation andeconomic growth. Ann Arbor: The University of MichiganPress, 1992.

Eliasson, G (1998), “From plan to market,” in Journal of Eco-nomic Behavior and Organization, Vol 34, pp 49–68.

Eliasson, G & Green, C (eds) (1998), The micro foundations ofeconomic growth. Ann Arbor: The University of MichiganPress.

Eliasson, G & Lindberg, T (1981), “Allocation and growth ef-fects of corporate income taxes,” in Eliasson, G & Södersten, J(eds), Business taxation, finance and firm behavior, ConferenceReports 1981:1. Stockholm: IUI.

Eliasson, G, Rybczynski, T & Wihlborg, C (1994), The necessaryinstitutional framework to transform formerly planned economies :with special emphasis on the institutions needed to stimulate foreigninvestment in the formerly planned economies. Stockholm: IUI.

Karlson, N (1993), The state of state : an inquiry concerning therole of invisible hands in politics and civil society. Stockholm:Almqvist & Wiksell International.

Karlson, N (ed) (1995), Can the present problems of mature wel-fare states such as Sweden be solved? Stockholm: City UniversityPress.

Scherer, F M & Perlman, M (eds) (1992), Entrepreneurship, tech-nological innovation and economic growth. Ann Arbor: The Uni-versity of Michigan Press.

Schumpeter, J A (1942), Capitalism, socialism and democracy.New York: Harper & Row.

30