monetary policy in a macro model - econ 40364: monetary ...esims1/slides_money_macro.pdf ·...

67
Monetary Policy in a Macro Model ECON 40364: Monetary Theory & Policy Eric Sims University of Notre Dame Fall 2017 1 / 67

Upload: duongtuong

Post on 10-Jul-2018

223 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Monetary Policy in a Macro ModelECON 40364: Monetary Theory & Policy

Eric Sims

University of Notre Dame

Fall 2017

1 / 67

Readings

I Mishkin Ch. 20

I Mishkin Ch. 21

I Mishkin Ch. 22

I Mishkin Ch. 23, pg. 553-569

2 / 67

Approach

I Want to study role of monetary policy in the aggregateeconomy

I For that reason, we will not bother to “micro-found” themacro model of the economy (unlike, for example, inintermediate macro)

I We will just posit a bunch of demand and supply relationshipsso as to to get a useable demand-supply macro model

I These demand and supply relationships (or something thatlooks like them) can be motivated from micro principles

3 / 67

Aggregate Demand

I Aggregate demand is the sum of planned expenditure by thefour primary actors in an economy:

1. Households (consumption)2. Firms (investment)3. Government (government purchases)4. Rest of the world (net exports)

I Total (real) aggregate demand is the sum of plannedexpenditure by each of these actors:

Y ad = C + I + G +NX

4 / 67

Consumption

I It is assumed that aggregate consumption is governed by aconsumption function:

C = C +mpc × (Y − T )

I Y is income and T is taxes, so Y − T is disposable incomeI C is autonomous consumption. “Autonomous” means the

exogenous component of an endogenous variable. C isconsumption independent of disposable income. Potentialfactors impacting it (which are not modeled explicitly):

I Future incomeI Interest ratesI UncertaintyI Government spending (via Ricardian Equivalence)

I mpc is the marginal propensity to consume and is between 0and 1

I Something like this can be derived from micro principles

5 / 67

Investment

I Investment refers to expenses by business on new physicalcapital (as well as new residential construction and inventoryaccumulation)

I Investment function:I = I − dr

I r is “the” real interest rate, d is a parameter governingsensitivity to the real interest rate, and I is autonomousinvestment (investment independent of the real interest rate).Possible factors:

I Expectations about the futureI Efficiency of producing new capitalI Government regulations and taxes

I Book includes a “credit spread” variable here. We will returnto that later

6 / 67

Government Spending and Taxes

I We assume that government spending and taxes arecompletely exogenous. Hence:

G = G (1)

T = T (2)

I We do not think explicitly about government debt, futuretaxes, or future spending. Also, taxes are “lump sum”

I Not modeling Ricardian Equivalence

7 / 67

Net Exports

I Net exports depend on the exchange rate (how much onecurrency buys of another), as well as on other non-modeledthings

I A high US interest rate results in an appreciation of the dollar(foreigners want to buy US assets, pushing the value of thedollar relative to other currencies up)

I An appreciation of the dollar leads to more imports (cheaperfor US citizens to buy foreign goods) and fewer exports (moreexpensive for foreigners to buy US goods) and hence reducesnet exports

I Net export function, where NX is autonomous net exportsand x is a parameter governing sensitivity to real interest rate:

NX = NX − xr

8 / 67

Putting it all together

I Total planned (or desired) expenditure:

Y ad = C −mpcT + I + G + NX +mpcY − (d + x)r

I For simplicity, let A = C −mpcT + I + G + NX

I Then:Y ad = A+mpcY − (d + x)r

I One equation in three “unknowns” (Y ad , Y , and r); d , x ,and mpc are parameters, and A is exogenous

I In equilibrium, total output must equal total plannedexpenditure, Y = Y ad , so:

Y =1

1−mpcA− d + x

1−mpcr

9 / 67

Keynesian Cross

𝑌𝑌

𝑌𝑌𝑎𝑎𝑎𝑎 𝑌𝑌𝑎𝑎𝑎𝑎 = 𝑌𝑌

𝑌𝑌𝑎𝑎𝑎𝑎 = ��𝐴 + 𝑚𝑚𝑚𝑚𝑚𝑚 ∙ 𝑌𝑌 − (𝑑𝑑 + 𝑥𝑥) ∙ 𝑟𝑟

��𝐴 − (𝑑𝑑 + 𝑥𝑥) ∙ 𝑟𝑟

𝑌𝑌∗

𝑌𝑌∗

10 / 67

The IS Curve

I The condition:

Y =1

1−mpcA− d + x

1−mpcr

Is one equation in two endogenous variables, r and Y

I The IS curve is the set of (r ,Y ) pairs where this conditionholds

I It can be derived graphically:I It is downward slopingI It shifts right whenever A increases

11 / 67

𝑌𝑌

𝑌𝑌𝑎𝑎𝑎𝑎 𝑌𝑌𝑎𝑎𝑎𝑎 = 𝑌𝑌

𝑌𝑌𝑎𝑎𝑎𝑎 = ��𝐴 + 𝑚𝑚𝑚𝑚𝑚𝑚 ∙ 𝑌𝑌 − (𝑑𝑑 + 𝑥𝑥) ∙ 𝑟𝑟

��𝐴 − (𝑑𝑑 + 𝑥𝑥) ∙ 𝑟𝑟0

𝑌𝑌0 𝑌𝑌

𝑟𝑟

𝑟𝑟0

𝑟𝑟1

𝑌𝑌1

��𝐴 − (𝑑𝑑 + 𝑥𝑥) ∙ 𝑟𝑟1

𝑟𝑟2

𝐼𝐼𝐼𝐼

��𝐴 − (𝑑𝑑 + 𝑥𝑥) ∙ 𝑟𝑟2

𝑌𝑌2

12 / 67

𝑌𝑌

𝑌𝑌𝑎𝑎𝑎𝑎 𝑌𝑌𝑎𝑎𝑎𝑎 = 𝑌𝑌

𝑌𝑌𝑎𝑎𝑎𝑎 = ��𝐴 + 𝑚𝑚𝑚𝑚𝑚𝑚 ∙ 𝑌𝑌 − (𝑑𝑑 + 𝑥𝑥) ∙ 𝑟𝑟

��𝐴0 − (𝑑𝑑 + 𝑥𝑥) ∙ 𝑟𝑟0

𝑌𝑌0 𝑌𝑌

𝑟𝑟

𝑟𝑟0

𝑌𝑌1

𝐼𝐼𝐼𝐼

��𝐴1 − (𝑑𝑑 + 𝑥𝑥) ∙ 𝑟𝑟0

𝐼𝐼𝐼𝐼′

13 / 67

The MP Curve

I To get an aggregate demand curve, which shows a relationshipbetween aggregate output and the inflation rate or theaggregate price level (where π = ∆P

P ), we need to combinethe IS curve with some description of monetary policy

I Traditionally, this was done through something called the LMcurve, which combines the liquidity preference of moneydemand with a money supply rule

I Given central bank’s modern focus on interest rates ratherthan money supply, we instead do so with the monetary policycurve (MP)

I Difference: with the LM curve, AD curve is downward-slopingin a graph with (P,Y ). With MP curve, AD curve isdownward-sloping with (π,Y )

I We need not model money at all, though we could figure outhow Fed must adjust M to meet money demand if we wanted

14 / 67

The MP curve and the Taylor Principle

I Recall the Fisher relationship, r = i − πe . Fed can control i ,but not necessarily r

I Assume adaptive expectations, so that πe = π.I Then assume Fed sets nominal rate according to:

i = r + aπ

I Similar to the Taylor rule. r is “autonomous monetary policy”(movements in rates unrelated to inflation). a > 1 – the“Taylor Principle”

I Can write the real interest rate as:

r = r + λπ

I Where λ = (a− 1). Taylor principle requires λ > 0. Idea:when π increases, Fed responds by raising r

15 / 67

The AD Curve

I Simply combine the IS and MP curves. You get:

Y =1

1−mpcA− d + x

1−mpc(r + λπ)

I Can also re-arrange with π on LHS:

π = − 1−mpc

(d + x)λY +

1

(d + x)λA− 1

λr

I Provided λ > 0 (Taylor principle satisfied):

1. AD curve is downward-sloping2. AD curve is flatter the bigger is λ3. AD curve shifts out/up when A increases4. AD curve shifts down/in when r increases

16 / 67

𝜋𝜋 𝜋𝜋

𝜋𝜋

𝜋𝜋

𝑟𝑟 𝑟𝑟

𝑌𝑌

𝑌𝑌

𝜋𝜋 = 𝜋𝜋

𝑟𝑟 = ��𝑟 + 𝜆𝜆𝜋𝜋

��𝑟

𝐼𝐼𝐼𝐼

𝜋𝜋0

𝜋𝜋0

𝑟𝑟0

𝑌𝑌0

𝜋𝜋1

𝑟𝑟1

𝑌𝑌1

𝜋𝜋2

𝜋𝜋2 𝜋𝜋1 𝑌𝑌2

𝐴𝐴𝐴𝐴

𝑟𝑟2

17 / 67

Shifts of the AD Curve

I The AD curve is drawn holding r (which governs the positionof the MP curve) and A (which governs the position of the IScurve) fixed

I An increase in r will result in an increase in the real interestrate for a given inflation rate; from the IS curve, this results ina lower level of output. So the AD curve shifts left

I An increase in A will shift the IS curve right. For a giveninflation rate, the real interest rate is given, which means thatoutput increases. So the AD curve shifts right

18 / 67

𝜋𝜋 𝜋𝜋

𝜋𝜋

𝜋𝜋

𝑟𝑟 𝑟𝑟

𝑌𝑌

𝑌𝑌

𝜋𝜋 = 𝜋𝜋

𝑟𝑟 = ��𝑟 + 𝜆𝜆𝜋𝜋

��𝑟0

𝐼𝐼𝐼𝐼

𝜋𝜋0

𝜋𝜋0

𝑟𝑟0

𝑌𝑌0

𝐴𝐴𝐴𝐴

��𝑟1

𝑟𝑟1

𝑌𝑌1

𝐴𝐴𝐴𝐴′

19 / 67

𝜋𝜋 𝜋𝜋

𝜋𝜋

𝜋𝜋

𝑟𝑟 𝑟𝑟

𝑌𝑌

𝑌𝑌

𝜋𝜋 = 𝜋𝜋

𝑟𝑟 = ��𝑟 + 𝜆𝜆𝜋𝜋

��𝑟

𝐼𝐼𝐼𝐼

𝜋𝜋0

𝜋𝜋0

𝑟𝑟0

𝑌𝑌0

𝐴𝐴𝐴𝐴

𝐼𝐼𝐼𝐼′

𝑌𝑌1

𝐴𝐴𝐴𝐴′

20 / 67

The Taylor Principle and the Slope of the AD Curve

I The Taylor principle (a > 1 or λ > 0) calls for the Fed toraise the real interest rate when inflation increases

I The higher real interest rate causes output to decline from theIS curve, which makes the AD curve downward-sloping

I What if the Taylor principle isn’t satisfied? i.e. λ < 0?

I Higher inflation results in lower real interest rates, whichstimulates output from the IS curve

I The AD curve is upward-sloping. For reasons we will talkabout later, this is undesirable.

21 / 67

𝜋𝜋 𝜋𝜋

𝜋𝜋

𝜋𝜋

𝑟𝑟 𝑟𝑟

𝑌𝑌

𝑌𝑌

𝜋𝜋 = 𝜋𝜋

𝑟𝑟 = ��𝑟 + 𝜆𝜆𝜋𝜋, λ < 0

��𝑟

𝐼𝐼𝐼𝐼

𝜋𝜋0

𝜋𝜋0

𝑟𝑟0

𝑌𝑌0

𝜋𝜋1

𝑟𝑟0

𝑌𝑌1

𝜋𝜋2

𝜋𝜋2 𝜋𝜋1 𝑌𝑌2

𝐴𝐴𝐴𝐴

𝑟𝑟2

𝑟𝑟1

22 / 67

Aggregate Supply

I Relationship between π and Y (or P and Y )I Accepted paradigm:

I Aggregate supply (AS) curve is vertical in the “long run” or“medium run.” The level of output where it’s vertical, or“potential output,” is determined by labor supply, availablecapital, and technology.

I Prices and/or wages are “sticky” in the short run, so “shortrun” AS curve is upward-sloping instead of vertical

I Many policy debates among macroeconomists are over the“shape” of the AS curve (i.e. how far from vertical is the AScurve in the short run) and how long it takes to transitionfrom short run to medium/long run

I Let Y P denote potential output; take this to be exogenous(equilibrium concept in model without nominal rigidity)

I LRAS is vertical at this point

23 / 67

Short Run AS

I The assumed short run AS curve is:

π = πe + γ(Y − Y P) + ρ

I Where:

1. πe : how much inflation firms/households expected for today2. γ: parameter governing how steep AS is (related to underlying

price and/or wage stickiness)3. ρ: “inflation shock” (e.g. increase in oil prices), also called

“cost-push shock.” Zero on average; if it changes, onlychanges for one period

I If Y > Y P , firms/households have pressure to increaseprices/wages, which puts upward pressure on π. γ big: it’seasy to do this. γ small: prices/wages are very sticky

24 / 67

𝜋𝜋 = 𝜋𝜋𝑒𝑒 + 𝛾𝛾(𝑌𝑌 − 𝑌𝑌𝑃𝑃) + 𝜌𝜌

𝑌𝑌𝑃𝑃

𝜋𝜋𝑒𝑒 + 𝜌𝜌

𝑌𝑌

𝜋𝜋 LRAS

𝛾𝛾 𝑠𝑠𝑠𝑠𝑠𝑠𝑠𝑠𝑠𝑠

𝛾𝛾 𝑏𝑏𝑏𝑏𝑏𝑏

25 / 67

Short Run AS Curve

I The following are relevant things to remember about the AScurve:

1. If γ→ ∞, no distinction between SRAS and LRAS2. AS curve crosses point Y = Y P at π = πe + ρ. The inflation

shock ρ is zero on average, so we’ll often think of this point asbeing where π = πe . In other words, if households and firmsare not surprised by inflation, then Y = Y p regardless of whatγ is

3. The AS curve shifts up if πe or ρ increase4. The AS curve shifts right if Y P increases

26 / 67

𝜋𝜋 = 𝜋𝜋𝑒𝑒 + 𝛾𝛾(𝑌𝑌 − 𝑌𝑌𝑃𝑃) + 𝜌𝜌

𝑌𝑌𝑃𝑃

𝜋𝜋0𝑒𝑒 + 𝜌𝜌

𝑌𝑌

𝜋𝜋 LRAS

𝜋𝜋1𝑒𝑒 + 𝜌𝜌

27 / 67

𝜋𝜋 = 𝜋𝜋𝑒𝑒 + 𝛾𝛾(𝑌𝑌 − 𝑌𝑌𝑃𝑃) + 𝜌𝜌

𝑌𝑌𝑃𝑃

𝜋𝜋𝑒𝑒 + 𝜌𝜌0

𝑌𝑌

𝜋𝜋 LRAS

𝜋𝜋𝑒𝑒 + 𝜌𝜌1

28 / 67

𝜋𝜋 = 𝜋𝜋𝑒𝑒 + 𝛾𝛾(𝑌𝑌 − 𝑌𝑌𝑃𝑃) + 𝜌𝜌

𝑌𝑌0𝑃𝑃

𝜋𝜋𝑒𝑒 + 𝜌𝜌

𝑌𝑌

𝜋𝜋 𝐿𝐿𝐿𝐿𝐿𝐿𝐿𝐿0

𝑌𝑌1𝑃𝑃

𝐿𝐿𝐿𝐿𝐿𝐿𝐿𝐿1

29 / 67

General Equilibrium

I Equilibrium occurs where AD and AS intersect

I For simplicity, assume these intersect at the LRASI Exogenous variables cause curves to shift and change the

equilibriumI Demand shocks:

I IS shocks: changes in A (C , I , T , G , NX )I Monetary shocks: changes in r

I Supply shocks:I Potential output shocks: changes in Y P

I Inflation shocks: changes in ρI Expected inflation shocks: changes in πe

30 / 67

𝐴𝐴𝐴𝐴

𝑌𝑌0

𝜋𝜋0

𝑌𝑌

𝜋𝜋 𝐿𝐿𝐿𝐿𝐴𝐴𝐴𝐴

𝐴𝐴𝐷𝐷

31 / 67

Demand Shock

𝐴𝐴𝐴𝐴

𝑌𝑌0

𝜋𝜋0

𝑌𝑌

𝜋𝜋 𝐿𝐿𝐿𝐿𝐴𝐴𝐴𝐴

𝐴𝐴𝐴𝐴

𝑌𝑌1

𝜋𝜋1

𝐴𝐴𝐴𝐴′

32 / 67

IS Shock: What Happens to r

𝜋𝜋 𝜋𝜋

𝜋𝜋

𝜋𝜋

𝑟𝑟 𝑟𝑟

𝑌𝑌

𝑌𝑌

𝜋𝜋 = 𝜋𝜋

𝑟𝑟 = ��𝑟 + 𝜆𝜆𝜋𝜋

��𝑟

𝐼𝐼𝐼𝐼

𝜋𝜋0

𝜋𝜋0

𝑟𝑟0

𝑌𝑌0

𝐴𝐴𝐴𝐴

𝐼𝐼𝐼𝐼′

𝑌𝑌0′

𝐴𝐴𝐴𝐴′

𝐴𝐴𝐼𝐼

𝜋𝜋1

𝑟𝑟1

𝑌𝑌1 𝜋𝜋1

(a)

(a) (a)

(a)

(b)

(b)

(c) (c)

(c) (c)

(a) to (b): direct effect (b) to (c): indirect effect due to higher 𝜋𝜋

33 / 67

MP Shock: What Happens to r

𝜋𝜋 𝜋𝜋

𝜋𝜋

𝜋𝜋

𝑟𝑟 𝑟𝑟

𝑌𝑌

𝑌𝑌

𝜋𝜋 = 𝜋𝜋

𝑟𝑟 = ��𝑟 + 𝜆𝜆𝜋𝜋

��𝑟0

𝐼𝐼𝐼𝐼

𝜋𝜋0

𝜋𝜋0

𝑟𝑟0

𝑌𝑌0

𝐴𝐴𝐴𝐴

��𝑟1

𝑟𝑟0′

𝑌𝑌0′

𝐴𝐴𝐴𝐴′

𝐴𝐴𝐼𝐼

𝜋𝜋1

𝜋𝜋1 𝑌𝑌1

𝑟𝑟1

(a)

(a) (a)

(a)

(b) (b)

(b)

(c)

(c) (c)

(c)

(a) to (b): direct effect (b) to (c): indirect effect due to lower 𝜋𝜋

34 / 67

Monetary Neutrality: MP Shock When AS is Vertical

𝜋𝜋 𝜋𝜋

𝜋𝜋

𝜋𝜋

𝑟𝑟 𝑟𝑟

𝑌𝑌

𝑌𝑌

𝜋𝜋 = 𝜋𝜋

𝑟𝑟 = ��𝑟 + 𝜆𝜆𝜋𝜋

��𝑟0

𝐼𝐼𝐼𝐼

𝜋𝜋0

𝜋𝜋0

𝑟𝑟0

𝑌𝑌0

𝐴𝐴𝐴𝐴

��𝑟1

𝑟𝑟0′

𝑌𝑌0′

𝐴𝐴𝐴𝐴′

𝐴𝐴𝐼𝐼

𝜋𝜋1

𝜋𝜋1 𝑌𝑌1

(a)

(a) (a)=(c)

(a)

(b) (b)

(b)

(c)

(c)

(c)

(a) to (b): direct effect (b) to (c): indirect effect due to lower 𝜋𝜋

35 / 67

Supply Shock: Increase in πe or ρ

𝐴𝐴𝐴𝐴

𝑌𝑌0

𝜋𝜋0

𝑌𝑌

𝜋𝜋 𝐿𝐿𝐿𝐿𝐴𝐴𝐴𝐴

𝐴𝐴𝐴𝐴

𝐴𝐴𝐴𝐴′

𝜋𝜋1

𝑌𝑌1

36 / 67

Supply Shock: Increase in Y P

𝐴𝐴𝐴𝐴

𝑌𝑌0

𝜋𝜋0

𝑌𝑌

𝜋𝜋 𝐿𝐿𝐿𝐿𝐴𝐴𝐴𝐴

𝐴𝐴𝐴𝐴

𝐴𝐴𝐴𝐴′

𝐿𝐿𝐿𝐿𝐴𝐴𝐴𝐴′

𝜋𝜋1

𝑌𝑌1

37 / 67

Decrease in Y P : Effect on r

𝜋𝜋 𝜋𝜋

𝜋𝜋

𝜋𝜋

𝑟𝑟 𝑟𝑟

𝑌𝑌

𝑌𝑌

𝜋𝜋 = 𝜋𝜋

𝑟𝑟 = ��𝑟 + 𝜆𝜆𝜋𝜋

��𝑟

𝐼𝐼𝐼𝐼

𝐴𝐴𝐴𝐴

𝐴𝐴𝐼𝐼

𝑌𝑌0 𝜋𝜋0

𝜋𝜋0

𝑟𝑟0

𝐴𝐴𝐼𝐼′

𝜋𝜋1

𝑟𝑟1

𝜋𝜋1 𝑌𝑌1

(c)

(a) (a)

(a) (b)

(c)

(a)

(c) (c)

(a) to (b): direct effect (b) to (c): indirect effect due to higher 𝜋𝜋

38 / 67

Algebraically Solving for EquilibriumI AS with AD:

π = πe + γ

(1

1−mpcA− d + x

1−mpc(r + λπ)− Y p

)+ ρ

I Solve for π:

π =1−mpc

1−mpc + (d + x)λγ(πe + ρ)+

γ

1−mpc + (d + x)λγA

− (d + x)γ

1−mpc + (d + x)λγr − γ(1−mpc)

1−mpc + (d + x)λγY P

I Once you have this, you can get Y from the AS curve:

Y = Y P +1

γ(π − πe − ρ)

I Then can get r = r + λπ and components of output

39 / 67

Dynamics and the “Self-Correcting Mechanism”

I Assume ρ = 0 (its average value)

I From AS, if Y 6= Y P , then π 6= πe

I Y > Y p ⇒ π > πe : agents were surprised with moreinflation than they expected

I Stands to reason that, going forward in time, they will thenrevise up expectations

I πe going up: shifts AS curve up, which makes Y fall with noeffect on Y P

I This process will continue until Y = Y P and inflation stopschange

I And vice-versa in the other direction

40 / 67

Adjustment from Positive Gap: Qualitative

𝐴𝐴𝐴𝐴

𝜋𝜋0

𝑌𝑌

𝜋𝜋 𝐿𝐿𝐿𝐿𝐴𝐴𝐴𝐴

𝐴𝐴𝐴𝐴

𝑌𝑌0 𝑌𝑌1 = 𝑌𝑌𝑃𝑃

𝜋𝜋𝑒𝑒

𝜋𝜋1

𝐴𝐴𝐴𝐴′

41 / 67

Being More SpecificI Put time subscripts on all variables: t is present, t − 1 is one

period in past, t + 1 one period in future, and so onI Assume adaptive expectations, so that πe in the AS curve is

πt−1I Then AS curve is:

πt = πt−1 + γ(Yt − Y P

t

)+ ρt

I AD curve is:

Yt =1

1−mpcAt −

d + x

1−mpc(rt + λπt)

I The interesting dynamics are on the supply side. As πt

changes, the position of the AS curve will change dynamicallyover time. Assume ρt = 0 (unconditional mean)

I Adjustment occurs slowly, only eventually do you get to Y P

42 / 67

Adjustment from Positive Gap: More Specific

𝐴𝐴𝐴𝐴

𝜋𝜋𝑡𝑡

𝑌𝑌

𝜋𝜋 𝐿𝐿𝐿𝐿𝐴𝐴𝐴𝐴

𝐴𝐴𝐴𝐴

𝑌𝑌𝑡𝑡 𝑌𝑌𝑃𝑃

𝜋𝜋𝑡𝑡−1

𝐴𝐴𝐴𝐴′

𝜋𝜋𝑡𝑡+1

𝑌𝑌𝑡𝑡+1

𝜋𝜋𝑡𝑡+2

𝑌𝑌𝑡𝑡+2

𝐴𝐴𝐴𝐴′′

43 / 67

Quantitative Dynamics

I Create an Excel file

I Assume the following parameters and exogenous variables:mpc = 0.7, d = 0.3, x = 0.1, r = 1, λ = 1, A = 4.95,γ = 0.5, Y P = 12.5

I Assume πt−1 = 0

I Implies that πt = 0.8 and Yt = 14.1

I Use Excel to trace out dynamic paths

44 / 67

Adjustment from Positive Gap: Quantitative

0

0.5

1

1.5

2

2.5

0 2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 18 20 22 24 26 28 30

Inflation

12

12.5

13

13.5

14

14.5

0 2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 18 20 22 24 26 28 30

Output

45 / 67

Positive IS Shock: Dynamic Adjustment

𝐴𝐴𝐴𝐴

𝑌𝑌𝑃𝑃

𝜋𝜋𝑡𝑡−1

𝑌𝑌

𝜋𝜋 𝐿𝐿𝐿𝐿𝐴𝐴𝐴𝐴

𝐴𝐴𝐴𝐴

𝑌𝑌𝑡𝑡

𝜋𝜋𝑡𝑡

𝐴𝐴𝐴𝐴′

𝐴𝐴𝐴𝐴′

𝑌𝑌𝑡𝑡+1

𝜋𝜋𝑡𝑡+1

𝐴𝐴𝐴𝐴′′

𝜋𝜋𝑡𝑡+2

𝑌𝑌𝑡𝑡+2

46 / 67

Quantitative Adjustment from Positive IS Shock

1

1.2

1.4

1.6

1.8

2

2.2

2.4

2.6

2.8

3

-5 0 5 10 15 20 25

Inflation

12.2

12.3

12.4

12.5

12.6

12.7

12.8

12.9

13

13.1

13.2

-5 0 5 10 15 20 25

Output

2

2.2

2.4

2.6

2.8

3

3.2

3.4

3.6

3.8

4

-5 0 5 10 15 20 25

r

47 / 67

Monetary Shock

I An exogenous monetary tightening (increase in r) has effectsin terms of output and inflation similar to an IS shock(exogenous increase in A)

I Difference: monetary shock does not affect rt in medium/longrun

I “Natural rate of interest”: r consistent with IS curve holdingat Y P . Call it rP (potential or long run real interest rate):

rP = −1−mpc

d + xY P +

1

d + xA

I Does not depend on r

48 / 67

Adjustment from Positive r Shock

0

0.5

1

1.5

2

2.5

-5 0 5 10 15 20 25

Inflation

11.2

11.4

11.6

11.8

12

12.2

12.4

12.6

-5 0 5 10 15 20 25

Output

2

2.2

2.4

2.6

2.8

3

3.2

3.4

3.6

3.8

-5 0 5 10 15 20 25

r

49 / 67

Application: Volcker Disinflation

0.002.004.006.008.00

10.0012.0014.0016.0018.0020.00

FFR

-0.04

-0.03

-0.02

-0.01

0

0.01

0.02

0.03

0.04

0.05

0.06

1980

-07-

0119

80-0

9-01

1980

-11-

0119

81-0

1-01

1981

-03-

0119

81-0

5-01

1981

-07-

0119

81-0

9-01

1981

-11-

0119

82-0

1-01

1982

-03-

0119

82-0

5-01

1982

-07-

0119

82-0

9-01

1982

-11-

0119

83-0

1-01

1983

-03-

0119

83-0

5-01

1983

-07-

0119

83-0

9-01

1983

-11-

0119

84-0

1-01

1984

-03-

0119

84-0

5-01

1984

-07-

01

Output

0.0

2.0

4.0

6.0

8.0

10.0

12.0

14.0

1980

-07-

0119

80-0

9-01

1980

-11-

0119

81-0

1-01

1981

-03-

0119

81-0

5-01

1981

-07-

0119

81-0

9-01

1981

-11-

0119

82-0

1-01

1982

-03-

0119

82-0

5-01

1982

-07-

0119

82-0

9-01

1982

-11-

0119

83-0

1-01

1983

-03-

0119

83-0

5-01

1983

-07-

0119

83-0

9-01

1983

-11-

0119

84-0

1-01

1984

-03-

0119

84-0

5-01

1984

-07-

01

Inflation

50 / 67

Adjustment from Positive Y P Shock

𝐴𝐴𝐴𝐴

𝑌𝑌0𝑃𝑃

𝜋𝜋𝑡𝑡−1

𝑌𝑌

𝜋𝜋 𝐿𝐿𝐿𝐿𝐴𝐴𝐴𝐴

𝐴𝐴𝐴𝐴

𝐴𝐴𝐴𝐴′

𝐿𝐿𝐿𝐿𝐴𝐴𝐴𝐴′

𝜋𝜋𝑡𝑡

𝑌𝑌𝑡𝑡 𝑌𝑌1𝑃𝑃

𝐴𝐴𝐴𝐴′′

𝜋𝜋𝑡𝑡+1

𝑌𝑌𝑡𝑡+1

𝐴𝐴𝐴𝐴′′′

𝜋𝜋𝑡𝑡+2

𝑌𝑌𝑡𝑡+2

51 / 67

Quantitative Adjustment from Positive Y P Shock

1

1.2

1.4

1.6

1.8

2

2.2

-5 0 5 10 15 20 25

Inflation

12

12.2

12.4

12.6

12.8

13

13.2

13.4

13.6

-5 0 5 10 15 20 25

Output

2

2.2

2.4

2.6

2.8

3

3.2

-5 0 5 10 15 20 25

r

52 / 67

Adjustment from One Period ρ Shock

𝐴𝐴𝐴𝐴

𝑌𝑌𝑃𝑃

𝜋𝜋𝑡𝑡−1

𝑌𝑌

𝜋𝜋 𝐿𝐿𝐿𝐿𝐴𝐴𝐴𝐴

𝐴𝐴𝐴𝐴

𝐴𝐴𝐴𝐴′

𝜋𝜋𝑡𝑡

𝑌𝑌𝑡𝑡

𝜋𝜋𝑡𝑡−1 + 1

𝐴𝐴𝐴𝐴′′

𝜋𝜋𝑡𝑡+1

𝑌𝑌𝑡𝑡+1

𝐴𝐴𝐴𝐴′′′

𝜋𝜋𝑡𝑡+2

𝑌𝑌𝑡𝑡+2

53 / 67

Quantitative Adjustment from Positive ρ Shock

1

1.2

1.4

1.6

1.8

2

2.2

2.4

2.6

2.8

-5 0 5 10 15 20 25

Inflation

11.2

11.4

11.6

11.8

12

12.2

12.4

12.6

-5 0 5 10 15 20 25

Output

2.7

2.8

2.9

3

3.1

3.2

3.3

3.4

3.5

3.6

3.7

-5 0 5 10 15 20 25

r

54 / 67

Application: Oil Shocks and Stagflation

0

0.02

0.04

0.06

0.08

0.1

0.12

Output

0.0

2.0

4.0

6.0

8.0

10.0

12.0

14.0

Inflation

55 / 67

Monetary Policy Objectives

I When it comes to the business cycle, monetary policy has adual mandate: it wants to stabilize inflation around some lowand stable rate and achieve “maximum employment”

I In the context of our model, we can think about the first halfof the mandate as keeping πt close to constant, and thesecond half as keeping Yt close to Y P

t

I Define the output gap as Xt = Yt − Y Pt

I Hence, objectives are to keep πt close to constant and Xt

close to zero

56 / 67

Monetary Policy Tools

I The primary tool of monetary policy (in this simple model) isthe parameter λ

I Governs how strongly policy reacts to inflation

I Recall algebraic expression for AD curve:

π = − 1−mpc

(d + x)λY +

1

(d + x)λA− 1

λr

I λ influences two things:I Slope of AD curve (bigger λ and AD curve is flatter)I Shift of AD curve conditional on IS shock, A (bigger λ and AD

curve shifts up less; horizontal shift of AD curve unaffected byλ)

57 / 67

λ and the Effects of IS Shocks

𝐴𝐴𝐴𝐴

𝑌𝑌0

𝜋𝜋0

𝑌𝑌

𝜋𝜋 𝐿𝐿𝐿𝐿𝐴𝐴𝐴𝐴

𝐴𝐴𝐴𝐴 (𝜆𝜆 𝑠𝑠𝑠𝑠𝑠𝑠𝑠𝑠𝑠𝑠)

𝐴𝐴𝐴𝐴 (𝜆𝜆 𝑏𝑏𝑏𝑏𝑏𝑏) 𝐴𝐴𝐴𝐴′

𝐴𝐴𝐴𝐴′

𝑌𝑌1

𝜋𝜋1 𝜋𝜋1′

𝑌𝑌1′

58 / 67

λ and IS Shocks

I After an increase in A, a bigger λ results in:

1. Smaller increase in π2. Smaller increase in Y . Since Y P doesn’t change, this means

that the gap, X , goes up by less

I Bigger λ is a “win-win” from perspective of dual mandateconditional on IS shocks

59 / 67

IS Shock: λ = 1 vs. λ = 10

11.21.41.61.8

22.22.42.62.8

3

-5 0 5 10 15 20 25

Inflation

lambda=1 lambda=10

12.212.312.412.512.612.712.812.9

1313.113.2

-5 0 5 10 15 20 25

Output

lambda=1 lambda=10

22.22.42.62.8

33.23.43.63.8

4

-5 0 5 10 15 20 25

r

lambda=1 lambda=10

60 / 67

λ and the Effects of Y P Shocks

𝐴𝐴𝐴𝐴

𝑌𝑌0𝑃𝑃

𝜋𝜋0

𝑌𝑌

𝜋𝜋 𝐿𝐿𝐿𝐿𝐴𝐴𝐴𝐴

𝐴𝐴𝐴𝐴 (𝜆𝜆 𝑠𝑠𝑠𝑠𝑠𝑠𝑠𝑠𝑠𝑠)

𝑌𝑌1𝑃𝑃

𝐿𝐿𝐿𝐿𝐴𝐴𝐴𝐴′

𝐴𝐴𝐴𝐴′

𝐴𝐴𝐴𝐴 (𝜆𝜆 𝑏𝑏𝑏𝑏𝑏𝑏)

𝜋𝜋1′

𝑌𝑌1′

𝜋𝜋1

𝑌𝑌1

61 / 67

λ and Potential Output Shocks

I After an increase in Y P , a bigger λ results in:

1. Smaller increase in π2. Bigger increase in Y . Since Y P increases, this means that the

gap, X , goes down by less the bigger is λ

I Bigger λ is a “win-win” from perspective of dual mandateconditional on potential output shocks shocks

62 / 67

Y P Shock: λ = 1 vs. λ = 10

0

0.5

1

1.5

2

2.5

-5 0 5 10 15 20 25

Inflation

lambda = 1 lambda=10

12

12.2

12.4

12.6

12.8

13

13.2

13.4

13.6

-5 0 5 10 15 20 25

Output

lambda = 1 lambda=10

2

2.2

2.4

2.6

2.8

3

3.2

-5 0 5 10 15 20 25

r

lambda=1 lambda=10-0.7

-0.6

-0.5

-0.4

-0.3

-0.2

-0.1

0-5 0 5 10 15 20 25

Output Gap

lambda=1 lambda=10

63 / 67

Divine Coincidence

I Divine Coincidence: there is no tradeoff between objectives ofmonetary policy

I Responding strongly to inflation both stabilizes inflation andthe output gap

I So named by Blanchard and Gali (2007)

I Forms the basis of the call for “inflation targeting,” eitherimplicity or explicitly done by several leading central banks

I Divine coincidence does not hold conditional on inflationshocks (ρ)

64 / 67

λ and the Effects of ρ Shocks

𝐴𝐴𝐴𝐴

𝑌𝑌0

𝜋𝜋0

𝑌𝑌

𝜋𝜋 𝐿𝐿𝐿𝐿𝐴𝐴𝐴𝐴

𝐴𝐴𝐴𝐴 (𝜆𝜆 𝑠𝑠𝑠𝑠𝑠𝑠𝑠𝑠𝑠𝑠)

𝐴𝐴𝐴𝐴′

𝜋𝜋1

𝑌𝑌1

𝜋𝜋0 + 1

𝐴𝐴𝐴𝐴 (𝜆𝜆 𝑏𝑏𝑏𝑏𝑏𝑏)

𝑌𝑌1′

𝜋𝜋1′

65 / 67

ρ Shock: λ = 1 vs. λ = 10

1

1.2

1.4

1.6

1.8

2

2.2

2.4

2.6

2.8

-5 0 5 10 15 20 25

Inflation

lambda=1 lambda=10

9.5

10

10.5

11

11.5

12

12.5

13

-5 0 5 10 15 20 25

Output

lambda=1 lambda=10

2.72.82.9

33.13.23.33.43.53.63.7

-5 0 5 10 15 20 25

r

lambda=1 lambda=10

66 / 67

Inflation Shocks and the Inflation-Gap Tradeoff

I Big λ: flat AD, little change in inflation, but big drop inoutput

I Small λ: steep AD, little change in output, but big increase ininflation

I Central bank faces a tradeoff: cannot simultaneously achievestable inflation and stable output gap conditional on inflationshocks

67 / 67