new tools for improving government

32
Grant Report October 1999 The PricewaterhouseCoopers Endowment for The Business of Government New Tools for Improving Government Regulation: An Assessment of Emissions Trading and Other Market- Based Regulatory Tools Gary C. Bryner Director Natural Resources Law Center School of Law University of Colorado

Upload: others

Post on 28-Oct-2021

2 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: New Tools for Improving Government

G r a n t R e p o r t

October 1999

The PricewaterhouseCoopers Endowment for

The Business of Government

New Tools for Improving Government

Regulation: An Assessment of

Emissions Trading and Other Market-

Based Regulatory Tools

Gary C. BrynerDirectorNatural Resources Law CenterSchool of LawUniversity of Colorado

Page 2: New Tools for Improving Government

About The EndowmentThrough grants for Research, Thought Leadership Forums, andthe SES Leadership Program, The PricewaterhouseCoopersEndowment for The Business of Government stimulatesresearch and facilitates discussion on new approaches toimproving the effectiveness of government at the federal, state,local, and international levels. All grants are competitive.

Founded in 1998 by PricewaterhouseCoopers, The Endowmentis one of the ways that PricewaterhouseCoopers seeks toadvance knowledge on how to improve public sector effec-tiveness. The PricewaterhouseCoopers Endowment focuses on the future of the operation and management of the publicsector.

The PricewaterhouseCoopers Endowment for

The Business of Government

Page 3: New Tools for Improving Government

New Tools for Improving Government Regulation 1

New Tools for Improving

Government Regulation:

An Assessment of Emissions Trading and

Other Market-Based Regulatory Tools

Gary C. BrynerDirector

Natural Resources Law CenterSchool of Law

University of Colorado

October 1999

Page 4: New Tools for Improving Government

2 New Tools for Improving Government Regulation

TABLE OF CONTENTS

Foreword ......................................................................................3

Executive Summary ......................................................................4

Introduction ................................................................................6

Study FindingsEmissions Trading Programs in Place ......................................9

Federal Government Emissions Trading Programs..........................................................................9State and Local Government Emissions Trading Programs ..........................................................11Other Countries’ Experience with Emissions Trading Programs ..........................................................14

Results of Emissions Trading Programs..................................14Reducing Regulatory Costs ............................................15Achieving Environmental Goals ....................................17Enhancing Governmental Capacity ................................19

Conclusions and Recommendations ..........................................21

Notes ..........................................................................................24

About the Author........................................................................27

Key Contact Information ............................................................28

Page 5: New Tools for Improving Government

New Tools for Improving Government Regulation 3

Foreword

October 1999

On behalf of The PricewaterhouseCoopers Endowment for The Business of Government, we are pleased to publish what is now our sixth research grant report. This report by Gary Bryner, “New Tools forImproving Government Regulation: An Assessment of Emissions Trading and Other Market-BasedRegulatory Tools,” provides a comprehensive overview of this regulatory tool on the federal, state, andinternational level, and offers recommendations as to when and how it can be effectively used.

Market-based approaches to environmental regulation are popular tools for achieving environmentalresults. Emissions trading has fostered innovation, saved companies money, and reduced emissions thatcause smog problems. The principle of emissions trading is to use market incentives to achieve environ-mental objectives at the lowest possible cost. Emissions trading programs can provide a powerful incentivefor pollution sources to reduce the amount of pollutants emitted into the atmosphere, and then sell theexcess allowances to others.

Although not a cure-all for the problems of environmental regulation, emissions trading programs can helpthe environment and the economy. If structured correctly, emissions trading programs should create a fun-damental shift in practices that affect the environment, and not just a one-time decrease in emissions. Theresearch and recommendations contained in Professor Bryner’s research will shed light on how and underwhat circumstances a successful emissions trading program should be structured, and will further under-standing of market-based regulatory tools. We hope that you find this report informative and helpful.

Paul Lawrence Ian LittmanPartner, PricewaterhouseCoopers Partner, PricewaterhouseCoopersCo-Chair, Endowment Advisory Board Co-Chair, Endowment Advisory [email protected] [email protected]

The PricewaterhouseCoopers Endowment for

The Business of Government

Page 6: New Tools for Improving Government

4 New Tools for Improving Government Regulation

Critics of environmental regulation argue that cur-rent pollution control policies are inefficient, andthat it is too costly to impose nationwide standardson sources of pollution that differ according tolocal conditions. They believe it makes little sense,from an economic perspective, to require allsources to comply with these regulations, eventhough the cost of compliance varies considerablyacross sources. Regulations that mandate specificcontrol technologies lock industries into existingequipment and processes, and fail to create incen-tives for industries to develop new, cleaner, moreefficient technologies.

One of the most important and popular remediesfor the ills that many believe plague environmentalregulation is the use of market-based approaches toregulation. The purpose of this report is to examinethe use of emissions trading in air pollution regula-tion, the most widely used market-based regulatorytool, discuss its strengths and limitations in regulato-ry programs, and suggest when and how emissionstrading might best be employed in environmentalregulation.

Market-based regulatory tools, particularly emis-sions trading programs, promise to dramaticallyreduce the cost of achieving environmental goals,while giving regulated industries more flexibility,and to streamline the tasks of regulatory agencies.In emissions trading, polluters are allocated a limit-ed number of allowances, or units, of emissions forrelease into the environment. Companies can eithermake the changes necessary to stay within the lim-its or buy allowances from others. Tradable emis-

sion permits can be saved or banked for future use,or sold by polluting companies as long as limits ontotal emissions are not exceeded. Polluters have anincentive to reduce their emissions beyond theirallowances so that they can generate revenuesthrough the sale of their excess allowances. Totalemissions can be reduced over time by decreasingthe number of allowances distributed to pollutionsources.

Emissions trading programs were the basis of thenational acid rain program that reduced emissionsfrom coal-fired power plants, and are part of manystate programs to achieve national air quality stan-dards and other environmental goals. Emissionstrading and other market incentives will continueto play a central role in dealing with problems suchas acid rain and ozone depletion, and are expectedby many to be a central element of whatever effortsthe United States and other countries undertake toachieve the goals agreed to under the KyotoProtocol for climate change.

Emissions trading makes sense in addressing someregulatory tasks, such as giving sources more flexi-bility by allowing them to meet facility-wide emis-sion limits rather than imposing standards on eachsource. Emissions trading may be a critical elementin generating political support for new regulatoryinitiatives.

However, the popularity of emissions trading posesa risk: It may be seen as a panacea for the prob-lems of regulation and be used in situations whereits disadvantages outweigh its advantages. Emissions

Executive Summary

Page 7: New Tools for Improving Government

New Tools for Improving Government Regulation 5

trading, if not carefully designed and integratedwith other regulatory requirements, can createproblems such as high concentrations of pollutantsin some areas, particularly those where low-income residents live. Trading may undermine the power of moral arguments that pollution shouldbe reduced and challenges the principle that allsources of pollution should reduce emissions. Itmay fail to create incentives for the development or dissemination of new control technologies.Trading requires emissions monitoring equipmentand processes that may simply not be in place. Itrequires regulatory officials and managers of regu-lated facilities to take risks with new approaches to regulation.

Experience suggests that emissions trading pro-grams work best when they are based on accurateemissions information, are built on emission limitsthat give adequate protection to environmentalquality and natural resources, are stable, pre-dictable, and rigorously enforced, and are com-bined with requirements that sources make someminimum emissions reductions. In addition, emis-sions trading programs need to be seen as a step-ping-stone to other policies that increase the extentto which the true costs of production are includedin the prices charged, and they need to createmore effective incentives to reduce pollution andencourage economic activities that are ecologicallysustainable.

Page 8: New Tools for Improving Government

6 New Tools for Improving Government Regulation

Environmental policy in the United States is a studyin paradox. Public opinion polls and other measuresof public sentiment show strong support for environ-mental regulation.1 Recent reports have found thatsignificant progress has been made towards improv-ing environmental quality; the nation’s air and wateris cleaner; national programs are helping implementnew international agreements to reduce global envi-ronmental risks; threats to children’s health posed bylead in the environment have diminished; farmersare reducing soil erosion and pesticide runoff intostreams; and industries are reducing their release oftoxic pollutants.2

Despite this progress, reforming environmental lawand regulation has become a regular refrain ofAmerican politics and policy-making. As soon asthe ink was dry on the first modern federal environ-mental laws, critics began questioning whetherthey were too expensive and intrusive. As theframework of environmental law developed into acomplex maze of statutes, rules, and agencies, agrowing number of voices from a variety of per-spectives have called for changes in the way inwhich we regulate pollution and pursue environ-mental quality.

One of the most important and popular remediesfor the ills that many believe plague environmentalregulation is the use of market-based approaches toregulation. In the conventional, or command-and-control, approach to regulation, federal agenciesissue national standards that apply to all sources inall areas, and agency officials mandate specifictechnologies and compliance actions. Market-based regulatory tools seek to create incentives forcompanies to find the most cost-effective ways ofreducing emissions. This gives companies the flexi-bility to devise their own methods for achieving thereductions required of them.

There are several kinds of market-like mechanismsthat might be employed in environmental regulation:

• monetary incentives, including taxes, fees, subsidies, and tax incentives;

• government-created markets for buying, selling,saving, and trading emissions;

• deposit/refund systems that discourage disposaland encourage collection or recycling of pollution-producing materials;

Introduction*

* I am pleased to acknowledge the many colleagues, scholars, government officials, and activists with whom I have discussed, overthe past decade, market-based regulatory tools and other ideas for improving environmental regulation. I have received helpful com-ments and suggestions in exchanges with discussants and other participants at conferences of the American Political ScienceAssociation, Western Political Science Association, and the Association for Policy Analysis and Management; reviewers for and edi-tors of books I have written on environmental policy with CQ Press, St. Martin’s Press, and W.W. Norton and Company; policy ana-lysts at the Office of Technology Assessment; members of the Clean Air Network; and Sheldon Kamieniecki, George A. Gonzalez,and Robert O. Vos, editors of Flashpoints in Environmental Policymaking, State University of New York Press, 1997. I wish to thankMark A. Abramson for his interest in and support of the project, Susan Mitchell for the many improvements she made to the paper,Stuart Fribush and Barry Korb for many helpful comments and suggestions, and The PricewaterhouseCoopers Endowment for TheBusiness of Government for its interest in and commitment to improving the effectiveness of government.

Page 9: New Tools for Improving Government

New Tools for Improving Government Regulation 7

• disclosure of information to consumers;

• environmental auditing and releasing publicdata on kinds and levels of emissions;

• government procurement policies.3

The two most controversial instruments are pollu-tion charges and emissions trading. Pollutioncharges, or taxes, are levied on emissions of pollu-tants or on input to activities producing pollutants.Polluters are charged a fee for each unit of pollu-tion they emit. A pollution tax or fee, if it is highenough, can provide a strong incentive for compa-nies to reduce their emissions in whatever way ismost efficient for them, such as closing down someoperations, using cleaner fuels, investing in controltechnologies, or changing work practices. It alsoprovides a clear incentive for reducing emissionsbelow permitted levels.

In emissions trading, polluters are allocated a limited number of allowances or units of emissionsfor release into the environment. Companies caneither make the changes necessary to stay withinthe limits, or they can buy allowances from others.Tradable emission permits can be saved or bankedfor future use, or sold by polluting companies aslong as limits on total emissions are not exceeded.Polluters have an incentive to reduce their emis-sions beyond the allowances given to them so thatthey can generate revenues through the sale ofexcess allowances.4 Over time, decreasing thenumber of allowances distributed to pollutionsources can reduce total emissions further.

The use of market-based regulatory tools raisesthree primary questions, which are addressed in this report.

1. How well do market-based approaches helpachieve their goal of reducing the costs of compliance and making regulation more costeffective?

Given the billions of dollars spent on pollutioncontrol and cleanup ($140 billion a year accord-ing to some estimates) there are strong expecta-tions that market-based tools can significantlyreduce the cost of environmental regulation.

Market-Based Tools for Environmental Regulation5

Deposit/Refund Payments required when Systems purchasing products or

containers that are refunded when products/containers are returned

Emissions Sources are allocated Trading emission permits that can

be bought, sold, or tradedin order to meet levels ofemissions permitted

Fees Payments for services pro-vided, such as monitoringof emissions or treatment of pollutants

Government Purchases by governments Procurement of products that have desir-

able impacts on environ-mental quality

Reporting Sources of emissions are Requirements required to disclose to the

public information on thekinds and quantities of pollutants released

Subsidies Direct payments to encour-age or discourage emissionsproduction, conservation,or other behavior

Tax Incentives Reductions or increases in taxes to encourage ordiscourage behavior

Taxes (Pollution Mandatory payments forCharges) the release of pollutants

and wastes based on thequantity of discharges

Page 10: New Tools for Improving Government

8 New Tools for Improving Government Regulation

2. To what extent do these regulatory tools con-tribute to the achievement of environmentalquality goals?

No matter how well market instruments reducethe costs of spending on pollution control, theprimary question is whether environmental problems have been effectively remedied andnatural resources protected.

3. How do market-based instruments facilitate theefficient and effective functioning of regulatoryagencies, and contribute to the capacity of governments at all levels to achieve their policy goals?

The successes and failures of every major policyeffort accumulate in ways that, over time,strengthen or weaken our ability to collectivelysolve common problems.

Emissions trading programs are the most popularmarket-based regulatory tools that the United Statesgovernment is experimenting with, because of theirpromise to reduce compliance costs, increase theflexibility given regulated industries, improve theefficiency and effectiveness of regulatory agencies,and achieve environmental and public healthgoals. It is for these reasons that they are the prima-ry focus of this paper.

Emissions trading programs have been enthusiasti-cally embraced by both regulated industries andpolicy makers, and have become part of virtuallyevery policy proposal currently before Congressand state and federal environmental protectionagencies. It is difficult to imagine a new regulatoryprogram being proposed that does not include atleast some form of emissions trading.

This study focuses on three categories of tradingprograms and proposals:

1. federal emissions trading programs under thefederal Clean Air Act, including sulfur dioxideemissions in the acid rain program, and othernational efforts, which were the earliest efforts todevise emissions trading programs;

2. state innovations, such as Southern California’sSouth Coast Air Quality Management District’sRECLAIM program for trading sulfur and nitro-gen oxide emissions;

3. trading programs in other advanced industrial-ized democracies.

This mix of regulatory innovations at different levelsof government, for different environmental prob-lems, and for different countries provides a broadbase for examining the advantages and disadvan-tages of market-based regulatory tools and theirimplications for improving the management of reg-ulatory agencies.

Emissions trading programs are also being used todeal with other environmental problems, such asreducing water pollution and the generation andstorage of hazardous wastes, but space does notpermit a discussion of all trading programs here.6

The experience of emissions trading in air pollutionprograms can provide important lessons for its usein addressing other pollution problems.

Emissions trading programs are quite new, so defin-itive studies of their costs and benefits will come in the future. But given the tremendous interest inthem, this study seeks to assess the strengths andweaknesses of trading programs, based on the lim-ited experience with them, and suggests questionsthat policy makers and others should ask beforethey embrace market-based tools, particularlyemissions trading, as a way to improve the effec-tiveness of existing regulatory programs and designthe next generation of environmental laws andpolicies.

Page 11: New Tools for Improving Government

New Tools for Improving Government Regulation 9

Emissions Trading Programs in Place

Federal Government Emissions Trading ProgramsThe U.S. Environmental Protection Agency (EPA)has experimented with a number of emissions trad-ing programs. Beginning in 1974, the agency insti-tuted the first trading program, the Offset Program.The Offset Program required that new sourcesbeginning operation in areas that have not metnational air quality standards must buy enoughemission reductions to offset their projected emis-sions, plus purchase an additional percentage ofreductions in order to contribute to the attainmentof the air quality standards. Most of the credits pur-chased for offsets have come from the closing ofexisting facilities. One study estimated that morethan 10,000 tons of pollutants have been boughtand sold through offsets for more than $2 billion,but it is difficult to gain information because thesetrades are private transactions.7

If new emissions come from an expansion of anexisting source, the increase can be offset frominternal sources through a process called “netting.”Netting has become the most commonly used trad-ing program, because it has fewer restrictions thanoffsets. Owners of existing facilities frequently con-struct new sources, and they can use the nettingprocess to avoid the costs and delays associatedwith obtaining permits to operate new sources ofpollution. One of the EPA’s most recent innova-tions, the Environmental Excellence and LeadershipProgram, or “XL” program, includes pilot projectsthat allow facilities to alter their mix of emissions

without having to obtain a new operating permit as long as total emissions do not exceed the facility’s cap.8

The second EPA trading program, proposed in 1979and put in place in 1986, was the bubble policy.This policy allowed companies to receive credit foremissions reductions in a specified area, as opposedto an individual location. Total emissions from eachfacility could be viewed as encapsulated within alarge “bubble,” rather than from individual smoke-stacks. Or two new adjoining power plants coulduse the bubble concept to combine their emissions.Regulatory officials established maximum totalallowable emissions and left managers free to deter-mine optimal emissions from individual sources, sothat total compliance costs could be minimized. Bythe mid-1980s, the EPA had approved some 50bubbles, and states had approved many more undertheir authority. Bubbles are still used to give facili-ties some flexibility in meeting emission limits.9

A third experiment with trading began with thephase out of lead in gasoline in 1979, when theEPA limited the average lead content permitted forlarge refiners. These refiners could average the con-tent of leaded and unleaded gasoline in order toshow compliance. In order to meet reduction goalsrequired by 1982 and beyond, the EPA allowedrefiners and importers of fuels who reduced thelead content of their fuel below the new EPA stan-dards to sell earned credits to other refiners orimporters. This was done by allowing them to aver-age the lead content of leaded and unleaded fuel.

Study Findings

Page 12: New Tools for Improving Government

10 New Tools for Improving Government Regulation

Banking was discontinued in 1987, when all fuelswere required to meet the standard, and the pro-gram was terminated in 1996 when all leadedgasoline for highway use was banned.

Other national programs authorized in the 1990Clean Air Act Amendments have used tradingmechanisms or variations. The Stratospheric OzoneProtection Program established a marketable permitsystem for producers and importers of chlorofluoro-carbons (CFCs). Under this program, the EPAallows manufacturers of heavy-duty engines tomeet emission standards by averaging emissionsacross their entire production and allows averagingbetween manufacturers. The Air Toxics EarlyReduction Program allows sources of toxic pollu-tants that reduce emissions by 90 percent beforenational emission standards for hazardous air pollutants are proposed, to be able to delay theircompliance with those standards when they areeventually issued.10

The EPA has also mandated emission limits fornitrogen oxide emissions (NOx) from electric utili-ties in the 12 Northeastern states and the District ofColumbia in an effort to reduce ozone pollution.The Ozone Transportation Commission’s (OTC)NOx Budget Program is in effect from May toNovember of each year, beginning in 1999. NOxallowances are allocated to sources in each of thestates and the District of Columbia. These unitsmay set up trading systems to implement the pro-gram and achieve the emissions goals. The emis-sions trading program will spread to 22 states in2003. Interstate emissions trading for the OTCstates, and an additional 24 Eastern states, is alsobeing developed.11

One of the most important innovations of the CleanAir Act of 1990 was the market-based incentive sys-tem to reduce acid-rain-producing emissions fromcoal-fired power plants through a nationwide capand trade system. The first set of major rules toimplement the sulfur dioxide (SO2) allowance tradingprogram was issued in 1993 and took effect in 1995.The heart of the acid rain emissions trading system isa cap on total emissions projected by the year 2010,which will result in a reduction of sulfur dioxideemissions of 10 million tons from 1980 levels. Theplan is implemented in two phases. In phase one,110 plants in 21 Midwestern and Eastern states were

Emissions Trading in Federal Government Program

Offsets New sources beginning operationin areas that have not met nationalair quality standards buy enoughemission reductions to offset thenew source’s projected emissions,plus an additional percentage ofreductions so that the new sourcehelps contribute to the attainmentof the air quality standards.

Netting If new emissions come fromexpansion of an existing source,the increase can be offset frominternal sources, through netting,so that the facility’s owners canavoid the costs and delays associ-ated with obtaining permits tooperate new sources of pollution.

Bubbles Companies can receive credit foremissions reductions in someareas for higher emissions else-where; total emissions from eachfacility are viewed as encapsulat-ed within a large “bubble,” ratherthan from individual smokestacks.

Averaging Producers of products beingphased out, such as leaded gaso-line and heavy-duty engines, havebeen allowed to show complianceby using an average of their prod-ucts, rather than being required toshow that every product complieswith the standard.

Early Sources of pollutants can gain Reduction credits or delay compliance with

future standards if they reduceemissions before reductions arerequired.

Cap and Allowances are allocated toTrade sources; a cap on total allowances

is set and ratcheted down to meetenvironmental goals; sources canbuy, sell, or trade allowances inorder to meet their emission limits.

Page 13: New Tools for Improving Government

New Tools for Improving Government Regulation 11

given allowances in the 1990 act. An allowance is apermit to emit one ton of sulfur dioxide. Allowanceshave been allocated for the years 1995 through2030 (they cannot be used for compliance until theyears for which they are designated). In phase two,the number of sources included in the program willbe greatly expanded. The allowances for thesesources are allocated by a formula based on theamount of fuel the plants used during a base-yearperiod. The number of allowances will be capped at8.95 million tons per year by 2010, when the pro-gram is fully implemented. Plants that are able tocontrol emissions below the levels allocated to themcan save them for future use, or trade or sell theirexcess emission permits to others who exceed theirallowance. Transactions do not need to be approvedby the EPA.

The first trade of acid rain allowances occurred in1992. The EPA also auctions a small fraction of thetotal allowances allocated each year at an annualauction. The first auction of SO2 allowances tookplace in 1993. Anyone can bid for allowances, and all allowances are sold each year. The proceedsof the auction are distributed to the sources fromwhich the allowances were withheld. Auctionsinclude spot allowances, which are only valid for the immediate year, and advance allowances,which are valid for future years. Participatingsources must meet stringent monitoring require-ments, usually through continuous emissions monitoring.

Emissions trading is also central to the developingU.S. policy for climate change. In October 1997,the Clinton administration proposed a five-year, $5 billion program of tax incentives and researchand development aimed at reducing carbon diox-ide emissions that included an emissions tradingscheme for greenhouse gases that would cut emis-sions by 30 percent from projected levels in 2008.Sources that moved early to reduce emissionswould get credits that they could use later whenand if allowances are issued. The trading systemwould eventually expand internationally, and U.S.companies could buy and sell their allowances toemit greenhouse gases and encourage the mostcost-effective ways of reducing emissions.12 A 1998Clinton plan called for achieving up to 75 percentof the reductions by purchasing allowances fromEastern Europe.13

A bipartisan group of senators has recently intro-duced legislation that would amend the Clean AirAct to allow the president to make binding agree-ments with U.S. businesses that reduce their green-house gas emissions to get credit for those reduc-tions if and when a mandatory program is devised.The legislation’s future is uncertain. Industry groupshave sent conflicting signals to Congress. Somehave opposed the early credit scheme because itmay encourage the ratification of the KyotoProtocol. Others favor it as a useful protection forcompanies that make early reductions voluntarilyin case binding reductions are later mandated.14

State and Local Government Emissions TradingProgramsThere is considerable variety across the states interms of the specific elements of emissions tradingprograms. (See page 12).15 As of early 1999, 14states have developed air pollution reduction programs that include some variation on the ideaof emissions trading.16 The programs were createdbetween 1994 and 1998. The purpose of state-levelprograms is primarily to help bring the areas intoattainment of national ambient air quality stan-dards. The pollutants are particulate matter (PM),ozone, sulfur dioxide, nitrogen oxide, lead, andcarbon monoxide. (Emissions of lead, the otherpollutant regulated through national air qualitystandards, have fallen so dramatically, as a result of unleaded fuel, that lead is no longer a majorconcern of air pollution regulation.)

Most state programs are voluntary; regulatedsources need not bank or sell or otherwise trade inemission allowances. If sources do choose to par-ticipate, they typically must demonstrate thatreductions used to claim credits are quantifiable,real reductions in emissions, subject to enforceablerequirements, surplus, and represent permanentreductions. Credits usually have a 10-year life.Some programs are limited to stationary sources,such as power plants and factories, while othersinclude the creation of credits through vehiclescrappage programs, and some include reductionsfrom area sources such as off-road equipment, consumer products, small commercial facilities,and other dispersed sources. Some states allowsources themselves to verify the creation of surplusallowances, while others require independent

Page 14: New Tools for Improving Government

California allows sources that exceed emissions ofvolatile organic compounds (VOCs) for one productto offset them by “overcomplying” with the stan-dards for other products. Regulations issued in 1997provide guidelines for interchangeable air pollutionemission reduction credits for local air pollutioncontrol districts. They establish a uniform credit cur-rency, expressed in pounds of pollutant in the yeargenerated, for trades between stationary, mobile,and area sources for all the criteria pollutantsexcept lead. The state also has in place several mar-ket-based measures to encourage the early retire-ment of motor vehicles and the use of cleanerfuels.17

Colorado’s generic emissions trading and bankingprogram, adopted in 1996, allows sources to gener-ate emission reduction credits by shutting down orcurtailing production or by changing processes ormaterials. Mobile credits can be generated by scrap-ping high-emitting vehicles and replacing them withlower-emitting ones, switching to cleaner fuels, andtrip reduction plans. One city, Telluride, requiresresidents who seek a permit to install new fireplacesor wood-burning stoves to turn into thecity two existing fireplace/stove permits for everynew permit granted.18

Connecticut began allowing trading and banking ofnitrogen oxide emissions for both stationary andmobile sources in 1995. Credits generated outsideof the summer ozone season cannot be used withinthe season. Mobile source credits are discounted by10 percent.

Delaware’s trading and banking program, adoptedin 1996, includes NOx and VOCs; the state dis-counts credits by 10 percent in order to improve airquality. Reductions occurring after January 1, 1991,are eligible. Trading between mobile and stationarysources is permitted, as is trading with sources out-side of the state and within the Northeast OzoneTransport Region.

Georgia, in a program approved in 1998, allowsowners of vehicle fleets to earn credits for theirvehicles that exceed federal clean-fueled fleetrequirements; they can bank them for future use orsell them to other fleet owners. Fleets include 10 ormore vehicles that are centrally fueled. Owners can

earn credit by purchasing clean-fueled vehicles ear-lier than required, purchasing more than is required,or purchasing those with emissions cleaner thanrequired by federal standards.

Illinois instituted a pilot program in 1993 of buyingand scrapping pre-1980 automobiles. The state pur-chased vehicles for between $600 and $1,000 andmeasures the tailpipe emissions and fuel evapora-tion before destroying them.19 The program now per-mits “allotment trading units” to be earned by scrap-ping vehicles. Stationary sources operating in areasthat violate national air quality standards may buythese allotments and use them to meet emissionlimits.

A Louisiana trading program, promulgated in 1994,is in effect only in areas with current or past ozonepollution problems, and includes sources of NOxand VOCs. Stationary sources may obtainallowances by scrapping vehicles; motorists arepaid the fair market value of their vehicles.

Maine approved in 1998 a trading program for sta-tionary sources of NOx and VOCs. Credits can begenerated by any permanent change in emissionsand have an unlimited life — they can be bankedand used anytime in the future. Credits obtainedfrom another New England state require a 15 per-cent surcharge (if a source needing 100 tons ofcredits buys them from outside the state, it mustpurchase 115 tons of credit; if the source is outsideof New England but still within the NortheastOzone Transport Region, it must buy two times therequired credits). NOx credits can be used to offsetVOC emissions and vice versa.20

Massachusetts’ Innovative Market Program for AirCredit Trading, for NOx, VOCs, and carbon monox-ide (CO), was placed in operation in 1994 and is ineffect statewide. Credits can be generated throughimplementing more stringent controls, sourcereduction, fuel switching, energy conservation, fleetconversions, lawn and garden equipment trade-in,vehicle scrappage, or ride sharing. Inter-pollutanttrading is not allowed. Massachusetts was the firststate to have its economic incentives programapproved by the EPA; since October 1996, the statehas not been required to gain EPA approval of eachcredit generated and used.21

State Emissions Trading Programs

12 New Tools for Improving Government Regulation

Page 15: New Tools for Improving Government

verification. Different states allow or prohibit inter-pollutant trading. Many states build into their trading program a requirement that the value ofcredits be reduced or discounted in order todecrease emissions over time and ensure that airquality improves.22

One of the most ambitious emissions tradingschemes has been developed in southernCalifornia. The South Coast Air Quality Manage-ment District (SCAQMD), the agency responsiblefor addressing the greater Los Angeles area’s airpollution problems, put in place an emissions trad-ing program called the Regional Clean AirIncentives Market, or RECLAIM, in 1994. RECLAIMaffects some 350 sources in the Los Angeles areathat produce at least four tons of nitrogen or sulfuroxide emissions a year. These sources are requiredto reduce their emissions by a fixed percentageeach year for the regulated pollutants. They aregiven an annual allocation of allowances and arefree to find the most cost-effective means to reduceemissions. Sources that reduce emissions of nitro-gen and sulfur oxide beyond the caps imposed onthem may sell their excess credits, called RegionalTrading Credits, to companies that have exceededtheir limits.23

A brief mention should be made of a number ofother market-based incentive programs that stateshave devised that do not involve trading systems,but are reflective of the range of possibilities formaking environmental regulation more efficient.Maryland, for instance, was the first state to insti-tute a “gas guzzler” law that imposes a surchargeon the sale of cars that consume high levels of fueland gives a rebate to buyers of fuel-efficient auto-mobiles.24 Florida and California have developedcongestion pricing programs that vary the price oftraffic on toll roads, depending on the time of dayand level of congestion. Since 1994, MaricopaCounty, Arizona, has had in place a trip reductionprogram that includes several market-based incen-tives such as parking charges, preferential parkingfor carpool vehicles, and subsidies and prize draw-ings to encourage the use of alternative modes oftransportation.25

Michigan’s Emission Trading Program, establishedin 1996, applies to all criteria pollutants and isavailable to all stationary, mobile, and areasources. Credits are discounted by 10 percent inorder to contribute to improved air quality andcan be used for up to five years.

New Hampshire adopted an Emissions ReductionCredits Training Program in 1997 to reduce NOx,VOC, and CO emissions from stationary, mobile,and area sources. The goal of the program is notto reduce emissions but to give sources subject tocontrol requirements flexibility and opportunitiesto reduce compliance costs. Credits generated byfacility shutdowns cannot be traded; if the sourcedoes not use them, they become public creditsthat state officials can use to create or retain jobsin the state. Credits cannot be banked for futureuse.

New Jersey’s Open Market Emissions Trading pro-gram, established in 1996, authorizes the creation, use, and trading of emissions reductionsfrom stationary or mobile sources for NOx and VOCs. Credits must be verified by an inde-pendent party, such as a licensed professionalengineer or certified public accountant. Inter-pollutant trades are not allowed. Credits are discounted by 10 percent. Sources may also purchase credits from sources in other states tothe west or south.

New York’s New Source Review Offset Program,promulgated in 1994, allows credits only to beused to offset the introduction of new sources.Credits are not discounted and have unlimitedlife. All types of emission reductions are allowed,including shutdowns.

Pennsylvania’s Nitrogen Oxide AllowanceRequirements Program, approved in 1997, operates during the summer ozone season. It is a mandatory cap-and-trade program: fossil-fuel-powered electric-generating plants are allocated a certain number of allowances each season;sources may trade allowances in demonstratingthat their emissions are within the allowancesallocated. Other kinds of sources may voluntarilyopt-in the program.

New Tools for Improving Government Regulation 13

Page 16: New Tools for Improving Government

14 New Tools for Improving Government Regulation

Other Countries’ Experience with EmissionsTrading ProgramsAs is true in the United States, European countriesprimarily rely on traditional, or command-and-con-trol, approaches to environmental regulation. Mostof the advanced industrialized democracies ofWestern Europe — countries that are members ofthe Organisation for Economic Co-operation andDevelopment (Canada, Japan, and the UnitedStates are also members of OECD) — have increas-ingly devised and implemented market-based inno-vations to regulation, but have selected approachesmuch different from the emissions trading programsthat have been employed in the U.S.

In the 1970s and 1980s, a number of these countries instituted emissions taxes and charges. By 1987, approximately 80 different environmentaltaxes and charges were in place in 14 OECD countries. Between 1987 and 1993, the number of economic instruments used in environmentalregulation increased by 50 percent. In the 1990s,OECD countries increasingly turned to “green”taxes to create financial incentives for environmen-tal protection. The initial policy debate focused on whether countries should embrace traditionalcommand-and-control regulation or market-basedinstruments. That question is now largely obsolete,as virtually every OECD country relies on a mix

of both approaches, with market-based programstypically used as adjuncts to traditional regulatoryschemes to create additional incentives for reduc-ing emissions and/or to generate resources for otherenvironmental protection efforts.26

Few European countries have followed the UnitedStates’ lead in developing tradable emissions per-mit systems. German air pollution law allowssources to transfer emission reduction obligations,but that rarely occurs. The Netherlands has a bub-ble policy for power plants that allows facilities totreat all emissions from one facility as one source.Australia, Canada, and the United Kingdom haveconsidered pollution trading policies, but no coun-try has embraced the idea of emissions tradingexcept the United States.

Europeans have chosen, instead, to focus on greentaxes. Denmark, Finland, Norway, Sweden, and theNetherlands, for example, have all introduced car-bon taxes. Many countries have imposed ecotaxeson leaded gasoline, pesticides, fertilizers, chemi-cals, batteries, lubricants, and packaging.

Europeans also have in place high energy taxes thatlend themselves to restructuring for environmentalpurposes. They are also becoming increasinglyinterested in identifying tax and spending subsidiesthat result in environmental harm, such as free

Examples of Market-Based Instruments in European Environmental Regulation

Water Effluent Charges France and other countries use these charges to finance pollutioncontrol facilities.

Ecotaxes Sweden uses taxes to encourage reduction of sulfur content of fuels. Norway taxes carbon dioxide emissions from stationary sources and

motor vehicles.Denmark has increased taxes on non-hazardous wastes to encourage

recycling.Most countries impose high taxes on gasoline to encourage

conservation.

Deposit/Refund Systems Several countries in Europe require deposits for aluminum cans, plastic containers, and glass beverage bottles.

Emissions Trading Rarely used; the Netherlands has a bubble policy in place.

Page 17: New Tools for Improving Government

New Tools for Improving Government Regulation 15

parking and company vehicles for employees,which encourages driving; reduced taxes for dieselfuels; subsidies for coal and water development;and agricultural payments.

Some countries, particularly the Scandinaviannations, are transforming their entire tax system tobe more environmentally friendly. Sweden’s 1991tax reform law reduced income taxes and replacedthe lost revenue with new taxes on carbon, sulfur,and nitrogen oxides. Denmark has shifted taxesfrom labor and income to pollution and scarce natural resources. The Netherlands has a number ofecotaxes that generate about 2.5 percent of thenation’s total tax revenue.27

Results of Emissions TradingProgramsEmissions trading is an important and useful inno-vation in environmental regulation in the UnitedStates. As the experience with this regulatory toolin federal and state environmental programs shows,pollution trading can reduce the compliance costsof regulated industries and give them more flexibil-ity to meet emission goals, and can also help gen-erate political support for new regulatory programsand serve as the basis for fashioning compromisesacceptable to a wide range of interests. Carefullydesigned programs can simplify some of the regu-latory tasks for government agencies and reducecompliance burdens that fall on regulated sources.

Trading programs may reduce the cost of achievingexpensive environmental goals to acceptable levels, and may make it possible to take on envi-ronmental problems that otherwise are notaddressed. They may encourage the diffusion of rel-atively inexpensive control technologies thatreduce emissions enough to achieve environmentalstandards when combined with the purchase ofemission credits. Most importantly, emissions trading can serve as a transition to a more effectiveset of market-based regulatory instruments.

However, trading should be used with caution.Emissions trading, if not carefully designed andintegrated with minimum standards, can result inproblems such as high concentrations of pollutantsin some areas. Enthusiasm for its use may divertattention from decisions about what is required toachieve environmental goals. Trading may under-

mine the power of moral arguments that pollutionshould be reduced and conflicts with the expecta-tion that all sources of pollution should take actionto reduce emissions. It may fail to create incentivesfor continued technological innovation if pollutionsources buy emission credits rather than invest incontrol equipment. Trading requires emissionsmonitoring capacity that may simply not exist.Some pollutants, particularly those where the totalvolume of pollution is the concern, are better suit-ed for trading programs than pollutants posinglocalized health and environment threats. Intro-ducing an emissions trading program, like anyother policy change, creates some uncertaintiesand risks that regulatory officials and regulatedindustries may both resist.

Trading is not a panacea for all the difficultiesposed by environmental regulation. It is not suit-able for use in every regulatory program. The challenge is to determine when it should be used,and, when it is appropriate, how to design andimplement trading in ways that ensure environmen-tal protection and economic efficiency goals areachieved.

Reducing Regulatory Costs Emissions trading programs generally reduce thecost of compliance for regulated industries. Theacid rain control program is widely viewed asresulting in a significant reduction in the cost ofpollution controls. The initial projections for meet-ing the goals of the acid rain program estimatedcompliance costs of $4.9 billion a year by 2010.The U.S. General Accounting Office’s most recentestimate of those costs is now less than $2 billion ayear in 2010.28

Industry groups estimated that the cost of reducinga ton of emissions under the traditional regulatoryapproach at about $1,500/ton; the EPA’s estimate,about $650/ton. The actual prices of allowancesavailable for purchase between 1993 and 1996 atthe Chicago Board of Trade (where allowances aretraded like other commodities) fell from $122 to$66. Transactions for more than 36 millionallowances have been recorded, 25 million ofwhich have been traded between different compa-nies. Trades within companies are believed to bemore numerous than those between firms (trades

Page 18: New Tools for Improving Government

16 New Tools for Improving Government Regulation

within firms are not yet required to be reported).The EPA has also auctioned over 500,000allowances since 1993.29

According to a 1998 study by the president’sNational Science and Technology Council, thecosts of administering the acid rain trading programare lower than traditional regulatory schemesbecause it “eliminates the need to devise source-

specific emission limits and to review control tech-nologies and detailed compliance schedules.”30 TheEPA’s decision to eliminate its case-by-case reviewand approval of each trade has also reduced theadministrative and transaction costs. The programcosts about $12 million a year to operate, whichtranslates into an administrative cost of $1.50/tonof pollution reduced. Lower costs are attributed to“cost reduction efforts and improved performance

Strengths and Weaknesses of Emissions Trading

Strengths

Usually reduces the cost of achievingregulatory goals

Usually gives regulated sources moreflexibility and discretion in meeting theemission goals given them

Helps generate broad political supportfor new regulatory programs by promis-ing to reduce the cost of meeting newenvironmental goals

Reinforces the idea that regulation canhelp prices approximate true costs,including the environmental costs associated with producing goods andservices

Can simplify some administrative tasksof regulatory agencies by focusing onoutputs rather than on mandates forcontrol technologies and processes

May encourage the development andbroader use of control technologies that are cost-effective and might not otherwise be used because they don’tproduce compliance with emission standards

Weaknesses

May result in hot spots — areas of concentrated emissions where sourcesbuy permits from others instead ofreducing emissions — if it is not care-fully integrated with ambient air qualitystandards and if monitoring of theseareas is inadequate

May not require all sources to make at least some emissions reductions

Requires accurate monitoring data for emissions, but monitoring data orinstruments may not exist; also requiresaggressive enforcement of monitoringand reporting requirements

May fail to encourage the developmentand dissemination of new technologiesand processes to reduce or eliminateemissions if companies simply choose tobuy credits rather than invest in pollution control

May be opposed by agency and industryofficials who fear the uncertainties andrisks of failure associated with policychanges and the possibility that tradingmay not achieve the environmentalgoals in place

Page 19: New Tools for Improving Government

New Tools for Improving Government Regulation 17

of scrubbers and changes in fuel markets;” it is dif-ficult to estimate “future technological improve-ments, the more efficient use of existing technolo-gies, and future economic conditions,” but techno-logical innovation, prompted by competition,seems to have fueled cost savings.31

Southern California’s emissions trading programalso seems to have been successful in achieving itsgoal of decreasing the cost of reducing air pollu-tion. A 1996 audit by the South Coast Air QualityManagement District found that during its first twoyears, more than 100,000 tons of nitrogen and sulfur oxides had been traded for more than $10million. The trading program was on track to meetits goal of reducing NOx emissions by 77 tons/dayand SOx emissions by 15 tons/day by 2003. Theprice of NOx credits in 1994 was $24/ton and$132/ton for SOx, well under the $15,000/ton levelthat is the state of California’s trigger point forreviewing the program’s cost effectiveness.32 Duringthe following 15 months (1996 and the first quarterof 1997), more than $20 million worth of creditswere traded.

However, emissions trading may not reduce com-pliance costs in every case. Not all emissions trad-ing programs are simple. The EPA’s bubble programis a complicated system that requires the agency toreview each transaction. Transaction costs are rela-tively high — often $10,000 according to one esti-mate — which may be counterproductive for smalltrades.33 It requires extensive emissions modeling,assessments of alternative control technologies, andcompliance schedules, and is part of a complicatedsystem of command-and-control emission limitsand technological controls. What seems to workbest is allowing trading within a facility, so thatplant managers do not need to obtain new operat-ing permits when production processes change, aslong as the total emissions from the facility do notexceed its cap.

Achieving Environmental Goals Emissions trading programs can be effective toolsfor improving environmental quality and preservingnatural resources if sufficient information is avail-able to policy designers to ensure that the emissiontargets they set will accomplish the environmentalgoals. If the targets are sound and the trading pro-

gram is effectively monitored and enforced, thegoals will likely be achieved. However, the nation-al and state trading programs in place have not yetresolved the problems at which they were aimed.While it is too early to judge emissions tradingdefinitively, there are some troubling indicators.

Under the acid rain program, sulfur dioxide emis-sions from the power plants in phase I of the pro-gram (1995-1999) were to decline each year for atotal reduction of 3.5 million tons; during phase II(2000-2010), emissions are to fall another 5 milliontons. Emissions in 1996 were 35 percent below thecap for that year. The program has reduced emis-sions and may prevent future damage, but emissionreductions do not appear to be sufficient to restorelakes in the Adirondacks and elsewhere that arehighly acidified. Lakes vary in their susceptibility toacid deposition, and some lakes are more damagedthan others. The program’s goal of reducing totalemissions does not appear to be sufficient to provide protection for all lakes. Legislation beforeCongress in 1999 calls for a study to assesswhether emissions reductions projected under thecurrent acid rain program are sufficient to protectlakes in the Adirondacks and elsewhere.34

Despite the RECLAIM program, it is not clear thatthe Los Angeles area will ever achieve current airquality standards. At the start of the RECLAIM program, some critics argued that the initialallowances were too generous and that actualemissions could initially increase. Emissions didincrease in 1995 over the 1993 baseline year, but District officials concluded that the increasedtrading in 1996 and 1997 was evidence that thesurplus allowances built into the first years of theprogram were disappearing.35

More controversial was a proposal in 1995 toexpand the RECLAIM program to include volatileorganic compounds, pollutants that are precursorsof ground-level ozone pollution. The proposalrequired all sources of VOCs emitting at least four tons a year to keep their emissions under anassigned cap that would decline each year. Inresponse to complaints by both industry and envi-ronmental groups, the District’s board of directorsrejected the proposal and in 1996 ordered theagency to institute technology-based standards forindividual industries that use large amounts of

Page 20: New Tools for Improving Government

18 New Tools for Improving Government Regulation

chemicals that produce VOC fumes. Sources wouldbe allowed to earn credits by reducing emissionsfrom motor vehicles and area sources. Board members feared that the earlier proposal wouldlimit economic growth in the area.

In August 1997, the California Air Resources Board,a state agency, suspended all rules that permittedthe trading of VOC emissions because of com-plaints that the trading program had violated feder-al civil rights laws. The complaint argued that emis-sions trading in the Los Angeles area between sta-tionary sources and motor vehicles resulted in dis-proportionately higher air pollution levels in minor-ity communities near the facilities that purchasedthe credits.36

In theory, such problems should not be possible,since the Clean Air Act requires monitors to belocated throughout airsheds and compels state officials to show attainment of the national stan-dards at all monitors. But many people believe that national standards for pollutants like particu-late matter and ozone are not sufficiently strong to protect humans from adverse health effects, sohigher concentrations in minority communities,even if national standards are not exceeded, can be unfair.37

Emissions trading programs are a cost-effectivemeans to accomplish the goals of environmentalpolicies, but the goals themselves may not be suffi-cient to remedy the problems at which the policiesare aimed. This is not the fault of emissions tradingprograms. They are policy tools that are neutral interms of policy goals. If regulatory programs are notcarefully designed to ensure that all areas meetminimum air quality standards, trading systemsmay not produce the environmental and healthbenefits expected of them.

Trading programs also clash with some importantexpectations held for environmental policy. In onesense, trading schemes are inconsistent with the“polluter pays” principle that is one of the key val-ues underlying environmental regulation. Tradingtends to distribute equally the cost of pollutioncontrols across all sources, rather than imposingthe greatest control costs on the sources that pro-duce the greatest emissions. Some firms are able toexternalize costs of production to other sources,

rather than ensuring they account for all of thosecosts.38 Trading programs may not reward sourcesthat have reduced emissions voluntarily. Ifallowances are distributed based on past emissionlevels, high polluters will, in effect, be rewarded fortheir recalcitrance, while innovators who havealready invested in emissions reductions will havefewer allowances to work with.

One of the underpinnings of environmental policyhas been to encourage or force the development ofcleaner, less polluting technologies. Despite theflaws in the conventional approach to regulation, ithas often served to expand the use of cleaner tech-nologies and to encourage the development of newtechnologies. This momentum can be lost if firmsfind emission credits available at a lower price thaninvesting in newer, cleaner technologies. However,trading gives sources more flexibility in meetingstandards, and they may be able to make more useof cheaper technologies. For example, tradingencourages washing coal to reduce its sulfur con-tent, a technology that alone will not lead to theachievement of emissions standards, but can becombined with other actions, such as purchasingcredits, at a fraction of the cost of other controltechnologies.39

In contrast to emissions trading, pollution taxesprovide a continuous incentive to devise newprocesses and technologies, since every timereductions are made, lower taxes result. Emissionstrading programs, unless aggressively structured,may reduce the pressure for developments in technology. Trading programs, unlike pollution prevention efforts, may simply move pollution fromone location to another rather than provide clearincentives to reduce emission levels. Credits earnedby plant shutdowns may create incentives for regu-lated industries to close existing facilities and moveto new, less regulated areas. Accurate past emis-sions from these sources may be difficult to obtain.

As the Los Angeles case shows, emissions tradingprograms may not adequately remedy the publichealth threats posed by pollution. They assume thatthere are safe levels of pollution for human healthand ecosystems, but those estimates of safe thresh-olds of exposure are often difficult to make. Theymay result in increased exposures to some groups,particularly minority communities, who live near

Page 21: New Tools for Improving Government

New Tools for Improving Government Regulation 19

areas where sources find it cheaper to buy creditsfrom others rather than reduce their emissions.Residents who are poor or lack the political cloutto demand pollution reductions may be exposed tohigher levels of toxic pollutants than their wealthierneighbors, and higher levels than before tradingprograms were instituted.40

Despite these shortcomings, emissions trading pro-grams can contribute to broader shifts in policytowards true cost accounting. In a political econo-my fundamentally committed to market exchanges,regulatory strategies that help ensure that the realcosts of production are included in the pricescharged can make a critical contribution to achieving environmental protection goals and a sustainable economy. Economic goals of efficientuse of resources are similarly fostered as prices areadjusted to reflect more accurately the real costs ofproduction. No policy innovation will likely have amore significant impact on environmental qualityand protection of natural resources than to movetowards a system where the impacts on environ-mental factors are fully represented in prices paid.

Ending subsidies and reforming price structures arethe key to a more effective regulatory system, and,ultimately, more effective environmental protection.Emissions trading programs are an incremental steptoward that goal. The real importance of tradingprograms lies in their ability to help generate sup-port for the idea of market-based incentives, gener-ate some data on ecological costs and benefits, andpave the way for more fundamental policy reformsthat will lead to ecologically sustainable economies.

The idea of ecological sustainability requires thatrenewable resources should be used only as fast asthey can be renewed by natural resources.Nonrenewable resources should be used only asfast as renewable substitutes can be developed.Sustainability implies that public policies shouldencourage pollution prevention, reduced consump-tion of nonrenewable resources, increased relianceon alternative energy sources, and consumption ofrenewable resources that match renewal rates.41

These goals can be achieved through traditionalregulation and economic incentives, ending subsi-dies that encourage the use of nonrenewableresources or consumption levels beyond sustain-

able yield levels, and other policies. Pollution pre-vention and waste reduction are the most importantways of protecting the health of the ecosphere, andthe most effective ways of reducing emissions andwastes are to increase production costs to includeall of the present and future costs of production including pollution, environmentaldegradation, and other effects.42 Emissions tradingprograms can make an important contribution infacilitating the transition to the next generation ofenvironmental policies.43

Enhancing Governmental CapacityWhile there is little agreement over what environ-mental goals should be, once they are established,market-based regulatory tools can help generatesupport for these proposals. The debate over envi-ronmental goals is often extremely contentious.Conflicts could be softened if the costs of achievingthose goals were reduced. The acid rain program isa classic example of how emissions trading madepossible a new regulatory program with aggressiveenvironmental goals.

If economic instruments can be devised to achieveenvironmental goals at lower cost than convention-al command-and-control regulation, they willbecome one of the most important developmentsin public policy and will play a major role in themove toward more ecologically sustainable soci-eties. They can help make possible the pursuit ofenvironmental goals that appeared too expensive toachieve with conventional regulatory approaches.

Emissions trading programs can facilitate publicdebate by focusing discussion on overall environ-mental quality goals and total levels of emissions tobe reduced, rather than embroiling interested par-ties in debates over what constitutes the best avail-able control technologies and other bureaucraticrules and regulations. Economist Herman Daly hascharacterized the advantages of emissions tradingprograms this way. Emissions trading clarifies threefundamental economic problems. First, communi-ties must decide how much pollution is to be toler-ated, how much damage to be permitted. Second,they must decide how the ownership of rights topollute will be distributed, who will be responsiblefor reducing emissions. The first two problems areaddressed through political choices. The third prob-

Page 22: New Tools for Improving Government

20 New Tools for Improving Government Regulation

lem, making reductions the most economically effi-cient way, then becomes a function of markets.44

Proposals for market instruments, while based onthe virtue of the simplicity of the market, are oftencomplex. Discussion about the details of tradingplans may obscure broader questions about theamount of required emissions reductions and howmuch should be spent to improve environmentalquality. Regulatory goals that are poorly designedor misdirected are not salvaged, because the costof complying with them is reduced through tradingprograms. Trading schemes may become the focusof attention, as interests jockey over the specificprovisions and mechanisms to be used. The envi-ronmental goals may be slighted or ignored, anddiscussions and analyses may turn to how the trad-ing will work rather than whether it will actuallyreduce emissions and achieve environmental pro-tection goals. A study of the Los Angeles RECLAIMprogram concluded that trading programs areinconsistent with democratic values since tradingdecisions are largely beyond public scrutiny.45

There are other political risks in using emissionstrading and other market-based tools. The kind ofregulatory instrument selected may have an impacton the political system and the policy-makingprocess as well as on environmental quality.46 Theidea of buying permits to pollute may threaten themoral, symbolic power and appeal of pollutioncontrol. Environmental regulation is no longer seenas a moral imperative in protecting human healthand those innocent third parties who enjoy few ofthe benefits of pollution-producing activity yet takeon most of the burdens. Pollution simply becomesanother cost of doing business. The efficiencypromised by emissions trading might unwittinglyproduce equity problems. For instance, trading mayresult in increased pollution levels in areas whereresidents are poor or lack the political clout todemand pollution reductions instead of purchasesof more pollution allowances. Some policy makersand environmental advocates are skeptical of emis-sion trading policies, warning that they have beenoriented more toward “regulatory relief than regu-latory reform,” and that these policies often lack“equivalency in accountability, enforceability, andenvironmental progress.”47 The changes involved inmoving to a trading system raise risks for regulatoryofficials, who may be criticized for devising newapproaches that may not work.

Reliance on pollution taxes and fees may also serve to weaken public commitment to a sharedenvironmental ethic. As decisions are left to themarketplace, there is less need for educational andother collective efforts to foster public awareness of and concern for the environment. If trading sys-tems are used to create property rights in pollutionemissions, communities may have less opportunityto make decisions about what level of air pollutionthey are willing to accept. Market-like incentivesmay send the wrong signal that pollution is accept-able if the polluter is wealthy enough to pay for it.

The creation of a free market in pollution simplyallows companies to buy permits when theychoose not to install control measures or otherwiseprevent pollution. Proponents of environmentalregulation have long rested their arguments on the belief that individuals have the right to breatheclean, healthy air, and that public health and natural resource goals should be pursued indepen-dent of cost calculations. Clean air, clean water,national parks, and the environment in general are all part of a shared common endowment.Placing all of these values in a market may ulti-mately result in their unequal distribution andeventual devaluation.48

Page 23: New Tools for Improving Government

New Tools for Improving Government Regulation 21

Emissions trading and other market incentives inregulation will likely become increasingly impor-tant in U.S. environmental policy making. Not onlywill they continue to play a central role in dealingwith some problems like acid rain and ozone, butthey are expected by many to be a central elementof whatever efforts the United States and at leastsome other countries undertake to achieve thegoals agreed to under the Framework Conventionon Climate Change and the Kyoto Protocol.Emissions trading has two important advantages: It can lead to reduced compliance costs, and it can be the basis of broadening support for a newregulatory program.

The acid rain program of tradable permits is themost successful example of emissions tradingreducing compliance costs. Several features havecontributed to its success:

• The total level of emissions, rather than the loca-tion of sources, is critical. This characteristicfacilitates trading.

• The time frame in which emissions occur is notcritical, another factor that facilitates tradingopportunities. The EPA does not need to be con-cerned with when exactly the allowances areused.

• Monitoring of emissions is critical. There isalready in place a fairly extensive system of continuous emissions monitors for sulfur dioxide.

• The trading program was not transplanted onto acommand-and-control system that complicatedtrading; it is a relatively simple system.

• The cap on total emissions and the allocation ofallowances to each source is simpler than otherregulatory programs. The EPA is required only tokeep track of the allowances for each source andis not required to approve each transaction.

• The policy is seen by many as the result of apartnership between government and industry.

• The statutory authority for the acid rain emis-sions trading program is clear. Congress provid-ed stringent default provisions in the event thatthe EPA failed to issue regulations on schedule.This gave regulated industries an incentive tosupport rather than fight EPA rule making.Congress also made adjustments in the alloca-tion of allowances, rather than leaving that diffi-cult task to the administrative process. This wasdone for political and distributional reasons.

• The allocation of extra allowances in the capand trade system allowed policy makers to dealwith distributional issues related to who wouldbe responsible for making the reductions. Thisalso helped to overcome resistance from politi-cal leaders representing areas responsible forcleanup costs.

• The trading system was so effective in reducingcost estimates that achieving the reductions inacid rain levels became politically feasible.49

Conclusions andRecommendations

Page 24: New Tools for Improving Government

22 New Tools for Improving Government Regulation

Although the acid rain program has significantlyreduced regulatory costs, it may still fail to resolvethe problem of acid rain in many areas.

Despite their current popularity and potential forbroadening political support for environmental reg-ulation, emissions trading is a limited policy tool.The conclusions below suggest those tradable per-mits be used only in limited circumstances and notbe used in many others. If they are to be used,emissions trading programs should be accompa-nied by several conditions. It is critical that theground rules surrounding their creation, regulation,and eventual elimination are clearly understood.Finally, emissions trading programs should be seenas a temporary policy intervention that leads to the use of other policy tools that more effectivelycreate incentives to reduce pollution and encour-age more ecologically sustainable activity.

1. Emissions trading is a useful regulatory tool thatcan be used at all levels of government underthe following circumstances:

• the same emissions have the same effectthroughout the area in which they occur;

• minimum ambient concentrations are satisfiedthroughout the affected areas;

• emissions are quantifiable (emissions reduc-tions can be determined and calculations replicated) and permanent;50

• emissions are relatively easy to measure and monitoring systems are in place so thatemissions can be accurately measured;

• a limited number of major sources that canafford the transaction costs are involved (trading schemes do not work well whenthere are a large number of small sources,because the transaction costs will be toohigh);

• aggressively enforced penalties are in place for excess emissions, including fines andreductions in allowances for subsequentyears;

• emission limits can be ratcheted down overtime to ensure environmental quality goals are achieved;

• regulated industries see the trading system asstable and predictable;

• trading is combined with a requirement thateach source make some minimum reduction in emissions, so that no source is seen asescaping at least some obligation to help solve the pollution problem; and

• there is clear understanding that allowancesare only temporary permits to pollute; theyare not permanent rights that can be changedas environmental conditions change.

2. Before employing an emissions trading program,policy makers should be able to answer affirma-tively the following questions:

• Is there an accurate emissions inventory inplace for determining the allocation ofallowances? Will all sources be treated fairly?

• Is an appropriate baseline used? Does it fairlyreflect economic ups and downs, breakdownsand other problems with maintenance andoperation, investments in and performance ofpollution control equipment, and a host ofother factors?

• How are allowances allocated? Are sourcesthat have already reduced their emissions treated fairly?

• Are there sufficient authority and resourcesfor effective monitoring and enforcement?Can regulatory officials ensure that quantifi-able emissions reductions can be determinedand that reductions are surplus, quantifiable, permanent, and enforceable?

• Is trading among pollutants that pose differenthealth and environmental risks prohibited?

• Are all sources required to make at least somereductions in emissions?

• Will trading programs encourage the development and diffusion of new controltechnologies?

• Will environmental quality be significantlyimproved? Will caps on emissions be suffi-cient to achieve environmental quality goals?

Page 25: New Tools for Improving Government

New Tools for Improving Government Regulation 23

3. Emissions trading programs should lead toother, more powerful regulatory innovationsthat will more effectively encourage ecological-ly sustainable activities.

Emissions trading programs should be designedas a transition to a system of emissions fees ortaxes and other efforts to reflect true costs inprices and to create more powerful incentives toreduce and prevent pollution. The ultimate testof an emissions trading program is its contribu-tion to a more fundamental shift in practicesaimed at reducing pollution, improving efficien-cy, and conserving resources.

Page 26: New Tools for Improving Government

24 New Tools for Improving Government Regulation

1. Riley E. Dunlap, “Public Opinion in the 1980s:Clear Consensus, Ambiguous Commitment”Environment 33 (October 1992): 32.

2. See, for example, Council on EnvironmentalQuality, Environmental Quality: 25th AnniversaryReport (Washington, DC: Council onEnvironmental Quality, 1996).

3. National Commission on the Environment,Choosing a Sustainable Future (Washington, DC:Island Press, 1993.

4. See Robert W. Hahn, “Innovative Approaches forRevising the Clean Air Act,” Natural ResourcesJournal 28 (winter 1988): 171-84.

5. For more on these other kinds of market-basedregulatory tools, see U.S. Congress, Office ofTechnology Assessment, Environmental PolicyTools: A User’s Guide (Washington, DC:Government Printing Office, 1995).

6. For a broader discussion of emissions tradingand other market-based approaches to regulation,see Timothy E. Wirth and John Heinz, “Project 88,Harnessing Market Forces To Protect OurEnvironment” (unpublished report, December1998); Wirth and Heinz, “Project 88–Round II,Incentives for Action: Designing Market-BasedEnvironmental Strategies” (unpublished report, May1991); Daniel J. Dudek and John Palmisano,“Emissions Trading: Why is this ThoroughbredHobbled?” Columbia Journal of EnvironmentalLaw, vol. 13 (1988): 217-56; Robert Stavins,

“Harnessing Market Forces to Protect theEnvironment,” Environment, vol. 31, no. 1 (1989):5-35.

7. Barry Korb, “U.S. Experience with EconomicIncentives for Emissions Trading” in Organisationfor Economic Co-operation and Development,Applying Market-Based Instruments toEnvironmental Policies in China and OECDCountries (Paris: OECD, 1998): 99-115, at p. 107.

8. Korb, “U.S. Experience with EconomicIncentives for Emissions Trading,” p. 105.

9. Korb, “U.S. Experience with EconomicIncentives for Emissions Trading,” pp. 108-09.

10. Korb, “U.S. Experience with EconomicIncentives for Emissions Trading,” p. 105.

11. U.S. General Accounting Office, “Overviewand Issues on Emissions Allowance TradingPrograms,” GAO/T-RCED-97-183 (July 9, 1997): 10;“EPA Unlikely to Include Nuclear Generators inNOx Trading Plan,” Clean Air Report (September 3,1998): 4.

12. John Fialka and Jackie Calmes, “ClintonProposes Global-Warming Plan.” The Wall StreetJournal (October 23, 1997): 2.

13. Christopher Flavin, “Last Tango in BuenosAires” World-Watch 11 (November/December1998): 10-18, at 4-15.

Notes

Page 27: New Tools for Improving Government

New Tools for Improving Government Regulation 25

14. Neil Franz, “Congress prepares for debate overglobal warming treaty.” Environment and EnergyUpdate (November 20, 1999).

15. More information on these state programs canbe found at the U.S. EPA’s “Market IncentivesResource Center,” http://www.epa.gov/oms/transp/traqmkti.htm, accessed in June 1999.

16. See Georgia Institute of Technology, “EmissionsBanking and Trading: A Survey of U.S. Programs”(unpublished manuscript, April 1994).

17. South Coast Air Quality Management District,“Regional Clean Air Incentives Market, SummaryRecommendations” (Spring 1992); South Coast AirQuality Management District, http://www.aqmd.gov/aqmp/97draft/eir/ch2.html (accessed June 1999).

18. Barry Korb, “U.S. Experience with EconomicIncentives for Emissions Trading,” p. 105.

19. Illinois Environmental Protection Agency, “DraftProposal: Design for NOx Trading System” (unpub-lished manuscript, September 22, 1993); “IllinoisBegins Pilot Project to Scrap Old, Polluting Cars inChicago,” Clean Air Report (8 October 1992, T-9).

20. Information updated through a telephone con-versation with Judy Landers, Maine Department ofEnvironmental Protection, 21 June 1999.

21. U.S. EPA, “First Emission Credit TradingProgram Approved” (21 October 1996), Release#96-10-17.

22. More information on these state programs canbe found at the U.S. EPA’s “Market IncentivesResource Center,” http://www.epa.gov/oms/transp/traqmkti.htm, accessed in June 1999.

23. U.S. General Accounting Office, “Overviewand Issues on Emissions Allowance TradingPrograms,” GAO/T-RCED-97-183 (July 9, 1997).

24. Peter Jensen, “’Gas guzzler’ law’s value as taxsource questioned,” The Baltimore Sun (22 April1992): 1A.

25. U.S. EPA, “Market Incentives Resource Center,”http://www.epa.gov/oms/transp/traqmkti.htm,accessed in June 1999.

26. Jean-Phillipe Barde, “Economic Instruments forEnvironmental Protection: Experience in OECDCountries,” in Organisation for Economic Co-oper-ation and Development, Applying Market-BasedInstruments to Environmental Policies in China andOECD Countries (Paris: OECD, 1997): 31-58, at 34-36.

27. Barde, “Economic Instruments forEnvironmental Protection,” pp. 37-41.

28. U.S. General Accounting Office, “Overview and Issues on Emissions Allowance TradingPrograms,” p. 6.

29. Korb, “U.S. Experience with EconomicIncentives for Emissions Trading,” p. 112.

30. National Science and Technology Council,“NAPA Biennial Report to Congress: An IntegratedAssessment,” (May 1998): 93.

31. National Science and Technology Council,“NAPA Biennial Report to Congress,” p. 93.

32. South Coast Air Quality Management District,AQMD News (January 12, 1996)http://www.aqmd.gov/news1/Archives/recaudit.html(accessed June 1999).

33. Korb, “U.S. Experience with EconomicIncentives for Emissions Trading,” p. 107.

34. S. 172, 106th Congress.

35. U.S. General Accounting Office, “Overviewand Issues on Emissions Allowance TradingPrograms.”

36. Roger Stevens, “Emissions-Trading RulesSuspended by California,” The Wall Street Journal(August 29, 1997): A4.

37. Natural Resources Defense Council, BreathTaking: Premature Mortality Due to Particulate AirPollution in 238 American Cities (New York:NRDC, May 1996).

Page 28: New Tools for Improving Government

26 New Tools for Improving Government Regulation

38. Daniel A. Seligman, “Air Pollution EmissionsTrading: Opportunity or Scam?” (Washington, DC:Sierra Club, unpublished paper, 1994): 8-10.

39. This example was provided by Barry Korb,meeting, August 14, 1999.

40. Richard Toshiyuki Drury, Michael E. Belliveau,J. Scott Kuhn, and Shipra Bansal, “Pollution Tradingand Environmental Injustice: Los Angeles’ FailedExperiment in Air Quality Policy,” DukeEnvironmental Law and Policy Forum, vol. 9(1999): 231-86, at 251-58.

41. For a recent assessment of sustainable develop-ment, see The President’s Council on SustainableDevelopment, Towards Sustainable America(Washington, DC: President’s Council onSustainable Development, May 1999).

42. See Robert Repetto et al., Green Fees: How aTax Shift Can Work for the Environment and theEconomy (Washington, DC: World ResourcesInstitute, 1992).

43. For a very thoughtful discussion of future direc-tions in environmental policy, see Marian R.Chernow and Daniel C. Esty, eds., ThinkingEcologically: The Next Generation ofEnvironmental Policy (New Haven: Yale UniversityPress, 1997).

44. See “Sustainable Development, Part 5:Emissions Trading,” Rachel’s Environment & HealthWeekly #628 (December 10, 1998) (availablethrough [email protected]).

45. Druy, Belliveau, Kuhn, and Bansal, “PollutionTrading and Environmental Justice,” pp. 278-79.

46. Michael Gartner, “A Skeptic Speaks,” EPAJournal Vol 18:2 (May/June 1992): 26.

47. Environmental Reporter, “California: ProblemsSeen Setting Baseline Levels in South CoastEmissions-Trading Program” (29 May 1992): 437.

48. Steven Kelman, What Price Incentives? (Boston:Auburn House, 1981).

49. Korb, “U.S. Experience with EconomicIncentives for Emissions Trading,” pp. 112-14.

50. U.S. EPA, “The New Generation ofEnvironmental Protection,” unpublished paper(April 15, 1994).

Page 29: New Tools for Improving Government

New Tools for Improving Government Regulation 27

Gary C. Bryner is director of the Natural Resources Law Center and Research Professor of Law at theUniversity of Colorado School of Law. He has also been a professor of political science at Brigham YoungUniversity, where he directed the Public Policy program. He is a graduate of the University of Utah (eco-nomics), Cornell University (government), and Brigham Young University (law). He has been a guest fellowat the Brookings Institution, the National Academy of Public Administration, and the Natural ResourcesDefense Council. He has taught courses in policy analysis, environmental regulation, natural resources pol-icy, international development policy, social policy, and the policy making process. Bryner is the author ofBureaucratic Discretion: Law and Policy in Federal Regulatory Agencies (1987); In Search of the Republic:Public Virtue and the Roots of American Government, with Richard Vetterli (1987, 1995); Blue Skies, GreenPolitics: The Clean Air Act of 1990 and its Implementation (1992, 1995), From Promises to Performance:Achieving Global Environmental Goals (1997); Environmental Politics: Domestic and Global Dimensions,with Jacqueline Vaughn Switzer (1998); Politics and Public Morality: The Great American Welfare ReformDebate (1998); and U.S. Land and Natural Resources Policy (1998).

About the Author

Page 30: New Tools for Improving Government

28 New Tools for Improving Government Regulation

To contact the author:Gary C. BrynerDirectorNatural Resources Law CenterUniversity of Colorado School of LawCampus Box 401Boulder CO 80309-0401(303) 492-1287

e-mail: [email protected]

Key Contact Information

Page 31: New Tools for Improving Government

ENDOWMENT REPORTS AVAILABLE

Managing Workfare: The Case of the Work ExperienceProgram in the New York City Parks Department (June 1999)

Steven CohenColumbia University

Results of the Government Leadership Survey:A 1999 Survey of Federal Executives (June 1999)

Mark A. AbramsonSteven A. ClyburnElizabeth MercierPricewaterhouseCoopers

Credit Scoring and Loan Scoring: Tools for ImprovedManagement of Federal Credit Programs (July 1999)

Thomas H. StantonJohns Hopkins University

The Importance of Leadership: The Role of School Principals(September 1999)

Paul TeskeMark Schneider State University of New York at Stony Brook

Leadership for Change: Case Studies in American LocalGovernment (September 1999)

Robert B. DenhardtJanet Vinzant DenhardtArizona State University

Managing Decentralized Departments: The Case of the U.S.Department of Health and Human Services (October 1999)

Beryl A. RadinState University of New York at Albany

New Tools for Improving Government Regulation: AnAssessment of Emissions Trading and Other Market-BasedRegulatory Tools (October 1999)

Gary C. BrynerUniversity of Colorado School of Law

To download or order a copy of these reports, visit the Endowment website at endowment.pwcglobal.com

Page 32: New Tools for Improving Government

About PricewaterhouseCoopersPricewaterhouseCoopers (www.pwcglobal.com) helps itsclients develop and execute integrated solutions to buildvalue, manage risk and improve their performance. Drawingon the knowledge and skills of 150,000 people in 150 countries, we provide a full range of business advisory and consulting services to leading global, national and local companies and to public institutions.Our objective is to have measurable impact. Our goal is to work with clients to make the world a better place.

For additional information, contact:Mark A. AbramsonExecutive DirectorThe PricewaterhouseCoopers Endowment for

The Business of Government1616 North Fort Myer DriveArlington, VA 22209

(703) 741-1077fax: (703) 741-1076e-mail: [email protected]: endowment.pwcglobal.com

1616 North Fort Myer DriveArlington, VA 22209-3195

The PricewaterhouseCoopers Endowment for

The Business of GovernmentBulk Rate

US Postage

P A I DPermit 1112

Merrifield, VA