optimal interest rates and fiscal policy

Upload: striider

Post on 03-Apr-2018

215 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

  • 7/28/2019 Optimal Interest Rates and Fiscal Policy

    1/52

    Optimal Interest Rates Under Endogenous Fiscal Policy

    Mercedes Haga

    Ponticia Universidad Catlica de Chile

    March 17, 2009

    Abstract

    It is a fact that some politicians once they reach the power do not behave as benev-

    olent planners but as self-interested bureaucrats, according to which, they make scaldecisions. On the other hand, central bank independence claims that the monetary

    authority should set its control variable only in accordance to its loss function. This

    paper studies wether this is still true in an environment where scal expenditure is

    endogenously determined by a self-interested incumbent whose scal decisions might

    be contrary to individuals welfare. I nd that the central bank should always care

    about the way the scal authority sets its consumption path as a signaling eect. Fur-

    thermore, the larger is the government relative to the private sector, the more sensitive

    the central banks reaction should be. I also nd microfoundations for forward-looking

    Taylor rules. Finally, even if the government would also be concerned with individuals

    welfare; the central bank should still consider deviations of scal expenditure in its

    reaction function.

    1 Introduction

    It is a fact that some politicians once they reach the power do not behave as benevolent

    planners but as self-interested bureaucrats (sometimes with non-social objectives such as

    personal enrichment or re-election), according to which, they make decisions. One of those

    decisions is to specify scal expenditure. Fiscal expenditure has a high social impact

    not only because of its direct eect on welfare, but also because it inuences the price

    level determination and therefore ination. However, current general equilibrium modelsdo not account for this feature and consider scal choices as an exogenous process. On

    the other hand, agency models do deal with political economy issues, but they are all

    1

  • 7/28/2019 Optimal Interest Rates and Fiscal Policy

    2/52

    partial equilibrium models. In this way, many interactions between variables might not be

    considered not only in general equilibrium models but also in partial equilibrium ones; for

    example, how should the monetary authority react in the presence of a scal shock when

    the incumbent cares only about its own welfare? How will households allocate consumptionand labor when they know that the government is not interested in soften shocks for them?

    Will rms also behave in a dierent way? And more importantly, what can we expect from

    the interaction between a self-interested scal authority and a central bank concerned with

    consumerss welfare? In other words, what is gained in terms of interaction between scal

    and monetary authorities when one of them behaves in a selsh way?

    By the end of 2008 a group of twenty eight developed and developing countries have

    adopted ination targeting regimes as a way to conduct their monetary policy.1 The rst

    one to do it was New Zealand in 1990 while the last one was Ghana in May, 2007. It is

    interesting to notice that even though countries are very dierent from each other as long astheir macro variables are concerned (for example current ination, interest rates, GDP per

    capita, etc.), all targets uctuate between 0% and 5%.2 In this way; and precisely due to

    their dierence in macro fundamentals, it is not expected for example, for the Reserve Bank

    of Australia to react in the same way as the Central Bank of Chile or the Central Bank

    of Peru whenever a shock occurs. Considering target interest rate, scal expenditure and

    ination data for these three countries I nd that the percentage change of the interest rate

    to a 1% change in scal expenditure is not statistically signicant in the case of Australia,

    but equals 0:955 for Peru and 2:024 for Chile (regressions are shown in the appendix). This

    tells us that there are some considerations underlying that makes central banks to behave

    dierently in each country.

    Keeping the previous discussion in mind, this paper investigates how political economy

    aects the structure and dynamics of consumption, labor, ination and how do optimal

    interest rate rules change when it is present the interaction between a self-interested in-

    cumbent and a "benevolent" and independent central bank that wants to minimize its loss

    function. For that, I use a closed-economy general equilibrium model to address the con-

    ict of interest that arrises between voters and rent-seeking politicians who like to consume

    for their own purposes the same type of goods as households. This approach will allow

    us to obtain a general equilibrium model able to describe the behavior and interaction

    1 Finland and Spain however, have abandoned the regime in 1999 when they joined the European Eco-nomic and Monetary Union.

    2 Exceptions are Indonesia and Ghana with targets of 6% (1%) and 0 10% respectively.

    2

  • 7/28/2019 Optimal Interest Rates and Fiscal Policy

    3/52

    of all variables (for example, the behavior of ination, not present in partial equilibrium

    models), and at the same time incorporate distortions in scal expenditure manipulation

    arising from political economy; all of which has a direct impact on ination and therefore

    on the central banks best response to this environment. It is important to note that theintitutionality underlying this model is such that even though it can not prevent the incum-

    bent from taking over a portion of total scal expenditure, it does guarantee the central

    banks independence; that is to say, the government can not pressure the central bank to

    deviate from its loss function.

    This work is related to two dierent literatures: political economy and optimal targeting

    rule. As long as political economy is concerned, this work is placed within "opportunistic-

    rent-seeking" politicians models in line with Diermeier, Keane and Merlo [2005], Shi and

    Svensson [2006] and Acemoglu, Golosov and Tsyvinski [2008] where re-election is pursued

    for politicianss own welfare in terms of expected returns of being in power (i.e. ego rentsor self-enrichment). I will assume politicians want to hold oce because it enables them

    to appropriate from a certain fraction of public expenditure for their own consumption.

    On the other hand, the optimal targeting rule part of this paper is most closely related

    to Clarida, Gal and Gertlers seminal contribution on the eld as I will analyze dierent

    interest rate rules for monetary policy that come from the interest (or command) of the

    central bank in minimizing a quadratic loss function.3 In particular, I will work with the

    hybrid neokeynesian Phillips curve proposed by Gal and Gertler [1999] in order to capture

    ination persistence that seems to characterize the data.4

    In this way the model is derived by the interaction between a self-interested incumbent

    concerned with holding oce and an independent central bank concerned with households

    welfare. I study a monopolistic competitive closed economy with no capital and scal

    shocks, equivalent to the framework used in Walsh [2003]. To capture the fact that politi-

    cianss incentives are not always aligned with the citizenss ones, I will assume that the

    policymaker would like to manipulate scal expenditure in a selsh way. In other words, the

    incumbent will be willing to mislead the voters perception about his competence through

    scal expenditure and have a higher probability of reappointment, as implied by Shi and

    Svenssons [2006] work.

    I nd that not only for the case with no government but also for the case where scal

    expenditure is exogenously determined, the monetary authority should set the interest3 Woodford [2003] show that this is consistent with the maximization of the consumers welfare.4 See for example Henzel and Wollmershaeuser [2006] for a recent discussion.

    3

  • 7/28/2019 Optimal Interest Rates and Fiscal Policy

    4/52

    rate considering deviations of expected ination with respect to its steady state level and

    current and expected output gap. On the other hand, if scal expenditure is determined

    by a self-interested incumbent, the central bank should react not only to expected ination

    but also to scal deviations with respect to its steady state value. This is because evenin the case where the government is considered, if scal expenditure is exogenously given,

    the central bank can do nothing to change this level; but this is not true if the incumbent

    endogenously decide it. In this sense, changes in the interest rate when deviations of scal

    expenditure around its steady state level occur, acts as a signal to the government which

    reminds him how committed to ination the central bank is and looks forward to discourage

    him from high expenditures levels by raising the interest rate. This signalling eect is, in

    fact, bigger the bigger the public sector is relative to the private sector.

    The paper is organized as follows. Section 2 briey summarizes the literature related

    to this work. Section 3 describes the basic model. Section 4 solves it for the benchmarkcase of no government, for the case of a government with an exogenous expenditure path

    and for the case of a self-interested incumbent (all of them considering an independent

    central bank ). Section 5 shows the impulse response functions to a one percent scal

    shock and section 6 extends the model for the case when not only the central bank but

    also the government is concerned with individuals welfare. Finally section 7 concludes.

    An appendix shows the estimated regressions and proves the main equations.

    2 Related Literature

    Two motivations are put forward in the political economy literature to capture politi-

    cians incentives to move away from a benevolent behavior. On one hand, they might

    be "ideologically-motivated" and in this way only care about the well-being of particular

    groups of society; which means that they will choose policies in order to maximize a social

    welfare function that puts a disproportionate weight on these groups. These are known

    as partisan politicians. On the other hand, politicians can act in a purely self-interested

    way if they choose policies as to hold oce because of its value per se; or because holding

    oce allows them to extract tangible rents. These are known as opportunistic politicians,

    and to be more precise, those who want to hold oce per se are called "oce-seeking",

    while those who also want to extract tangible rents are called "rent-seeking". As it wassaid before, I shall focus on "opportunistic-rent-seeking" politicians in line with the ones

    present in Diermeier, Keane and Merlo [2005], Shi and Svensson [2006] and Acemoglu,

    4

  • 7/28/2019 Optimal Interest Rates and Fiscal Policy

    5/52

    Golosov and Tsyvinski [2007]. Next I will briey discuss these papers along with Clarida,

    Gal and Gertler [1999].

    Diermeier, Keane and Merlo [2005] want to explore motivations and objectives of elected

    politicians in a context of political career in order to quantify the returns of a United StatesCongress career. For this, they use the idea that politicians are forward-looking rational

    individuals that make decisions over their career taking into account the expected returns

    of dierent choices; and they also count on novel data base with information about post-

    congressional employment of former members of Congress and their wages. In this way,

    politicians might be interested in choosing a congressional career not only because of the

    utility of being in oce, but also because of its monetary returns. Their key innovation is

    that they explicitly model career opportunities of politicians outside Congress when they

    leave it: they can choose between a job in the private sector or in the public sector. Their

    salary depends on their age, education, number of terms in oce committee assignmentsand weather their exit was voluntary or due to electoral defeat. At the same time, politi-

    cians can dier in their personal characteristics that may aect not only elections outcome

    but also their wage out of Congress. In this way, the authors propose a dynamic problem

    in which a Congress member must decide weather to run for re-election, run for a higher

    oce or exit from Congress (either to work in the public or private sector or to retire)

    every two years. To solve this problem, they assume there is a "minimum age" and a

    "terminal" age to be a congressman (thirty and eighty years respectively); then by posing

    the determinants of post-congressional payos, senators decisions, representatives deci-

    sions, re-election probabilities and the evolution of exogenous state variables, they solve it

    backwards. Their main results are the following: Congress experience has a positive and

    signicant eect on post-congressional wages (in both, the public and the private sector);

    second, non-pecuniary earnings from being in congress are as considerable as monetary ones

    (in fact, monetary earnings alone are not enough to explain politicians behavior); third,

    non obsevable skills like charisma helps politicians to increase their re-election probability,

    but does not help them to get a higher wage out of Congress; fourth, there is no evidence of

    selectivity bias about who runs for re-election but the contrary happens when a politician

    must run for a higher oce; nally, to impose a limit for terms would rise signicantly

    "voluntary exits", biased towards who have better political skills and the older.

    Shi and Svensson [2006] contribute to the empirical cross-country literature on politicalbudget cycles and formulate a model that accounts for the evidence of the existence of

    political budget cycles and their systematic dierences between developing and developed

    5

  • 7/28/2019 Optimal Interest Rates and Fiscal Policy

    6/52

    countries. In a partial equilibrium model they focus on the incumbents optimizing behav-

    ior, where they assume that the government likes to consume the same type of goods as

    households; but its consumption path will be conditioned to being reelected. To achieve

    this, the incumbent manipulates public expenditure in order to confuse uninformed voterswho can not see clearly weather a higher expenditure level means policy manipulation or

    governments competence (that is to say, they work with a political career model). They

    nd that, rst of all, the governments budget balance is inuenced by the timing of the

    elections: prior to elections politicians have incentives to expand expenditure in order to

    increase his re-election probability; which in turn will be stronger if there are high rents

    from being in power and if there is a bigger portion of uninformed voters. This is very

    intuitive as greater rents from being in power will make incumbents be willing to hold oce

    no matter what and on the other hand, if by manipulating expenditure the incumbent can

    mislead a greater share of voters, he will have incentives to do so; higher rents and higherportions of uninformed voters are expected to be consistent with less developed countries.

    In this way, the authors can account for the mentioned dierence in political budget cycles

    between developed and less developed countries.

    Acemoglu, Golosov and Tsyvinski [2008] study optimal taxation also in a context where

    the system is not operated by a benevolent planner but by a rent-seeking self-interested

    politician. Political economy environment though, is dierent from the present paper as

    they deal with an electoral accountability model; that is, politicians have complete discre-

    tion once in oce, but voters can oust them from oce at the next elections; so voters

    act retrospectively and deliberately punish bad behavior by replacing the bad government.

    Their main contribution is to introduce political economy to a dynamic Mirrlees problem

    and in that way, give conditions under which political economy distortions persist or dis-

    appear in the long run. In particular, optimal tax structure will be the same as in the case

    with no political economy distortions if politicians are as patient as individuals; otherwise

    aggregate taxes on labor and income will persist even in the long run. To design the best

    mechanism that might best avoid the distortions created by the presence of this type of

    politicians and lack of commitment, contrary to this paper, they only need a partial equi-

    librium model that species individual preferences and game present between the selsh

    politician and the executioner voters to obtain the subgame perfect equilibrium path for

    taxes.On the other hand, the other pillar of this paper and what makes it original is the

    interaction of this self-interested government with the central bank. For this, I will rest on

    6

  • 7/28/2019 Optimal Interest Rates and Fiscal Policy

    7/52

    the New Keynesian perspective of monetary policy pioneered by Clarida, Gal and Gertler

    [1999]. In their paper they obtain the optimal monetary policy stressing the existence of

    nominal rigidities and also incorporating micro-founded bases to their model. In this way,

    they analyze the cases of a discretionary and a committed central bank that minimizes anination and output gap quadratic loss function taking into account the demand side of

    the economy given by consumers optimal behavior and the supply side of the economy,

    given by the rms optimal behavior. These cases allow them to show the gains from

    commitment: it eliminates the inationary bias in the case the central banks target for

    real output exceeds the market clearing level and more importantly, if the central bank

    is to credibly ght ination in the future, commitment improves output-ination trade

    o faced by the central bank. Even though it is not the aim of this paper to see the

    gains of rules versus discretion (in fact, I will consider a committed central bank that can,

    through this, aect ination and output expectations); it will be useful for the presentwork to make the central bank behave in the same way as theirs. Moreover, within the

    New Keynesian perspective, I will use the hybrid concept of the Phillips curve proposed

    by Gal and Gertler [1999]. To capture the ination inertia that seems to characterize US

    ination time series, the authors set out a model with nominal rigidities and a fraction of

    rms that set their prices not by maximizing the present value of future expected prots,

    but by a backward-looking rule. They empirically test the dynamics of ination for US

    data for the period 1960 - 1997 and use labor income share in the non-farm business sector

    to approximate real marginal cost instead of using output gap. They actually nd that

    "backwardness" though statistically signicant, it was of no quantitative importance and

    so, the New Keynesian Phillips curve gives a good approximation to US ination dynamics.

    They nally claim that this may be so because the source of ination inertia might be the

    sluggish adjustment in real marginal costs and not backward-looking rms. Some authors

    however, argue that this result is only due to estimation methods used in the paper.5

    3 The Model

    I will use the moral hazard model proposed by Shi and Svensson [2006] and put it to work

    on a standard cashless neokeynesian general equilibrium model as the one used in Walsh

    5 See Rudd and Whelan [2005] and Lind [2005] for a more recent discussion and Gal, Gertler andLpez-Salido [2005] for an answer to it.

    7

  • 7/28/2019 Optimal Interest Rates and Fiscal Policy

    8/52

    [2003].6 In this way I will be able to derive an expression for the ination rate consistent

    with an optimizing policymaker.

    In this model there are four types of agents: households, rms, politicians and a central

    bank. This section describes the decision problem for each of them.

    3.1 Households

    There is a continuum of innitely lived agents who drive utility from consumption and

    leisure. Consumption is provided either by the public sector in a proportion of total

    governments expenditure, or by the private sector. Individuals have the same preferences

    over the public good, the composite consumption good and labor. However, they dier

    over idiosyncratic preferences concerning candidates other policies (besides scal ones).

    These idiosyncratic preferences are captured by the parameter s assumed to be uniformly

    distributed on 12 ; 12 : Government is in charge of any of the two existing political parties,a or b; At is a binary variable that equals 1=2 if party a is elected and equals 1=2 if b

    is elected. Preferences are concave in public and private consumption and in labor; in

    particular, I assume this concave function is isoelastic and additive in its arguments (this

    assumption has no impact on the results and greatly simplies the mathematics). The

    instantaneous utility function for consumers is then:

    Us (t) =(Gt)

    1

    1 +

    C1t1

    R10 N

    1+jt dj

    1 + + sAt

    where Gt is the level of a Dixit-Stiglitz aggregate of public good; Ct is also a Dixit-Stiglitzaggregate of private consumption of each of the continuum of dierentiated goods cjt ,

    Ct [

    Z10

    c1

    jt dj]

    1

    with > 1 the price elasticity of individual goods and is the intertemporal elasticity of

    substitution of the composite good. Njt is the labor supply of the representative agent to

    sector j, for which she receives wt and is the corresponding elasticity.7

    Households are the owners of the rms for which they receive prots t and hold

    6

    As Cochrane [1998] shows, provided the Fiscal Theory of the Price Level, cash can be deleted andthe price level still determined, if the government accepts maturating government bonds directly for taxliabilities or electronically convert them in dollars for a "nanosecond" before accepting them.

    7 Note that wjt = wt 8j, this means perfect labor mobility among sectors.

    8

  • 7/28/2019 Optimal Interest Rates and Fiscal Policy

    9/52

    one-period riskless nominal bonds issued by the central bank, Bt, which pay the nominal

    interest rate it. Finally, let be the private sector discount factor and Pt the general price

    level in period t; so, the consumer problem for citizen s is given by:

    maxCt;Nt;Bt

    Et

    1Xi=0

    i[(Gt+i)

    1

    1 +

    C1t+i1

    R10 N

    1+jt+idj

    1 + + sAt+i]

    s:t : Ct +BtPt

    =wtR10 Njt dj

    Pt+ (1 + it1)

    Bt1Pt

    + t (1)

    3.2 Firms

    There is also a continuum of prot-maximizing rms of measure one that operate under

    monopolistic competition; so, they face their demand curve that will be given by FOC of

    the consumers problem. The technology available is a CRS function with no capital and

    a productivity shock Zt. The only thing that distinguishes one rm from another (besides

    its output) is that they adjust their prices in dierent dates. In this way, output j is of the

    form:

    yjt = ZtNjt ; Zt iid

    1; 2Z

    and aggregate output is dened as:

    Yt

    Z10

    pjtPt

    yjt dj

    where pjt is the price set for good j in period t. Prices are staggered la Calvo (1983); everyperiod, only a fraction 1 ! of all rms adjust prices. Ination persistence is introduced by

    a fraction (1 ) of adjusting rms that set prices in a forward-looking way such that they

    maximize the expected discounted value of current and future prots; and the remaining

    fraction set prices in a backward-looking way. Let pjt be the optimal price set by all

    adjusting rms that produce variety j; ination persistence comes from assuming that:

    pjt = (1 )pf o

    jt + pba

    jt (2)

    where pf ojt is the price set by a forward-looking rm and pba

    jt is the price set by a backward-

    looking rm. Lastly, let t be the income tax rate paid the rms.

    9

  • 7/28/2019 Optimal Interest Rates and Fiscal Policy

    10/52

    To solve the pricing decision, a forward-looking rm will choose pf ojt to maximize

    Et

    1

    Xi=0 !ii;t+i[(

    pf ojt

    Pt+i)yj;t+i(1 t+i) t+iyj;t+i]

    where !i is the probability of not adjusting price between t and t+i; i;t+i is the subjective

    discount factor; as households own rms, this discount factor is related to marginal utility

    of private consumption and due to the utility form it equals i(Ct+i=Ct):8 Lastly, t

    is the rms real marginal cost, which is obtained from the cost minimization problem

    faced by the rm and equals wt=PtZt : On the other hand, I will use a very simple rule for

    backward-looking rms. In fact, I will assume backward-looking rms set their price equal

    to the optimal price set by adjusting rms the period before; i.e.:

    pbajt = pjt1 (3)

    It is worth noting that even though this very simple rule says that backward-looking rms

    are completely short-sighted, they are actually incorporating information about future

    expectations as pjt1 has a forward-looking part, pf o

    jt1: So, backward-looking rms are

    somehow naive, but not so much.

    3.3 Government

    Regardless from the ruling party, let gjt be the level of good j consumed by the govern-

    ment in period t. Therefore, the level of composite public good Gt (assumed to have the

    same elasticity of individuals goods as households), is Gt [R10 g

    1

    jt dj]

    1 . Gt will be

    exogenously given or endogenously obtained by solving a utility maximization problem

    for a self-interested incumbent. Nevertheless, in both cases this level is, in every period,

    constrained by tax revenues and a scal shock "t. The scal shock can be associated to,

    for example, natural catastrophes and comes to be public information at the end of every

    period. So, the government budget constraint can be expressed as:

    Gt = tYt + "t; "t iid

    0; 2"

    (4)

    8 In general, the stochastic discount factor between t and t + 1 equals u0

    (ct+1)u0(ct)

    :

    10

  • 7/28/2019 Optimal Interest Rates and Fiscal Policy

    11/52

    3.4 Central Bank

    Smoothing policies are in charge of an independent central bank that is not exclusively

    concerned about stabilizing ination but also with the stability of the real economy. In

    this way, the central bank acts with commitment and sets the nominal interest rate as

    to minimize a quadratic intertemporal loss function, considering the eect of changes in

    the interest rate on ination through its impact on private consumption and tax rates.

    The central bank dislikes high ination, t and high levels of output gap xt (which has an

    exogenous relative weight ), these targets are derived from an optimal policy problem that

    wants to maximize a welfare measure given by the expected utility function of households. 9

    The central banks loss function is then:

    Et

    1

    Xi=0i(

    1

    22t+i +

    2x2t+i)

    It is important to note two things: rst, that because of the non existence of capital in

    this economy, a central bank is needed so that the equilibrium interest rate is determined

    and second, the central bank when it sales bonds, it collects goods, pays its previous debt

    and throws away any possible excess.

    3.5 Equilibrium

    The previous description of all agentss behavior, yield to the following equilibrium deni-

    tion:

    Denition 1 An equilibrium in this economy is a sequencenCt; Gt; Nt; Bt; Yt; p

    jt ; Pt; t; wt; t; ito1

    t=0such that:

    Consumers maximize expected utility,

    Firms maximize prots,

    Aggregate price level is a weighted average of individual prices and last periods

    aggregate price level,

    The government maximizes its expected utility;

    9 For a formal derivation, see Benigno and Woodford [2003] or Woodford [2003], chapter. 4.

    11

  • 7/28/2019 Optimal Interest Rates and Fiscal Policy

    12/52

    The central bank minimizes its loss function and

    Markets clear.

    4 Solving the Model

    The timing of the events is as follows: rst, the central bank minimizes its loss function

    by choosing the nominal interest rate, then the government (in the case of a self-interested

    one) sets its expected consumption level and, as a residual from its budget constraint, the

    tax rate needed to get a balanced budget. At this point is important to emphasize that the

    government does not issue public debt and so, it does not aect the economys interest rate

    through this channel (I made this assumption because with no default probability, this type

    of bonds should be a perfect substitute of the ones issued by the central bank; this only

    adds noise to my model and has no implications for the core of the paper). The third player

    in this sequential game are rms which decide the optimal price level from which ination

    can be obtained. Finally, consumers determine their optimal levels of private consumption,

    labor and bond holdings. Solving backwards, I rst present consumers utility maximization

    subject to their budget constraint, which will give us the private side of aggregate demand

    curve; then rms maximize prots subject to consumers optimal choice and in this way

    I obtain the aggregate supply curve; the Hybrid New Keynesian Phillips Curve. Thirdly,

    the government solves its problem which will be trivial if scal expenditure is considered as

    an exogenous process and will be microfounded for the case of a self-interested incumbent.

    In the later case, the government will maximize its own utility subject to the re-electionprobability and the behavior of rms and households. Finally, the central bank solves its

    problem subject to the demand and the supply side of the economy (the demand side will

    consider scal behavior, whether it is exogenous or endogenous).

    4.1 Benchmark Case: No Government

    4.1.1 Households

    As mentioned, I will start by solving the households problem. Like in standard procedures,

    I divide the problem in two parts:

    (a) First choose the optimal combination of individual goods that minimize the cost of

    purchasing a certain level of composite good, given its denition. From the FOC, I

    12

  • 7/28/2019 Optimal Interest Rates and Fiscal Policy

    13/52

  • 7/28/2019 Optimal Interest Rates and Fiscal Policy

    14/52

    remaining fraction ! of all rms that set their price in earlier periods. To obtain Pt, from

    (6) it can be shown that the average price in period t satises10

    P

    1

    t = (1 !)(p

    t )1

    + !P

    1

    t1 (11)

    where pt is dened in equation (3) :

    Let bkt denote the percentage change of a variable Kt around its steady state level K. Ialso assume that the steady state involves a zero ination rate, then (10) can be linearized

    around the steady state to obtain aggregate ination as:

    t = 2Ett+1 + 3t1 + 4bt (12)where the coecients s are dened in the appendix, are all positive and for the special case

    of pure forward-looking rms scenario, it is true that 2 = ; 3 = 0 and 4 =1!

    ! (1 !)as in the traditional New Keynesian Phillips curve. Equation (12) is known as the Hybrid

    New Keynesian Phillips Curve (HNKPC). Here, ination is forward-looking, it also has an

    inertial component and real marginal cost is a very important determinant of the ination

    rate. As standard results, ination rate does not directly depend on output gap, but it can

    re related to deviations of real marginal cost; in fact, deviations of real marginal cost can

    be expressed as: bt = ( + ) (byt byft )where the superscript f denotes the exible price equilibrium (i.e. ! = 0):

    4.1.3 Central Bank

    The central bank will minimize its loss function subject to the demand and supply side of

    the economy. Let xt byt byft be the output gap with respect to the exible price case;linealization of the Euler equation results in the demand side, or the IS curve, whereas

    the supply side is given by the HNKPC. In accordance with its steady state level, it was

    assumed that the central bank has a zero ination target. The central banks problem is

    10 See Walsh [2003], chapter 5.

    14

  • 7/28/2019 Optimal Interest Rates and Fiscal Policy

    15/52

    presented as follows:

    mint+i;xt+i;it+i

    Et

    1

    Xi=0i(

    1

    22t+i +

    2x2t+i)

    st :

    xt = Etxt+1 +1

    Ett+1

    i

    bit + ut

    t = 2Ett+1 + 3t1 + 4 ( + ) xt

    where ut Etbyft+1 Etbyft is an exogenous disturbance. I will divide the problem intwo stages: rst, minimize the loss function subject to the ination equation considering

    that, because of commitment, the central bank can eectively aect output and ination

    expectations. Then, conditional on the optimal values of xt and t, nd the value of it

    implied by the demand curve.11 The FOC of this problem entails the following dynamics

    for the output gap:

    xt Etxt+1 =4 ( + )

    Ett+1 3Etxt+2 +

    1

    1

    2

    xt

    The optimal policy rule for the interest rate that emerges from the demand side is then:

    bit = 1i

    1

    4 ( + )

    Ett+1 +

    i3Etxt+2

    i

    1

    1

    2

    xt +

    iut (13)

    So, from equation (13) we can see that interest rate will depend exclusively on expected

    ination and, because of the existence of backward-looking rms, on actual and expectedoutput gap. Higher expected output gap will make the central bank to rise the interest rate

    as expected and higher deviations of output today will also imply a higher interest rate for

    a suciently low degree of stickiness (i.e. for a suciently high value of the probability

    !). On the other hand, the central banks reaction to a higher expected ination rate

    depends on the portion of rms adjusting prices through the parameter 4, on labor and

    consumption elasticities and on the exogenous relative weigh for the output gap . If

    there is a higher fraction of rms adjusting prices, output gap will be lower ( as can be

    seen in the appendix, 4 is an increasing function of the fraction of rms adjusting prices)

    and the central bank will not have to tighten so hard the interest rate if there is a risein the expected ination rate. The same eect will have a higher labor and consumption

    11 This is because the demand side is not an active restriction in this problem.

    15

  • 7/28/2019 Optimal Interest Rates and Fiscal Policy

    16/52

    elasticities. A higher sensibility of labor supply makes the output gap be lower due to

    the eect of hours worked on consumption through the individuals budget constraint.

    Meanwhile, higher intertemporal elasticity of substitution means consumers can easily

    transfer consumption to the future or vice versa, implying small changes in policy havebig eects on this variable and therefore on output gap. It is also true that if the output

    gap has a high weigh in the central banks loss function, the monetary authority will

    be willing to react largely to changes in the expected ination rate as this variable has an

    indirect eect on output gap through the FOC of the consumers. Finally, it is worth noting

    that, due to the backward-looking part of the model, I have obtained a forward-looking

    Taylor rule; forward-looking not only because interest rate reacts to expected ination, but

    also to expected output gap; so "backwardness" can be seen as a microfoundation for this

    type of rules.

    4.2 The Case of an Exogenous Fiscal Expenditure

    Households should not change their behavior with respect to the previous section. Firms,

    however, must now consider governments demand for goods and the central bank, must

    now take into account the governments expenditure level before solving its problem. This

    section describes these changes.

    4.2.1 Firms

    There are two major considerations in this setting. First of all, distorted sales taxes t levied

    by the government must be considered and second, now equilibrium needs yjt = cjt + gjt ;where gjt is the symmetric denition for the government demand of individual good j.

    Using this, it can be shown that yj;t+i = (pjt

    Pt+i)CTt+i; where C

    Tt is total consumption of

    composite good (private: Ct and public: Gt). Then, the forward-looking rms problem

    can be rewritten as:

    maxpfojt

    Et

    1Xi=0

    !ii;t+i[(pf ojtPt+i

    )1(1 t+i) t+i(pf ojtPt+i

    )]CTt+i

    The FOC for this problem is now given by:

    pf otPt

    =

    1

    EtP

    1

    i=0 !iiCt+i (Ct+i + Gt+i)t+i(

    Pt+iPt

    )

    EtP

    1

    i=0 !iiCt+i (Ct+i + Gt+i)(1 t+i)(

    Pt+iPt

    )1(14)

    16

  • 7/28/2019 Optimal Interest Rates and Fiscal Policy

    17/52

    This is the same result as in the previous section, except that the optimal price is

    now explicitly aected by the presence of the government consumption and the tax rate.

    Considering a distorted tax rate makes the price charged by each forward-looking rm to

    rise. This is a consequence of the type of tax assumed plus imperfect competition. If thepolicymaker decides to rise taxes on sales, producers will, due to their monopolistic power,

    transfer some portion of it to the consumers and thereby rise the price.

    From the previous equation, government consumption has not a clear cut eect on

    prices. However intuitively, as higher public consumption is assumed to be nanced only

    trough taxes, scal expenditure should have a direct eect on prices. That is to say, the

    scal authority must contract public expenditure if it does not want to put pressure on

    prices. Ination rate is now given by:

    t = 1bt + 2Ett+1 + 3t1 + 4bt (15)where s are dened in the appendix.

    As well as in equation (12), ination is forward-looking, real marginal cost is a very

    important determinant of the ination rate, but so are taxes in a positive way because of

    rms monopolistic power, as explained earlier.12 On the other hand, real marginal cost

    can again be expressed as:

    bt = P + P (b

    yt

    byft )

    GP

    (

    bgt

    bg ft ) (16)

    where P is the private participation in total consumption, with P + G = 1: So, whenthe governments behavior is taken into consideration, the real marginal cost deviation is

    a weighted average of the output gap and the "public gap". If we think of byt as composedby bct and bgt, the later has a lower weight. If for example there is a positive productivityshock and output increases, this pushes labor demand, which has a positive impact on real

    wage and therefore on real marginal cost. However, higher private consumption has an

    additional eect: higher consumption makes labor supply to contract, which means that

    real wage must rise, as well as real marginal cost. This last eect is not present in public

    consumption and that is why it has a lower weigh in the real marginal cost deviation.

    12

    Equation (15) is in line with the one found by Benigno and Woodford [2006] for the case of distortionarysales taxes.

    17

  • 7/28/2019 Optimal Interest Rates and Fiscal Policy

    18/52

    4.2.2 Government

    When scal expenditure is considered to be an exogenous process, I will claim it is of the

    form:

    Gt = G 8t

    So deviations around its steady state will be equal to zero in every moment of time

    (i.e. bgt = 0 8t) :4.2.3 Central Bank

    The central bank will again minimize its loss function subject to the demand and supply

    side of the economy. Demand side is obtained from the linelization of the Euler equation.

    Recalling that the output gap is dened as xt

    byt

    byft where goods market equilibrium

    imply byt = Pbct + Gbgt and exogenous scal expenditure implies bgt = 0; it will still be truethat the IS curve for this economy will be simply given by the linelization of the Euler

    equation. Dierent from the previous section, deviations of real marginal cost do take into

    account the presence of the government and therefore the central banks problem is now

    given by:

    mint+i;xt+i;it+i

    Et

    1Xi=0

    i(1

    22t+i +

    2x2t+i)

    st :

    xt = Etxt+1 +P

    Ett+1 Pi

    bit + utt = 1bt + 2Ett+1 + 3t1 + 4 P +

    Pxt

    The FOC of this problem still needs the output gap to behave as before, except that

    now it must be considered the private participation in total output P:

    xt Etxt+1 =4 (P + )

    PEtt+1 3Etxt+2 +

    1

    1

    2

    xt

    The optimal policy rule for the interest rate is now:

    bit = 1i1 4 ( + )

    2P

    Ett+1 + iP

    3Etxt+2 iP

    1 1

    2 xt + iP

    ut (17)

    18

  • 7/28/2019 Optimal Interest Rates and Fiscal Policy

    19/52

    So, the deviations of the interest rate around its steady state will behave in the same

    way as when no government was considered.

    4.3 The Case of a Self-interested Incumbent

    To see the behavior of economic variables when political issues are considered, I use the

    former except for the governments nature. As mentioned before, I assume politicians

    are self-interested and like to consume for their own purposes the same type of goods as

    households do, but to do this, the incumbent must be re-elected. However, re-election only

    happens if voters nd that the incumbent did well during its term in oce in terms of con-

    sumption and hours worked. That is to say, economic performance signals the incumbents

    competence and voters reward competence with reappointment. So, to understand how

    the incumbent decides on scal decits under this environment, it is useful to introduce

    rst the timing of the events and then present his maximization problem.

    4.3.1 Timing

    I shall focus the attention just on period t as it is not the aim of this paper to explain the

    economys behavior due to the existence of a political cycle but only due to an optimally

    driven scal decision, I therefore assume terms last only one period. The timing is the exact

    one as the described in the previous section, except that as far as re-election is concerned,

    the individuals will have to vote not only considering economic results but also inferring the

    governments competence. That is to say, during period t three dierent shocks occur: the

    productivity and scal shocks introduced earlier and also a government competence shockjt (j = a; b), which is private information for the government and may cause eective

    expenditure to be dierent from what expected. That is to say, while the government can

    commit to a tax code, it is uncertain (as well as citizens are) about the tax revenues it

    will generate; and consequently on its expenditure level. Competence is a time persistent

    variant process of the form:

    jt = jt +

    jt1; j = a; b

    where jt and jt1 are i.i.d. random variables with zero mean, known variance, distribution

    function F() and density function f() :

    At the end of period t citizens can observe the tax rate, the eective level of public

    19

  • 7/28/2019 Optimal Interest Rates and Fiscal Policy

    20/52

    expenditure and consequently the eective ination rate which can be dierent from the

    one induced by the central bank because of the possibly dierent expenditure level. They

    can also partially deduce governments competence; that is to say, they can guess t1

    using information from the announced public expenditure. To see this, note that at thebeginning of period t; E(Zt) = 1; E("t) = 0; E(t) = 0; so it must be true that:

    Gannouncedt = E(tYt) + t1

    from where t1 can be obtained. On the other hand, competence is not fully reveled

    because at the end of period t voters are not able to distinguish between the portion of

    public expenditure due to the productivity shock and the portion due to the competence

    shock t, and so, they must infer this component. This is the scenario under which elections

    take place at the end of period t.

    4.3.2 Incumbents Maximization Problem

    Policymakers are drawn randomly from citizenry and, since politicians are citizens, their

    preferences are derived from the specication of the preferences of voters.13 To capture

    this idea, I assume that when a candidate wins the elections, it will be able to consume

    the remaining fraction of public good by devoting the maximum amount of labor, N to

    the public sector. In contrast to Shi and Svenssons work I will not assume that while

    being in power, the policymaker is able to extract some "ego rents" (these ego rents could

    capture not only altruistic perceived benets, but also monetary private benets obtained

    each period). Furthermore, I suppose that if the incumbent is defeated in any re-election

    or voluntarily leaves the power, he never becomes a citizen again, i.e. there is no possibility

    of a "political career" (when politicians leave the oce to work again in the private sector);

    in other words, I will assume that no re-election entails minus innity utility. In this way,

    the incumbents utility function is,

    Vt =1X

    i=0

    i[((1 ) Gt+i)

    1

    1

    N1+

    1 + ]di

    13 In this sense, this model ts into the citizen-candidate framework in political economy. However in this

    case politicians are "exogenous", that is to say, citizens do not choose weather to run for public oce ornot, it is random.

    20

  • 7/28/2019 Optimal Interest Rates and Fiscal Policy

    21/52

    where di is an indicator function that equals di1 if the politician is in power in period t = i

    and zero otherwise; with d0 = 1: Now, because of the competence shock, the governments

    budget constraint is:

    Gt = tYt + "t + t

    The second idea to capture is that to hold oce it is necessary for the incumbent to

    be re-elected. As long as re-election is concerned, suppose party a is in power in period

    t, assuming that citizens do not vote strategically but sincerely, voter i will re-elect the

    incumbent if

    Et [Ua (t + 1)] Et [Ub (t + 1)] i

    0

    Dierence in expected utility is given by:

    Et [Ua (t + 1)] Et [Ub (t + 1)] = (G)1 Etbgat+1 Etbgbt+1 + C1 Etbcat+1 Etbcbt+1

    N1+

    Etbnat+1 Etbnbt+1It must be noticed that while citizens can learn about the incumbents competence,

    there is no way they can infer the challengers one and so Etbt+1 = 0. Taking expectation

    to the governments budget constraint and using the fact that Etat+1 = Et

    at ; the Euler

    equation and the linearized labor market equilibrium condition, the expected share of

    votes (ES V) can be expressed in terms of dierences of expected ination and tax rates

    as follows:

    ES V = Pr i Et [Ua (t + 1)] Et [Ub (t + 1)]= (G)1

    1

    P

    Etbat+1 Etbbt+1 1 Etat+1 Etbt+1 + 1PG Etat

    C1

    Et

    at+1 Et

    bt+1

    N1+

    Et

    at+1 Et

    bt+1

    + 1=2

    Therefore, the ES V depends on the expected dierence of tax rates between the two

    candidates, on expected dierence of ination rates and on the expected incumbents com-

    petence, all of which have a clear-cut eect. Higher taxes is the other side of higher public

    expenditure and higher public expenditure raises utility because a fraction of it is re-

    turned to households; this same logic applies for expected competence as higher publicexpenditure can also be due to the incumbentss competence. As long as expected ina-

    tion is concerned, higher ination rate tomorrow means lower expected consumption which

    21

  • 7/28/2019 Optimal Interest Rates and Fiscal Policy

    22/52

    lowers expected utility.

    To obtain the re-election probability it is necessary to notice rst that the term (G)1

    PG

    will be always positive for positive values of scal expenditure. Therefore, if candidate j

    wins the oce with simple majority, the incumbent will be re-elected if the expected shareof votes exceeds 1=2; in this way, using steady state relations, the probability of re-election

    is:

    = Pr (ES V 1=2)

    = Prn

    at G

    Etbat+1 Etbbt+1 + Etat+1 Etbt+1o= 1 F

    hG

    Etbat+1 Etbbt+1 + Etat+1 Etbt+1i (18)

    where (G)1

    PG h(G)1

    +C1

    +N1+

    i > 0: The rst thing to notice is that ifination and taxes are expected to be the same between the incumbent and the challenger,the incumbent will be reelected with probability one, this is because voters can learn

    something about the incumbent but know nothing about the challenger. Also, we can see

    that raising tax rates raises re-election probability but raising expected ination lowers this

    probability for the reasons given above.

    Now, to see the incumbents maximization problem, note that it will have no incentives

    to manipulate expenditure to impress voters beyond period t + 1. This is because the

    probability of re-election at the end oft + 1, which determines periods t + 2 outcome, will

    be inuenced by the incumbents expected competence at t + 2. The fact that competence

    is a MA(1) process, autocorrelation of order two or higher is zero. In other words, expectedcompetence in t+2 is independent of actual competence, i.e., Et

    t+2=t

    = Et

    t+2

    = 0:

    So, the incumbent will be interested in maximizing its total expected utility only over

    the next two periods by choosing the optimal tax rate, that is to say, the incumbents

    22

  • 7/28/2019 Optimal Interest Rates and Fiscal Policy

    23/52

    maximization problem is given by:

    maxt

    Et[(1 ) Gt]

    1

    1 + Et

    [(1 ) Gt+1]1

    1

    st :

    = 1 Fh

    G

    Etbat+1 Etbbt+1 + Etat+1 Etbt+1iEtt+1 =

    11 23

    Etbt+1 + 21 23

    Ett+2 +4

    1 23Etbt+1

    +13

    1 23bt + 34

    1 23bt + 231 23t1bt = P + P (byt byft ) GP (bgt bg ft )

    byt = P

    bct + G

    bgt

    and Gt = tYt + "t + t

    holds 8t

    The FOC for the former problem leads to the following optimal consumption path:

    EtG

    t = f ()34G

    (1 ) (1 23) GEtG

    1t+1 (19)

    where G

    Etbat+1 Etbbt+1+ Etat+1 Etbt+1 : This equation shows that a self-interested incumbent will also equalize marginal benet of public expenditure to marginal

    cost. Marginal benet is independent from the fraction of public good that is returned to

    households (this is because of the functional form assumed for the preferences and therefore

    is not only aecting the marginal benet, but also the marginal cost; that is to say, the

    incumbent does not care the percentage of public expenditure it can appropriate as long

    it is positive (i:e:0 < < 1) and does not change over time) and equals the consumption

    level the incumbent can have today. Marginal cost is equal, on the other hand, to the

    consumption level he is giving up tomorrow times the change in the re-election probability

    he causes when he raises scal expenditure today and therefore puts pressure on ination.

    4.3.3 Central Bank

    I will linearize the equation for optimal scal expenditure and use it as the public component

    of the output gap; the private component will be given again by the Euler equation. The

    23

  • 7/28/2019 Optimal Interest Rates and Fiscal Policy

    24/52

    central banks problem is, therefore,

    mint+i;xt+i

    Et

    1

    Xi=0i(

    1

    22t+i +

    2x2t+i)

    st :

    xt = Etxt+1 +P

    Ett+1 Pi

    bit G

    Etbgt+1 + ut

    t = 1bt + 2Ett+1 + 3t1 + 4 P + P

    xt GP

    (bgt bg ft )The optimal policy rule for the interest rate is now:

    bit =

    Pi

    P

    4 (P + )

    P

    Ett+1 +

    iP3Etxt+2

    iP

    1

    1

    2

    xt

    +

    G

    Pi (1 )bgt + Pi ut (20)While it is still true that this is a forward-looking type of interest rate rule, comparing

    the two interest rules obtained (equations (17) and (20)); the rst thing to notice is that now

    the best response of the central bank should explicitly consider governments deviations

    with respect to is steady state. If the incumbent rises scal expenditure such that it

    overheats the economy, the central bank, in response to his loss function, must rise the

    interest rate to cool down the economy. This is a signaling eect for the government of

    how committed is the central bank with ination; when scal expenditure is given by an

    exogenous process, the central bank can do nothing to change its level; however, if scal

    expenditure is handled with discretion, it can somehow threaten him in order not to put

    so much pressure on ination. Furthermore, the bigger the public sector relative to the

    private one, the more responsive the monetary authority should be.

    5 Economys Response to Shocks

    I will allow scal expenditure to have a one percent external shock (explained for example

    with a natural catastrophe or the implementation of a public policy that required more

    resources than expected); and see how should the central bank react in both scenarios: when

    scal expenditure is given and when it is endogenously determined. I will use the Rotenbergand Woodford [1997] calibration for US data; a value of seventy percent for the fraction

    of rms using the backward-looking rule (Gal and Gertler [1999] mention a value between

    24

  • 7/28/2019 Optimal Interest Rates and Fiscal Policy

    25/52

    sixty and eighty percent of rms adjusting prices in a backward-looking way); a relative

    low fraction of scal expenditure returned to households and a weigh of thirty percent for

    the relative importance of output gap in the central banks loss function. In this way, the

    set of parameters to be used are: = 0:99; ! = 0:3; = 0:157; = 0:2; = 0:7; = 0:1and = 0:1: Relevant equations for the impulse response functions are:

    Linearized Euler equation;

    Linearized labor supply;

    Linearized labor demand,

    Ination equation (HNKPC);

    Linearized FOC for the government;

    Linearized governments budget constraint and

    Optimal interest rate rule.

    The resulting policy and transition functions are as follows:

    bit = 4:4455t1 + 0:0231"tt = 0:0921t1 + 0:0359"t

    bgt = "t

    bt = 0:3496t1 + 0:9749"tbct = 0:3714t1 0:0358"tbnt = bzt1 + 0:2916t1 + 0:0281"twhen scal expenditure is considered as an exogenous process, and:

    bit = 0:0665bgt1 + 4:4455t1 + 0:3572"tt = 0:0069bgt1 + 0:0921t1 + 0:0373"tb

    gt = 0:1862

    bgt1 + "t

    bt = 0:1774bgt1 + 0:3496t1 + 0:9525"tbct = 0:0022bgt1 0:3714t1 0:012"tbnt = bzt1 0:0017bgt1 + 0:2916t1 + 0:0094"t25

  • 7/28/2019 Optimal Interest Rates and Fiscal Policy

    26/52

    when scal expenditure is considered as an endogenous process.

    Figure 1 presents the impulse response functions for a one percent scal shock; the

    doted line represents the case where scal expenditure is an exogenous process while the

    solid line represents the case where scal expenditure is manipulated by a self-interestedincumbent. The main dierence between the two lines, and my main focus, is how reactive

    the interest rate is in each scenario. While in the case of an exogenous scal process the

    interest rate must rise by 0:0359 to a scal shock, in the case of an endogenous scal policy

    it must rise by 0:3572: That is to say, the central bank must react in a signicantly higher

    way to a scal shock to give the government a suitable signal of how committed it is to

    its ination target. This is purely signaling as, due to the economys structure, inations

    reaction is not signicantly dierent in both scenarios. We can also see that a one percent

    shock to scal expenditure makes tax rate to rise a little less than proportional, this is

    because total output (the tax base) will be lower after the shock. This is because eventhough the increase of scal expenditure relative higher than the decrease in consumption,

    the parameter set used implies a very low scal participation in total output, G: Thereby,

    the increase of total output ends up being lower than 1% and so is the increase in the tax

    rate. It is also true that, starting from the steady state, higher scal expenditure puts

    inationary pressures and therefore the central bank must contract the economy. This

    higher interest rate level has a negative impact on consumption and this has a positive

    impact on labor; this is why consumption and labor react in a very similar way (though

    26

  • 7/28/2019 Optimal Interest Rates and Fiscal Policy

    27/52

    opposite in sign).

    Interest Rate

    -0,05

    0

    0,05

    0,1

    0,15

    0,2

    0,25

    0,3

    0,35

    0,4

    1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10

    End Exo

    Inflation

    -0,01

    -0,005

    0

    0,005

    0,01

    0,015

    0,02

    0,025

    0,03

    0,035

    0,04

    1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10

    End Exo

    Fiscal Expenditure

    -0,4

    -0,2

    0

    0,2

    0,4

    0,6

    0,8

    1

    1,2

    1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10

    End Exo

    Tax Rate

    -0,4

    -0,2

    0

    0,2

    0,4

    0,6

    0,8

    1

    1,2

    1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10

    End Exo

    Consumption

    -0,04

    -0,035

    -0,03

    -0,025

    -0,02

    -0,015

    -0,01

    -0,005

    0

    0,005

    1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10

    End Exo

    Labor

    -0,005

    0

    0,005

    0,01

    0,015

    0,02

    0,025

    0,03

    1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10

    End Exo

    Figure 1: IRF0s to a 1% F iscal S hock

    27

  • 7/28/2019 Optimal Interest Rates and Fiscal Policy

    28/52

    6 Extension: The Case of a Benevolent Government

    In the previous sections I have obtained the optimal interest rate rule that came up when

    scal and monetary authorities are not coordinated and have opposite interests. That is to

    say, I have answered the question of how monetary policy be conducted if the central bank

    is concerned with individuals welfare but the government is only concerned with his own

    welfare (in terms of consumption and re-election). Monetary authority should behave in a

    dierent, and in particular in a more aggressive way, when the government has incentives

    to manipulate scal expenditure in order to maximize his own consumption and re-election

    probability, compared to the case where scal expenditure is an exogenous process. That

    is to say, the fact that scal and monetary authorities incentives are not aligned makes

    the central bank be willing to signal its commitment to ination and rise the interest rate

    whenever the government rises scal expenditure beyond its steady state level.

    This section on the other hand, poses the question of how monetary policy should be

    conducted is scal and monetary authorities incentives are aligned. That is to say, if not

    only the central bank but also the government is concerned with individuals welfare. This

    assumption gives us a very interesting scenario where the institutionality underlying has

    guaranteed not only the use of the interest rate but also os scal expenditure in favor

    of individuals welfare; as can be expected to be in countries that actually use ination

    targeting.

    6.1 Government

    To obtain the optimal interest rate rule, three things must be noticed. First, households

    should not change their behavior with respect to the previous sections. Second, rms

    must still consider governments demand for goods; and nally, there is no reason why a

    benevolent incumbent should not be reappointed in oce. A benevolent incumbent should

    always be reappointed because it is known by voters that he will have no incentives (or no

    means) to appropriate from a portion of public expenditure; so the challenger should not be

    any dierent from the incumbent.14 In this way, a benevolent planner will be interested in

    setting scal expenditure as to maximize the representative households utility, aware that

    the consumer will set its allocation eciently where the Euler equation holds and marginal

    14 Another way to deal with this issue is to assume that the incumbent wins the elections with an exogenousprobability . Considering 8t is just a special case that has no impact in the optimal interest rate ruleobtained.

    28

  • 7/28/2019 Optimal Interest Rates and Fiscal Policy

    29/52

    utility of private consumption and leisure are equal. Moreover, the problem will also be

    restricted by the prot maximization of rms through the HNKPC (considered one period

    ahead) and market clearing: a feasibility condition that private and public consumption

    should not exceed output, and labor demand equalizing labor supply. So, the benevolentplanners problem will be:

    maxGt

    Et

    1Xi=0

    i[(Gt+i)

    1

    1 +

    C1t+i1

    R10 N

    1+jt+idj

    1 + ]

    s:t: :

    Ct = (1 + it)EtPt

    Pt+1Ct+1 ;

    NtCt

    =wtPt

    ; (Labor Supply)

    Ett+1 = 11 23

    Etbt+1 + 21 23

    Ett+2 + 41 23

    Etbt+1+

    131 23

    bt + 341 23

    bt + 231 23t1bt = P + P (byt byft ) GP (bgt bg ft )Yt Ct + Gt

    Nt =YtwtPt

    ; (Labor Demand)

    and Gt = tYt + "t holds 8t

    Optimal expenditure must then satisfy:

    1Gt +

    Y

    341 23

    (1 + it) C1t Et

    Ct+1

    (1 + t+1)2

    1 +

    1 + N1t (Ct + Gt)

    =

    N1t1 +

    Ct

    "1 +

    Y

    341 23

    (1 + it) EtCt+1

    (1 + t+1)2

    #(21)

    So, a benevolent government equals marginal benet of public expenditure to its mar-

    ginal cost. The former is given by the direct eect of scal expenditure on utility, the term1Gt and the indirect eect of scal expenditure on utility through expected ination.

    Higher expenditure today means, ceteris paribus, higher expected ination for tomorrow,

    29

  • 7/28/2019 Optimal Interest Rates and Fiscal Policy

    30/52

    which lowers real interest rate; the Euler equation says households will make intertemporal

    substitution raising present consumption and therefore utility. The second part of this

    indirect eect says that higher consumption today makes labor supply to contract, making

    households to work fewer hours which raises utility even further. Marginal cost of publicconsumption has, likewise, a direct and indirect eect. Higher public consumption pushes

    aggregate demand so that production must raise and so must labor demand. higher labor

    demand means more hours devoted to work and therefore lower utility. The indirect eect

    is again a consequence of the ination channel. As mentioned before, public expenditure

    has a positive eect on current consumption through expected ination. This in turn has

    a positive eect on aggregate demand that expands further with the consistent decrease in

    utility.

    6.2 Central Bank

    The central bank will again minimize its loss function subject to the demand and supply

    side of the economy. As in the previous section, let xt byt byft be the output gap withrespect to the exible price case; recalling that byt = Pbct+Gbgt, linealization of the FOC forthe incumbent (which already incorporates the linearization of the Euler equation) results

    in the demand side, whereas the supply side is given by the HNKPC. The central banks

    problem is now as follows:

    mint+i;xt+i

    Et

    1

    Xi=0i(

    1

    22t+i +

    2x2t+i)

    st :

    xt = Etxt+1 + GB1Ett+1 + (GB2 + P)bct + GB3bit+GB4bnt + (GB5 P) Etbct+1 GEtbgt+1 + ut

    t = 1bt + 2Ett+1 + 3t1 + 4 P + P

    xt GP

    (bgt bg ft )where coecients B0s are dened in the appendix. The FOC of this problem still needs

    the output gap to behave as before:

    xt Etxt+1 =

    4 (P + )

    P Ett+1 3Etxt+2 + 1 12xt

    30

  • 7/28/2019 Optimal Interest Rates and Fiscal Policy

    31/52

    The optimal policy rule for the interest rate is now:

    bit = 1Ett+1 2xt+2 + 3xt + 4Et

    bct+1 + 5

    bgt + 6Et

    bgt+1 +

    eut (22)

    where the 0s and eut are dened in the appendix. In this way, I obtain an interest raterule that once again is dierent from the one found in Clarida et al (it = i (Ett+1; gt))

    but not dierent from more general specications of forward looking Taylor rules.15 I

    would like to highlight four things about this last equation. First, equation (22) says

    that the monetary authority sets the interest rate using the information available in t to

    forecast ination and public and private consumption for next period; so, this interest

    rate rule that explicitly incorporates the optimal decision problem of a benevolent planner

    also gives microfoundations to forward looking Taylor rules. However, in contrast to the

    optimal interest rate rule found for the case of a self-interested incumbent, the forward-

    looking part is independent of "backwardness"; that is to say, even in the special case

    where all rms adjust prices in a forward-looking way (i.e. 2 = 3 = 0) I would still

    obtain a microfounded forward-looking Taylor rule. Another important result is that (22)

    tells us that the presence of a government (even a benevolent one) must alter the central

    banks behavior. The central bank must explicitly consider scal policy not only because

    this model assumes that a fraction of public expenditure is returned to households, but

    also (and more relevant) because public expenditure aects expected ination a that has

    a direct eect on households welfare through private consumption.16 In third place, and

    closely related to the previous point, optimal interest rate rules for the case of a benevolent

    planner diers from the one for the case of a self-interested incumbent in the fact that for theformer, the central bank is also concerned about expected deviations of scal expenditure

    the next period. The intuition behind this result is that when a self-interested incumbent

    is in charge of scal policy, he faces a trade-o between actual expenditure and re-election

    probability. If the self-interested incumbent rises scal expenditure beyond its steady

    state level, it is expected to be lower tomorrow so that his re-election probability does

    not drop deeply. So, deviations of scal expenditure today have information about scal

    expenditure tomorrow and in this way, bgt turns to be the relevant variable for the centralbanks decisions. This trade-o however, is no longer present when scal expenditure is

    15

    Of the form it = i + (et+1 ) + xx

    et+1:16 This result does not change if the game between the government and the central bank would be

    simultaneous.

    31

  • 7/28/2019 Optimal Interest Rates and Fiscal Policy

    32/52

    in charge of a benevolent planner; so the central bank must also consider expected scal

    expenditure tomorrow before setting the interest rate. Finally, it is possible to show that

    for certain parameters values (in particular for and suciently low), contrary to what

    the optimal interest rate rule tells us when the government is purely self-interested, interestrate is less reactive the bigger is the public sector relative to the private sector. This is

    because incentives are now aligned and both authorities are looking forward individuals

    welfare; so if the public sector is relatively large, the central bank can somehow rest on the

    government and need not to have a so aggressive policy.

    7 Conclusion

    Governments do not always take their scal decisions thinking about individuals welfare

    but thinking only in their owns. This has a great impact on the decisions an independent

    and welfare-concerned central bank makes. In this paper I have used a general equilibrium

    model with nominal rigidities (staggered prices) and ination inertia that comes from the

    assumption that a fraction of rms behave in a backward-looking way. This model has

    enabled me to study how does optimal interest rate rules should change when there is

    no government and when government expenditure is considered as an exogenous process

    or is in charge of a self-interested incumbent that reveals its competence only partially.

    The main contribution of this paper is the interaction between the central bank and a

    self-interested incumbent whose trade-o is given by the fact that he would like to rise

    todays expenditure level in order to appropriate from a fraction of it but, starting from

    the steady state, scal expenditure puts inationary pressures in the economy. Due to

    ination inertia present, higher ination today implies higher ination tomorrow, and this

    aects in a negative way to the incumbents re-election probability, which clearly curbs

    scal decision.

    At the beginning of the paper, in the introduction, I put forward regression results for

    Australia, Chile and Peru that showed that target interest rates react dierently in each

    country. The Federal Reserve Bank of Australia has a very little response (and even not

    statistically signicant) to a 1% change in scal expenditure; while this is considerably

    larger in Chile and Peru. In tune with this observation, the main result of the paper is

    that if scal expenditure is given by an exogenous process, then the central bank can donothing to change it and therefore, the optimal interest rate rule says that deviations of the

    nominal interest rate should not consider scal expenditure at all; as if no government was

    32

  • 7/28/2019 Optimal Interest Rates and Fiscal Policy

    33/52

    present. When scal expenditure is, on the other hand, manipulated by a self-interested

    incumbent, then the central bank should signal how much it is willing to defend ination

    and rise the interest rate above its steady state level. This over-reaction is bigger the bigger

    the public sector is relative to the private sector.Starting form the steady state, if I disturb the economy with a 1% scal shock, impulse

    response functions tell us that the interest rate response is ten times larger with a self-

    interested incumbent than with an exogenous process. This over-reaction is, as implied by

    the model, purely a signaling eect as the change in ination does not dier signicantly

    in both scenarios (this is clearly due to the economys structure).

    Another result is that, considering a fraction of rms that set prices in a backward-

    looking way results in a forward-looking Taylor rule. It is a forward-looking Taylor rule

    not only because interest rate reacts to expected ination, as happens to be in standard

    models, but also because interest rate reacts to expected output gap. In this way, thismodel gives a microfoundation to this type of rules.

    Finally, if instead of a self-interested incumbent I assume the governments and central

    banks incentives are aligned in such way that they both care about individuals welfare, I

    nd that the optimal interest rate rule must consider not only deviations of scal expendi-

    ture two periods ahead (which is a consequence of the backward-looking assumption of the

    model), but must also consider deviations of scal expenditure for the next period. The

    intuition behind this result is that when the government behaves as a benevolent planner

    there no longer exists the trade-o between actual expenditure and re-election probability.

    In this way, actual deviations of scal expenditure tells nothing to the central bank about

    tomorrows level of public consumption (relative to its steady state level) and therefore the

    central bank must use the information available in t to forecast scal expenditure in t + 1.

    Furthermore incentives alignment enables the monetary authority to be less reactive to de-

    viations of scal expenditure; that is to say, the central bank should response to deviations

    of public consumption in a more friendly way if it knows the government is manipulating

    his consumption not to maximize his own utility but to maximize individuals one.

    33

  • 7/28/2019 Optimal Interest Rates and Fiscal Policy

    34/52

    A Appendix A: Regressions

    For the regressions mentioned in the introduction I used target interest rates declared by

    central banks, seasonally adjusted public consumption and the percentage change in CPI

    index for Australia, Chile and Peru. Data was collected from the websites of the central

    banks and national statistical oces of each country. Regressions were run in logs for

    the target interest rates and scal expenditure so that the estimated coecients are the

    elasticity of interest rate with respect to scal expenditure; ination was considered in

    percentages. As an independent variable, scal expenditure was introduced with one lag

    because information on GDP is available with some delay (in fact this is the reason why I

    did not include the last quarter of 2008 in the data). The estimation method was simply

    OLS. Output windows are the following:

    Table 1 - Regressions

    Dependent Variable: log(Target Interest Rate)

    Country Australia Chile Peru

    Method OLS OLS OLS

    Observations 62 21 16

    log(Fiscal Expenditure) 0.02171 2.02405* 0.95506*

    (0.8796) (0.0000) (0.0035)

    Ination 0.08658** 0.108*** -0.01873

    (0.0176) (0.01018) (0.7967)

    * Signicant at the 1% level

    ** Signicant at the 5% level

    *** Signicant at the 10% levelp-values shown in parenthesis

    34

  • 7/28/2019 Optimal Interest Rates and Fiscal Policy

    35/52

    B Appendix B: Solving the Model

    B.1 Households

    Consumers problem is solved in two stages: rst minimize the cost of buying a certainlevel of composite good Ct and then maximize their utility function subject to their budget

    constraint. Minimization implies the solution of the following problem:

    mincjt

    Z10

    pjt cjt dj

    s:t : Ct [

    Z10

    c1

    jt dj]

    1

    Let t be the lagrange multiplier associated to the constraint, the FOC with respect to cjt

    is:

    pjt = t[Z10

    c1

    jt dj]

    11

    c 1

    jt

    But [R10 c

    1

    jt dj]1

    1 = C1

    t ; so the former condition can be rewritten as:

    pjt = tC1

    t c

    1

    jt

    cjt = Ct

    pjtt

    Using the denition of the composite good:

    Ct =

    Z10

    c1

    jt dj]

    1

    Ct = [

    Z10

    C1

    t

    pjtt

    1dj]

    1 )

    t = [

    Z10

    p1jt dj]

    1

    t = [

    Z10

    p1jt dj]1

    1 Pt

    35

  • 7/28/2019 Optimal Interest Rates and Fiscal Policy

    36/52

    Substituting the denition of the lagrange multiplier in the FOC obtained earlier, I obtain

    the demand for individual good j :

    cjt = Ct pjtPt

    The second step will give us the Euler equation and the labor supply:

    maxCt;Nt;Bt

    Et

    1Xi=0

    i[(Gt+i)

    1

    1 +

    C1t+i1

    R10 N

    1+jt+idj

    1 + + sAt+i]

    s:t : Ct +BtPt

    =wtR10 Njt dj

    Pt+ (1 + it1)

    Bt1Pt

    + t

    Let t be the corresponding lagrange multiplier; then FOC with respect to Ct; Ct+1; Njt

    and Bt are, respectively:

    Ct = t

    EtCt+1 = t+1

    Njt = twtPt

    tPt

    = (1 + it)t+1Pt+1

    Using the fourth FOC and combining the rst three, I obtain the Euler equation (equation

    (8)) and labor supply (equation (9)):

    CtEtC

    t+1

    = (1 + it)Pt

    Pt+1)

    Ct = (1 + it) EtPt

    Pt+1Ct+1 and

    Njt = Ct

    wtPt

    B.2 Firms

    Let me rst obtain equation (15) and then show that (12) is just a special case when

    no government is considered. Forward-looking rms, as well as consumers, also have atwo-step solution to set their optimal price; they rst minimize costs from where the real

    marginal cost is obtained and then choose the price pjt that maximizes the present value

    36

  • 7/28/2019 Optimal Interest Rates and Fiscal Policy

    37/52

    of expected utilities. The rst part of the problem implies solving:

    minNjt

    wtPt

    Njt

    s:t : yjt = ZtNjt

    Let t be the lagrange multiplier, then, the FOC is:

    t =wtPt

    Zt

    So, t is the real marginal cost. On the other hand, each rm must face the demand for its

    dierentiated product, then total demand of product j

    cTjt

    is given by individual demand

    from households and government:

    cTjt = cjt + gjt

    = Ct

    pjtPt

    + Gt

    pjtPt

    =

    pjtPt

    (Ct + Gt)

    =

    pjtPt

    CTt

    Imposing market clear condition for goods, it must be true that:

    yjt = cT

    jt

    =

    pjtPt

    CTt

    Then the pricing decision for the forward-looking rm can be expressed as:

    maxpfojt

    Et

    1Xi=0

    !ii;t+i[(pf ojtPt+i

    )1(1 t+i) t+i

    pf ojt

    Pt+i

    !]CTt+i

    37

  • 7/28/2019 Optimal Interest Rates and Fiscal Policy

    38/52

    The FOC with respect to the optimal price is:

    Et

    1

    Xi=0 !ii;t+i[(1 ) (

    pf ojt

    Pt+i

    )(1 t+i)1

    Pt+i

    + t+i pf ojt

    Pt+i!1

    1

    Pt+i

    ]CTt+i = 0

    As all rms face the same problem, they will all set the same optimal price pf ot so that:

    Et

    1Xi=0

    !ii;t+i[(1 ) (pf ot

    Pt+i)(1 t+i) + t+i]C

    Tt+iP

    t+i = 0

    Recall that the stochastic discount factor is i;t+i = i(Ct+i=Ct)

    ; so pf ot must satisfy:

    Et

    1

    Xi=0 !iiCt+i (Ct+i + Gt+i)[(1 )

    pf otPt

    PtPt+i

    (1 t+i) + t+i]Pt+i = 0

    Then solving forpfotPt

    :

    pf otPt

    =

    1

    EtP

    1

    i=0 !iiCt+i (Ct+i + Gt+i)t+i(

    Pt+iPt

    )

    EtP

    1

    i=0 !iiCt+i (Ct+i + Gt+i)(1 t+i)(

    Pt+iPt

    )1

    The optimal price set by each forward and backward-looking rm must be linearized

    around its steady state in order to obtain the HNKPC, where ination is dened as t

    ln

    Pt

    Pt1: To obtain equation (15) lets rst dene Qt as the relative price a rm sets

    when it has to adjust prices, so Qt p

    tPt ; note that in steady state, when all rms can

    adjust prices it must be true that, QSS = 1; and also note that bqt = ln QtQSS : Secondly,we know that the general price level Pt is a weighted average between the price set by

    adjusting rms and the general price level the period before; I also have an equation for

    the optimal price set by adjusting rms (forward and backward-looking) and nally, the

    FOC for forward-looking rms: So the relevant equations are:

    Qt ptPt

    ; Qf ot pf otPt

    ; Qbat pbatPt

    (B.1)

    P1t = (1 !)(p

    t )1 + !P1t1 (B.2)

    38

  • 7/28/2019 Optimal Interest Rates and Fiscal Policy

    39/52

    pt = (1 )pf ot + p

    bat (B.3)

    pbat = p

    t1 (B.4)

    pf otPt

    =

    1

    EtP

    1

    i=0 !iiCt+i (Ct+i + Gt+i)t+i(

    Pt+iPt

    )

    EtP

    1

    i=0 !iiCt+i (Ct+i + Gt+i)(1 t+i)(

    Pt+iPt

    )1(B.5)

    Expressing (B:2) in percentage deviations around the steady state, we can see that:

    1 = (1 !)(ptPt

    )1 + !

    Pt1

    Pt

    1)

    0 = (1 !)bqt !tbqt = !1 !

    t

    From (B:4) ; I can express the price set by backward-looking rms as:

    pbatPt

    =pt1Pt1

    Pt1Pt

    )

    Qbat = Qt1Pt1

    Pt)

    bqbat = bqt1 t

    I can use this in (B:3), previously expressed in percentage deviations around the steady

    state:

    Qt = (1 ) Qf ot + Q

    bat )bqt = (1 )bqf ot + bqbat )bqt = (1 )bqf ot + bqt1 t

    Leaving this aside for a moment, note that if for simplicity I dene 1 ; (B:5) can

    39

  • 7/28/2019 Optimal Interest Rates and Fiscal Policy

    40/52

    be expressed as:

    Qt "Et1

    Xi=0 !iiCt+i (Ct+i + Gt+i)(1 t+i)(

    Pt+iPt

    )1#= Et

    1Xi=0

    !iiCt+i (Ct+i + Gt+i)t+i(Pt+i

    Pt)

    So that the LHS (which I will denote by ) can be approximated by:

    (SS) +@

    @Qt+i

    SS

    Qf ot+i 1

    +

    @

    @Ct+i

    SS

    (Ct+i C) +@

    @Gt+i

    SS

    (Gt+i G)

    +@

    @t+i

    SS

    (t+i ) +@

    @Pt+i

    Pt

    SS

    Pt+i

    Pt 1

    (a) (SS) =C(C+G)(1)

    1!

    (b) @@Qt+i

    SS

    (Qt+i 1) =C(C+G)(1)

    1! bqf ot(c) @@Ct+i

    SS

    (Ct+i C) = (1 )X

    i

    !ii

    (1 ) C1 CG

    Etbct+i(d) @@Gt+i

    SS

    (Gt+i G) = (1 )X

    i

    !iiCGEtbgt+i(e) @

    @t+i SS (t+i ) = C(C+ G)Xi !iiEtbt+i(f ) @

    @Pt+iPt

    SS

    Pt+i

    Pt 1

    = (1 ) C(C+ G)

    Xi

    !ii ( 1) (Etbpt+i bpt)On the other hand, denote the RHS by ; so that it can be approximated by:

    (SS) +@

    @Ct+i

    SS

    (Ct+i C) +@

    @Gt+i

    SS

    (Gt+i G)

    +@

    @t+i SS t+i

    + +@

    @Pt+i

    Pt

    SS

    Pt+iPt

    1

    (a) (SS) =

    C(C+G)1!

    40

  • 7/28/2019 Optimal Interest Rates and Fiscal Policy

    41/52

    (b) @@Ct+i

    SS

    (Ct+i C) = X

    i

    !ii

    (1 ) C1 CG

    Etbct+i(c) @@Gt+i SS (Gt+i G) = Xi !

    iiCGEtbgt+i(d) @@t+i

    SS

    t+i

    = C(C+ G)

    Xi

    !iiEtbt+i(e) @

    @Pt+iPt

    SS

    Pt+i

    Pt 1

    = C(C+ G)

    Xi

    !ii(Etbpt+i bpt)Equating both sides and canceling terms:

    bpf ot + bq

    f ot = (1 !)"

    1 Xi !iiEtbt+i + Xi !

    ii Etbt+i + Etbpt+i#I can then bring forward this expression, take the expected value in t and then replace

    it again in the previous equation so that bpf ot and bqf ot will be expressed only in terms ofbpf ot+1 and bqf ot+1 :bqf ot = (1 !) 1 bt + bt

    + !Etbqf ot+1 + !Ett+1

    It is also possible to express Et

    bqf ot+1 in terms of Et

    bqt+1;

    bqt and Ett+1: Finally, recall

    that

    bqt = !1 !

    t )

    Etbqt+1 = !1 !

    Ett+1

    Substituting these two equations in the resulting one from the previous steps, I can

    obtain an expression for the ination rate, which is equation (15) :

    t = 1

    bt + 2Ett+1 + 3t1 + 4

    bt

    41

  • 7/28/2019 Optimal Interest Rates and Fiscal Policy

    42/52

    where

    0

    !

    1 !+

    !

    1 +

    1

    1 0 (1 )(1 !) 1

    2 0!

    (1 )

    +

    !

    (1 !)

    3 0

    !

    1 !4 0 (1 )(1 !)

    Note that for the special case where no government is considered, = 0 and in that

    way I obtain equation (12) :

    B.3 Central Bank

    In order to obtain the central banks best response function (13) ; I must solve the following

    problem:

    mint+i;xt+i;it+i

    Et

    1Xi=0

    i(1

    22t+i +

    2x2t+i)

    st :

    xt = Etxt+1 +1

    Ett+1

    i

    bit + ut

    t = 2Ett+1 + 3t1 + 4 ( + ) xt

    Let t and t be the lagrange multipliers associated to the IS and HNK PC curves

    respectively; then the FOC whith respect to it+i says that:

    t+i

    = 0

    42

  • 7/28/2019 Optimal Interest Rates and Fiscal Policy

    43/52

    which implies that t = 08t; that os to say, the IS curve is not an active restriction. In

    this way, I can rewrite the central banks problem as:

    mint+i;xt+i Et

    1Xi=0

    i(1

    2 2t+i +

    2 x2t+i)

    st :

    t = 2Ett+1 + 3t1 + 4 ( + ) xt

    Let again t be the lagrange multiplier associated to the active restriction, the FOCs

    with respect to t+i and xt+i respectively are:

    t+i + t+i 2

    t+i1 3t+i+1 = 0

    xt+i t+i4 ( + ) = 0

    Then, using the value of the lagrange multiplier from the second equation and replacing it

    in the rst one, I obtain:

    t+i =

    4 ( + )xt+i

    t+i1 =

    4 ( + )xt+i1

    t+i+1 =

    4 ( + )xt+i+1

    Therefore:

    t+i =2

    4 ( + )xt+i1

    4 ( + )xt+i + 3

    4 ( + )xt+i+1 )

    Ett+1 =

    4 ( + )

    2

    xt Etxt+1 + 3Etxt+2

    )

    xt Etxt+1 = 4 ( + ) Ett+1 3Etxt+2 +

    1

    2

    xt

    43

  • 7/28/2019 Optimal Interest Rates and Fiscal Policy

    44/52

    Now, replace this in the IS curve:

    xt Etxt+1 =1

    Ett+1 i

    bit

    + ut (IS curve)

    4 ( + ) Ett+1 3Etxt+2 + 1 2 xt = 1

    Ett+1 ibit + ut

    The optimal interest rule is:

    bit = 1i

    1

    4 ( + )

    Ett+1 +

    i3Etxt+2

    i

    1

    1

    2

    xt +

    iut

    If the government with an exogenous expenditure level is considered, the IS curve is

    still not binding, so the central banks problem is as follows:

    mint+i;xt+i

    Et

    1Xi=0

    i( 12 2t+i + 2 x

    2t+i)

    st :

    t = 1bt + 2Ett+1 + 3t1 + 4 P + P

    xt

    This is because as Gt = G8t, then bgt = 08t ) xt = byt byft = Pbct byft : The FOC are now:t+i =

    P4 (P + )

    xt+i

    t+i1 = P4 (P + )

    xt+i1

    t+i+1 =P

    4 (P + )xt+i+1

    Which implies:

    t+i =P

    4 (P + )

    2

    xt Etxt+1 + 3Etxt+2

    Ett+1 =

    P4 (P + )

    2

    xt Etxt+1 + 3Etxt+2

    xt Etxt+1 = 4 (P + )

    PEtt+1 3Etxt+2 + 1 2

    xt

    44

  • 7/28/2019 Optimal Interest Rates and Fiscal Policy

    45/52

    Once again, I replace this condition in the IS curve:

    xt Etxt+1 =P

    Ett+1 i

    bit

    + ut (IS curve) )

    bit = 1i1 4 ( + )

    2P

    Ett+1 + iP

    3Etxt+2 iP

    1 1

    2xt + iP

    ut

    For the case of a self-interested government the only dierence in the central banks

    problem is given by the IS curve as Gt obeys equation (20):

    xt Etxt+1 =P

    Ett+1 ibit P

    Etbgt+1 + ut (IS curve)

    Therefore:

    bit = Pi P 4 (P + )P Ett+1 + iP 3Etxt+2 iP 1 12xt+

    G

    Pi (1 )bgt +

    Piut

    B.4 Extension: The Case of a Benevolent Government

    To obtain the interest rate rule in the case of a benevolent planner, it is necessary rst to

    solve the governments problem as follows:

    maxGt

    Et

    1

    Xi=0i[

    (Gt+i)1

    1 +

    C1t+i1

    R10 N

    1+jt+idj

    1 + ]

    s:t: :

    Ct = (1 + it)EtPt

    Pt+1Ct+1 ;

    Nt =

    (Ct + Gt) Ct

    1

    Ett+1 =1

    1 23Etbt+1 + 2

    1 23Ett+2 +

    41 23

    Etbt+1+

    131 23

    bt + 341 23

    bt + 231 23t1b

    t =P +

    P(P

    bct