parenthood wage penalties in a double income society

26
Parenthood wage penalties in a double income society Sara Cools Marte Strøm Received: 14 March 2013 / Accepted: 22 February 2014 Ó Springer Science+Business Media New York 2014 Abstract We estimate how parenthood affects hourly wages using panel data for Norwegian employees in the years 1997–2007. Though smaller than for most other OECD countries, we find substantial wage penalties to motherhood, ranging from a 1.2 % wage reduction for women with lower secondary education to 4.9 % for women with more than four years of higher education. Human capital measures such as work experience and paid parental leave do not explain the wage penalties, indicating that in the Norwegian institutional context, mothers are protected from adverse wage effects due to career breaks. We do however find large heterogeneity in the effects, with the largest penalties for mothers working full time and in the private sector. Contrary to most studies using US data and to previous research from Norway, we find a small wage penalty also to fatherhood. Also for men, the penalty is greater for those who work full time and in the private sector. A substantial share of the fatherhood wage penalty is explained by paternity leave. Keywords Parenthood penalties Welfare state Gender wage gap We are grateful to Jenny Clarha ¨ll, Eva Kløve, Andreas Kotsadam, Ingrid Kru ¨ger, Jo Thori Lind, Kalle Moene and Fredrik Willumsen for helpful comments and suggestions. The authors bear all responsibility for errors and shortcomings. This paper is part of the research activities at the center of Equality, Social Organization, and Performance (ESOP) at the Department of Economics at the University of Oslo, in collaboration with the Ragnar Frisch Centre for Economic Research. We acknowledge funding from the Norwegian Research Council (Frisch project 1110). Data made available by Statistics Norway have been essential for the research project. ESOP is supported by the Research Council of Norway. S. Cools BI Norwegian Business School, Oslo, Norway e-mail: [email protected] M. Strøm (&) Institute for Social Research, Oslo, Norway e-mail: [email protected] 123 Rev Econ Household DOI 10.1007/s11150-014-9244-y

Upload: marte

Post on 24-Jan-2017

213 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

  • Parenthood wage penalties in a double income society

    Sara Cools Marte Strm

    Received: 14 March 2013 / Accepted: 22 February 2014

    Springer Science+Business Media New York 2014

    Abstract We estimate how parenthood affects hourly wages using panel data forNorwegian employees in the years 19972007. Though smaller than for most other

    OECD countries, we find substantial wage penalties to motherhood, ranging from a

    1.2 % wage reduction for women with lower secondary education to 4.9 % for

    women with more than four years of higher education. Human capital measures

    such as work experience and paid parental leave do not explain the wage penalties,

    indicating that in the Norwegian institutional context, mothers are protected from

    adverse wage effects due to career breaks. We do however find large heterogeneity

    in the effects, with the largest penalties for mothers working full time and in the

    private sector. Contrary to most studies using US data and to previous research from

    Norway, we find a small wage penalty also to fatherhood. Also for men, the penalty

    is greater for those who work full time and in the private sector. A substantial share

    of the fatherhood wage penalty is explained by paternity leave.

    Keywords Parenthood penalties Welfare state Gender wage gap

    We are grateful to Jenny Clarhall, Eva Klve, Andreas Kotsadam, Ingrid Kruger, Jo Thori Lind, Kalle

    Moene and Fredrik Willumsen for helpful comments and suggestions. The authors bear all responsibility

    for errors and shortcomings. This paper is part of the research activities at the center of Equality, Social

    Organization, and Performance (ESOP) at the Department of Economics at the University of Oslo, in

    collaboration with the Ragnar Frisch Centre for Economic Research. We acknowledge funding from

    the Norwegian Research Council (Frisch project 1110). Data made available by Statistics Norway have

    been essential for the research project. ESOP is supported by the Research Council of Norway.

    S. Cools

    BI Norwegian Business School, Oslo, Norway

    e-mail: [email protected]

    M. Strm (&)Institute for Social Research, Oslo, Norway

    e-mail: [email protected]

    123

    Rev Econ Household

    DOI 10.1007/s11150-014-9244-y

  • JEL Classification J13 J22 J24 J31

    1 Introduction

    Womens labor force participation increased greatly in Norway during the last

    decades of the twentieth century, closely approaching that of men. Over the same

    period, as several European countries experienced falling fertility rates, the total

    fertility rate in Norway increased and stayed far above the European average. In a

    country where the combination of work and family is encouraged through public

    policies such as universal child care, paid parental leave and extensive job

    protection for parents, and where not only the two career household, but also the two

    carer household, is encouraged, the double fact of high female labor force

    participation and high fertility is the hallmark of these policies success.

    Unfortunately, and puzzling to some, the gender gap in hourly wage has not declined

    as successfully over the period. It seems rather that the convergence in mens and

    womens hourly wage stagnated some time during the 1980s, only to pick up slightly

    from 2000 onwards. As in most other countries, the gender wage gap is greater among

    parents than among non-parentsa phenomenon known as the family gap in wages.

    Quantifying the wage effects of parenthood is therefore of interest to policy

    makers wishing to address the overall gender wage gap. In this paper we study how

    children affect mens and womens hourly wages, using panel data on hourly wages

    in Norway from 1997 to 2007. Using fixed effects estimation and register data

    covering both the private and the public sector (in total 80 % of the working

    population), this is the first broad panel data study of parenthood wage effects in

    Norway. In addition to rich register data, the institutional setting provided by

    Norway as a typical Nordic welfare state makes it an interesting case for the

    exploration of causes behind the family wage gap.

    The international empirical evidence on a negative relationship between having

    children and womens labor market outcomes, like wages and labor supply, is

    substantial (e.g. Korenman and Neumark (1992), Waldfogel (1997) and Budig and

    England (2001)). The evidence on the effects of fatherhood is both more scarce and less

    consistent (see for instance Millimet (2000), Lundberg and Rose (2002), Simonsen and

    Skipper (2008), Astone et al. (2010), Wilde et al. (2010)). Generally, the literature finds a

    smaller family gap in pay for mothers in the Scandinavian countries (Datta Gupta and

    Smith 2002; Harkness and Waldfogel 2003a). Differences in family policies are argued

    to be key in explaining differences in family gaps across countries (Waldfogel 1998).

    For example, Waldfogel (1998) show that in countries with paid parental leave, women

    return to work more quickly and at the same time maintain a good job match. The

    institutional context may therefore leave a smaller role for the motherhood wage penalty

    being caused by an adverse effect on firm-specific human capital.

    This paper aims to investigate further two main explanations for why we observe

    a negative wage effect on mothers wages.1 Commonly, children are considered to

    1 Unless tied specifically to institutional or biological gender differences, these explanations would also

    apply to fatherhood wage penalties.

    S. Cools, M. Strm

    123

  • have an effect on womens productivityby a comparative reduction either in their

    human capital or in their work effortwhich again will be reflected in their wages.

    As proposed by Mincer and Polachek (1974), childbearing and child rearing may

    cause a comparative reduction in mothers labor market experience, both through

    periods out of the labor market and through periods of reduced working hours,

    which then adversely affects mothers accumulation of human capital. Several

    empirical studies have shown that when controlling for experiencemeasured as

    time in active employment, net of career breaks and/or adjusted for part time

    worka large part of the wage penalty is explained (Waldfogel 1997; Budig and

    England 2001; Datta Gupta and Smith 2002; Anderson et al. 2002; Wilde et al.

    2010).

    We explore a human capital explanation for the family wage gap by including

    actual job experience, the length of parental leave and part-time work as explanatory

    variables in our estimations of parenthood wage effects. As the Norwegian

    institutional setting provides, on the one hand, long periods of parental leave, while

    on the other, high job-protection during leave, we expect two conditions to be met:

    First, that the overall wage penalty is lower in Norway if the loss of job-specific

    human capital explains a large share of the wage-penalty in other settings. Second,

    that the inclusion of experience measures explains a smaller share of the wage

    penalty because they only pick up the deterioration of human capital in general.

    In the other part of the productivity explanation for mothers reduced hourly

    wage, Becker (1985) theory of a conflict between effort in home production and

    effort at work implies that among women working the same number of hours,

    mothers will put in less effort per hour. Several studies have found a negative

    relationship between housework load and wages (Coverman 1983; Shelton and

    Firestone 1989; McAllister 1990; Hersch and Stratton 1997). Career break effects

    may also wrongly be attributed to loss of human capital. Using Swedish data,

    Albrecht et al. (1999) find that the type of career break matters for its effect on

    wages, and that the effects vary by gender. As they find no effect of maternity leave

    and a negative effect of paternity leave, they interpret this as parental leave

    signalling worker effort.2

    We explore the effort explanation in different ways. First, we expect workers to

    be more free to regulate their own effort in occupations requiring higher education,

    whereas workers in occupations requiring lower education will be relatively more

    forced to reducing working hours rather than effort in their work. We therefore

    expect parenthood to affect hourly wages more negatively in higher education

    groups (whereas it affects working hours more negatively in the lower education

    groups). Second, Anderson et al. (2003) suggest that the role of effort can be

    investigated by studying how the parenthood wage penalty evolves as the child

    grows older, since smaller children demand more effort at home than older children.

    The parenthood wage penalty should consequently be smaller when the child grows

    2 Mothers being expected by employers to take leave for a considerable period of time means maternity

    leave is not a strong signal to the employer of their type. For men, on the other hand, the length of

    parental leave is a strong signal of how much effort they will spend at work.

    Parenthood wage penalties in a double income society

    123

  • older.3 Third, if effort is part of the explanation and there is a constant amount of

    effort to be shared between parents, we would expect mens penalties to increase as

    womens decline. Last, we should also expect to see larger wage penalties in the

    private sector, where individual wage setting is more common but job protection

    still applies, as long as individually bargained wages are more closely linked to

    effort.

    Other explanations from both the empirical and theoretical literature do not

    evoke an effect of children on womens productivity: Mothers may earn lower

    wages than non-mothers due to employers discrimination or because they seek

    employment in mother-friendly jobs, for instance offering greater flexibility or

    requiring skills that deteriorate less rapidly during time spent out of the labor

    forceat the expense of lower wages (Budig and England 2001; Nielsen et al.

    2004). We do not test hypotheses of discrimination in this paper, and cannot rule out

    that it plays a role. Public sector jobs are often viewed as more easily compatible

    with family life. We explore whether a change in sector of employment can explain

    some of the parenthood wage effects by including sector of employment as an

    explanatory variable in our regressions.

    Our results show that even in the context of a double income welfare state like

    Norway, there is a substantial wage penalty to motherhood. Ranging from 1.2 %

    during the first years for women with lower secondary education to 4.9 % for

    women with more than four years of higher education, motherhood wage penalties

    in Norway are lower than estimates found for the UK (Harkness and Waldfogel

    2003b) and the US (Korenman and Neumark 1992; Budig and England 2001; Wilde

    et al. 2010), and comparable to estimates found for Germany (Harkness and

    Waldfogel 2003b) and Denmark (Nielsen et al. 2004), among others. Contrary to

    most other studies, we find a negative (though comparatively small) effect of having

    children of about .3 to .4 % on the hourly wages of men with middle length

    education.

    The wage penalty to motherhood is not explained when we include measures of

    experience, parental leave, working part time and sector of employment. The results

    indicate that Norwegian family policies protect mothers from adverse wage effects

    following a career break. We find evidence that changes in effort might be important

    for the explanation of a parenthood wage effect. As hypothesized, the wage effects

    to parenthood is larger for higher educational groups and for people working in the

    private sector, where we expected a change in effort to affect wages more.

    2 Estimating the wage penalty to parenthood

    The obvious problem of childbearing being endogenous to wagesand to labor

    market outcomes in generalis dealt with most completely in studies that use

    3 However, Wilde et al. (2010) argue that if parenthood affects both wage levels and wage growth, the

    effect of reduced effort during early years may have a lasting effect. If the wage trajectory changes

    growth rate, the difference between parents and childless individuals may even be increasing, a pattern

    found in Wilde et al. (2010) on US data. A long term persistence in motherhood wage effects is found in

    several other studies, like Viitanen (2014) using UK data.

    S. Cools, M. Strm

    123

  • instrumental variables for the childbearing decision. A shortcoming of this approach

    is that it cannot be applied to the study of effects of having the first child.4 The

    literature on the wage penalties to parenthood is mainly concerned with effects of

    the first child, although effects of subsequent children are often estimated in

    addition. Given this focus, endogeneity is primarily addressed by the inclusion of

    individual fixed effects in the estimation (this is done by Waldfogel (1997), Hersch

    and Stratton (1997), Budig and England (2001) and Anderson et al. (2002)).

    Even when controlling for individual fixed effects, there is the possibility of

    selection of individuals into parenthood and of systematic differences in the career

    path of individuals who have children at different ages, which would both yield

    biased estimates (Korenman and Neumark 1991; Antonovics and Town 2004).

    Wilde et al. (2010) address the issue of selection into parenthood by restricting their

    sample to contain only individuals who are observed to become parents. This

    restriction in combination with fixed effects estimation means identification of the

    parenthood wage penalties comes from comparing the development in wages of

    individuals with children to the development in wages of individuals who have not

    yet had childrenin essence, causal interpretation rests on the assumption of

    exogenous variation in the timing of when to have children.5Wilde et al. (2010)

    further address the endogeneity in the timing of childbearing by running separate

    analyses of the wage effects for different skill levels (defined by Armed Forces

    Qualification Test scores taken at ages 1421). If the timing of children is random

    within a skill group, separate analyses will yield unbiased estimates. Put less

    strongly, if part of the unobserved heterogeneity that is correlated both with the

    timing of children and with wages varies systematically between certain groups,

    estimation of wage effects within groups will reduce the bias.

    Our data do not contain any exogenous measure of ability. Given that there is a

    strong tradition in Norwegian centralized wage setting of tying qualification to

    education length, the length of individuals education will in large part determine

    how their wages develop. Length of education is also a major factor influencing

    when to have children. For these reasons, subsample analysis based on education

    length might reduce the bias resulting from time-variant heterogeneity amongst

    individuals who have children at different points in time. We divide the sample into

    four educational categories.6 We include individual fixed effects in order to take out

    time-invariant unobservable heterogeneity that is correlated both with the average

    wage level and with the propensity to have children at different ages. The resulting

    identifying assumption for a causal interpretation of our results is that, within an

    education group, there is no systematic difference in the wage paths of those who

    4 The most widely applied instruments for having additional children are twins and child gender

    composition (first used by Rosenzweig and Wolpin (1980) and Angrist and Evans (1998), respectively).5 As postponing childbearing is found to reduce the negative career effects of having children (Hofferth

    1984; Taniguchi 1999; Buckles 2008; Miller 2011), the assumption is under siege.6 Our divisionfurther described in Sect. 3is similar to one in Anderson et al. (2003), but we have a

    separate group with a master degree or higher. This is a small group, but interesting because of the large

    career potential, meaning motherhood may be a substantial hinder as is shown in e.g. Bertrand et al.

    (2010). The timing of the first child is clearly different between education groups: Age at first birth

    increases by one year on average between one educational group and the next.

    Parenthood wage penalties in a double income society

    123

  • have children at a certain point in time and those who do notother than what is

    caused by the event of having children itself.

    We estimate the following relationship between wages and having children:

    ln wit p1aChild11 5it p1bChild16 10it p1cChild111 15it p1dChild1[ 15it p2aChild21 5it p2bChild26 10it p2cChild211 15it p2dChild2[ 15it p3aChild31 5it p3bChild36 10it p3cChild311 15it p3dChild3[ 15it p4Child4it qaPregnantit qbBabyit df Ageit et vi uit;

    1

    where i indicates individual and t indicates year of the observation. w denotes hourly

    wage, which enters log transformed. The Child1it variables are variables indi-cating the age categories of the first child. Child11 5it takes a value between 0and 1 according to how much of year t individual is first child is between the age of

    1 to 5. Child16 10it thus takes a value between 0 and 1 according to how muchof year t individual is first child is aged 6 to 10, and so on. The Child2it variablesindicate the age categories of a second child, and the Child3it variables those ofthe third child. Child4it indicates whether the individual has had a additional chil-

    dren beyond the third child.

    Parental leave benefits in Norway entail wage replacement during approximately

    the first year after a child is born, contingent on the parents labor market behavior

    during the last 10 months prior to the childs birth. Wages observed during pregnancy

    and during the parental leave period may therefore differ significantly from wages

    received prior to the pregnancy, and from the wage realized after returning to the labor

    force. The variable Pregnantit, which takes a value between 0 and 0.75 according to

    how much of the year was spent in pregnancy, and the variable Babyit, taking a value

    between 0 and 1 according to how much of that year the individual had a first-born

    baby younger than 1 year, take out the variation in wages caused by these periods.

    We also include a fourth order polynomial in each parents age (f Age). etdenotes year fixed effects and vi individual fixed effects. Hence, the wage path of

    non-parents is given by the age function, net of year and individual fixed effects.7

    Our main interest lies with the parameters p1a, p1b and p1c, the effect on wages ofhaving a first child aged 15 years, 610 years and 1115 years, respectively. For

    (weakly) negative values of the p1s, p1a p1b p1c would correspond to a constantwage effect of parenthood over time. jp1aj[ jp1bj[ jp1cj corresponds to a scenario ofparents wages catching up with their original wage path, whereas jp1aj\jp1bj\jp1cjcorresponds to the case in which parents wages keep deteriorating relative to the

    wages of non-parents.

    3 Data

    The basis for our main sample is all Norwegian residents born between 1950 and

    1980, except parents who at one point had twins, triplets or any type of multiple

    7 The fourth order polynomial is chosen in order to be as flexible as possible, given that the use of age

    dummies is not feasible due to multicollinearity with year and individual fixed effects.

    S. Cools, M. Strm

    123

  • birth. The sample is further restricted by the availability of data on hourly wages

    (described below).

    We run separate estimations in four subsamples based on the length of

    individuals education. The education data is provided by Statistics Norway and

    makes it possible to track individuals highest registered education over time. As an

    individuals ultimate education level may be influenced by childbearing, we face a

    trade-off between a late observation of education, that more likely reflects the

    individuals actual wage path, and an early and less endogenous measure of

    education. Since it is not clear how much there is to gain in terms of exogeneity by

    using observations on education at younger ages, and because there is something to

    be gained by moving close to the actual education of the individual during his or her

    working life, we use education measured at age 25 for the main part of our analysis.

    The median age at which an individual attains the highest registered education is 24

    years in our sample.

    The first education group is the group of individuals who have completed nine

    years of lower secondary education or less (this group also includes individuals for

    whom education information is missing). This group constitutes about 40 % of our

    sample, based on the observation of education at age 25. Typical occupations for

    this education group are for instance shop clerks, transport workers (men), cleaning

    personnel (women). The second group has completed additional three years of upper

    secondary education, and constitutes roughly 30 % of our sample. Typical

    occupations are technicians and electricians (men) and secretaries and health care

    personnel (women). The third group has a lower degree in higher education (four

    years or less of higher education, typically a bachelors degree or the equivalent),

    and is typically employed as engineers (men) or nurses (women). This group

    constitutes almost 30 % of the sample. Finally, the fourth education group consists

    of those with four years or more of higher education (and thus a higher degree).

    Constituting only about 2 % of the whole sample, this group is typically employed

    as doctors, architects and engineers.

    Our measure of hourly wages is constructed using information on contracted

    hours and monthly wages in Statistics Norways Wage statistic (Lnnsstatis-

    tikken). The Wage statistic is based on employer reports for a sample of

    Norwegian enterprizes on all employees by the 1st of October. 8 Every year all

    public enterprizes and all private enterprizes with more than a certain number of

    employees are included (the number varies with industry and year), for the

    remaining private sector a 50 % sample of medium size enterprizes and a 20 %

    sample of small enterprizes is drawn every year. Employment in agriculture,

    hunting and forestry is left out. So are enterprizes with 3 or less employees. On

    average, the Wage statistic covers about 80 % of Norwegian employees (100 % of

    the public sector employees and 70 % of the private sector employees) every year.

    The information on birth year, education and the linking of parents to their children

    comes from Statistics Norways demography, family and education registers.

    8 Results are therefore representative of employees only. The share of self-employed in the labor force is

    about 4 % for women and almost 10 % for men during the period under study, with smaller shares for

    individuals with small children (Villund 2005).

    Parenthood wage penalties in a double income society

    123

  • The resulting panel is unbalanced, both due to the sampling of medium size

    enterprizes, and because people may move in and out of employment covered by the

    Wage statistic. A missing observation for a given year may mean either that the

    person in question does not work that year, that she is self-employed, or that she is

    employed in an enterprize that is not included in that years sample.9

    In Sect. 5, we include four covariates that are clearly endogenous to the

    childbearing decision (so-called bad controls) in order to see to what extent they

    explain the parenthood wage penalties. In Sect. 6 we divide the sample into

    different subsamples based on these four variables. As some of these variables are

    only observable from 1993 onwards, the samples used in the analyses in Sects. 5

    and 6 will be restricted to parents of children born between 1994 and 2007.

    Experience is constructed counting the cumulative number of years the

    individual is registered with occupational income above the basic amount of the

    Norwegian social security system (G), which is a common measure of labor force

    participation based on Norwegian income data. Parental leave counts the

    cumulative number of days the individual has been registered with paid parental

    leave. This register has reliable information from 1993 onwards. Third, the variable

    Part time is constructed as a dummy variable equal to one if the individual is

    registered as working 30 h or less per week, zero if the registered number of weekly

    hours is more than 30. Lastly, the Public sector variable used in Sect. 5 is based on

    whether the individual is registered with a public sector employment code in the

    Wage statistic. When we split the sample according to which sector individuals

    worked in the year they became parents, we again use information from the

    Employer/Employee register, going back to 1993.

    Descriptive statistics for the samples and subsamples we use in the analyses in

    Sects. 46 are given in Table 1.

    4 Baseline results

    Table 2, columns (1)(5) shows the results from fixed effects regression on Eq. 1

    for our main sample of women. Estimated on the whole sample together, having

    children on average reduces womens earnings by 1 % during the first years. This

    estimate for the whole sample is smaller than in any of the subsamples.10 The effect

    9 Using other official registries we find that about 20 % of women and 7 % of men who have a missing

    wage observation when their first child is 3 years old have earnings below the basic amount (G) of the

    Norwegian social security system, meaning that they are marginally or not employed at all that year (from

    January 1 2010, G is NOK 72 881, approximately USD 12 500). About 50 % of the women and 75 % of

    the men with missing wage observations are registered as employed. Some of the remaining missing

    observations may indicate self-employment.10 When the timing of children differs between educational groups, the estimate for the full sample will

    typically be different from the average over the within-group estimates. Estimating the effect of children

    relative to the counterfactual wage path for the full sample means individuals in the highest education

    group are over-represented among the (still) childless, while individuals in the lower education group are

    over-represented among those who have already had children. The same pattern is found in Anderson

    et al. (2002).

    S. Cools, M. Strm

    123

  • Ta

    ble

    1D

    escr

    ipti

    ve

    stat

    isti

    cs

    All

    Sec

    ondar

    yed

    uca

    tion

    Hig

    her

    educa

    tion

    Lo

    wer

    Up

    per

    Lo

    wer

    deg

    .H

    igher

    deg

    .

    Mea

    nS

    DM

    ean

    SD

    Mea

    nS

    DM

    ean

    SD

    Mea

    nS

    D

    Wo

    men

    :o

    bse

    rva

    tio

    ns

    in2

    00

    2

    Ho

    url

    yw

    age

    (19

    98

    NO

    K)

    13

    3.3

    1(3

    7.0

    0)

    12

    3.0

    2(2

    9.4

    9)

    13

    1.0

    6(3

    5.7

    6)

    14

    8.0

    6(3

    9.6

    0)

    18

    3.7

    9(6

    3.1

    5)

    Nu

    mb

    ero

    fch

    ild

    ren

    1.6

    1(1

    .20

    )1

    .90

    (1.1

    4)

    1.4

    2(1

    .15

    )1

    .35

    (1.2

    3)

    1.1

    6(1

    .18

    )

    Ag

    eo

    ffi

    rst

    chil

    d1

    3.3

    0(9

    .92

    )1

    8.2

    0(8

    .79

    )9

    .79

    (8.5

    7)

    8.7

    8(9

    .15

    )5

    .94

    (7.7

    8)

    Ag

    e3

    8.2

    4(8

    .40

    )4

    1.7

    1(7

    .42

    )3

    5.3

    1(7

    .80

    )3

    5.8

    5(8

    .43

    )3

    4.0

    8(7

    .34

    )

    Wo

    men

    :o

    bse

    rva

    tio

    ns

    in2

    00

    2,

    sam

    ple

    wit

    hfi

    rst

    chil

    db

    orn

    19

    94

    20

    07

    Ex

    per

    ien

    ce(y

    ears

    )1

    0.1

    8(5

    .32

    )1

    0.9

    0(6

    .45

    )1

    0.5

    9(5

    .08

    )9

    .59

    (4.8

    7)

    9.2

    1(4

    .59

    )

    Cum

    ula

    ted

    par

    enta

    lle

    ave

    (yea

    rs)

    0.7

    5(0

    .77

    )0

    .80

    (0.7

    5)

    0.7

    8(0

    .76

    )0

    .71

    (0.7

    9)

    0.7

    8(0

    .83

    )

    Par

    tti

    me

    0.4

    2(0

    .49

    )0

    .52

    (0.5

    0)

    0.4

    4(0

    .50

    )0

    .36

    (0.4

    8)

    0.2

    1(0

    .41

    )

    Pu

    bli

    cse

    cto

    r0

    .61

    (0.4

    9)

    0.5

    2(0

    .50

    )0

    .51

    (0.5

    0)

    0.7

    4(0

    .44

    )0

    .47

    (0.5

    0)

    Tak

    esle

    ave

    wit

    hfi

    rst

    chil

    d0

    .82

    (0.3

    9)

    0.7

    8(0

    .41

    )0

    .83

    (0.3

    8)

    0.8

    2(0

    .39

    )0

    .85

    (0.3

    6)

    Fir

    stch

    ild

    leav

    e(y

    ears

    )0

    .68

    (0.4

    3)

    0.6

    1(0

    .41

    )0

    .68

    (0.4

    2)

    0.7

    0(0

    .44

    )0

    .74

    (0.4

    4)

    Fu

    llti

    me

    bef

    ore

    chil

    dre

    n0

    .80

    (0.4

    0)

    0.7

    2(0

    .45

    )0

    .77

    (0.4

    2)

    0.8

    5(0

    .36

    )0

    .95

    (0.2

    1)

    Pu

    bli

    cse

    cto

    rb

    efo

    rech

    ild

    ren

    0.5

    9(0

    .49

    )0

    .49

    (0.5

    0)

    0.4

    8(0

    .50

    )0

    .73

    (0.4

    5)

    0.4

    7(0

    .50

    )

    N1

    39

    ,03

    72

    8,0

    75

    46

    ,87

    66

    0,7

    22

    3,3

    64

    Men

    :o

    bse

    rvati

    on

    sin

    20

    02

    Ho

    url

    yw

    age

    (19

    98

    NO

    K)

    16

    0.3

    1(7

    0.0

    8)

    14

    5.5

    9(6

    2.5

    3)

    15

    8.9

    8(6

    7.2

    8)

    18

    1.0

    7(7

    5.5

    3)

    22

    1.3

    4(8

    6.4

    8)

    Nu

    mb

    ero

    fch

    ild

    ren

    1.4

    1(1

    .26

    )1

    .60

    (1.2

    8)

    1.2

    7(1

    .22

    )1

    .28

    (1.2

    6)

    1.4

    5(1

    .30

    )

    Ag

    eo

    ffi

    rst

    chil

    d1

    0.9

    6(9

    .36

    )1

    4.2

    7(9

    .25

    )8

    .71

    (8.5

    5)

    8.4

    8(8

    .95

    )9

    .26

    (8.8

    1)

    Ag

    e3

    7.8

    9(8

    .42

    )4

    0.6

    7(8

    .05

    )3

    5.5

    5(8

    .01

    )3

    6.6

    3(8

    .28

    )3

    7.5

    7(8

    .19

    )

    Men

    :o

    bse

    rvati

    on

    sin

    20

    02,

    sam

    ple

    wit

    hfi

    rst

    chil

    db

    orn

    19

    94

    20

    07

    Ex

    per

    ien

    ce(y

    ears

    )1

    2.2

    4(5

    .94

    )1

    3.0

    7(7

    .02

    )1

    2.5

    0(5

    .47

    )1

    1.1

    8(5

    .30

    )1

    1.0

    8(5

    .57

    )

    Parenthood wage penalties in a double income society

    123

  • Ta

    ble

    1co

    nti

    nued

    All

    Sec

    ondar

    yed

    uca

    tion

    Hig

    her

    educa

    tion

    Lo

    wer

    Up

    per

    Lo

    wer

    deg

    .H

    igher

    deg

    .

    Mea

    nS

    DM

    ean

    SD

    Mea

    nS

    DM

    ean

    SD

    Mea

    nS

    D

    Cum

    ula

    ted

    par

    enta

    lle

    ave

    (yea

    rs)

    0.0

    6(0

    .12

    )0

    .05

    (0.1

    0)

    0.0

    6(0

    .12

    )0

    .07

    (0.1

    4)

    0.0

    9(0

    .18

    )

    Par

    tti

    me

    0.0

    8(0

    .27

    )0

    .10

    (0.2

    9)

    0.0

    7(0

    .25

    )0

    .08

    (0.2

    8)

    0.0

    5(0

    .22

    )

    Pu

    bli

    cse

    cto

    r0

    .31

    (0.4

    6)

    0.2

    2(0

    .41

    )0

    .24

    (0.4

    3)

    0.5

    0(0

    .50

    )0

    .35

    (0.4

    8)

    Tak

    esle

    ave

    wit

    hfi

    rst

    chil

    d0

    .55

    (0.5

    0)

    0.4

    7(0

    .50

    )0

    .57

    (0.5

    0)

    0.6

    0(0

    .49

    )0

    .63

    (0.4

    8)

    Fir

    stch

    ild

    leav

    e(y

    ears

    )0

    .04

    (0.0

    8)

    0.0

    3(0

    .06

    )0

    .04

    (0.0

    7)

    0.0

    5(0

    .09

    )0

    .06

    (0.1

    0)

    Fu

    llti

    me

    bef

    ore

    chil

    dre

    n0

    .92

    (0.2

    8)

    0.9

    0(0

    .29

    )0

    .93

    (0.2

    5)

    0.9

    0(0

    .29

    )0

    .96

    (0.1

    9)

    Pu

    bli

    cse

    cto

    rb

    efo

    rech

    ild

    ren

    0.3

    2(0

    .47

    )0

    .23

    (0.4

    2)

    0.2

    5(0

    .43

    )0

    .50

    (0.5

    0)

    0.3

    7(0

    .48

    )

    N1

    37

    ,19

    83

    7,8

    25

    56

    313

    38

    767

    4,2

    93

    Sam

    ple

    isw

    om

    enan

    dm

    enb

    orn

    bet

    wee

    n1

    95

    0an

    d1

    98

    0w

    ho

    are

    regis

    tere

    dw

    ith

    emplo

    ym

    ent

    inS

    tati

    stic

    sN

    orw

    ays

    Wag

    est

    atis

    tic.

    Wo

    rkin

    gle

    ssth

    an3

    0h

    per

    wee

    kis

    clas

    sifi

    edas

    par

    tti

    me

    emplo

    ym

    ent,

    work

    ing

    30

    ho

    rm

    ore

    iscl

    assi

    fied

    asfu

    llti

    me

    S. Cools, M. Strm

    123

  • Ta

    ble

    2T

    he

    effe

    cto

    fch

    ild

    ren

    on

    wo

    men

    and

    men

    sh

    ou

    rly

    wag

    e

    Wo

    men

    Men

    All

    Sec

    ondar

    yed

    uca

    tion

    Hig

    her

    educa

    tion

    All

    Sec

    ondar

    yed

    uca

    tion

    Hig

    her

    educa

    tion

    Lo

    wer

    Up

    per

    Lo

    wer

    deg

    .H

    igh

    erd

    eg.

    Lo

    wer

    Up

    per

    Lo

    wer

    deg

    .H

    igh

    erd

    eg.

    (1)

    (2)

    (3)

    (4)

    (5)

    (6)

    (7)

    (8)

    (9)

    (10

    )

    Fir

    stch

    ild

    Ag

    e1

    5

    0

    .009

    8*

    **

    0

    .01

    2*

    **

    0

    .033

    **

    *

    0.0

    25

    **

    *

    0.0

    49

    **

    *0

    .006

    7*

    **

    0.0

    02

    6

    0.0

    02

    8*

    0

    .00

    39

    **

    0.0

    01

    7

    (0.0

    00

    79

    )(0

    .00

    17

    )(0

    .00

    14

    )(0

    .00

    12

    )(0

    .00

    61

    )(0

    .00

    10

    )(0

    .00

    18

    )(0

    .00

    16

    )(0

    .00

    19

    )(0

    .00

    58

    )

    Ag

    e6

    1

    0

    0.0

    13

    **

    *

    0.0

    14

    **

    *

    0.0

    44

    **

    *

    0.0

    35

    **

    *

    0.0

    45

    **

    *0

    .002

    7*

    *0

    .003

    6

    0.0

    06

    7*

    **

    0

    .01

    3*

    **

    0.0

    04

    3

    (0.0

    01

    1)

    (0.0

    021

    )(0

    .00

    19

    )(0

    .00

    17

    )(0

    .00

    88

    )(0

    .00

    14

    )(0

    .00

    24

    )(0

    .00

    22

    )(0

    .00

    26

    )(0

    .00

    79

    )

    Ag

    e1

    1

    15

    0

    .016

    **

    *

    0.0

    17

    **

    *

    0.0

    51

    **

    *

    0.0

    42

    **

    *

    0.0

    42

    **

    *

    0.0

    01

    50

    .001

    3

    0.0

    08

    6*

    **

    0

    .01

    7*

    **

    0

    .000

    59

    (0.0

    01

    3)

    (0.0

    024

    )(0

    .00

    23

    )(0

    .00

    21

    )(0

    .01

    1)

    (0.0

    016

    )(0

    .00

    27

    )(0

    .00

    26

    )(0

    .00

    32

    )(0

    .00

    95

    )

    Ag

    e[

    15

    0

    .015

    **

    *

    0.0

    16

    **

    *

    0.0

    53

    **

    *

    0.0

    46

    **

    *

    0.0

    29

    **

    -0

    .004

    5*

    *0

    .000

    16

    0

    .009

    6*

    **

    0

    .02

    0*

    **

    0

    .004

    3

    (0.0

    01

    4)

    (0.0

    026

    )(0

    .00

    27

    )(0

    .00

    23

    )(0

    .01

    4)

    (0.0

    018

    )(0

    .00

    30

    )(0

    .00

    31

    )(0

    .00

    37

    )(0

    .01

    1)

    Sec

    on

    dch

    ild

    Ag

    e1

    5

    0

    .009

    5*

    **

    0

    .00

    16

    0

    .019

    **

    *

    0.0

    21

    **

    *

    0.0

    37

    **

    *0

    .010

    **

    *0

    .009

    0*

    **

    0.0

    04

    0*

    **

    0.0

    01

    5

    0.0

    01

    6

    (0.0

    00

    70

    )(0

    .00

    14

    )(0

    .00

    12

    )(0

    .00

    11

    )(0

    .00

    59

    )(0

    .00

    09

    4)

    (0.0

    017

    )(0

    .00

    15

    )(0

    .00

    18

    )(0

    .00

    53

    )

    Ag

    e6

    1

    0

    0.0

    12

    **

    *

    0.0

    06

    2*

    **

    0

    .025

    **

    *

    0.0

    27

    **

    *

    0.0

    35

    **

    *0

    .012

    **

    *0

    .011

    **

    *0

    .004

    9*

    *

    0.0

    00

    77

    0.0

    03

    2

    (0.0

    00

    93

    )(0

    .00

    17

    )(0

    .00

    17

    )(0

    .00

    15

    )(0

    .00

    86

    )(0

    .00

    12

    )(0

    .00

    21

    )(0

    .00

    20

    )(0

    .00

    24

    )(0

    .00

    72

    )

    Ag

    e1

    1

    15

    0

    .013

    **

    *

    0.0

    08

    7*

    **

    0

    .029

    **

    *

    0.0

    31

    **

    *

    0.0

    40

    **

    *0

    .015

    **

    *0

    .015

    **

    *0

    .004

    6*

    0

    .00

    04

    90

    .011

    (0.0

    01

    1)

    (0.0

    020

    )(0

    .00

    21

    )(0

    .00

    19

    )(0

    .01

    1)

    (0.0

    015

    )(0

    .00

    25

    )(0

    .00

    25

    )(0

    .00

    30

    )(0

    .00

    89

    )

    Ag

    e[

    15

    0

    .010

    **

    *

    0.0

    06

    6*

    **

    0

    .026

    **

    *

    0.0

    34

    **

    *

    0.0

    43

    **

    *0

    .015

    **

    *0

    .015

    **

    *0

    .002

    30

    .00

    15

    0.0

    03

    6

    (0.0

    01

    2)

    (0.0

    021

    )(0

    .00

    24

    )(0

    .00

    22

    )(0

    .01

    3)

    (0.0

    017

    )(0

    .00

    27

    )(0

    .00

    30

    )(0

    .00

    35

    )(0

    .01

    1)

    Th

    ird

    chil

    d

    Ag

    e1

    5

    0

    .008

    9*

    **

    0

    .00

    24

    0

    .011

    **

    *

    0.0

    18

    **

    *

    0.0

    41

    **

    *0

    .008

    6*

    **

    0.0

    08

    3*

    **

    0.0

    08

    3*

    **

    0.0

    00

    72

    0

    .001

    0

    (0.0

    00

    87

    )(0

    .00

    16

    )(0

    .00

    16

    )(0

    .00

    14

    )(0

    .00

    76

    )(0

    .00

    12

    )(0

    .00

    20

    )(0

    .00

    19

    )(0

    .00

    23

    )(0

    .00

    64

    )

    Parenthood wage penalties in a double income society

    123

  • Ta

    ble

    2co

    nti

    nued W

    om

    enM

    en

    All

    Sec

    ondar

    yed

    uca

    tion

    Hig

    her

    educa

    tion

    All

    Sec

    ondar

    yed

    uca

    tion

    Hig

    her

    educa

    tion

    Lo

    wer

    Up

    per

    Lo

    wer

    deg

    .H

    igh

    erd

    eg.

    Lo

    wer

    Up

    per

    Lo

    wer

    deg

    .H

    igh

    erd

    eg.

    (1)

    (2)

    (3)

    (4)

    (5)

    (6)

    (7)

    (8)

    (9)

    (10

    )

    Ag

    e6

    1

    0

    0.0

    13

    **

    *

    0.0

    07

    0*

    **

    0

    .018

    **

    *

    0.0

    25

    **

    *

    0.0

    50

    **

    *0

    .012

    **

    *0

    .009

    8*

    **

    0.0

    09

    7*

    **

    0.0

    01

    60

    .004

    8

    (0.0

    01

    1)

    (0.0

    019

    )(0

    .00

    20

    )(0

    .00

    18

    )(0

    .01

    1)

    (0.0

    015

    )(0

    .00

    25

    )(0

    .00

    25

    )(0

    .00

    30

    )(0

    .00

    84

    )

    Ag

    e1

    1

    15

    0

    .011

    **

    *

    0.0

    06

    8*

    **

    0

    .016

    **

    *

    0.0

    27

    **

    *

    0.0

    55

    **

    *0

    .015

    **

    *0

    .014

    **

    *0

    .011

    **

    *0

    .00

    19

    0.0

    07

    5

    (0.0

    01

    3)

    (0.0

    021

    )(0

    .00

    25

    )(0

    .00

    21

    )(0

    .01

    3)

    (0.0

    018

    )(0

    .00

    28

    )(0

    .00

    30

    )(0

    .00

    36

    )(0

    .01

    0)

    Ag

    e[

    15

    0

    .007

    0*

    **

    0

    .00

    34

    0

    .006

    7*

    *

    0.0

    30

    **

    *

    0.0

    56

    **

    *0

    .018

    **

    *0

    .018

    **

    *0

    .014

    **

    *0

    .00

    13

    0

    .001

    0

    (0.0

    01

    4)

    (0.0

    022

    )(0

    .00

    29

    )(0

    .00

    24

    )(0

    .01

    7)

    (0.0

    020

    )(0

    .00

    31

    )(0

    .00

    37

    )(0

    .00

    41

    )(0

    .01

    2)

    Ob

    serv

    atio

    ns

    4,1

    85

    ,653

    1,9

    27

    ,527

    1,0

    39

    ,05

    71

    ,16

    7,1

    12

    51

    ,95

    73

    ,325

    ,98

    91

    ,377

    ,70

    91

    ,120

    ,625

    73

    6,9

    30

    90

    ,72

    5

    Ind

    ivid

    ual

    s6

    46

    ,86

    93

    ,11

    ,87

    91

    70

    ,46

    21

    57

    ,18

    87

    ,340

    56

    7,3

    21

    25

    6,2

    82

    19

    2,2

    27

    10

    6,0

    54

    12

    ,75

    8

    Eac

    hco

    lum

    npro

    vid

    esF

    Ees

    tim

    ates

    from

    are

    gre

    ssio

    nbas

    edon

    Eq.

    1o

    nth

    esa

    mp

    leo

    fN

    orw

    egia

    nw

    om

    enan

    dm

    enb

    orn

    bet

    wee

    n1

    95

    0an

    d1

    98

    0.T

    he

    colu

    mn

    s(2

    )(5

    )an

    d

    (7)

    (10)

    corr

    espond

    tosu

    bsa

    mple

    sac

    cord

    ing

    toin

    div

    idual

    sle

    ngth

    of

    educa

    tion

    mea

    sure

    dat

    age

    25.

    Yea

    rdum

    mie

    s,a

    poly

    nom

    ial

    inag

    ean

    din

    div

    idual

    fixed

    effe

    cts

    are

    incl

    ud

    edin

    all

    spec

    ifica

    tio

    ns.

    So

    are

    con

    tro

    lsfo

    rp

    reg

    nan

    cy,

    hav

    ing

    ab

    aby

    yo

    un

    ger

    than

    1y

    ear

    and

    for

    hav

    ing

    more

    than

    3ch

    ild

    ren

    .R

    ob

    ust

    stan

    dar

    der

    rors

    are

    in

    par

    enth

    eses

    .*

    p\

    0:1

    0;*

    *p\

    0:0

    5;

    **

    *p\

    0:0

    1

    S. Cools, M. Strm

    123

  • Ta

    ble

    3T

    he

    effe

    cto

    fch

    ild

    ren

    on

    wo

    men

    and

    men

    sh

    ou

    rly

    wag

    e

    Wo

    men

    Men

    All

    Sec

    ondar

    yed

    uca

    tion

    Hig

    her

    educa

    tion

    All

    Sec

    ondar

    yed

    uca

    tion

    Hig

    her

    educa

    tion

    Lo

    wer

    Up

    per

    Lo

    wer

    deg

    .H

    igher

    deg

    .L

    ow

    erU

    pp

    erL

    ow

    erd

    eg.

    Hig

    her

    deg

    .

    (1)

    (2)

    (3)

    (4)

    (5)

    (6)

    (7)

    (8)

    (9)

    (10

    )

    Pa

    nel

    A:

    ba

    seli

    ne

    Fir

    stch

    ild

    Ag

    e1

    5

    0

    .029

    **

    *

    0.0

    18

    **

    *

    0.0

    34

    **

    *

    0.0

    27

    **

    *

    0.0

    52

    **

    *

    0.0

    05

    9*

    **

    0

    .002

    0

    0.0

    06

    6*

    **

    0

    .006

    0*

    **

    0.0

    04

    3

    (0.0

    00

    90

    )(0

    .00

    21

    )(0

    .00

    16

    )(0

    .00

    13

    )(0

    .00

    63

    )(0

    .00

    11

    )(0

    .00

    21

    )(0

    .00

    17

    )(0

    .00

    21

    )(0

    .00

    60

    )

    Ag

    e6

    1

    0

    0.0

    46

    **

    *

    0.0

    24

    **

    *

    0.0

    44

    **

    *

    0.0

    37

    **

    *

    0.0

    49

    **

    *

    0.0

    18

    **

    *

    0.0

    03

    0

    0.0

    14

    **

    *

    0.0

    13

    **

    *0

    .008

    5

    (0.0

    01

    3)

    (0.0

    030

    )(0

    .00

    23

    )(0

    .00

    20

    )(0

    .00

    95

    )(0

    .00

    16

    )(0

    .00

    30

    )(0

    .00

    26

    )(0

    .00

    31

    )(0

    .00

    86

    )

    Ag

    e1

    1

    13

    0

    .056

    **

    *

    0.0

    27

    **

    *

    0.0

    46

    **

    *

    0.0

    45

    **

    *

    0.0

    47

    **

    *

    0.0

    29

    **

    *

    0.0

    07

    0*

    0

    .02

    1*

    **

    0

    .016

    **

    *0

    .011

    (0.0

    01

    9)

    (0.0

    039

    )(0

    .00

    32

    )(0

    .00

    29

    )(0

    .01

    5)

    (0.0

    024

    )(0

    .00

    42

    )(0

    .00

    37

    )(0

    .00

    45

    )(0

    .01

    3)

    Obse

    rvat

    ions

    1,4

    39,8

    05

    298,6

    90

    485,6

    26

    619,8

    74

    35,6

    15

    1,4

    49,5

    91

    402,6

    89

    595,7

    52

    405,2

    42

    45,9

    08

    Ind

    ivid

    ual

    s2

    57

    ,69

    16

    6,3

    53

    91

    ,56

    69

    4,4

    54

    5,3

    18

    26

    8,5

    44

    88

    ,10

    11

    10

    ,89

    36

    2,6

    52

    6,8

    98

    Pa

    nel

    B:

    incl

    ud

    ing

    exp

    lan

    ato

    ryva

    ria

    ble

    s

    Fir

    stch

    ild

    Ag

    e1

    5

    0

    .031

    **

    *

    0.0

    21

    **

    *

    0.0

    38

    **

    *

    0.0

    29

    **

    *

    0.0

    48

    **

    *

    0.0

    05

    1*

    **

    0

    .001

    9

    0.0

    04

    0*

    *

    0.0

    02

    40

    .007

    0

    (0.0

    01

    1)

    (0.0

    026

    )(0

    .00

    20

    )(0

    .00

    16

    )(0

    .00

    79

    )(0

    .00

    12

    )(0

    .00

    22

    )(0

    .00

    18

    )(0

    .00

    22

    )(0

    .00

    63

    )

    Ag

    e6

    1

    0

    0.0

    48

    **

    *

    0.0

    27

    **

    *

    0.0

    48

    **

    *

    0.0

    39

    **

    *

    0.0

    45

    **

    *

    0.0

    17

    **

    *

    0.0

    03

    5

    0.0

    12

    **

    *

    0.0

    09

    6*

    **

    0.0

    11

    (0.0

    01

    5)

    (0.0

    034

    )(0

    .00

    26

    )(0

    .00

    22

    )(0

    .01

    1)

    (0.0

    017

    )(0

    .00

    31

    )(0

    .00

    26

    )(0

    .00

    32

    )(0

    .00

    89

    )

    Ag

    e1

    1

    13

    0

    .059

    **

    *

    0.0

    30

    **

    *

    0.0

    50

    **

    *

    0.0

    46

    **

    *

    0.0

    42

    **

    *

    0.0

    28

    **

    *

    0.0

    07

    4*

    0

    .01

    9*

    **

    0

    .012

    **

    *0

    .013

    (0.0

    02

    0)

    (0.0

    042

    )(0

    .00

    35

    )(0

    .00

    30

    )(0

    .01

    6)

    (0.0

    024

    )(0

    .00

    43

    )(0

    .00

    37

    )(0

    .00

    47

    )(0

    .01

    3)

    Ex

    per

    ien

    ce0

    .00

    21

    ***

    0.0

    04

    7*

    **

    0.0

    02

    8*

    **

    0

    .000

    45

    0.0

    07

    0

    0.0

    04

    2*

    **

    0.0

    00

    50

    0

    .00

    02

    70

    .004

    9*

    *0

    .011

    (0.0

    00

    59

    )(0

    .00

    11

    )(0

    .00

    09

    9)

    (0.0

    009

    8)

    (0.0

    06

    6)

    (0.0

    013

    )(0

    .00

    23

    )(0

    .00

    25

    )(0

    .00

    22

    )(0

    .00

    76

    )

    Parenthood wage penalties in a double income society

    123

  • Ta

    ble

    3co

    nti

    nued

    Wo

    men

    Men

    All

    Sec

    ondar

    yed

    uca

    tion

    Hig

    her

    educa

    tion

    All

    Sec

    ondar

    yed

    uca

    tion

    Hig

    her

    educa

    tion

    Lo

    wer

    Up

    per

    Lo

    wer

    deg

    .H

    igher

    deg

    .L

    ow

    erU

    pp

    erL

    ow

    erd

    eg.

    Hig

    her

    deg

    .

    (1)

    (2)

    (3)

    (4)

    (5)

    (6)

    (7)

    (8)

    (9)

    (10

    )

    Par

    enta

    lle

    ave

    0

    .003

    0*

    **

    0

    .00

    41

    **

    0

    .002

    9*

    0

    .002

    5*

    *

    0.0

    06

    2

    0.0

    09

    8*

    **

    0

    .011

    *

    0.0

    32

    **

    *

    0.0

    36

    **

    *

    0.0

    39

    **

    *

    (0.0

    00

    81

    )(0

    .00

    20

    )(0

    .00

    15

    )(0

    .00

    11

    )(0

    .00

    57

    )(0

    .00

    27

    )(0

    .00

    61

    )(0

    .00

    46

    )(0

    .00

    44

    )(0

    .01

    2)

    Par

    tti

    me

    0.0

    17

    **

    *0

    .02

    6*

    **

    0.0

    23

    **

    *0

    .013

    **

    *0

    .005

    6*

    0

    .001

    70

    .02

    1*

    **

    0.0

    16

    **

    *

    0.0

    30

    **

    *

    0.0

    34

    **

    *

    (0.0

    00

    43

    )(0

    .00

    10

    )(0

    .00

    07

    7)

    (0.0

    006

    1)

    (0.0

    03

    2)

    (0.0

    014

    )(0

    .00

    25

    )(0

    .00

    25

    )(0

    .00

    21

    )(0

    .00

    79

    )

    Pu

    bli

    cse

    cto

    r0

    .00

    55

    ***

    0

    .00

    66

    ***

    0

    .000

    67

    0.0

    20

    **

    *

    0.0

    03

    1

    0.0

    05

    9*

    **

    0

    .010

    **

    *

    0.0

    00

    80

    0.0

    08

    7*

    **

    0

    .017

    **

    *

    (0.0

    00

    60

    )(0

    .00

    12

    )(0

    .00

    09

    4)

    (0.0

    010

    )(0

    .00

    40

    )(0

    .00

    06

    9)

    (0.0

    01

    5)

    (0.0

    011

    )(0

    .00

    12

    )(0

    .00

    36

    )

    Obse

    rvat

    ions

    1,4

    39,8

    05

    298,6

    90

    485,6

    26

    619,8

    74

    35615

    1,4

    02,0

    30

    390,4

    62

    576,0

    88

    391,2

    83

    44,1

    97

    Ind

    ivid

    ual

    s2

    57

    ,69

    16

    6,3

    53

    91

    ,56

    69

    4,4

    54

    53

    18

    26

    0,2

    10

    85

    ,57

    81

    07

    ,42

    26

    0,5

    59

    6,6

    51

    Incl

    udin

    gco

    ntr

    ols

    for

    exp

    erie

    nce

    ,p

    aren

    tal

    leav

    e,p

    art

    tim

    ean

    dse

    cto

    ro

    fem

    plo

    ym

    ent

    Eac

    hco

    lum

    nin

    each

    pan

    elp

    rov

    ides

    FE

    esti

    mat

    esfr

    om

    are

    gre

    ssio

    nb

    ased

    on

    Eq

    .1

    for

    the

    sam

    ple

    of

    ind

    ivid

    ual

    sw

    ho

    had

    thei

    rfi

    rst

    chil

    din

    19

    94

    or

    late

    r.Y

    ear

    du

    mm

    ies,

    a

    po

    lyn

    om

    ial

    inag

    e,in

    div

    idual

    fix

    edef

    fect

    san

    da

    set

    of

    du

    mm

    ies

    for

    hav

    ing

    ase

    con

    dan

    da

    thir

    dch

    ild

    atv

    ario

    us

    ages

    are

    incl

    ud

    edin

    all

    spec

    ifica

    tio

    ns.

    So

    are

    con

    tro

    lsfo

    r

    pre

    gn

    ancy

    ,h

    avin

    ga

    bab

    yy

    ou

    ng

    erth

    ano

    ne

    yea

    ran

    dfo

    rh

    avin

    gm

    ore

    than

    3ch

    ild

    ren

    .In

    the

    low

    erp

    anel

    add

    itio

    nal

    con

    trols

    are

    incl

    ud

    ed.

    Rob

    ust

    stan

    dar

    der

    rors

    are

    in

    par

    enth

    eses

    .*

    p\

    0:1

    0;*

    *p\

    0:0

    5;

    **

    *p\

    0:0

    1

    S. Cools, M. Strm

    123

  • of having children is strongest for the highest education group, and weakest for the

    lowest education group. During the first years after having children wages are

    reduced by 4.9 % for those who have a higher university degree and by 1.2 % for

    women who have lower secondary education.11 In all education groups except the

    highest one, and in the sample as a whole, the effect of the first child grows over

    time.

    Restricting the sample to mothers only, as is done by Wilde et al. (2010), gives

    more negative estimates in the sample as a whole, whereas the estimates in the

    subsamples based on education length change only marginally. The results indicate

    that women who do not have children are on a lower wage-path, yielding a smaller

    estimated impact of children when the control group includes these women. If we

    further restrict the sample to parents of at least two children, effects are again

    somewhat larger in the aggregate, but the main pattern across subsamples and child

    ages remains the same. The estimated effect of having a second child is stronger for

    women in all education groups and at all ages of the second child. Lastly, splitting

    the sample into subgroups based on education measured at age 22 instead of 25

    though yielding too few observations to get meaningful estimates in the group with

    the highest educationthe pattern across the other groups is still one of larger wage

    penalties with higher education.12

    Table 2, columns (6)(10) gives the results on the wage penalties to fatherhood.

    In the whole sample, the estimated effect is positive initially, at .67 %, and only

    becomes negative as the child is older than 15, at .45. However, when we estimatethe effect on wages separately for the four education groups, there are negative

    effects in the two middle education groups already at the outset, at .28 and .39 %

    respectively. Also for men in these groups, the wage penalty to parenthood grows as

    the child gets older, ending up at 1 % in the group with upper secondary education,

    and 2 % for those with 4 years or less of higher education.

    Restricting the sample to fathers only, the estimated effects of the first child tend

    to become stronger, in both directions, but the general picture remains the same.

    Further restricting the sample to fathers of at least two children, effects of having a

    second child are estimated to be negative, indicating that fathers of two children are

    positively selected with respect to wages. There are no significant differences when

    we use the observed level of education at age 22 instead of 25.13

    The statistically and economically significant wage penalty to fatherhood that we

    find here contrasts with the findings of other studies on US data (Lundberg and Rose

    2000, 2002), and also those by Simonsen and Skipper (2008) for Denmark. Wilde

    et al. (2010), who restrict their sample to those who become fathers, also find small

    negative effects on mens wages of having children.

    The estimated effects of further children are positive and statistically significant

    for men in the two lower education groupsand in the sample as a whole. However,

    11 For comparison, the average return to one more year of education for women in Norway in this period,

    lies between 5 and 6 % (Hgeland and Kirkeben 2007, p.14) and the gender wage gap in Norway lies

    around 16 % (NOU 2008:6).12 Results are available from the authors upon request.13 Results are available from the authors upon request.

    Parenthood wage penalties in a double income society

    123

  • when we restrict the sample of men to those who are eventually observed to have at

    least two children, the estimated impact of the second child is negative.

    5 Explaining the wage penalties to parenthood

    We examine the determinants of the motherhood wage penalty in two different

    ways. In this section, we investigate how changes in observable circumstances

    explain the wage effect of children. Specifically, we study the respective roles of

    work experience, parental leave, part time work and sector of employment.

    As discussed in Sect. 3, the sample we use are those who have their first child

    between 1993 and 2008. Panel A gives the baseline results from estimating Eq. 1 for

    this sample. Results are very similar to those for the whole sample, given in Table 2.

    In Panel B, the potential explanatory variables are included in the regression.

    Comparing the two panels of Table 3 for women, we see that inclusion of these

    variables does not significantly alter the coefficients. If anything, the estimated

    impact of children is larger when they are included. We explored the results further

    by including only one variable at the time. This showed that adding measures for

    experience, maternity leave and sector of work does not alter the estimated impact

    of having children on womens wages. However, when a dummy for working less

    than 30 h per week is added, the estimated wage penalty becomes greater. It is thus

    the case that working part time, in itself positively associated with hourly wage in

    all education groups (except in the highest one where there is no significant

    association), is also positively correlated with having children. When the part time

    dummy is omitted from the analysis, the effect of children on wages is smaller

    because switching to part time work ameliorates the wage penalty to motherhood.

    The economically insignificant role of experience, part time work and parental

    leave in explaining the motherhood wage penalties point to the importance of labor

    market policies, as these variables are found to explain a large part of the

    motherhood wage penalty in other countries (Waldfogel 1997; Lundberg and Rose

    2000; Budig and England 2001; Datta Gupta and Smith 2002; Anderson et al. 2002;

    Wilde et al. 2010). A possible explanations for the small role of career breaks is that

    policies of job protection during child related absence from work have an effect14. A

    less optimistic explanation is that career breaks around birth are already accounted

    for in the wage offer that the woman gets even before pregnancy. This is the

    reasoning in Albrecht et al. (1999), who do not find a negative effect of child related

    career breaks for Swedish women. It could also be that women have already chosen

    jobs where the negative effects of a career break are small. If women select into

    more child-friendly occupations even before they have children, some of the

    motherhood wage effect is already realized. Adda et al. (2011) suggest such a pre-

    birth wage penalty is substantial.

    14 The positive effects of job protection on mothers wages may explain parts of the differences in the

    size of motherhood wage penalties across countries (Sanchez-Marcos 2013).

    S. Cools, M. Strm

    123

  • Table 4 The effect of children on womens hourly wage

    All Secondary education Higher education

    Lower Upper Lower deg. Higher deg.

    (1) (2) (3) (4) (5)

    Panel A: no parental leave

    First child

    Age 15 0.026*** 0.034*** 0.033*** 0.0099* 0.033(0.0036) (0.0074) (0.0063) (0.0052) (0.038)

    Age 610 0.042*** 0.040*** 0.036*** 0.017** 0.026(0.0044) (0.0088) (0.0079) (0.0067) (0.050)

    Age 1113 0.050*** 0.039*** 0.035*** 0.026*** 0.15**(0.0057) (0.011) (0.010) (0.0091) (0.066)

    Observations 245,061 63,128 73,200 103,659 5,074

    Individuals 58,494 20,352 16,888 20,253 1,001

    Panel B: short length parental leave

    First child

    Age 15 0.020*** 0.0096*** 0.027*** 0.022*** 0.047***(0.0017) (0.0036) (0.0028) (0.0025) (0.011)

    Age 610 0.035*** 0.013** 0.036*** 0.031*** 0.051***(0.0025) (0.0053) (0.0041) (0.0038) (0.017)

    Age 1113 0.042*** 0.014* 0.038*** 0.035*** 0.023(0.0035) (0.0070) (0.0057) (0.0056) (0.026)

    Observations 397,366 89,395 140,172 158,203 9,596

    Individuals 68,809 18,111 25,993 23,322 1,383

    Panel C: middle length parental leave

    First child

    Age 15 0.029*** 0.017*** 0.037*** 0.029*** 0.043***(0.0017) (0.0038) (0.0029) (0.0026) (0.013)

    Age 610 0.047*** 0.021*** 0.051*** 0.040*** 0.039*(0.0026) (0.0055) (0.0044) (0.0041) (0.020)

    Age 1113 0.059*** 0.027*** 0.054*** 0.048*** 0.019(0.0036) (0.0073) (0.0060) (0.0059) (0.031)

    Observations 351,706 75,906 125,978 142,738 7,084

    Individuals 59,327 14,507 22,847 20,931 1,042

    Panel D: long length parental leave

    First child

    Age 15 0.025*** 0.015*** 0.035*** 0.021*** 0.059***(0.0020) (0.0055) (0.0037) (0.0027) (0.012)

    Age 610 0.040*** 0.026*** 0.046*** 0.033*** 0.057***(0.0029) (0.0075) (0.0052) (0.0040) (0.017)

    Age 1113 0.055*** 0.041*** 0.053*** 0.046*** 0.057**(0.0040) (0.010) (0.0071) (0.0056) (0.025)

    Parenthood wage penalties in a double income society

    123

  • In themselves, experience and part time work are generally positively associated

    with the level of wages, whereas maternity leave hardly seems to matter. Public

    sector work is negatively associated with wages in all education categories except

    for the one with lower degree higher education, where the association is strong and

    positive. If women choose to work in the public sector because they plan to have

    children (and believe that a public sector job entails better job protection, greater

    flexibility or lower attrition of skills during career breaks), the true effect of having

    children on womens wages is larger than our estimates, as some of the cost is taken

    even before birth.

    In Table 3, column (6)(10), the corresponding results are given for men who had

    their first child in 1993 or later. Panel A shows that in this sample the average effect

    of children on wages for all men, irrespective of education level, is negative, at

    .59 %. This sample thus differs significantly from both the baseline sample used in

    Table 3 and a sample excluding childless men. This is reflected also in a stronger

    point estimate for the wage penalty in the two middle education groups, at .66 and

    .60 % respectively (columns (8) and (9)). The difference is due to the exclusion of

    parents to children born before 1994. The results are consistent with the observation

    that men increasingly share in the caring for children, consequently also sharing in

    the wage effects.

    When we include the potentially explanatory variables in the regression the

    impact is significant, although most of the effect estimated for the whole sample is

    left unexplained. The coefficient on having a first child aged between 1 and 5 years

    is no longer significant for the group with higher education, lower degree (column

    (9)), and for the group with upper secondary education it is cut in half. Also the

    persistence of the effect, reflected in the coefficients on having a first child aged

    610 years and 1114 years, is reduced, although not by as much.

    Including each of these variables separately shows that the wage penalty to

    fatherhood hardly covaries with experience, part time work or sector of employ-

    ment. It is the inclusion of parental leave that matters for the estimated effect on

    mens wages of having children. In the two groups where having children does have

    a statistically significant impact on mens wages, paternity leave explains a

    substantial part of the effect.

    Table 4 continued

    All Secondary education Higher education

    Lower Upper Lower deg. Higher deg.

    (1) (2) (3) (4) (5)

    Observations 396,786 60,440 130,141 193,584 12,621

    Individuals 62,649 11,366 22,853 26,721 1,709

    Subsample analysis according to relative length of parental leave

    Each column in each panel provides FE estimates from a regression based on Eq. 1 for the sample of

    individuals who had their first child in 1994 or later. Year dummies, a polynomial in age, individual fixed

    effects and controls for further children, being pregnant and having a baby younger than one year are

    included in all specifications. Robust standard errors are in parentheses. * p\0:10; ** p\0:05;*** p\0:01

    S. Cools, M. Strm

    123

  • The variation in parental leave in itself explains a great deal of mens hourly

    wages. For the three highest education groups (columns (8) to (10)), one year of

    parental leave is associated with a 34 % reduction in wagesabout the whole

    wage penalty for women, who typically take somewhat less than a year of leave. We

    are not able to determine to what extent this is due to the adverse effect of paternity

    leave on human capital accumulation or whether the length of paternity leave

    reflects mens propensity to spend more effort at home relative to market work,

    thereby reducing wages. The finding that parental leave is more strongly associated

    with the wage effects of parenthood for men than for women is in accordance with

    Albrecht et al. (1999)s finding in their study on Swedish data. They find that career

    breaks around birth are associated with negative wage effects only for men, not for

    women. Their interpretation is that the negative wage effect stems from the

    employer offering lower wages to women even before they have children because

    they expect women to have a career break around birth. Employers do not expect the

    same from men, and parental leave is therefore a stronger signal of the strength of

    mens commitment to market work. Another possible explanation that would give

    the same empirical pattern, however, is that men to a larger extent than women

    choose jobs where a career break has a larger effect.

    Part time work is associated with higher wages for those with secondary

    education (columns (7) and (8)) and with lower wages for those with higher

    education (columns (9) and (10)). Public sector work is generally associated with

    having lower wages, except in the group with lower degree higher educationlike

    for women.

    6 Heterogeneous effects

    In this section we investigate whether the wage penalty is stronger for some groups

    than for others. We do this by running separate regressions on different subgroups;

    on those who take relatively longer or shorter parental leave, on those who work full

    time and part time, and on those who work in the public or in the private sector.

    Individuals are sorted into groups based on the observed length of parental leave

    taken with the first child, or according to sector or working time category the year

    before their first child is born. As the variables we condition on are available from

    1993 onwards, we limit the sample to individuals having their first child after 1993

    (like in Sect. 5).

    6.1 Parental leave

    Probably the most direct labor market effect of having children is the period of

    parental leave. In Tables 4 and 5, we investigate whether parenthood wage effects

    are stronger for those who take relatively longer leave. We have divided the samples

    in four: Those who take no, little, middle and long leave. The division into little,

    middle and long is based on the assigned percentile in the distribution of all

    parents of the same sex with children born in the same quarter of the year. The

    Parenthood wage penalties in a double income society

    123

  • distribution is divided in three. For men, though, there is very little spread in the

    number of leave days taken, and the middle groupcontaining less than 1 % of the

    samplehas therefore been included in the group of men taking a short period of

    leave.

    Table 5 The effect of children on mens hourly wage

    All Secondary education Higher education

    Lower Upper Lower deg. Higher deg.

    (1) (2) (3) (4) (5)

    Panel A: No parental leave

    First child

    Age 15 0.015*** 0.011*** 0.0093*** -0.012*** 0.011(0.0019) (0.0031) (0.0030) (0.0039) (0.011)

    Age 610 0.032*** 0.017*** 0.019*** -0.023*** 0.023(0.0027) (0.0044) (0.0043) (0.0054) (0.016)

    Age 1113 0.047*** 0.024*** 0.031*** -0.026*** 0.0070(0.0037) (0.0060) (0.0059) (0.0077) (0.023)

    Observations 618,598 207,085 242,647 153,265 15,601

    Individuals 127,953 50,982 48,601 25,839 2,531

    Panel B: short or middle length parental leave

    First child

    Age 15 0.0013 0.0044 0.0031 0.0014 0.00090(0.0016) (0.0032) (0.0024) (0.0030) (0.0096)

    Age 610 0.0076*** 0.0077* 0.0097*** 0.0041 0.0015(0.0024) (0.0046) (0.0036) (0.0044) (0.014)

    Age 1113 0.016*** 0.0050 0.016*** 0.0079 0.0094(0.0035) (0.0066) (0.0052) (0.0066) (0.020)

    Observations 651,320 161,248 286,487 184,084 19,501

    Individuals 111,740 30,629 51,018 27,233 2,860

    Panel C: long length parental leave

    First child

    Age 15 0.014*** 0.0018 0.016*** 0.014*** 0.025**(0.0032) (0.0078) (0.0057) (0.0047) (0.012)

    Age 610 0.020*** 0.012 0.021** 0.018** 0.028(0.0048) (0.011) (0.0083) (0.0072) (0.018)

    Age 1113 0.019** 0.023 0.023* 0.017 0.000059(0.0075) (0.016) (0.013) (0.012) (0.028)

    Observations 132,112 22,129 46,954 53,934 9,095

    Individuals 20,517 3,967 7,803 7,487 1,260

    Subsample analysis according to relative length of parental leave

    Each column in each panel provides FE estimates from a regression based on Eq. 1 for the sample of

    individuals who had their first child in 1994 or later. Year dummies, a polynomial in age, individual fixed

    effects and controls for further children, being pregnant and having a baby younger than one year are

    included in all specifications. Robust standard errors are in parentheses. * p\0:10; ** p\0:05;*** p\0:01

    S. Cools, M. Strm

    123

  • Among the parents who are not registered with taking any paid parental leave are

    both individuals who have have not earned the right to paid parental leave and

    individuals who may have earned the right but do not use it. It is very uncommon for

    women not to use the right to maternity leave, hence the group of women taking no

    leave can generally be thought of as consisting of women who did not earn the right.

    For men, it is much more common not to take the paid leave granted them. Also,

    mens right to wage compensated paternity leave does not only depend on their own

    earned right but also on the childs mother having earned the right. Hence the group

    of men taking no leave is more mixed, consisting of men who did not earn the right,

    men whose spouse did not earn the right, and men who have the right to paid

    parental leave but do not use it.

    The results for women are given in Table 4. On average, there is not much

    variation in the immediate effect of having children between the four groups, and

    though there is some variation within each education group according to the relative

    length of maternity leave taken with the first child, there is no clear pattern of

    statistically significant difference between the groups. In the group of women with

    the highest education (column (5)), taking longer leave, relative to taking no leave at

    all, is clearly associated with a greater wage penalty to having children the first four

    years after the wage compensated maternity leave period is over. For the two groups

    with no more than secondary education (columns (2) and (3)), the wage penalty

    during the first years is stronger for the group who does not take paid maternity leave,

    and then it increases in the relative length of the leave period. All in all, the wage

    penalty to motherhood is not very clearly linked to the length of maternity leave (as is

    also found by Albrecht et al. (1999)). This is consistent with the insignificant role of

    maternity leave in explaining motherhood wage penalties discussed in Sect. 5, and is

    a further indication that in the Norwegian institutional context career breaks are less

    important for how wages develop after having children.

    The results for men are given in Table 5. For men, there is a U-shaped

    relationship between the penalty and the propensity to take leave. The wage penalty

    to fatherhood is greatest for the group of men taking no leave and the group of men

    taking longer leave than what is usual. The average wage penalty in the two groups

    of men is considerable, at about 1.5 %. As mentioned, the group of men taking no

    leave is a diverse group, making the interpretation of the results for this group

    harder to interpret. A stronger parenthood wage effect for men taking longer

    parental leave is on the other hand in line with the findings of Albrecht et al. (1999).

    6.2 Full time versus part time employment

    Having children is associated with a reduction in working hours both for men and

    womenbut mainly for women (Cools and Strm 2012). As documented in Sect. 5,

    changing working time status to part time is what correlates most with a motherhood

    wage penalty. Here we investigate whether wage penalties are smaller for those who

    already work part time before having children. However, if part time work is chosen

    in advance because the individual plans to have a child, this would cause an upward

    bias in our estimates of the effect of having children.

    Parenthood wage penalties in a double income society

    123

  • Table 6 The effect of children on hourly wage

    All Secondary education Higher education

    Lower Upper Lower deg. Higher deg.

    (1) (2) (3) (4) (5)

    Panel A: full time, women

    First child

    Age 15 0.035*** 0.020*** -0.039*** 0.033*** -0.056***(0.0011) (0.0026) (0.0019) (0.0015) (0.0067)

    Age 610 0.054*** 0.030*** -0.052*** 0.045*** -0.053***(0.0016) (0.0039) (0.0028) (0.0023) (0.010)

    Age 1113 0.067*** 0.036*** -0.057*** 0.056*** -0.039**(0.0023) (0.0052) (0.0040) (0.0033) (0.016)

    Observations 941,388 155,330 311,908 444,460 29,690

    Individuals 152,488 29,385 55,171 63,681 4,251

    Panel B: part time, women

    First child

    Age 15 0.014*** 0.0055 0.020*** 0.011*** 0.020(0.0024) (0.0046) (0.0038) (0.0043) (0.036)

    Age 610 0.022*** 0.0070 -0.027*** 0.012** 0.029(0.0035) (0.0065) (0.0055) (0.0061) (0.051)

    Age 1113 0.026*** 0.012 -0.027*** 0.0071 0.044(0.0048) (0.0086) (0.0076) (0.0085) (0.067)

    Observations 230,963 61,801 89,058 78,610 1,494

    Individuals 42,296 12,490 16,703 12,852 251

    Panel C: full time, men

    First child

    Age 15 0.0084*** 0.0021 0.0075*** 0.0087*** 0.00088(0.0013) (0.0024) (0.0019) (0.0024) (0.0065)

    Age 610 0.026*** 0.0071** 0.019*** 0.020*** 0.0069(0.0019) (0.0035) (0.0029) (0.0035) (0.0093)

    Age 1113 0.040*** 0.015*** 0.027*** 0.030*** 0.014(0.0027) (0.0050) (0.0041) (0.0053) (0.014)

    Observations 1,083,899 275,061 467,116 304,117 37,605

    Individuals 187,504 53,613 83,455 44,952 5,484

    Panel D: Part time, men

    First child

    Age 15 0.0089* 0.00051 0.0096 0.013* 0.021(0.0046) (0.0083) (0.0078) (0.0079) (0.036)

    Age 610 0.023*** 0.016 0.022* 0.034*** 0.012

    (0.0065) (0.012) (0.011) (0.011) (0.055)

    Age 1113 0.036*** 0.023 0.028* 0.070*** 0.032(0.0092) (0.017) (0.016) (0.015) (0.080)

    S. Cools, M. Strm

    123

  • The results for women are given in Panel A and B in Table 6. On average, the

    negative wage effects of having children are two to three times stronger for the

    women who were registered with full time employment the year before they had

    children, compared to the women who had part time employment before having

    children. Also, on average, there is a clear pattern of the wage penalty increasing

    over time for the group of full time working women, reaching a wage reduction of

    6.7 % when the first child turns 11 years old.

    In the very small group of women with the highest education who worked part

    time before having children, we see the first instance of a wage premium to having

    children, reaching 7.8 % and significant at the 5 % level by the time the child turns

    11 years old. This may indicate that for women who already started part time work

    before having children, the extra effort put into child rearing does not intervene as

    strongly with the effort put into work.15

    Panel C and D in Table 6 give the corresponding results for men. Here, the

    difference between the two groups is even more striking. The men who worked full

    time before becoming fathers on average experience a wage penalty to fatherhood,

    at .88 %. This is a 50 % larger penalty than the .51 % wage penalty estimated for

    the whole sample given in Table 6. The penalty grows significantly over time, like

    the case is for women who work full time before having children. The wage penalty

    estimated for the sample of full time working men is on average stronger than for

    the part time working women, especially as the first child grows older.

    Consistent with the conjecture that part time workers face less of a trade-off in

    effort between home and market work (they may thus even spend more effort at

    work after they have children), for men who worked part time before becoming

    fathers we find statistically significant wage premia to fatherhood when looking at

    the whole sample (column (1) in Panel D) and in the two middle education groups.

    The premium grows as the child gets older.

    We also investigated the heterogeneity of effects according to sector of

    employment and found that wage penalties are larger for both men and women

    Table 6 continued

    All Secondary education Higher education

    Lower Upper Lower deg. Higher deg.

    (1) (2) (3) (4) (5)

    Observations 95,634 28,386 33,631 32,228 1,389

    Individuals 17,845 6,080 6,356 5,190 219

    Subsample analysis according to being employed full time or part time the year before having children

    Each column in each panel provides FE estimates from a regression based on Eq. 1 for the sample of

    individuals who had their first child in 1994 or later. Year dummies, a polynomial in age, individual fixed

    effects and controls for further children, being pregnant and having a baby younger than one year are

    included in all specifications. Robust standard errors are in parentheses. * p\0:10; ** p\0:05;*** p\0:01

    15 If part time work is chosen by women because they anticipate childbearing, the wage penalty may

    have been realized even before the child is born, and will not be picked up by our estimates.

    Parenthood wage penalties in a double income society

    123

  • working in the private sector prior to having the first child.16 The results are

    consistent with the hypothesis that parenthood wage effects are due to reduced effort

    at work. A slowing down of wages in a sector with large wage potential, has large

    consequences for the individual.

    7 Conclusion

    In spite of the encouragement built into the labor market institutions of the Nordic

    countries to combine work and family, the two remain in conflict, as is pointed out

    by the wage penalties to parenthood documented in this paper. Like in most other

    countries, women bear the greater share of the cost of having children also in

    Norway. Wage penalties to motherhood are however smaller than what is observed

    in many other countries, where the previous literature has found that career breaks

    and loss of work experience explain a large share of the wage penalty. As such

    measures of human capital do not seem to explain the family gap in Norway, these

    findings indicate that family policies such as paid parental and job protection

    contribute to reducing the adverse wage effects of parenthood.

    We find indicative evidence that a reduced effort is more important than loss of

    human capital in explaining the family wage gap. With a larger workload at home,

    effort at work can be affected negatively. In groups where wages may be expected

    to depend more on efforthigher educated women, women working full time and

    in the private sectorwe find larger wage penalties to motherhood.

    Contrary to earlier studies using US data and to previous research from Norway,

    we find negative (though comparatively small) wage penalties also to fatherhood,

    consistent with mens increasing involvement in child rearing. Contrary to the

    findings for women, the length of parental leave can explain a large share of the

    fatherhood wage penalty. Parental leave periods for fathers are generally short, and

    the asymmetry in the importance of parental leave between men and women may

    reflect that the length of parental leave serves as a signal of future effort at work,

    rather than being an adverse human capital effect (Albrecht et al. 1999).

    We conclude that in the Norwegian context, human capital is of little importance

    in explaining the family gap in wages. It may as such serve as an explanation for

    why the observed motherhood wage penalty is smaller in Norway than in many

    other countries. Though suggesting that effort plays a comparatively more important

    role, the evidence presented in this article is not conclusive. For a deeper

    understanding of the mechanisms, further research is needed.

    References

    Adda, J., Dustmann, C., & Stevens, K. (2011). The career costs of children. Working paper.

    Albrecht, J. W., Edin, P.-A., Sundstrm, M., & Vroman, S. B. (1999). Career interruptions and

    subsequent earnings: A reexamination using Swedish data. Journal of Human Resources, 34(2),

    294311.

    16 Results are available from the authors upon request.

    S. Cools, M. Strm

    123

  • Anderson, D. J., Binder, M., & Krause, K. (2002). The motherhood wage penalty: Which mothers pay it

    and why? American Economic Review, 92(2), 354358.

    Anderson, D. J., Binder, M., & Krause, K. (2003). The motherhood wage penalty revisited: Experience,

    heterogeneity, work effort, and work-schedule flexibility. Industrial and