patterns of business creation, survival, and growth...

43
Patterns of Business Creation, Survival, and Growth: Evidence from a Developing Country Leora Klapper y Christine Richmond z November 2009 Abstract We study rm dynamics using a novel database of all formally registered rms in Cote dIvoire from 1977-1997, which account for about 60% of GDP. During this pe- riod, Cote dIvoire experienced (separate) episodes of trade reform, scal reform, and monetary reform, and we examine the impact of these shocks on private sector dy- namics. First, we examine entry and exit patterns over this period and the role of new and exiting rms versus incumbents in job creation and destruction. In comparison with the U.S., new rms play a relatively important role in job creation and growth, particularly during periods of political uncertainty. Yet, in absolute terms, incumbent rms have a much larger impact on net employment. Next, we examine survival rates We thank Francois Bourguignon for providing us the data and Daniel Dias, Sebastian Edwards, Phil English, Vesela Grozeva, Ed Leamer, Phil Kim, Javier Miranda, Nico Voigtlander, Mark Wright, Romain Wacziarg, and seminar participants at the World Bank and 2009 COST Workshop on Firm-level Data Analysis in Transition and Developing Economies, George Mason University-Kau/man Foundation Business Creation Symposium, and 2009 Northeast Universities Development Consortium for helpful comments. Financial assistance from UCLA CIBER is gratefully acknowledged by Christine Richmond. The opinions expressed do not necessarily represent the views of the World Bank, its Executive Directors, or the countries they represent. y World Bank, Development Research Group. The World Bank. 1818 H St. N.W., Washington, DC 20433. Tel: +1.202.473.8738; Email: [email protected]. z Anderson Graduate School of Management, UCLA. Anderson Graduate School of Management, UCLA. 110 Westwood Plaza, Entrepreneurs Hall, Suite C525, Los Angeles, CA 90095-1481. Tel.: +1 310.825.8207; Email: [email protected]. 1

Upload: phungcong

Post on 11-Jul-2018

215 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

  • Patterns of Business Creation, Survival, and Growth:

    Evidence from a Developing Country

    Leora Klappery Christine Richmondz

    November 2009

    Abstract

    We study rm dynamics using a novel database of all formally registered rms in

    Cote dIvoire from 1977-1997, which account for about 60% of GDP. During this pe-

    riod, Cote dIvoire experienced (separate) episodes of trade reform, scal reform, and

    monetary reform, and we examine the impact of these shocks on private sector dy-

    namics. First, we examine entry and exit patterns over this period and the role of new

    and exiting rms versus incumbents in job creation and destruction. In comparison

    with the U.S., new rms play a relatively important role in job creation and growth,

    particularly during periods of political uncertainty. Yet, in absolute terms, incumbent

    rms have a much larger impact on net employment. Next, we examine survival rates

    We thank Francois Bourguignon for providing us the data and Daniel Dias, Sebastian Edwards, PhilEnglish, Vesela Grozeva, Ed Leamer, Phil Kim, Javier Miranda, Nico Voigtlander, Mark Wright, RomainWacziarg, and seminar participants at the World Bank and 2009 COST Workshop on Firm-level DataAnalysis in Transition and Developing Economies, George Mason University-Kauman Foundation BusinessCreation Symposium, and 2009 Northeast Universities Development Consortium for helpful comments.Financial assistance from UCLA CIBER is gratefully acknowledged by Christine Richmond. The opinionsexpressed do not necessarily represent the views of the World Bank, its Executive Directors, or the countriesthey represent.

    yWorld Bank, Development Research Group. The World Bank. 1818 H St. N.W., Washington, DC20433. Tel: +1.202.473.8738; Email: [email protected].

    zAnderson Graduate School of Management, UCLA. Anderson Graduate School of Management, UCLA.110 Westwood Plaza, Entrepreneurs Hall, Suite C525, Los Angeles, CA 90095-1481. Tel.: +1 310.825.8207;Email: [email protected].

    1

  • and nd that survival increases monotonically with rm size. Furthermore, higher

    GDP growth increases survival rates, and periods of economic growth have the largest

    impact on the reduction in the exit rates of small rms, relative to large rms. Finally,

    we nd that all reforms decreased rm survival, although the impact varied by sector:

    for instance, political reforms increased the exit rate of foreign-owned rms (relative

    to domestic rms), while both trade and monetary reforms decreased survival rates of

    rms in the trade sector.

    JEL Classication: G18, G38, L51, M13

    Keywords: Business Incorporation; Regulatory Barriers; Economic Growth

    2

  • 1 Introduction

    Firm entry and exit Schumpeterian creative destructionis critical for the continued

    dynamism of the modern economy. Though evidence has linked entrepreneurship and eco-

    nomic growth in developed countries, we have scarce evidence that a relationship exists

    in developing countries. For instance, to what extent does entrepreneurship contribute to

    job creation in countries with regulatory, legal, and tax barriers to entry and exit? In this

    paper, we examine job creation and destruction, at both new and incumbent rms, in Cote

    dIvoire, ranked 161 out of 181 countries in the Doing Business "Ease of Doing Business"

    ranking (where 1 indicates the most favorable business environment) (World Bank, 2009).

    We use a new and unique database that includes the complete census of registered

    rms in Cote dIvoire from 1976 through 1997. This includes data collected at the time

    of registration (ownership, sector, etc.) as well as annual reporting of total employment.

    Unlike comparable studies that use survey data or manufacturing censuses, we can compute

    over time exact formal sector entry and exit rates; growth and contraction at incumbent

    rms; and the impact of macroeconomic and policy reforms on sectoral distribution and

    growth.

    First, we examine business dynamics in Cote dIvoire, using the complete census of

    registered rms over the period 1976 to 1997. We decompose trends in job creation and

    growth into entry of new rms and expansion of incumbent rms, and job destruction

    into exit and contraction. We also illustrate trends in Cote dIvoire, relative to the U.S.

    (Haltiwanger et al., 2008), and compare dierences and similarities in formal business

    creation and destruction across very dierent investment climates.

    Next, we examine the impact of three policy reforms on entrepreneurship: The rst

    reform removed import quotas and other trade restrictions. The second reform reduced

    public sector wages (in an attempt to reduce the budget decit). The third reform devalued

    the currency by half. We study the eect of these scal, monetary, and trade reforms on

    the creation of new rms, the average size of rms that incorporate, and the growth of

    3

  • incumbent rms, controlling for rm size, ownership, and age. Finally, we use a survival

    analysis to study the impact of the business cycle and government reforms on rm exit.

    New research on the survival of rms in low-income countries has important implications

    for development strategies. In order for the private sector to act as an engine of growth

    and advance the development process, it is necessary for rms to survive and grow. It is also

    important for policymakers to understand and consider the impact of government policies

    on private sector survival and growth.

    Our paper proceeds as follows. Section 2 reviews previous literature related to rm

    dynamics. Section 3 reviews the relevant economic and political history in Cote dIvoire.

    Section 4 compares business dynamics in Cote dIvoire and the U.S. Section 5 discusses our

    survival test methodology and results. Section 6 concludes.

    2 Related Literature

    Empirical studies of rm dynamics overwhelming focus on rm behavior in the US, Canada,

    and other industrialized countries.1 In general, these studies nd that gross entry is sub-

    stantial in most industries and is signicantly higher than net entry due to the high death

    rate of infant rms.2 Successful entrants grow rapidly, so that an entrant cohorts initial

    market share falls slowly. For instance, an early study of patterns of rm entry, growth, and

    exit in US manufacturing industries over the period 1963-1982 shows that there is substan-

    tial and persistent dierences in entry and exit rates across industries and that industries

    with higher than average entry rates tend to also have higher than average exit rates (Dunne

    et al., 1988). The authors also nd that most entrants and exiters are substantially smaller

    than existing or continuing producers.

    Recent cross-country studies have examined the impact of country characteristics, in

    particular, the legal and regulatory environment, on rm entry and growth. For instance, a

    1See Caves(1998) for a thorough survey of the literature on job turnover and rm mobility.2There is also a substantial literature on entry into an industry (possibly by a rm from another industry)

    as distinguished from rm creation or entrepreneurship; see Gilbert (1989) for a comprehensive survey.

    4

  • comprehensive picture of entry rates across Europe (using a rm-level database of registered

    rms) use a dierence-in-dierence approach to show that onerous entry regulations hamper

    the creation of new rms, especially in industries that naturally should have high entry.

    Furthermore, the consequences of regulatory barriers against entrepreneurship are seen, not

    in young rms, but in older rms, who grow more slowly and to a smaller size (Klapper

    et al, 2006). Another paper uses this database and a cross-country approach and nds

    complementary evidence that entry regulations have a negative impact on rm entry (Desai

    et al., 2003). A study using rm-level data from OECD countries to analyze rm entry and

    exit nds that higher product market and labor regulations are negatively correlated with

    the entry of SMEs in OECD countries (Scarpetta et al., 2002). Finally, a study of entry

    rates in over 100 countries nds signicant relationships between entrepreneurial activity

    and indicators of economic and nancial development and growth, the quality of the legal

    and regulatory environment, and governance (Klapper et al., 2009).

    Other studies have studied rm size distribution, i.e. the importance of small and

    medium sized rms (SMEs) in the economy. For instance, a study of the creative destruction

    process in 24 developed and developing countries over the 1990s nds that countries are

    dominated by micro and small rms (with less than 20 employees), which accounts for more

    than 80% of the rm population, yet only accounts for up to 30% of employment (Bartelsman

    et al., 2004). A study of 76 countries nds a strong association between the importance of

    SMEs and GDP per capita growth, although not necessarily a causal relationship (Beck et

    al., 2005).

    The shortcoming of most studies in low- and middle-income countries is their dependence

    on survey data. For instance, surveys for ve Eastern and Southern African countries

    (Botswana, Kenya, Malawi, Swaziland, and Zimbabwe) as well as the Dominican Republic

    are used to examine the magnitude and determinants of rm births, deaths, and expansions

    of micro and small enterprises (MSEs) (Mead and Liedholm, 1998). The authors nd that

    the annual rate of new MSE start-ups averages over 20%, and that the vast majority of

    5

  • new rms were one-person establishments. For MSE closures, location plays a signicant

    role with urban MSEs having an almost 25% greater chance of surviving the year, ceteris

    peribus, compared to rural MSEs.

    A number of studies have also used rm surveys to study the determinants of rm

    growth. Using a survey of manufacturing rms in Cote dIvoire, Sleuwaegen and Goedhuys

    (2002) nd that younger rms grow faster than older rms, yet larger entrants experience

    greater growth opportunities that improve over time. A broad review of manufacturing

    rm performance across developing countries nds that most economies are small, have

    limited domestically produced intermediate inputs and capital equipment, face low rates

    of secondary education and a lack of technicians, have limited infrastructure, experience

    greater macroeconomic and relative price volatility than developed countries, have thin

    credit markets with debt heavily skewed towards short-term instruments, and face weak

    legal systems and higher instances of corruption (Tybout, 2000). Overall, these challenges

    hamper the growth of small, entering rms.

    Another important question in this literature is the determinants of rm survival. For

    example, evidence from Portuguese manufacturing rms nds that drivers of a rms survival

    include start-up size, with larger rms having a higher probability of survival, and fast

    growing industries having a positive eect on rm duration. Furthermore, the probability

    of rm failure decreases with the age of the rm, consistent with the view that rm entry

    is a process of selection and learning (Mata and Portugal, 1994).

    Finally, the literature examines the impact of macroeconomic and other shocks on private

    sector behavior. For instance, large macroeconomic disturbances are found to aect the

    rm turnover process. A study of the cyclical behavior of small versus large manufacturing

    rms in the U.S. and the response to monetary policy, nds that small rms account for

    a signicantly disproportionate share of the decline in manufacturing that follows a shift

    to tight money (Gertler and Gilchrist, 1994). A related paper focusing specically on new

    rms in the U.S. nds that startup rates are substantially shaped by both macroeconomic

    6

  • uctuations as well as industry-specic characteristics; macroeconomic expansion serves

    as a catalyst for startup activity, but new-rm startups are promoted by a low cost of

    capital as well as high unemployment rates (Audretsch and Acs, 1994). A study of rms

    in West Germany rms nds that the exit of new plants is not responsive to aggregate

    cyclical uctuations, rather, exit is large among new entrants at any stage of the business

    cycle; however, among incumbent plants, the survival of older rms is more sensitive to the

    aggregate cycle (Boeri and Bellmann, 1995).

    Previous literature has also studied the impact of trade reform. An investigation of

    employment patterns in Chilean manufacturing rms following a major trade liberalization

    between 1975-1979 which made the economy more outward-oriented, removed quantitative

    trade restrictions and slashed tari rates, privatized rms, relaxed government controlled

    prices, and reformed nancial markets nds that in the years following the trade liber-

    alization, rm size matters for job creation and destruction; job churning is very high in

    both expanding and contracting industries; and job creation and destruction varies with

    whether the rm is operating in the tradable or non-tradable sectors (Levinsohn, 1999).

    The importance of rms size in determining survival is supported by another study that

    examines rms in Ghana, Kenya, and Tanzania during the 1990s, when market reforms

    were implemented to eliminate protection of the domestic rms (Harding, et al., 2004). To

    summarize, the literature in developing countries generally nds that the main determinant

    of rm exit is size, with small rms having much higher exit rates than large rms, and nd

    no evidence that productivity impacts rm survival.

    7

  • 3 Macroeconomic Background and Government Re-

    forms

    In 2006, Cote dIvoire was ranked 164 out of 177 in the World Bank Human Development

    Index (World Bank, 2009).3 This followed a period of political instability and civil war

    (2002 to 2003). Yet, Cote dIvoire remains one of the largest economies in the region and

    accounts for close to 40% of the economic activity in the West Africa Economic Monetary

    Union (WAEMU). Furthermore, the countrys relatively high GDP per capita (US$ 1,027

    in 2007) suggests opportunities for private sector development and growth.

    Cote dIvoire grew rapidly after achieving independence in 1960, and by 1974, nominal

    GNI per capita rose from 190 to 450 CFA (over 300% in real terms). This expansion

    was primarily due to growth in the agricultural sector as the country benetted from high

    international prices of coee and cocoa, for which the country is a major exporter. In

    addition, the countrys investment code and stable government and policies encouraged

    foreign capital investment in agribusiness activities. By 1978, the World Bank declared,

    The so-called Ivorian Miraclehas not been a matter of luck. . . and the countrys political

    stability and favorable economic environment led international organizations to believe that

    the country could be the rst African country to achieve "developed" status (Tuinder,

    1978).4 However, with the collapse of coee and cocoa prices and the oil shock in 1979, the

    Ivorian economy experienced a severe annualized contraction of 12% in 1980 and entered a

    prolonged recessionary period that persisted through most of the 1980s. For most of this

    period, GDP growth was less than 3% and private credit (as a percentage of GDP) sharply

    declined from about 30% to less than 20%.

    After defaulting on commercial bank loans in 1983, the country undertook a series of

    foreign debt reschedulings with both o cial and private creditors. For the next decade,

    3This section draws on Trebesch (2008), Reuda-Sabater and Stone (1992), and Library of CongressCountry Studies (1988).

    4From 1960 to 1993, the country was led by a one-party rule: Houphouet-Boigny ruled from 1960 untilhis death in 1993.

    8

  • Cote dIvoire instituted a series of trade, scal, and monetary reforms, which we will show

    impacted private sector entry, exit, and growth.

    First, from 1985 to 1987, the government removed a series of import quotas, in order to

    increase competition and reduce prices. The government removed quantitative restrictions

    and unied eective rates of protection across intermediate and nal goods, which reduced

    the competitive advantage of domestic manufacturers vis--vis foreign exporters (Harrison,

    1994).

    Following the implementation of this trade reform, domestic conditions deteriorated

    drastically in 1987 with international coee prices dropping more than 30% (YoY), which

    led to a scal decit greater than 8% of GNP and external debt ratios higher than 145% of

    GNP, and caused the government to declare an o cial debt moratorium in May 1987. In

    December 1987, the government reached a multi-year rescheduling of US$ 931 million with

    Paris Club creditors and an agreement with London Club creditors worth US$ 1,575 million

    in March 1988. In support of the agreements with creditors, the IMF extended US$ 240

    million in loans in March 1988, and the government undertook a series of revenue-raising

    measures.

    While the countrys default episode was not fully resolved until 1998 (additional reschedul-

    ings occurred in 1989 and 1997), the workout arrangements with creditors and IMF support

    ensured access (albeit limited) to external capital markets. Yet by the late 1980s the gov-

    ernment faced signicant di culties implementing IMF and World Bank mandated reforms,

    particularly attempts to contain the public sector wage bill which amounted to than 60% of

    non-interest expenditures. These moves led to protests by trade unions, strikes, demonstra-

    tions, and led to a rise in student militancy. At the end of 1992, the government announced

    its plans to abandon salary cuts (and introduce a multi-party political system), which de-

    fused public protests.

    Due to further deteriorations in the terms of trade, the Central Bank of West African

    States (BCEAO) implemented an IMF-backed nominal devaluation of the CFA by 50% in

    9

  • mid-January 1994 in an eort to restore the regions international competitiveness. After

    being pegged to the French franc at the same rate for 46 years, the currency value was

    reduced from CFA/FRF 50 to CFA/FRF 100 (equivalent to CFA/EUR 656). Cote dIvoire

    responded well to the devaluation as the government simultaneously undertook a series of

    reforms to improve competitiveness and promote investment, including a revised investment

    code, removal of price controls and export duties on key exports, and privatization program,

    in order to maximize the benets associated with the devaluation.

    To summarize, our empirical analysis will focus on the impact of private sector activity

    following three government interventions:

    Trade reform (1985-1987): Removal of import quotas;

    Fiscal reform (1989-1990): Reduction in public sector wages;

    Monetary reform (1994): 50% currency devaluation.

    4 Data and Summary Statistics

    The dataset is comprised of 5,941 unique rms in Cote dIvoire from 1976 through 1997,

    which covers the complete census of formal, private sector corporations in the country.5

    The data was hand-collected from the Registrar of Companies for the Modern Enterprise

    Sector, and does not include a sample bias of exited rms. These rms are expected to pay

    the full range of taxes, and may benet from bank nance and state technical assistance.

    This dataset appears to be consistent with the overall private sector in Cote dIvoire, which

    includes about 800 large, formally registered enterprises (with at least 50 employees), several

    thousand formally and informally operating medium-sized enterprises (10-50 employees),

    and several hundred thousand informal microentrepreneurs, which mostly generate self-

    employment (Reuda-Sabater and Stone, 1992).

    5The database excludes the primary sectors and state-owned rms.

    10

  • The structure of the data is an unbalanced panel of about 37,000 rm/year observations.

    That is, there is detailed information tracking rms over time and the dataset includes rms

    that enter over the course of the sample period, as well as rms that exit during the sample.

    The variables of interest are information on sector classication at the two-digit sector

    level and rm ownership, collected at the time of registration, and annual data on rm

    employment, collected from required annual lings.6 Our dataset also includes balance

    sheet and income statement nancial information, which is available for the sub-period

    1976-1987.

    We summarize this dataset in two dimensions: First, we provide the rst illustration of

    rm dynamics in a low-income country, across sectors and time. This includes entry and

    exit rates, as well as job creation and destruction rates and new versus incumbent rms.

    Second, we present a comparison of formal sector dynamics in Cote dIvoire, relative to

    private sector dynamics in the U.S. Following recent work by Haltiwanger et al. (2008), we

    use the U.S. Bureau of the Census, Business Demography Statistics (BDS), which provides

    detailed data on rm births and deaths and job creation and destruction, by rm size,

    age, and sector.7 An important caveat is that we are not able to compare the two overall

    economies: Data for the U.S. covers virtually the complete private sector, while data for

    Cote dIvoire includes a very small number of rms that chose to formally register in a

    challenging business environment. Yet, this comparison might shed light on barriers to

    private sector job creation and growth, which encumbers many developing nations.

    4.1 Business and employment formation

    On average, there are about 2,000 registered rms per year, with on average 29 employees

    (and median employment of 7), which employ about 100,000 individuals. Although this is a

    6All registered companies are required to submit annual lings to the Registrar of Companies withnancial and employment information. Our panel includes only two missing rm/year observations.

    7An important caveat is that US data is on the establishment (plant) level, while the Ivorian data is onthe rm (consolidated) level. However, nearly all rms in Cote dIvoire operate in only one location. Tomake the databases comparable, we exclude from the Cote dIvoire sample rms in the nancial, insurance,and real estate (FIRE) sectors.

    11

  • small fraction of overall employment, including individuals self-employed or employed in the

    informal sector, the formal sector represents over 60% of GDP (OECD African Economic

    Outlook, 2004). Figure 1, Panel A, shows that while the total number of registered rms in

    a given year has remained at, on average, over the period, total employment in the formal

    private sector declines over time. These are important trends for policymakers trying to

    promote high-growth, employment generating, private sector rms. While average rm size

    in Cote dIvoire has decreased over time, Panel B shows that average rm size in the U.S.

    grew by over 7% over the same period.

    Figure 2 presents summary statistics, by size buckets over the entire sample period. For

    the purpose of our analysis, we dene smallas less than 10 employees; middleas 10-49

    employees; largeas 50-149 employees; and very largeas more than 150 employees.

    Economy-wide, 40% of rms have less than 10 employees and an additional 40% of rms

    have 10-49 employees. Interestingly, we also nd in the U.S. that 80% of rms have less

    than 50 employees, though a larger number, 62%, have less than 10 employees. The smaller

    percentage of micro rms (with less than 10 employees) in Cote dIvoire might reect

    the fact that because of burdensome regulations, high marginal tax rates, the absence of

    monitoring and compliance (of both registration and tax regulations), and other weaknesses

    in the business environment, many rms might nd it optimal to evade regulations and

    operate in the informal sector. For instance, the cost of starting a business (as a percentage

    of income per capita) is 133% in Cote dIvoire versus 0.7% in the U.S, and the minimum

    capital required to start a business (as a percentage of income per capita) is 205% in Cote

    dIvoire, versus 0% in the U.S (Doing Business, 2009). Previous literature has highlighted the

    potential advantages to formal sector participation, including police and judicial protection

    (and less vulnerability to corruption and the demand for bribe), access to formal credit

    institutions, the ability to use formal labor contracts, and greater access to foreign markets

    12

  • (Schneider and Enste, 2000).8 The tendency of rms in Cote dIvoire to choose to stay

    small and informal might be unable to realize their full growth potential.

    Figure 3 shows the distribution of rms and employees, by sector. Although almost 50%

    of rms are identied as service providers, 46% of employment is generated by the manufac-

    turing sector (as compared to 37% of employment in the service sector). Similarly, we nd

    about 50% of rms in the U.S. are service rms and generate about 40% of employment.

    Yet, we nd a notable dierence in the contribution of the manufacturing sector in Cote

    dIvoire, which comprises about 17% of rms and 46% of employment (as compared to 10%

    of rms and 31% of employment in the U.S). On the one hand, it is surprising that manu-

    facturing rms which require relatively higher levels of investment, human resources, and

    capital remain a large percentage of rms in Cote dIvoire; for example, nancial devel-

    opment (measured as private credit as a percentage of GDP) is only 33% over our sample

    period. However, on average, approximately 70% of Ivorian rms are owned by foreigners

    from industrialized countries with the majority of these owners being French (not shown).9

    The lack of access to domestic nance might also explain the notable dierences in rm

    size distribution, by sector. Though the manufacturing sector has the fewest number of

    rms, average rm size is signicantly larger than it is for rms operating in the trade or

    service sectors. However, the median rm size is small for all sectors, with only a median

    of 8 employees in trade sector rms. We nd notable dierences in comparison to the

    U.S. distribution. Most strikingly, across all sectors we nd less than half the number of

    rms in the category of 10-49 employees, which is novel evidence that the missing middle

    phenomena applies to sectors other than manufacturing.

    For instance, within the manufacturing sector, we nd 44% of rms in Cote dIvoire are

    small (less than 10 employees) and only 27% are large (more than 50 employees), relative to

    14% and 42% of rms in the U.S., respectively; possibly, the growth of manufacturing rms

    8The benets of formal sector registration might vary by industry. This is discussed in Section 5.3.9We also nd that the sectoral distribution of foreign- and domestically-owned rms is nearly identical

    (not shown).

    13

  • in Cote dIvoire is limited by capital constraints. Service sector rms display an even more

    disparate distribution: 72% of rms operate with less than 10 employees in Cote dIvoire,

    relative to 45% of rms in the U.S. In contrast, close to 50% of rms operating in the

    tradable sector in both Cote dIvoire and the U.S. have less than 10 employees, yet 28% of

    rms in Cote dIvoire are large, while only 9% of tradable rms have at least 150 employees.

    It might be the case that in developing countries with costly and timely barriers to starting

    a business, only rms in wholesale and retail trade might have the greatest incentive to

    formally register, for instance, in order to receive a Value Added Tax (VAT) number, which

    might be required for domestic and international sales.

    4.2 Firm and employment dynamics

    In an eort to describe the entry and exit patterns of Ivorian and U.S. rms, we begin by

    constructing measures of entry and exit as well as their size relative to other rms in the

    industry. We count a rm as a new entrant if it appears for a second year, that is, we

    exclude rms that survive less than a year.

    Similar to Dunne et al. (1988), we dene the following variables, where bucket i is

    equal to either 2-digit industry classications (manufacturing, services, or trade) or size

    (micro, small, medium or large):

    NEit = number of rms that enter bucket i between years t 1 and t

    NTit = total number of rms in bucket i in year t, including rms that

    enter bucket i between years t 1 and t

    NXi(t1) = number of rms that exit bucket i between years t 1 and t

    Next, we construct entry (ERit), exit (XRit), and turnover (TRit) rates as:

    ERit = NEit=NTi(t1)

    XRi(t1) = NXi(t1)=NTi(t1)

    TRit = (NEit +NXit)=NTi(t1)

    14

  • The denominator for both entry and exit rates is the total number of rms in bucket i in

    year t-1. This is because we want to capture the pool of potential exiting rms. These

    measures are comparable to gross measures of entry and exit and allow us to compare our

    ndings to those of US rm studies.

    We also construct survival rates as the probability of exiting at t using the Kaplan-Meier

    estimator such that

    S(t) =tYj=1

    [(n t)=(n j + 1)](t):

    S(t) is the estimated survival function, n is the total number of rm lifespans, ()t is a

    dummy equal to one for completed spells and 0 for censored spells. In our sample we nd

    that the average lifespan of rms is 6.7 years, with a median of 5.0 years.

    We follow Haltiwanger, et al.s (2008) analysis of business dynamics in the U.S. Firm-

    level employment growth is :10

    git = (Eit Eit1)=Xit; where Xit = :5 (Eit + Eit1)

    and aggregate employment growth is given by the weighted average of rm-level growth:

    gt = i(Xit=Xt)git; where Xt = iXit:

    Employment growth can be decomposed into creation and destruction:

    JCit = i(Xit=Xt)maxfgit; 0g

    JDit = i(Xit=Xt)maxfgit; 0g:

    Next we decompose job creation into entry and expansion and job destruction into exit

    and contraction:

    JC_Entryt = i(Xit=Xt)Ifgit = 2g;10This follows the methodology of Davis et al. (1994).

    15

  • where I is an indicator variable equal to one if the expression in the brackets hold and zero

    otherwise, and git = 2 denotes an entrant.

    JC_Exitt = i(Xit=Xt)Ifgit = 2g;

    where I is an indicator variable equal to one if the expression in the brackets hold and zero

    otherwise, and git = 2 denotes an exit.

    We commence with a comparison of business dynamics across the U.S. and Cote dIvoire

    over the sample (Figure 5). The rst observation is the high volatility of entry and turnover

    rates in Cote dIvoire, which reect larger business cycle swings and macroeconomic instabil-

    ity (that is, a strong correlation between real GDP and entry rates), political uncertainty,

    and a more challenging business environment (Panels A and B). This is consistent with

    Klapper et al. (2006) and Bartelsman, et al. (2009), which nd a (contemporaneous)

    relationship between entry rates and the business environment.

    The second striking feature of these graphs is that on average, the entry rates in Cote

    dIvoire and the US are so similar (12.4% and 13.2%, respectively), across such dierent

    economic, legal, and institutional environments. This is consistent with similar results

    shown for a larger sample of over 100 countries in the World Bank Entrepreneurship Survey

    database, which nds very low variation in entry rates of formally registered corporations

    across a wide range of countries, e.g. the data nds, on average, entry rates of 8% in

    middle- and low-income countries, versus 11% in industrialized countries (Klapper et al.,

    2008). This is also consistent with Bartelsman et al., (2009), which nds very similar entry

    rates across OECD countries. It is important to bear in mind that we are comparing only

    formal sector dynamics; i.e. it is interesting to consider that rms that overcome the hurdles

    of registering in a challenging business environment look similar to other registered rms

    around the world.

    We also compare one-year survival rates of rms in Cote dIvoire and the U.S. over our

    sample period (Panel C). Similar to our ndings on entry rates, we nd high volatility of sur-

    16

  • vival rates in Cote dIvoire, which reect both larger business cycle swings (macroeconomic

    instability), weaker bankruptcy laws, and greater political instability. However, again, an

    interesting observation is that on average, the 2-year survival rates in Cote dIvoire and

    the US are very similar, 83% and 84%, respectively. Taken together, this might, intrigu-

    ingly, suggest naturalentry and exit rates of registered rms over time, regardless of the

    investment climate.

    Next, in Figure 6, we look at employment dynamics at new and exited rms (Panel A)

    and jobs created and lost at incumbent rms, normalized to 100% (Panel B). Over time,

    net employment is always positive, that is, more jobs are created at new rms then lost

    at exiting rms. However, the absolute number of new jobs added to the private sector is

    remarkably small on average, fewer than 3,000 formal, private sector jobs are added on

    an annual basis. In comparison, the net number of new jobs generated at incumbent rms

    is negative for all years from 1979 through 1995. The largest net job losses occurred during

    the 1980 macroeconomic downturn over 10,000 jobs were shed in 1979 although net jobs

    at incumbent rms remained negative even during periods of GDP growth.

    In comparison to the U.S., an important implication is that new rm creation appears

    to be relatively more important for job creation in Cote dIvoire, relative to incumbent

    growth. This might suggest that expanding opportunities for entrepreneurial potential is

    important for macroeconomic growth. An important caveat, however, is that jobs created

    by new rms are highly volatile and not necessarily as good as those provided by large rms

    (Haltiwanger et al., 2009). This suggests that economic and employment growth in Cote

    dIvoire might be hampered by the inability of incumbent rms to grow, relative to growth

    and job creation rates in developed countries, such as the U.S. This data can be interpreted

    as quantitative evidence of the impact of barriers in the business environment such as

    costly and timely procedures to obtain licenses, register property and movable collateral,

    resolve disputes, and close a business (Doing Business, 2009) on private sector growth.

    17

  • Finally, we compare average job ows by sector (Figure 7). The most prominent ob-

    servation is that across all US all sectors, job growth is driven from incumbent expansion.

    While we continue to see similar patterns of job creation arising from rm entry and job

    destruction from rm exit, the dierence in dynamics is arising from job ows in expanding

    and contracting rms.

    5 Survival Model and Results

    The previous section highlights barriers in employment creation at existing incumbent rms.

    In order to better understand the barriers to growth, we begin by addressing the primary

    question of what determines rm survival. Understanding the factors that appear to most

    inuence rm survival is necessary to develop and implement policies that will improve and

    help rms better adapt and prepare for challenges and promote opportunities for growth.

    Our research aims to identify rm characteristics, such as sector and size, that predict

    greater vulnerability to business cycles and policy interventions. First, we examine the

    relationship between economic growth (measured by annual GDP growth rates) and rm

    survival. Next, we explore the impact of specic monetary, scal, and trade reforms on rm

    survival.

    5.1 Firm dynamics and reforms

    We begin by summarizing rm and job dynamics, relative to annual GDP growth and

    economic reforms. Figure 8, Panels A and B, show the absolute number and one-year

    growth rates of entering and exiting rms, by year, relative to one-year GDP growth. For

    most of the period, we nd that the formal private sector both gains and looses about 200

    rms per year, which is a growth and contraction rate equal to about 10%. This trend is

    surprisingly stable over time and macroeconomic conditions. Panel C shows the impact of

    policy reforms: Although GDP growth was relatively at during the reform periods, the

    18

  • trade and scal reforms led to a sharp decrease in the number of rms. In particular, the

    scal reform led to a relatively sharper decline in foreign-owned rms as political instability

    increased. In contrast, the monetary devaluation (and growth in GDP) was associated with

    an increase in new rm creation.

    Next, in Figure 9, Panels A and B, we look at changes in new employment at new and

    exited rms (Panel A) and jobs created and lost at incumbent rms (Panel B), relative

    to annual GDP growth. Over time, net employment is always positive, i.e. more jobs

    are created at new rms then lost at exiting rms. However, the absolute number of new

    jobs added to the private sector is remarkably small on average, fewer than 3,000 formal,

    private sector jobs are added on an annual basis. In comparison, the net number of new

    jobs generated at incumbent rms is negative for all years from 1979 through 1995. The

    largest net job losses occurred during the 1980 macroeconomic downturn over 10,000 jobs

    were shed in 1979 although net jobs at incumbent rms remained negative even during

    periods of GDP growth. Panel C shows that net employment at new/exited rms has

    little variation over our sample period, while employment at incumbent rms appears more

    sensitive to government reforms, in particular, the period following the introduction of scal

    reforms.

    Finally, Figure 10 shows net employment creation, by sector, relative to GDP and eco-

    nomic reforms. Interestingly, we nd dierent patterns across sectors, suggesting that eco-

    nomic and political shocks aect job creation and destruction dierently across sectors. For

    instance, employment in trade is relatively at, perhaps because these jobs are driven by

    external factors, while manufacturing jobs are most sensitive to macroeconomic uctuations

    and government interventions, which might reect their greater size and capital dependency.

    5.2 Survival test methodology

    Our comprehensive panel data allows us to study the rm-level determinants of rm survival.

    We estimate a discrete time duration model with time-varying covariates. The parametric

    19

  • specication we consider is a proportional hazard model with a piecewise constant baseline

    hazard. Specically, we use a baseline hazard with six parameters, j(j = 1; 2; 3; 4; 5; 6):

    one for each of the rst four three-year periods and one for the remaining years. We also

    accommodate unobserved individual heterogeneity with the inclusion of a multiplicative

    error term in the hazard function, for which a gamma distribution with mean 1 and variance

    2 is assumed.

    The hazard function for rm i in period t is specied as being proportional to:

    exp(f(Zi;Wt; Xit));

    where Wt is a vector of macroeconomic variables and reform dummies, Zi is a vector that

    includes dummies for rm sector, initial size, location, and owner, and Xit is a vector of

    individual time varying characteristics of the rm, including current number of employees.

    For rm i we dene it as the elapsed duration since the rms birth in period t and let

    Ti be the duration of the spell. Under the assumption of a proportional hazard model with

    a piecewise constant baseline hazard and unobserved heterogeneity, the hazard function can

    be expressed by:

    (itjZi;Wt; Xit; vi) = re exp(f(Zi;Wt; Xit))vi;

    where vi is the unobserved component for rm i and re = j for it 5 and it = 6 for

    it 6: Standard results imply that the survival function for Ti can be written as:

    S(TijZi;Wt; Xit; vi) = exp(vi

    T rXt=1

    re exp(f(Zi;Wt; Xit))

    ):

    Thus the contribution to the log-likelihood function from item i can be written as:

    ln(Li) = ln[S(Ti 1jZi;Wt; Xit) &iS(TijZi;Wt; Xit)];

    20

  • where &i is a dummy variable which equals 1 for completed spells and 0 for (right) censored

    events.

    5.3 Results

    Table 1 shows summary statistics of our dependent and explanatory variables. Our depen-

    dent variable is a dummy (0/1), equal to one in the rst year that the rm exits from the

    sample, and equal to zero otherwise. On average, rms in our sample survive 6.6 years.

    We include a series of rm characteristics as our dependent variables: First, we include a

    dummy for rms located in the Abidjan (capital) region, which includes 90% of the sample.

    Second, a dummy for foreign ownership is included, with 72% of rms being foreign owned.

    Third, we include sector dummies to indicate rms in the manufacturing (18%) or trade

    sectors (34%); we omit the service sector (49%). Finally we include size dummies to indicate

    a rms entrysize at the time of registration: small (46%), medium (35%), or large (9%);

    we omit the very largecategory (10%). Next, we include dummies indicating the three

    reform periods: trade (1985-1987), scal (1989-1990), and monetary (1994). Finally, we in-

    clude real annual GDP growth. In all specications we use leading GDP growth to address

    the concern of endogeneity arising from the largest rms contributing the most towards

    aggregate GDP (since rm exits occurs in the rst year after we no longer observe the rm).

    To summarize our baseline hazard function in our regressions, we consider domestically-

    owned rms located outside of the Abidjan commercial region, entering with at least 150

    employees, and operating in the service sector. A correlation matrix of the explanatory

    variables is shown in Table 2.

    Table 3 shows the determinants of rm exit, where a positive coe cient indicates a

    lower likelihood of survival. We do not nd any eect of operating in the capital and do

    not nd that survival rates vary by sector. However, we nd that foreign rms exit more

    frequently than domestically-owned rms, which might reect a higher voluntary exit rate

    among foreigner owners who are more sensitive to economic and political volatility. We also

    21

  • nd stark dierences in the exit rate of rms according to their initial size: the larger a

    rm is at entry, the less likely it is to exit. Next, we nd a signicant eect of declining

    GDP growth and lower survival rates. Finally, we nd that all reform periods are associated

    with higher exit rates; the scal reform had the largest impact on survival, followed by the

    monetary reform, and lastly the trade reform. In terms of economic signicance, the scal

    reform raised the probability of exit by 66%, the monetary reform raised the probability of

    exit by 40%, and the trade reform raised the probability of exit by 19%, all relative to the

    baseline hazard.

    Table 4 presents the impact of GDP growth on rm exit. We use interaction terms

    to test if macroeconomic growth had a dierential impact on the exit rate of rms across

    dierent sectors, ownership, and size. We nd that the business cycle has a marginal eect

    on only the manufacturing sector, relative to service sector rms (at the 10% level) and

    nd no marginal eect by rm ownership. However, we nd a strong eect of rm size:

    smaller rms entering with 10-49 or 50-149 employees are most exposed to economic

    downturns, relative to large rms entering with 150+ employees. This likely reects the

    added vulnerability of small rms to downturns in the business cycle.

    Finally, Table 5 examines the impact of government reforms on exit rates. From our

    initial set of results presented in Table 3 we know that all reforms increased the exit rate for

    rms, with the scal reform having the greatest impact. First, we nd that the manufactur-

    ing sector experienced relatively higher exit rates during the scal crisis; we hypothesize that

    this reects the larger, more capital intensive nature of rms in the industry. These results

    are in line with previous literature showing that rms with larger market capitalization are

    more politically connected, and uncertainty surrounding these political relationships can

    negatively impact rmsperformances (Faccio 2006 and 2007 and Fisman, 2001). Next, we

    nd that trade reform signicantly increased the probability of exit for rms operating in

    the tradable sector, relative to the service sector, which was expected given the removal of

    22

  • import quotas and increased competition facing the domestic economy. We nd no sector

    or size specica impact of the monetary reform.

    As a robustness check of our results, we estimate regression models using contempora-

    neous log employment levels instead of entry size dummies. While not reported here, the

    results are qualitatively similar.

    Finally, an interesting nding is the shape of the baseline hazard (Figure 11). Our esti-

    mates reveal an increasing baseline hazard function, which can be interpreted as suggesting

    that that the probability of exit increases as the rm ages over time. This result is somewhat

    surprising and counterintuitive, given that rms observed in developed countries exhibit an

    increasing probability of survival as they age (see, for example, Audretsch and Mahmood,

    1995 and Holmes et al., 2008). Furthermore, we do not observe an inection point where age

    begins to increase the probability of survival, suggesting that rm vulnerability to exiting

    does not decrease over time. It might be the case that rms become more visibleas they

    age, which makes it more di cult to avoid costly operating and labor regulations.

    6 Conclusion

    We study rm dynamics using a database of all formally registered rms in Cote dIvoire

    from 1977-1997, which account for about 60% of GDP. During this period, Cote dIvoire

    experienced (separate) episodes of trade reform, scal reform, and monetary reform, and

    we examine the impact of these shocks on private sector dynamics. First, we examine entry

    and exit patterns over this period and the role of new and exiting rms versus incumbents

    in job creation and destruction.

    Next, we examine survival rates and nd that survival increases monotonically with size.

    Furthermore, higher GDP growth increases survival rates, and periods of economic growth

    have the largest impact on the reduction in the exit rates of small rms, relative to large

    rms. Finally, we nd that all reforms decreased rm survival.

    23

  • A comparison of business patterns in the U.S. and Cote dIvoire highlights the need to

    encourage and inspire greater experimentation and innovation among African entrepreneurs.

    Start-up rms in the U.S. generally enter small and face low survival rates, but those that do

    survive grow and create new jobs, displacing those rms that do not innovate. Improvements

    in the institutional environment such as easing rm entry and closure might promote

    greater risk taking and high growth entrepreneurship.

    7 References

    1. Audretsch, D. B. and T. Mahmood. 1995. New rm survival: new results using a

    hazard function. Review of Economics and Statistics 77(1): 97-103.

    2. Audretsch, D. B. and Z. J. Acs. 1994. New-rm startups, technology, and macroeco-

    nomic uctuations. Small Business Economics 6: 439-449.

    3. Bartelsman, E. J., J. Haltiwanger, and S. Scarpetta, 2009. Cross country dierences

    in productivity: the role of allocative e ciency. University of Maryland, Department

    of Economics, mimeo.

    4. Bartelsman, E. J., J. Haltiwanger, and S. Scarpetta. 2004. Microeconomic evidence

    of creative destruction in industrial and developing countries. World Bank Policy

    Research Working Paper No. 3464.

    5. Beck, T., A. Demirguc-Kunt, and R. Levine. 2005. SMEs, growth, and poverty:

    cross-country evidence. Journal of Economic Growth 10(3): 199-229.

    6. Boeri, T. and L. Bellmann. 1995. Post-entry behavior and the cycle: evidence from

    Germany. International Journal of Industrial Organization 13(4): 483-500.

    7. Caves, R. E. 1998. Industrial organization and new ndings on the turnover and

    mobility of rms. Journal of Economic Literature 36(4): 1947-1982.

    24

  • 8. Davis, S., J. Haltiwanger, and S. Schuh. 1994. Small Business and Job Creation:

    Dissecting the Myth and Reassessing the Facts. Labor Markets, Employment Policy,

    and Job Creation, Westview Press.

    9. Desai, M., Gompers, P., Lerner, J., 2003. Institutions, capital constraints and entre-

    preneurial rm dynamics: Evidence from Europe. NBER Working Paper No. 10165.

    10. Dunne, T., M. J. Roberts, and L. Samuelson. 1988. Patterns of rm entry and exit

    in U.S. manufacturing industries. RAND Journal of Economics 19(4): 495-515.

    11. Faccio, M. 2007. The characteristics of politically connected rms. Krannert School

    of Management, Purdue University, Working Paper No. 2007-006.

    12. Faccio, M. 2006. Politically connected rms. American Economic Review 96(1): 369-

    386.

    13. Fisman, R. 2001. Estimating the value of political connections. American Economic

    Review 91(4): 1095-1102.

    14. Gertler, M. and S. Gilchrist. 1994. Monetary policy, business cycles, and the behavior

    of small manufacturing rms. Quarterly Journal of Economics 109(2): 309-340.

    15. Haltiwanger, J., R. Jarmin, and J. Miranda. 2009. Who creates jobs? Small vs. large

    vs. young. University of Maryland, Department of Economics, mimeo.

    16. Haltiwanger, J., R. Jarmin, and J. Miranda. 2008. Business formation and dynamics

    by business age: results from the Business Demography Statistics. US Census Bureau,

    mimeo.

    17. Harding, A., M. Sderbom, and F. Teal. 2004. Survival and success among African

    manufacturing rms. Centre for Study of African Economies Working Paper No.

    2004-05.

    25

  • 18. Harrison, A. E. 1994. Productivity, imperfect competition, and trade reform: theory

    and evidence. Journal of International Economics 36: 53-73.

    19. Holmes, P., I. Stone, and P. Braidford. 2008. An analysis of new rm survival using

    a hazard function. Applied Economics, forthcoming.

    20. Klapper, L., R. Amit, and M. Guillen. 2008. Entrepreneurship and rm formation

    across countries. NBER Volume on International Dierences in Entrepreneurship, J.

    Lerner and A. Schoar, eds., University of Chicago Press.

    21. Klapper, L., L. Laeven, and R. Rajan. 2006. Entry regulation as a barrier to entre-

    preneurship. Journal of Financial Economics 82(3): 591-629.

    22. Levinsohn, J. 1999. Employment responses to international liberalization in Chile.

    Journal of International Economics 47(2): 321-444.

    23. Library of Congress Country Studies. 1988. Cote dIvoire. Washington, DC: Library

    of Congress.

    24. Mata, J. and P. Portugal. 1994. Life duration of new rms. Journal of Industrial

    Economics 42(3): 227-245.

    25. Mead, D. C. and C. Liedholm. 1998. The dynamics of micro and small enterprises in

    developing countries. World Development 26(1): 61-74.

    26. OECD. 2004. African Economic Outlook 2003/2004, Cote dIvoire. Paris: OECD,

    African Development Bank.

    27. Reuda-Sabater, E. and A. Stone. 1992. Cte dIvoire: private sector dynamics and

    constraints. World Bank Policy Research Working Paper No. 1047.

    28. Scarpetta, S., P. Hemmings, T. Tressel, and J. Woo. 2002. The role of policy and

    institutions for productivity and rm dynamics: evidence from micro and industry

    data. OECD Economics Department Working Paper No. 329.

    26

  • 29. Schneider, F. and D. Enste, 2000. Shadow economies: Size, causes and consequences.

    Journal of Economic Literature, 38(1): 77-114.

    30. Sleuwaegen, L. and M. Goedhuys. 2002. Growth of rms in developing countries,

    evidence from Cte DIvoire. Journal of Development Economics 68: 117-135.

    31. Trebesch, C. 2008. Delays in debt restructurings. Should we really blame the credi-

    tors? Free University of Berlin, mimeo.

    32. Tuinder, B. A. den. 1978. Ivory Coast, the challenge of success: report of a mission

    sent to the Ivory Coast by the World Bank. Baltimore, MD: The Johns Hopkins

    University Press.

    33. Tybout, J. 2000. Manufacturing rms in developing countries: how well do they do,

    and why? Journal of Economic Literature 38(1): 11-44.

    34. World Bank. 2009. Doing Business, 2009. Available from http://www.doingbusiness.org

    27

  • Figure 1: Comparison of Total Employment and umber of Firms, 1977-1997

    Panel A: Cote dIvoire

    1,000

    1,200

    1,400

    1,600

    1,800

    2,000

    2,200

    -

    20,000

    40,000

    60,000

    80,000

    100,000

    120,000

    140,000

    160,000

    77 78 79 80 81 82 83 84 85 86 87 88 89 90 91 92 93 94 95 96

    Number of Firms

    Number of Employees

    Total Employees Total Firms

    Source: Cote dIvoire Centrale de Bilans des Entreprises, 1977-1997.

    Panel B: U.S.

    4,000

    4,500

    5,000

    5,500

    6,000

    6,500

    -

    20,000

    40,000

    60,000

    80,000

    100,000

    120,000

    77 78 79 80 81 82 83 84 85 86 87 88 89 90 91 92 93 94 95 96 97

    Number of Firms

    (thousands)

    Number of Employees

    (thousands)

    Total Employees Total Firms

    Source: US Census Bureau's Longitudinal Business Database, 1977-1997.

  • Figure 2: Comparison of Firm Size Buckets, Average 1977-1997

    Panel A: Cote dIvoire

    40%

    40%

    12%

    8%

  • Figure 3: Comparison of umber of Firms and Employment, by Sector,

    Average 1977-1997

    Panel A: Cote dIvoire

    49%

    34%

    17%

    Distribution of Firms

    service

    trade

    manufacturing

    37%

    17%

    46%

    Distribution of Employment

    service

    trade

    manufacturing

    Panel B: U.S.

    50%

    40%

    10%

    Distribution of Firms

    service

    trade

    manufacturing

    40%

    29%

    31%

    Distribution of Employment

    service

    trade

    manufacturing

    Source: Cote dIvoire Centrale de Bilans des Entreprises, 1977-1997 and the U.S. Census Bureaus Longitudinal

    Business Database.

  • Figure 4: Comparison of Firm Size Buckets, by Sector, Average 1977-1997

    Panel A: Manufacturing Sector

    44%

    29%

    6%

    21%

  • Figure 5: Comparison of Firm Dynamics, 1978-1997

    Panel A: Average Entry Rates

    0%

    5%

    10%

    15%

    20%

    78 79 80 81 82 83 84 85 86 87 88 89 90 91 92 93 94 95 96 97

    Cote d'Ivoire

    United States

    Panel B: Average Turnover Rates

    0%

    10%

    20%

    30%

    40%

    78 79 80 81 82 83 84 85 86 87 88 89 90 91 92 93 94 95 96

    Cote d'Ivoire

    United States

    Panel C: Average Survival Rates, 1978-1995

    70%

    75%

    80%

    85%

    90%

    95%

    78 79 80 81 82 83 84 85 86 87 88 89 90 91 92 93 94 95

    Cote d'Ivoire

    United States

    Source: Cote dIvoire Centrale de Bilans des Entreprises, 1977-1997 and the U.S. Census Bureaus

    Longitudinal Business Database.

  • Figure 6: Comparison of Employment Dynamics, Average 1978 1997

    Panel A: Average Job Creation and Destruction Rates

    Panel B: Average !umber of Employees, !ormalized to 100%

    Source: Cote dIvoire Centrale de Bilans des Entreprises, 1977-1997 and the U.S. Census Bureaus

    Longitudinal Business Database.

    0%

    4%

    8%

    12%

    16%

    20%

    Cote d'Ivoire US Cote d'Ivoire US

    Job Destruction Job Creation

    Exit Exit Entry Entry

    Contraction Contraction Expansion Expansion

    0%

    20%

    40%

    60%

    80%

    100%

    Cote d'Ivoire US Cote d'Ivoire US

    Job Destruction Job Creation

    Exit

    Exit Entry Entry

    Contraction Contraction Expansion Expansion

  • Figure 7: Comparison of Employment Dynamics, by Sector, Average 1978 1997

    Panel A: Manufacturing

    Panel B: Services

    Panel C: Trade

    0%

    4%

    8%

    12%

    16%

    20%

    Cote d'Ivoire US Cote d'Ivoire US

    Job Destruction Job Creation

    Exit Exit

    EntryEntry

    Contraction

    Contraction

    Expansion

    Expansion

    0%

    4%

    8%

    12%

    16%

    20%

    Cote d'Ivoire US Cote d'Ivoire US

    Job Destruction Job Creation

    Exit Exit Entry Entry

    Contraction Contraction Expansion Expansion

    0%

    4%

    8%

    12%

    16%

    20%

    Cote d'Ivoire US Cote d'Ivoire US

    Job Destruction Job Creation

    Exit ExitEntry

    Entry

    Contraction

    Contraction

    Expansion

    Expansion

  • Figure 8: Cote DIvoire Firm Dynamics, GDP Growth, and Economic Reforms

    Panel A: !umber of Firms and GDP Growth

    -15

    -10

    -5

    0

    5

    10

    15

    0

    50

    100

    150

    200

    250

    300

    350

    78 79 80 81 82 83 84 85 86 87 88 89 90 91 92 93 94 95 96

    GDP growth (annual %)

    Number of Firms

    Entry Exit GDP growth (annual %)

    Panel B: Growth in !umber of Firms and GDP Growth

    -15

    -10

    -5

    0

    5

    10

    15

    0%

    5%

    10%

    15%

    20%

    78 79 80 81 82 83 84 85 86 87 88 89 90 91 92 93 94 95 96

    GDP growth (annual %)

    Annual Growth (%)

    Entry Rates Exit Rates GDP growth (annual %)

    Panel C: !et !ew Firms and Economic Reforms

    -150

    -100

    -50

    0

    50

    100

    150

    78 79 80 81 82 83 84 85 86 87 88 89 90 91 92 93 94 95 96

    # of firm

    s

    Source: Cote dIvoire Centrale de Bilans des Entreprises, 1977-1997.

    Trade Fiscal Monetary

  • Figure 9:Cote DIvoire Job Dynamics, GDP Growth and Economic Reforms

    Panel A: !umber of Jobs Created at !ew Firms and Lost at Exiting Firms

    and GDP Growth

    -15

    -10

    -5

    0

    5

    10

    15

    -

    5,000

    10,000

    15,000

    20,000

    25,000

    78 79 80 81 82 83 84 85 86 87 88 89 90 91 92 93 94 95 96

    GDP growth (annual %)

    Job Creation/Destruction

    Jobs created at new firms Jobs lost at exiting firms GDP growth (annual %)

    Panel B: !umber of Jobs Created and Lost at Incumbent Firms and GDP Growth

    -15

    -10

    -5

    0

    5

    10

    15

    -

    5,000

    10,000

    15,000

    20,000

    25,000

    78 79 80 81 82 83 84 85 86 87 88 89 90 91 92 93 94 95 96

    GDP growth (annual %)

    Job Creation/Destruction

    Jobs created at incumbent firms Jobs lost at incumbent firms GDP growth (annual %)

    Panel C: !et Employment at Incumbent and !ew/Exit Firms and Economic Reforms

    0

    2000

    4000

    6000

    8000

    10000

    -18000

    -12000

    -6000

    0

    6000

    12000

    78 79 80 81 82 83 84 85 86 87 88 89 90 91 92 93 94 95 96

    Net Employment

    Incumbants Entry/Exit

    Source: Cote dIvoire Centrale de Bilans des Entreprises, 1977-1997.

    Trade Fiscal Monetary

  • Figure 10: et Employment Growth, GDP Growth, and Economic Reforms,

    by Sector, 1978-1997

    Panel A: Manufacturing

    -0.04

    -0.035

    -0.03

    -0.025

    -0.02

    -0.015

    -0.01

    -0.005

    0

    -15%

    -10%

    -5%

    0%

    5%

    10%

    15%

    78 79 80 81 82 83 84 85 86 87 88 89 90 91 92 93 94 95 96 97

    Manufacturing

    GDP

    Panel B: Services

    -0.04

    -0.035

    -0.03

    -0.025

    -0.02

    -0.015

    -0.01

    -0.005

    0

    -15%

    -10%

    -5%

    0%

    5%

    10%

    15%

    78 79 80 81 82 83 84 85 86 87 88 89 90 91 92 93 94 95 96 97

    Services GDP

    Panel C: Trade

    -0.04

    -0.035

    -0.03

    -0.025

    -0.02

    -0.015

    -0.01

    -0.005

    0

    -15%

    -10%

    -5%

    0%

    5%

    10%

    15%

    78 79 80 81 82 83 84 85 86 87 88 89 90 91 92 93 94 95 96 97

    Trade GDP

    Source: Cote dIvoire Centrale de Bilans des Entreprises, 1977-1997.

    Trade Fiscal Monetary

  • Figure 11: Baseline Hazard Function

    0

    0.02

    0.04

    0.06

    0.08

    0.1

    0.12

    0.14

    0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20

    baseline hazard rate

    # years since entry

  • Table 1: Variables and Summary Statistics

    Variable Definition Mean

    Survival Age of firm when it dies (in years)

    6.66

    Abidjan Dummy (0/1), =1 if the firm is located in the Abidjan (capital) region, =0

    otherwise

    0.90

    Foreign_owned Dummy (0/1), =1 if the firm is foreign owned, =0 if the firm is

    domestically owned

    0.72

    Service Dummy (0/1), =1 if the firm operates in the service sector, =0 otherwise

    0.49

    Trade Dummy (0/1), =1 if the firm operates in the trade sector, =0 otherwise

    0.34

    Manufacturing Dummy (0/1), =1 if the firm operates in the trade sector, =0 otherwise

    0.18

    Entry_small Dummy (0/1), =1 if the firm enters operation with less than 10

    employees, =0 otherwise

    0.46

    Entry_ medium Dummy (0/1), =1 if the firm enters operation with 10-49 employees, =0

    otherwise

    0.35

    Entry_ large Dummy (0/1), =1 if the firm enters operation with 50-149 employees, =0

    otherwise

    0.09

    Entry_very large Dummy (0/1), =1 if the firm enters operation with 150+ employees, =0

    otherwise

    0.10

    Reform_trade Dummy 0/1, =1 in 1985-1987, the years during which trade reform was

    undertaken

    0.16

    Reform_fiscal Dummy 0/1, =1 in 1989 and 1990, the years during which fiscal/political

    reform was undertaken

    0.10

    Reform_monetary Dummy 0/1, =1 in 1994, the year during which monetary reform was

    undertaken

    0.05

    GDP_growth Real one-year GDP growth

    1.50

  • Table 2: Correlation Matrix

    Note: Asterisk indicates significance at the 5% level.

    (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) (10) (11) (12)

    Abidjan (1) 1.0000

    Foreign_owned (2) -0.0391* 1.0000

    Service (3) -0.1083* 0.0490* 1.0000

    Manufacturing (4) 0.0687* 0.0334* -0.4445* 1.0000

    Trade (5) 0.0590* -0.0783* -0.6970* -0.3325* 1.0000

    Entry_small (6) -0.0028 -0.0458* 0.0846* -0.2547* 0.1148* 1.0000

    Entry_medium (7) -0.0224* 0.0273* -0.0554* 0.0703* 0.002 -0.6776* 1.0000

    Entry_large (8) -0.0149* 0.0265* -0.0767* 0.1816* -0.0646* -0.2848* -0.2300* 1.0000

    Entry_very large (9) 0.0396* -0.0037 -0.0719* 0.2041* -0.0877* -0.2379* -0.1921* -0.0807* 1.0000

    Reform_trade (10) 0.0068 0.0179* 0.0095 -0.0064 -0.0049 0.0081 -0.0001 -0.0087 -0.0073 1.0000

    Reform_monetary (11) -0.0050 -0.0414* -0.0151* 0.0062 0.0109* 0.0291* -0.0126* -0.0081 -0.0118* -0.0968* 1.0000

    Reform_fiscal (12) -0.0082 -0.0092 -0.0014 -0.0035 0.0043 0.0135* -0.0010 -0.0068 -0.0076 -0.1429* -0.0742* 1.0000

    GDP_growth (13) -0.0108* -0.0405* -0.0238* 0.0119* 0.0155* 0.0148* -0.0078 0.0022 -0.0035 -0.0170* 0.2846* -0.1530*

  • Table 3: Survival Model: Determinants of Firm Exit

    This table reports estimates using a discrete time-duration model with time-varying covariates The

    dependent variables in all models is a dummy (0/1) equal to one in the first year that the firm exits from the

    sample, and equal to zero otherwise. Explanatory variables are defined in Table 1. Standard errors are

    shown below, ***, **, * indicate significance at the 1%, 5%, and 10% level, respectively.

    (1) (2) (3)

    Coeff S.E. Coeff S.E. Coeff S.E.

    Abidjan -0.014 0.082 -0.020 0.080 -0.012 0.077

    Foreign_owned 0.266 0.058 *** 0.255 0.057 *** 0.261 0.055 ***

    Manufacture 0.006 0.077 0.006 0.075 -0.008 0.073

    Trade -0.039 0.057 -0.041 0.055 -0.049 0.053

    Entry_small 1.683 0.132 *** 1.650 0.130 *** 1.541 0.127 ***

    Entry_medium 0.956 0.124 *** 0.938 0.121 *** 0.872 0.118 ***

    Entry_large 0.502 0.157 *** 0.483 0.153 *** 0.441 0.148 ***

    GDP_growth -0.016 0.004 *** -0.015 0.004 ***

    Reform_trade 0.176 0.051 ***

    Reform_fiscal 0.509 0.054 ***

    Reform_monetary 0.337 0.080 ***

    Constant -2.160 0.212 *** -2.176 0.207 *** -2.359 0.202 ***

    1 -1.053 0.207 *** -0.986 0.204 *** -0.826 0.200 ***

    2 -0.876 0.171 *** -0.859 0.169 *** -0.728 0.165 ***

    3 -0.628 0.144 *** -0.623 0.142 *** -0.548 0.140 ***

    4 -0.434 0.127 *** -0.432 0.125 *** -0.476 0.126 ***

    5 -0.138 0.112 -0.157 0.111 -0.277 0.113 **

    Gamma variance 1.168 1.077 0.960

    # Observations 36529 36529 36529

  • Table 4: Survival Model: The Impact of GDP Growth

    This table reports estimates using a discrete time-duration model with time-varying covariates The

    dependent variables in all models is a dummy (0/1) equal to one in the first year that the firm exits from the

    sample, and equal to zero otherwise. Explanatory variables are defined in Table 1. Standard errors are

    shown below, ***, **, * indicate significance at the 1%, 5%, and 10% level, respectively.

    (1) (2) (3)

    Coeff S.E. Coeff S.E. Coeff S.E.

    Abidjan -0.020 0.080 -0.019 0.080 -0.019 0.080

    Foreign_owned 0.255 0.057 *** 0.256 0.058 *** 0.258 0.057 ***

    Manufacture 0.006 0.075 0.026 0.076 0.004 0.076

    Trade -0.041 0.055 -0.032 0.056 -0.041 0.056

    Entry_small 1.650 0.130 *** 1.650 0.130 *** 1.679 0.13 ***

    Entry_medium 0.938 0.121 *** 0.937 0.121 *** 0.984 0.12 ***

    Entry_large 0.483 0.153 *** 0.481 0.153 *** 0.539 0.16 ***

    GDP_growth -0.016 0.004 *** -0.010 0.009 0.013 0.016

    GDP_growth*foreign 0.000 0.009

    GDP_growth*manufacture -0.019 0.011 *

    GDP_growth*trade -0.009 0.008

    GDP_growth*small -0.022 0.017

    GDP_growth* medium

    -0.042 0.017 **

    GDP_growth*large -0.053 0.022 **

    Constant -2.176 0.207 *** -2.177 0.207 *** -2.192 0.209 ***

    1 -0.986 0.204 *** -0.991 0.204 *** -1.007 0.203 ***

    2 -0.859 0.169 *** -0.865 0.169 *** -0.879 0.169 ***

    3 -0.623 0.142 *** -0.628 0.142 *** -0.638 0.142 ***

    4 -0.432 0.125 *** -0.436 0.125 *** -0.443 0.125 ***

    5 -0.157 0.111 -0.162 0.111 -0.164 0.111

    Gamma variance 1.077 1.077 1.088

    # Observations 36529 36529 36529

  • Table 5: Survival Model: The Impact of Government Reforms

    This table reports estimates using a discrete time-duration model with time-varying covariates The

    dependent variables in all models is a dummy (0/1) equal to one in the first year that the firm exits from the

    sample, and equal to zero otherwise. Explanatory variables are defined in Table 1. Standard errors are

    shown below, ***, **, * indicate significance at the 1%, 5%, and 10% level, respectively.

    (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) Coeff S.E. Coeff S.E. Coeff S.E. Coeff S.E. Coeff S.E. Coeff S.E.

    Abidjan -0.012 0.077 -0.012 0.077 -0.012 0.077 -0.013 0.077 -0.013 0.077 -0.012 0.077 Foreign_owned 0.270 0.062 *** 0.262 0.055 *** 0.260 0.055 *** 0.260 0.055 *** 0.261 0.055 *** 0.261 0.055 *** Manufacture -0.007 0.073 -0.054 0.081 -0.057 0.059 -0.050 0.053 -0.050 0.053 -0.049 0.053 Trade -0.048 0.053 -0.049 0.054 -0.008 0.073 -0.009 0.072 -0.009 0.073 -0.008 0.073 Entry_small 1.541 0.127 *** 1.544 0.128 *** 1.539 0.127 *** 1.553 0.128 *** 1.537 0.127 *** 1.540 0.127 *** Entry_medium 0.872 0.118 *** 0.872 0.118 *** 0.870 0.118 *** 0.862 0.118 *** 0.844 0.121 *** 0.871 0.118 *** Entry_large 0.441 0.148 *** 0.444 0.149 *** 0.440 0.148 *** 0.434 0.148 *** 0.439 0.148 *** 0.478 0.153 *** GDP_growth -0.015 0.004 *** -0.015 0.004 *** -0.015 0.004 *** -0.015 0.004 *** -0.015 0.004 *** -0.015 0.004 *** Reform_trade 0.249 0.097 *** 0.154 0.054 *** 0.122 0.062 ** 0.189 0.079 ** 0.167 0.059 *** 0.185 0.051 *** Reform_fiscal 0.465 0.103 *** 0.470 0.058 *** 0.551 0.065 *** 0.611 0.082 *** 0.461 0.064 *** 0.512 0.055 *** Reform_monetary 0.359 0.130 *** 0.373 0.085 *** 0.345 0.098 *** 0.362 0.130 *** 0.331 0.092 *** 0.338 0.092 *** Reform_trade*foreign -0.095 0.110 Reform_fiscal*foreign 0.061 0.118 Reform_monetary*foreign -0.034 0.160 Reform_trade*manufacture 0.151 0.132 Reform_fiscal*manufacture 0.279 0.141 ** Reform_monetary*manufacture -0.247 0.226 Reform_trade*trade 0.156 0.098 * Reform_fiscal*trade -0.124 0.109 Reform_monetary*trade -0.020 0.159 Reform_trade*small -0.023 0.097 Reform_fiscal*small -0.171 0.105 * Reform_monetary*small -0.040 0.159 Reform_trade*medium 0.029 0.101 Reform_fiscal* medium 0.153 0.109 Reform_monetary* medium 0.023 0.172 Reform_trade*large -0.236 0.227 Reform_fiscal*large -0.071 0.223 Reform_monetary*large -0.001 0.170 Constant -2.367 0.202 *** -2.340 0.202 *** -2.356 0.202 *** -2.386 0.203 *** -2.356 0.201 *** -2.365 0.201 ***

    1 -0.826 0.200 *** -0.841 0.200 *** -0.823 0.199 *** -0.801 0.201 *** -0.817 0.200 *** -0.821 0.199 *** 2 -0.727 0.166 *** -0.741 0.166 *** -0.726 0.165 *** -0.709 0.167 *** -0.721 0.166 *** -0.723 0.17 *** 3 -0.549 0.140 *** -0.558 0.140 *** -0.544 0.140 *** -0.536 0.141 *** -0.544 0.140 *** -0.544 0.140 *** 4 -0.476 0.126 *** -0.487 0.126 *** -0.478 0.126 *** -0.471 0.127 *** -0.475 0.126 *** -0.464 0.126 *** 5 -0.277 0.113 ** -0.291 0.113 *** -0.278 0.113 ** -0.294 0.114 *** -0.282 0.113 ** -0.272 0.113 ** Gamma variance 0.959 0.967 0.958 0.940 0.953 0.959 # Observations 36529 36529 36529 36529 36529 36529