pay spread and skewness,employee effort and firm productivity

Upload: marhelun

Post on 02-Apr-2018

223 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

  • 7/27/2019 Pay Spread and Skewness,Employee Effort and Firm Productivity

    1/25

  • 7/27/2019 Pay Spread and Skewness,Employee Effort and Firm Productivity

    2/25

    2

    1 Introduction

    Incomplete contracts and dysfunctional responses have been important elements in the

    growing literature on the internal labour economics of the firm.1 Workers focus on

    rewarded aspects of performance, in particular those that are measurable. Since

    contracts incompletely specify desired worker behaviour, agents respond to objective

    contracts for private benefit, which may be harmful to the employer. Multitask agency

    models have extended this earlier literature to allow workers several instruments.Multi-dimensional effort gives agents greater scope to game a compensation system

    to their private advantage. Rank-order tournaments are a setting where agents

    compete against each other for fixed prizes. They provide a simple structure, which

    can be extended to incorporate aspects of incomplete contracts and multitask agency.

    Tournament theory provides many testable predictions, which articulate that in certain

    contexts weak incentives may be more effective in eliciting desired performance than

    high powered, but dysfunctional ones.

    This paper tests several predictions from tournament theories of firm compensation

    structures, and thus, adds to the rather small empirical literature on theories of

    organizational hierarchies and pay structures.2 Previous studies have primarily been

    concerned with special groups of employees, and managerial workers in particular.

    Moreover, most previous studies have tested only a few theoretical predictions at one

    time. As emphasized by Prendergast (1999), the literature suffers from empirical

    identification problems, as many empirical outcomes are consistent with several

    competing theories and distinguishing between them is difficult. Care is taken to

    discuss alternative non-tournament behaviour also consistent with the data. The

    burden of proof is somewhat greater than other studies in that firstly we examine

    different parts of firms where tournaments as well as other theories should bedifferentially evident, and secondly we consider both individual and collective

    effort/performance measures for which theories predict distinct outcomes.

    There are three novelties distinguishing this from previous empirical tournament

    studies as well as other analyses of the relationship between wage dispersion and

    productivity. First, evidence is sought for tournaments in the whole pay distribution of

    firms in terms of several outcome measures, which allow testing of common and

    distinctive theoretical predictions.3 Second, predictions are examined from multi-task

    1 See Gibbons and Waldman (1999) for a survey.

    2 Prendergast (1999) provides a recent review.

    3 To our knowledge the only other paper looking at tournaments and the whole pay structure of firms isWinter-Ebmer and Zweimller (1999). However, they do not use conventional corporate or individualperformance measures, but proxy them by wage level. This obviously leads to intractable simultaneityproblems in the relation between pay spread and pay level.

  • 7/27/2019 Pay Spread and Skewness,Employee Effort and Firm Productivity

    3/25

  • 7/27/2019 Pay Spread and Skewness,Employee Effort and Firm Productivity

    4/25

    4

    The effort function is C = C(), with both first and second derivatives positive. The

    probability of winning depends positively on the players own effort and negatively

    on the competitors effort. Thus, the expected utility of player j is

    (2) p(W1 - C(j)) + (1-p) (W2 - C(j))

    where p is the probability of winning. The probability that j wins is then

    (3) prob (qi > qj) = prob (k - j) < (j - k) = prob ((j - k) > ) =

    H(j - k),

    where = k- j ; h(), H is the cumulative distribution function of and E()= 0.

    Each player maximizes (3) by choosing the effort level. Optimum conditions are:

    (4) (W1 W2)(p/i) - C/i = 0

    and

    (5) (W1 W2)(2 p/i

    2) - 2 C/i2 < 0

    In Nash equilibrium, j = k, and the outcome of the game is random:

    (6) (W1 W2) h(0) - C/i = 0

    Given (6) and assuming that firms maximize profits per worker, the optimum pay

    spread is:

    (7) (W1 W2)/2 = C()

    and

    (8) W1 W2 = h(0)-1

    According to equation (6), equilibrium effort is increasing in the prize spread. In the

    case with several positions (players), it can be shown that prize increment increases

    with higher prizes, or in other words, that the prize-position relationship is convex.

    Furthermore, from (6) and (8) it can be seen that the convexity increases as

    performance measurement becomes more noisy (i.e., h(0) decreases). Allowing for

    several players, the probability of winning obviously becomes smaller. How effort is

  • 7/27/2019 Pay Spread and Skewness,Employee Effort and Firm Productivity

    5/25

    5

    affected is examined by McLaughlin (1988), who shows that the prize spread is

    increasing in tournament size, that is, pay rises associated with promotions increase as

    the number of contestants grows. Another extension considered by Knoeber and

    Thurman (1994) is mixed and biased tournaments, that is when players know their

    own as well other players abilities. They demonstrate that mixed and biased

    tournaments reduce performance for the best contestants as well as other players.4

    Rosen (1986) extends the basic tournament model to account for dynamics by

    examining sequential elimination contests.5 Why do firms run sequential contests?

    One argument is that since rank is easier to observe than individual output, it is cost

    efficient to have winners play winners. In Rosens model career trajectories are the

    outcomes of competition among peers to attain higher rankings and better-paid jobs

    over the life cycle. The reward structure influences competition at each stage of the

    game. Since performance incentives at each stage include an option value on

    competing in all successive higher stages, it follows that in order to maintain

    incentives throughout the game, an extra reward is required for the overall winner

    (typically, the CEO). If players are risk averse, the incentive maintaining prize

    structure requires strictly increasing inter-rank pay spreads. Sequential eliminationcontests, therefore, give rise to skewed pay distributions. Consequently, in addition to

    pay spread, we should expect pay skewness to affect performance in compensation

    which is structured like a tournament.

    The original model of Lazear and Rosen (1981) and their followers was formulated in

    terms of one-dimensional effort. Lazear (1989) extends the rank-order tournament

    model to allow that in addition to productive effort (from the firms perspective),

    which furthers the agents, own success directly, the agent can also improve her own

    chances of success by non-productive effort (sabotage or lobbying to makecompetitors look bad) to induce rivals failure. This can easily be modeled by

    augmenting the players production and effort functions with a sabotage parameter, ,

    showing the harm inflicted on the other player. The first-order conditions for the

    employees maximization problem now become:

    (9) (W1 W2)(p/i) = C/i

    and

    4 Baker, Gibbons and Murphy (1994) is an example of another one-dimensional effort paper where thesocial and private optimum effort diverge, but in a non-tournament framework.

    5 In the working paper version, Lazear and Rosen (1979), of their 1982 article Lazear and Rosen had asection on sequential games. Rosen (1986) expands on this.

  • 7/27/2019 Pay Spread and Skewness,Employee Effort and Firm Productivity

    6/25

    6

    (W1 W2)(p/) = C/

    Without strategic behaviour the first-order conditions for the firms maximization

    problem are:

    (10) (1-(C/)) /W1 = 0

    and

    (1-(C/)) /W2 = 0,

    whereas in presence of strategic behaviour they are:

    (11) (1-(C/)) /W1 - (1 + (C/)) /W1 = 0

    and

    (12) (1-(C/)) /W2 - (1 + (C/)) /W2 = 0

    Since (C/) > 0, equilibrium effort is lower when players behave strategically

    against their competitors than when they do not. The optimum prize spread is smaller

    with sabotage than in the case where one worker cannot affect co-workers

    productivity. 6

    The employer is assumed to only observe total individual worker effort and cannot

    distinguish between effort, which is productive and unproductive. So individuals with

    the lowest cost of effort will be promoted, regardless of effort type. If there is a

    positive correlation between types of effort, i.e. productive individuals are also good

    saboteurs, then the population of tournament winners will over-represent good

    saboteurs (Lazear, 1989). Hence, saboteurs should be increasingly present higher up

    in the hierarchy as competitive or aggressive players rise to the top. Relative payment

    of higher-level workers is potentially quite damaging because of the greater degree of

    potentially counterproductive behaviour among that group. Optimum prize spread will

    be smaller at senior levels of the hierarchy since sabotage is of increasing relevance.

    Alternatively, relative comparisons between competitive workers should only be

    made where they cannot affect each others performance.7 Especially higher-level

    6 Other two-dimensional effort papers, which do not assume a tournament compensation structure, areItoh (1992) and Milgrom and Roberts (1988).

    7 See Carmichael and MacLeod (1993 and 2000) for empirical analyses of worker cooperation.

  • 7/27/2019 Pay Spread and Skewness,Employee Effort and Firm Productivity

    7/25

    7

    workers, who can be particularly counterproductive, need to be kept apart.8 This can

    be achieved for example by organising work by product rather than function. Firms,

    which replicate organisational structures at several distinct sites, keep managers apart.

    If there are only weak complementarities in production between managers then the

    incentive benefits of the greater pay spread which will be allowed if they are located

    separately may dominate. Thus, optimum pay spread is expected to be larger in multi-

    plant compared to single-plant firms.

    Allowing workers to affect the productivity of co-workers has implications for the

    structure of relative compensation and for organizational form. When it is not possible

    to keep competitive individuals apart, firms have to use less high-powered incentives

    by compressing pay dispersion for workers to compete with each other less

    aggressively in order to avoid counterproductive effort.9 It is simple to show that

    allowing multitasking in a sequential tournament leads to a similar counter-

    productivity result to that found in the repeated or one-shot tournament case, only

    now it is too much skewness which induces the wrong type of effort.10

    The important result of Lazear (1989) is that within relevant groups, some wagecompression is efficient. The efficiency argument does not need to appeal to notions

    of fairness, whereby workers own utility includes a term in co-workers utility, which

    is the key feature in fairness/reciprocity analyses. This literature typically builds on

    psychological research using experiments in game settings or survey investigations to

    postulate that firms and workers operate under a fairness constraint.11 Behavioral

    game theory, motivated by apparent anomalies for standard game theory, which are

    produced in experimental settings, has made progress analysing situations where

    players care about social allocations, fairness and perceived intentions of other

    players.12 If firms set wages for some workers below what is perceived as a fair level,their workers will respond by reducing effort.

    Three other arguments for why it may be socially advantageous to compress the wage

    structure have been suggested.13 The first is that reduced wage dispersion speeds up

    8 Milgrom (1988) and Holmstrm and Milgrom (1991) are related analyses outside a tournamentframework with similar implications for organisational design.

    9 Another multitask agency paper is Baker (1992) which is similar to Lazear (1989) in that contracting

    on a single agents value contribution is ruled out.10 By extension to Lazear (1989).

    11 Examples are Frank (1984), Akerlof and Yellen (1990) and Levine (1991a and 1991b).

    12 Rabin (1993) is an early discussion of fairness equilibria. Camerer (1997) gives a brief introductionto behavioural game theory.

    13 Agell (1999) provides an extended discussion.

  • 7/27/2019 Pay Spread and Skewness,Employee Effort and Firm Productivity

    8/25

    8

    the rate of structural change by eliminating low-productivity sectors or firms and

    subsidizing high-productivity performers. This is frequently referred to as a

    motivation for centralised wage bargaining.14 A second argument is that smaller pay

    differentials may provide incentives for skill formation as increased relative wages of

    unskilled workers leads to a reduced demand for them, wage compression creates

    incentives for schooling (Agell and Lommerud (1997) and Acemoglu and Pischke

    (1999)).A third rationale for wage compression is that it may act as a social insurance

    against changes in individuals relative position in the wage distribution (Agell and

    Lommerud (1992)).

    The applied gambling literature has long evidenced betting market inefficiency

    through long shot bias. This is the phenomenon of positive rates of return for hot

    favourites. Players are found to bet on long shots to a higher degree than justified by

    rates of return. Recently this apparent negative risk aversion has been rationalised by

    tastes for prize skewness.15

    It is useful to summarize the essential predictions from the tournament papers we have

    discussed, and contrast these with competing theories, so that they can be placed inthe context of our empirical work. In a one-shot tournament game between two

    players, it is the prize spread, which creates incentives for effort. Extending this to

    more players and more prizes, prize skewness is shown to be important. These results

    are carried over to repeated tournaments. However, in a sequential elimination

    tournament between two players, it is the option value of competing in future rounds

    of the tournament which leads to prize skewness rather than spread driving incentives.

    All of the prize spread and skewness results have to be moderated in a multi-task

    setting where more than one type of effort is allowed, to the effect that after a pointspread and skewness become net counter-productive. The type of behaviour induced

    depends, of course, on the incentive structure. However, in our empirical context we

    do not know exactly what game the agents are playing. Furthermore, it is certainly not

    explicitly set up as a rank-order tournament, especially for its own sake. But if some

    pay structures exhibit important tournament features, do workers act according to

    theory? Since we do not have access to narrowly defined job levels, we cannot

    establish whether workers are on a career track or in a dead end job 16, whether they

    14

    See Hibbs and Locking (2000) for an aggregate time-series analysis on Swedish data of productivityeffects.

    15 Golec and Tamarkin (1998) were the first to find tastes for skewness in betting markets, analysingthe apparent market inefficiency anomaly of long shot bias in horse race betting. Garret and Sobel(1999) find similar tastes for skewness among lotto players.

    16 Baker, Gibbs and Holmstrm (1994) and a number of followers describe careers in largecorporations. The promotion perspectives differ widely between jobs, and an interesting researchquestion is whether incentives are found to differ accordingly.

  • 7/27/2019 Pay Spread and Skewness,Employee Effort and Firm Productivity

    9/25

    9

    could be thought of as playing a sequential or repeated game, respectively. In practice

    we would expect to find a mixture of the two, and it is an empirical question which

    we shall be examining in this paper, whether incentives can explained accordingly.

    What predictions are common to tournaments, tastes for skewness and fairness

    theory? (1) Pay spread after a point reduces collective productivity for tournaments

    and fairness. Pay skewness increases collective productivity both in tournament and

    taste for skewness models. Although the recent applied gambling literature has not

    tested whether utility decreases in skewness after a point, casual evidence that most

    prize structures are not winner-takes-all would suggest that skewness too might also

    reduce collective productivity if it becomes high enough. (2) The effects of pay

    distribution in multi- versus single-plant firms may simply be a question of relevant

    reference group for calculating spread. The part of the within-firm between-worker

    pay spread which is between plants is irrelevant for fairness and makes sabotage more

    difficult in tournaments. (3) Different parts of the hierarchy may have different effects

    on productivity anyway, if there is a magnification effect of any behaviour at the top.

    This suggests that tournaments, fairness and tastes for skewness may be

    observationally equivalent.

    What prediction does tournament theory deliver that tastes for skewness and fairness

    theory do not? The Lazear (1989) model has essentially two different types of effort,

    only one of which is collectively counter-productive. Own private effort should not

    exhibit counter productive effects. Only tournament theory makes this distinction.

    3 Previous empirical research

    The empirical analysis of tournaments has followed two routes. One asks whether,given an explicit tournament reward structure, agents do respond as theory predicts.

    These studies have used either experimental data (Bull, Schotter and Weigelt, 1987)

    or data from sports (Ehrenberg and Bognano, 1990a and 1990b on golf). The only

    study of a business setting is Knoeber and Thurman (1994) who examine how a

    tournament compensation structure affects the behaviour of broiler chicken producers.

    The other approach asks whether tournament-like settings are associated with

    behaviour suggested by the theory and has primarily examined whether there is

    evidence of tournaments in the structure of top managers compensation. The earlystudies focused on only a few predictions (examples are OReilly, Main and Crystal

    (1989), Leonard (1990) and Lambert, Larcker and Weigelt (1993)), whereas two more

    recent papers, Main, OReilly and Wade (1993) and Eriksson (1999), have attempted

    to test a more comprehensive set of predictions. In the main, these studies have

    produced evidence indicating tournaments are present in the compensation of

    managerial employees. Thus, they as well as a number of other studies (for example

  • 7/27/2019 Pay Spread and Skewness,Employee Effort and Firm Productivity

    10/25

    10

    Conyon and Peck (1999)) find that the pay-job level relationship is convex. There is

    also support for the prediction that pay differentials increase with the number of

    contestants and/or declining promotion probabilities. However, the evidence on the

    effects of pay spread on firm performance is mixed. Leonard (1990) and Main,

    OReilly and Wade (1993) do not find that greater pay dispersion is associated with

    better company performance, whereas the results in Eriksson (1999) show a

    significantly positive, albeit quantitatively relatively weak, relationship between

    managerial pay spread and firm profitability.

    Three studies have been concerned with multi-task settings. Cowherd and Levine

    (1992) examine the determinants of customer-assessed quality in US and UK firms

    and find that pay differentials between managers and blue collar workers as well as

    within the management group reduce quality. Drago and Garvey (1998) use

    Australian workplace survey data and find that increased promotional incentives give

    rise to higher effort, as proxied by reduced absenteeism, and that a wider pay spread

    leads to more individual effort but less time spent on helping co-workers.

    In a recent study, Hibbs and Locking (2000) test for fairness amongst otherhypotheses on Swedish aggregate time-series data. They do not find that wage

    compression within workplaces or industries have had productivity enhancing effects.

    The authors do not discuss nor attempt to test predictions from tournament models.

    Although there seems to be some empirical support for tournament predictions in

    various settings, several limitations of the available evidence should be noticed. It is

    not very surprising that explicit tournament settings (like sports) give rise to predicted

    incentives. However, most labour contracts are considerably more complicated.

    Hence, the results from explicit tournament contexts may not necessarily apply tomany businesses. As pointed out by Prendergast (1999), outside sports, the empirical

    research on tournaments, and incentive schemes in general, has focused on agents,

    such as executives, whose output is easily observed.17 Again, the strength of the

    evidence of these studies seems limited, as it is obvious that most jobs are not like

    this. Furthermore, the literature is to some extent plagued by an observational

    equivalence problem in that many of the empirical outcomes studied are also

    consistent with alternative theories and setting up tests which discriminate between

    competing hypotheses is difficult. The burden of proof in this paper is somewhat

    heavier than in other studies. Firstly, we examine different parts of firms wheretournaments as well as other theories should be differentially evident. Secondly, we

    consider both individual and collective effort/performance measures for which

    theories predict distinct outcomes.

    17 An exception is Farrell (1996) on US law firm promotion tournaments.

  • 7/27/2019 Pay Spread and Skewness,Employee Effort and Firm Productivity

    11/25

    11

    4 Data description and empirical strategy

    Initial sample selection is the population of Danish private sector firms with 20 or

    more full-time equivalent employees during any year in the period 1992-95. These

    firms are kept for any year 1992-95 when they have 5 or more employees in each of

    three occupation groups: management, white collar non-managerial and blue collar.

    The resulting sample consists of 6,501 unique firms, each followed for on average 3.5

    years, yielding 22,665 firm-year observations.

    The important feature of the data is the link between firms and employees which is

    consistent over time. Our data originates from two separate registers maintained by

    Statistics Denmark: the integrated database for labour market research (IDA) and the

    business statistics database (BSD).18 While the matched registers contain a rich set of

    background variables, we have access to a subset for the current study, which are now

    described.

    Business statistics at the firm-year level include annual sales, wage bill, book value of

    capital, industry and municipality. Worker characteristics at the person-year level

    include gender, age, ongoing tenure, years of education, occupation, periods of

    absence, home municipality, annual labour earnings at the current employer and

    sufficient information to calculate income tax liability.

    A primary goal of the analysis is to establish a link between moments of the pay

    distribution within firms and firm-level outcomes of interest, and to evaluate whether

    this relation is as predicted by tournament theory. In particular, the paper focuses on

    the effect of pay spread and pay skewness on firm productivity and individual effort.

    The economic model of Section 2 gives guidance on construction of measures of thepay distribution. Regardless of whether efficiency, fairness or tastes for skewness are

    the causal links driving the relation between pay distribution moments and effort, it is

    the part of compensation which is due to unobserved characteristics which drives

    incentives, equality concerns or distributional tastes. Pay dispersion, all else equal, is

    relevantly defined only within an appropriate reference group. Ideally, the part of

    compensation which remains unexplained should be within precisely defined job

    levels, controlling for human capital. In the absence of narrowly defined job levels,

    we take three broad occupations within the same firm-year as relevant reference

    groups and control for gender, age, education, and tenure.

    Specifically, we run ordinary least squares (log) earnings equations on our sample of

    persons once and for all, and calculate the residuals. Summary statistics and

    18 It is the work of Sren Leth-Srensen and Claus W. Andersen in checking the consistency of thematch between IDA and BSD which makes this work possible.

  • 7/27/2019 Pay Spread and Skewness,Employee Effort and Firm Productivity

    12/25

    12

    regression coefficients are presented in Table 1. Descriptive statistics show that the

    sample of workers employed in medium-to-large establishments have age, education

    and tenure which is slightly higher than the population of private sector employees as

    a whole. Regression coefficients age and tenure are conventionally quadratic.

    Education is negative quadratic due to the inclusion of occupation dummy variables,

    and reverts to a conventional positive quadratic function if occupations are omitted.19

    The residuals are grouped according to occupation-firm-year cell, and for each cell,

    second and third moments of the residuals distribution are calculated.

    Table 1. Worker Descriptives and Earnings Equation Estimates (OLS)

    Variable Coefficient Std. Error Mean Std.dev.

    Intercept 9.209 0.007

    Male 0.287 0.001 0.689 0.462

    Age 0.123 0.000 36.401 12.177

    Age2 -0.001 0.000 1473.326 941.687

    Education -0.027 0.001 11.325 2.489

    Education2 0.003 0.000 134.446 56.520

    Tenure 0.096 0.000 4.898 4.016

    Tenure2 -0.005 0.000 40.111 55.591

    Manager 0.211 0.001 0.101

    Blue collar -0.110 0.001 0.583

    1992 0.013 0.001 0.245

    1993 -0.013 0.001 0.241

    1995 0.016 0.001 0.260

    Log(earnings) 12.179 0.709

    Absence 1.648 2.295

    R2 0.435

    # observations 2280607

    # persons 859574Notes: log (annual earnings) (2000 DKK) regression. Omited categories are white-collar non-

    managerial and 1994.

    We make use of two alternative performance measures: one measuring collective and

    the other individual effort. Solow residual measures of total factor productivity are the

    most widely used and accepted measures of firm productivity (Hulten, 2000). We

    assume a Cobb-Douglas production function and compute Solow residual productivity

    measures from that. Firm-wise descriptive statistics and production function estimates

    are presented in Table 2. The population of Danish firms with 20 or more employeescomprises somewhat smaller firms than elsewhere in the Nordic countries, Europe

    and the US. Business statistics on sales, wages and capital vary accordingly. Cobb-

    Douglas production function estimates exhibit conventional signs.

    19 Reference groups in the earnings regression are women, non-managerial white collar workers and theyear 1994.

  • 7/27/2019 Pay Spread and Skewness,Employee Effort and Firm Productivity

    13/25

    13

    Table 2. Firm Descriptives and Production Function Estimates (OLS)

    Variable Coefficient Std. Error Mean Std.dev.

    Intercept 6.896 0.038

    Log(capital) 0.375 0.003 8.462 1.707

    Log(wagesum) -0.356 0.005 9.104 0.943

    1992 -0.023 0.011 0.250

    1993 -0.066 0.011 0.250

    1995 0.022 0.011 0.250

    Log(sales/worker) 6.818 0.798

    Capital 15975 39327

    Wagesum 16109 27872

    sSles 84181 168159

    siSe 75 241

    R2 0.372

    # observations 22665

    # firms 6055

    Notes: log (annual sales) (2000 DKK) regression. Cobb-Douglas production function. 1994 is the

    omitted year

    For our measure of individual effort we follow Drago and Garvey (1998) and proxy

    effort by the inverse of the firms average rate of absenteeism. That is, we use the

    log(1-annual proportion of full-time equivalent days lost though absence) as a

    dependent variable. Tournament agency models require unobserved total effort.

    Absenteeism is only part of productive effort. Employers cannot base payment on that

    because of moral hazard problems of employees turning up for work when they are

    sick. Even though absenteeism is a noisy proxy for individual productive effort,

    employers not being able to contract on it, makes it a valid measure for testingtournament predictions.

    Having defined the outcomes of interest: collective productivity and individual (or

    collective productive) effort, and covariates of interest: moments of the pay residual

    distribution; we next turn to the primary analysis. The discussion of tournament

    theories in Section 2 focuses on the implications of moments of the relevant pay

    distribution for effort incentives. Specifically, productive effort is increasing in both

    pay spread and skewness up to a point, after which counterproductive behaviour

    dominates. This hypothesis can be tested in a regression framework as follows:

    (13) ft = 12ft + 22ft2 + 33ft + 43ft

    2 + Xft + f+ ft

    where ft is productivity of firmfin yeart,2 and 3 are second and third moments

    of the pay residual distribution within the firm-year, s are associated vectors of

  • 7/27/2019 Pay Spread and Skewness,Employee Effort and Firm Productivity

    14/25

    14

    coefficients, Xft is a matrix of exogenous characteristics, is an associated vector of

    coefficients, fis a firm-specific error term and ft is an idiosyncratic error term. The

    null hypothesis of the tournament models discussed is that the s are respectively

    positive, negative, positive and negative. However, this finding alone is consistent

    with non-tournament explanations of productivity, such as fairness concerns.

    Employees in different parts of the firm may exhibit differential productivity effects

    predicted by tournament theory. However, fairness arguments can be extended toallow magnified counter-productivity effects higher up the hierarchy, since managers

    behaviour has greater impact than that of other workers. Similar productivity

    magnification arguments can augment tastes for skewness predictions so that they also

    have an occupational distributional effect similar to tournaments.

    Moments are computed for three different levels in the occupational hierarchy --

    managers, non-managerial white-collar workers and blue-collar workers -- within

    each firm-year. Equation (13) is then estimated separately for each occupation group.

    The productivity measure is always at the firm-year level since we are unable toallocate productivity between different occupations.

    A major empirical problem facing all observational studies of the effect of pay on

    firm performance is simultaneity. That is, firms which perform well may pass product

    market rents on to top managers, or their employees in general. However, it may not

    be the case that firms where top managers contracts have such a structure are

    necessarily those which perform well. Failure to deal with the potential endogeneity

    of the pay structure, could lead to biased estimates of the relationship of interest,

    because of the spurious correlation. It is an important contribution of the current paperthat we are the first to address this issue.

    The structure of the Danish income tax system provides institutional variation which

    has the potential of being used in estimation for breaking this simultaneity. What is

    needed is a source of variation which determines the between firm-year differences in

    the within-firm pay distribution, but which at the same time does not also affect firm

    performance. Specifically, we need instruments for moments of the within-firm pay

    distribution in an equation explaining firm performance.

    Income tax rates in Denmark vary according to workers municipality (of which there

    are 275) of residence. Consequently, firms employing workers from different

    municipalities, have workforces with differential marginal and average tax rates, over

    and above that variation which is gross income related due to the piecewise linear (3

    segment) nature of the income tax schedule. Assuming firm location is exogenous at

    the margin for productivity, between municipality income tax rate variation provides

  • 7/27/2019 Pay Spread and Skewness,Employee Effort and Firm Productivity

    15/25

    15

    candidate instruments for the within firm wage distribution. Alternatively stated:

    exogenous regional differences in income tax progressivity identify the effect of

    moments of the gross earnings distribution on productivity. The part of the variation

    in moments of pay which is explained by progressivity is useful for determining the

    effects of pay moments on productivity, because that part is purged of the spurious

    correlation which would otherwise bias estimates. It is arguably sensible to assume

    that firm location is exogenous at the margin, since it is the changes in progressivity

    over time between regions (the difference in differences) which will identify measures

    of interest.20 Having discursively motivated the identification strategy, it is of course

    an empirical question whether our choice of instruments are statistically appropriate.

    Diagnostic tests are presented in a later section.

    Table 3. Analysis of Variance

    Productivity Effort Std.dev. (Std.dev.)2 Skewness (Skewness)2

    Firm 0.818 0.288 0.150 0.141 0.159 0.138

    3 digit industry code 0.444 0.067 0.011 0.010 0.010 0.010

    5 digit industry code 0.569 0.101 0.021 0.019 0.020 0.019

    SIC3-year 0.477 0.079 0.057 0.059 0.055 0.059SIC5-year 0.640 0.160 0.058 0.060 0.056 0.059

    Municipality 0.092 0.019 0.005 0.005 0.005 0.005

    Municipality-year 0.105 0.051 0.056 0.059 0.055 0.006

    Note: Each cell is an R2 measure from a separate dummy variable regression. Regressions are ofvariables defined in the column header on dummies defined in the row header. SIC3 and SIC5 arerespectively industry codes with 50 and 800 unique realisations.

    The basic unit of the primary analysis is firm-year. Some important points can be

    noticed from the variance of outcomes (productivity and effort) and the explanatory

    variables (pay residual moments) of interest. Table 3 presents R2

    measures ofgoodness-of-fit from regressions of variables defined in the column headers on

    dummies defined in the row headers. Each cell represents a different regression. For

    example, the first substantive cell is the R2 from a regression of Solow residuals on

    firm dummies. Firm is the first level of dummy considered. Remaining variation must

    be over years within-firm. To benchmark this consider 5- (800 realisations) and 3-

    digit (50 realisations) industry codes, which respectively explain about a half and two

    thirds as much variation in all dimensions as firms themselves. Sweeping across the

    columns we can see that there is most heterogeneity between units in Solow residuals,

    about a quarter as much in individual effort, and much less in pay moments.

    21

    Secondand third moments have very similar between-unit heterogeneity.

    20 This builds on the assumption that the costs of re-location are higher than any gain from movingmunicipality in order to change tax progressivity. See Papke (1991) for a counter-argument.

    21 Lazear (1999) finds that within firms, wages are compressed relative to output.

  • 7/27/2019 Pay Spread and Skewness,Employee Effort and Firm Productivity

    16/25

    16

    It is important to appreciate that both the dependent variable and the regressors of

    interest in the primary analysis are themselves generated, and as such have a variance

    which should properly be accounted for in estimation. In order to avoid this problem,

    it is often simpler to perform the analysis in a single step, but in our context this is not

    feasible because of the different dimensionality of the first stage regressions: firm-

    year and worker-year. We could appeal to the fact that we are analysing a population,

    and leave it at that, but in the interests of generality of the results outside Denmark,

    we have performed some bootstrap sensitivity checks on the standard errors. 22

    5 Results and discussion

    Selected productivity estimates are presented in Table 4. They are easiest divided into

    9 blocks of 3 columns comprising different samples (all firms, single-plant firms and

    multi-plant firms) and 3 rows comprising different occupation groups within the firm

    (managers, non-managerial white collar and blue collar). Within each of the 9 blocks

    are 2 columns of coefficients and associated t-statistics and 4 rows defining

    coefficients on pay residual moments and moments squared. Consider for example

    rows 1-4 in column 3, which refer to instrumental variables estimates of coefficients

    on moments of managers pay in a productivity regression.23

    Beginning with the estimates for all firms together, presented in columns 3-4, we may

    see that for white collar workers (managers and non-managers), pay spread (second

    moment) and skewness (third moment) have a quadratic relation with productivity.

    That is, they increase productivity up to a point, after which they become counter

    productive. The counter-productivity effect is greatest for managerial workers. The

    latter is consistent with Lazears (1989) model according to which hawks rise to the

    top and therefore optimum spread is lower in the upper parts of the hierarchy.However, it cannot be ruled out that the differences between employee-groups

    observed, to a large extent may reflect magnification of effects at senior levels of the

    hierarchy.

    22 We drew 100 samples from the population of firms (of size 100% with replacement), and re-estimated the model; then we drew 100 samples of workers, and re-estimated. Re-sampling firms hadnegligible impact on standard errors. However, re-sampling persons increased standard errors often toinsignificance. This is mainly due to a large number of smaller firms falling below our size thresholdfor moment calculation. We base this conclusion on results from restricting the estimation sample toinclude only firms of size 50 and above, and re-sampling therefrom. Analytic and bootstrappedstandard errors coincide much more closely.

    23 OLS estimates available on request.

  • 7/27/2019 Pay Spread and Skewness,Employee Effort and Firm Productivity

    17/25

    17

    Table 4. Firm-Level Productivity Estimations

    Productivity All firms Single-plant firms Multi-plant firms

    coef. t-stat coef. t-stat coef. t-stat

    Managers std.dev. 0.139 4.848 0.137 4.318 0.177 5.805

    std.dev.2 -0.007 -3.371 -0.008 -3.379 -0.001 0.177

    skew. 0.754 2.598 0.735 2.822 0.763 5.274

    skew.2 -0.429 -2.632 -0.432 -3.484 -0.416 0.546

    std.dev. 0.088 4.982 0.072 3.767 0.135 2.103White collar

    workers std.dev.2 -0.005 -0.735 -0.004 -2.094 -0.008 -0.949

    skew. 0.631 5.890 0.635 6.688 0.793 2.264

    skew.2 -0.433 -2.512 -0.443 -2.434 -0.439 -0.311

    std.dev. 0.042 1.102 0.037 0.333 0.053 3.486Blue collar

    workers std.dev.2 -0.002 -0.121 -0.001 -1.723 -0.002 -0.248

    skew. 0.417 2.014 0.440 2.834 0.361 2.524

    skew.2 -0.346 -1.246 -0.355 -1.282 -0.308 0.110

    Notes: Selected IV regression coefficients explaining Solow residual productivity. Each set of 4coefficients comes from a separate regression. The column header defines the firm sample andestimator, and the row header occupation. Other explanatories included but not presented areproportions of workers by age group, occupation, gender, education and tenure and firm size.

    Blue-collar pay moments exhibit weak, if any, productivity effects. However, the

    relative importance of skewness compared to spread increases as one moves down the

    hierarchy. This finding is consistent with the idea that sequential tournaments are the

    more important concept lower down the job hierarchy. In other words, promotion to

    the next round of the tournament which allows competition for bigger prizes may be

    the relevant incentive rather than just the single or repeated tournament at the current

    job level.

    Splitting the sample into single plant and multi-plant firms, we turn to compareestimates in columns 5-6 with those in columns 7-8. Direct comparison of regression

    coefficients between the two samples is valid because the different means are washed

    out of higher moments and units are consistently year 2000 Danish Kroner. The

    incentive effects of pay moments appears to be greater in multi-plant firms.

    Furthermore, counter productivity effects kick in somewhat later in multi-plant firms,

    though these differences are hardly significant. Thus one conclusion to extract from

    the estimates in Table 4 is that they provide moderate support for the organisational

    form implications of industrial politics (see Lazear, 1989). To the extent that the

    between-plant part of within-firm between-worker pay spread is irrelevant for what isconceived of as fair wage differences, these findings are not inconsistent with fairness

    explanations.

    So far we have been concerned with collective effort as measured by firm level

    productivity. Individual effort is notoriously hard to measure, except in rather special

    occupations. We use the inverse of the average firm rate of absenteeism as our proxy

  • 7/27/2019 Pay Spread and Skewness,Employee Effort and Firm Productivity

    18/25

  • 7/27/2019 Pay Spread and Skewness,Employee Effort and Firm Productivity

    19/25

    19

    Table 6. Goodness-of-Fit R2

    All firms Single-plant firms Multi-plant firms

    Productivity managers 0.184 0.204 0.168

    white collar workers 0.190 0.204 0.183

    blue collar workers 0.214 0.236 0.180

    Effort managers 0.049 0.047 0.050

    white collar workers 0.050 0.048 0.049

    blue collar workers 0.054 0.053 0.047

    # obs. 22665 15466 7199

    Note: Goodness-of-fit associated with Tables 4 and 5

    Table 7. Instrument Diagnostics

    All firms Single-plant firms Multi-plant firms

    test-stat p-value test-stat p-value test-stat p-value

    Managers F-test std.dev. 806 0.000 602 0.000 162 0.000

    std.dev.2 1355 0.000 999 0.000 287 0.000

    skew. 1034 0.000 794 0.000 181 0.000skew.2 1157 0.000 877 0.000 219 0.000

    Hausman prod. 56.82 0.000 43.40 0.000 15.71 0.000

    effort. 6.72 0.000 3.93 0.003 8.36 0.000

    Overident. prod. 20.20 0.010 16.19 0.028 5.73 0.325

    effort. 6.73 0.250 3.77 0.550 5.00 0.450

    F-test std.dev. 713 0.000 710 0.000 62 0.000White collar

    workers std.dev.2 1055 0.000 1054 0.000 78 0.000

    skew. 656 0.000 669 0.000 39 0.000

    skew.2 808 0.000 811 0.000 49 0.000

    Hausman prod. 90.62 0.000 68.83 0.000 20.19 0.000

    effort. 10.85 0.000 7.41 0.000 6.61 0.000

    Overident. prod. 27.74 0.000 2.15 0.020 6.32 0.720

    effort. 8.66 0.450 5.06 0.760 5.50 0.740

    F-test std.dev. 836 0.000 947 0.000 72 0.000Blue collar

    workers std.dev.2 1115 0.000 1269 0.000 91 0.000

    skew. 521 0.000 576 0.000 46 0.000

    skew.2 705 0.000 782 0.000 50 0.000

    Hausman prod. 94.22 0.000 75.04 0.000 18.27 0.000

    effort. 6.72 0.000 4.49 0.001 4.73 0.000

    Overident. prod. 21.54 0.007 1.58 0.996 5.81 0.305

    effort. 7.60 0.480 4.42 0.805 5.00 0.450Notes: F-tests are of significance of instruments explaining endogenous variables. Hausman tests are ofsignificance of first stage residuals in the second stage regression. Overidentification tests areuncentered R2 from regressing structural equation residuals on instruments.

  • 7/27/2019 Pay Spread and Skewness,Employee Effort and Firm Productivity

    20/25

    20

    6 Summary and conclusions

    Two types of theories predict that reduced pay spread may be productivity enhancing.

    Tournament theories provide a simple structure, which articulates the point made by

    theories of incomplete contracts and multi-task agency, that weak incentives can be

    more effective in inducing desired worker performance than high-powered but

    dysfunctional ones. Models based on notions of fairness and reciprocity show that

    fairness concerns a may act as a constraint on firms wage setting behaviour, and thus,increases in pay dispersion may be counter-productive. Both tournament models and

    tastes for prize skewness are consistent with skewness effects on productivity. A

    number of predictions arise regarding individual and collective incentives, and this

    paper tests these empirical implications together for the first time.

    Our analysis differs from previous ones in that we consider the entire pay distribution

    of firms. This is informative in that the burden of proof is greater and potentially

    theory is more seriously evaluated if in the same general setting both presence and

    absence of effects can be tested. In other words, tournament-like compensation

    structures are expected to have certain effects for some groups and different effects

    for others. The cuts in the data we have chosen which test a number of predictions

    common to competing theories of tournaments, fairness and tastes for skewness are

    between managers, non-managerial white collar workers and blue collar workers; and

    single- and multi-plant firms. Those which distinguish tournaments are collective

    productivity versus individual effort.

    The application is to a longitudinal matched employer-employee dataset comprising

    the population of Danish medium-to-large private sector firms. This together with the

    nature of the Danish tax system, provides exogenous contract variation required toidentify the effect of moments of the pay distribution on productivity and effort. The

    results of our empirical analysis can be briefly summarised as follows: In common to

    all theories, for white collar workers, pay spread and skewness are found to increase

    firm productivity up to a point, after which it becomes counter-productive. Among

    white collars, counter-productive behaviour is more important higher up in hierarchy.

    Only weak productivity effects are detected for blue-collar workers. More pay spread

    and skewness is productive in multi-plant compared to single-plant firms. However,

    importantly, there are no counter-productivity effects on individual effort. Individual

    effort is increasing with pay spread and skewness, which is a distinctive prediction oftournament models.

    The novelty of this paper has been to examine firm productivity and individual effort

    effects of the whole pay distribution of firms. Differences in firm productivity effects

    between occupational groups and types of firms give support to theories of fairness,

    tournaments and tastes for skewness. Only individual effort effects, proxied by

  • 7/27/2019 Pay Spread and Skewness,Employee Effort and Firm Productivity

    21/25

    21

    absenteeism, support tournament theory alone. A more convincing test would require

    isolating predictions exclusive to fairness and skewness models not in common with

    tournaments. Rejecting those predictions would base tournament theory on still firmer

    empirical ground.

  • 7/27/2019 Pay Spread and Skewness,Employee Effort and Firm Productivity

    22/25

    22

    References

    Acemoglu, Daron, and Pischke, Jrn-Steffen The Structure of Wages and Investment

    in General Training.Journal of Political Economy 107 (1999): 539-573.

    Agell, Jonas On the Benefits from Rigid Labour Markets: Norms, Market Failures,

    and Social Insurance,Economic Journal 109 (1999): F143-F164.

    Agell, Jonas, and Lommerud, Kjell Erik Union Egalitarianism as Income Insurance,

    Economica 59 (1992): 295-310.

    Agell, Jonas, and Lommerud, Kjell Erik Minimum Wages and the Incentives for

    Skill Formation,Journal of Public Economics 64 (1997): 25-40.

    Akerlof, George, and Yellen, Janet The Fair Wage-Effort Hypothesis and

    Unemployment, Quarterly Journal of Economics 105 (1990): 255-283.

    Arellano, Manuel Underidentification?, Institute for Fiscal Studies, Mimeo, 1999.

    Baker, George Incentive Contracts and Performance Measurement, Journal of

    Political Economy 100 (1992): 598-614.

    Baker, George; Gibbs, Michael; and Holmstrm, Bengt The Internal Economics of

    the Firm: Evidence from Personnel Data, Quarterly Journal of Economics 109

    (1994): 881-918.

    Baker, George; Gibbons, Robert; and Murphy, Kevin Subjective PerformanceMeasures in Optimal Incentive Contracts, Quarterly Journal of Economics 109

    (1994): 1125-1156.

    Bull, Clive; Schotter, Andrew; and Weigelt, Keith Tournaments and Piece Rates:

    An Experimental Study,Journal of Political Economy 95:1 (1987): 1-33.

    Camerer, Colin Progress in Behavioral Game Theory, Journal of Economic

    Perspectives 11:4 (1997): 167-188.

    Carmichael, Lorne, and MacLeod, Bentley Multitasking, Technical Change and the

    Japanese Firm,Economic Journal 103: 416 (1993): 142-160.

    Carmichael, Lorne, and MacLeod, Bentley Worker Cooperation and the Ratchet

    Effect,Journal of Labor Economics 18:1 (2000): 1-19.

  • 7/27/2019 Pay Spread and Skewness,Employee Effort and Firm Productivity

    23/25

    23

    Conyon, Martin, and Peck, M. Corporate Tournaments and Executive Compensation:

    UK Evidence, Mimeo: Warwick University, 1999.

    Cowherd, Douglas, and Levine, David Product Quality and Pay Equity Between

    Lower-Level Employees and Top Management: An Investigation of Distributive

    Justice Theory.Administrative Science Quarterly 37:2 (1992): 302-330.

    Cue Kristine (1996) Promotions and Wage Growth, Journal of Labor Economics, 14,

    175-209.

    Drago, Robert, and Garvey, Gerald Incentives for Helping on the Job: Theory and

    Evidence,Journal of Labor Economics 16:1 (1998): 1-25.

    Ehrenberg, Ronald, and Bognano, Michale Do Tournaments Have Incentive

    Effects?Journal of Political Economy 98 (1990a): 1307-1324.

    Ehrenberg, Ronald, and Bognano, Michale The Incentive Effects of Tournaments

    Revisited: Evidence from the European PGA Tour, Industrial and Labor Relations

    Review 43 (1990b): 74S-88S.

    Eriksson, Tor Executive Compensation and Tournament Theory: Empirical Tests on

    Danish Data,Journal of Labor Economics 17:2 (1999): 224-242.

    Farrell, Chris Promotions and Incentives in Partnerships: Evidence from Major U.S.

    Law Firms, Canadian Journal of Economics 29:4 (1996): 1-20.

    Farrell, Chris Empirical Analysis of Occupational Hierachies, Journal of HumanResources 32:1 (1997): 1-34.

    Frank, Robert Are Workers Paid Their Marginal Products? American Economic

    Review 74 (1984): 117-140.

    Garrett, Thomas, and Sobel, Russel Gamblers Favor Skewness, Not Risk: Further

    Evidence from United States' Lottery Games,Economics Letters 63:1 (1999): 85-90.

    Gibbons, Robert, and Waldman, Michael Careers in Organisations: Theory andEvidence. InHandbook of Labor Economics, Volume 3, edited by Orley Ashenfelter

    and David Card. Amsterdam: North Holland, 1999.

    Golec, Joseph, and Tamarkin, Maurry Bettors Love Skewness, Not Risk, at the

    Horse Track,Journal of Political Economy 106:1 (1998): 205-25.

  • 7/27/2019 Pay Spread and Skewness,Employee Effort and Firm Productivity

    24/25

    24

    Hibbs Jr., Douglas, and Locking, Hkan Wage Dispersion and Productive

    Effiociency: Evidence for Sweden,Journal of Labor Economics 18 (2000): 755-782.

    Holmstrm, Bengt, and Milgrom, Paul Multitask Principle-Agent Analyses:

    Incentive Contracts, Asset Ownership and Job Design, Journal of Law, Economics

    and Organisation 7 (1991): 24-52.

    Itoh, Hideshi Incentives to Help in Multi-Agent Situations, Econometrica 59

    (1992): 611-636.

    Knoeber, Charles, and Thurman, Walter Testing the Theory of Tournaments: An

    Empirical Analysis of Broiler Production, Journal of Labor Economics 12 (1994):

    155-179.

    Lambert, Richard; Larker, David; and Weigelt, Keith The Structure of

    Organisational Incentives,Administrative Science Quarterly 38 (1993): 438-461.

    Lazear, Edward Pay Equality and Industrial Politics,Journal of Political Economy

    87 (1989): 1261-1284.

    Lazear, Edward Personnel Economics: Past Lessons and Future Directions,Journal

    of Labor Economics 17:2 (1999): 199-236.

    Lazear, Edward, and Rosen, Sherwin Rank-Order Tournaments Optimum Labor

    Contracts. NBER Working Paper 401, 1979.

    Lazear, Edward, and Rosen, Sherwin Rank-Order Tournaments as Optimum LaborContracts,Journal of Political Economy 89 (1981): 841-864.

    Leonard, Jonathan Executive Pay and Firm Performance, Industrial and Labor

    Relations Review 43 (1990): 13S-29S.

    Levine, David Fairness, Markets, and Ability to Pay: Evidence from Compensation

    Executives,American Economic Review 83 (1991a): 1241-1259.

    Levine, David Cohesiveness, Productivity and Wage Dispersion, Journal ofEconomic Behavior and Organisation 15 (1991b): 237-255.

    MacLeod, Bentley, and Malcomson, James Motivation and Markets, American

    Economic Review 88 (1998): 388-411.

  • 7/27/2019 Pay Spread and Skewness,Employee Effort and Firm Productivity

    25/25

    Main, Brian; O'Reilly, Charles; and Wade, James Top Executive Pay: Tournament or

    Teamwork?Journal of Labor Economics 11 (1993): 606-628.

    McLaughlin, Ken Aspects of Tournament Models: A Survey. In Research in Labor

    Economics Vol. 9, edited by Ronald Ehrenberg. Greenwich CT: JAI Press, 1988.

    Milgrom, Paul Employment Contracts, Influence Activities, and Efficient

    Organisation Design,Journal of Political Economy 96:1 (1988): 42-60.

    Milgrom, Paul, and Roberts, John An Economic Approach to Influence Activities in

    Organisations,American Journal of Sociology 94 (1988): S154-S179.

    Nalebuff, Barry, and Stiglitz, Joseph Prizes and Incentives: Towards a General

    Theory of Compensation and Competition,Bell Journal of Economics 14 (1983): 21-

    43.

    OReilly, Charles; Main, Brian; and Crystal, Graef CEO Compensation as

    Tournament and Social Comparison: A Tale of Two Theories, Administrative

    Science Quarterly 33 (1989): 257-274.

    Papke, Leslie Interstate Business Tax Differentials and New Firm Location,Journal

    of Public Economics 45 (1991): 47-68.

    Prendergast, Canice The Provision of Incentives in Firms, Journal of Economic

    Literature 37 (1999): 7-3.

    Rabin, Matthew Incorporating Fairness into Game Theory and Economics,American Economic Review 83:5 (1993): 1281-1302.

    Rosen, Sherwin Prizes and Incentives in Elimination Tournaments, American

    Economic Review 76:4 (1986): 701-715.

    Winter-Ebmer, Rudolf, and Zweimller, Josef Intra-firm Wage Dispersion and Firm

    Performance, Kyklos 52:4 (1999): 555-572.