political-bureaucratic alliances for fiscal restraint in...

26
51 Political-bureaucratic alliances for fiscal restraint in Japan Gregory W. Noble Abstract Japan’s dismal and rapidly worsening fiscal situation has led to increasingly desperate calls for bold political leadership, and bitter indictments of elite bureaucrats as profligate spenders more interested in protecting their own jurisdictions and budgets than in restoring balance to the nation’s finances. In the campaign for the 2008 House of Councillors elections, the left- center Democratic Party of Japan (DPJ) and Watanabe Yoshio’s right-leaning “Your Party” (み んなの党) could agree on little but the urgent necessity for political leaders to bring recalcitrant bureaucrats under control. While Japan’s fiscal situation is indeed grave, wasteful spending is not the primary cause, as suggested by the OECD’s Economic Survey of Japan 2008: Achieving progress on fiscal consolidation by controlling government expenditures: “...the deficit fell at an annual pace of around ½ percent of GDP, adjusted for cyclical factors, between 2002 and 2007,” with revenue increases (mostly due to improved economic conditions) and expenditure cuts each contributing about half of the improvement (OECD 2008). Particularistic spending on areas such as public works and agricultural subsidies declined sharply over that period, and despite Japan’s aging population, aggregate spending remained remarkably restrained. Japanese finances did deteriorate sharply in 2009-2010, as the government engaged in additional deficit spending to counter the sharp decline in exports and overall economic growth caused by the global financial Japan lacks political leadership and wallows in pork, critics charge, yet from the late 1990s Japanese leaders exercised surprising restraint over aggregate spending, and reoriented budgetary expenditures from distributive outlays such as public works toward social welfare and other forms of programmatic spending. The departure from particularism reflected not only commonly-cited electoral and bureaucratic reforms strengthening the hand of the prime minister, but also the efforts of senior LDP policy experts such as fiscal hawk Yosano Kaoru and rising tide advocate Nakagawa Hidenao to combine with sections of the bureaucracy, particularly officials seconded to the cabinet from the Ministry of Finance and METI, to overcome factional and backbench resistance and restrain expenditures. LDP leaders eventually reached a consensus on the need to increase taxes, but failure to convince the public contributed to the LDP’s downfall. Key words: Japan, fiscal policy, policy reform, political parties, delegation

Upload: others

Post on 10-Nov-2020

3 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Political-bureaucratic alliances for fiscal restraint in Japanjww.iss.u-tokyo.ac.jp/jss/pdf/jss6201_051076.pdfPolitical-bureaucratic alliances for fiscal restraint in Japan 53 (2)

51

Political-bureaucratic alliances forfiscal restraint in Japan

Gregory W. Noble  

Abstract

Japan’sdismalandrapidlyworseningfiscalsituationhasledtoincreasinglydesperatecallsforboldpoliticalleadership,andbitterindictmentsofelitebureaucratsasprofligatespendersmoreinterestedinprotectingtheirownjurisdictionsandbudgetsthaninrestoringbalancetothenation’sfinances. In thecampaign for the2008HouseofCouncillorselections, the left-centerDemocraticPartyofJapan(DPJ)andWatanabeYoshio’sright-leaning“YourParty”(みんなの党)couldagreeonlittlebuttheurgentnecessityforpoliticalleaderstobringrecalcitrantbureaucratsundercontrol. WhileJapan’sfiscalsituationisindeedgrave,wastefulspendingisnottheprimarycause,as suggestedby theOECD’sEconomic Survey of Japan 2008: Achieving progress on fiscal consolidation by controlling government expenditures: “...thedeficit fell at anannualpaceofaround½percentofGDP,adjustedforcyclicalfactors,between2002and2007,”withrevenueincreases(mostlyduetoimprovedeconomicconditions)andexpenditurecutseachcontributingabouthalfoftheimprovement(OECD2008).Particularisticspendingonareassuchaspublicworksandagriculturalsubsidiesdeclinedsharplyoverthatperiod,anddespiteJapan’sagingpopulation, aggregate spending remained remarkably restrained. Japanese finances diddeterioratesharplyin2009-2010,asthegovernmentengagedinadditionaldeficitspendingtocounterthesharpdeclineinexportsandoveralleconomicgrowthcausedbytheglobalfinancial

Japan lackspolitical leadershipandwallows inpork,criticscharge,yet fromthe late1990sJapanese leaders exercised surprising restraint over aggregate spending, and reorientedbudgetaryexpendituresfromdistributiveoutlayssuchaspublicworkstowardsocialwelfareandotherformsofprogrammaticspending.Thedeparturefromparticularismreflectednotonlycommonly-citedelectoralandbureaucraticreformsstrengtheningthehandoftheprimeminister,butalsotheeffortsofseniorLDPpolicyexpertssuchasfiscalhawkYosanoKaoruand rising tide advocate Nakagawa Hidenao to combine with sections of the bureaucracy,particularly officials seconded to the cabinet from the Ministry of Finance and METI, toovercomefactionalandbackbenchresistanceandrestrainexpenditures.LDPleaderseventuallyreachedaconsensusontheneedtoincreasetaxes,butfailuretoconvincethepubliccontributedtotheLDP’sdownfall.

Key words:Japan,fiscalpolicy,policyreform,politicalparties,delegation

Page 2: Political-bureaucratic alliances for fiscal restraint in Japanjww.iss.u-tokyo.ac.jp/jss/pdf/jss6201_051076.pdfPolitical-bureaucratic alliances for fiscal restraint in Japan 53 (2)

SpecialIssue:Onstructuraldevelopments,Koizumireforms,andthecollapseofLDPrule

52

crisis.YetincomparisonwithexpansionaryspendinginChina,theUnitedStates,andmostofWesternEurope,andconsideringthemagnitudeoftheeconomicshock,thetwosupplementarybudgetsforFY2009andtheFY2010budgetasrevisedbytheincomingDemocraticPartyofJapan(DPJ)administrationremainedfairlymodestinsize,andtheylargelyavoidedrelianceonpublicworksandotherparticularisticspending(Noble2010). TotheextentthatobservershaverecognizedthissuccessinrestrainingexpendituresinJapanatall,theyhavetendedtoascribeittostructuralpoliticalandadministrativereformsdatingbacktothemid-1990s,andespeciallytoPrimeMinisterKoizumiJun’ichirō’scleveruseofthenewadministrativemachinerytoovercometheforcesofresistanceintherulingLiberalDemocraticParty(LDP)andthebureaucracy.Thisapproachprovidesagoodstart,butitdoesnotexplainwhytherestrictivetrendscontinuedevenunderthemuchweakerandlesseffectiveprimeministerssucceedingKoizumi.Directassertionofleadershipbytheprimeministerandcabinet,itseems,wasnotsufficient. Theconventionalframeworksettingtheprimeministeragainstthe“forcesofresistance”inthecommitteesoftheLDP’sPolicyAffairsResearchCommittee(PARC),alongwithalliedinterestgroupsandbureaucraticagencies,missesacrucialdimensionofconflict:themixtureofsparringandcoordinationcarriedoutbyseniorLDPmembersintermediateinpowerandinfluence between the prime minister on the one hand, and the “zoku” (policy tribe) DietmembersinthePARCandtheirfollowersontheother.LeadingmembersoftheLDPwithparticular interest in economicpolicy alliedwithprogressive elements of thebureaucracy,particularlytheMinistryofFinance(MOF)andtheMinistryofEconomy,TradeandIndustry(METI),aswellascabinet-orientedpartsofotherministries,topushforfiscalreconstruction,includingbothexpenditurecutsandanincreaseintheconsumptiontax.Thisuniondidnotsimplyrepresenthiddenbureaucraticinfluence—politiciansandbureaucratsoftenconflictedand the bureaucrats did not necessarily win—but they generally saw eye to eye on keybudgetaryissues.OtherinfluentialLDPmembersmoresuspiciousofthebureaucracyreliedonoutsidersorahandfulofrenegadebureaucratsandresistedcallstoincreasetheconsumptiontax.Thetwosidesagreed,however,onthepressingneedtorestrainspending,especiallynon-welfarespending.Eventuallythepro-taxsidewonthebattleofpolicymakers—buttheninthe2010HouseofCouncillorselectionsthepoliticiansfailedtopersuadethevotersoftheircase,leavingJapanesepublicfinancesinperilousshape,despitetherelativerestraintinexpendituresandtheemergingeliteconsensusonthenecessityforincreasingtaxes.

Budgetary outcomes in the 2000s

After markedly improving in the mid-2000s, the ratio of tax revenue to expendituresdeterioratedsharplyafter2008astheglobalcrisishammeredtheeconomy,leavingthecentralgovernmentdependentonbondsformorethanhalfofitsrevenue(MinistryofFinance2010:

Page 3: Political-bureaucratic alliances for fiscal restraint in Japanjww.iss.u-tokyo.ac.jp/jss/pdf/jss6201_051076.pdfPolitical-bureaucratic alliances for fiscal restraint in Japan 53 (2)

Political-bureaucraticalliancesforfiscalrestraintinJapan

53

(2) Trends in General Account Tax Revenues, Total Expenditures, and Government Bond Issues

2.1 3.5 4.5 4.3 6.3 7.2 5.9 7.0 6.7 6.4 6.0 5.02.5 4.1 4.8

11.08.5

24.321.9 20.9

25.828.7 26.8

23.521.1 19.3

26.2

38.4 38.0

3.23.7

5.0 6.37.1 7.0

7.0 7.0 6.8 6.4 6.3 6.26.9

6.2 6.4 6.3 6.79.5

16.212.3

16.4

10.79.9

17.0

13.2

11.19.1

9.16.7 8.7

7.8

6.46.0

7.0

15.0

6.4

0.21.0

17.01.0

13.815.7

17.3

21.923.7

26.929.0 30.5

32.434.9

38.241.9

46.8

50.8

54.9

60.1 59.8

54.4 54.151.0 51.9 52.1

53.9

49.447.2

50.747.9

43.8 43.345.6

49.1 49.151.0

20.924.5

29.1

34.1

38.8

43.446.9 47.2

50.6 51.5 53.0 53.6

57.761.5

65.969.3 70.5 70.5

75.1 73.675.9

78.8 78.5

84.4

89.0 89.3

84.8 83.7 82.484.9 85.5

81.4 81.8

102.6

5.37.2

9.6 10.713.5 14.2

12.9 14.0 13.5 12.8 12.3 11.39.4

7.2 6.6 6.79.5

16.2 16.5

21.2 21.7

18.5

34.0

37.5

33.0

30.0

35.0 35.3 35.5

31.3

27.525.4

33.2

53.5

44.344.3

36.9 37.4

84.7

92.3

7.3

0

20

40

60

80

100

120

1975 1976 1977 1978 1979 1980 1981 1982 1983 1984 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010(FY)

(Trillion yen)

(Note 1) FY1975-2008: Settlement, FY2009:Second revised budget, FY2010: Initial budget(Note 2) Ad-hoc deficit-financing bonds (approx. 1 trillion yen) were issued in FY1990 as a source of funds to support peace and reconstruction efforts in the Persian Gulf Region.

Total Expenditures

Tax Revenues

Construction Bond Issues

Special Deficit-FinancingBond Issues

2

(3) Government Bond Issues and Bond Dependency Ratio

2.1 3.5 4.5 4.36.3 7.2 5.9 7.0 6.7 6.4 6.0 5.0

2.5 1.04.1 4.8

11.08.5

24.321.9 20.9

25.828.7

38.0

3.23.7

5.0 6.3

7.1 7.07.0

7.0 6.8 6.4 6.36.2

6.96.2 6.4 6.3 6.7

9.5

16.2

12.3

16.4

10.7

9.9

17.0

13.2

11.19.1

9.16.7 8.7

7.8

6.46.0

7.0

15.0

6.4

17.0

38.4

26.2

21.1

26.823.5

19.3

0.2

1.0

32.6

26.624.8

23.2

21.0

48.0

16.3

25.3

32.9

31.3

34.7

39.2

31.0

41.841.842.9

36.9

23.5

27.628.0

11.6

10.1 10.69.5

13.5

21.5

22.4

40.3

35.436.6

33.7

27.5

29.7

42.1

52.1

29.4

5.37.2

9.610.7

13.5 14.212.9

14.0 13.5 12.8 12.311.3

9.4

7.2 6.6 6.7

9.5

16.2 16.5

21.2 21.7

18.5

37.5

33.0

30.0

35.033.2

44.3

34.0

53.5

25.4

31.3

35.3 35.5

27.5

7.3

0

10

20

30

40

50

60

75 76 77 78 79 80 81 82 83 84 85 86 87 88 89 90 91 92 93 94 95 96 97 98 99 00 01 02 03 04 05 06 07 08 09 10(FY)

(Trillion yen)

0

10

20

30

40

50

60(%)

Ad-Hoc Deficit-Financing Bonds

Construction Bonds

Special Deficit-Financing Bonds

Bond Dependency Ratio (right axis)

Government Bond Issues (left axis)

(Note) FY1975-2008: Settlement, FY2009: Second revised budget, FY2010: Initial budget

3

    http://www.mof.go.jp/english/budget/e20091225b.pdf.Sources:MinistryofJapan,“Japan'sFiscalSituation(December25,2009)”

Page 4: Political-bureaucratic alliances for fiscal restraint in Japanjww.iss.u-tokyo.ac.jp/jss/pdf/jss6201_051076.pdfPolitical-bureaucratic alliances for fiscal restraint in Japan 53 (2)

SpecialIssue:Onstructuraldevelopments,Koizumireforms,andthecollapseofLDPrule

54

4). Japan’s fiscal condition is indeed grim. Net government indebtedness is well over 100percent,worsethaninanyotherOECDcountry(OECD2010a).UnlikethecaseinfinanciallytroubledEuropeancountriessuchasGreeceandItaly,Japan’sdomesticsavingsaresufficientto absorb government deficits, and interest rates remain low, but at some point decliningdomesticsavingsandincreasedinterestratescouldputtremendouspressureonbudgets,andpossiblyigniteacrisisofconfidence. Japan’sfiscalwoesarenotprimarily the result ofunrestrained spendingbyprofligatepoliticians.GovernmentspendingasashareofGDPisamongthelowestintheOECD:in2007(the latest year for which comparable data are available), total expenditure of generalgovernmentasapercentageofGDPwas36.01percent—slightlylowerthanthatoftheUnitedStates,andfarlowerthaninmostEuropeancountries(OECD2010b).Instead,weakeconomicperformance and deflation have depressed revenues and created “reverse bracket creep.”NeitherinJapannorabroadistherefullrecognitionofthemagnitudeofthetaxcollapse.Afterclimbingsteadilyandrapidlyfordecades,taxrevenuesinthegeneralaccountbudgetpeakedat60.1trillionyenin1990.Theydeclinedbyalmostathirdto43.3trillionyenin2002,andthenrecoveredto51.0trillionyenin2007,beforeslumpingtoadisastrous36.9trillionyenin2009(MOF2010). Totheextentthatpressurestoexpandspendingincreased,theyreflectednotincreasedwasteorper-capitagenerosity,buttheagingofthepopulation.Fromthelate1990stothelate2000s,theshareofpublicworksinGDPdeclinedbyoverhalf,andthegovernment’sspendingonagriculturedeclinedbyalmostasmuch.Defensespendingstagnated,educationspendingdeclinedsignificantlyasthenumberofschoolagechildrendropped,andforeignaidplunged.Pension benefits, healthcare coverage and reimbursements to physicians all shrank, whilepensionandhealthpremiumsincreased,butbecauseoftherapidagingofthepopulation,socialwelfare spending jumped from35percentageof thebudget in2000 to48percent in2008.(Noble2010:247-251).

Sources of fiscal restraint: Structural Reforms and the Koizumi-Takenaka Team

Totheextentthatrestraintinexpendituresisrecognizedatall,ittendstobeattributedtotheincreasedstrengthoftheprimeministersincetheelectoralandadministrativereformsofthe1990s,andparticularlytheconfluenceofstructuralreformsandskilfulleadershipunderPrimeMinisterKoizumi(2001-2006)(Fujimura2009;Uchiyama2007;Shimizu2005).Electoralandcampaignfinancingreformweakenedtheinfluenceoffactions,strengthenedthepoweroftheprimeminister,andcontributedtoconsolidationofthepartysystem,creatingagenuinealternative to the LDP (Rosenbluth and Thies 2010, Köllner 2009). Elections increasinglybecameasimultaneouschoiceofparty,platform,andprimeministerialcandidate(政治改革推進協議会(民間政治臨調)1996). The end of the cold war and of the bubble economy, and the

Page 5: Political-bureaucratic alliances for fiscal restraint in Japanjww.iss.u-tokyo.ac.jp/jss/pdf/jss6201_051076.pdfPolitical-bureaucratic alliances for fiscal restraint in Japan 53 (2)

Political-bureaucraticalliancesforfiscalrestraintinJapan

55

increase in uncommitted “floating voters” at the expense of “organized voters” furtherstrengthened themove away from particularistic politics and factionalized clientelism andtowardamoreprogrammaticorientationtopolicy(Noble2010).Strengtheningoftheprimeministerandcabinet(Shinoda2005)andcreationoffourkeyadvisorycouncilsundertheprimeministerincreasedthecapacityofpoliticalleaderstoprovidemorecoherentpolicies. PrimeMinisterKoizumimadeparticularlygooduseoftherevampedinstitutions.Koizumicraftedeffectivepoliticalmanifestos,effectivelywieldedthethreatofparliamentarydissolution,andkeptfirmcontrolovercabinetandotherpersonneldecisionsonceleftlargelytofactions.Hemobilizedcharm,abilitytocraftboldanddecisive-soundingsoundbites,andskilfuluseofa wide range of news and information media to advance his agenda of structural reformagainstopponentshecannilydesignatedas“forcesofresistance.” AcrucialweaponwastheCabinet’sCouncilonEconomicandFiscalPolicy(CEFP),whichcameintoexistencejustmonthsbeforeKoizumiassumedofficeaspartofthereformscraftedinthe1990sbyPrimeMinisterHashimotoRyūtarō.Koizumisettheagendaandbroadlinesofpolicy,thendelegatedauthorityforeconomicpolicytoone-timegovernmentpolicyanalystandKeioUniversityprofessorTakenakaHeizō, theonlypersonto lastthroughall threeof theKoizumicabinets(Takenaka2008).KoizumigaveTakenakahiscompletetrust,andTakenakainturnprovidedabsoluteloyalty,runningfortheHouseofCouncillorsin2004whenKoizumiaskedhimtoincreasehispoliticalheft,andretiringfromtheDietinmid-termwhenKoizumifinishedhistenureasprimeminister.Takenakacombinedacademicexpertise,extendedstaysatleadingAmericanuniversities,andyearsexperienceworkingintheeconomicbureaucracy.Hebuiltasmall,ideologicallycompatibleandintenselyloyalteam,andstrovetoreducetheinfluenceoftheministries. Thefour“private”membersoftheCEFP—twoeconomistsandtwobusinessexecutivesfromleadingfirmsinsuchexternallyorientedsectorsasautomobiles,electronicsandtrade—servedasavanguard,pushingthepolicyenvelope.Theprivatemembersquicklyovercametheirdifferencestoforgeaunitedfront,seizingcontrolofthepolicyagendawithprovocativeandunanimouslysigned“privatemember[policy]papers.”Theystressedtheimportanceoftransparencytoneutralizetheinformationasymmetrytypicallyfavoringthebureaucrats,andproddedreluctantministriestoestablishspecifictimetablesandnumericaltargets(Ota2006:124-127).TheCEFP under StateMinisterTakenaka forced theministries and agencies toprovide counter-offers rather than merely veto uncongenial proposals, and after intensiveeffortsatpersuasion,lettheboldandpopularprimeministermakethefinaldecision,typicallyfavoringfurtherreforms(Takenaka2008:224-225). TheCEFPunderKoizumi andTakenaka overcame the opposition of bureaucrats andbackbenchpoliticianstoachieveanumberofcrucialbreakthroughs,manyofwhichdirectlyorindirectlyreducedpressureongovernmentspending.TheCEFP:1.ControlledthedirectionofthebudgetandtheFiscalInvestmentandLoanProgram(FILP)or “second budget,” overcoming resistance from bureaucrats, interest groups and LDP

Page 6: Political-bureaucratic alliances for fiscal restraint in Japanjww.iss.u-tokyo.ac.jp/jss/pdf/jss6201_051076.pdfPolitical-bureaucratic alliances for fiscal restraint in Japan 53 (2)

SpecialIssue:Onstructuraldevelopments,Koizumireforms,andthecollapseofLDPrule

56

backbencherstoinflictsignificantcutsinpublicworksandhealthcare(vialowerreimbursementsto doctors; increased co-pays, and increased contributions); and squeezedpensions (sharplyhighercontributionratespluslowerfuturepayments).2.Forcedbankstocastofftheirnon-performingloans(overresistancefrombanks,andtheMinistryofFinance,andsuchborrowersasbigretailersandtheiroverseerMETI).3.ForcedtheBankofJapantoswitchmoreamoreaccommodatingmonetarypolicytocombatdisinflation(CargillandSakamoto2008:142-143)4.Consolidatedandprivatizedgovernment-ownedfinancialinstitutions(againstthestrenuousoppositionoftheMinistryofFinance,whichplacedmanyofitsformerofficialsincushypost-retirementamakudaripositionsatthebanks).5.Beganprivatizationofthepostalsystem(includingthegiganticpostalsavingsandinsurancesystems),despitestrenuousoppositionfromtheMinistryofInternalAffairsandCommunication(MIC)andbackbenchpoliticians.6.Cutsomedisbursementstolocalgovernmentsinreturnforturningoveraportionoftaxrevenues, and consolidated many small local governments, both over the opposition of areluctantMICandagainstthewishesofmanylocalgovernments.

Beyond the powerful prime minister

The preceding explanation is fine as far as it goes, but it is incomplete: control ofexpenditurescontinuedevenunderKoizumi’sthreeweaker, lesseffectiveandshorter-livedLDPsuccessors,whofailedtomatchKoizumi’sappealandstrategies(Shimizu2009;Takenaka2008,pp.225-232).Koizumi’ssuccessors--Failedtoproduceboldmanifestoswithconcreteandimmediategoals.--Didnotmakegooduseofcontroloverpersonnelordelegateclearlytoonechiefeconomicadvisor;instead,theytriedtobalancecabinet,factions,andforceswithintheLDPratherthannamingfiguresreliantonthemselves.--ReliedontheelectoralmajorityleftoverfromKoizumi’shistoricvictoryinthe2005HouseofRepresentativeselectionratherthandaringtoseekownelectoralmandatesviaparliamentarydissolution.AndyettightcontroloverbudgetaryexpendituresandtheFILPprogramcontinued,withonlyamodestrelaxationaftertheglobalfinancialcrisisin2009,andeventhatresponsedifferedfundamentallyfromtheparticularisticpump-primingofthelate1990s. Each ofKoizumi’s threeLDP successors lacked crucial skills or committed significanterrors,andthelasttwowerehobbledbytheopposition’sseizureofcontroloftheupperhouseinthe2007HouseofCouncillorselections.Eachlastedbutayear.PrimeMinisterAbeoccupiedhimselfwithdistantandunrealisticgoalsoflittledirectappealtovoters,suchasconstitutionalrevision,failedtosetconcreteshort-termgoals,andmadenumeroustacticalerrors.Ideologically,

Page 7: Political-bureaucratic alliances for fiscal restraint in Japanjww.iss.u-tokyo.ac.jp/jss/pdf/jss6201_051076.pdfPolitical-bureaucratic alliances for fiscal restraint in Japan 53 (2)

Political-bureaucraticalliancesforfiscalrestraintinJapan

57

AbewasclosesttoKoizumi,buthelackedKoizumi’shard-earnedreputationasaprincipledandtenaciousreformer,andKoizumi’sfeelfortheconcernsoftheelectorate,lurchingfromagenericconservatismtoapositionfartotherightofthemedianLDPlegislator,muchlessthevotingpublic(KabashimaandOokawa2006).InsharpcontrasttoKoizumi’scareinpersonnelselection,Abe’sfailuretovetcabinetpickscarefullyledtoastreamofgaffesandscandals,andcriticism that he relied on a “cabinet of friends.” The revelation on Abe’s watch that thegovernmenthadlosttensofmillionsofpensionrecordsmostlyreflectedbadluck,sincetheproblemsdatedbackdecades,butAbedidnotrespondeffectivelytothepublic’sunderstandablefearandoutrage.Aboveall,hisdecisiontoacceptbackintotheLDPthe“postalrebels”whohaddefiedKoizumioverpostalprivatization in2005andhadbecomesymbolsof the “old”LDP’sunwillingnesstoreform,turnedouttobeadisastrouserror(Shimizu2009:156-175). Abe’ssuccessorFukudaYasuowaslesscommittedtoneo-liberalreformthanKoizumiandAbe,andcouldnotmatchKoizumi’sskillatcommunication.Thesonofaformerprimeminister,Fukudahadbeenaneffective“insider”asChiefCabinetSecretaryunderKoizumi,andhewasmoresensitivetotheimmediateconcernsofvotersthanwasAbe,asseeninhisdetermination tocreateanewconsumerprotectionagency,buthewasoldand lacking incharismaandpublicspeakingskills.LDPbackbenchersquestionedhisabilitytowinelections(Asahi Shinbun,September17,October2,2007).Fukudafailedtocraftanewmanifesto,andcarriedoveralmosttheentirepreviouscabinetfromAbe,ratherthancreatinganewteamandindependentimage.Especiallytellingwashisbotchedattemptstocreatenewsloganstosummarizehispolicydirection,borrowingmuchofhisterminologyfromtheoppositionparties,and then repeatedly mangling the wording in public (Shimizu 2009: 257-258). Attempts toconveyasenseofmodestyandcircumspection(suchasdescribinghispoliticalsituationas背水の陣[forcedtofightalast-ditchbattle])onlymadehimsoundweak. Finally, Fukuda’s flighty successor Asō Tarō repudiated the signature stances of the“Koizumistructuralreform”agendaonpostalprivatizationandfiscalreconstruction, joiningtheresurgenceofpro-expendituregroupsintheLDP(Nihon Keizai ShinbunAugust6,2008).The word “reform” literally disappeared from Aso’s campaign posters (Asahi Shinbun September 25, 2008). Aso’s repeated misreading of Japanese expressions exposed him toridiculeandunderminedhisreputationforseriousnessandcompetence. Koizumi’ssuccessorsstruggledtodealwiththebacklashagainstfiveyearsofvigorousreformunderKoizumi,including“reformfatigue,”scandalsattributed,withvaryingdegreesofplausibility,tothederegulationcarriedoutunderKoizumi,andthewidespreadimpressionthatKoizumi’s policies had contributed to a rapid increase in economic inequality in Japanesesociety.Mostimportant,theopposition’svictoryinthe2007HouseofCouncillorselectiongavetheDPJapreciousincreaseinperceivedlegitimacyandseriousness,andhobbledthepolicyinitiativesoftheCEFPandtheLDP,sincetheupperhousecouldvetoalllegislationexceptbudgetsandtreaties.Infact,animportantreasonthatFukudacameacrossassomuchlessresolute than Koizumi was his repeated, and ultimately fruitless, efforts to craft a grand

Page 8: Political-bureaucratic alliances for fiscal restraint in Japanjww.iss.u-tokyo.ac.jp/jss/pdf/jss6201_051076.pdfPolitical-bureaucratic alliances for fiscal restraint in Japan 53 (2)

SpecialIssue:Onstructuraldevelopments,Koizumireforms,andthecollapseofLDPrule

58

coalitionwiththeDPJtoovercomethegridlockcausedbydividedgovernment,suchastryingtogarnertheDPJ’ssupportfortheU.S.militaryeffort intheIndianOcean,andapossibleincreaseintheconsumptiontax. Insum,primeministerKoizumi’shaplessandunluckysuccessorsstillmanagedtopresideover continuing budgetary stringency, and even succeeded at passing some legislativebreakthroughs, suchasFukuda’s creationof theconsumerprotectionagency, even thoughtheylackedmanyofKoizumi’sskillsandfailedtoimitatehiscleveruseofthepowersoftheprime ministership created by the 1990s reforms. The “structural reform” explanation isnecessary,butnotsufficient. Moreover,itistellingthatevenKoizumireliedfarmoreonthebureaucracy,andnotjustnewinstitutionssuchastheCEFP,thantherhetoricoftheTakenakateamandmuchofthepresscoveragewouldleadonetobelieve.Takenaka(2008:124-126)andhischiefassistant,OtaHiroko(2006:250-252)emphasizethegalvanizingroleoftheCEFPandparticularlyitsprivatemembers,andexpresssuspicionandevenhostilitytowardstaffsecondedfromthebureaucracy,buttheilluminatingaccountbyKoizumi’slong-timepoliticalsecretaryIijimaIsao(2006)makesclearthattheKoizumiadministrationrelieddeeplyonaselectgroupofsecondedbureaucrats.Dependence on support from bureaucrats was especially crucial in Koizumi’s last year:opponentsintheLDPwereeitherdefeatedorcowedbyKoizumi’sgreatvictoryinthe2005election,whileTakenakarelinquishedcontrolover theCEPFtooversee implementationofpostalreformatMIC.KoizumientrustedtheCEFPtofiscalconservativeYosanoKaoru,whopledgedtoworkwith,ratherthanagainst,therulingparty.ItistruethatAbe,Fukuda,andAsotosomeextendcoastedonthebudgetaryoutlinessetoutunderKoizumi,butthecrucialcompromises were forged under Yosano in the “unified expenditure/revenue reform”incorporatedinthe2006“Honebuto”(bigboned)programforeconomicmanagement(CEFP2006).

Reconsidering relations between politicians and bureaucrats: beyond strict delegation

Untilthelate2000s,analysesofJapanesepoliticsincreasinglystressedpoliticalcontrolofthe bureaucracy. Whereas scholars in the immediate post-war decades focused on thedomination of policymaking by bureaucrats and the limitations of Japan’s new democracy(Tsuji1969),bytheearly1980s,apositiveaffirmationofpluralismasserteditself.Surveysfoundthatbothbureaucratsandpoliticiansviewedthelatterasthemostimportantplayersinthepolicyprocess(Muramatsu1981).Drawingonmassesofinternalpartydocuments,SatōandMatsuzaki(1986)showedthattheLDPhaddevelopedastablesenioritysystem,andthatitsleadingpoliticiansplayedanactiveroleinpolicy.ExtendingtheworkofAberbach,PutnamandRockman(1981)onwesterndemocracies,theyproclaimedthatpoliticiansandbureaucratsinJapanhadmergedintoanew“hybrid.”InoguchiandIwai(1987)concurred,highlightingthe

Page 9: Political-bureaucratic alliances for fiscal restraint in Japanjww.iss.u-tokyo.ac.jp/jss/pdf/jss6201_051076.pdfPolitical-bureaucratic alliances for fiscal restraint in Japan 53 (2)

Political-bureaucraticalliancesforfiscalrestraintinJapan

59

active role of LDP politicians in distributing political resources. Japanese policymaking, itseemed,hadbecomedemocratic,pluralistic,andhighlyresponsivetopartypolitics,ifstillnotquiteasfreewheelingasintheUnitedStates. After1989,theLDP’s lossofcontroloftheUpperHouseandfrom1993-1994eventheHouseofRepresentatives,anditsconsequentdependenceoncoalitionpartnersconfirmedtheideathatpolitics,notbureaucracy,heldthekeytoJapanesepolitics(HiwatariandMiura2002).Atthesametime,widespreadreportingoftheputativefailingsoftheministriesquietedtalkofbureaucraticdominance:theburstingoftheeconomicbubblein1990,scandalsinvolvingtheministries of finance and health, the perceived failure to deal effectively with the KobeearthquakeandthesubwaypoisoningattacksoftheOumShinrikyōsect,theinabilityoftheFinanceMinistrytopreventthecollapseofnumerousfinancialinstitutionsandtheaccumulationof bad loans, and above all the prolongation of deflation and slow and erratic growth allunderminedthereputationofthebureaucracy. Principal-agentmodelsdevelopedelsewherealsobegantoinfluencestudiesofJapanesepolitics.Theassentofpoliticiansisneededtopasslegislationandbudgets,andscholarsexploredanincreasinglywidevarietyoftechniquespoliticianscouldusetoinfluencethebehaviorofbureaucrats, includingscreening,directand indirectmonitoring (includingprovisionof “firealarms”),andcontroloveradministrativeprocedures,agencybudgets,andcareeropportunitiesavailable to bureaucrats (Miller 2005). Ramseyer and Rosenbluth (1993) found significantevidencethatmanyofthesetechniqueswerealsoatworkinJapan.McCubbinsandNoble(1995) showed that Japanese budgets, far from being rigid and incremental, responded tofluctuationsinthegoalsoftopleadersandthesizeoftheLDPcontingentintheDiet.Masuyama(2003), followingCox andMcCubbins (1993), argued thatLDP leaders guidedpolicymakingthroughtheircontrolovertheDiet’sagenda. Just as the “mepoliticalprincipal, youbureaucratic agent” approachbecameacceptedwisdominJapan,theliteratureinthewestgrewmorecomplexandsophisticated,emphasizingvariationsinthetypeandbreadthofdelegation,andthevaryingresourcesavailabletobothpoliticiansandbureaucrats,nottheleastthefactthatbureaucratshaveamassiveadvantagein numbers, experience, expertise and continuity. Many analysts applied the economics ofindustrial organization and transaction costs to political arrangements, concluding thatpoliticianswillnotdevoteunlimitedresourcestowritinglegislationormonitoringbureaucrats,butwillcompareinternalcosts(producinglawsandregulationthroughlegislativecommittees)totheexternaltransactioncostsinvolvedwithdelegationtobureaucracy.Politiciansaremorelikely todelegate, forexample,underunifiedrather thandividedgovernment (EpsteinandO’Halloran1999).HuberandShipan(2002)arguedthatthedegreeofdelegationdependsuponthe character of the issue (for example, how conflictual or technical); the availability ofalternativessuchascourtsorfederalism;andthecapacitiesofpoliticians(especiallyministers)andlegislatures(e.g.time,salaries,andcommitteesystems).Similarly,AlesinaandTabellini(2007)predictedgreaterdelegationwhenthepolicymakingiscomplexoruncertain,andless

Page 10: Political-bureaucratic alliances for fiscal restraint in Japanjww.iss.u-tokyo.ac.jp/jss/pdf/jss6201_051076.pdfPolitical-bureaucratic alliances for fiscal restraint in Japan 53 (2)

SpecialIssue:Onstructuraldevelopments,Koizumireforms,andthecollapseofLDPrule

60

whenthecontentinvolvesdistributingvaluableresourcestospecificclients. Arelatedstrainofresearchpointedoutthatpoliticianssometimesdeliberatelyforsakepolitical discretion in the presence of time-inconsistency, short-termism, and strong vestedinterests(AlesinaandTabellini2008).Thetrendtowardmoreindependentcentralbanksisafamousexample (AlesinaandSummers1993,butseealsoHallettetal. 2009on limitationsarising from interactions with fiscal policy). Independent regulatory agencies, once limitedlargely to the United States, have spread to Europe and even Japan, partly via diffusionmechanisms, but alsobecauseof their ability to increase credibility andbind thehandsofsuccessors (Gilardi 2008). Politicians may even deliberately tie their hands and limit theirdiscretionsoastoincreasetheirbargainingleveragewithotherplayersorothercountries(Miller2005). Morerecentlyandintriguingly,politicalscientistshavenoticedthatbureaucratsarenotsimplyagentswithsignificanthands-oninformationandexpertise,butpoliticalplayerscapableofmobilizingformidablepoliticalresourcesoftheirown.InSwedenandothersocialdemocraticcountries, public sector unions are major supporters of leading political parties. Even inAmerica,unionsofteachers,prisonguardsandotherpublicemployeescanmobilizesignificantnumbersofvotersandcontributors(Moe2006;Zimringetal.2001).Agenciesalsooftensitatthe nexus of interest groups, academics and professionals involved in the policy process.Carpenter(2001)demonstratedthattheAmericanpostofficeandDepartmentofAgriculture(thoughnotsomuchtheDepartmentoftheInterior)wereabletoprovideuniqueservicesthatcaused related interest groups to rally around the agency and protect against hostile orindifferentpoliticians.Similarly,PresidentRonaldReagan’sabilitytouseappointmentpowerstoreinintheEnvironmentalProtectionAgency(EPA)wasslowedandlimitedbytheEPA’snetworkofsupporters(WoodandWaterman1994). Insomecases,bureaucraciescanusetheirinformationadvantageandimageofbeinglesscorruptthanpoliticianstoswaylargerswathsofpublicopinion.RobertMoses,forexample,usedhiscontroloveranindependentincomestream(bridgeandroadtolls)todominatepublicconstructioninNewYorkfordecades,lastingthroughfivemayorsandsevengovernors,untilhelostcontrolofpublicopinionintheearly1960sandwaspushedaside(Caro1974).Inadditiontomobilizingpositiveopinionontheirownbehalf,bureaucratscanleakdamaginginformationto discredit their political “masters,” as lightly fictionalized in the famed British televisionseries “Yes, Minister” (Makihara 2003:17-18). Finally, on occasion, bureaucrats can unleashagainstpoliticalopponents(andtheirsupporters)thecoercivepowersofthestate,suchastaxaudits,regulatoryinvestigations,andprosecutions. By the 2000s, as the economy continued to flounder despitemassive budget stimuluspackages, similarobservationsproliferated in Japan.Lossof confidence in thebureaucracygavewaytolargerquestionsaboutpoliticalgovernance.Scholarsincreasinglyquestionedthepowerof theprimeminister toovercomenot just thebureaucracybutalso thepluralisticforcesintheLDPthatoftenalignedwithindividualministriestodemandresourcesandresist

Page 11: Political-bureaucratic alliances for fiscal restraint in Japanjww.iss.u-tokyo.ac.jp/jss/pdf/jss6201_051076.pdfPolitical-bureaucratic alliances for fiscal restraint in Japan 53 (2)

Political-bureaucraticalliancesforfiscalrestraintinJapan

61

callsforstructuralchange.TheHashimotoandKoizumireformscreatedsomeoptimism,butevenKoizumi’ssubordinatesandsupportersexpresseddoubtsthatstructuralreformwouldsurvivehisretirement(Takenaka2008:225-232).Manyscholarsagreedthatpoliticaldirectionremainedweak.IioJun’s(2007)award-winningbookpointedtocontinuingweaknessesinthequalityofministersanddeliberation inbothDietandcabinet.Despitesome improvementsafterelectoralreform,henotedthatbureaucracyremaineddeeplyembeddedwithproducerand other social groups. Bureaucrat-scholar Nakajima (2007) and prominent LDP figureNakagawaHidenao(2008:31)expressedevengreaterskepticism. By the2009and2010elections, the insurgentDPJ,LDPconservatives, and journalists(Shimizu2009)joinedtogetherindecryingtheweaknessofJapanesegovernanceandcallingforgreaterpoliticalleadership.ConservativessuchasNakagawa(2008)andTakahashi(2008)assailedthebureaucracy’suseof leaks, informationfreezes,andsabotage.ForeignMinistryofficials, for example, used information leaks to discredit Koizumi’s first Foreign Minister,TanakaMakiko (Ehrhardt2009: 636).During thepostalprivatizationdrive,PrimeMinisterKoizumi even sacked two MIC officials for carrying out secret negotiations with LDPbackbenchers(Takenaka2008:183).Nakagawa(2008:33-35)assailedbureaucratsformobilizinginterestgroupsand localgovernments topressurepolitical leaders.Rather thanpoliticiansdeterminingthepromotionofbureaucrats,hecharged,bureaucratswereabletomanipulatethe imagesand thuscareerprospectsofpoliticians.Nor,heclaimed (Nakagawa: 56-64)didbureaucratsintheMinistryofFinanceandelsewherehesitatetousetaxauditsandregulatorypowersagainstreportersandothersperceivedtobeunsympathetictobureaucraticinterests.Doubts even emerged about the independence of prosecutors. Johnson (2002) showed thatprosecutorswereevenmoreimmunefromoversightinJapanthaninmostotheradvanceddemocracies, though he argued that in general they handled their discretion responsibly.FormerForeignMinistryofficialSato (2010),however, claimed thatbureaucrats selectivelyprosecutedcertainpoliticiansandpartieswhileleavingmorepliablepoliticiansalone(fortheinteractionbetweenleaksbyprosecutorsandpliablenewsmediaintherun-uptothe2009House ofCouncillors election, see alsoNew York Times,May 28, 2009).The conclusion ofNakagawa(2008:35):bureaucratsstillwieldoverwhelminginfluenceinpolicymaking. In sum, while the claim that delegation to the bureaucracy amounts to out-and-outabdicationisimplausibleinanelectoraldemocracy,andplentyofcomparativestaticsevidencesuggeststhatchangesinpoliticalarrangementsleadtochangesinpolicyoutcomes,andarenotjuststymiedbybureaucraticresistance,logicandconsiderableevidenceprovidereasonsto believe that politicians often prefer fairly loose delegation and on occasion will evendeliberatelycreatestrongbureaucraticcontrol,notleastviatheMinistryofFinance.Moreover,theassumptionthatpoliticiansholdanabsoluteadvantageinpoliticallegitimacyandlegislativecontrol over their bureaucratic agents can be exaggerated: the resources available tobureaucrats include not only information, expertise, hierarchical control and institutionalcontinuity, but also legitimacy, extensive contactswitheconomicand socialgroups, andat

Page 12: Political-bureaucratic alliances for fiscal restraint in Japanjww.iss.u-tokyo.ac.jp/jss/pdf/jss6201_051076.pdfPolitical-bureaucratic alliances for fiscal restraint in Japan 53 (2)

SpecialIssue:Onstructuraldevelopments,Koizumireforms,andthecollapseofLDPrule

62

timesevensignificantelectoralmobilizationcapacity.TheseresourceshelpexplainhowleaderswithintheLDPcoulduseallianceswithpartsofthebureaucracytocontrolspendingevenunderweakerprimeministers.

Beyond the prime minister: influential LDP MPs and alliances with the bureaucracy

DespitetherhetoricoftheDPJelectoralmanifestos(DemocraticPartyofJapan2009),inJapan as elsewhere, policymaking conflict rarelyneatlypits politicians against bureaucrats(Aberbach, Putnam, and Rockman, 1981: 252). Normally, one set of politicians, relatedbureaucrats,andalliedinterestgroupsconfrontsotherclustersofpoliticians,bureaucrats,andinterests.Traditionally,subgovernmentsandirontriangleswereespeciallyperniciousinJapanbecauseoftheinternalpoliticalcompetitionresultingfromthe“medium-sizedconstituency”orSingleNon-TransferableVote(SNTV)electoralsystem(Campbell1984).Asnotedabove,theelectoralandcampaignreformsof1994diminishedinternalconflict,underminedfactions,andstrengthenedparty labels andprimeministers as party leaders.Despite thedramaof theKoizumiyears,however,policymakingdoesnotjustrevolvearoundaconflictbetweenprimeministers and the pluralistic “forces of resistance,” but often includes conflict over policydirectionandbalanceacrossspendingprograms.Theseconflictsarenotnew,buttheygrewinrelativeprominenceasfactionsandzokuleadersweakened.Backinthe1980s,SatoandMatsuzaki(1986:50-51,97)notedtheimportanceof“influentialDietmembers”有力議員withseniority(twoormoretermsinthecabinetor“topfour”partyposts)and(unlikemerezoku)aplausible claim to expertise and influence in multiple policy areas. Influential membersdemonstrate their status (and suitability for future positions, including prime minister) byrestrainingtheirowndemands, imposingdisciplineonjuniormembers,andbrokeringdealsacrosspolicyareas.EvenamongzokuDietmembers,InoguchiandIwai(1987)distinguishedbetween “hunting dogs” that constantly sought new resources for themselves and theirfollowers, and “guard dogs” (猟犬/番犬). After the structural reforms, influential memberswithouttheirownfactionsplayedanevenmoreimportantrole.

Major axis of conflict: Consumption taxes

AftertheaccessionofPrimeMinisterKoizumi,thegreatestconflictineconomicpolicycenteredonwhether,when,andhowmuchtoraisetaxestocovertheyawningbudgetdeficit.Theweaknessoftheeconomyandfearsofintensifieddeflationservedtodelaycallsfortaxincreases,asdidtherepeatedsetbackstheLDPhadexperiencedwhenitproposed,passed,andlaterincreasedtherateoftheconsumptiontax.Thebusinesscommunity,wellrepresentedthroughthepeakassociationNipponKeidanrenandtheCEFP,arguedthatthehighestpriority

Page 13: Political-bureaucratic alliances for fiscal restraint in Japanjww.iss.u-tokyo.ac.jp/jss/pdf/jss6201_051076.pdfPolitical-bureaucratic alliances for fiscal restraint in Japan 53 (2)

Political-bureaucraticalliancesforfiscalrestraintinJapan

63

wastostimulatedomesticinvestmentbycuttingcorporatetaxes,sinceprofitablebigcompaniesfacerelativelyhighrates,especiallycomparedtothoseofneighboringAsiancountries.PrimeMinister Koizumi flatly declared that he would not raise the consumption tax during histenure,whichreassuredconsumersandinvestors,butalsopostponedtheproblem. Policymakerspaidrelativelylittleattentiontogainingmorerevenuefromfarmers,small-businesses,andmiddle-classtaxpayers,eventhoughJapan’staxbasewasnarrowerthanthatofotherleadingdemocracies(Steinmo2010).ProfessorIshiHiromitsuoftheGovernmentTaxCommittee,anadvisorycouncilundertheMinistryofFinance,proposedimplementationofa“standard”corporatetaxonvalueaddedandinvestedcapitalinordertocapturerevenuefromthetwo-thirdsofcompaniesreportinglosses.PrimeMinisterKoizumihadspokeninfavorofwideningthetaxbase,andProfessorHonmaMasaakiandtheprivatemembersoftheCEFPwerenotopposedinprinciple,buttheCEFPdoubtedthatthemeasurewouldbringinmuchrevenueand thebusiness sectorwasbitterly opposed.Whenawatered-down systemwasfinallyintroducedin2004,itappliedonlytocompanieswithcapitalofatleast100millionyen,andtheCEFPturneditsattentionbacktocuttingcorporatetaxrates(Ota2006:180-187).In2003,theKoizumiteamintroducedsomeminor“policytaxcuts”oncorporateandpersonalincometaxrates,butafterthattaxpolicychangedrelativelylittle(Ota2006:193-196),apartfromsome inadvertentreversebracketcreepthat furthercut intorevenues.Ontheotherhand,theKoizumiadministrationalsoimplementedsomesignificantincreasesinsocialsecuritycontributionsandhikedco-paymentsbypatients,effectivelyshiftingsomeofthetaxburdenfromcorporationstohouseholds.

Tax cutters

TaxaversiondominatedtheKoizumiadministrationandremainedapowerfulmovementunderhis successors. In 2005, theprivatemembers of theCEFPset out a framework for“integratedexpenditure/revenuereform,”includingthreeunderlyingprinciples(CEFP2005):smallgovernment;vitality(includingcross-generationalequity);andtransparency.Ofthese,themostimportantwas“smallgovernment,”andTakenakarepeatedlydeclared,“Iamtheministerfor smallgovernment” (Takenaka2008:211, 225-232).Policymakers tried to stimulatemorerapid growth, and made optimistic (or unrealistic) assumptions about its likelihood. Theyfocusedonmicroeconomicreformssuchasderegulationaswellasmacroeconomicpolicy,andaimedforamoderatelyhighnominalgrowthrate;thatis,theywereimplicitlywillingtouseamoderateamountofinflationtoeatawaythegovernment’sdebts.Advocatesoflowertaxestendedtostartwiththemaximumacceptabletaxburden,thenfiguredoutexpenditurecutsnecessarytomaintainthem(Ota2006:123-165).Themainthrustwasclear:cutcorporateandothertaxestotheextentpossible,andrelyonacceleratedgrowthandcutsinexpenditures,includingsocialsecurity,tocontrolthedeficit. InadditiontoKoizumiandTakenaka,prominentadvocates includedtheCEFPprivate

Page 14: Political-bureaucratic alliances for fiscal restraint in Japanjww.iss.u-tokyo.ac.jp/jss/pdf/jss6201_051076.pdfPolitical-bureaucratic alliances for fiscal restraint in Japan 53 (2)

SpecialIssue:Onstructuraldevelopments,Koizumireforms,andthecollapseofLDPrule

64

members ledbyProfessorHonma,whohadoncerecruitedTakenaka toOsakaUniversity(Shiota2005).Theprivatemembersdidnotalwaysagreeonneo-liberalprinciples—ProfessorYoshikawaHiroshiofTokyoUniversityhadstudiedunderthe famedKeynesianeconomistJamesTobinatYale—andatfirsttheytriedtoimplementadivisionoflaborbytopic,buttheysoonconcludedthattheirinfluencedependedonmaintainingunity,andtheyagreedthatthefirstprioritywascuttingexpendituresandprivatizingwherepossible(Ota2006:255) AnumberofseniorLDPpoliticianssharedthisview.Some,ledbyNakagawaHidenao,opposedvirtuallyalltaxincreases;others,suchasPrimeMinisterAbe,FinanceMinistersOmiKōjiandNukagaFukushirōandMETIMinisterAmariAkira,werewillingtoconsiderasmallincreaseintheconsumptiontaxifitcouldbeusedtoreducecorporateorincometaxes.ThemostconsistentandvociferousproponentofcuttingexpendituresratherthanincreasingtaxeswasNakagawa.AgraduateofKeioUniversity’sLawFaculty,Nakagawaworkedasareporterfor the leadingbusinessdailyNihon Keizai Shinbunbefore inheritingaDiet seat fromhisfather-in-law, a party politician and fierce critic of the bureaucracy (Nakagawa 2008: 30).Nakagawaenteredthecabinetinmodestpostsin1996and2000.Hewasnotafactionleaderandprovedelectorallyvulnerable,failingontwooccasionstowinelectiontotheDiet,butfrom2002-2005hespentarecord-breakingtermastheLDP’spointmanforDietnegotiations.Hisbooks“RisingTide”and“TheCollapseoftheBureaucraticState”(Nakagawa2006,2008)calledon Japan to surf on a rising tide of growthby cutting taxes, and assailed Japan’s “stealthhybrid”elite,particularlygraduatesoftheLawFacultyattheUniversityofTokyo,whowerefarmorelikelytobefiscalhawksthantaxcutters(orbigspenders).Nakagawaarguedthatitwasunfairandpoliticallyunviabletoaskordinarycitizensfortaxincreasesbeforeeliminatingwastefulexpenditures.

Fiscal Hawks

In contrast, the Ministry of Finance, its advisory bodies, many economists, and LDPleaders such as Finance Ministers Tanigaki Sadakazu and Yosano Kaoru and financialservicesministerYanagisawaHakuoclaimedthat“healthy”or“prudent”fiscalpolicyrequiredanincreaseintheconsumptiontax.Likethebureaucrats,manyofthefiscalhawksintheLDPhailed fromtheLawFacultyof theUniversityofTokyo. Manyweresonsofbureaucrats(Yosano)orpoliticians(Tanigaki)orlinkedtotheMinistryofFinance.Noneheadedafaction,andmosthadrelativelyweakelectoraland fund-raisingrecords,yet theywereamongtheLDP’smostinfluentialmembers.YosanocameinsecondtoAsointheLDP’spresidentialrace,andTanigakiranseveraltimesbeforefinallyassumingpresidencyofthepartyafterAso’sdisastrouslossinthe2009HouseofRepresentativeselection. Thefiscal hawksgavefirst priority to restoringfiscal discipline, initially by achieving“primarybalance” (balancing thebudget other thanbond repayments) as soon as possible.Theyacceptedtheeconomicandpoliticalcaseforcuttingunnecessaryexpendituressuchas

Page 15: Political-bureaucratic alliances for fiscal restraint in Japanjww.iss.u-tokyo.ac.jp/jss/pdf/jss6201_051076.pdfPolitical-bureaucratic alliances for fiscal restraint in Japan 53 (2)

Political-bureaucraticalliancesforfiscalrestraintinJapan

65

publicworksbeforeincreasingtaxes,buttheybelievedthatitwaspoliticallyunrealisticandnormativelyundesirabletocutsocialspending(Yosano2008:150-152).Ratherthantakingahypothesizedmaximumtaxburdenasastartingpoint,theyarguedforcalculatingtheamountnecessarytofundsocialwelfareexpendituresatclosetocurrentlevels,andthenworkingoutacombinationofexpenditurecutsandtaxincreasessufficienttopayforthem.Asapracticalmatter,theysettledontheconsumptiontaxforitsstabilityandprodigiouscapacitytogeneraterevenue.Whiletheconsumptiontaxwasregressiveinincidence,thespendingitsupportedwas generally progressive, and exemption of basic items such as food could soften theregressivity,albeitatthecostofincreasedcomplexityandlowerrevenue(Kato2003).Fiscalhawksarguedformakingrealisticassumptionsaboutgrowthandinterestrates,andassailedthedeliberatecourtingofinflationtomeltoffpublicdebtasa“demonictechnique”悪魔的手法(YosanoinShimizu2009:93).

Big spenders

Despiteheateddisagreementsovertaxpolicy,taxcuttersandfiscalhawksagreedontheimportance of cutting expenditures. Naturally, many politicians, bureaucrats, and interestgroupsresistedattemptstocutfavoredprograms.Afterthefailureofthehugebudgetstimuluspackagesofthelate1990s,fewLDPleadersadvocatedexpansionaryfinanceasamatterofprinciple, butbackbenchpressurewasunrelenting, andwhenelections loomed, even someleaderscalledforexpandingexpenditures.Forexample,in2008,DietcountermeasureschiefKogaMakoto,PARCchairHoriKōsuke,andpresidentialcandidateAsōTarōallcalled forresistingexpenditurecuts(Nihon Keizai ShinbunAugust6,2008).Thesevoicesrarelyappearedin the CEFP, however, and they typically defended specific items rather than making aprincipled case for larger expenditures (Asahi Shinbun, November 15, 2007). Instead, theycriticized theunelectedprivatemembers of theCEFP (includingTakenakabeforehewaselected to theHouse of Councillors in 2004), and complained about inconvenient timing ofexpenditurecuts(Asahi ShinbunOctober16,2007;YamanakaSadanoriinOta2006:191). Overall,though,thestrikingfeatureofthebigspenderswastheirweaknessandlackofconfidence.Theyrarelyheldkeypolicymakingdecisionsintherulingpartyorgovernment,andtheydidnotattempttoarticulateaseriousideologyormountasustainedmediacampaign.Theywieldedonlymarginalinfluence,andcouldnotstopnetbudgetcuts.

Fiscal hawks gradually gain the advantage

FromthelatterpartoftheKoizumiadministration,thefiscalhawksslowlyandalmostimperceptiblypulledahead.ThoughtheAbeadministrationwasideologicallyconservativeandfavoredtaxcuts,CEFPMinisterOtadeniedbeinganadvocateofthe“risingtide,”andPrime

Page 16: Political-bureaucratic alliances for fiscal restraint in Japanjww.iss.u-tokyo.ac.jp/jss/pdf/jss6201_051076.pdfPolitical-bureaucratic alliances for fiscal restraint in Japan 53 (2)

SpecialIssue:Onstructuraldevelopments,Koizumireforms,andthecollapseofLDPrule

66

MinisterAbetoldtheDiet,“AsfarasIcanrecall,Ihaveneverusedtheexpression.”(Shimizu2009:196,198).AbeandOtasoughttoincreaseproductivitythroughderegulationandevenconsumerprotection,andfocusedontheimplicationsoffiscalpolicyforproductivity,ratherthanavoidingalltaxcutsperse. Fukuda,whose fatherhadbeenheadof thebudgetbureauat theMinistryofFinancebeforebecomingprimeminister, basically favoredprudentfinance andprotection of socialsecurity.UnlikeKoizumi,hewasnotunalterablycommittedtoworkingthroughtheCEFPwithitseconomistsandbusinessexecutives.Forexample,in2007heestablishedajointLDP-Komeitocommitteeonjointconsiderationoftaxesandsocialwelfare.UnliketheCEFP,thecommittee included the minister responsible for social welfare and labor (Asahi Shinbun October23,2007andSeptember27,2007).Politically,Fukudawasnotinpositiontoactasanactive fiscal hawk.Hobbled by aweak party base, a cabinet coalition, and the opposition-dominatedHouseofCouncillors,hetriedtobalancefactionsandpolicygroups,andreliedonmultipleadvisorycouncils. AsowasevenlesscommittedtoKoizumi’sstructuralreformsandpubliclyquestionedthepriorityplacedonbalancedbudgets.UnlikeAbeandFukuda,hedidnotreceiveKoizumi’ssupport in theLDPpresident’s race. But likeFukuda, he engaged in balancing in a futileattempttoretainsupportanddealwiththeopposition.HeformedanunlikelyalliancewithYosano,andpromisedtogettoworkonthedeficit—later.Finally,afterthefallofAso,theLDPunder Tanigaki incorporated into its electoral platform for the 2010 House of Councillorselectionapledgetohiketheconsumptiontaxto10percent.ToTanigaki’sannoyance,theDPJimmediatelycopiedtheproposal.Increasingtheconsumptiontaxhadbecomethemainstreamconsensusamongpolicymakersandtheleadingparties—butthevotersrejectedtaxincreases,handingtheDPJadefeat,andfavoringsmalleroppositionpartiesasmuchastheLDP. EspeciallystrikingfromthelastyearoftheKoizumi’sadministrationthroughhisthreeLDPsuccessorswastherecurrentrelianceontheleaderofthefiscalhawks,YosanoKaoru.Thegrandsonoffamouspoets,sonofadiplomat,andgraduateoftheTokyoUniversityLawFaculty,Yosanoworkedbrieflyinthesemi-privatesector(JapanAtomicPowerGeneration,ajoint venture of the regional electric power monopolies) before working as a secretary toformerPrimeMinisterNakasoneYashuhiroandasDeputyChiefCabinetSecretaryunderLDPheavyweightKajiyamaSeiroku.Yosanoenteredthecabinetaseducationministerin1994,andthenservedprimeministerObuchiKeizoasaMITIministerin1998.Despitehiselitebackground, powerful patrons and widespread contacts in the bureaucracy and businesscommunity,Yosanofailedtobuildapowerfulelectoralbaseandneverheadedafaction.ThreetimeshefailedtowinelectiontotheDiet,includingduringthefirsthalfofKoizumi’sterm;heonlyscrapedhiswaybackintotheDietin2003byvirtueofaspotontheLDP’sproportionalrepresentationticket. Yosano was a moderate, pragmatic conservative. He supported Koizumi’s structuralreformsasrightfortheirtime,butdeniedthattheyrepresentedeternalverity.Sharplycritical

Page 17: Political-bureaucratic alliances for fiscal restraint in Japanjww.iss.u-tokyo.ac.jp/jss/pdf/jss6201_051076.pdfPolitical-bureaucratic alliances for fiscal restraint in Japan 53 (2)

Political-bureaucraticalliancesforfiscalrestraintinJapan

67

of “market fundamentalism,” he advocated “market realism,” and “humanist democracy”(Yosano2008:70).Hesaidthatthegovernmenthadtoseekfairnessbutnotequalityperse.Aboveall, ithadtobepragmatic (Yosano2008:76-80).Yosanowasbasicallypositiveaboutbureaucrats.HesaidhehadlearnedfromKajiyamahowtousebureaucratswithoutbeingusedbythem,andclaimedthatheseldomacceptedpolicybriefingsfrombureaucrats(Yosano2008:32-38,26).Hesawbureaucratsasmotivatedprimarilybyasenseofhonorandmission(Yosano2008:139)andrarelymentionedamakudariorbureaucraticscandals.Hepresentedadetailedrefutationoftheargumentsofthe“risingtide”faction,andforcefullyadvocatedasimplepolicyprescription:raisetheconsumptiontaxtorestorefiscalbalance(Yosano2008:149-171). DuringtheadministrationsofKoizumiandhissuccessors,Yosanoservedinaremarkablearrayofposts.In2004,KoizuminamedhimheadoftheLDP’sPolicyAffairsResearchCouncil,wherehewasresponsibleforguidingpostalprivatization—Koizumi’ssignaturepolicyinitiative,draftedbytheTakenakateam—throughtheparty.In2005,afterKoizumi’striumphinthe“postalelection,”Yosanoservedasministerofstateforeconomicandfiscalpolicy.AsCEFPminister,hetookresponsibilityforcompilingKoizumi’sfinal“bigboned”(honebuto)report.TothedisgustofTakenakaandOta,YosanoarguedforcoordinatingwiththeLDPratherthantryingtoovercomeitsopposition.KoizumibalancedYosanoand“risingtide”leadersNakagawa,endinginanambiguousvictoryforYosanointhefinalreport,whichcalledforbothhighertaxesandahighernominalgrowthrate(Shimizu2009:93-97).Forbigspenders,however,thereportwasclearlyamajordefeat.Theplanaimedtobringtheprimarybalanceofthecombinedcentralandlocalgovernmentbudgetsbackintotheblackby2011.Theintegratedreformofexpendituresandrevenuecalledforashiftof16.5trillionyenoverthefollowingfiveyears,includingatleast11.4trillionyen—over70percentofthetotal—inexpenditurecuts(CEFP2006:15-19,47-48). InOctober2006Yosanowastemporarilysidelinedbya13-houroperationforcancerofthepharynx(Yosano2008:113-115).Evenafterhisrecovery,hedidnotatfirstreceiveapositionundertheyoung,growth-orientedAbe,whofocusedoninnovationandopennessasawaytostimulategrowthandobviatetheneedfortaxincreases.Butinthelastmonthofhisterm,aflailingAbebroughtinYosanoasSecretaryGeneralinafutilebidtorestorehispopularityandauthority. Yosano also initially failed towin a position under Fukuda, but he still exertedindirectinfluencethroughtheinterimreportoftheResearchGrouponFiscalReform,ofwhichhewaschair.Thereport(LDP2007)calledforcontinuedreductionsinexpenditures,anda“streamlinedandefficient”(ratherthansmall)governmentwithamid-sizedwelfare/mid-sizedtaxburden,andahikeintheconsumptiontaxto10percentbythemid-2010stopayforit.WhenFukuda’ssupporterratingssagged,he,likeAbebeforehim,calledonYosano,naminghimspecialministerfortheCEFPandforregulatoryreform,justamonthbeforetheendoftheFukudacabinet. Aso,onceanavowedskepticofprudentfinance,keptYosanoon.WhenNakagawaShōichi,minister of both finance and financial supervision, resigned after showing up drunk at an

Page 18: Political-bureaucratic alliances for fiscal restraint in Japanjww.iss.u-tokyo.ac.jp/jss/pdf/jss6201_051076.pdfPolitical-bureaucratic alliances for fiscal restraint in Japan 53 (2)

SpecialIssue:Onstructuraldevelopments,Koizumireforms,andthecollapseofLDPrule

68

internationalmeetinginRomeinearly2009,AsoaddedthosetwopoststoYosano,leavinghimincompletecontrolofeconomicpolicymaking.Bythattime,ironically,theglobalfinancialcrisiswasexertingstaggeringcontractionarypressureontheJapaneseeconomy,andtheadvocateof balanced budgets resigned himself to supervising creation of a large stimulus package:"WithintheLDP,Ihavebeencategorizedaspartofthe‘fiscaldisciplinefaction’財政規律派,butforthetimebeingIhavechangedmysect.Fiscaldisciplineisimportant,butacrisisrequiresanappropriateresponse.Wewilladoptallpolicymeasuresnecessarytoachievetheeconomicrecoveryagreedtobythenationsoftheworld." (Shimizu2009:45).Despitethispragmatictacticalretreat,thedependenceofsuccessiveprimeministersontheseniorpolicyspecialist,andthepowerlessnessofbackbencherstostoptheleaderofthefiscalhawks,wasclear.

Bureaucratic staff

IfinfluentialpolicyspecialistswithintheLDPplayedaroleinrestrainingexpendituresfarbeyond that captured by the dramaturgy of “prime minister versus backbench forces ofresistance,” bureaucratic staffers, particularly officials seconded to the cabinet from MOF,METIandtheMIC,werealsocrucialplayers incoordinatingand implementingbudgetaryreforms.Themost stridentadvocatesof structural reforms,particularly leadersof the taxavoidancegroupsuchasTakenakaandAbe,oftenharshlycriticizedbureaucrats,not leastthoseservinginthecabinet.RisingtideleaderNakagawaquotedPrimeMinisterMurayama,whomNakagawaservedasanassistantin1994,aslamentingthatinacabinetofficecontaining300bureaucrats,theprimeministerandthreeotherpoliticiansweremere“birdsinacage”(Nakagawa2008:39).Koizumiaccusedthebureaucratsofattendingonlytotheironlyinterests.EarlyinhisadministrationheparticularlylamentedtheMinistryofFinance’slackofenthusiasmforstructuralreformssuchasprivatizationofhighwaysandpostalservices, reformof theFiscalInvestmentandLoanProgram,government-relatedfinancialorganizations,andspecial-purposecorporations:“TheFinanceMinistrysaidnothingaboutalltheseprogramsthatIamnowreforming” (CEFP2002: 25).Takenaka (2008: 40, 124-126) complained thatbureaucratsstuck toprecedentbecause theywereunwilling toadmitpastpolicy failures.Otaand theCEFPprivatememberOkudaHiroshi (ChairmanofToyota)castigated thebureaucracyascautious,slow,compromising,chronicallyinclinedtowardadjustinginterestsratherthantakingboldinitiatives,andextremelyreluctanttoacceptspecifictimetablesandnumericaltargets(Ota2006:83-94). Koizumiandhisadvisorsdevelopedanumberofcountermeasurestoovercomebureaucraticaversiontostructuralreform.Koizumi frequently insistedthatthekeywascontrollingthedetailsratherthandelegatingthemtothebureaucracy(大事なのは各論)(Ota2006:88).Takenaka(2008:88,162)echoedtheimportanceoffollowinguponthedetails.Ota(2006:17-18)saidthatitwasimportanttorelyontheprivatemembersandtheprimeminister’soffice(官邸)rather

Page 19: Political-bureaucratic alliances for fiscal restraint in Japanjww.iss.u-tokyo.ac.jp/jss/pdf/jss6201_051076.pdfPolitical-bureaucratic alliances for fiscal restraint in Japan 53 (2)

Political-bureaucraticalliancesforfiscalrestraintinJapan

69

thanthecabinet,butsheadmittedthatinpracticeitwasoftendifficulttoascertainwhowasissuingorders.SometimestheKoizumi-Takenakateamtriedtoignoreorperformanendrunaround the bureaucrats, especially when it came to postal reform, though Takenaka washimself a formerbureaucrat, andmadegreat use of the renegadeMOFofficialTakahashiYōichi,abittercriticofthebureaucracy(Shiota2005). Despitethisingrainedsuspicionandhostility,eventhosemostcriticalofthebureaucracyagreedthatsecondedbureaucratswerecrucialtothepolicymakingprocess.Incoolermoments,Ota(2006:13)acknowledgedthatArticle4ofMOF’sestablishmentlawassignsresponsibilityforcompilingthebudgettotheFinanceMinistryanddoesnotevenmentiontheCEFP.Shealso noted (Ota 2006: 92) that while relations between CEFP and MOF were sometimesconflictual,theywerealsosometimescooperative.TakahashiYōichiandhiscoauthor(TakahashiandSuda2010:47-48)advisedthatcontrollingtheAssistantChiefCabinetSecretaries,ofwhichanofficialsecondedfromtheMOFismostimportant,isthe“heart”(literally“liver”)oressenceof political leadership.Bureaucrat sympathizerYosano (2008: 136-142)went even further—makegooduseofbureaucrats,andyouwon’tevenhavetoworkhard! TheMinistryofFinanceandMETIoccupydominantpositionsamongsecondedstaffinthecabinet.FourofthefivepositionsasExecutiveSecretarytothePrimeMinister(秘書官)havebeenreservedforkeyagencies:MOF,METI,theForeignMinistry,andthepoliceAgency,ofwhichMOFandMETIareby far themost influential, especially onbudgetsandothereconomicissues(thefifthpositionisreservedforapoliticalsecretary).AllbutoneofKoizumi’sExecutiveSecretariesservedthroughhisfulltermoffiveyearsandfivemonths(seethelistatIijima2006:334).IfthebroaddirectionforthebudgetissuedfromtheprimeministerandCEFP,the“ceiling”frameworktorestrictbudgetaryrequestsandtheevaluationofindividualitemsstillcamefromtheMOF(Ota2006:110). Special project teams at a slightly lower level of seniority came from four other bigministries,buttheywereexpectedtoshowloyaltytothecabinet,andnotsimplyworkonissuesofinteresttothehomeministry(Iijima2006:28-32).Manybureaucratsworkedinthecabinetforextendedperiods,sometimescoveringtwoormorecabinets,andextendingasfarbackasHashimotointhemid-1990s.ThevastmajorityweregraduatesoftheLawFacultyattheUniversityofTokyo. Secondedbureaucratsremainimportantpartlybecausefourofthealternativesadvancedsincethe1990shavenotprovedparticularlysuccessful,aseventheiradvocatesacknowledge.Increasing the number of juniorministers (Takenaka 2002) has notmademuch differencebecausejuniorministerisstillprimarilyalearningposition,anddistributionofposts(unlikethecasewithministers)isstillprimarilydeterminedbyfactions(seee.g.Asahi ShinbunSeptember28,2006fortheexampleoftheAbecabinet).Someprimeministers,notablyAbe,attemptedtorelyonspecialadvisorstotheprimeminister(内閣総理大臣補佐官),butthespecialadvisorslackindependent legal authority and often conflictwithministers (Shimizu 2009: 134-139;Asahi Shinbun September 29, 2006). Fixed-term contract staff from universities and the private

Page 20: Political-bureaucratic alliances for fiscal restraint in Japanjww.iss.u-tokyo.ac.jp/jss/pdf/jss6201_051076.pdfPolitical-bureaucratic alliances for fiscal restraint in Japan 53 (2)

SpecialIssue:Onstructuraldevelopments,Koizumireforms,andthecollapseofLDPrule

70

sector have played some role—Ota was initially hired on a fixed-term contract—but theimportance of seniority and the difficult of carrying out mid-career hires in the Japanesepersonnelsystemhasprovedamajorobstacle,andindividualsparachutedinfromtheprivatesectoroftenhavefoundthemselvesisolatedandcutofffromtheinformationcontrolledbythebureaucrats(Wedge,December2007:10-12).Afteraninitialburstofinterest,thenumberofcontractstaffatCEFPdeclined(Ota:260-262).NorhasthestaffoftheDietanditslegislativecommitteesexpandedmuch,despiterepeatedproposalsfromNakagawaHidenaoandotherpoliticiansandscholars(Nakajima2007:235-239;Nakagawa2008:35-36). Moreusefulhavebeenthe“MinistersofStateforSpecialMissions”introducedaspartofthereorganizationofthecentralministriesandcabinetin2001.Specialministerspossesslegalauthority,belongtothecabinet,andareresponsibletotheDiet,yettheycanrespondflexiblytoaddressnewpolicyissues.PrimeMinisterKoizumi,forexample,wasabletonameTakenakaHeizōspecialministerforpostalprivatization.Ofcourse,confusionoverrolesandthepotentialforconflictwiththeministersofthelineagenciesstillexists(Ota2006:16),andspecialministerslackbackupfromministerialstaff—forcingthemtorelyprimarilyonofficialssecondedfromthevariousministries. TheCEFPplayedthecrucialroleinsettingthedirectionofbudgetarypolicy,anditreliedheavilyonbureaucraticstaff.Mostof its200orsomembershailedfromtheoldEconomicPlanningAgency (EPA),asupportrather than lineministry thathaddevelopedsignificantexpertiseinmacro-economicsbutwieldedlittlepower(andindeedwaslargelycolonizedbytheFinance Ministry). Of seven Directors-General for Policy (政策統括官) in the cabinet, threeworkedattheCEFP.AmongthecrucialsecondedbureaucratsatCEFPwereKishiHiroyukiofMETIandTakahashiYōichiofMOF(Shimizu2005:272-275;Shiota2005).Kishi,akōhaiofTakenakaattheeconomicsdepartmentatHitotsubashiUniversityandholderofanMBAfromColumbia,workedinthecabinetforTakenakaformorethanfouryears.Takahashi,agraduateofthemathematicsandeconomicsdepartmentsatTokyoUniversity,wasavisitingscholaratPrincetonunderBenBernanke,who laterheaded theFederalReserve.TakahashiassistedTakenaka from 2001, officially entered the cabinet in 2003, and stayed through the Abeadministration. Some seconded bureaucratswere renegadeswho cut tieswith their homeministries and after leaving the cabinet became academics, managers, or private businessexecutives.In2008,bothKishiandTakahashijoinedEdaKenji,aMETIbureaucratwhohadhelpeddesignmanyofPrimeMinisterHashimoto’sreformsbeforecomingapolitician,andotherprominentfiguresincreating“ThegroupofformerbureaucratschangingbureaucraticstateJapan”[官僚国家日本を変える元官僚の会](脱藩官僚の会)]. TheCEFPprivatemembersdidnottrustbureaucratsnotto leak informationbacktotheirhomeministries,soin2002theCEFPcreateda“specialorders”teamunderProfessorHonmatosetthecouncil’sagenda.Initially,ex-EPAofficialsandcontractemployeesfromtheprivatesectorstaffedtheteam,butitlateraddedsecondedmembersfromvariousministries.EvenTakenaka admitted that independent expertswere rare in Japan, and that his anti-

Page 21: Political-bureaucratic alliances for fiscal restraint in Japanjww.iss.u-tokyo.ac.jp/jss/pdf/jss6201_051076.pdfPolitical-bureaucratic alliances for fiscal restraint in Japan 53 (2)

Political-bureaucraticalliancesforfiscalrestraintinJapan

71

bureaucratic “Team Takenaka” and “guerrilla team” for postal reform relied heavily on“visionarybureaucrats”(Takenaka2008:139).Moregenerally,onceproposalsfromtheprivatesectormembersmovedtospecificitemsforincorporationintotheHonebutoplans,theCEFPhadtomobilizethefullpanoplyofbureaucraticsupport(Ota2006:150-152;cf.alsoTakenaka2008: 225-227).AsPrimeMinisterKoizumi noted, “Unlesswe thoroughly revise thewholestructure of wasteful spending, it will not be possible to regenerate the economy…Ifdisagreementsonspecificissues[suchasthesizeorcompositionofexpenditurecuts]arise,wewillrequesttheassistanceoftheMinistryofFinance.IwanttheFinanceMinistrytopleasethinkofitselfasthesecretariatfortheCEFP.”(CEFP2001:16) OutsidetheCEFP,theKoizumicabinet’srelianceonbureaucraticstafftokeepcontrolover expenditureswas evenmore obvious. Iijima Isao (2006: 60),who served asKoizumi’spoliticalsecretaryformorethan30years,wasespeciallyemphatic:

TheabilitytoincorporatesoradicallythespecificfeaturesoftheKoizumireformsintheHonebutoprogramdependeduponthepoweroftheteamofCabinetSecretariatCounsellorsunderAssistantChiefCabinetSecretaryTakeshima,whostoodat the forefrontof thebattletosupporttheprivatesectorfigureMinisterTakenaka,andDirector-GeneralSaka,whocurbedtheresistanceoftheministriesandagencies.ThisisanexampleofwhatImeanby'makingfulluseofbureaucrats'.

TakeshimaKazuhiko,acareerMOFofficial,servedasIijima’s“Mr.Outside,”whileSakaAtsuo,another elite MOF official, served as “Mr. Inside” (Shimizu 2009: 148). Tango Yasutake, abudgetspecialistwholater(2009)ascendedtoMOF’stopcareerpostofadministrativeviceminister,alsoplayedakeyroleduringtheKoizumiadministration(Iijima2006:28-32). OfthelastLDPprimeministers,Abewasthemostskepticalofbureaucrats,especiallyMOFbureaucrats,anddidthemosttoseparatethemfromtheirhomeministries.Hereliedonopenapplicationsfromindividualofficials(公募)ofwhichhereceivedmorethan80,ratherthannominationsbytheministries(Asahi Shinbun,September27,2006).Hetoldwould-beapplicantstoexpecttoburntheirbridgestotheirhomeministries;successfulcandidateswerenottocontacttheirhomeministries,andwereassignedtoproblemsunrelatedtotheexpertisetheyhaddevelopedattheirhomeministries(Shimizu2009:150).IfAbetriedtoreducethepoweroftheMinistryofFinance, intheendhereliedheavilybothonthecoordinatingpowersofsecondedMOFofficialSakaAtsuo,andonavarietyofMETI-relatedbureaucratsandpoliticians,includingMETI alumni in theLDP (Shimizu 2009: 148, 185, 136). For his “AsiaGateway”project(www.kantei.jo.jp/jp/singi/asia/),AbereliedonExecutiveSecretaryNemotoTakumi,anex-ConstructionMinistrymemberof the lowerhouse,withadministrativebacking fromMETIandMOF,whileattheCEFPOtaleanedonMETI’sNoharaSatoshi. Like Abe, Prime Minister Fukuda relied heavily on MOF’s Saka, and indeed one ofFukuda’sproblemswashisperceivedbiastowardbureaucrats.HisattempttobalancemembersfromMOF,theBankofJapan,andacademiceconomicsledhimtokeepnominatingex-MOFofficialstotheBOJ,eventhoughtheDPJopposedappointmentofex-bureaucratsandwasina

Page 22: Political-bureaucratic alliances for fiscal restraint in Japanjww.iss.u-tokyo.ac.jp/jss/pdf/jss6201_051076.pdfPolitical-bureaucratic alliances for fiscal restraint in Japan 53 (2)

SpecialIssue:Onstructuraldevelopments,Koizumireforms,andthecollapseofLDPrule

72

position todefeathisnominations (Shimizu2009:334-339).Constrainedby thealliancewithKomeitoandthedesiretocreateamodusvivendiwiththeopposition-controlledupperhouse,FukudaandtheCEFPunderhisdirectiondelegatedmuchoftheauthoritytosetbudgetaryprioritiestoMOF,leadingtocomplaintsof“arevivalinMOFpower”(Asahi ShinbunJuly29,2008).Tocounterfearsthathewaslosingmomentuminthefightagainstwastefulexpenditures,theLDPunderFukudaestablishedaprojectteamtoreduceadministrativewaste—withhelpfromJapanInitiative (構想日本),aprivateorganizationfoundedbyformerMinistryofJapanofficialKatōHideki(Asahi ShinbunJune27,2008).

Conclusion

Japan’sfiscalsituationisindeedgrave,butcontrarytoconventionalwisdom,itsprimaryproblemisnotpoliticalfailurebutdemographicandeconomicpressures.Anagingsocietywitha shrinking work force has combined with two financial crises—domestic after 1990 andespecially after the financial collapses of 1997, and international in 2008-2009—to constrictpolitical choices. Japan’s gaping budget deficit and huge accumulated debt have resultedprimarily from a catastrophic decline in tax revenue, not from ballooning budgetaryexpenditures.Despitethetremendouspressures,politicalleadersoverthelastdecadehaveexercised considerable restraint over aggregate spending, and have reoriented budgetaryexpendituresfromdistributiveoutlayssuchaspublicworkstowardsocialwelfareandotherformsofprogrammaticspending. Totheextentthatthisoutcomehasevenbeenrecognized,theconventionalexplanationhighlights institutionalreformssuchasrevisionoftheelectoralsystem,campaignfinancingreform,andthestrengtheningofthecabinetsystem,leadingtostrongerpoliticalleadership,assymbolizedbyPrimeMinisterKoizumi.Clearly, institutionalreformsarepartof thestory.After2005,however,continuedconstrictionofexpenditurescontinueddespiteweak(orinthecaseofKoizumiafterthe2005election,preoccupied)primeministers.Thissuggeststhatwemust lookbeyondthe “reformistprimeministerversusprofligatebackbenchers”structure.InfluentialseniorLDPleaderswithreputationsaspolicyexpertssuchasrisingtideadvocateNakagawaHidenaoandfiscalhawkYosanoKaorucombinedwithsectionsofthebureaucracy,particularly officials seconded to the cabinet from the Ministry of Finance and METI, torestrainexpenditures.Insomeways,thisharksbacktoapatternidentifiedbyMakihara(2003)for the 1950s and early 1960s, in which officials from MOF and parts of other ministriesorientedtowardthecabinetcooperatedwithleadingLDPofficials(seealsoNakajima2007:127-129onlonger-termtrendstowardthedevelopmentof“cabinetbureaucrats.”). To be sure, pressures to boost spending, especially particularistic spending, welledwhenever theeconomyweakenedoranelection loomed, and seniorpoliticiansperiodicallygavevoicetothosedemands.NordidinfluentialLDPleadersalwaysseeeyetoeyewiththe

Page 23: Political-bureaucratic alliances for fiscal restraint in Japanjww.iss.u-tokyo.ac.jp/jss/pdf/jss6201_051076.pdfPolitical-bureaucratic alliances for fiscal restraint in Japan 53 (2)

Political-bureaucraticalliancesforfiscalrestraintinJapan

73

MinistryofFinance;evenKoizumiandthefiscalhawksoccasionallyclashedwithMOFandMETI bureaucrats. Yet the politicians with the reputations for serious and sustainedcommitmenttopolicyweregenerallyabletorelyonofficialssecondedfromMOFandMETItoimplementrestraintonexpenditures,andfrom2001untiltheLDPfellfrompowerin2009,fiscalstringencyandrestrictionofparticularisticspendingconsistentlywon. Ontherevenueside,weakerprimeministerswereactuallymorewillingthanKoizumitoconsidertaxincreases.Afteralongstruggle,thefiscalhawksdefeatedthetaxcutters,andaneliteconsensusemergedthattheconsumptiontaxshouldincreasetoatleast10percent.Themootedtaxhikewasblockednotbyweakleadershiporvetoplayersinthepoliticalsystem,butbytheelectorate,whichpunishedtheDPJ(andtoalesserextenttheLDP)forchampioningtheincreaseintheconsumptiontax. Rejectionoftheconsumptiontaxreflectedthepublic’sconflictedattitudetowardwelfarespending,andevenmoreitsskepticismabouttheeffectivenessandfairnessofgovernmentspending.Numeroussurveysoverthelastdecadehaveshownthatthemajorityofrespondentspreferhighbenefitstolowcosts(Takegawa2010).AnAsahi Shinbunpollfrom2008foundthepublicmoreevenlysplitonwhethertosupporta“hightax,highbenefit”model,ora“lowtax,low benefit” approach, but it showed that an overwhelming majority believed that thegovernment,ratherthanindividuals,boreprimaryresponsibilityforprovidinghealthcareandpensions (Asahi Shinbun July 26, 2008). Cabinet (2010) surveys also demonstrated theconsistentlyhighprioritythepublicplacedonpublicpensionsandhealthcare.Surprisingly,poorpeopleandwomenwerelesssupportiveofthehightax-highbenefitmodelthanweremenandthebetteroff,reflectingboththeburdenoftheweakeconomy,andthepoliticalrealitythatfordecadesthepoliticalsystemchanneledrevenuestofarmersandotherclientsoftheLDPratherthantothepopulationasawhole.Manypoorervotersappeartofearthattheywillpaythehigherconsumptiontaxes,butreceivefewbenefitsinreturn(Takegawa2010),afearthatiswell-supportedby theoverwhelmingevidenceof theparticularisticbiasof the JapanesewelfaresystemunderSNTV(Estevez-Abe2008). Inmanyways,developmentsinJapanresemblethoseintheUK,whereastrongerprimeministersurroundedby“primeministercliques”appeared:“Whilenotall-powerful,theprimeministercanbemorepowerfulasanindividualthanthecabinetcanbeasacollectivebody.TonyBlairmostcertainlyhasbeen"(Heffernan2005:40).Yettheprimeministerisnotalwayseffective,particularly ineconomicpolicy,asTonyBlairalsoproved,particularlyafter2003.Powerwasactuallywieldedbya“coreexecutive”spreadacrossanumberofagencies(RhodesandDunleavy1995),mostnotablytheTreasuryunderGordonBrown."TheBrown-Blairrivalryis not just about personalities and court politics. It is aboutwho controls theheart of themachineandtheTreasurywon” (FawcettandRhodes2007:102). It isnoteworthythatthechangesinBritainoccurreddespiteastableelectoralsystem.Rather,theincreasingpoweroftheprimeministerandtreasurerreflectedchangesinthedomesticpoliticalenvironment(thegrowthoftelevisionnewsandthedeclineinunionsandthesalienceofsocialclass)aswellas

Page 24: Political-bureaucratic alliances for fiscal restraint in Japanjww.iss.u-tokyo.ac.jp/jss/pdf/jss6201_051076.pdfPolitical-bureaucratic alliances for fiscal restraint in Japan 53 (2)

SpecialIssue:Onstructuraldevelopments,Koizumireforms,andthecollapseofLDPrule

74

Britain’s international situation (the emergence of the European Union and the increasingfrequencyofinternationalsummits).Similardevelopmentshavemarkedthelargemajorityofparliamentarysystems(PoguntkeandWebb2005). Japan--liketheUKafterBlair,Brown,andthefinancialcrisis—faceshugefiscaldeficits.TheshrinkingworkforceandthepressureofdeflationmeanthatJapanisconstantlyteeteringontheedgeofrecession,leadingtopopulardissatisfactionandevenmorereluctancetoraisetaxesthanintheUKorUS.UnliketheUKoreventheUS,however,Japanasanetcapitalexporterfaceslittleexternalpressuretoreform—atleastyet.UncertaintyaboutwhenJapan’sgravefiscalproblemscouldbecomeanactualcrisisalso inhibitsaction.Moreover, the latedevelopmentoftheconsumptiontaxmakesitmoredifficulttoreducethedeficitbyincreasingtaxesthanintheUKandmostEuropeancountries(Kato2003).Japan’sbicameralsystem,withits diverging electoral systems and lack of double dissolution, also raises the prospect ofgreater gridlock under divided government, as has occurred since 2007. Recent researchsuggeststhatdemocraticsystemscanprovesurprisinglyresponsive(seee.g.Kitscheltetal.2010onLatinAmericaandSorokaandWlezien2009onAnglo-Americancountries).JapanesevoterscanonlyhopethatthosefindingsproveapplicabletoJapanaswell. Ifso, influentialseniorpoliticiansandelitebureaucratsfromMOFandMETIarelikelytoplayacrucialroleinsupplementingtheinitiativesofprimeministers.

ReferencesAberbach,JoelD.,RobertD.Putnam,andBertA.Rockman.1981.Bureaucrats and Politicians in Western

Democracies.Cambridge,Mass.:HarvardUniversityPress.Alesina,Alberto,andGuidoTabellini.2007.BureaucratsorPoliticians?PartI:ASinglePolicyTaskAmerican

Economic Review97(1):169-179.Alesina,Alberto,andGuidoTabellini.2008.Bureaucratsorpoliticians?PartII:Multiplepolicytasks.Journal

of Public Economics92(3-4):426-447.Cabinet.2010.内閣府,国民生活に関する世論調査,図48,政府に対する要望atwww8cao.go.jp/survey/h22/h22-

life/z48.htmlCargill,ThomasF.,andTakayukiSakamoto.2008.Japan since 1980.Cambridge:CambridgeUniversityPress.RobertCaro.1974.The Power Broker: Robert Moses and the Fall of New York.NewYork:Knopf.Carpenter, Daniel P. 2001. The Forging of Bureaucratic Autonomy: Reputations, Networks, and Policy

Innovation in Executive Agencies, 1862-1928.Princeton:PrincetonUniversityPress.CEFP(CouncilonEconomicandFiscalPolicy).2001.「議事録(平成13年第11回)」.June21.Atwww5.cao.

go.jp/keizaishimon/minutes/2001/0621/minutes-s.pdfCEFP(CouncilonEconomicandFiscalPolicy).2002.「議事録(平成14年第26回)」.September9.CEFP(CouncilonEconomicandFiscalPolicy).2006.「経済財政改革に関する基本方針2006」。July7,2006.At

www5.cao.go.jp/keizaishimon/minutes/2006/0707/item1.pdfCox, Gary W., and Mathew D. McCubbins. 1993. Legislative Leviathan: Party Government in the House.

Berkeley:UniversityofCaliforniaPress.DemocraticPartyofJapan.2009.2009ChangeofGovernment.TheDemocraticPartyofJapan’sPlatformfor

Government.PuttingPeople’sLivesFirst.18August[Translationof民主党政権政策,July27,2009].Ehrhardt,George.2009.AdministrativeReforminEastAsia:TheImportanceofMultiplePrincipals.Asian

Survey49(4):625–646.

Page 25: Political-bureaucratic alliances for fiscal restraint in Japanjww.iss.u-tokyo.ac.jp/jss/pdf/jss6201_051076.pdfPolitical-bureaucratic alliances for fiscal restraint in Japan 53 (2)

Political-bureaucraticalliancesforfiscalrestraintinJapan

75

Epstein,David, andSharynO'Halloran.1999.Delegating Powers: A Transaction Cost Politics Approach to Policy Making under Separate Powers.Cambridge:CambridgeUniversityPress.

Estévez-Abe,Margarita.2008.Welfare and capitalism in postwar Japan. Cambridgestudiesincomparativepolitics.Cambridge:CambridgeUniversityPress.

Fawcett,Paul,andR.A.W.Rhodes.2007.CentralGovernment. InBlair's Britain, 1997-2007,editedbyA.Seldon.Cambridge:CambridgeUniversityPress.

Fujimura,Naofumi.2009.ExecutiveLeadershipandFiscalDiscipline:ExplainingPoliticalEntrepreneurshipinCasesofJapan.Japanese Journal of Political Science10(2):175-190.

Gilardi,Fabrizio.2008.Delegation in the Regulatory State: Independent Regulatory Agencies in Western Europe.Cheltenham:EdwardElgar.

Hallett,AndrewHughes,JanLibich,andPetrStehlik.2009.Rogoffrevisited:Theconservativecentralbankerpropositionunderactivefiscalpolicies.Economics Letters104(3):140-143.

Heffernan,Richard,andPaulWebb.2005.TheBritishPrimeMinister:MuchMorethan'FirstAmongEquals'.In The Presidentialization of Politics: A Comparative Study of Modern Democracies, edited by T.PoguntkeandP.Webb.NewYork:OxfordUniversityPress.

Huber, John D., and Charles R. Shipan. 2002. Deliberate Discretion? : The Institutional Foundations of Bureaucratic Autonomy.Cambridge:CambridgeUniversityPress.

Iijima.2006.飯島勲.小泉官邸秘録.東京:日本経済新聞社.Iio.2007.飯尾潤.日本の統治構造:官僚内閣制から議院内閣制へ.東京:中央公論新社.InoguchiandIwai.1987.猪口孝,岩井奉信 共著「族議員」の研究:自民党政権を牛耳る主役たち.東京:日

本経済新聞社.Johnson,DavidT.2002.The Japanese way of justice: prosecuting crime in Japan.NewYork:OxfordUniversity

Press.KabashimaIkuo蒲島郁夫,andOokawaChihiro大川千寿.2006.安倍晋三の研究[ResearchonAbeShinzo].世

界(11月):70-79.Kato, Junko. 2003. Regressive Taxation and the Welfare State: Path Dependence and Policy Diffusion.

Cambridge:CambridgeUniversityPress.Kitschelt,Herbert,KirkA.Hawkins,JuanPabloLuna,GuillermoRosas,andElizabethJ.Zechmeister.2010.

Latin American Party Systems.Cambridge:CambridgeUniversityPress.Köllner,Patrick.2006.TheLiberalDemocraticPartyat50:SourcesofDominanceandChangesintheKoizumi

Era.Social Science Japan Journal9(2):243-257.LDP(LiberalDemocraticParty).自由民主党財政改革研究会「財政改革研究会の中間とりまとめ」(平成19年

11月21日)Atwww.jimin.jp/jimin/seisaku/2007/pdf/seisaku-026.pdfMasuyama Mikitaka 増山幹高. 2003. 議会制度と日本政治: 議事運営の計量政治学 (Agenda power in the

Japanese Diet).東京:木鐸社.McCubbins,MathewD.,andGregoryW.Noble.1995.PerceptionsandRealitiesofJapaneseBudgeting. In

Structure and Policy in Japan and the United States,editedbyPeterCowheyandMathewD.McCubbins.Cambridge:CambridgeUniversityPress.

Miller,GaryJ.2005.ThePoliticalEvolutionofPrincipal-AgentModels.Annual Review of Political Science8:203–25.

MinistryofFinance.2010.我が国の財政事情「22年度予算政府案」.Moe,TerryM.2006.PoliticalControlandthePoweroftheAgent.Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization

22(1):1-29.NakagawaHidenao中川秀直.2006.「上げ潮の時代:GDP1000兆円計画」東京:講談社.NakagawaHidenao中川秀直.2008.官僚国家の崩壊TheCollapseoftheBureaucraticState.東京:講談社.Nakajima,Makoto中島誠.2007.立法学—序論・立法過程論新版.京都:法律文化社.Noble,GregoryW.2010.TheDeclineofParticularisminJapanesePolitics.Journal Of East Asian Studies10

(2):239-273.

Page 26: Political-bureaucratic alliances for fiscal restraint in Japanjww.iss.u-tokyo.ac.jp/jss/pdf/jss6201_051076.pdfPolitical-bureaucratic alliances for fiscal restraint in Japan 53 (2)

SpecialIssue:Onstructuraldevelopments,Koizumireforms,andthecollapseofLDPrule

76

OECD(Organization forEconomicCooperationandDevelopment).2008.Economic Survey of Japan 2008: Achieving progress on fiscal consolidation by controlling government expenditures.Paris:OECD

OECD 2010a “Annex Table 33. General government net financial liabilities” at www.oecd.org/dataoecd/5/51/2483816.xls

OECD 2010b. “Total expenditure of general government, percentage ofGDP,” inNationalAccounts at aGlance—2009edition.http://stats.oecd.org./index.aspx

Ota,Hiroko大田弘子.2006.経済財政諮問会議の戦い.東京:東洋経済新報社.Poguntke,Thomas,andPaulWebb,eds.2005.The Presidentialization of Politics: A Comparative Study of

Modern Democracies.Oxford:OxfordUniversityPress.Ramseyer,J.Mark,andFrancesMcCallRosenbluth.1993.Japan's Political Marketplace.Cambridge:Harvard

UniversityPress.Rhodes, R.A.W., and Patrick Dunleavy, eds. 1995. Prime Minister, Cabinet and Core Executive. London:

Macmillan.Rosenbluth,FrancesMcCall,andMichaelF.Thies.2010.Japan Transformed: Political Change and Economic

Restructuring.Princeton:PrincetonUniversityPress.SatoandMatsuzaki.1986.佐藤誠三郎,松崎哲久 共著「自民党政権」東京:中央公論社.SatōMasaru佐藤優.2010.“石川議員が僕に語ったこと.”中大公論 三月号.Shimizu Masato, 清水真人. 2005. 官邸指導:小泉純一郎の革命 [Cabinet Leadership: Koizumi Jun'ichiro's

Revolution].東京:日本経済新聞社.Shimizu,Masato清水真人.2009.首相の蹉跌―ポスト小泉権力の黄昏.東京:日本経済新聞出版社.Shinoda,Tomohito.2005.Japan'sCabinetSecretariatanditsEmergenceasCoreExecutive.Asian Survey45

(5):800-821.ShiotaUshio塩田潮.2005.「竹中平蔵の挑戦:政治を目指した学者の軌跡(中):政策の決定権を巡る霞ヶ関と

の攻防戦」論座(12月):111-121.Soroka,StuartN.,andChristopherWlezien.2009.Degrees of Democracy: Politics, Public Opinion, and Policy.

Cambridge:CambridgeUniversityPress.Steinmo, Sven. 2010. The Evolution of Modern States: Sweden, Japan, and the United States. New York:

CambridgeUniversityPress.TakahashiYoichi高橋洋一.2008.さらば財務省!官僚すべてを敵にした男の告白.東京:講談社.Takenaka,Heizo.2008.The Structural Reforms of the Koizumi Cabinet: an Insider's Account of the Economic

Revival of Japan.TranslatedbyJillianYorke.Tokyo:NikkeiPublishing.Originallypublishedas構造改革の真実:竹中平蔵大臣日誌(東京:日本経済新聞社,2006).

Tsuji.1969.辻清明.日本官僚制の研究.東京大学出版会.Wood, B. Dan andRichardW.Waterman. 1994. BureaucraticDyanamics: TheRole of Bureaucracy in a

Democracy.Boulder:Westview.Uchiyama,Yū.2010.Koizumi and Japanese Politics: Reform Strategies and Leadership Style.Translatedby

CarlFreire.NewYork:Routledge.Originallypublishedas小泉政権―「パトスの首相」は何を変えたのか(東京:中大公論社,2007).

Yosano.2008.与謝野馨.堂々たる政治.東京:新潮社.Zimring.FranklinE.,GordonHawkinsandSamKamin.2001.PunishmentandDemocracy:ThreeStrikesand

You’reOutinCalifornia.Oxford:OxfordUniversityPress.政治改革推進協議会(民間政治臨調).総選挙にむけての緊急アピール.平成8年10月1日