price elasticity of energy demand according to poverty condition: … · 2019. 12. 16. · price...

22
1 Price elasticity of energy demand according to poverty condition: the case of Mexican Households Araceli Ortega Díaz 1 Kenneth Medlock 2 (DRAFT) Abstract The price elasticities demand of electricity, gas, oil fuel, gasoline and steam coal are estimated using household surveys from 1992 to 2014. The analysis uses alternative econometric techniques, from OLS, SURE to Quadratic Almost Ideal Demand System QUAIDS- based in the methodology of Banks, Blundell and Lewbel considering socioeconomic characteristics of the households to account for the difference in demand of energy related goods. It is found that fuels are price inelastic, and the differences in elasticities between poor and non-poor households are small but statically significant. Income elasticities are elastic, and the differences are higher between poor and non-poor household. Consequently, there would be a differentiated reaction of consumers to changes in energy prices according to their poverty status. We also found that income elasticities are positive, an increase in income would increase energy goods consumption except for steam coal and firewood which could be considered inferior goods. The contribution of the elasticities obtained in this study would help policy makers to perform the necessary welfare household analysis applying changes in energy prices given the current fiscal and energy reform that Mexico is implementing. Key Words: QUAIDs, Energy Price Elasticities, Poverty JEL D120 D300 Q410 I320 1. Introduction Provision of basic services to all population in Mexico has been steadily increasing in the last decades. Nevertheless, the access that is provided to substantial percentage of the population comes from government monopolies, with pricing schemes highly regulated which entails low quality services. For instance, electricity blackouts have occurred in major areas of the country when there is high use of power; potable water is not provided to all municipalities and some communities have not pipelines to receive natural gas so they 1 [email protected], School of Government of Tecnológico de Monterrey. This research was finished while being an academic visitor at the Center for Energy Studies of the Baker Institute of Public Policy. The author thanks to the support of Puentes Consortium, the research assistance of Perla Arellano in the first stages of this paper and the Statistical Office ( INEGI) for their support in clarifying coding. 2 James A. Baker III Institute for Public Policy, Rice University, United States.

Upload: others

Post on 15-Sep-2020

3 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Price elasticity of energy demand according to poverty condition: … · 2019. 12. 16. · Price elasticity of energy demand according to poverty condition: the case of Mexican Households

1

Price elasticity of energy demand according to poverty condition: the case of Mexican

Households

Araceli Ortega Díaz1

Kenneth Medlock2

(DRAFT)

Abstract

The price elasticities demand of electricity, gas, oil fuel, gasoline and steam coal are

estimated using household surveys from 1992 to 2014. The analysis uses alternative

econometric techniques, from OLS, SURE to Quadratic Almost Ideal Demand System –

QUAIDS- based in the methodology of Banks, Blundell and Lewbel considering

socioeconomic characteristics of the households to account for the difference in demand of

energy related goods. It is found that fuels are price inelastic, and the differences in

elasticities between poor and non-poor households are small but statically significant.

Income elasticities are elastic, and the differences are higher between poor and non-poor

household. Consequently, there would be a differentiated reaction of consumers to changes

in energy prices according to their poverty status. We also found that income elasticities are

positive, an increase in income would increase energy goods consumption except for steam

coal and firewood which could be considered inferior goods. The contribution of the

elasticities obtained in this study would help policy makers to perform the necessary

welfare household analysis applying changes in energy prices given the current fiscal and

energy reform that Mexico is implementing.

Key Words: QUAIDs, Energy Price Elasticities, Poverty

JEL D120 D300 Q410 I320

1. Introduction

Provision of basic services to all population in Mexico has been steadily increasing in the

last decades. Nevertheless, the access that is provided to substantial percentage of the

population comes from government monopolies, with pricing schemes highly regulated

which entails low quality services. For instance, electricity blackouts have occurred in

major areas of the country when there is high use of power; potable water is not provided to

all municipalities and some communities have not pipelines to receive natural gas so they

1 [email protected], School of Government of Tecnológico de Monterrey. This research was finished

while being an academic visitor at the Center for Energy Studies of the Baker Institute of Public Policy. The

author thanks to the support of Puentes Consortium, the research assistance of Perla Arellano in the first

stages of this paper and the Statistical Office ( INEGI) for their support in clarifying coding. 2 James A. Baker III Institute for Public Policy, Rice University, United States.

Page 2: Price elasticity of energy demand according to poverty condition: … · 2019. 12. 16. · Price elasticity of energy demand according to poverty condition: the case of Mexican Households

2

keep using alternative sources of lighting, heating and cooking.3 However, the percentage

of the population connected to the electricity grid has increased 70 percentage points in the

last 55 years (See in Graph 1).

Graph 1. Tendency of household access to basic services

Source: Authors´ own elaboration using data from INEGI.4

Electricity is provided by a regulated institution of the Mexican government called Federal

Commission of Electricity (CFE), past research using CFE tariffs and average consumption

has shown that short run price elasticities range from -0.348 at national level to -0.036 at

pooled-regional level, and in the long run -0.811 to -0.107 respectively (Berndt &

Samaniego, 1984).

The prices of gasoline are regulated by PEMEX, the National petroleum company, which is

a State Monopoly. The household’s consumption of gasoline and diesel is highly

influenced by using public or private transportation. Public transport in Mexico is

expensive compare to its quality, it is also insecure, obsolete and unreliable, has bad

coverage, and its closest substitute is private shuttles that operate without quality control.

3 In fact, many poverty studies in Mexico use the variable “ownership of an electro domestic appliance” as

proxy of electricity infrastructure in the area, the same happened with the variable “ownership of a gas

stove”. 4 INEGI is the National Institute of Statistic and Geographical Information in Mexico.

Page 3: Price elasticity of energy demand according to poverty condition: … · 2019. 12. 16. · Price elasticity of energy demand according to poverty condition: the case of Mexican Households

3

When income increases, household invest in buying a car rather than using public transport.

(Crôtte, Noland, & Graham, 2010) found that price elasticities of gasoline change over time

and differ between the national and local levels, with smaller price responses in Mexico

City where the long run price elasticity oscillates from -0.2 to -0.26, while previous

gasoline demand surveys mainly based on country data report average elasticities between -

0.6 and -0.8. These authors calculate the use of transport measured by the traffic in Mexico

City, and found that the combined elasticities of income and vehicle stock are close to

unity, and the elasticity for metro fares is negligible, which suggests little substitution

between transport types (Crôtte, Noland, & Graham, 2009).

Gas is use for cooking and heating all over the country, but households in the rural areas

use substituted like firewood or fuel oil. Provision of Natural gas is outsourced, and Mexico

has become a major imported of natural gas, the price of the service has increased in the

last years. (Bacon, Bhattacharya, & Kojima, 2010) point out that to study the wellbeing of

households it is necessary to analyze the patterns of expenditure on electricity, petroleum

products (kerosene, gasoline, diesel, and liquefied petroleum gas), natural gas, and transport

at different income levels and in rural and urban areas, and whether household can afford

the these services and good in case of a price or subsidy change.

In general, available studies for Mexico regarding energy demand are concentrated at sector

level and not at household level. For instance, (Galindo, 2005) use annual data for the

period 1965–2001 of sectoral energy consumption in agriculture, industry, residential and

transport taking a relative price energy index calculated as the ratio between the energy

price index of electricity and fuels and the consumer price index finding that “demand for

energy is driven by income and that the effect of the relative prices is basically

concentrated on the short run with the exception of the industrial sector, which also shows

a long-term price impact.”

The aim of this paper is to calculate, for first time to our knowledge, the price elasticity of

demand for energy goods for poor and non-poor households using household surveys and

real prices of energy fuels. In doing so we summarized in the next section the price

Page 4: Price elasticity of energy demand according to poverty condition: … · 2019. 12. 16. · Price elasticity of energy demand according to poverty condition: the case of Mexican Households

4

elasticity literature to calculate short and long terms elasticities using different types of data

bases and methods. In section 3 we explain the methods and the data in section 4. Section 5

presents the results, section 6 the discussion and section 7 the conclusion and policy

recommendations.

2. Previous Literature

There are several meta-analyses about the estimated elasticities for energy fuels, most of

them for gas, gasoline and heating oil. These analysis for the range of elasticities is

explained by the difference in estimation methods (cross-section, time series or panel),

functional forms of estimated equations (linear, quadratic, systems), datasets used

(household surveys, enterprise data, governments reports, etc.),

According to (Miller & Alberini, 2016), price elasticities of energy (electricity) vary due to

several factors: sample period, level of aggregation, use of different econometric techniques

that account for heterogeneity or endogeneity, and inclusion of household characteristics.

The studies they revise, and their own calculations use linear specifications, and found

energy elasticities for USA are ranging from -1.11 to -0.08, and from -1.25 to -0.07 in some

OECD countries.

(Hansen, 2018) found that energy elasticities for heating are important in household

everyday life decisions, and the effects are stronger in higher income households. The

elasticities in USA, UK and Norway range from -0.73 to -0.02.

(Dahl, 2012) revised 240 studies in more than 70 countries on income and price elasticities

of demand for transport fuels, they all use linear regressions, removing outliers that have

found even positive elasticities, the modal range if (-0.41 to 0). For Mexico is -0.31

(gasoline) and -0.30 (diesel).

(Labandeira, Labeaga, & López-Otero, 2017) conducted a meta-analysis on the price

elasticity of energy demand (electricity, transport fuels and heating fuels) which range from

(-1.65, 0.63) in the short term and (-61.11, +1.03) in the long term.

Page 5: Price elasticity of energy demand according to poverty condition: … · 2019. 12. 16. · Price elasticity of energy demand according to poverty condition: the case of Mexican Households

5

Some estimations using panel data from 1982 to 1988, for annual expenditure of gasoline

of car owners at State level, found an estimate of -0.6 for the own-price elasticity of

gasoline in the short-term and elasticity estimates of 1.25 to - 1.13 for five- to ten-year

periods. Elasticities coincide with those estimated for gas/gasoline/turbosine demand for

railroad, air transport and motor vehicle modes that range from -0.17 in the short run to -

0.96 in the long run (Berndt & Botero, 1985). The authors created a fuel price index for

railroad, using the transformed quantities of the two fuels (diesel and combustoleo for

1960-79), in the case of air transportation they use a system of equations combining

domestic and foreign demand for jet fuel, and for moto vehicles the data is pooled cross-

section and time-series for the 32 states for 1973-78.

In the current paper we are not only accounting for all the factors mentioned above but in

addition we consider linear and quadratic functional forms, and we estimate the price and

income elasticities for each good separately with OLS, and simultaneously for all using

QUAIDs. We also account for regional differences and climate variables that affect the use

of fuels. The general objective is to estimate a consistent set of price elasticities using

products that include transport fuels, non-transport fuel, fuel appliances, public transport,

and private transport considering the factors pointed as relevant in previous studies and

summarized in Table 1.

Table 1. Factors considered as relevant when calculating price and income elasticities

Factors Previous Studies Our Research

Sample period: short / long term X X

Level of aggregation: household vs region X X

Product aggregation One product One product / Basket product

Linear regression/Quadratic linear both

Page 6: Price elasticity of energy demand according to poverty condition: … · 2019. 12. 16. · Price elasticity of energy demand according to poverty condition: the case of Mexican Households

6

Factors Previous Studies Our Research

Whole Household Budget Simultaneous estimation

X

Endogeneity (IV estimation) X X

Household Characteristics X X

Poverty Condition

X

Climate / Regional Characteristics Few X

Source: Author´s own classification.

3. Methodology

The methodology of (Banks, Blundell, & Lewbel, 1997) is the more suitable for the

purpose of this research because it takes into account social characteristics of the agents.

The indirect utility used is the following:

1

1

ln( ) ln( ( )ln ( , ) ( )

( )

m a pV p m p

b p

−− −

= +

where ip is the price of good i , 0,1,...,i n= , ( )b p is the function that aggregate prices

0

( ) i

n

i

i

b p p

=

= , 0

( ) lnn

i i

i

p p =

= and ln( ( ))a p the transcendent logarithmic function

defined as:

0

0 0 0

1ln( ( )) ln( ) ln( ) ln( )

2

n n n

i i ij i k

i i j

a p p p p = = =

= + +

Subject to homogeneity restrictions and Slutsky equation:

0

0n

i

i

=

= , 0

0n

i

i

=

= , 0

0n

ij

j

=

= , ij ji = , y

0

1n

i

i

=

=

We define i=0 as the rest of the expenditure, iq denotes the quantity consumed of each

good i=0,1,…,n such that i ii

p qw

m= is the percentage in monetary terms spent in each good

Page 7: Price elasticity of energy demand according to poverty condition: … · 2019. 12. 16. · Price elasticity of energy demand according to poverty condition: the case of Mexican Households

7

with respect to the total expenditures, subject to 0

1n

i

i

w=

= . Following (Banks et al., 1997)

and Roy´s identity we obtain each participation i=0,1,…,n :

2

0

ln( ) ln ln( ) ( ) ( )

ni

i i ij i

j

m mw p

a p b p a p

=

= + + +

m is the expenditures of the households. Next, we incorporate the poverty variable, and

other socioeconomic characteristics denoted as z . Then the expenditure function can be

written as ( , )Re p u for a household.

We can transform this equation to be rewritten in econometric terms

as 0( , , ) ( ) ( , , )e p z u m z p z u=

Where 0 ( ) 1 ´m z z= + measures the increments in the expenditure of the household as a

function of poverty z, and the second term controls the consumption patterns or

participations.

( )´

0 0

0

1ln( ( , , ))

1ln( )

j jn n z

j jj j

n

j jj

p pp z u

pu

= =

=

−=

The jth Colum of parameters is j and the equation of expenditure for each good is:

2

0 0 0

ln ( ´ ) ln ln( ) ( ) ( ) ( , ) ( ) ( )

ni

i i ij j i j

j

m mw p z

m z a p b p c p z m z a p

=

= + + + +

with ´

0

( , ) j

nz

j

j

c p z p

=

= , 0

0n

rj

j

=

= , 0,1,...,i n=

Elasticities are estimated assuming symmetry in the Slustky equation, and where the non-

compensated elasticities of good i with respect to a change in price j are:

( )

00

2

0

2´ ln ln

( ) ( , ) ( ) ( )1

´ln

( ) ( , ) ( ) ( )

ni

ij i j j ij j

j

ij ij

ii j i

mz p

b p c p z m z a p

w z m

b p c p z m z a p

=

− + + +

= +

+ −

And the compensated are C

ij ij i jw = + with i being the income elasticity of good i.

In addition, we estimate the elasticities using OLS regression for each good separately and

Seemingly Unrelated Estimators.

Page 8: Price elasticity of energy demand according to poverty condition: … · 2019. 12. 16. · Price elasticity of energy demand according to poverty condition: the case of Mexican Households

8

4. Data

We use the national survey of income and expenditure of households (ENIGH) conducted

by the national statistical office (INEGI) which is a biannual survey since 1992 that share

the same methodology from 1992 to 2014 and includes an extra survey for the year 2005.

This survey is a cross section because does not interview the same households over time. It

is representative at national, regional and rural/urban strata. From 2008 the survey became

representative at the state level for some household expenditures in goods use to calculate

the official poverty lines, and from 2016 the methodology changed (CONEVAL, 2018).

We coded all expenditures on services and good across the years to make them comparable,

see Table A1 in the appendix. One common feature in consumption of energy is that

respondents report the consumption but the price and quantity consumed were absent

(Deaton, 1997) , in that case we use unit prices from the IEA for the period 1992 to 2014.

We do not use prices beyond 2014, see Graph 2.

Graph 2. Selected Nominal Fuel Prices (IEA)

Source: Authors´own elaboration using prices from IEA.

We use the official definition of income poverty which count as poor all households which

income is not enough to buy altogether: the food basket, education, health, transport,

Page 9: Price elasticity of energy demand according to poverty condition: … · 2019. 12. 16. · Price elasticity of energy demand according to poverty condition: the case of Mexican Households

9

housing and clothing using all their income, that accounts for around 50% of the population

of Mexico in the period of analysis (see Table 2), this type is known as Patrimony poverty

(CONEVAL, 2009).

Table 2. Poverty in Income Poverty

Year Millions of people (%)

1992 46.1 53.1

1994 47.0 52.4

1996 64.0 69.0

1998 60.7 63.7

2000 52.7 53.6

2002 50.4 50.0

2004 48.6 47.2

2005 48.9 47.0

2006 46.5 42.9

2008 53.4 47.8

2010 58.5 51.1

2012 61.4 52.3

2014 66.1 55.1

2016 64.9 52.9

When we calculate the expenditure share on different fuels across the years and the

behavior of the prices, we observe that the expenditures shares for poor and non-poor

households for the year 2004 have an outlier behavior, so we decided to exclude that survey

given that estimations where unstable, even when we split the periods, see the set of Graphs

3.

Graph 3. Expenditure shares and prices for non-poor and poor households (prices at 2010

base)

0.0%

0.5%

1.0%

1.5%

2.0%

2.5%

3.0%

3.5%

4.0%

4.5%

0

200

400

600

800

1000

1200

1400

1600

Me

an E

xpe

nd

itu

re s

har

e

pe

so/M

Wh

Electricity-np

pcalc1 w1

0.0%

0.5%

1.0%

1.5%

2.0%

2.5%

3.0%

3.5%

4.0%

4.5%

0

200

400

600

800

1000

1200

1400

1600

Me

an E

xpe

nd

itu

re s

har

e

pe

so/M

Wh

Electricity-p

pcalc1 w1

Page 10: Price elasticity of energy demand according to poverty condition: … · 2019. 12. 16. · Price elasticity of energy demand according to poverty condition: the case of Mexican Households

10

0.00%

0.50%

1.00%

1.50%

2.00%

2.50%

3.00%

0

50

100

150

200

250

300

350

400

450

500

Me

an E

xpe

nd

itu

re S

har

e

Pe

so/M

Wh

Gas-np

pcalc2 w2

0.00%

0.50%

1.00%

1.50%

2.00%

2.50%

3.00%

0

50

100

150

200

250

300

350

400

450

500

Me

an E

xpe

nd

itu

re S

har

e

Pe

so/M

Wh

Gas-p

pcalc2 w2

0.0%

0.0%

0.0%

0.1%

0.1%

0.1%

0.1%

0

1

2

3

4

5

6

7

8

9

Me

an E

xpe

nd

itu

re S

har

e

Pe

so/L

itre

Light Fuel Oil - np

pcalc3 w3

0.0%

0.1%

0.1%

0.2%

0.2%

0.3%

0.3%

0.4%

0.4%

0.5%

0.5%

0

1

2

3

4

5

6

7

8

9

Me

an E

xpe

nd

itu

re S

har

e

Pe

so/L

itre

Light Fuel Oil -p

pcalc3 w3

0.0%

0.1%

0.1%

0.2%

0.2%

0.3%

0.3%

0.4%

0

50

100

150

200

250

Me

an E

xpe

nd

itu

re S

har

e

Pe

so/K

g

Steam Coal-np

pcalc4 w4

0.0%

0.1%

0.2%

0.3%

0.4%

0.5%

0.6%

0.7%

0.8%

0.9%

1.0%

0

50

100

150

200

250

Me

an E

xpe

nd

itu

re S

har

e

Pe

so/K

g

Steam Coal-p

pcalc4 w4

0.0%

0.0%

0.0%

0.1%

0.1%

0.1%

0.1%

0.1%

0.2%

0.2%

0

200

400

600

800

1000

1200

1400

1600

Me

an E

xpe

nd

itu

re s

har

e

Pe

sos

Fuel Appliances - np

pcalc5 w5

0.0%

0.0%

0.0%

0.1%

0.1%

0.1%

0.1%

0.1%

0.2%

0

200

400

600

800

1000

1200

1400

Me

an E

xpe

nd

itu

re s

har

e

Pe

sos

Fuel Appliances- p

pcalc5 w5

0.0%

1.0%

2.0%

3.0%

4.0%

5.0%

6.0%

7.0%

0

200

400

600

800

1000

1200

Me

an E

xpe

nd

itu

re S

har

e

Pe

sos

Public Transport - np

pcalc6 w6

0.0%

1.0%

2.0%

3.0%

4.0%

5.0%

6.0%

7.0%

8.0%

0

100

200

300

400

500

600

700

Me

an E

xpe

nd

itu

re S

har

e

Pe

sos

Public Transport -p

pcalc6 w6

Page 11: Price elasticity of energy demand according to poverty condition: … · 2019. 12. 16. · Price elasticity of energy demand according to poverty condition: the case of Mexican Households

11

0.0%

0.5%

1.0%

1.5%

2.0%

2.5%

3.0%

0

500

1000

1500

2000

2500

3000

3500

4000

4500

Me

an E

xpe

nd

itu

re S

har

e

Pe

sos

Private Transport - np

pcalc7 w7

0.0%

0.1%

0.2%

0.3%

0.4%

0.5%

0.6%

0.7%

0.8%

0.9%

0

500

1000

1500

2000

2500

3000

3500

Me

an E

xpe

nd

itu

re S

har

e

Pe

sos

Private Transport - p

pcalc7 w7

0.0%

1.0%

2.0%

3.0%

4.0%

5.0%

6.0%

7.0%

0

50

100

150

200

250

Me

an E

xpe

nd

itu

re S

har

e

Pe

sos/

Litr

e

Gasoline - np

pcalc8 w8

0.0%

0.5%

1.0%

1.5%

2.0%

2.5%

3.0%

0

20

40

60

80

100

120

140

Me

an E

xpe

nd

itu

re S

har

e

Pe

sos/

Litr

e

Gasoline - p

pcalc8 w8

0.78

0.8

0.82

0.84

0.86

0.88

0.9

0.92

0.94

0

50

100

150

200

250

300

350

400

Me

an E

xoe

nd

itu

re S

har

e

Pe

sos

Rest of the Budget - np

pcalc9 w9

0.82

0.84

0.86

0.88

0.9

0.92

0.94

0.96

0

50

100

150

200

250

Me

an E

xoe

nd

itu

re S

har

e

Pe

sos

Rest of the Budget - p

pcalc9 w9

We also test whether the expenditure behavior in the different fuels was the same for poor

and non-poor households, and all the results show they are different. See Table 3.

Table 3. Two-sample t test with unequal variances of expenditure shares between poor and

non-poor

Fuel Non-poor Poor Diff. T.test p-vaue

1- Electricity (Household) 0.0315 0.0307 0.0008 4.1506 0

2- Natural Gas (EGEN) 0.0226 0.0233 -0.0007 -4.9579 0

3- Light Fuel Oil (Industry) 0.0001 0.0007 -0.0006 -20.6868 0

4- Steam Coal (EGEN), Firewood and other fuels 0.0022 0.0069 -0.0048 -54.4896 0

5- Fuel appliances 0.0012 0.0008 0.0003 8.6657 0

6- Public Transport 0.0540 0.0616 -0.0075 -22.5653 0

7- Private Transport 0.0206 0.0052 0.0153 66.6484 0

8- Gasoline 0.042759 0.0185 0.0242 99.3259 0

9- Rest of the budget 0.8251 0.8521 -0.0270 -54.5481 0

Note: Observation for non-poor are 122,648 and 102,764 for poor.

Page 12: Price elasticity of energy demand according to poverty condition: … · 2019. 12. 16. · Price elasticity of energy demand according to poverty condition: the case of Mexican Households

12

5. Estimation Results

To investigate how robust were the elasticities estimates we use different periods, using different methods and test for the significance

among the different elasticities. All estimations are available on request from the authors and they include the estimation of QUAIDS

for the whole period 1992 to 2014, or the same period excluding 2004 which behaves as an outlier in the prices and expenditures, also

for the periods 1992 to 2006 (excluding 2004) and the period 2008 to 2014. We consider that the most stable elasticities are shown in

Table 4, and the estimation of coefficients in the Appendix.

Table 4. Estimation results of price and income elasticities

HH Surveys Mexico 1992-2014 (exl. 2004) Estimates of own price elasticities of demand (QUAIDS) without 2004 Income elasticities

Poor

uncompensated

Poor

compensated

Non-Poor

uncompensated

Non-Poor

compensated Poor Non-Poor

1- Electricity (Household) -0.71 -0.69 -0.72 -0.70 0.44 0.23

2- Natural Gas (EGEN) -0.84 -0.82 -0.83 -0.81 0.92 0.84

3- Light Fuel Oil (Industry)* -0.57 -0.57 1.18 1.18 0.77 0.46

4- Steam Coal (EGEN), Firewood and other fuels -0.65 -0.65 0.09 0.09 0.24 -0.36

5- Fuel appliances* -0.89 -0.89 -0.92 -0.92 1.01 1.01

6- Public Transport -0.83 -0.76 -0.78 -0.71 1.30 1.30

7- Private Transport -0.08 -0.06 -0.76 -0.72 2.71 2.29

8- Gasoline -1.00 -0.97 -1.00 -0.94 1.21 1.18

9- Rest of the budget -0.95 -0.12 -0.94 -0.14 0.98 0.99

Source: Authors ‘own calculations. * Non statistically significant.

The price elasticities for light fuel oil are not statistically significant, neither for fuel appliances which includes electric stove. The

price elasticities of steam coal and private transport have the higher differences between poor and non-poor household. Light fuel oil is

inelastic for poor families but elastic for non-poor, then steam coal and private transport behave in the opposite way even if they all are

inelastic. In the case of income elasticities, it stands out that steam coal is an inferior good. The income elasticity of fuel appliances,

Page 13: Price elasticity of energy demand according to poverty condition: … · 2019. 12. 16. · Price elasticity of energy demand according to poverty condition: the case of Mexican Households

13

transport and gasoline is elastic, in contract with electricity , natural gas and light fuel oil which are inelastic (see Table 4 and Graph

4).

Graph 4. Price and income Elasticities of Energy Goods (QUAIDS) 1992-2014 (excl. 2004)

-0.7

1

-0.8

4 -0.5

7

-0.6

5

-0.8

9

-0.8

3

-0.0

8

-1.0

0

-0.9

5-0.6

9

-0.8

2 -0.5

7

-0.6

5

-0.8

9

-0.7

6

-0.0

6

-0.9

7

-0.1

2

-0.7

2

-0.8

3

1.1

8

0.0

9

-0.9

2

-0.7

8

-0.7

6

-1.0

0

-0.9

4-0.7

0

-0.8

1

1.1

8

0.0

9

-0.9

2

-0.7

1

-0.7

2

-0.9

4

-0.1

4

0.4

4

0.9

2

0.7

7

0.2

4

1.0

1 1.3

0

2.7

1

1.2

1

0.9

8

0.2

3

0.8

4

0.4

6

-0.3

6

1.0

1 1.3

0

2.2

9

1.1

8

0.9

9

-1.50

-1.00

-0.50

0.00

0.50

1.00

1.50

2.00

2.50

3.00

1-

Ele

ctr

icit

y (

Ho

use

hold

)

2-

Nat

ura

l G

as

(EG

EN

)

3-

Lig

ht F

uel

Oil

(In

du

stry

)

4-

Ste

am

Coal

(EG

EN

), F

irew

ood a

nd

oth

er f

uel

s

5-

Fu

el a

ppli

ance

s

6-

Pu

bli

c T

ransp

ort

7-

Pri

vat

e T

ransp

ort

8-

Gas

oli

ne

9-

Rest

of

the

budg

et

Poor uncompensated Poor compensated Non-Poor uncompensated

Non Poor compensated Income elasticity Poor Income elasticity Non-poor

Graph 5. Difference Poor minus Non-poor demand elasticities (QUAIDS) without 2004

Page 14: Price elasticity of energy demand according to poverty condition: … · 2019. 12. 16. · Price elasticity of energy demand according to poverty condition: the case of Mexican Households

14

0.014

-0.006

-1.746

-0.737

0.034

-0.051

0.667

-0.029

0.018

-2.000 -1.500 -1.000 -0.500 0.000 0.500 1.000

1- Electricity (Household)

2- Natural Gas (EGEN)

3- Light Fuel Oil (Industry)

4- Steam Coal (EGEN), Firewood and other fuels

5- Fuel appliances

6- Public Transport

7- Private Transport

8- Gasoline

9- Rest of the budget

(Poor - Non Poor) compensated (Poor - Non Poor) uncompensated

Source: Authors ‘own elaboration.

Page 15: Price elasticity of energy demand according to poverty condition: … · 2019. 12. 16. · Price elasticity of energy demand according to poverty condition: the case of Mexican Households

15

The estimations were also calculated using Almost ideal demand systems, SUREG and

OLS, varying periods and including/excluding outliers. From all estimations, we compute

the minimum and maximum elasticities and summaries them in Table 5.

Table 5. Summary or price elasticities using QUAIDS, AIDS, SUREG and OLS

HH Surveys Mexico 1992-2014

Summary of estimations Min Max

1- Electricity (Household) -0.86 0.58

2- Natural Gas (EGEN) -0.90 0.90

3- Light Fuel Oil (Industry)* -1.08 1.18

4- Steam Coal (EGEN), Firewood and other

fuels -0.72 0.35

5- Fuel appliances* -0.93 0.99

6- Public Transport -0.85 1.23

7- Private Transport -0.79 2.25

8- Gasoline -1.01 1.14

9- Rest of the budget -0.97 1.01

Source: Authors ‘own calculations. * Non statistically significant.

6. Discussion

The estimation of elasticities shows that price elasticity demand for fuels is in general

inelastic, which mean household keep using the fuel even when price increases. Income

elasticity for non-transport fuels is inelastic, but elastic for transport. Poor and non-poor

household respond differently to steam coal prices which seems to be an inferior good, the

higher the income the less household use this fuel to heat or cook.

Elasticities in those ranges seem plausible as fuel is used with a saturation point, once

household have reached, they basic needs of fuel to cook, heath and transport, they will not

use more of it. We can see that across time that expenditure shares on fuel and transport do

not surpass 18% of their total budget. In fact it is approximately 10% for transport and

gasoline and 7% for non-transport fuels, which is analogous to what (Bacon et al., 2010)

found for several developing countries. This saturation point is twofold, it has the

advantage that when prices fall of subsidies increase on fuels, the households can save

money or see it to buy other goods, but the disadvantage of being price-inelastic is that they

Page 16: Price elasticity of energy demand according to poverty condition: … · 2019. 12. 16. · Price elasticity of energy demand according to poverty condition: the case of Mexican Households

16

would need to decrease their consumption on other good to keep paying fuel goods and

services.

In several discussions of poverty energy, considering it as the percentage of people that has

access due to the existence of infrastructure and providers, but cannot afford it, increasing

prices without assessing the impact may decrease household wellbeing throe three sources:

reduce consumption of other goods, health worsen due to the use of fuel cheap substitutes

like coal and firewood, and pollution due to the use of low quality transport providers.

7. Conclusions and Policy Recommendation

Using household survey data for Mexico in the period 1992 to 2014, the elasticities for six

fuels and two transport services were estimated using QUAIDS methodology, which

indicated that price elasticities across poor and non-poor households are inelastic. This

elasticities complement the study of (Bacon et al., 2010) whose work point to the

usefulness of having elasticities to take public policy recommendation about taxes and

subsidies for fuels across different income types.

Expenditure patters on fuels between poo and non-poor households are similar, but the

amounts spend are statistically different. The higher differences are observed in the amount

spend in coal and firewood, public and private transport, as well as gasoline, where the first

two reached a higher share for the poor households , and the last two are higher for the non-

poor households.

Price elasticities of households should be taken into account given that the prices of fuels in

Mexico have a tendency to increase, and the energy reform has not yet show results in

efficiently providing the services by increasing market competition in fuel providers, or

defining a transparent schedule of taxes and subsidies for different household types, in

addition that the country is not self-sufficient to generate its own supply.

Page 17: Price elasticity of energy demand according to poverty condition: … · 2019. 12. 16. · Price elasticity of energy demand according to poverty condition: the case of Mexican Households

17

APPENDIX

An example of some codes of the energy goods in ENIGH are presenting in the coding table.

Table A1. Coding of goods in the household surveys (name code in Spanish)

Goods 1992 2000 2002 2004 2005 2006 2008 2010 2012 2014

Fuels

Gasoline, diesel o gas

Gasolina (F006)

Gasolina,

diesel o gas (F007) Gasolina, diesel o gas (F010)

Gasolina,

diesel o gas (F010)

Gasolina,

diesel o gas (F010)

Gasolina,

diesel o gas (F010)

Gasolina

magna

(F010)

Gasolina

magna

(F007)

Gasolina

magna

(F007)

Gasolina

magna

(F007)

Gasolina premium

(F011)

Gasolina premium

(F008)

Gasolina premium

(F008)

Gasolina premium

(F008)

Diesel y gas (F012)

Diesel y gas (F009)

Diesel y gas (F009)

Diesel y gas (F009)

Electricity and fuels

Electric

Energy

Energía

Eléctrica

(G022)

Energía

Eléctrica

(G026)

Energía Eléctrica

(G003,G010,G014,G019,G025,G029,G035)

Energía

Eléctrica

(G008)

Energía

Eléctrica

(G008)

Energía

Eléctrica

(G008)

Energía

Eléctrica

(G008)

Energía

Eléctrica

(R001)

Energía

Eléctrica

(R001)

Energía

Eléctrica

(R001)

Gas Gas (G023) Gas (G027)

Gas

(G004,G011,G015,G020,G026,G030,G036) Gas (G009) Gas (G009)

Gas LP

(G009)

Gas LP

(G009)

Gas LP

(G009)

Gas LP

(G009)

Gas LP

(G009)

Gas natural

(G010)

Gas natural

(G010)

Gas natural

(R003)

Gas natural

(R003)

Gas natural

(R003)

Fuel oil

Petróleo

(G024)

Petróleo

(G028) Petróleo (G041)

Petróleo

(G023)

Petróleo

(G023)

Petróleo

(G024)

Petróleo

(G016)

Petróleo

(G010)

Petróleo

(G010)

Petróleo

(G010)

Carbon

Carbón

(G025)

Carbón

(G029) Carbón (G043)

Carbón

(G025)

Carbón

(G025)

Carbón

(G026)

Carbón

(G018)

Carbón

(G012)

Carbón

(G012)

Carbón

(G012)

Firewood Leña (G026) Leña (G030) Leña (G044) Leña (G026) Leña (G026) Leña (G027) Leña (G019) Leña (G013) Leña (G013) Leña (G013)

Other Fuels

Combustible

para calentar (G027)

Combustible

para calentar (G031)

Combustible para calentar (G045)

Combustible para calentar

(G027)

Combustible para calentar

(G027)

Combustible para calentar

(G028)

Combustible para calentar

(G020)

Combustible para calentar

(G014)

Combustible para calentar

(G014)

Combustible para calentar

(G014)

Diesel (G042) Diesel (G024)

Diesel (G024)

Diesel (G025)

Diesel (G017)

Diesel (G011)

Diesel (G011)

Diesel (G011)

Velas y

veladoras

(G028)

Velas y

veladoras

(G032) Velas y veladoras (G046)

Velas y

veladoras

(G028)

Velas y

veladoras

(G028)

Velas y

veladoras

(G029)

Velas y

veladoras

(G021)

Velas y

veladoras

(G015)

Velas y

veladoras

(G015)

Velas y

veladoras

(G015)

Otros

combustibles

(G029)

Otros

combustibles

(G033) Otros combustibles (G047)

Otros

combustibles

(G029)

Otros

combustibles

(G029)

Otros

combustibles

(G030)

Otros

combustibles

(G022)

Otros

combustibles

(G016)

Otros

combustibles

(G016)

Otros

combustibles

(G016)

Source: authors own source using ENIGH.

Page 18: Price elasticity of energy demand according to poverty condition: … · 2019. 12. 16. · Price elasticity of energy demand according to poverty condition: the case of Mexican Households

18

Table A2. Summary Statistics 1992 to 2014

Variable Obs Mean Std. Dev. Min Max Obs Mean Std. Dev. Min Max Obs Mean Std. Dev. Min Max

w_ele 225,412 0.031 0.044 0.000 0.943 122,648 0.031 0.044 0.000 0.941 102,764 0.031 0.044 0.000 0.943

w_gas 225,412 0.023 0.035 0.000 0.939 122,648 0.023 0.032 0.000 0.846 102,764 0.023 0.038 0.000 0.939

w_oil 225,412 0.000 0.006 0.000 0.844 122,648 0.000 0.004 0.000 0.556 102,764 0.001 0.008 0.000 0.844

w_carb 225,412 0.004 0.020 0.000 0.854 122,648 0.002 0.012 0.000 0.676 102,764 0.007 0.026 0.000 0.854

w_app 225,412 0.001 0.009 0.000 0.741 122,648 0.001 0.010 0.000 0.741 102,764 0.001 0.009 0.000 0.534

w_pub_tra 225,412 0.057 0.078 0.000 1.000 122,648 0.054 0.074 0.000 1.000 102,764 0.062 0.083 0.000 1.000

w_pri_tra 225,412 0.014 0.058 0.000 0.914 122,648 0.021 0.071 0.000 0.867 102,764 0.005 0.035 0.000 0.914

w_gasoline 225,412 0.032 0.060 0.000 0.855 122,648 0.043 0.065 0.000 0.855 102,764 0.019 0.050 0.000 0.824

w_rest 225,412 0.837 0.118 0.000 1.000 122,648 0.825 0.121 0.000 1.000 102,764 0.852 0.114 0.000 1.000

pcalc_ele 225,412 1,172.87 209.24 13.23 1,356.61 122,648 1,179.31 217.81 13.23 1,356.61 102,764 1,165.18 198.25 13.23 1,356.61

pcalc_gas 225,412 273.05 126.60 3.47 456.49 122,648 283.08 127.83 3.47 456.49 102,764 261.07 124.05 3.47 456.49

pcalc_oil 225,412 4.29 2.10 0.03 8.30 122,648 4.38 2.05 0.03 8.30 102,764 4.19 2.16 0.03 8.30

pcalc_carb 225,412 167.51 233.50 0.03 5,178.21 122,648 166.60 236.39 0.03 5,178.21 102,764 168.60 230.01 0.03 5,178.21

pcalc_app 225,412 685.88 1,258.43 0.00 26,439.32 122,648 739.39 1,340.71 0.00 26,439.32 102,764 622.01 1,149.32 0.00 26,439.32

pcalc_pub_tra 225,412 378.20 1,575.36 0.00 127,214.00 122,648 471.75 1,946.42 0.00 127,214.00 102,764 266.55 948.27 0.01 127,214.00

pcalc_pri_tra 225,412 1,636.72 11,024.19 0.00 1,259,025.00 122,648 1,854.58 12,319.06 0.00 1,259,025.00 102,764 1,376.70 9,237.66 0.00 1,259,025.00

pcalc_gasoline 225,412 27.78 184.63 0.08 15,618.42 122,648 31.73 214.75 0.08 15,618.42 102,764 23.07 140.33 0.08 8,817.09

pcalc_rest 225,412 132.14 234.78 0.01 26,954.75 122,648 178.06 290.67 0.01 26,954.75 102,764 77.34 120.62 0.17 12,172.08

g_ele 225,412 227.86 450.39 0.00 38,380.69 122,648 309.97 570.19 0.00 38,380.69 102,764 129.86 198.22 0.00 9,202.99

g_gas 225,412 155.35 201.21 0.00 11,432.49 122,648 196.50 234.98 0.00 11,432.49 102,764 106.24 135.92 0.00 4,232.75

g_oil 225,412 0.73 9.64 0.00 1,688.45 122,648 0.40 9.98 0.00 1,688.45 102,764 1.12 9.19 0.00 633.97

g_carb 225,412 16.26 66.66 0.00 5,196.72 122,648 12.71 62.31 0.00 5,196.72 102,764 20.50 71.28 0.00 4,098.77

g_app 225,412 9.46 80.93 0.00 4,442.69 122,648 13.47 99.85 0.00 4,442.69 102,764 4.66 49.22 0.00 2,156.18

g_pub_tra 225,412 419.92 717.87 0.00 78,585.27 122,648 508.23 858.44 0.00 78,585.27 102,764 314.53 480.06 0.00 9,541.03

g_pri_tra 225,412 292.09 2,234.36 0.00 211,558.10 122,648 496.28 2,971.58 0.00 211,558.10 102,764 48.38 550.20 0.00 62,057.17

g_gasoline 225,412 347.21 727.56 0.00 36,645.50 122,648 546.75 896.91 0.00 36,645.50 102,764 109.05 311.07 0.00 8,214.25

g_rest 225,412 7,973.11 11,651.07 0.00 755,388.60 122,648 10,812.01 14,107.30 0.00 755,388.60 102,764 4,584.91 6,256.14 0.00 590,241.20

gt 225,412 9,441.98 12,990.69 10.08 756,568.70 122,648 12,896.32 15,749.05 29.35 756,568.70 102,764 5,319.24 6,550.37 10.08 591,913.40

Poor=1 225,412 0.46 0.50 - 1.00 122,648 - - - - 102,764 1.00 - 1.00 1.00

Rural=1 225,412 0.39 0.49 - 1.00 122,648 0.30 0.46 - 1.00 102,764 0.49 0.50 - 1.00

Hosehols size 225,412 4.13 2.09 1.00 43.00 122,648 3.51 1.75 1.00 21.00 102,764 4.87 2.21 1.00 43.00

Adults 225,412 3.07 1.55 1.00 33.00 122,648 2.87 1.44 1.00 15.00 102,764 3.32 1.63 1.00 33.00

altitud 223,501 1,135.35 923.83 1.00 2,840.00 122,009 1,133.92 934.47 1.00 2,840.00 101,492 1,137.08 910.86 1.00 2,840.00

lenght 223,501 (99.98) 5.69 (117.06) (86.75) 122,009 (100.62) 5.93 (117.06) (86.75) 101,492 (99.20) 5.28 ###### (86.75)

latitud 223,501 21.39 3.70 14.68 32.66 122,009 21.86 3.90 14.68 32.66 101,492 20.84 3.35 14.68 32.66

mean temperature225,360 20.23 22.56 8.00 613.00 122,627 19.81 20.55 8.00 613.00 102,733 20.73 24.74 8.00 613.00

mean rain 225,360 957.93 601.71 23.50 4,000.00 122,627 867.11 528.58 26.00 4,000.00 102,733 1,066.32 662.65 23.50 4,000.00

year 225,412 2,004.40 5.93 1,992.00 2,013.00 122,648 2,004.77 5.69 1,992.00 2,013.00 102,764 2,003.96 6.18 ###### 2,013.00

Dem

og

rap

hic

s an

d c

on

tro

ls

All observations Non-poor Poor

Ex

pen

dit

ure

per

cen

tag

esR

eal

Pri

ces

(20

10

= 1

00

)R

eal

Ex

pen

dit

ure

PERIOD 1992-2014

Page 19: Price elasticity of energy demand according to poverty condition: … · 2019. 12. 16. · Price elasticity of energy demand according to poverty condition: the case of Mexican Households

19

Table A3. Estimated Coefficients of QUAIDS

Fuel Param Coefficient

Constant terms αi

1- Electricity (Household) alpha_1 -0.093 ***

2- Natural Gas (EGEN) alpha_2 0.051 ***

3- Light Fuel Oil (Industry) alpha_3 -0.021 **

4- Steam Coal (EGEN), Firewood and other fuels alpha_4 -0.036 ***

5- Fuel appliances alpha_5 0.004 *

6- Public Transport alpha_6 0.585 ***

7- Private Transport alpha_7 0.118 ***

8- Gasoline alpha_8 0.106 ***

9- Rest of the budget alpha_9 0.286 ***

Income term βi

1- Electricity (Household) beta_1 0.032 ***

2- Natural Gas (EGEN) beta_2 0.014 ***

3- Light Fuel Oil (Industry) beta_3 -0.001

4- Steam Coal (EGEN), Firewood and other fuels beta_4 -0.005 ***

5- Fuel appliances beta_5 0.001 *

6- Public Transport beta_6 0.054 **

7- Private Transport beta_7 0.015 **

8- Gasoline beta_8 0.047 ***

9- Rest of the budget beta_9 -0.158 ***

Prices (own and crossed) term γij

1- Electricity (Household) gamma_1_1 0.010 ***

gamma_2_1 0.005 ***

gamma_3_1 0.001 *

gamma_4_1 0.001 ***

gamma_5_1 0.000

gamma_6_1 -0.003 *

gamma_7_1 -0.002 ***

gamma_8_1 -0.003 **

gamma_9_1 -0.009 ***

2- Natural Gas (EGEN) gamma_2_2 0.005 ***

gamma_3_2 -0.001 *

gamma_4_2 0.000 ***

gamma_5_2 0.000

gamma_6_2 0.006 ***

gamma_7_2 0.000

gamma_8_2 0.001

gamma_9_2 -0.015 ***

3- Light Fuel Oil (Industry) gamma_3_3 0.000

gamma_4_3 0.000

gamma_5_3 0.000

Page 20: Price elasticity of energy demand according to poverty condition: … · 2019. 12. 16. · Price elasticity of energy demand according to poverty condition: the case of Mexican Households

20

Fuel Param Coefficient

gamma_6_3 -0.002 **

gamma_7_3 0.000 *

gamma_8_3 0.000

gamma_9_3 0.001 **

4- Steam Coal (EGEN), Firewood and other fuels gamma_4_4 0.003 ***

gamma_5_4 0.000 ***

gamma_6_4 -0.002 ***

gamma_7_4 -0.001 ***

gamma_8_4 0.000

gamma_9_4 -0.001

5- Fuel appliances gamma_5_5 0.000

gamma_6_5 0.000

gamma_7_5 0.000

gamma_8_5 0.000

gamma_9_5 0.000

6- Public Transport gamma_6_6 0.064 ***

gamma_7_6 0.004

gamma_8_6 0.002

gamma_9_6 -0.070 ***

7- Private Transport gamma_7_7 0.007 ***

gamma_8_7 -0.002 ***

gamma_9_7 -0.006

8- Gasoline gamma_8_8 0.001

gamma_9_8 0.001

9- Rest of the budget gamma_9_9 0.098 **

Quadratic term λi

1- Electricity (Household) lambda_1 0.000 ***

2- Natural Gas (EGEN) lambda_2 0.001 ***

3- Light Fuel Oil (Industry) lambda_3 0.000

4- Steam Coal (EGEN), Firewood and other fuels lambda_4 0.000

5- Fuel appliances lambda_5 0.000

6- Public Transport lambda_6 0.005 ***

7- Private Transport lambda_7 0.000

8- Gasoline lambda_8 0.000

9- Rest of the budget lambda_9 -0.005 ***

Social/Climate Variables own term

Param Coef (b) Param Coef (b)

rho_poblp3 1.864 rho_l_altitud 0.719 **

rho_rururb -50.691 rho_l_latitud 27.845

rho_lhhsize 1.042 rho_l_tem_mean -8.235 **

rho_ladults -1.803 ** rho_l_rain_mean 4.343 ***

rho_l_longitud -1.857

Page 21: Price elasticity of energy demand according to poverty condition: … · 2019. 12. 16. · Price elasticity of energy demand according to poverty condition: the case of Mexican Households

21

Param Coef (b) Eta ηj Param Coef (b) Eta ηj

Social/Climate Variables by Good Social/Climate Variables by Good

eta_poblp3_1 0.001 ***

Po

ver

ty=

=1

eta_l_altitud_1 0.000 ***

Alt

itu

de

eta_poblp3_2 0.000 *** eta_l_altitud_2 0.000 ***

eta_poblp3_3 0.000 eta_l_altitud_3 0.000

eta_poblp3_4 0.000 *** eta_l_altitud_4 0.000 ***

eta_poblp3_5 0.000 *** eta_l_altitud_5 0.000

eta_poblp3_6 0.000 *** eta_l_altitud_6 0.000 ***

eta_poblp3_7 0.001 *** eta_l_altitud_7 0.000

eta_poblp3_8 0.002 *** eta_l_altitud_8 0.000

eta_poblp3_9 -0.003 *** eta_l_altitud_9 0.000 ***

eta_rururb_1 0.000

Ru

ral=

=1

eta_l_latitud_1 -0.002 ***

Lat

itu

de

eta_rururb_2 0.000 ** eta_l_latitud_2 0.000

eta_rururb_3 0.000 ** eta_l_latitud_3 0.000

eta_rururb_4 -0.001 *** eta_l_latitud_4 0.001 ***

eta_rururb_5 0.000 eta_l_latitud_5 0.000 *

eta_rururb_6 0.002 *** eta_l_latitud_6 0.005 ***

eta_rururb_7 0.001 *** eta_l_latitud_7 -0.003 ***

eta_rururb_8 0.001 *** eta_l_latitud_8 -0.006 ***

eta_rururb_9 -0.003 *** eta_l_latitud_9 0.006 ***

eta_lhhsize_1 0.001 ***

Ho

use

ho

ld s

ize

eta_l_tem_mean_1 -0.001 ***

Mea

n T

emp

erat

ure

eta_lhhsize_2 0.001 *** eta_l_tem_mean_2 0.001 ***

eta_lhhsize_3 0.000 eta_l_tem_mean_3 0.000 ***

eta_lhhsize_4 0.000 *** eta_l_tem_mean_4 0.000

eta_lhhsize_5 0.000 * eta_l_tem_mean_5 0.000 ***

eta_lhhsize_6 0.002 *** eta_l_tem_mean_6 0.003 ***

eta_lhhsize_7 0.000 *** eta_l_tem_mean_7 0.000

eta_lhhsize_8 0.000 eta_l_tem_mean_8 0.000 *

eta_lhhsize_9 -0.003 *** eta_l_tem_mean_9 -0.003 ***

eta_ladults_1 -0.001 ***

Nu

mb

er o

f ad

ult

s

eta_l_rain_mean_1 0.001 ***

Mea

n r

ain

eta_ladults_2 -0.001 *** eta_l_rain_mean_2 0.000 ***

eta_ladults_3 0.000 * eta_l_rain_mean_3 0.000 **

eta_ladults_4 0.000 *** eta_l_rain_mean_4 0.000 ***

eta_ladults_5 0.000 *** eta_l_rain_mean_5 0.000

eta_ladults_6 -0.002 *** eta_l_rain_mean_6 0.000 **

eta_ladults_7 0.000 *** eta_l_rain_mean_7 0.000 ***

eta_ladults_8 0.000 *** eta_l_rain_mean_8 0.000

eta_ladults_9 0.004 *** eta_l_rain_mean_9 0.000 **

eta_l_longitud_1 -0.007 ***

Len

gth

eta_l_longitud_6 0.005 ***

Len

gth

eta_l_longitud_2 -0.001 *** eta_l_longitud_7 0.000

eta_l_longitud_3 0.000 * eta_l_longitud_8 -0.006 ***

eta_l_longitud_4 0.000 eta_l_longitud_9 0.009 ***

Page 22: Price elasticity of energy demand according to poverty condition: … · 2019. 12. 16. · Price elasticity of energy demand according to poverty condition: the case of Mexican Households

22

eta_l_longitud_5 0.000

References

Bacon, R., Bhattacharya, S., & Kojima, M. (2010). Expenditure of Low-Income

Households on Energy: Evidence from Africa and Asia. Retrieved from

http://siteresources.worldbank.org/EXTOGMC/Resources/336929-

1266963339030/eifd16_expenditure.pdf

Banks, J., Blundell, R., & Lewbel, A. (1997). Quadratic Engel curves and consumer

demand. Review of Economics and Statistics, 79(4), 527-539.

Berndt, E. R., & Botero, G. (1985). Energy demand in the transportation sector of Mexico.

Journal of Development Economics, 17(3), 219-238.

doi:https://doi.org/10.1016/0304-3878(85)90091-4

Berndt, E. R., & Samaniego, R. (1984). Residential Electricity Demand in Mexico: A

Model Distinguishing Access from Consumption. Land Economics, 60(3), 268-277.

doi:10.2307/3146187

CONEVAL. (2009). Evolución de la pobreza en México. Consejo Nacional de Evaluación

de la Política de Desarrollo Social Retrieved from www.coneval.gob.mx

CONEVAL. (2018). Metodología para la medición multidimensional de la pobreza en

México. MEXICO

Crôtte, A., Noland, R. B., & Graham, D. J. (2009). Estimation of Road Traffic Demand

Elasticities for Mexico City, Mexico. Transportation Research Record, 2134(1), 99-

105. doi:10.3141/2134-12

Crôtte, A., Noland, R. B., & Graham, D. J. (2010). An analysis of gasoline demand

elasticities at the national and local levels in Mexico. Energy Policy, 38(8), 4445-

4456. doi:https://doi.org/10.1016/j.enpol.2010.03.076

Dahl, C. A. (2012). Measuring global gasoline and diesel price and income elasticities.

Energy Policy, 41, 2-13. doi:https://doi.org/10.1016/j.enpol.2010.11.055

Deaton, A. (1997). Analysis of Household Surveys: A microeconometric approach to

development policy: The World Bank.

Galindo, L. M. (2005). Short- and long-run demand for energy in Mexico: a cointegration

approach. Energy Policy, 33(9), 1179-1185.

doi:https://doi.org/10.1016/j.enpol.2003.11.015

Hansen, A. R. (2018). Heating homes: Understanding the impact of prices. Energy Policy,

121, 138-151. doi:https://doi.org/10.1016/j.enpol.2018.06.021

Labandeira, X., Labeaga, J. M., & López-Otero, X. (2017). A meta-analysis on the price

elasticity of energy demand. Energy Policy, 102, 549-568.

doi:https://doi.org/10.1016/j.enpol.2017.01.002

Miller, M., & Alberini, A. (2016). Sensitivity of price elasticity of demand to aggregation,

unobserved heterogeneity, price trends, and price endogeneity: Evidence from U.S.

Data. Energy Policy, 97, 235-249. doi:https://doi.org/10.1016/j.enpol.2016.07.031