school finance reform and the distribution of student...

88
School Finance Reform and the Distribution of Student Achievement * July 2016 Julien Lafortune University of California, Berkeley [email protected] Jesse Rothstein University of California, Berkeley and NBER [email protected] Diane Whitmore Schanzenbach Northwestern University and NBER [email protected] ABSTRACT We study the impact of post-1990 school finance reforms, during the so-called “adequacy” era, on absolute and relative spending and achievement in low-income school districts. Using an event study research design that exploits the apparent randomness of reform timing, we find that reforms lead to sharp, immediate, and sustained increases in spending in low-income school districts. Using representative samples from the National Assessment of Educational Progress, we also find that reforms cause increases in the achievement of students in these districts, phasing in gradually over the years following the reform. The implied effect of school resources on educational achievement is large. * This research was supported by funding from the Spencer Foundation and the Washington Center for Equitable Growth. We are grateful to Apurba Chakraborty, Elora Ditton, and Patrick Lapid for excellent research assistance. We thank Julie Cullen, Tom Downes, Kirabo Jackson, Rucker Johnson, Richard Rothstein, Max Schanzenbach, and conference and seminar participants at APPAM, AEFP, Bocconi, Brookings, Chicago, Erasmus, Wisconsin (IRP), LSE, New York University, Northwestern, Princeton, RAND, Teachers’ College, Texas A&M, Warwick, and the 2015 Stavanger-Bergen-Berkeley workshop for helpful comments and discussions.

Upload: others

Post on 16-Feb-2021

1 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

  • SchoolFinanceReformandtheDistributionofStudentAchievement*

    July2016

    JulienLafortune

    UniversityofCalifornia,[email protected]

    JesseRothstein

    UniversityofCalifornia,BerkeleyandNBER

    [email protected]

    DianeWhitmoreSchanzenbachNorthwesternUniversity

    [email protected]

    ABSTRACT

    Westudytheimpactofpost-1990schoolfinancereforms,duringtheso-called“adequacy”era,onabsoluteandrelativespendingandachievementinlow-incomeschooldistricts.Usinganeventstudyresearchdesignthatexploitstheapparentrandomnessofreformtiming,wefindthatreformsleadtosharp,immediate,andsustainedincreasesinspendinginlow-incomeschooldistricts.UsingrepresentativesamplesfromtheNationalAssessmentofEducationalProgress,wealsofindthatreformscauseincreasesintheachievementofstudentsinthesedistricts,phasingingraduallyovertheyearsfollowingthereform.Theimpliedeffectofschoolresourcesoneducationalachievementislarge.

    *ThisresearchwassupportedbyfundingfromtheSpencerFoundationandtheWashingtonCenterforEquitableGrowth.WearegratefultoApurbaChakraborty,EloraDitton,andPatrickLapidforexcellentresearchassistance.WethankJulieCullen,TomDownes,KiraboJackson,RuckerJohnson,RichardRothstein,MaxSchanzenbach,andconferenceandseminarparticipantsatAPPAM,AEFP,Bocconi,Brookings,Chicago,Erasmus,Wisconsin(IRP),LSE,NewYorkUniversity,Northwestern,Princeton,RAND,Teachers’College,TexasA&M,Warwick,andthe2015Stavanger-Bergen-Berkeleyworkshopforhelpfulcommentsanddiscussions.

  • 2

    Introduction

    Economistshavelongbeenskepticalofresource-basededucationpolicies,

    basedinpartonobservationalstudiesshowingsmallorzeroeffectsofadditional

    funding(see,e.g.,Colemanetal.1966,Hanushek1986,Hanushek2006).2Hanushek,

    forexample,writes:“Simplyprovidingmorefundingoradifferentdistributionof

    fundingisunlikelytoimprovestudentachievement(eventhoughitmayaffectthe

    taxburdensofschoolfinancingacrossthecitizensofastate)”(1997,p.153).

    Accordingly,recentpolicydiscussionshavefocusedonwaystoimprovethe

    productivityofexistinginputsratherthanonchangesinschoolresourcelevels.

    Nevertheless,stateshavecontinuedtoimplementaggressiveresource-based

    policies,aimedinpartatreducingachievementgaps.Between1990and2011,

    averagerealspendingperpupilinK-12schoolsrosebyabout40%.Thisincrease

    wasconcentratedinlow-incomeschooldistricts.Figure1showstheevolutionof

    averagerevenuesperpupil,in2013dollars,inthelowest-incomeschooldistricts

    (definedasthebottomfifthofeachstate’sdistrict-levelmeanhouseholdincome

    distribution)andthehighest-incomedistricts(thetopfifth),from1990to2011.3

    Overthisperiod,realper-pupilrevenuesrosebyroughly30%inthehighest-income

    districts,andby50%inthelowest-incomedistricts.Thus,whilelow-income

    2Therearealsoobservational(CardandKrueger1992a)andexperimental(Krueger1999;Dynarski,Hyman&Schanzenbach2013)studiespointingtopositiveschoolresourceeffects.Thereisnoconsensusabouthowtoreconcilethese(see,e.g.,Burtless1996;Hanushek2003;Krueger2003).3HawaiiandtheDistrictofColumbiaareexcluded.Statemeansweightdistrictsbylogenrollment,thenareaveragedwithoutweightsinFigure1.Numbersinthetextweightstatesbyenrollmentforcomparabilitywithnationalaggregates.WediscussdatasourcesanddefinitionsinSectionIII.

  • 3

    districtscollectedabout15%lessthanhigh-incomedistrictsin1990,theyhave

    beeninroughparitysincearound2001.

    Muchofthischangecameviareformstostateeducationfundingformulas.

    Figure2showsrevenuesoflow-incomedistrictsrelativetohigh-incomedistricts,

    eachdefinedasinFigure1,separatelyforthe26statesthathaveimplemented

    schoolfinancereforms—typicallybutnotalwaysundercourtorder—since1990

    andfor23statesthathavenot.Growthinlow-incomedistricts’relativerevenues

    hasbeenmorethantwiceasrapidintheformerstatesthaninthelatter.

    Theimplicationsofschoolfinancereforms(SFRs)fortheleveland

    distributionofschoolfundinghavebeenmuchstudied(see,e.g.,Hanushekand

    Lindseth,2009;CardandPayne,2002;Murray,Evans,andSchwab,1998;Laddand

    Fiske2015).Theexistingresearchfocusesprimarilyonso-called“equity”reformsin

    the1970sand1980s,whichaimedtoreducedisparitiesinfundingacrossdistricts.

    Butmostreformssince1990havebeen“adequacy”reformsthataimtoachievean

    adequateleveloffundinginlow-incomedistricts,regardlessoftheimplicationsfor

    equity.Adequacyreformshavebeenmuchmorenumerousthantheearlierequity

    reforms,buthavebeenmuchlessstudied.

    SFRsarearguablythemostsubstantialpolicyeffortaimedatpromoting

    equalityofeducationalopportunitysincetheturnawayfromschooldesegregation

    inthe1980s.Butthereislittleevidenceabouttheireffectsonstudentachievement.

    Whatevidencethereisderivesfromnon-representativedataonstudentswhotook

    theSATcollegeentranceexam(CardandPayne2002);fromlong-runoutcomes

    measuredintherelativelysmallPanelStudyofIncomeDynamicssample(Jackson,

  • 4

    Johnson,andPersico2016);orfromcasestudiesofindividualreforms(Clark2003;

    Hyman2013;Guryan2001).4Thesestudiesprimarilyexaminepre-1990,equity-

    basedSFRs,andgenerallyfindpositiveeffectsonstudentoutcomes.Butfunding

    levelsweremuchhigherby1990thanearlier,andthemostsevereinequitiesin

    schoolresourceshadbeenaddressed.Thus,theremayhavebeenlessscopefor

    morerecent,adequacy-basedSFRstobenefitstudents.

    Theliteratureregardingwhether“moneymatters”ineducation(Cardand

    Krueger1992a;Hanushek1986,2003,2006;Burtless1996)iscontentiousanddoes

    notofferclearguidance.Statefundingformulasarethemainpolicytoolavailableto

    addressinequitiesinacademicoutcomes,sofundingshiftsderivingfromchangesin

    theseformulasarethemostpolicy-relevantvariationinschoolresources.Thevery

    limitedevidenceontheimpactsofearlySFRs,andthenear-totallackofevidence

    regardingmorerecentreforms,representsamajorshortcomingintheliterature.

    Weprovidethefirstevidencefromnationallyrepresentativedataregarding

    theimpactofSFRsonstudentachievement.Weexploitlittle-useddatafromthe

    NationalAssessmentofEducationalProgress(NAEP),alsoknownas“theNation’s

    ReportCard.”NAEPhasadministeredtestsinmathandreadingtostate-

    representativesamplesof100,000-200,000studentsinthefourthandeighthgrades

    everytwotofouryearssince1990.Importantly,thetestshavebeenuniformacross

    thecountryandovertime,facilitatingcomparisons.5

    4CascioandReber(2013)andCascio,Gordon,andReber(2013)examinetheintroductionoffederalTitleIfundingtolow-incomeschoolsviathe1965ElementaryandSecondaryEducationAct.5Severalstudies(e.g.,DeeandJacob2011,LevineandSchanzenbach2009)exploitstatemeanscores.Microdataareavailableunderrestricted-usedatalicensesfromtheNationalCenterforEducationStatistics(NCES).WearegratefultoBruceKaplan,KatePashley,andFatihUnlufortheirassistanceinlocatingthecrosswalkfromtheolderNAEPdatatoschoolsanddistricts.

  • 5

    WeusetheNAEPdatatoconstructastate-by-yearpanelofrelative

    achievementinlow-incomeschooldistricts,coveringtheperiodfrom1990-2011.

    Conveniently,thebeginningofourNAEPpanelcoincideswiththeonsetofthe

    adequacyeraofschoolfinance,whichdatestothe1990KentuckyEducationReform

    Act(KERA).Figure3showstheNAEPscoregap(instandarddeviationunits)

    betweenlow-andhigh-incomedistrictsovertime,usingthesamedefinitionsasin

    Figures1and2.Itshowsthatthetestscoregaphasbeenstableinstatesthatdidnot

    implementreforms,buthasnarrowedinstatesthatimplementedreforms.

    Figures2and3canbeseenaslong-differenceestimatesoftheeffectofSFRs,

    andindicatethatSFRsledtoincreasesinfundingandtestscoresinlow-income

    schooldistricts.Butthesepatternscouldbedrivenbyothertrendsthatdiffer

    betweenstatesthatdidanddidnotimplementreforms.Totestthis,weuseanevent

    studyframework,takingadvantageofplausiblyrandomvariationinthelocation

    andtimingofpost-1990SFRs.Wefindnosignofsystematicchangesineither

    fundingortestscoresintheperiodleadinguptoareform,supportingour

    assumptionthatreformtimingisexogenous.Followingreforms,wedocumentsharp

    increasesinstaterevenues,withlargerincreasesinlow-incomedistrictsand

    smallerbutstillpositiveincreasesinhigh-incomedistricts.6Thesechangesoccur

    quicklyafterreformevents,persistformanyyears,andarenotoffsetbyreductions

    inlocalrevenues.Absoluteandrelativefundinginlow-incomedistrictsrisesby

    approximately$1,200and$700perpupilperyear,respectively.

    6Anecdotally,legislatorsfacingcourtorderstoincreasefundingtolow-incomedistrictsoftenrespondbyincreasingoverallfunding,asawayofdisguisingtheresultingredistribution.Reformsareassociatedwithsharpincreasesintotalstateeducationexpendituresandtaxcollections.

  • 6

    Notsurprisingly,wefindnoimmediateeffectofreformsonachievement.But

    wedofindclearchangesinachievementtrendsfollowingevents.Thesecumulate

    overtime:Tenyearsafterareform,relativeachievementofstudentsinlow-income

    districtshasrisenbyroughly0.1standarddeviation,approximatelyone-fifthofthe

    baselinegapbetweenhigh-andlow-incomedistricts.Theimpliedimpactis0.12-

    0.24standarddeviationsper$1,000perpupilinannualspending.Thisisatleast

    twicetheimpactperdollarthatisimpliedbytheTennesseeProjectSTARclasssize

    experiment.7Givenexistingestimatesoftherelationshipbetweentestscoresand

    students’subsequentearnings,ourresultsimplythatthebenefitsofmarginal

    increasesinschoolresourcesinlow-income,poorlyresourcedschooldistricts,in

    termsofstudents’increasedeventualearnings,exceedthecosts.

    Ourpapermakesthreeprimarycontributions.First,wepresentthefirst

    comprehensiveevidenceregardingthefiscalimpactsofpost-1990,adequacySFRs.8

    Weshowthatthesereformsleadtoincreasedprogressivityofstateaidandtotal

    schoolfinance,withlittleifanyoftheadditionalstatefundingdissipatedthrough

    reducedlocaleffortandwithnosignofreactionsthatreduceoverallfunding.

    Second,wepresentthefirstnationalevidenceregardingtheeffectofany

    financereformsontheachievementofarepresentativesampleofstudents.Our

    estimatesimplythatadditionalfundingdistributedthroughcourt-mandated

    changesinfinanceformulasishighlyproductiveinlow-incomeschooldistricts.7STARraisedcostsbyabout30%inK-3,andraisedtestscoresby0.17SDs(KruegerandWhitmore2001).CurrentspendingperpupilinTennesseeisaround$9,000,socomparableproportionalclasssizereductionswouldcostaround$2,700perpupilperyear.Theimpliedeffectisthusaround0.06SDsper$1,000perpupil.ThiscomparisonimplicitlyassumesthatmaintainingthesmallerSTARclasssizesbeyond3rdgradewouldyieldnoadditionalgrowthintestscores.8Sims(2011a)andCorcoranandEvans(2015)contrastfiscalimpactsofequityandadequacyreforms.Buttheirsamplesendin2002,andthusreflectonlythebeginningoftheadequacyera.

  • 7

    Finally,wepresentthefirstanalysisoftheimpactoffinancereformson

    overalleducationalequity.Wefindnodiscernableeffectofreformsoneitherthe

    gapinachievementbetweenhigh-andlow-incomestudentsortheminority-white

    gap.Thisisnotbecausefundingisunproductive.Rather,low-incomeandminority

    studentsarenotveryhighlyconcentratedinschooldistrictswithlowmean

    incomes,soarenotcloselytargetedbydistrict-basedfinancereforms.Thus,while

    ouranalysissuggeststhatfinancereformscanbequiteeffectiveatreducing

    between-districtinequities,otherpolicytoolsaimedatwithin-districtresourceand

    achievementgapswillbeneededtoaddressoverallequityconcerns.

    I. Schoolfinancereforms9

    Historically,Americanpublicschoolswerelocallymanagedandfinanced

    primarilyvialocalpropertytaxes.Asschooldistrictsvarywidelyinboththeirtax

    basesandtheirvoters’willingnesstotaxthemselvestofundschools,thismeantthat

    schoolresourcesvariedsubstantiallyacrossdistricts.

    Inthe1960s,agroupoflegalscholarsarguedthatlocalschoolfinance

    violatesfederalandstateconstitutionalprovisionsthatguaranteeequalaccessto

    publicservices(see,e.g.,Wise1967;Horowitz1966;Kirp1968;andCoons,Clune,

    andSugarman1970).Advocatesbroughtandwonsuitsinmanystatesdemanding

    moreequitableschoolfinancesystems;inotherstates,legislaturesactedwithout

    courtdecisions(oftentostaveoffpotentialrulings).10

    9OurdiscussionheredrawsheavilyonKoskiandHahnel(2015).10AnearlyU.S.SupremeCourtdecision,SanAntonioIndependentSchoolDistrictv.Rodriguez(411US1,1973)heldthateducationisnotafundamentalrightundertheU.S.Constitution.Subsequentsuitsfocusedonstateconstitutions,whichoftenarticulateresponsibilityforasystemofpubliceducation.

  • 8

    Theresultingfinanceregimesofteninvolvedsubstantialincreasesinstate

    transferstodistrictsthatdependedeitheronlocalfiscalcapacity(“power

    equalization”)orrealizedlocalrevenues(“matching”or“variable”grants).An

    extensive“fiscalfederalism”literatureexaminestheeffectsofthesereformsonthe

    distributionofschoolfunding(see,e.g.,HanushekandLindseth,2009;Corcoranand

    Evans,2015;CardandPayne,2002;Murray,Evans,andSchwab,1998).Aparticular

    focusiswhetherformulasthatraisethemarginallocalcostofadditionalschool

    spendingaffectvoters’choicesaboutthelocalspendinglevel(e.g.,Hoxby2001).

    Asecondwaveoffinancereforms—thefocusofthispaper—iscommonly

    datedtoa1989KentuckySupremeCourtruling.Here,theCourtfoundthatthestate

    constitution,whichasinmanyotherstatesdictatesan“efficientsystem”ofpublic

    schools,requiresthat“[e]achchild,everychild,…mustbeprovidedwithanequal

    opportunitytohaveanadequateeducation”(Rosev.CouncilforBetterEducation11;

    emphasisinoriginal).Therulingemphasizedthatequalfundingwasnotsufficient,

    andarticulatedastandardclosertoequalityofoutcomesforstudentsinlow-income

    districts(e.g.,“sufficientlevelsofacademicorvocationalskillstoenablepublic

    schoolstudentstocompetefavorablywiththeircounterpartsinsurroundingstates,

    inacademicsorinthejobmarket”).TheKentuckylegislaturerespondedwiththe

    KentuckyEducationReformActof1990(KERA),whichrevampedthestate’s

    educationalfinance,governance,andcurriculum.Clark(2003)andFlanaganand

    Murray(2004)findKERAsubstantiallyincreasedspendinginlow-incomedistricts.

    11790SW2d186.Rosewasnotthefirstadequacyruling,butearlierrulingsattractedlessattention.

  • 9

    Since1990,courtsinmanyotherstateshavefoundadequacyrequirements

    intheirownconstitutions.Inmanycasesreformshaveaimedathigherspendingin

    low-incomethaninhigh-incomedistricts,tocompensatefortheout-of-school

    disadvantagesthatlow-incomestudentsface.12

    Reformadvocateshaveconsciouslyimitatedthepushforschool

    desegregationeffortinthe1950s-1980s,andlikethatmovementhaveoperated

    opportunistically,takingadvantageofvariationinlegalprecedentandthe

    availabilityofsympatheticjudgestoadvanceanationaleffort.Courtsindifferent

    stateshaveinterpretedseeminglysimilarstateconstitutionallanguagequite

    differently,eitherimposingorrulingoutadequacyrequirements.13Thereislittle

    reasontothinkthatthecasesarebroughtinresponsetopoliticalorother

    developmentsthatwouldhaveindependentlyaffectedachievementgapsinastate.

    Moreover,thevagariesofthejudicialprocess—casesaretypicallyappealedupward

    throughseverallevelsofreview—anddecisionsinsomestatestoimplement

    legislativereformstosettleongoingcasesorforestallfearedcourtrulingsgenerate

    additionalquasi-randomvariationintiming.Ouranalyticstrategy,developedbelow,

    ispremisedontheassumptionthatreformtimingisuncorrelatedwithother

    determinantsoftrendsin(relative)spendingandachievementinlow-income

    districts.WepresentevidenceinsupportofthisassumptioninSectionsIVandV.

    12Asmallindustryhasdevelopedtocalculatethespendinglevelneededtosatisfyanadequacystandard.See,e.g.,DownesandSteifel(2015)andDuncombe,Nguyen-Hoang,andYinger(2015).13Forexample,theIllinoisSupremeCourthasfoundthatschoolfinancereformcasesarenotjusticiablebythecourtsandmustbeaddressedinsteadbythelegislature(672N.E.2d1178).Therelevantclauseinthestate’sconstitution(“anefficientsystemofhigh-qualitypubliceducationalinstitutionsandservices”)issimilartothatinOhio(“athoroughandefficientsystemofcommonschoolsthroughouttheState”),wherethecourtshaveintervened.

  • 10

    WehaveattemptedtoidentifyallmajorSFRsbetween1990and2011.We

    beganwithlistsofcourt-orderedreformscompiledbyJacksonetal.(2016)and

    CorcoranandEvans(2015).Wesupplementedthesewithourownresearchinto

    casehistories,andupdatedthemthrough2011.Wealsotabulatedmajorlegislative

    SFRs.Insomeimportantcases(e.g.,Colorado,California),legislaturesreformed

    financesystemswithoutpriorcourtdecisions,oftentoforestalladversejudgments

    inthreatenedorongoinglawsuits.Ourprimaryanalysesincludethese,thoughwe

    alsopresentresultsthatfocusexclusivelyoncourtorders.

    AppendixTableA1presentsacompletelistofoureventsandcomparesitto

    thoseusedinotherstudies.Weidentifyatotalof64schoolfinancereformeventsin

    21statesbetween1990and2011.1439(61%)involvecourtorders;theremainder

    arelegislativeactionswithoutamajorcourtorderinthesameyear.

    Figure4showsthedistributionofeventsovertime,withlegislativeSFRs

    indicatedbydarkerbars.Therehavebeensubstantiallymorecourt-orderedSFRs

    duringtheadequacyerathanintheprior,morestudiedequityera.15Figure5shows

    thegeographicdistribution.Stateswitheventsarequitegeographicallydiverse,

    thoughreformsarerareinthedeepSouthandupperMidwest.

    18stateshadmultipleeventsinourperiod.Theseweregenerallyclosely

    spaced:60%werethreeorfeweryearsapart.Inthesecases,wesuspectthatonly

    onegeneratedamajorchangeinthestate’sfinancerulesandthatothersare

    proceduralsteps(e.g.,courtordersthatweredisregardedorlegislationchanges

    14Ourpanelexcludesthe1989RosedecisionbutincludesKERA,thelegislature’sresponsein1990.15Jacksonetal.(2016)code15court-orderedSFRsfrom1971through1989,and48sincethen.Wecodeafewcasesdifferentlythanhaveearlierauthors.ThesearediscussedintheAppendix.

  • 11

    thatwerelaterfoundinadequate).Ouranalyticalstrategyisbuiltwiththisideain

    mind,thoughourresultsarenotsensitivetohowmultipleeventsaretreated.

    Aswithearlierequityreforms,statesunderadequacyordershavevariedin

    thefinancesystemsthattheyhaveadopted.Despitethisheterogeneity,thereare

    twoimportantreasonstoexpectthatadequacyreformshaddifferentimpactsonthe

    levelanddistributionofschoolfundingthandidearlierequityreforms.First,equity

    reformsoftenfocusedondistricts’propertytaxbases,whereadequacyreforms

    focusedonstudentdisadvantage;thetwomaynotbestronglycorrelated(Fischel

    1989).Second,whereastatemightrespondtoanequityorderby“levelingdown”to

    stingybutequalfunding,thiswouldnotsatisfyanadequacymandate.Statesseem

    insteadtohaveincreasedfundingtoalldistrictstomeetadequacyrequirements

    whilestillallowinghigher-incomedistrictstodifferentiatethemselves.

    Overall,then,weexpectthatadequacyreformscausedhigherspending,in

    generalandparticularlyinlow-incomedistricts,thandidequityreforms,but

    perhapsalsoyieldedsmallerreductionsinthebetween-districtdispersion(Baker

    andGreen,2015;DownesandStiefel,2015).Weconfirmthesepredictionsbelow.

    II. Analyticapproach

    Theprimarychallengeinestimatingthecausaleffectofadequacyreformsis

    thatthesereformsmaybecorrelatedwithotherfactorsthataffectrealizedschool

    financeorstudentoutcomes.Animportantconcernisthatstatesthataremore

    aggressiveintargetingfundingtolow-incomeschooldistrictsmayalsodifferin

    otherways—theymayhavebetterdevelopedsocialwelfaresystems,more

  • 12

    equitablehousingpricedistributions,ordifferentapproachestoregulatingschool

    quality(Hanushek,Rivkin,andTaylor1996a,b).

    Toaddressthis,weleveragevariationinthetimingofreformeventsinan

    event-studyframework.Ourstrategyisbasedontheideathatstateswithoutevents

    inaparticularyearformausefulcounterfactualforstatesthatdohaveeventsin

    thatyear,afteraccountingforfixeddifferencesbetweenthestatesandforcommon

    timeeffects.Thekeyassumptionisthattheexacttimingofeventsisasgoodas

    random.Wethinkthisisplausible,giventheidiosyncrasiesofjudicialprocesses

    discussedabove.Anattractivefeatureofourapproachisthatitbuildsinteststhat

    shouldidentifylikelyviolationsofthisassumption.

    Oursimplesteventstudyspecificationmodelseventsaspermanent,

    immediateshiftsinoutcomesrelativetootherstates:

    (1) !!" = !! + !! + 1 ! > !!∗ !!"#$ + !!" .

    Here,!!"representssomesummaryofthedistributionoffundingorachievementin

    statesinyeart.Wediscussourparticularmeasuresbelow.!!and!!represent

    stateandyeareffects,respectively.!!∗isthedateonwhichstates’seventoccurred.

    (Fornow,weassumethateachstatejustoneevent;thistermissettozeroforstates

    thatdonothaveevents.)Thecoefficientestimate!!"#$representsthechangein

    theoutcomefollowingtheevent.

    SFRsmaynotaffect!!"immediately,butmaydevelopmoregradually.Thisis

    particularlytrueforstudentachievementoutcomes,astheachievementofastudent

    inyeartlikelydependsinpartonthequalityoftheschoolingshereceivedinprior

    years.Inaddition,ifeventtimingisnon-random,stateswitheventsmaydiverge

  • 13

    fromstateswithouteventsevenbeforethedateoftheevent.Toaccommodatethese

    ideas,weaddtwotrendtermsto(1):

    (2) !!" = !! + !! + 1 ! > !!∗ !!"#$ + 1 ! > !!∗ ! − !!∗ !!!!"#$% + ! −

    !!∗ !!"#$% + !!" .

    !!!!"#$%capturesdelayedeventeffectsandrepresentstheannualchangein

    outcomesinstatesafter!!∗,relativetothesamestatepriortotheevent.!!"#$% ,

    whichisidentifiedfromchangesinsrelativetootherstatesinyearspriorto!!∗,

    representsafalsificationtest:!!"#$% ≠ 0wouldindicatethateventtimingis

    meaningfullynon-random.

    Wealsoestimatenon-parametricmodelsthatdonotconstrainthephase-in

    andpriortrendeffectstobelinear:

    (3) !!" = !! + !! + 1 ! = !!∗ + !!!"#!!!!"# !! + !!" .

    Here, rrepresentstheeffectofaneventinyear!!∗onoutcomesryearslater(or

    previously,forr

  • 14

    differentfromzero,andinthiscaseitappearstobeanidiosyncraticblipinasingle

    β-rcoefficient(seeFigure12).Thissupportsouridentifyingassumption.

    Whenweexaminefinanceoutcomes,allofthepost-eventeffectappearstobe

    nearlyimmediate,sowefocusonthesimplerspecification(1).Bycontrast,inour

    studentachievementanalysis,the“jump”isneverdistinguishablefromzero,andall

    oftheeffectthatweestimateoperatesthroughthe!!!!"#$%coefficient.Wethus

    emphasizespecificationsthatallowforaphase-ineffectbutnopost-eventjump.In

    eachcase,thesesimplespecificationsfitthenon-parametricresultsquitewell.

    Difference-in-differencesandtriple-differences

    Theeventstudymethodologyoutlinedaboveisaformofdifference-in-

    differences,identifyingtheeffectofeventsfromdeviationsinthetrendin“treated”

    statesrelativetostatesthathavenotyethadevents.Theidentifyingassumptionis

    thatwithoutfinancereforms,outcomeswouldhaveevolvedinparallelintreated

    anduntreatedstates.Hanusheketal.(1996a,b)arecriticalofthisassumptionwith

    regardstotheimpactsofschoolspendinginstate-by-yearpanels,arguingthatthe

    paralleltrendassumptionisunlikelytohold,biasingtheDDestimates.

    Accordingly,whilewepresentbelowDDestimateswithmeanspendingor

    meantestscoresinastateastheoutcome,webelievethatmorecredibleestimates

    oftheeffectoffundingreformscanbeobtainedfromtriple-differencemodelsthat

    comparetheimpactsofSFReventsonhigh-andlow-incomedistrictsinastate.We

    implementtheseusingtheDDmethodologyabovebyusingasthedependent

    variable!!"ameasureoftheachievementoflow-incomedistrictsinastaterelative

  • 15

    tothatinhigher-incomedistricts.Withthistypeofdependentvariable,theevent

    studystrategyisrobusttoarbitrarystate-by-yearshockstospendingor

    achievement,solongastheyhavesimilareffectsondistrictsatdifferentincome

    levels.Theidentifyingassumptionisthattherelativeoutcomesoflow-income

    districtswouldhavefollowedparalleltrendsacrossstatesintheabsenceofSFRs.

    Weconsidertwomeasuresofrelativespendingorachievementinlow-

    incomedistricts.First,weusethegapbetweendistrictsinthetopandbottom

    quintilesofthestateincomedistribution,asinFigures2and3.Thesequintilegaps

    arequitenoisy,inpartbecausetheydiscardinformationonthemiddle60%of

    districts.Wethusemphasizeasecondmeasure,theslopeofdistrict-leveloutcomes

    withrespecttologaverageincomeacrossalldistrictsinthestate.16Amorenegative

    slopecorrespondstohigherrelativeoutcomesinlow-incomedistricts.Appendix

    FigureA2repeatsthelong-differenceanalysisfromFigures2and3,thistimeusing

    ourslopemeasureinplaceofthequintilegaps.Resultsareevenstronger.

    Toillustrate,Figure6showsthescatterplotofperpupilstatetransfersto

    districtsagainstlogmeandistrictincome(measuredin1990)foreachdistrictin

    Ohio,firstin1990andthenin2011.Asthefigureshows,statetransfersrose

    dramaticallyoverthisperiod,particularlyinthelower-incomedistricts.Weoverlay

    twofittedseriesontopofthis:Oneshowsmeantransfersacrossalldistrictsineach

    incomequintile,andtheothershowstheslopeasdescribedabove.Inthiscase,the

    16Specifically,weregressdistrict-levelspendingperpupilormeanachievementonlogmeanincome,controllingforlogenrollment.Theregressionisestimatedseparatelyforeachstateandyear,andinachievementmodelsforeachsubjectandgrade.Thedistrictlogincomecoefficientsareusedas!!"forsubsequentanalysesatthestate-year-(subject-grade)level.SeetheAppendixforfurtherdetail.

  • 16

    log-linearspecificationfitsthequintilemeansfairlywell.Acrossstates,theslopeis

    correlated-0.78withthefirst-quintile/fifth-quintilegap.

    WeshowbelowthatSFRsleadtohigherabsoluterevenuesinalldistrictsina

    stateandtohigherrelativerevenuesinlow-incomedistricts,asseenforOhioin

    Figure6.Eachofthesecouldaffecttherelativeachievementofstudentsinlow-

    incomedistricts.First,ifmoneymatters,thentheincreaseinrelativespending

    shouldraiselow-incomedistricts’achievement.Second,themarginaleffectofextra

    fundsmaybehigherinlow-incomedistricts,perhapsduetodecliningmarginal

    productivityofadditionalresources.Ifso,evenanacross-the-boardspending

    increasewouldraiserelativetheirrelativeachievement.Giventhesetwochannels,

    andtimingissuesthatwillbecomeclearbelow,wearecautiousinconvertingour

    estimatedeffectsonachievementintoestimatesofoutputperdollar,asitisnot

    clearwhatistheappropriatedenominatorforourDDDtreatmenteffects.

    Eventstudieswithmultipleevents

    Asnotedabove,manystateshadmultipleevents(courtordersorlegislation)

    overourperiod.Unfortunately,thereisnoacceptedstrategyforconductingevent

    studieswithmultipleeventsperunit.

    Ohioillustratesboththechallengeandourproposedsolution.Thestate

    SupremeCourtruledfourtimesontheDeRolphv.Statecase,in1997,2000,2001,

    and2002.The1997rulingdeclaredthestate’sfinancesystemunconstitutionalon

    adequacygrounds,andspecificallyrejectedthestate’srelianceonlocalproperty

    taxes.TheCourtordereda“completesystematicoverhaul”oftheschoolfunding

  • 17

    system.In2000,theCourtdeterminedthatthelegislaturehadfailedtoactandthat

    fundinglevelsremainedinadequate.Thesameyear,thelegislaturerevisedthe

    system,andasubsequentrulingin2001determinedthatthenewsystem,witha

    fewminorchanges,satisfiedconstitutionalrequirements.Thisdecisionwas

    reversedin2002,bythesameCourt(albeitwithadifferentmakeupofjudges),and

    thelegislatureorderedtomakefurtherchanges.Toourknowledge,thelegislature

    didnothingtocomplywiththis.

    OurreformdatabaseincludesOhioeventsin1997,2000,and2002.Basedon

    theabovecasehistory,wemightexpectonlythe2000eventtobeassociatedwith

    majorchangesinschoolfinanceinOhio.Butthedatatelladifferentstory.Figure7

    showsthetimeseriesofourtwomeasuresoftheprogressivityofstateaidinOhio

    (withtheslopemeasureinvertedforcomparability):Thedifferenceinaveragestate

    transfersperpupilbetweenthelowest-incomeandhighest-incomefifthsofOhio

    schooldistricts(solid)andtheslopeofstatetransferswithrespecttologincome,

    multipliedby-1(dashed).Verticallinesindicatethereformevents.Thefigure

    showsthatstatetransferswereprogressivein1990andslowlybecamemoresoin

    thefirstfewyearsofourdata.Around1998,thetrendbecamenotablysteeper,and

    by2002averagestateaidperpupilwas$4,851higherinlow-incomethaninhigh-

    incomedistricts.Ifanything,relativefundinghasdeclinedsince2002.Thispattern

    appearsconsistentwithagradualreactiontotheinitial1997ruling.Thereisless

    visualevidenceofthe2000event,whichdidnotinterrupttheprevioustrend,while

    the2002rulingseemstocoincidewithanendtotheincreasesinprogressivity.

  • 18

    BasedonthepatternsinOhioandelsewhere,weadoptedtwoanalytical

    decisionsforourprimaryestimates.First,wechooseasingleeventineachstate.

    Ourideahereisthatwhenstateshavemultipleevents,theyoftenrepresent

    jockeyingbetweenthelegislatureandthecourtswithonlyminorchangesinschool

    financeuntilthelegislaturefinallyenactsamajorreform,andthencontinued

    jockeyingafterwardasadvocatescontinuetopushforsmalleradditionalchanges.

    Second,wedonotrelyonreviewsofcasehistoriestoidentifythe

    consequentialevents,astherhetoricincourtordersandpreamblestobillsisoften

    (asinOhio)misleadingaboutthemagnitudeofthechangebeingmade.Rather,we

    usethestateaiddatatoidentifyaregimechangeintheprogressivityofastate’s

    financesystem,relyingonmethodsfortheidentificationofchangepointsintime

    seriesdata(e.g.,Bai1997;seealsoCard,Mas,andRothstein2008).

    Specifically,let!!"beourslopemeasureoftheprogressivityofstateaid.For

    eachstateandeachpotentialeventdate!!∗,weestimateatimeseriesregression

    usingastheonlyexplanatoryvariableanindicatorforobservationsafterthatdate:

    (4) !!" = ! + 1 ! > !!∗ ! + !!" .

    Weselectthedatethatyieldsthelargesttstatisticfor!–orequivalentlythe

    smallestmeansquarederror–forthistimeseriesregression.17Wetreatthe

    selecteddateasthesingleeventinstates.Bai(1997)showsthatthismethodis

    super-consistent(withfasterthan !convergence)forthelocationofastructural

    breakinatimeseries,permittinginferenceregardingthemagnitudeofthebreakto

    treatitslocationasknown.

    17Werestrictattentiontot*forwhichtheestimated!hastheexpectedsign.

  • 19

    Wepresentestimatesfromtwoadditionalapproachestomultipleevents.

    Oneincludesallevents,withoutjudgmentabouttheirrelativeimportance.We

    createaseparatecopyofthetimeseriesforthestateforeachevent,foreachcopy

    usingadifferentvalueof!!∗.Wethenstackthesecopies,replacingthestateeffectsin

    equations(1)-(3)withstate-by-event-copyeffects.18InMonteCarlosimulations,

    thismethodworkswelltoidentifytheaverageeffectofeventsbothwheneach

    eventhasthesameeffectandwhenonlyoneeventinastatehasanon-zeroeffect.

    Ourfinalapproachfollowsthepriorliteraturebyfocusingontheinitialcourt

    orderineachstate.Pastauthorshavearguedthatthetimingofinitialcourtordersis

    effectivelyrandombutthatlegislativeeventsandsubsequentcourtordersmaynot

    be.Thedrawbacktothisapproachisthattherecanbelonglagsbetweentheinitial

    courtorderandtheimplementationofareform.Itisthusbettersuitedtosimple

    modelslike(1)thatarenothighlysensitivetomis-timingthestructuralbreak—

    mostpastworkusingthisapproachhasfocusedonsuchmodels—thantomore

    flexiblemodelslikeournon-parametricspecification(3).

    Inappropriatespecifications,resultsarequiterobustacrossallthree

    methods.Accordingly,wedonotviewmultipleeventsasamajorissueinpractice.

    III. Data

    Ouranalysisdrawsondatafromseveralsources.Webeginwithour

    databaseofstateSFRevents,discussedabove.Wemergethistodistrict-levelschool

    financedata,fromtheNationalCenterforEducationStatistics’(NCES)annual

    18Resultsareunchangedwhendataarereweightedtooffsettheoverrepresentationofstateswithmultipleevents.

  • 20

    censusofschooldistricts(theCommonCoreofData,orCCD,districtfinancefiles,

    alsoknownasthe“F-33”survey)andtheCensusofGovernments;meanhousehold

    incomebydistrictfromthe1990Census;andNAEPachievement.

    TheCCDdistrictfinancedatareportenrollment,revenuesandexpenditures

    annuallyforeachlocaleducationagency(LEA).19Weconvertalldollarfiguresto

    2013dollarsperpupil,andexcludedistrictswithhighlyvolatileenrollmentor

    implausibleper-pupil-funding.Detailsareintheappendix.

    OurstudentoutcomemeasurescomefromtheNationalAssessmentof

    EducationalProgress(NAEP).Weuserestricted-usemicrodatafromthe“State

    NAEP,”designedtoproducestate-representativesamples.StateNAEPbeganin

    1990,with42statesparticipating.Ithasbeenadministeredroughlyeverytwoyears

    since.Since2003,allstateshaveparticipatedin4thand8thgradeassessmentsin

    mathandreadingineveryodd-numberedyear.20Table1showstheschedule.Tests

    areadministeredtoaround100,000students(moreinlateryears)ineachsubject-

    grade-year.Theseconsistofrepresentativesamplesofabout2,500studentsper

    state,spreadacrossabout100schools.

    TheNAEPusesaconsistentscoringscaleacrossyearsforeachsubjectand

    grade.Westandardizescorestohavemeanzeroandstandarddeviationoneinthe

    firstyearthatthetestwasgivenforthegradeandsubject,butallowboththemean

    19Censusdataareavailablein1989-90and1991-92,andannuallysince1994-95.WeusesamplesfromtheCensusBureau’sAnnualSurveyofGovernmentFinancesfor1992-93and1993-94.20TheNAEPalsotests12thgraders,butsamplesaresmaller,andothersubjects.

  • 21

    andvariancetoevolveafterward.Wethenaggregatetothedistrict-year-grade-

    subjectlevelandmergetotheCCDandSDDB.21

    Table2apresentsdistrict-levelsummarystatistics,poolingdatafrom1990-

    2011.Table2bpresentssummarystatisticsforthestate-yearpanel.

    IV. Financereformsandschoolfinance

    WebeginourempiricalanalysisbydocumentingtheimplicationsofSFR

    eventsforschoolfinance.WeusetheapproachdiscussedinSectionIItoidentifya

    singleSFReventineachstate,selectingamongcandidateeventstheonethatbest

    explainsthetimeseriesofthestateaid–logdistrictincomeslopeinthestate.

    Figure8,panelAgraphseventstudyresultsforaveragestatetransfersper

    pupilinthestate,poolingalldistricts.Wepresentanumberofplotsofthisbasic

    form.Thesolidlinepresentsestimatesofthenon-parametriceventstudy

    specification(3),whiledottedlinesshowpointwise95%confidenceintervals.The

    dashedlineshowstheparametricspecification(2).

    Pointestimatesindicatethataveragestatetransferstodistrictsriseinthe

    yearsleadinguptoanevent,thoughthiscouldbejustsamplingerror–thep-value

    forequalityacrossallyearspriortotheeventsis0.31.Bycontrast,inthefouryears

    followingtheeventaveragestatetransfersrisebyroughly$1,000.Theydecline

    somewhatinsubsequentyears,buteven15yearsafterthefocaleventremain

    approximately$500abovewhatwouldhavebeenexpectedwithouttheevent.The

    differencesfromtheeventyeararesignificantbothcollectively(p

  • 22

    individuallyforrelativeyears1-10.Theparametricspecificationfitsthe

    nonparametricresultswell.PanelBofFigure8repeatstheexercise,thistimeusing

    totalper-pupilrevenues(inclusiveoflocalrevenuesandfederaltransfers)asthe

    dependentvariable.Thepatternisquitesimilarhere,withlittleindicationthat

    increasesinstaterevenuesareoffsetbyreductionsinlocaleffortonaverage.

    Columns1and3ofTable3presentcoefficientsfromoursimplestone-

    parametereventstudyspecification(1),firstforstaterevenuesandthenfortotal

    revenues.Eventsareassociatedwithincreasesinstateaidof$912perpupil,and

    withslightlysmallerincreases($829perpupil)intotalrevenues.Columns2and4

    presentthethree-parameterspecification(2).Post-eventeffectsarequitesimilarto

    thoseseenintheone-parametermodels;whilepointestimatesindicatethatthey

    trenddownoversubsequentyears,thesearenotdistinguishablefromzero.In

    column2,theupwardtrendprecedingeventsthatwasvisibleinFigure8aissmall

    andinsignificant,supportingourassumptionthateventtimingisrandom.

    Theseresultspreviewageneralpatternweseethroughoutourfinance

    analyses.Nonparametricmodelsshowalargejumpoverthefirstthreetofouryears

    followingtheevent,withrelativelysmalltrendsbeforeandafter.Pre-eventtrends

    areneverstatisticallysignificant,andwhilewecangenerallyrejectzeroeffectof

    eventsonallpost-eventoutcomes,wecannever(inthethree-parametermodel)

    rejectasinglejumpfollowingtheeventthatpersistsunchangedthereafter.

    Accordingly,wefocusontheone-parametermodelforsubsequentfinanceanalyses.

    Inadditionalanalysesofstatebudgets,(AppendixTableA2)wehavefound

    noindicationthatgrowthineducationalspendingfollowingeventscrowdsoutstate

  • 23

    spendingonotherprograms;rather,SFRsareassociatedwithincreasesinstatetax

    collectionslargeenoughtofullyfundtheincreaseinstatetransferstodistricts.

    WeturnnexttoexaminingtheimpactofSFRsonthedistributionoffunding

    acrossschooldistricts.Figure9presentseventstudyanalyses,similartothosein

    Figure8,foraveragestateaidandtotalrevenuesperpupilindistrictsinthetopand

    bottomquintilesofthestateincomedistribution.Thereisagainsomeindicationof

    pre-eventupwardtrendsinstaterevenues,butagainwecannotrejectthenull

    hypothesisofzeropre-eventdifferences.Bothlow-andhigh-incomedistrictssee

    increasesinstateandtotalrevenuesfollowingtheevent,buttheincreasesare

    largerinlow-incomedistricts:Roughly$1,300bythe4thpost-eventyear,vs.less

    thanhalfthat(andnotrobustlysignificant)inhigh-incomedistricts.Thoughout-

    yearestimatesarenoisy,impactsappeartopersistthroughtheendofoursample.

    Patternsfortotalrevenuesareverysimilartothoseforstaterevenues,andshow

    littlesignthatstaterevenueincreasesareoffsetbyreductionsinlocalrevenues.

    PanelsBandCofTable3presenttheparametricestimatesforthelowest-

    andhighest-incomedistricts.Averagestatefundingis$1,225higheraftereventsin

    firstquintiledistrictsand$527(notsignificant)higherinfifthquintiledistricts;in

    eachcase,totalrevenuechangesareofsimilarmagnitude,andthemoreflexible

    specificationyieldssimilarresults.

    Figure10showsestimatesofimpactsontheprogressivityoftotalrevenues,

    usinginthetoppanelthedifferenceinfundingbetweenbottom-andtop-quintile

    districtsandinthelowerpaneltheslopeoffundingwithrespecttologdistrict

    income.ParametricmodelsfortheseoutcomesareshowninColumn4ofTable4.

  • 24

    Usingeachmeasure,weseesharpincreasesinrelativestatefundingforlow-income

    districtsfollowingeventsthataresustained(thoughnotalwaysprecisely

    estimated)formanyyears.Innocaseisthereanysignofapre-eventtrendthat

    wouldsuggestaviolationofourrandomtimingassumption.Noristhereanysignin

    Table4thatincreasedprogressivityofstateaidisoffsetbylocalrevenues.22

    Anaturalquestionishowtheadditionalfundsarespent.Table5presents

    event-studycoefficientsfromourone-parametermodelforper-pupilrevenuesand

    spendinginvariouscategories.ThereisnoapparentimpactofSFRsonlocalor

    federalrevenues.WeseesubstantialimpactsofSFRsonaverageinstructional

    spending,bothoverallandinQ1districts(columns2and3).Wealsoseeeffectson

    teachersperpupil,suggestingthatdistrictsuseadditionalfundstoreduceclasssize,

    thoughwefindnosignofimpactsonteacherpay.23Wealsoseelargeincreasesin

    non-instructionalexpenditures,particularlycapitaloutlays.

    Columns4and5showresultsforrelativespendinginlow-incomedistricts.

    Littleoftheincreaseinrelativefundinggoestoinstructionalexpenditures,while

    roughlyhalfgoestocapitalspending.Thecapitalspendingeffectisnotsurprising;

    manylawsuitsspecificallyconcerndreadfulconditionsinlow-incomeschools,and

    SFRremediesoftencreatedfundstosupportrenovationofschoolsinpoorshape.24

    22WhenweestimatespecificationssimilartoCardandPayne’s(2002)closelyrelatedanalysisofearlierSFRs(AppendixTableA3),estimatedSFReffectsareslightlylargerbutimprecise,andwellwithintheearlierconfidenceintervals.WhereCardandPaynefindthattotalrevenuesrisebyabout$0.50perextra$1instateaid,ourestimatesindicatemuchmorestickinessfortherecentreforms.23Usingadifferentresearchdesign,Sims(2011b)findseffectsofSFRsonteacherpay.24NeilsonandZimmerman(2014)findthatschoolreconstructioncausesincreasesinstudentachievement.Cellinietal.(2010)andMartorell,Stange,andMcFarlin(2015)failtofindsignificanteffects,buteachstudyisunder-poweredtodetecteffectsofplausiblemagnitude.

  • 25

    V. Financereformsanddistrict-levelstudentachievement

    Wecannowturntoourmainanalysis,examiningtheeffectofSFRson

    studentachievement.Theaboveresultsestablishthatreformeventsareassociated

    withsharp,immediateincreasesintheprogressivityofschoolfinance,withabsolute

    andrelativeincreasesinrevenuesinlow-incomeschooldistricts.Ifadditional

    fundingisproductive,wemightexpecttoseeimpactsonstudentoutcomes.

    Wherethe!!"schoolfinancemeasuresformedastate-by-yearpanel,fortest

    scoreswehavetwoadditionaldimensions:Gradeandsubject.Wereplacetheyear

    fixedeffects(!!)in(1)-(3)withsubject-grade-yeareffects.Thesecaptureany

    differencesintestsbetweenadministrations,aswellaschangesinstudent

    performancebygradeand/orsubjectthatarecommonacrossstates.Toavoid

    confoundingfromstate-levelshocks,wefocusonDDDspecificationsthatusethe

    achievementgapbetweenlow-andhigh-incomedistrictsasthedependentvariable.

    Sharp,permanentchangesinfunding,ifusedproductively,shouldincrease

    theflowofeducationalservices.Achievementiscumulative,sotheseservicesare

    unlikelytohaveimmediateimpactsontestscores,butshouldraisescoresgradually

    asstudentsareexposedforlonger.Effectsshouldgrowatleastuntilstudentshave

    beenexposedtothenewfundinglevelsfortheirentirecareers.Theymayeven

    continuetogrowbeyondthispoint.Forexample,considerastatethatrespondstoa

    courtorderbycreatinganewpermanentfacilitytofundseveralschoolrenovation

    andconstructionprojectseachyear.Initially,onlyafewstudentsbenefit,butover

    timegrowingsharesofstudentsareexposedtofundedprojects.Insofarasbetter

    facilitiespromotestudentlearning,achievementeffectswouldcontinuetogrow

  • 26

    untilseveralyearsafterthelastprojectiscomplete,potentiallydecadesafterthe

    initialpolicychange.Wethusemphasizethephase-incoefficientfromequation(2)

    astheprimarymeasureofSFReffectsontestscores.

    Figure11presentsourevent-studyanalysisoftheslopeofachievementwith

    respecttodistrictincome.Asbefore,wepresentnon-parametricresults(equation

    3)asasolidlineandestimatesofourthree-parametermodel(equation2)asa

    dashedline.Thereisnoindicationofadifferentialtrendinreformstatespriorto

    events.Followingevents,thenon-parametricseriesdoesnotreactimmediately,but

    beginstrendingnoticeablydownwardstartinginaboutthefifthpost-eventyear.

    Thedownwardtrendcontinuesthroughtheendofoursample.25

    Table6presentsparametricestimates.WebegininColumn1withourthree-

    parametermodel,asshowninFigure11.Again,theestimatedpre-eventtrendis

    essentiallyzero,andthepost-eventjumpisalsosmall,butthepost-eventchangein

    trendislargeandstatisticallysignificant.Column2presentsaspecificationthat

    discardstheothertwocoefficients.Resultsarequitesimilar.Theestimatedchange

    intheslopeis-0.010peryear.Thisimpliesthateachyearafteranevent,adistrict

    withlogmeanincomeoneunit(abouttwothirds)belowthestateaverageseesits

    scoresriserelativetothestateaverageby0.010standarddeviations,accumulating

    to0.10SDsovertenyears.Thisisquantitativelymeaningful–onaverageinour

    sampletheslopeoftestscoreswithrespecttologincomeis0.96soSFRsreducethis

    gradientbyapproximatelyone-tenthwithintenyears.

    25ThesawtoothpatternattheendofthesamplelikelyreflectsthebiannualNAEPtestingschedule.

  • 27

    Asdiscussedabove,thepatternofgraduallygrowingeffectsinFigure11is

    consistentwithaviewofachievementasastockreflectingaccumulatedpastinput

    flows.Thepatterndeviatesfromexpectationsinonerespect,however:Thereisno

    indicationthatthephase-inoftheeffectslowsfiveornineyearsaftertheevent,

    whenthe4thand8thgraders,respectively,willhaveattendedschoolsolelyinthe

    post-eventperiod.26Thismayreflecttheuseofsomeadditionalfundsfordurable

    investments,asdiscussedabove.Wedonothaveenoughprecision,however,torule

    outaflatteningoftheeffectattheexpectedtime.

    Figure12presentsestimatedtestscoreimpactsforthelowest-andhighest-

    incomedistricts.Theeffectsontheincomegradientaredrivenbydramatic

    increasesintestscoresinthelowest-incomedistricts.27Inhigher-incomedistricts,

    thereislittlesignofasystematicpost-eventchange.Parametricestimatesare

    showninColumns3and4ofTable6;Column5showsthattheimpactofeventson

    thetestscoregapbetweenbottom-andtop-quintiledistrictsis0.008SDsperyear.

    Thisgrowswhentrendtermsareincluded(column6).Thegapinmeanlogincomes

    betweenthetopandbottomquintilesaverages0.65,sothequintilepointestimateis

    largerthanwhatweobtainforourincomeslopemeasureincolumns1-2.Our

    earlierfinanceanalysesalsoindicatedlargereffectsforquintilegapsthanforslopes.

    AppendixFigureA3presentsestimatesofthephase-incoefficientforallfive

    quintiles.Onlythefirstquintileeffectislargeordistinguishablefromzero.Theratio

    26Wehaveestimatedseparatenon-parametricmodelsfor4thand8thgradescores.Bothsetsofeffectsgrowroughlylinearlythroughtheendofourpanels.SeeAppendixFigureA4.27Forthelowest-incomedistricts(Figure12A),wecanrejectthenullhypothesisofzeropre-eventeffects.Thisisdrivenbywhatappeartobeablipintestscorestwoyearspriortoevents.Asimilarblipisapparentforhigh-incomedistrictsinPanelB.Thereisnosignofsystematicpre-eventtrends.

  • 28

    oftestscoreeffectstospendingeffectsislargeratthebottomoftheincome

    distribution,consistentwiththeideathatfundingismoreproductiveinlow-income

    districts,butequalratioscannotberuledout.

    Table7presentsestimatesseparatelybygradeandsubject.Wecannotreject

    thenullhypothesisofequaleffectsacrosseachdimension.

    A. RobustnessTable8presentsestimatesofourkeyspecificationsfromourtwoalternative

    approachestoeventmultiplicity.Column1repeatstheestimatesfromourpreferred

    approachfromTables4and6.InColumn2,weincludeallidentifiedevents,creating

    separatepanelsforeach;inColumn3,wefocusonlyonthefirstcourtorderineach

    state.Resultsaresimilartothosefromourmainspecifications,thoughtheinitial

    courtorderapproachyieldslessprecise,insignificantestimatesoffinanceeffects.

    Onepotentialexplanationfortheachievementimpactsthatweidentifyis

    thattheyreflectchangesinpopulationstratificationratherthanchangesin

    educationalproduction.SFRsthatflattenthegradientofschoolfundingwithrespect

    todistrictincomeandthatreducethelocalshareofschoolfinancereducethevalue

    oflivinginahigh-incomedistrict,andmayleadsomehigh-incomefamiliesto

    relocatetopreviouslylow-incomedistricts.Thiscouldleadtorisingachievementin

    thesedistrictswithnochangeinschooleffectiveness.

    Weassessthispossibilityinthreeways.First,wehavetestedwhether

    between-districtincomegapsnarrowintheyearsfollowingSFRs.Wehavefoundno

    evidenceforthis–districtlogincomesin2011arehighlycorrelatedwiththosein

    1990,andthereisnosignthatgapsnarrowinstatesthathadreformsvs.thosethat

  • 29

    didn’t.Second,wehaveconductedeventstudyanalyses,paralleltothosefortest

    scores,fordistrictincomeorthedistrictnon-whiteorfree-orreduced-pricelunch

    eligibleshare(AppendixTableA5).Inonlyonespecification–forthebetween-

    quintilegapinthefreelunchshare–dowefindevidencethatthedemographic

    compositionof(initially)low-incomedistrictschangesfollowingSFRs.Thisresultis

    notrobust,andissmallrelativetothetestscoreimpactsthatweestimate.

    Third,wedecomposetestscoresintotwocomponents,andestimate

    separateSFReffectsoneach.Specifically,weestimateanindividual-levelregression

    oftestscoresonstudentdemographiccharacteristics,poolingNAEPdataacross

    yearsforeachgrade-subjectpairandincludingyearfixedeffects.Wethenconstruct

    separateachievement-logdistrictincomegradientsfromthefittedvalues(excluding

    thefixedeffects)forthisregression,representingstudentcharacteristicsthatwould

    beaffectedbySFRsonlythroughchangesinsorting,andfromtheresiduals.Table9

    presentsresultsofoureventstudyanalysesofthesegradients.Wepresenttwo

    decompositions:Thefirstpanelusesonlyraceandgender,whichareconsistently

    availableineachNAEPwave,alongwithschoolmeansofthese.Thenextuses

    additionalcovariates,parentaleducationandfreelunchstatus,thatareless

    consistentlyavailable,includingindicatorsforyearsinwhicheachisunavailable.

    Thefirstsetofvariablesexplains22%ofthevarianceinstudenttestscores(netof

    thesubject-grade-yeareffects),whilethesecondsetexplains28%.

    Wefindnoevidencethatreformsaffectthedemographiccomponentofour

    testscoreprogressivitymeasures.Pointestimatesarelessthanhalfthesizeofour

    overalltestscoreimpacts,andareneversignificantlydifferentfromzero.By

  • 30

    contrast,estimatedeffectsontheresidualcomponentoftestscoresareall

    significant,andabouttwo-thirdsthesizeoftheoverallimpacts.Thus,whilewe

    cannotruleoutsmalleffectsofSFRsonstudentsorting,therobustnessofeffectson

    theresidualcomponentsupportsourinterpretationthatourresultsprimarily

    reflectchangesineducationalproductioninlow-incomeschooldistricts.

    Asafinalrobustnessexercise,wehavetestedwhethertheSFReffecton

    achievementissensitivetoincludingcontrolsforthepresenceofaschool

    accountabilitypolicyinastate,orwhethertheSFReffectvarieswithschool

    accountability.Wefoundevidenceforneither.

    VI. Financereformsandstatewideachievementgaps

    Thefinaltopicthatweinvestigateiswhetherfinancereformsclosedoverall

    testscoregapsbetweenhigh-andlow-achieving,minorityandwhite,orlow-income

    andnon-low-incomestudentsinastate.Theseareperhapsbettermeasuresthan

    ourslopesandquintilegapsoftheoveralleffectivenessofastate’seducational

    systematdeliveringequitable,adequateservicestodisadvantagedstudents

    (KruegerandWhitmore2002;CardandKrueger1992b).However,becausemost

    inequalityiswithindistricts,changesinthedistributionofresourcesacrossdistricts

    maynotbewellenoughtargetedtomeaningfullyclosethesegaps.

    Table10presentsestimatesofeffectsonmeantestscoresacrossdifferent

    subgroupsofinterest.Thefirstpanelshowsasmallandinsignificanteffectonmean

    (pooled)testscores.Thisissomewhatofapuzzle,giventheincreasesinmean

    revenuesdocumentedearlier.Itmustbenoted,however,thatourresearchdesignis

  • 31

    morecredibleforoutcomedisparitiesthanforthelevelofoutcomes,asthelatter

    wouldbeconfoundedbyunobservedshockstoaverageoutcomesinastatethatare

    correlatedwiththetimingofschoolfinancereforms(Hanushek,Rivkin,andTaylor

    1996a,b).Forexample,ifSFRsfollownegativeshockstomeanstudentachievement,

    thiseffectwouldbedownward-biased.Anotherinterpretationisthatthemarginal

    productivityofrevenuesisinfacthigherinlow-incomedistricts.

    Thesecondpanelshowsimpactsonthestandarddeviationorinterquartile

    rangeofachievementwithinstates,whilethethirdandfourthpanelspresent

    resultsbyraceandincome,respectively.Thereisnodiscernibleeffecton

    achievementgapsbyraceorincomeorontheoveralldispersionoftestscores.Point

    estimatesareallroughlyafullorderofmagnitudesmallerthantheearlierestimates

    fordistrict-levelprogressivityofmeanscores.

    AppendixTablesA6andA7resolvethediscrepancy.Whilenon-whiteand

    low-incomestudentsaremorelikelythantheirwhiteandhigher-incomepeersto

    attendschoolinlow-incomeschooldistricts,thedifferencesarenotverylarge.

    Roughlyone-quarterofnon-whitestudents,andone-thirdoflow-incomestudents,

    liveinfirst-quintiledistricts,whileonly10%ofeachliveinfifth-quintiledistricts.

    ThisleaveslittleroomforSFRstomuchaffecttherelativeresourcestowhichthe

    typicalminority,low-income,orlowscoringstudentisexposed.

    Toassessthismorecarefully,weassignedeachstudentthemeanrevenues

    forhis/herdistrictandestimatedeventstudymodelsfortheblack-whiteorincome

    gapintheseimputedrevenues.Results,inAppendixTableA7,indicatethatfinance

    eventsraiserelativeper-pupilrevenuesintheaverageblackstudent’sschool

  • 32

    districtbyonly$144(S.E.167),andreducerevenuesintheaveragelow-income

    student’sdistrictby$23(S.E.262).Eveniffundingwasmuchmoreproductivethan

    theaverageeffectimpliedbyouranalysis,thefundingchangesseenherewouldstill

    notbeenoughtoyieldeffectsonblackorlow-incomestudents’averagetestscores

    largeenoughtodetectwithourresearchdesign.Thus,whilereformsaimedatlow-

    incomedistrictsappeartohavebeensuccessfulatraisingresourcesandoutcomes

    inthesedistricts,weconcludethatwithin-districtchangeswouldbenecessaryto

    havedramaticimpactsontheaveragelow-income,minority,orlow-scoringstudent.

    VII. Discussion

    Afterdesegregation,schoolfinancereformisperhapsthemostimportant

    educationpolicychangeintheUnitedStatesinthelasthalfcentury.Butwhilethe

    effectsofthefirst-andsecond-wavereformsonschoolfinancehavebeenwell

    studied,thereislittleevidenceaboutthefinanceeffectsof“adequacy”reformsor

    abouttheeffectsofanyofthesereformsonstudentachievement.Ourstudy

    presentsnewevidenceoneachofthesequestions.

    Wefindthatstate-levelschoolfinancereformsenactedduringtheadequacy

    eramarkedlyincreasedtheprogressivityofschoolspending.Theydidnot

    accomplishthisby"levelingdown"schoolfunding,butratherbyincreasing

    spendingacrosstheboard,withlargerincreasesinlow-incomedistricts.Using

    nationallyrepresentativedataonstudentachievement,wefindthatthisspending

    wasproductive:Reformsincreasedtheabsoluteandrelativeachievementof

    studentsinlow-incomedistricts.OurestimatesthuscomplementthoseofJacksonet

  • 33

    al.(2016),whoexaminethelong-runimpactsofearlierschoolfinancereformsand

    findsubstantialpositiveimpactsonavarietyoflong-runoutcomes.

    Thedifferenttimepatternsofimpactsonresourcesandonstudent

    outcomes,combinedwiththecumulativenatureofthelatter,preventsasimple

    instrumentalvariablesinterpretationofthereduced-formcoefficientsintermsof

    theachievementeffectperdollarspent–itisnotclearwhichyears’revenuesare

    relevanttotheaccumulatedachievementofstudentstestedryearsafteranevent.

    Toassessthemagnitudeoftheimpactsweestimate,wefocusonestimatedeffects

    onstudentachievementtenyearsafteranevent.Becauseeffectsonschool

    resourcesarestableintheyearsfollowingevents,thesecanbeinterpretedasthe

    impactofachangeinresourcesforeveryyearofastudent’scareer(through8th

    grade).Nevertheless,thefocusonther=10estimateisarbitrary.Wewouldobtain

    largerestimatesoftheachievementeffectperdollarifweusedimpactsmorethan

    tenyearsafterevents,orsmallereffectswithashorterwindow.

    Ourpreferredestimates,basedonthegradientofstudentachievementwith

    respecttodistrictincome,indicatethatanSFRraisesachievementinadistrictwith

    logaverageincomeonepointbelowthestatemean,relativetoadistrictatthe

    mean,by0.1standarddeviationsaftertenyears.Ourfinanceestimatesindicatethat

    thisdistrictsawanincreaseinrelativestateaidof$622perpupilforeachofthose

    tenyears,andanincreaseintotalrevenuesof$424perpupil.

    $424perpupilinspendingeachyearfromkindergartenthroughgrade8,

    discountedtothestudent’skindergartenyearusinga3%rate,correspondstoa

    presentdiscountedcostof$3,400.Chettyetal.(2011)estimatethata0.1standard

  • 34

    deviationincreaseinkindergartentestscorestranslatesintoincreasedearningsin

    adulthoodwithpresentvalueof$5,350perpupil.Thisimpliesabenefit-costratioof

    1.5,evenwhenonlyearningsimpactsarecountedasbenefits.28

    Thisratioisnotwhollyrobust.Ourquintileanalysisshowslargerrevenue

    effects,implyingabenefit-costratiobelowone,whileJacksonetal.’s(2016)studyof

    theeffectsofearlierfinancereformsonstudents’adultoutcomesimpliesmuch

    largerbenefitsperdollarthandoesourcalculation.Thus,althoughthesesortsof

    calculationsarequiteimprecise,theevidenceappearstoindicatethatthespending

    enabledbyfinancereformswascost-effective,evenwithoutaccountingfor

    beneficialdistributionaleffects.

    Itisimportanttonotethatourresearchdesignispoorlysuitedtoidentifying

    theoptimalallocationofschoolresourcesacrossexpenditurecategories,orto

    testingwhetheractualallocationsareclosetooptimal.Itallowsusonlytosaythat

    theaveragefinancereform—whichweinterprettoinvolveroughlyunconstrained

    increasesinresources,thoughinsomecasestheadditionalfundswereearmarked

    forparticularprogramsortiedtootherreforms—ledtoaproductive(though

    perhapsnotmaximallyproductive)useofthefunds.29

    Ourresultsthusshowthatmoneycananddoesmatterineducation,and

    complementsimilarresultsforthelong-runimpactsofschoolfinancereformsfrom

    Jacksonetal.(2016).Schoolfinancereformsareblunttools,andsomecritics

    28Theearningseffectsofincreasesin8thgradetestscoresarelikelylargerthanthoseofincreasesinKindergartenscores,sousingestimatesofthelatterbiasesourbenefitcalculationdownward.29Strongerschoolaccountabilitymayprovideincentivestoschoolstoallocatetheirresourcesmoreefficiently(Hanushek2006).Weinvestigatedspecificationsthatallowedforinteractionsbetweenfinancereformeventsandthestate’saccountabilitypolicy,butfoundnoevidenceforthis.

  • 35

    (Hanushek,2006;Hoxby,2001)havearguedthattheywillbeoffsetbychangesin

    districtorvoterchoicesovertaxratesorthatfundswillbespentsoinefficientlyas

    tobewasted.Ourresultsdonotsupporttheseclaims.Courtsandlegislaturescan

    evidentlyforceimprovementsinschoolqualityforstudentsinlow-incomedistricts.

    Butthereisanimportantcaveattothisconclusion.AswediscussinSection

    VI,theaveragelow-incomestudentdoesnotliveinaparticularlylow-income

    district,soisnotwelltargetedbyatransferofresourcestothelatter.Thus,wefind

    thatfinancereformsreducedachievementgapsbetweenhigh-andlow-income

    schooldistrictsbutdidnothavedetectableeffectsonresourceorachievementgaps

    betweenhigh-andlow-income(orwhiteandblack)students.Attackingthesegaps

    viaschoolfinancepolicieswouldrequirechangingtheallocationofresourceswithin

    schooldistricts,somethingthatwasnotattemptedbythereformsthatwestudy.

  • 36

    References

    Bai,J.(1997).Estimationofachangepointinmultipleregressionmodels.ReviewofEconomicsandStatistics,79(4),551-563.

    Baker,B.D.,&Green,P.C.(2015).Conceptionsofequityandadequacyinschoolfinance.InH.F.LaddandM.E.Goertz,eds.,HandbookofResearchinEducationFinanceandPolicy,2ndedition.NewYork,NY:Routledge.

    Burtless,G.(1996).DoesMoneyMatter?TheEffectofSchoolResourcesonStudentAchievementandAdultSuccess.Washington,D.C.:BrookingsInstitutionPress.

    Card,D.,&Krueger,A.B.(1992a).Doesschoolqualitymatter?ReturnstoeducationandthecharacteristicsofpublicschoolsintheUnitedStates.JournalofPoliticalEconomy,100(1),1–40.

    Card,D.,&Krueger,A.B.(1992b).Schoolqualityandblack-whiterelativeearnings:Adirectassessment.QuarterlyJournalofEconomics,107(1),151-200.

    Card,D.;Mas,A.,&Rothstein,J.(2008).Tippingandthedynamicsofsegregation.QuarterlyJournalofEconomics,123(1),177–218.

    Card,D.,&Payne,A.A.(2002).Schoolfinancereform,thedistributionofschoolspending,andthedistributionofstudenttestscores.JournalofPublicEconomics,83(1),49-82.

    Cascio,E.U.,Gordon,N.,&Reber,S.(2013).Localresponsestofederalgrants:evidencefromtheintroductionoftitleIintheSouth.AmericanEconomicJournal:EconomicPolicy,5(3),126-159.

    Cascio,E.U.,&Reber,S.(2013).ThepovertygapinschoolspendingfollowingtheintroductionofTitleI.AmericanEconomicReview,103(3),423-427.

    Cellini,S.,Ferreira,F.,&Rothstein,J.(2010).Thevalueofschoolfacilityinvestments:Evidencefromadynamicregressiondiscontinuitydesign.QuarterlyJournalofEconomics125(1),215-261.

    Chetty,R.,Friedman,J.N.,Hilger,N.,Saez,E.,Schanzenbach,D.W.,&YaganD.(2011).HowdoesyourKindergartenclassroomaffectyourearnings?EvidencefromProjectSTAR.QuarterlyJournalofEconomics,126(4),1593-1660.

    Clark,M.A.(2003).Educationreform,redistribution,andstudentachievement:EvidencefromtheKentuckyEducationReformAct.Unpublishedworkingpaper,MathematicaPolicyResearch,Princeton,NJ.

    Coleman,J.S.,Campbell,E.Q.,Hobson,C.J.,McPartland,J.,Mood,A.M.,Weinfeld,F.D.,&York,R.(1966).EqualityofEducationalOpportunity.Washington,DC,1066-5684.

    Coons,J.E.,Clune,W.H.,&Sugarman,S.(1970).PrivateWealthandPublicEducation.Cambridge,MA:BelknapPress.

    Corcoran,S.P.,&Evans,W.N.(2015).Equity,adequacy,andtheevolvingstateroleineducationfinance.InH.F.LaddandM.E.Goertz,eds.,HandbookofResearchinEducationFinanceandPolicy,2ndedition.NewYork:Routledge.

    Dee,T.S.,&Jacob,B.(2011).TheimpactofNoChildLeftBehindonstudentachievement.JournalofPolicyAnalysisandManagement,30(3),418-446.

  • 37

    Downes,T.,Stiefel,L.(2015).Measuringequityandadequacyinschoolfinance.InH.F.Ladd&M.E.Goertz,eds.,HandbookofResearchinEducationFinanceandPolicy,2ndedition.NewYork,NY:Routledge.

    Duncombe,W.D.,Nguyen-Hoang,P.,&J.Yinger(2015).Measurementofcostdifferentials.InH.F.Ladd,&M.E.Goertz,eds.,HandbookofResearchinEducationFinanceandPolicy,2ndedition.NewYork,NY:Routledge.

    Dynarski,S.,Hyman,J.,&Schanzenbach,D.W.(2013).Experimentalevidenceontheeffectofchildhoodinvestmentsonpostsecondaryattainmentanddegreecompletion.JournalofPolicyAnalysisandManagement,32(4),692-717.

    Fischel,W.A.(1989).DidSerranocauseProposition13?NationalTaxJournal42(4):465-73.

    Flanagan,A.E.,andMurray,S.E.(2004).ADecadeofReform:TheImpactofSchoolReforminKentucky.InJ.Yinger,ed.,HelpingChildrenLeftBehind:StateAidandthePursuitofEducationalEquity(pp.165-213).Cambridge,MA:MITPress.

    Guryan,J.(2001).Doesmoneymatter?Regression-discontinuityestimatesfromeducationfinancereforminMassachusetts.NationalBureauofEconomicResearchWorkingPaperNo.8269.

    Hanushek,E.A.(1986).Theeconomicsofschooling:Productionandefficiencyinpublicschools.JournalofEconomicLiterature,24(3),1141-1177.

    Hanushek,E.A.(1997).Assessingtheeffectsofschoolresourcesonstudentperformance:Anupdate.EducationalEvaluationandPolicyAnalysis,19(2),141-164.

    Hanushek,E.A.(2003).Thefailureofinput-basedschoolingpolicies.TheEconomicJournal,113,F64-F98.

    Hanushek,E.A.(2006).Schoolresources.InE.A.HanushekandF.Welch,eds.,HandbookoftheEconomicsofEducation,vol.2.Elsevier.

    Hanushek,E.A.&Lindseth,A.A.(2009).Schoolhouses,CourthousesandStatehouses:SolvingtheFunding-AchievementPuzzleinAmerica’sPublicSchools.Princeton:PrincetonUniversityPress.

    Hanushek,E.A.,Rivkin,S.G.,&Taylor,L.L.(1996a).Aggregationandtheestimatedeffectsofschoolresources.TheReviewofEconomicsandStatistics78(4),611-627.

    Hanushek,E.A.,Rivkin,S.G.,&Taylor,L.L.(1996b).Theidentificationofschoolresourceeffects.EducationEconomics,4(2),105-125.

    Horowitz,H.(1966).Unseparatebutunequal:TheemergingFourteenthAmendmentissueinpublicschooleducation.UCLALawReview,13,1147-1172.

    Hoxby,C.M.(2001).Allschoolfinanceequalizationsarenotcreatedequal.TheQuarterlyJournalofEconomics,116(4),1189-1231.

    Hyman,J.(2013).Doesmoneymatterinthelongrun?Effectsofschoolspendingoneducationalattainment.Unpublishedmanuscript.

    Jackson,C.K.,Johnson,R.C.,&Persico,C.(2016).Theeffectsofschoolspendingoneducationalandeconomicoutcomes:Evidencefromschoolfinancereforms.QuarterlyJournalofEconomics131(1),157-218.

  • 38

    Kirp,D.L.(1968).Thepoor,theschools,andequalprotection.HarvardEducationalReview38,635-668.

    Koski,W.S.,&Hahnel,J.(2015).Thepast,presentandfutureofeducationalfinancereformlitigation.InH.F.LaddandM.E.Goertz,eds.,HandbookofResearchinEducationFinanceandPolicy,2ndedition.NewYork:Routledge.

    Krueger,A.B.(1999).Experimentalestimatesofeducationproductionfunctions.TheQuarterlyJournalofEconomics,114(2),497-532.

    Krueger,A.B.(2003).Economicconsiderationsandclasssize.TheEconomicJournal113,F34-F63.

    Krueger,A.B.,&Whitmore,D.M.(2002).Wouldsmallerclasseshelpclosetheblack-whiteachievementgap?InJ.E.ChubbandT.Loveless,eds.,BridgingtheAchievementGap.Washington:BrookingsInstitutionPress.

    Ladd,H.F.,&Goertz,M.E.(Eds.).(2015).HandbookofResearchinEducationFinanceandPolicy,2ndEdition.NewYork,NY:Routledge.

    Levine,P.B.,&Schanzenbach,D.(2009).Theimpactofchildren’spublichealthinsuranceexpansionsoneducationaloutcomes.ForumforHealthEconomics&Policy,12(1),1-26.

    Martorell,P.,Stange,K.M.,&McFarlin,I.(2015).Investinginschools:Capitalspending,facilityconditions,andstudentachievement.NBERWorkingPaper21515,September.

    Murray,S.E.,Evans,W.N.,&Schwab,R.M.(1998).Education-financereformandthedistributionofeducationresources.AmericanEconomicReview,88(4),789-812.

    Nielson,C.,&Zimmerman,S.(2014).Theeffectofschoolconstructionontestscores,schoolenrollment,andhomeprices.JournalofPublicEconomics120.

    Sims,D.P.(2011a).Liftingallboats?Financelitigation,educationresources,andstudentneedsinthepost-Roseera.EducationFinanceandPolicy,6(4),455-485.

    Sims,D.P.(2011b).Suingforyoursupper?Resourceallocation,teachercompensationandfinancelawsuits.EconomicsofEducationReview,30(5),1034-1044.

    Wise,A.(1967).RichSchools,PoorSchools:ThePromiseofEqualEducationalOpportunity.Chicago,IL:UniversityofChicagoPress.

  • Figures

    Figure 1: Mean revenues per pupil for highest and lowest income school districts, 1990-2012

    80

    00

    10

    00

    01

    20

    00

    14

    00

    0Q

    1,

    Q5

    Me

    an

    To

    tal R

    eve

    nu

    es

    1990 1995 2000 2005 2010Year

    Q1 Mean Q5 Mean

    Notes: Highest (lowest) income districts are those in the top (bottom) 20% of their states’ district-leveldistributions of mean household income in 1990, and are labeled as ”Q5” and ”Q1”, respectively. Seeappendix for details of quintile classifications. Revenues are expressed in real 2013 dollars. Districts areaveraged within states, weighing by log district enrollment; states are then averaged without weights. Hawaiiand the District of Columbia are excluded.

    39

  • Figure 2: Gap in revenues per pupil between lowest and highest income districts, by state finance reformstatus, 1990-2012

    −1

    00

    0−

    50

    00

    50

    01

    00

    0

    Q1

    −Q

    5 M

    ea

    n T

    ota

    l R

    eve

    nu

    es

    1990 1995 2000 2005 2010

    Year

    No Reform States Finance Reform States

    Notes: See notes to Figure 1. Finance reform states are those with school finance reforms between 1990 and2011, as listed in Appendix Table A1. Lines show unweighted best linear fit to time series.

    40

  • Figure 3: Gap in average test scores between lowest and highest income districts, by state finance reformstatus, 1990-2011

    −.7

    −.6

    −.5

    −.4

    Q1

    −Q

    5 M

    ea

    n S

    co

    re

    1990 1995 2000 2005 2010

    Year

    No Reform States Finance Reform States

    Notes: Lowest (Q1) and highest (Q5) income districts are defined as in Figure 1. NAEP observations indistricts in each quintile are averaged, using NAEP sampling weights and separately for each grade andsubject tested, and the Q1-Q5 di↵erence is computed for each state. State-grade-subject Q1-Q5 di↵erencesare averaged separately for each group of states, weighting by the harmonic mean of the sum of the studentweights in Q1 and Q5 districts. Lines show best linear fit to the time series.

    41

  • Figure 4: Timing of school finance events

    02

    46

    8E

    ven

    ts p

    er

    yea

    r

    1990 2000 2010Year

    Statute

    Court

    Notes: Each entry represents a state with a school finance reform event (a major court ruling and/orsubstantial statutory change) in a particular year. States may have multiple events. When states havemultiple events in the same year, they are counted only once, as a court event if any of the events were courtrulings and as a statute otherwise. Events are listed in Appendix Table A1.

    42

  • Figure 5: Geographic distribution of post-1989 school finance events

    No Event

    Post-1990 Reform Event

    Notes: Map indicates states that had school finance reform events, as listed in Appendix Table A1, between1990 and 2011.

    43

  • Figure 6: State revenues per pupil vs. district income, Ohio, 1990 and 2012

    05000

    10000

    15000

    20000

    9.5 10 10.5 11 11.5 12

    1990

    05000

    10000

    15000

    20000

    9.5 10 10.5 11 11.5 12

    2012

    Sta

    te a

    id p

    er

    pupil

    (2013$)

    ln(district avg. HH income, 1990)

    Notes: Each circle represents one district; size is proportional to average district enrollment over 1990-2012.Solid lines represent a regression of state revenue per pupil (2013$) on log 1990 district mean householdincome, controlling for enrollment and district type (see footnote 16). Dashed lines represent means amongdistricts in each quintile of the district mean income distribution.

    44

  • Figure 7: Progressivity of state revenue distributions, Ohio, 1990-2012

    10

    00

    20

    00

    30

    00

    40

    00

    50

    00

    20

    13

    $ p

    er

    pu

    pil

    1990 1995 2000 2005 2010Fiscal year

    Q1−Q5 difference

    −1*(Log income gradients)

    Notes: Dark line represents the di↵erence in mean state revenue per pupil (2013$) between the lowest (Q1)and highest (Q5) income districts in Ohio. Districts are classified based on 1990 mean household incomeand are weighted by log enrollment; see notes to Figure 1 for details. Lighter line represents regressions ofstate revenue per pupil on log mean income, controlling for enrollment and district type (see footnote 16); inthis figure, coe�cients are multiplied by -1 to facilitate comparisons. Solid vertical lines represent plainti↵victories in the Ohio Supreme Court in De Rolph v State I, II, and IV in 1997, 2000, and 2002.

    45

  • Figure 8: Event study estimates of e↵ects of school finance reforms on mean state and total revenues

    −2000

    −1000

    01000

    2000

    Change in

    mean s

    tate

    reve

    nues

    −5 0 5 10 15 20Years Since Event

    Non−Parametric Estimate Parametric Estimate

    (a) State revenue

    −2000

    −1000

    01000

    2000

    Change in

    mean tota

    l reve

    nues

    −5 0 5 10 15 20Years Since Event

    Non−Parametric Estimate Parametric Estimate

    (b) Total revenue

    Notes: Figure displays coe�cients from event study regressions, where the dependent variable is mean state(panel A) and total (panel B) revenues per pupil (2013$) across all districts in a state. Dashed lines showthe three-parameter parametric model (equation 2). Solid lines show the non-parametric model (equation3), with the event year (indicated as 0) as the excluded category; dotted lines represent 95% confidenceintervals. Estimates for the parametric models are reported in Table 3, Panel A, Columns 2 and 4. p valuesfor omnibus hypothesis tests of zero pre- and post-event e↵ects in the non-parametric model are 0.31 and¡0.001, respectively, in Panel A, and 0.15 and ¡0.001 in Panel B. In the parametric model, the p-value forthe hypothesis that the pre-event trend is zero is 0.18 in Panel A and 0.79 in Panel B; for the test that thepost-event jump and change in trend is zero it is 0.11 and 0.01, respectively.

    46

  • Figure 9: Event study estimates of e↵ects of school finance reforms on mean revenues in lowest and highestincome districts

    −2000

    −1000

    01000

    2000

    Change in

    Q1 m

    ean s

    tate

    reve

    nues

    −5 0 5 10 15 20Years Since Event

    Non−Parametric Estimate Parametric Estimate

    (a) State revenue, Q1−

    2000

    −1000

    01000

    2000

    Change in

    Q1 m

    ean tota

    l reve

    nues

    −5 0 5 10 15 20Years Since Event

    Non−Parametric Estimate Parametric Estimate

    (b) Total revenue, Q1

    −2000

    −1000

    01000

    2000

    Change in

    Q5 m

    ean s

    tate

    reve

    nues

    −5 0 5 10 15 20Years Since Event

    Non−Parametric Estimate Parametric Estimate

    (c) State revenue, Q5

    −2000

    −1000

    01000

    2000

    Change in

    Q5 m

    ean tota

    l reve

    nues

    −5 0 5 10 15 20Years Since Event

    Non−Parametric Estimate Parametric Estimate

    (d) Total revenue, Q5

    Notes: Figure displays coe�cients from event study regressions. Dependent variables are mean state revenuesin the lowest income quintile of districts (panel A), mean total revenues in these districts (panel B), andmean state and total revenues in the highest income quintile of districts (panels C and D, respectively), allmeasured in 2013 dollars per pupil. Dashed lines show the three-parameter parametric model (equation 2).Solid lines shows the non-parametric model (equation 3), with the event year (indicated as 0) as the excludedcategory; dotted lines represent 95% confidence intervals. Estimates for the parametric models are reportedin Table 3, Panels B and C, Columns 2 and 4. p values for omnibus hypothesis tests of zero post-evente↵ects in the non-parametric model in Panels A-D are 0.53, 0.39, 0.41, and 0.74, respectively; p-values forzero pre-event e↵ects are ¡0.001 in all panels. In the parametric model, the p-values for the hypothesis thatthe pre-event trend is zero are 0.24, 0.68, 0.21, and 0.78; for the test that the post-event jump and changein trend is zero they are 0.01, ¡0.001, 0.30, and 0.22.

    47

  • Figure 10: Event study estimates of e↵ects of school finance reforms on progressivity of district revenues

    −2000

    −1000

    01000

    2000

    Change in

    Q1−

    Q5 m

    ean tota

    l reve

    nues

    −5 0 5 10 15 20Years Since Event

    Non−Parametric Estimate Parametric Estimate

    (a) Q1-Q5 mean

    −2000

    −1000

    01000

    Change in

    tota

    l reve

    nue s

    lope

    −5 0 5 10 15 20Years Since Event

    Non−Parametric Estimate Parametric Estimate

    (b) Total revenue slope

    Notes: Figure displays coe�cients from event study regressions. Dependent variables are the di↵erence inmean total revenues per pupil (in 2013$) between districts in the bottom and top quintile by mean familyincome in the state (panel A), and the slope of total per-pupil revenues (in 2013$) with respect to logmean family income, controlling for log enrollment and district type (panel B). Dashed lines show the three-parameter parametric model (equation 2). Solid lines shows the non-parametric model (equation 3), withthe event year (indicated as 0) as the excluded category; dotted lines represent 95% confidence intervals.Estimates for the parametric models are reported in Table 4, Panels A and B, Columns 2 and 4. p-valuesfor omnibus hypothesis tests of zero pre-event e↵ects in the non-parametric model are 0.86 in Panel A and0.96 in Panel B; p-values for zero post-event e↵ects are ¡0.001 in each panel. In the parametric model, thep-value for the hypothesis that the pre-event trend is zero is 0.72 in Panel A and 0.58 in Panel B; for thetest that the post-event jump and change in trend is zero it is 0.01 and 0.11, respectively.

    48

  • Figure 11: Event study estimates of e↵ects of school finance reforms on progressivity of test scores

    −.3

    −.2

    −.1

    0.1

    Ch

    an

    ge

    in t

    est

    sco

    re s

    lop

    e

    −5 0 5 10 15 20Years Since Event

    Non−Parametric Estimate Parametric Estimate

    Notes: Figure displays coe�cients from event study regressions. Dependent variable is the slope of meantest scores with respect to log mean family income, controlling for log enrollment. Dashed lines show thethree-parameter parametric model (equation 2). Solid lines shows the non-parametric model (equation 3),with the event year (indicated as 0) as the excluded category; dotted lines represent 95% confidence intervals.Both event study regressions include state and subject-grade-year fixed e↵ects. Estimates for the parametricmodels are reported in Table 6, Column 1. p-values for the hypothesis that pre-event e↵ects are zero are 0.43in the non-parametric model and 0.80 in the parametric model; for zero post-event e↵ects, they are ¡0.001and 0.02, respectively.

    49

  • Figure 12: Event study estimates of e↵ects of school finance reforms on mean test scores in highest andlowest income school districts

    −.1

    0.1

    .2.3

    Change in

    Q1 M

    ean T

    est

    Sco

    res

    −5 0 5 10 15 20Years Since Event

    Non−Parametric Estimate Parametric Estimate

    (a) Q1 mean test scores

    −.1

    0.1

    .2.3

    Change in

    Q5 M

    ean T

    est

    Sco

    res

    −5 0 5 10 15 20Years Since Event

    Non−Parametric Estimate Parametric Estimate

    (b) Q5 mean test scores

    Notes: Figure displays coe�cients from event study regressions. Dependent variables are mean test scores forstudents at districts in the bottom quintile (panel A) or top quintile (panel B) of the state’s distribution of1990 district mean household incomes. Dashed lines show the three-parameter parametric model (equation2). Solid lines shows the non-parametric model (equation 3), with the event year (indicated as 0) as theexcluded category; dotted lines represent 95% confidence intervals. Both event study regressions includestate and subject-grade-year fixed e↵ects. p-values for omnibus hypothesis tests of zero pre-event e↵ects inthe non-parametric model are 0.01 in Panel A and 0.02 in Panel B; p-values for zero post-event e↵ects are¡0.001 in each panel. In the parametric model, the p-value for the hypothesis that the pre-event trend is zerois 0.59 in Panel A and 0.10 in Panel B; for the test that the post-event jump and change in trend is zero itis 0.01 and 0.34, respectively.

    50

  • Tables

    Table 1: NAEP Testing Years

    Year Subjects and grades covered Number of Number ofMath G4 Math G8 Reading G4 Reading G8 States Students

    1990 X 38 97,9001992 X X X 42 321,1201994 X 41 104,8901996 X X 45 228,9801998 X X 41 206,8102000 X X 42 201,1102002 X X 51 270,2302003 X X X X 51 691,3602005 X X X X 51 674,4202007 X X X X 51 711,3602009 X X X X 51 775,0602011 X X X X 51 749,250

    Notes: In final column, students are cumulated across all tested subjects and grades, and rounded to thenearest 10.

    51

  • Table 2: Summary statistics

    (a) District-year panel

    Overall Mean by subgroup

    N Mean SD Q1 Q5

    Enrollment 229,386 67,523 181,811 13,738 30,019

    Log(mean income, 1990) 223,334 10.53 .2935 10.21 10.9

    Total revenue p.p. 229,386 11,087 3,489 10,803 11,884

    State 229,386 5,135 2,291 6,373 4,007

    Local 229,386 5,094 3,273 3,257 7,359

    Federal 229,386 858.2 641.4 1,173 519.1

    Expenditures p.p. 229,386 11,264 3,685 10,831 12,125

    Instructional 229,386 5,845 1,953 5,661 6,180

    Non-instructional 229,386 5,419 2,221 5,169 5,944

    NAEP scores 49,867 .2559 .4578 .02941 .5887

    (b) State-year panel

    N Q1 Q5 Q1-Q5 di↵erence Gradient

    Mean SD Mean SD Mean SD Mean SD

    Log(mean income, 1990) 49 10.2 .135 10.8 .234 -.645 .167

    Total revenue p.p. 1,078 11,527 3,905 11,844 3,351 -329 2,158 539 3,574

    State 1,078 6,552 2,822 4,347 2,006 2,196 2,244 -3,086 3,470

    Local 1,078 3,658 1,600 6,893 3,477 -3,231 2,624 5,190 3,313

    Federal 1,078 1,317 1,082 604 482 706 722 -1,565 1,532

    Mean NAEP score 532 .0372 .316 .511 .303 -.474 .318 .955 .337

    Notes: Panel (a) reports summary statistics at the district by year level, weighted by district enrollmentfor the financial variables and by the sum of the student weights for the mean NAEP score. Panel (b) showssummary statistics for the unweighted state-year panel.

    52

  • Table 3: Event study estimates of e↵ects of school finance reforms on mean revenues per pupil, by districtincome

    State Revenue Total Revenue

    1p 3p 1p 3p

    Mean:

    Post Event 912⇤⇤ 672⇤⇤ 829⇤⇤⇤ 839⇤⇤⇤

    (359) (320) (302) (269)Trend 68 9

    (50) (32)Post Event * Yrs Elapsed -61 -17

    (60) (52)

    Observations 1,078 1,078 1,078 1,078

    Q1 Mean:

    Post Event 1,225⇤⇤⇤ 954⇤⇤⇤ 1,233⇤⇤⇤ 1,164⇤⇤⇤

    (343) (302) (370) (287)Trend 60 16

    (50) (39)Post Event * Yrs Elapsed -40 -11

    (70) (70)

    Observations 1,078 1,078 1,078 1,078

    Q5 Mean:

    Post Event 527 351 544⇤⇤ 471⇤

    (378) (325) (277) (277)Trend 72 9

    (56) (32)Post Event * Yrs Elapsed -84 2

    (61) (41)

    Observations 1,076 1,076 1,076 1,076

    Notes: Table reports estimates of the parametric event study models, equations (1) (columns 1 and3) and (2) (columns 2 and 4). Dependent variables are mean state revenues per pupil (columns 1-2) andmean total revenues per pupil (columns 3-4), weighting districts by their log enrollment; each is computedseparately for each state and year. In panel A, means are computed over all districts in each state; in panelsB and C, they are computed over the bottom and top, respectively, quintiles of the states’ district 1990mean household income distributions. Event study regressions include state and year fixed e↵ects, and areunweighted. Standard errors clustered at the state level.

    53

  • Table 4: Event study estimates of e↵ects of school finance reforms on progressivity of school finance

    State Revenue Total Revenue

    1p 3p 1p 3p

    Q1-Q5 Mean:

    Post Event 711⇤⇤ 606⇤⇤⇤ 701⇤⇤ 696⇤⇤⇤

    (316) (231) (309) (243)Trend -10 9

    (25) (24)Post Event * Yrs Elapsed 42 -14

    (36) (44)

    Observations 1,076 1,076 1,076 1,076

    Slopes:

    Post Event -622⇤⇤⇤ -522⇤⇤ -424 -469⇤⇤

    (223) (209) (304) (233)Trend -11 -25

    (25) (45)Post Event * Yrs Elapsed -5 53

    (21) (61)

    Observations 1,078 1,078 1,078 1,078

    Notes: Table reports estimates of the parametric event study models, equations (1) (columns 1 and3) and (2) (columns 2 and 4). In Panel A, dependent variable is the gap in state (columns 1-2) or total(columns 3-4) revenues per pupil between districts in the bottom and top quintiles of the states’ district 1990mean household income distributions. In Panel B, dependent variable is the coe�cient from a district-levelregression of the relevant per-pupil revenue measure on the log of the district’s 1990 mean household income,controlling for district log enrollment and district type (elementary / secondary / unified) and weighting bythe district’s average log enrollment over time. Event study regressions include state and year fixed e↵ects.Event study regressions are unweighted in Panel A, and is weighted by the inverse squared standard errorof the dependent variable in Panel B. Standard errors clustered at the state level.

    54

  • Table 5: Event study estimates of e↵ects of school finance reforms on components of district finance

    Mean of depvar Mean Q1 Mean Q1-Q5 Mean Slope

    Revenue E↵ects:

    Total revenue 11,593 829⇤⇤⇤ 1,233⇤⇤⇤ 701⇤⇤ -424(302) (370) (309) (304)

    State revenue 5,449 912⇤⇤ 1,225⇤⇤⇤ 711⇤⇤ -622⇤⇤⇤

    (359) (343) (316) (223)Local revenue 5,238 -146 -126 -126 90

    (307) (233) (235) (339)Federal revenue 907 63 134 116 34

    (83) (143) (116) (33)

    Expenditure E↵ects:

    Total expenditures 11,595 907⇤⇤⇤ 1,377⇤⇤⇤ 753⇤⇤ -449(290) (367) (309) (309)

    Current instructional exp. 6,000 443⇤⇤⇤ 604⇤⇤⇤ 243⇤ -161(134) (155) (127) (208)

    Teacher salaries + benefits 5,533 339⇤⇤ 449⇤⇤⇤ 143 -103(153) (169) (117) (189)

    Mean teacher salary 63,425 -286 -245 272 -259(1,024) (1,107) (947) (1,122)

    Pupil teacher ratio 15.40 -0.60⇤⇤⇤ -0.66⇤⇤⇤ 0.01 0.23(0.19) (0.19) (0.20) (0.17)

    Non-instructional exp 5,595 464⇤⇤ 773⇤⇤⇤ 511⇤⇤ -232(186) (257) (235) (176)

    Student support 3,426 221⇤⇤ 299⇤⇤ 100 -81(102) (119) (83) (88)

    Total capital outlays 1,076 272⇤⇤ 486⇤⇤⇤ 369⇤⇤ -87(114) (177) (181) (78)

    Other current exp. 431.0 7.9 9.2 -2.5 -2.9(12.4) (14.5) (13.3) (12.1)

    Notes: Each entry in columns 2-5 represents the coe�cient from a separate event study regression, usingthe one-parameter specification in equation (1). Dependent variables are constructed from district-levelfinance summaries indicated by row headings and expressed in per-pupil terms; means across districts arereported in column 1. Specifications correspond to columns 1 and 2 of Table 3, panels A (column 2) and B(column 3), and Table 4, panels A (column 4) and B (column 5). See notes to Tables 3 and 4.

    55

  • Table 6: Event study estimates of e↵ects of school finance reforms on student achievement

    Slopes Q1 Q5 Q1-Q5

    (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)

    Post Event * Yrs Elapsed -0.011⇤⇤ -0.010⇤⇤⇤ 0.007⇤⇤ -0.001 0.008⇤⇤ 0.014⇤⇤

    (0.004) (0.003) (0.003) (0.004) (0.004) (0.005)

    Trend 0.001 -0.007(0.003) (0.005)

    Post Event 0.001 0.011(0.023) (0.024)

    Observations 1498 1498 1509 1507 1505 1505p, total event e↵ect=0 0.02 0.01 0.01 0.84 0.05 0.04State FEs X X X X X XSub-gr-yr FEs X X X X X X

    Notes: Each column represents a separate event study regression, using specification (2) and, in columns2-5, constraining �jump = �trend = 0. Dependent variable in columns 1-2 is the slope of test scores with re-spect to log mean 1990 income in the district, using NAEP weights and controlling for log district enrollment.In columns 3-4, dependent variable is the weighted mean score in districts in the bottom or top quintile,respectively, of the state district-level income distribution. In columns 5-6, dependent variable is the di↵er-ence between the bottom and top quintiles. All are computed separately for each state-year-subject-gradecell with available data. All event study specifications include state and subject-grade-year fixed e↵ects, andare weighted by the inverse squared standard error of the dependent variable. p-values for total event e↵ectin columns 1 and 6 test the hypothesis that the �jump and �phasein coe�cients are both zero; in columns2-5, the p-value is for the hypothesis that �phasein = 0, with �jump constrained to zero.

    56

  • Table 7: Event study estimates of e↵ects of school finance reforms on student achievement by subject andgrade

    Test Score Slope Q1-Q5 Mean

    Pooled -0.010⇤⇤⇤ 0.008⇤⇤

    (0.003) (0.004)

    By Subject :

    Math -0.012⇤⇤⇤ 0.007⇤

    (0.003) (0.004)Reading -0.006 0.008⇤

    (0.005) (0.004)

    Di↵erence -0.006 -0.001p-value 0.09 0.68

    By Grade:

    G4 -0.010⇤⇤ 0.008(0.005) (0.005)

    G8 -0.010⇤⇤ 0.008⇤⇤

    (0.004) (0.004)

    Di↵erence 0.000 -0.000p-value 0.93 0.96

    Notes: First row repeats specifications from Table 6, columns 2 and 5. See notes to that table for details.Subsequent models restrict the event study sample to slope and quintile gaps computed in specific subjectsor grades. Di↵erence entries report the di↵erence in coe�cients between math and reading or grade 4 andgrade 8 specifications, with p-values for the hypothesis that the event study coe�cient is equal in the twosubsamples.

    57

  • Table 8: Sensitivity of event study estimates to the treatment of states with multiple events

    Selected Events All events (stacked) Initial court events

    Panel A: Gradients

    State revenue p.p. -622⇤⇤⇤ -479⇤⇤⇤ -432⇤

    (223) (160) (222)Total revenue p.p. -424 -197 -399

    (304) (269) (292)NAEP scores -0.010⇤⇤⇤ -0.009⇤⇤⇤ -0.009⇤⇤⇤